Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
Omega
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/omega
Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective$
L.P. Kerkhove a, M. Vanhoucke a,b,c,n
a
b
c
Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, Ghent University, Ghent, Belgium
Technology and Operations Management Area, Vlerick Business School, Ghent, Belgium
UCL School of Management, University College London, London, UK
art ic l e i nf o
a b s t r a c t
Article history:
Received 14 November 2014
Accepted 3 September 2015
Due to the adoption of more and more complex incentive contract structures for projects, designing the
best contract for a specific situation has become an increasingly daunting task for project owners.
Through the combination of findings from contracting literature with knowledge from the domain of
project management, a quantitative model for the contract design problem is constructed. The contribution of this research is twofold. First of all, a comprehensive and quantitative methodology to
analyse incentive contract design is introduced, based on an extensive review of the existing literature.
Secondly, based on this methodology, computational experiments are carried out, which result in a set of
managerial guidelines for incentive contract design. Our analysis shows that substantial improvements
can often be attained by using contracts which include incentives for cost, duration as well as scope
simultaneously. Moreover, nonlinear and piecewise linear formulae to calculate the incentive amounts
are shown to improve both the performance and robustness across different projects.
& 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Keywords:
Incentives
Contracting
Project Management
Decision Making
Strategy
1. Introduction
The project owner and the contractor executing the project are
two separated economic actors, each with their own set of
potentially conflicting objectives [53,80]. Hence, when the owner
expedites work to a contractor, a relationship must be established.
The nature of this relationship can be plotted on a spectrum
between an explicitly negotiated contract and an alliance in which
both parties are formally unified into a single economic actor for
the duration of the project. For projects where complexity is
limited, an explicit contract which specifies the deliverables can
suffice [82]. For complex projects on the other hand, it may be
more favourable to unify both actors in an alliance structure,
effectively forming a single economic entity [84]. Although valuable arguments can be made in favour of such alliance structures
[61], the implementation of such a structure is often highly complex [10]. Hence, the inclusion of incentive clauses, which form the
middle ground in the relational spectrum between explicit contracts and alliances, can provide a more workable alternative [9].
Performance related pay in general [25,27,90], and the design of
incentivised agreements for projects in particular (see Table 1)
have been widely studied in academic literature over the last
decades. Notwithstanding these recent advances, little guidance is
available for project owners on how to identify the best contract
for a specific project environment.
The aim of this paper is to provide a quantitative framework for
incentive contract design in projects, which can be used by the
project owner to select the most adequate contract for any given
project environment. This quantitative framework consists of
three components: a trade-off model describing the nature of the
project, an evaluation model describing the valuation of the different outcomes of the project for both the owner and contractor,
and a contract model which is capable of representing the
majority of (incentivised) contractual agreements used in practice.
Using these models, computational experiments have been
carried out to investigate the impact of different project environments on the performance of contract types. These experiments
take an economical rather than psychological perspective on the
problem, and therefore assume that the contractor is a risk neutral
profit-maximising actor. This risk-neutrality can be assumed since
we are considering economic actors rather than individuals [32].
The desirability of different types of contracts is judged by taking
into account both the expected profit of the owner, as well as the
degree to which the motivations of the owner and contractor are
aligned.
2. Literature review
☆
This manuscript was processed by Associate Editor Jozefowska.
Corresponding author at: Faculty of Economics and Business Administration,
Ghent University, Ghent, Belgium.
n
Literature relevant to incentive contract design for projects can
be divided into two main categories: literature dealing with the
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002
0305-0483/& 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
2
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
trade-offs in project management and literature concerned with
the design and implications of incentive contracts.
Project management literature dictates that the properties of a
project can be described along three dimensions: the costs associated with the project, the duration of the project and the scope
of a project (also known as the iron triangle [47]). These three
dimensions are viewed as an interrelated trade-off mechanism.
Ceteris paribus, decreasing the cost of a project will be accompanied by an increase in duration and/or a decrease in scope.
Similar statements are also true for the duration and scope
dimensions.
Within the context of this paper these three dimensions are
viewed as the outcomes of the project, as perceived by the project
owner. The cost reflects the financial payment the owner has to
make to the contractor to compensate for the work performed by
the latter, as well as the resources used in the project (insofar as
this amount is variable). The duration represents the time needed
by the contractor to complete the project. The scope of the project
Table 1
Overview of literature on incentive contracting and associated trade-offs.
Author(s)
Meinhart and Delionback [50]
McCall [49]
Cukierman and Shiffer [24]
Hiller and Tollison [35]
Weitzman [87]
Stukhart [75]
Herten and Peeters [34]
McAfee and McMillan [48]
Ryan et al. [64]
William and Ashley [88]
Abu-Hijleh and Ibbs [1]
Veld and Peeters [83]
Rosenfeld and Geltner [63]
Chapman and Ward [18]
Herbsman [33]
Jaraiedi et al. [37]
Ward and Chapman [86]
Jaafari [36]
Al-Subhi Al-Harbi [3]
Arditi and Yasamis [5]
Berends [7]
Paquin et al. [55]
Perry and Barnes [56]
Boukendour and Bah [8]
El-Rayes [28]
Dayanand and Padman [25]
Bower et al. [9]
Broome and Perry [11]
Bubshait [12]
Shr and Chen [71]
Shr and Chen [69]
Shr et al. [70]
Turner [80]
Bayiz and Corbett [6]
El-Rayes and Kandil [29]
Kandil and El-Rayes [38]
Pollack-johnson and Liberatore [57]
Tang et al. [76]
Tareghian and Taheri [78]
Afshar et al. [2]
Lee and Thomas [42]
Rosandich [59]
Sillars [72]
Chapman and Ward [19]
Rose [62]
Stenbeck [74]
Tang et al. [77]
Ghodsi et al. [31]
Ramón and Cristóbal [58]
Anvuur and Kumaraswamy [4]
Chan et al. [14]
Love et al. [44]
Mihm [52]
Rose and Manley [60]
Shahsavari Pour et al. [68]
Zhang and Xing [89]
[22]
Chan et al. [15]
Chan et al. [17]
Dimensionsa
C
D
S
E
I
I
–
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
–
I
I
I
I
I
I
–
I
I
–
–
I
I
I
T
–
T
I
–
T
I
T
I
T
T
–
I
T
T
I
T
I
T
T
I
I
I
I
I
T
T
T
I
I
I
–
I
–
–
I
I
–
–
I
I
I
–
–
I
I
–
I
–
I
–
–
–
–
I
I
I
T
I
I
I
I
–
I
T
I
T
I
T
T
I
I
I
T
I
–
I
T
T
I
–
I
–
I
T
T
I
T
–
I
–
–
–
–
I
I
–
–
I
I
I
–
–
–
I
–
T
–
T
–
T
–
–
–
–
I
T
I
–
–
–
–
–
T
–
T
I
T
T
T
I
–
–
I
I
I
T
T
I
–
I
–
I
T
T
–
T
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
T
–
–
T
–
–
–
–
–
T
–
–
–
–
T
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
T
T
T
–
–
–
–
T
–
T
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
Contract natureb
Cost contract typesc
A þ Bd
Validation5
L
L
L
L
L
L
P
L
L
–
P
P
L
L
L
L
P
P
L
L
P
–
L
P
L
–
P
P
L
L, N
L
L
L
L
–
–
–
–
–
–
L
L
L
L
P
L
L
–
–
L
L
P
L
L
–
–
L
L
L
FPI/TCC, CPIF
FFP, FPI/TCC, CPFF
–
FPI/TCC, CPFF, CPPF
FFP, CPIF, CPFF
FFP, GMP, FPI/TCC, CPFF, CPPF
FFP, FPI/TCC, CPIF, CPFF, CPPF
FFP, CPIF, CPFF, CPPF
FFP, FPI/TCC, CPFF
FFP, CPFF, CPPF
FFP, GMP, CPIF, CPFF, CPPF
FFP, FPI/TCC, CPIF, CPFF, CPPF
FFP, GMP, FPI/TCC, CPIF, CPFF, CPPF
FFP, CPFF, CPPF
–
FPI/TCC, CPIF
FFP, FPI/TCC, CPIF, CPFF
FFP, FPI/TCC
FFP, FPI/TCC, CPIF, CPFF, CPPF
FFP, FPI/TCC, CPIF, CPFF
FFP, FPI/TCC, CPIF, CPFF
–
FPI/TCC
GMP
–
–
FFP, CPIF
FPI/TCC, CPIF, CPFF
FPI/TCC, CPIF, CPFF, CPPF
–
–
–
FFP, GMP, FPI/TCC, CPIF, CPFF, CPPF
FFP
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
FPI/TCC
–
FPI/TCC, CPFF
FFP, CPIF
–
–
–
–
GMP
GMP, FPI/TCC
–
FPI/TCC
CPIF
–
–
–
FFP, GMP, FPI/TCC
GMP, FPI/TCC
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
x
x
–
–
–
x
–
–
–
–
x
–
–
–
–
x
x
x
–
–
x
–
–
–
–
–
x
–
x
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
CS
TE
–
CS, Sur
CS
–
Sur
CS
Sur
TE
–
Sur
–
–
CS, Sim
–
Sur
CS
TE
TE
–
TE
TE
CS
CS
Sur
CS
CS
CS
–
TE
TE
–
TE
Sur
TE
TE
CS
TE, Sim
CS
CS
CS
CS
CS, Sur
TE
CS
CS
Sur
Sur
–
CS
TE
CS
CS
Sur
Sur
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
3
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
Table 1 (continued )
Author(s)
Rose and Manley [61]
Chan et al. [13]
Choi and Kwak [21]
Keren and Cohen [40]
Mackley [45]
Meng and Gallagher [51]
Zhang et al. [91]
Lippman et al. [43]
Tavana et al. [79]
Cohen and Iluz [23]
Chen et al. [20]
Dimensionsa
C
D
S
E
I
I
T
T
T
I
T
I
T
T
T
I
–
I
T
I
I
T
–
T
T
I
I
–
–
T
–
I
T
–
T
T
–
–
–
T
–
–
–
–
T
–
–
–
Contract natureb
Cost contract typesc
A þ Bd
Validation5
L
L
L
–
P
L
–
L
–
–
P
–
FFP, GMP, FPI/TCC
–
–
–
FFP, FPI/TCC, CPIF, CPFF
–
FFP, CPIF, CPFF, CPPF
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
–
CS
Sur
CS
TE
CS
CS, Sur
TE
–
–
Sur
–
a
Indicates if the authors cover incentive contracting (I) or the trade-offs (T) associated with the cost (C), duration (D), scope (S) and effort (E) dimensions.
Incentive contracts can be linear (L), piecewise linear (P) or nonlinear (N).
c
Indicates which of the traditional cost contract types are treated, these include: firm fixed price (FFP), guaranteed maximum price (GMP), fixed price incentive/target
cost contract (TCC), cost plus incentive fee (CPIF) and cost plus fixed fee (CPFF) contracts.
b
Fig. 1. Visualisation of the modelling approach and the interrelations between models.
is a very general term which encompasses the amount of work
performed as well as the quality level of the performance.
When a project is expedited to a contractor, it is the latter who
controls the precise way in which the project is carried out.
Depending on the way in which the contractor decides to execute
the project, (s)he effectively selects one of the possible trade-off
points on the cost-duration-scope spectrum.
Due to the fact that the contractor is introduced as a second
party, a fourth dimension has to be introduced to extend the traditional cost-duration-scope trade-off: contractor effort. The reason
for this is that not all actions of the contractor can be directly
controlled or perceived by the owner. This concept has already
appeared widely in literature (see Section 2.1), albeit sometimes
under other aliases. Contractor effort can be defined as an
investment in the project by the contractor, which enhances the
outcome of one or more of the three traditional dimensions, but is
not directly perceived by the owner. Effectively, an increased effort
from the contractor increases the total utility which can be derived
from the project by the owner. Naturally, an increase in contractor
effort comes at a cost to the contractor, which (s)he will wish to
compensate by earning a larger incentive fee (see Section 2.1 for
more information on contractor effort).
The second body of literature studies the design and implementation of incentive contracts, as well as their (perceived)
effectiveness. A project owner can have several reasons for including incentive clauses, such as encouraging more innovative solutions [16], efficiently allocating risk, [19], improving communication
between both parties [53], or creating a more cooperative mindset
[61]. This research focusses on the two most prominently used and
quantifiable measures: the owner's expected profit, and the degree
to which the motives of the owner and contractor are aligned. The
owner's profit is viewed as an objective measure for the performance of the project [82,61,16,9], assuming that all relevant elements have been quantified. A second quantifiable motivation for
the implementation of contracts is the degree to which the contract
succeeds in transferring risks and motivations to the contractor [9].
The primary motivation for this is the removal of the risk associated
with agency-conflicts [65,32]. Moreover, the degree to which this is
done also heavily influences other beneficial effects such as the
cooperative atmosphere between the two parties [16,9]. Hence,
the implementation of an incentive agreement can be viewed as
being related to economic portfolio theory, maximising the return
(i.e. owner profit) for a given level of risk (i.e. objective alignment)
[19,46].
Practically, the owner's (expected) profit can be determined by
assuming that the contractor is a profit maximising economic
actor [82]. Under this assumption, the manner in which the project
is executed will guarantee maximal attainable profits for the
contractor. Hence, the expected profit for the owner is equal to the
profit associated with this scenario. Measuring the alignment of
motivations is done by comparing the relative outcomes for both
parties across the possible project outcomes.
The most relevant works in both domains are listed in Table 1,
where the “Dimensions” columns indicate whether the paper deals
with incentive contracts (I) for a specific dimension, or the tradeoff problem (T) related to a specific dimension.
The trade-off between the cost, duration, scope, and effort levels
which is controlled by the contractor should not be confused with the
balancing of the different dimensions of the incentive contract, which
are linked to the former three dimensions of the contractor's trade-off.
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
4
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
The difference between these concepts is shown by Fig. 1, which
indicates that the trade-off is a representation of the nature of the
project as perceived and controlled by the contractor. The same
illustration also shows that the contract uses the outcomes of the
project (i.e. the trade-offs) as an input, but the structure of the contract
itself is a separate decision controlled by the owner rather than the
contractor. To prevent any confusion regarding these concepts, the
remainder of this paper will only use “trade-off” when referring to the
trade-off decision of the contractor.
2.1. Trade-off literature
The most traditional trade-off problem in project management
is the one between the cost and duration of a project. The earliest
authors modelled this problem using a simple linear relationship
[39], but recent authors generally agree that the most realistic
model for this trade-off is a convex curve [71,21]. This trade-off
can be extended by considering the scope of the project, thus
forming the well-known concept of the iron triangle [47]. Again
the nature of the trade-offs between scope and cost or time are
generally assumed to be of convex nature [29].
The scope concept is used in a broad sense, encompassing not
only the amount of work performed, but also the quality of this
work and any other area of performance which is valued by the
owner [61,9]. Hence, it can also be considered to encompass
concepts such as occupational health and safety, environmental
impact and coordination which have received increasing amounts
of attention in recent years [51,77,30]. Nevertheless since it is
possible to incentivise these components separately, a disaggregation of the scope concept could be interesting for future
research.
As stated above, modelling the owner-x-contractor relationship
requires a fourth dimension to be added to the trade-off: contractor effort. Though the nomenclature differs between authors,
several examples of this dimension can be found in literature, as
shown by the “E”-Dimension column in Table 1.
The simplest example of contractor effort is managerial attention from the contractor [1,5], which can improve project performance, at a cost to the contractor. Another example is the proactive reduction of uncertainty through the development of contingency plans and by taking out insurance policies [18]. For
contracts where the personnel costs are not included in the project
cost dimension, but assumed to be included in the basic fee of the
contractor, the allocation of additional staff can also be considered
to be contractor effort [28,29]. Another very specific example is
presented by [42], who considered a road refurbishment project
where the contractor hired an on-site towing service to prevent
delays due to uncleared accidents. Bayiz and Corbett [6] also use a
similar dimension which they define as an unobservable element
to the project owner, which comes at a certain cost to the contractor. Moreover, they also assume the trade-off relationship to be
convex, something which also returns in the axioms used to
construct the trade-off model in Section 5.1.
2.2. Incentives literature
Incentive contracts for projects can be categorised along two
dimensions. The first dimension being the trade-offs which are
covered by the specific contract. An incentive contract can be
linked to any of the three trade-off dimensions which are perceived by the owner: cost (C), duration (D) and scope (S). Naturally,
an incentive contract can include multiple dimensions. Moreover,
an important decision in incentive contract design can be finding
the right balance between these different dimensions [1].
The second dimension is the nature of the equations used to
calculate the incentive amount earned, based on the value of the
relevant outcome dimension. These equations can be linear (L),
piecewise linear (P), or nonlinear (N). The Dimensions and Contract
Nature columns of Table 1 show how the existing literature on
incentive contracts can be categorised along these two dimensions.
2.2.1. Literature on cost incentive contracts
Cost incentives are the most researched incentive category, as
can easily be seen from Table 1. Moreover, the contracts which are
discussed can frequently be categorised as one of six basic contract
types [87]: firm fixed price (FFP), guaranteed maximum price
(GMP), fixed price incentive (FPI) (or target cost (TCC)), cost
plus incentive fee (CPIF), cost plus fixed fee (CPFF) and cost plus
percentage fee (CPPF) contracts. This set of cost contract types
forms a risk-transfer spectrum, where the FFP contract represents
the situation where all the risk is carried by the contractor, and the
CPPF is the situation where all the risk is carried by the owner [3].
Variations on these archetypes are also often used to manage cost
performance in production environments [85].
These contract types all use a single sharing ratio, sometimes
extended with a safeguard preventing excessive disincentives to
be allocated to contractors [80]. Hence, these types will be defined
as linear (L) contracts. In practice, piecewise linear (P) schemes are
frequently used to improve upon the basic cost incentive types
presented above, several practical examples of such incentive
schemes are given by Broome and Perry [11].
2.2.2. Literature on duration incentive contracts
Since no open accounting standards are needed to agree upon
the outcomes of the time dimension, the duration incentive is
arguably the easiest incentive to implement [1]. A very fruitful
area of research related to time incentive contracting is the
research done on the A þ B contracting method employed by the
US government in highway contracting (see column “Aþ B” in
Table 1). This is a bidding method where the contractors have to
submit a bid for both the expected cost and the expected duration
of a project, whereafter the road user cost (i.e. the economic
damage of closing the road for a day) is used to evaluate the total
cost of all offers. The implementation of such contracts is then
often accompanied by a per diem time incentive. Moreover, this
type of bidding allows the owner to get a better perspective on the
nature of the trade-offs from the perspective of the contractor
[22], thus aiding the owner in estimating the possible reaction of a
contractor to a given incentive contract more accurately.
Piecewise linear contracts for the duration dimension are discussed less frequently than piecewise linear contracts for the cost
trade-off dimensions. Nevertheless piecewise linear contracts for
time are used [44] and even nonlinear contracts using a quadratic
formula have been discussed in literature [71].
2.2.3. Literature on scope incentive contracts
Scope incentives are the least commonly used of all incentive
contracts, however in cases where they are used, they are often
considered the most influential incentive dimension of the contract [77]. Table 1 shows that scope incentives are rarely used
when cost and time incentives are not already in place. This is
most likely due to the added complexity of the valuation of the
performance along this dimension. Nevertheless, several authors
have proposed methods to facilitate the evaluation of scope performance. Most of these methods use key performance indicators
[62] or balanced scorecard techniques [77]. Along the same lines,
Pollack-johnson and Liberatore [57] use the analytic hierarchy
method to link these techniques to the work breakdown structure
of a typical project environment.
Although they are the least commonly used incentive category,
the adoption of scope incentives is not novel, Herten and Peeters
[34] discuss an interesting example of a scope-based incentive
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
5
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
4. Contract model
Any incentive contract can be split up into its three components: cost, duration and scope. Hence, the model presented here
also consists of three distinct components which can be used
either jointly or separately for cases where one or more dimensions are irrelevant to the owner. For each dimension, the owner
can opt to implement a linear, piecewise linear or nonlinear contract. For the duration dimension in particular, a lump sum
incentive attached to a specific deadline can also be included.
4.1. Cost incentive model
Fig. 2. Piecewise linear and nonlinear clauses.
contract from 1908 when the Wright brothers were awarded an
incentive based on the airspeed attained by an airplane.
3. Modelling the problem
The contract design problem faced by the contractor is
quantified using a combination of three models: the contract
model, trade-off model, and the evaluation model (see Fig. 1). The
underlying assumptions for each of these models are based on
existing literature.
The contract model represents the structure of the incentive
contract and is based on contracting literature. This model was
designed to be capable of representing the majority of incentive
contracts used in practice, thus allowing for a comprehensive
search of the solution space.
The trade-off model model describes the nature of the project
on which the incentive contract is to be used. The foundations for
this second model originate from project management literature,
from which six basic axioms have been derived. These six axioms
fully describe the relationship between the four discernible tradeoff dimensions of the contractor: direct cost, duration, scope and
contractor effort. Because the contractor is assumed to be a riskneutral profit-maximiser it suffices to define the trade-offs deterministically. Nevertheless, relaxing this assumption and working
with a stochastic definition of the project is an interesting topic for
future research.
The goal of the evaluation model is simply the valuation of a
project and contract combination. The model itself uses financial
valuations, rather than utility theory, since the latter is often much
harder to apply in practical situations [11]. This model quantifies
the evaluations of both parties, as well as their alignment in a way
which allows for an objective evaluation of the adequacy of a
contract.
In any project these three building blocks can be defined: there
is always a contract, there are always different ways of executing a
project,1 and both the contractor and owner always associate
certain costs and profits with different outcomes. For this research
paper we have designed the models in order to cover as much
practical cases as possible, but naturally it may be necessary to
extend these models for highly specific cases.
The details of these three models are further explained in
Sections 4, 5 and 6 respectively. For an overview of the introduced
notation, the reader is referred to Appendix A.
1
Should this not be the case, it would be irrelevant to implement any kind of
incentive contract.
Since the outcome of this dimension is already expressed as a
monetary amount, setting cost targets and evaluating the performance is relatively straightforward. The basic principle of a cost
incentive can be illustrated using a simple linear incentive contract
[56]. In such a contract the cost incentive (IC) paid to the contractor
is determined by multiplying the difference between the cost
target (Ct) and the direct cost incurred (C) by a sharing ratio
(sC A ½0; 1), as given by Eq. (1). When the cost incurred is lower
than the target cost, the difference is positive and a positive
incentive (IC) is awarded, the inverse also being true:
I C ¼ sC ðC t
CÞ
ð1Þ
All of the traditional linear cost contract types (see Section 2.2.1)
can be expressed as variations of this equation. This is done by
varying the sharing ratio sC, and in some cases capping the risk
exposure of either owner or contractor for extreme outcome scenarios (e.g. when the cost exceeds a certain threshold the disincentive no longer increases and the owner carries the remainder of
the downside risk, avoiding potential bankruptcy of the contractor).
An implementation of such a piecewise linear contract is
visualised in Fig. 2, where the horizontal axis represents the possible performance outcomes for the contractor in terms of direct
costs (C), and the vertical axis represents the incentive earned by
the contractor (IC). The piecewise linear contract in Fig. 2 defines
three regions, numbered r ¼ f0; 1; 2g. Each region r is defined by its
lower bound BrC. For each of these regions a sharing ratio is
defined as srC. The contract also contains a target for the direct cost
(Ct), which can be situated in any of the available regions. Eq. (2)
shows a mathematical expression for the 3-piecewise linear contract shown in Fig. 2, analogous expressions can of course be
created for contracts with more dimensions and/or targets lying in
other regions:
8 C
s ðC t
>
>
< 1
t
I C ¼ sC1 ðC
>
>
: sC ðC t
1
BC2 Þ þsC2 ðBC2
CÞ
if BC1 r C r BC2
CÞ
BC1 Þ þsC0
if C 4 BC2
ðBC1
CÞ
ð2Þ
if C o BC1
An alternative to the piecewise linear approach is the quadratic
contract form as presented in [71]. Other nonlinear forms can of
course also be used, but since their use is infrequent, only the
quadratic form is included in this paper. This quadratic form
requires the owner to specify upper (UBC) and lower (LBC) bounds,
which outline the region over which he wishes to spread his (dis)
incentive. Note that these express the distance from the target cost,
rather than an absolute cost. The magnitude of the incentive itself is
defined using two parameters: I Cmax A ½0; þ 1½ signifies the maximal possible incentive and I Cmin A 1; 0 which specifies the
biggest disincentive amount. The target cost (Ct) has to be specified as well. For this contract type, the cost incentive amount can
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
6
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
be calculated as follows:
0
8
!2 1
>
>
Ct C
>
C
C
@
A
>
min I max ; I max
>
>
>
LBC
<
0
IC ¼
!2 1
>
>
C Ct
>
C
C
>
@
A
>
max I min ; I min
>
>
:
UBC
if C rC t
ð3Þ
if C 4C
t
4.3. Scope incentive model
This type of incentive contract is visualised by the dotted line in
Fig. 2. An owner wishing to use such a contract is left to determine
the direct cost target (Ct), the maximal incentive and disincentive
amounts (I Cmax , I Cmin ), and the range wherein the incentive is to be
distributed (LBC, UBC).
4.2. Duration incentive model
Duration incentives are also frequently used in project management. Since the finishing time of a project is easy to observe in
an objective manner, it is also one of the easiest to implement.
However, it does require the owner to attach a monetary valuation
to the timeliness of project completion. An example of such a
valuation is the road user cost used by the US government when
evaluating different bids for road refurbishment [29,72].
Once this valuation has been determined, the owner has to
decide on the fraction of this valuation to be awarded to the
contractor as an incentive. Naturally the value transferred to the
contractor should never exceed the gain of the owner.
Similar to the cost incentive contracts of Section 4.1, this can be
done using a piecewise linear contract (Eq. (2)), or a nonlinear
contract (Eq. (3)). Eq. (4) shows how the piecewise linear cost
contract can be adjusted to a piecewise linear duration contract
with similar assumptions. The difference between these two
contracts is that rather than using a sharing ratio sCr A ½0; 1, a
valuation parameter vrD is used. This parameter defines the
monetary amount the contractor earns per unit of time saved in a
specific region, if the region is below the target duration specified
in the contract. If the region is situated above the contract's target
duration, the parameter signifies the disincentive amount.
The nonlinear contract for the duration dimension is identical to
the nonlinear contract for the cost dimension, and will not be
repeated here:
8
D
D
DÞ if D 4 BD
vD ðDt BD
>
2 Þ þ v2 ðB2
2
>
< 1
t
D
DÞ
if BD
ð4Þ
I D ¼ vD
1 rD rB2
1 ðD
>
>
: vD ðDt BD Þ þ vD ðBD DÞ if D o BD
1
1
0
1
such lump-sum incentive amounts can be combined with other
duration-related incentive provisions such as piecewise linear or
nonlinear incentive contracts, since the presence of a deadline
does not mean that additional time savings or delays have no
value to the project owner.
1
The concept of time in a project-environment is inherently
related to specific project deadlines. Oftentimes, projects have to
be completed prior to a certain date to ensure their value to the
project owner (e.g. facilities which have to be constructed for
Olympic games). Since delivering a project prior to an exact date
can be so important to the owner, incentive contracts are of course
adjusted to represent this.
Ensuring that the contractor's valuation of this date is aligned
with the owner's disproportionately large valuation (compared to
the dates prior and after this deadline) can be done using a single
lump sum incentive amount. When the contractor delivers the
project prior to the agreed upon date, the agreed incentive amount
is wholly awarded. In case the contractor fails to deliver on time,
he does not receive anything. This very simple principle can be
expressed as follows:
( D
I ls if D r Dtls
ID ¼
ð5Þ
0 if D 4 Dtls
where Dlst is the target date associated with the lump sum payment and IlsD is the amount of the lump-sum payment. Naturally,
The implementation of a scope incentive requires the adoption
of a measurement method. Because scope envelops a large number of concepts, its measurement often relies on subjective estimates [26]. However, such subjective estimates are of little use as a
basis for awarding incentive amounts, since the estimates of the
owner and contractor will most likely be skewed in opposite
directions. Stukhart [75] has proposed the use of an external party
to provide a more objective measurement in such cases, but even
so there is potential for disputes between both parties. Moreover,
the cost of hiring a third party also decreases the project profitability. The use of key performance indicators has been advocated
by Rose [62] as a method of making the performance measurement more objective. Whereas this method does indeed succeed
in removing the subjectivity of scope performance, it does not
include a formal method for aggregating the scope performance
over the complete project. A solution for this issue is a top-down
approach which defines a hierarchical structure for the complete
project, defining the relative importance of various components
until a degree of detail where objective evaluations are possible is
reached [73,57,44]. By using such techniques, the scope performance of the complete project can be measured on a ratio scale.
Hence, a value of 0 will always represent no work performed and
comparative calculations can be made using different values of the
scope (i.e. a scope of 2 is twice as valuable to the owner as a
scope of 1).
By taking this approach, the analysis of the scope dimension
can happen in a way which is largely analogous to the preceding
two dimensions. Assuming that the contract specifies a minimally
acceptable scope as well as a scope target, similar equations as
those constructed for the cost incentive in Section 4.1 can be
constructed. The piecewise linear incentive contract can be
adjusted for application on the scope dimension as follows:
8 S
v ðBS2 St Þ þ vS2 ðS
>
>
< 1
t
S
I ¼ vS1 ðS S Þ
>
>
: vS ðBS St Þ þ vS ðS
1
1
0
BS2 Þ
if S 4 BS2
if BS1 r S rBS2
BS1 Þ
if
ð6Þ
S o BS1
The key difference between the piecewise linear equation for
the duration dimension (Eq. (4)) is that the statements between
brackets are inverted. This is logical since a larger scope value is
more valuable than a smaller value. Again the valuation is done
using the vrS parameters. These parameters represent the monetary valuation of a unit of scope within a certain region r:
0
8
!2 1
>
>
S St
>
S
S
@
A
>
min I max ; I max
>
>
>
UBS
<
0
IS ¼
!2 1
>
>
St S
>
S
S
>
@
A
>
max I min ; I min
>
>
LBS
:
if S 4St
ð7Þ
if S rS
t
The adjustment of the nonlinear contract for the scope
dimensions is shown by Eq. (7). The sole difference between this
equation and the expression for the cost dimension (Eq. (3)) is that
the positive and negative senses are inverted.
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
7
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
5. Trade-off dynamics model
Contractors subjected to an incentive contract face a fourdimensional trade-off decision. These dimensions are: direct cost,
duration, scope and contractor effort. The first three of these
dimensions are directly observed by the project owner and can
potentially be used as a basis for an incentive provision. The fourth
dimension represents the possibility for the contractor to enhance
the project outcome using his own means.
5.1. Axioms
A number of axioms which are an extension of those proposed
by Ghodsi et al. [31] are used as a basis for the generation of
realistic problem environments for the contractor. These axioms
Convex relation
Direct Cost
A1
A3
Duration
Multiplicator
A2
Scope
A4
A5
A6
Contractor Effort
Fig. 3. Schematic overview of the components of the contractor's trade-off and the
associated axioms.
Axiom 1
are assumed to be valid on the level of the (aggregated) project as
well as on the level of individual activities. For sake of simplicity,
the relationship between the different dimensions is considered
on a two-by-two basis. A conceptual representation of these
axioms is given by Fig. 3, and a visual representation of their
implications is given by Fig. 4. The axioms can be summarised as
follows:
1 The direct cost is a non-increasing convex function of the duration
of the project. (The contractor will first use the cheapest
methods for time reduction.) Or in mathematical terms: ∂C=∂D
r 0 and ∂2 C=∂D2 Z 0.
2 The direct cost is an non-decreasing convex function of the scope
of the project. (Increasing the scope becomes progressively
more expensive as the low hanging fruit is picked first.) Or in
mathematical terms: ∂C=∂S Z0 and ∂2 C=∂S2 Z 0.
3 The direct cost is a non-increasing convex function of the contractor effort of the project. In mathematical notation this
becomes ∂C=∂E r0 and ∂2 C=∂E2 Z0. This effort can be viewed as
a way to influence the other relationships, i.e. making a
decrease in duration or an increase in scope less expensive in
terms of direct costs. Note that the cost in this case signifies the
cost to the owner, not the contractor. The contractor's costs
naturally increase when the effort is increased.
4 Shortening the duration of a high-scope project causes a cost
increase which is greater than or equal to the cost increase in a
low-scope project. Or in mathematical terms: 8 S1 4 S2 : ∂CðS1 Þ=
∂D r ∂CðS2 Þ=∂D r 0. Similarly, increasing scope will be at least as
Axiom 4 (1/2)
DC
S+
C
C
Linear Approx
Convex
Axiom 4 (2/2)
D
D
S
Axiom 2
Axiom 5 (1/2)
Axiom 5 (2/2)
DC
C
C
E-
S
D
E
Axiom 3
Axiom 6 (1/2)
Axiom 6 (2/2)
E
C
S+
C
C
E-
S
E
Fig. 4. The axioms visualised.
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
8
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
costly for a shorter duration project: 8 D1 o D2 : ∂CðD1 Þ=∂S Z
∂CðD2 Þ=∂S Z 0.
5 Decreasing the duration of a project will be less than or equally
costly when the effort invested in the project is greater. This can
be noted as 8 E1 o E2 : ∂CðE1 Þ=∂D r∂CðE2 Þ=∂D r 0. Analogously, a
smaller project duration will – ceteris paribus – result in a steeper
slope of the relation between invested effort and project cost:
8 D1 oD2 : ∂CðD1 Þ=∂E r ∂CðD2 Þ=∂E r 0.
6 Increasing the scope of a project will be relatively cheap when
the effort invested in the project is greater, and vice versa.
In mathematical terms this can be expressed as: 8 S1 4
S2 : ∂CðS1 Þ=∂E r ∂CðS2 Þ=∂E r 0. Analogously, a change in effort
level will have a greater impact on the project cost when the
effort invested is smaller, or in mathematical notation:
8 E1 o E2 : ∂CðE1 Þ=∂S Z ∂CðE2 Þ=∂S Z 0.
Note that the effect of the multiplicators presented in axioms
4–6 is represented visually in Fig. 4 by the change in slopes of the
upwardly translated functions, and not the upward translation
itself, which is a consequence of the first three axioms.
In order to quantify these relationships the direct cost is
assumed to be the dependent variable, and the three other
dimensions are considered to be independent variables. This is
merely a design choice which is made to improve the comprehensibility of the model. This design choice is visualised by image
in Fig. 4, where the first three axioms represent direct relationships
to the costs, and the latter three axioms are shown as multiplicators. An important note being that although the cost is the
dependent variable in this model, it is still possible for the contractor to make trade-offs between the independent variables by
making choices which inversely impact the cost of the project.
5.2. Mathematical representation
The relationships expressed above will now be quantified. The
complete model of the relationships is built in three stages: In the
first stage, the basic relationships are approximated using linear
relationships (axioms 1–3). Secondly, the interaction effects are
modelled, using the multiplicators which represent axioms 4–6.
Thirdly, the simplified linear relationships are transformed to
more realistic convex relationships.
All the trade-offs in this model are considered to be discrete,
meaning that the functions they create are piecewise linear
functions which connect a discrete number of points. These discrete points are indexed with subscript i, j and k for duration,
scope and effort respectively, assuming that: i; j; k ¼ 0; 1; …; n.
These discrete points can be seen on the left panel of Fig. 5,
counting from i¼0 for the rightmost point up to i¼ n for the
leftmost point of the trade-off. The following analysis assumes that
there is an equal number of points (n þ 1) for each of the independent dimensions. This is not a prerequisite for the analysis to
be valid but is simply a choice to simplify the notation which is
introduced.
Rather than modelling the direct cost (C), duration (D), scope
(S) and effort (E) directly, the model defines Δ-variables which
represent the distance of these values from their lowest cost option,
which is indexed 0 (see the left panel of Fig. 5):
ΔDi ¼ D0 Di
ð8Þ
ΔS j ¼ S i S 0
ð9Þ
ΔE k ¼ E 0 E k
ð10Þ
Fig. 5 illustrates this notation. The left panel shows the traditional relationship between the duration (D) on the horizontal axis
and the cost (C) on the vertical axis. For each of the possible discrete duration steps, an associated distance can be defined to the
lowest cost option, as illustrated by ΔD4 . Associated with this
ΔDi -value, a cost value can be defined as ΔC D4 , which is in effect
the cost increase due to the decreased duration of the project. The
right panel of Fig. 5 shows that by using these delta values on the
axes, an increasing convex relationship can be defined.
By defining all the variables in this manner the formulae are
simplified, since every dimension now has an increasing convex
relationship to the cost dimension. Moreover, each of these relations starts at the origin (e.g. ðΔD0 ; ΔC 0 Þ ¼ ð0; 0Þ). This also simplifies the definition of the convexity magnitude (see Section 5.2.3).
5.2.1. Linear relationships
The first expression is a basic linear relationship between the
cost (as a dependent) and the three other dimensions. This relationship is in effect the sum of the impacts of the duration, scope
and effort levels respectively. This is expressed by Eq. (11), where
ΔC Di represents the impact of selecting duration mode i on the
costs, and ΔC Sj and ΔC Ek are similar metrics for scope and effort
respectively. This is also illustrated on the right panel of Fig. 5,
where the vertical axis shows ΔC D
i graphically.
In order to define this relationship, the lowest possible direct
cost has to be given as a parameter ðC min ¼ C j ΔDi ¼ ΔSj ¼ ΔEk ¼ 0Þ.
Also for each of the independent dimensions, the slope of the curve
has to be defined: SD, SS and SE. This slope represents both the slope
of the linear approximation as well as the average slope of the
convex curve, since the start and end points of the linear approximation and the convex curve are made to coincide. Due to the Δ
transformation of the independent variables, these slopes can all be
represented as positive numbers, hence the absolute values in
Fig. 5. Illustration of the mathematical description, using the relationship between duration and cost as an example.
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
9
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
Eq. (12):
C ijk ¼ C min þ ΔC ijk ¼ C min þ Δ
CD
i þ
Δ
C Sj þ
C ijk ¼ C min þ jSD jΔDi þ jSS jΔSj þ jSE jΔEk
Δ
C Ek
ð11Þ
ð12Þ
Eq. (12) is in effect a simplified linear representation of the first
three axioms. Note that the independent dimensions are indexed
separately, since these dimensions can naturally be at different
positions (i.e. he contractor can select the positions of these
dimensions separately, the effect of which will be reflected in the
total cost of the project).
5.2.2. Interaction effects
Axioms 4–6 are then added to the linear expression through
the definition of the slope multiplicators. These are defined in the
following form: mab is the maximal impact of dimension b on the
slope of the relationship between the direct cost and dimension a,
expressed as a fraction added to the original slope of the curve. For
example mSD ¼ 0:2 indicates that the slope of the duration curve
will be 20% steeper when ΔS is at its maximal value.
ΔS j
ΔE k
C ijk ¼ C min þ jSD jΔDi mSD
þ1
mED
þ1
ΔS n
ΔE n
ΔD i
ΔE k
þ1
mES
þ1
þ jSS jΔSj mD
S
ΔD n
ΔE n
ΔS j
ΔDi
þ1
mSE
þ1
ð13Þ
þ jSE jΔEk mD
E
ΔDn
ΔS n
The effect of adding these multiplicators is shown in Fig. 4,
where the upwardly translated curves have a steeper slope than
the original curves.
5.2.3. Convexity
The third and final step is the conversion of these linear relationships into more realistic convex functions. To express the
degree of convexity of a relation quantitatively, the convexity
magnitude (CM) metric is introduced in this paper. The logic
behind this metric can be explained by looking at the right panel
of Fig. 5 where a triangle is formed by the simplified linear relationship and the projection towards the horizontal axis. Two zones
are defined within this triangle such that zone A is the surface
between the simplified linear relationship and the convex curve
and zone B is the area below the convex curve. Hence, the total
surface of the triangular surface is equal to A þ B. The CM is now
defined as the fraction of the triangle consisting of zone A.
Assuming an uniform step size (ΔΔDi ¼ ΔDn =n; 8 i ¼ 1; …; n), for
the duration dimension this metric can be calculated as follows
(see Appendix B for a full derivation):
CM D ¼
B¼
A
¼1
AþB
n
ΔDn X
n
i¼1
"
Δ
2B
ð14Þ
ΔDn ΔC Dn
CD
i 1þ
ΔC Di ΔC Di
2
1
#
ð15Þ
In the formula above ΔDn /ΔC D can of course be replaced by
ΔSn /ΔC S or ΔEn /ΔC E to model the degree of convexity of the
S
E
scope (CM ) and effort (CM ) respectively. Logically the value of
this metric lies in the interval ½0; 1½, where a value of 0 represents a
perfectly linear relation and higher values represent different
gradations of convexity. The actual upper bound on the convexity
depends on the number of discrete points n: CMD
max ¼ ðn 1Þ=n.
Although this upper bound is attainable, trade-off curves
approaching this bound will often have non-increasing regions
and very steep angles.
5.2.4. Specific project cases
The trade-off points for a specific scenario can either be defined
explicitly when full information on all feasible execution methods
is available, or fitted using partial information in combination with
the aforementioned axioms. Hence, although it is assumed that
the majority of projects will comply with the aforementioned
assumptions, this is not a prerequisite for the application of
the model.
6. Contract evaluation model
The preceding two models enable a quantitative representation
of contract and project trade-off structures respectively. The contract evaluation model presented in this section focusses on how
appropriate the use of a certain contract is for a given project.
From the perspective of the owner, the optimal contract has
three properties. First of all, it maximises the gain the owner can
expect from the project. Secondly, it guarantees that the evaluation of the contractor is well aligned with that of the owner.
Thirdly, the contract should guarantee an adequate return for the
contractor. An adequate contractor return has two facets, on the
one hand the absolute incentive amount has to be substantial
enough to be relevant to the contractor, on the other hand, the
range between the highest and lowest incentive amount has to be
large enough such that the contractor is motivated to locate the
optimum payoff.
The model presented in this section uses a single index l ¼ 1;
…; m which represents the m different possible outcome scenarios,
in no particular order. Such an outcome scenario is simply an
attainable point of the trade-off model (i.e. a combination of cost,
duration, scope and effort), for which the associated incentive
amount has been calculated. When combined with a trade-off
model as presented in Section 5 the value of m is equal to ðn þ 1Þ3 .
6.1. Maximisation of expected owner gain
First and foremost, the goal of the project owner is to maximise
his expected return. The contract evaluation model presented here
calculates this amount by assuming that the contractor is a riskneutral profit-maximiser [32]. Given that the choice of a trade-off
point is controlled by the contractor, the expected profit of the
project owner is the profit for the trade-off point where the contractor's profits are maximised. Hence, the first step in calculating
the expected net owner gain (E½NOG) is the maximisation of the
contractor's profit function.
When evaluating the discrete set of scenarios from the perspective of the contractor, two elements have to be considered for
every possible project outcome scenario l. First of all, the cost of
effort invested by the contractor (Elcost) and secondly, the total
incentive amount earned (Iltot). This total incentive amount is
simply the sum of the cost incentive (IlC), duration incentive (IlD)
and the scope incentive (IlS) amounts (which are defined by the
contract model, as presented in Section 4). Using these two elements, the net contractor gain (NCGl) can be calculated for every
scenario:
NCGl ¼ I tot
l
S
Ecost
¼ I Cl þI D
l
l þ Il
Ecost
l
ð16Þ
However, it must not be neglected that there is an opportunity
cost associated with investing effort in a project, since the same
effort could also earn a certain return elsewhere. Hence, the net
contractor gain (NCGl) has to be corrected for this opportunity cost
using the return on investment (ROIE) this effort could earn in
other projects or activities. The adjusted NCG can be calculated as
NCGadj
¼ I tot
l
l
Ecost
ð1 þ ROI E Þ
l
ð17Þ
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
10
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
This adjustment decreases the valuation of the scenarios with
the opportunity cost of the effort investment. By doing this, the
different NCGladj values can be directly compared. In the case
where there is no ulterior investment possibility for the contractor's effort, ROIE can be set to zero.
The owner's net gain from a specific scenario (NOGl) is equal to
the value derived from the direct cost (Cl), duration (Dl) and scope
(Sl) dimensions diminished by the total incentive amount awarded
to the contractor (Iltot):
NOGl ¼ OVðC l ; Dl ; Sl Þ
I tot
l
ð18Þ
where OV is a function expressing the financial value of a certain
outcome of the project for different values of direct cost, duration
and scope. This function can be further detailed as a simple sum of
the valuation of each of these three dimensions:
C
D
S
OVðC l ; Dl ; Sl Þ ¼ OV ðC l Þ þ OV ðDl Þ þ OV ðSl Þ
ð19Þ
C
As for the cost component, the owner's valuation (OV ) is
inversely proportional to the direct cost outcome:
OV C ðC l Þ ¼
Cl
ð20Þ
The time valuation is slightly more complex, containing both
the possibility of a linear value per time unit such as a road user
cost, and the possibility of a lump sum value representing an
important deadline”
(
μD ð Dl Þ
if Dl Z DL
D
ð21Þ
OV ðDl Þ ¼
μD ð Dl Þ þ μls if Dl o DL
In Eq. (21), μD represents the monetary valuation of an unit of
time by the owner (e.g. 1000 euro/day). This is similar to the road
user cost which is often defined in A þ B contracting methods for
roadwork manufacturing [72]. Analogously, the parameter μls is
used to represent the monetary value to the owner of satisfying a
certain deadline DL. Note that the parameter DL is different from
the Dtls parameter introduced in Section 4.2, the former signifies a
deadline relevant to the owner, whereas the latter is a deadline
clausule included in an incentive contract to which the contractor
is subjected. These two dates are not necessarily the same, since
the owner can choose to insert additional buffer in the contract by
setting the contractor's deadline prior to his own (i.e. DL ZDtls for
rationally designed contracts).
A similar construction is created for the valuation of scope, as
seen in Eq. (22). Based on the premise that scope can be measured
on a ratio scale (see Section 4.3), it suffices to introduce μS as the
monetary value of an unit of scope to the owner:
OV S ðSl Þ ¼ μS Sl
ð22Þ
Using the formulae above, the payoff functions for both the
owner and the contractor have been fully defined as NOGl and
NCGladj respectively. As stated above, the optimal contract design
has three evaluation criteria: a maximal return for the owner, an
accurate alignment of the evaluation of the contractor and the
owner, and an adequate payoff for the contractor. The first of these
criteria can be expressed as follows:
h
i
adj
¼
max
NCG
ð23Þ
E½NOG ¼ max NOGl j NCGadj
l
l
Eq. (23) effectively states that the expected gain of the owner is
equal to the gain he receives when the contractor selects the
scenario which maximises the contractor's own return. In the case
where there are multiple scenarios in which the contractor's
profits are maximised, the maximal net owner gain is used. The
reasoning behind this being that given the opportunity to do so,
the contractor will chose to maximise the owner's profits if this
does not affect his own return.
The top two panels of Fig. 6 illustrate the expected owner profit
(E½NOG) maximisation objective. On the horizontal axis all the
potential outcome scenarios (i.e. the tradeoff points which can be
chosen by the contractor) are listed in no particular order. The
vertical axis represents the profit for the owner and contractor for
the respective scenarios. As was formerly stated, the contractor is a
profit maximiser and will therefore always select the scenario
¼ maxl ðNCGadj
Þ). Hence, the
which maximises his profits (NCGadj
l
l
owner profit (NOGl) associated with this scenario is defined as the
expected net owner gain (E½NOG). This expected outcome is
indicated by the rectangle and the letter E in Fig. 6. Assuming the
owner is confronted with a choice between the contract represented by the upper left panel and the contract represented by the
upper right panel, the owner will prefer the right contract, since
this is likely to result in an outcome which yields a much greater
net owner gain (NOG). The situation in the top left pane is in fact
equivalent to rewarding a certain strategy, while hoping a different
strategy will be followed [41].
Fig. 6. Illustration of the optimisation objectives.
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
11
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
Note that the example presented in Fig. 6 is simplified in that a
change in the contract structure is likely to change the owner's
payoff function as well as the function of the contractor. This is one
of the reasons for the complex nature of incentive contract design.
6.2. Evaluation alignment
The two bottom panels of Fig. 6 present an intuitive example of
the importance of evaluation alignment. Again the horizontal axis
lists all possible outcome scenarios in no particular order, and the
vertical axis represents the contractor (NCGladj) and owner (NOGl)
gains for the respective scenarios. When comparing the two bottom panels, it is clear that both contracts have an identical
expected net owner gain E½NOG. Hence, if this was the only evaluation criterion used, the owner would be indifferent between
the contract resulting in the bottom left and the contract resulting
in the bottom right scenario. However, when looking at the most
attractive regions for the contractor, excluding the contractor's
optimal point, a case can be made for the contract represented in
the bottom right. Namely, it is clear that for the bottom left contract the attractive region coincides with the least attractive points
for the contractor. Hence, should external influence cause the
optimal point to be unattainable, it is likely that the outcome will
gravitate towards such an unattractive point. The opposite is true
for the contract on the bottom right, where even if the expected
point should not be obtained for whichever reason, the other
points still result in relatively attractive outcomes for the owner.
The theoretical example in the bottom panels of Fig. 6 can be
linked to the concept of balanced contract design in project
management practice [1]. For example, assume the only timerelated incentive of a contract is a lump-sum provision awarded in
case a certain deadline is met, but the contract also includes a
substantial cost incentive to encourage cost savings. Should it at
some point during the execution of this project become apparent
to the contractor that it will be impossible to deliver the project
before said deadline, it is highly likely that the contractor will
attempt to maximise his cost incentive and completely neglect the
time dimension. This would of course have a dramatic effect on
the value of the project to the contract owner, who of course
attaches a substantial value to the timely delivery of the project.
The concept of payoff alignment is a way of formalising this issue.
In order to quantify the alignment of the evaluation of the
owner and contractor, both values are expressed in relative terms,
meaning that they are rescaled in the range ½0; 1. This results in
the following relative expressions for contractor and owner
respectively:
NCGadj
l
RNCGadj
¼
l
NCGadj
max
RNOGl ¼
NCGadj
min
NCGadj
min
ð24Þ
NOGl NOGmin
NOGmax NOGmin
ð25Þ
Using these relative expressions, a perfect evaluation alignment
of both parties can be defined as the situation where the following
¼ RNOGl 8 l ¼ 1; …; m. Naturally this optimal
is true: RNCGadj
l
situation can never be attained in practice. Hence the need to
develop metrics to measure the degree of deviation from this
optimal situation. The following two metrics are used in order to
express the degree of alignment (i.e. the deviation from this
optimal situation):
MD ¼
m h
1X
RNCGadj
l
ml¼1
RNOGl
i
ð26Þ
MAD ¼
m
1X
RNCGadj
l
ml¼1
RNOGl
ð27Þ
Eq. (26) measures the mean deviation (MD) of the relative gains
of both parties. The value of this metric lies within the range
½ 1; 1, negative values indicating that there are more scenarios
where the owner gains are larger than those of the contractor and
positive values indicating that there are more scenarios where the
inverse is true. Hence, the value of this metric should be as close to
zero as possible.
The major flaw in Eq. (26) is of course that opposite deviations
cancel each other out. Hence, the mean absolute deviation (MAD)
is presented in Eq. (27). The MAD always has a value in the range
½0; 1, and gives an accurate reading of the overall deviations,
regardless of their sign. By using the MAD to measure the
average alignment in combination with the MD to measure
possible skewness, the overall alignment of the evaluations can be
quantified.
6.3. Constraints enforcing sensible contract design
The preceding two optimisation criteria can be extended by
adding constraints enforcing the contracts to adhere to certain
rules for good incentive contract design. Such guidelines have
been regularly proposed in literature and often include advice on
minimal sharing ratios [56], and a bias towards positive incentives
rather than disincentives [60]. The remainder of this section presents two constraints which can be used to enforce certain principles when evaluating contracts.
The first constraint guarantees that the maximal incentive
earned by the contractor is larger than or equal to a certain
minimal value. If this would not be enforced, the optimal solution
could potentially gravitate towards contracts which impose large
disincentives on contractors. Several authors have already indicated that such contracts are undesirable [1,60].
The level at which this constraint is set is of course strongly
project-specific, and several authors have quoted different values
depending on the industry in which they operated. Abu-Hijleh and
Ibbs [1] examined projects in industrial construction and found
incentive amounts up to 2.62% of total project cost. A study Veld
and Peeters [83] found that this percentage was approximately
0.7% in the aerospace industry. A much higher fraction is apparently used in road construction in the US, where an incentive cap
of approximately 5% of the total project cost is recommended [77].
By defining the maximal incentive which can be earned by the
contractor as I tot
, this
max and the lower bound for this value as LBI tot
max
constraint can be formulated as
I tot
max Z LBI tot
max
ð28Þ
The second constraint is introduced to guarantee that there is
sufficient variability in the payoff of the contractor. Insufficient
variability will impede the contractor's motivation to locate the
optimal payoff region. Hence, RItot is defined as the minimal range
required for adequate contractor motivation. The difference
tot
between the maximal (I tot
max ) and minimal (I min ) incentive awarded
to the contractor should then be at least as great as this minimal
range:
I tot
max
I tot
min Z RI tot
ð29Þ
7. Evaluating the performance of contract sets
One of the key objectives of this research is to evaluate the
performance of different types of contracts. However, due to the
presence of multiple objectives, comparing performance is not
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
12
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
trivial. In order to evaluate how different contract types perform,
all Pareto-efficient contracts of a specific type are considered
jointly. These local Pareto frontiers are then compared to a global
Pareto frontier, which can include all contracts regardless of their
type. This section discusses the methods used to make this
comparison.
As was stated in Section 6, the performance of a contract of a
contract is measured on two key dimensions: expected owner gain
(E½NOG), and the alignment of the relative payoffs of the contractor and the owner, as measured by the MD and MAD metrics.
Since the problem at hand has multiple objectives, the performance has to be evaluated accordingly. This is done by constructing a global three dimensional (E½NOG; MAD; MD) Pareto
frontier, containing all the contracts for a problem environment
which are not dominated. The performance of different contract
sets (i.e. the contracts belonging to a specific contract group, can
then be compared to this global Pareto frontier. When making
such comparisons, three aspects are of importance [66,54]: (i) the
distance to the global Pareto front, (ii) the spread of the solutions
found, and (iii) the number of elements found.
(i) Distance to the global Pareto front. Frequently used
metrics to measure the distance between the global Pareto front
and approximations thereof include the error rate (ER) , the generational distance (GD), the inverted generational distance (IGD) as
well as the Hausdorff distance (dH) [81,66]. However, each of the
aforementioned metrics displays certain shortcomings: the error
rate fails to measure the precise distance to the global Pareto front,
both the GD and IGD tend to zero as the number of elements on
the tested or global frontier is increased, and the Hausdorff distance only measures the worst case scenario. Hence, the averaged
Hausdorff distance (Δp), which was introduced by [67] to mitigate
these shortcomings, is used as a metric for the distance from the
tested set to the best known Pareto front, this metric is calculated
as follows:
2
!1p
N
1X
Δp ðX; YÞ ¼ max4
distðxi ; YÞp ;
Ni¼1
!1p 3
M
1 X
ð30Þ
distðyi ; XÞp 5
Mi¼1
Where X and Y are the two sets between which the distance is to
be measured (i.e. the global Pareto front and the tested front).
These sets contain N and M points respectively, which are represented as xi and yi. The function dist measures the distance from a
point to the closest point in the other set, using simple euclidean
distances. Finally, p is equal to the number of dimensions in the
Pareto front (i.e. p ¼3 in this study). The coordinate system used to
calculate this metric in the experiments below has been standardised to the range ½0; 1 for each of the dimensions measured, to
avoid one of the dimensions having a more substantial impact
than the others merely due its measurement scale. For more
information regarding this metric, the reader is referred to [67].
The calculation of the Δp metric is illustrated by Fig. 7. To allow
for a simple visual representation, two rather than three evaluation dimensions are considered in this example. By visual
inspection alone, it is hard to determine which of these two sets is
closest to the global Pareto front. The Δp metric can be used to
compare both of these sets (S1 and S2) to the global frontier (G).
The first step is to calculate the distance from each point on S1 to
Fig. 7. Graphical illustration of the metrics used to measure the performance of certain contract sets. The top left panel shows the Pareto frontier of two contract sets S1 and
S2, as well as the global Pareto frontier G, which is constructed using all the best known contracts regardless of their type. The top right and bottom left panels illustrate
components of the averaged Hausdorff distance (Δp) metric used to measure the distance to the global front. The bottom right panel illustrates the measurement of the
E½NOG spread associated with the respective sets.
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
13
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
Table 2
Contract dataset.
Base type
Accountability
Code
Downside
Upside
Linear
Contractor
Contractor
Shared
Owner
Owner
Contractor
Shared
Shared
Shared
Owner
3-Piecewise
Contractor
Contractor
Owner
Owner
4-Piecewise
Nonlinear
Contracts tested
Cost
Duration
Scope
LCC
LCS
LSS
LOS
LOO
7
56
63
56
7
168
1344
1512
1344
168
9
72
63
72
9
Firm fixed price
Guaranteed maximum price
Fixed price incentive
Cost plus incentive fee
Cost plus fixed fee
Contractor
Shared
Shared
Owner
3PCC
3PCS
3POS
3POO
336
1176
1512
336
8064
36,288
36,288
8064
432
3888
1944
432
–
–
–
–
Contractor
Contractor
Owner
Owner
Contractor
Shared
Shared
Owner
4PCC
4PCS
4POS
4POO
980
2940
4200
1260
0
0
0
0
1260
2520
3780
1260
–
–
–
–
Shared
Shared
–
N
28,672
1,102,248
59,049
Total
41,601
1,195,488
74,790
the global Pareto front, which is simply the euclidian distance to
the closest point on the global front. This is illustrated for the first
set (S1) in the top right panel of Fig. 7. By taking the power mean
of all these distances, the first of the two expressions within the
square brackets of formula 30 is found. The calculation of the
second expression is simply the inverse of the first and is done by
taking the power mean of the distances from every point on the
global front to the first set of points (S1). This is illustrated for the
first set S1 by the bottom left panel of Fig. 7. By taking the maximum of these two expressions, the “worst case”-averaged distance is acquired. When calculating the result for this small
example, it appears that the second set (S2) is somewhat closer to
the global Pareto front with a Δp value of 0.48, compared to a Δp
value of 0.57 for the first set (S1)
(ii) Spread of solutions. To determine the quality of the spread
of the tested Pareto front, a very simple metric is proposed which
compares the distance between the extreme outcomes for each
dimension of the tested front to the distance between the extreme
outcomes for the global Pareto front. For E½NOG this can be calculated as follows:
sprðE½NOGÞ ¼
In literature
E½NOGtest
max
E½NOGtest
min
E½NOGglob
max
E½NOGglob
min
ð31Þ
test
In Eq. 31, E½NOGtest
max and E½NOGmin represent the highest and
lowest values for the E½NOG metric in the Pareto front which is
glob
compared to the global front. Similarly, E½NOGglob
max and E½NOGmin
represent the highest and lowest values for E½NOG which can be
observed on the global Pareto front. Note that since the global Pareto
front will always include the best known solutions the following
test
glob
r E½NOGtest
is always true: E½NOGglob
min r E½NOGmax r E½NOGmax .
min
Hence, the spread will always be a value in the range ½0; 1. The
graphical interpretation of this metric is illustrated in the bottom
right panel of Fig. 7. For this example, it is clear that the spread of the
second set (S2) with regard to the E½NOG metric is superior to the
spread of the first set (S1). Since the spread for the MD and MAD
dimensions is calculated analogously, the respective equations for
these dimensions will not be repeated here.
(iii) Number of elements. The number of elements found on
the tested Pareto front will not be considered as a metric in this
paper, since this number will of course be strongly dependent on
the number of contracts which were tested. Which is an aspect of
the experimental setup, rather than a property of the contract
structure itself.
8. Computational experiments
The formal models presented in the preceding sections make it
possible to carry out computational experiments using carefully
constructed datasets. In order to structure the analysis, the following two concepts are defined:
Contract type: A collection of contracts which adhere to certain
design principles with respect to the dimensions which
are incentivised, the formulae used to calculate the
incentive and the owner and contractor accountability in
the case of extremely positive or negative outcomes.
Environment: The project setting in which a contract operates,
which is formed by combining a tradeoff model (see
Section 5) and an evaluation model (see Section 6).
The goal of these experiments is to compare the performance
of different contract types, as well as the impact of differences in
the environments in which contracts operate. Differences in
environments can of course be due to differences in the trade-off
model as well as differences in the evaluation model.
The computational experiments provide answers to four key
research questions: (1) How do different contract types perform in
practice? (2) How do environmental factors (i.e. the properties of
the project trade-off and the evaluation models) influence the
performance of these different contract types? (3) How substantial
are the added benefits of multi-dimensional contract forms when
compared to uni-dimensional contract forms? (4) How are these
multi-dimensional contract forms influenced by environmental
factors?
The answers to the former two research questions are provided
by the uni-dimensional experiment design (Section 8.2), whereas
the latter two research questions are answered through the multidimensional experiment design (Section 8.3). Before going into
further detail on these two experimental designs, more information on the datasets is provided in Section 8.1.
8.1. Datasets
In accordance with the methodology which was introduced
when modelling the problem, three separate datasets have been
created. Each of these datasets corresponds to one of the components used to model the problem: the contract, the trade-off and
the evaluation model (see Section 3). All these datasets are freely
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
14
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
available and can be downloaded from the following website:
http://www.projectmanagement.ugent.be/?q¼ research/
contracting.
8.1.1. Contract models
The goal of the contract model dataset is to present a comprehensive cross section of contracting techniques used in practice. By testing this cross section of contract structures on a wide
range of possible environments, the effectiveness of these techniques can be determined. As was mentioned in Section 7, the
contract dataset consists of several contract (sub)sets, grouping
contracts belonging to a specific type. An overview of this is given
in Table 2.
Contract types discussed in literature are usually defined based
on which party is accountable in case of extremely positive or
negative outcomes (see Section 2.1). This allocation of accountability for the different contract types is shown by the accountability columns in Table 2. Accountability can either be shared or
allocated to the contractor/owner. Allocating the downside
accountability to the contractor means that all overruns beyond a
certain point will be paid in full by the contractor. Where this
specific point lies depends on the other parameters set in the
contract. Contrarily, when the upside risk is allocated to the contractor, (s)he can fully benefit from all the gains of the performance (e.g. cost savings) beyond a certain point. Alternatively, the
risk can also be shared between the two parties according to a
certain ratio. This accountability in the extrema is translated into a
shortened contract code which will be used from now on to
identify the different contract types (see the code column in
Table 2). The final column of Table 2 also mentions the nomenclature used in existing literature for these specific types of contracts, insofar as this nomenclature exists.
Practically, allocating the accountability to the owner or contractor is equivalent to setting the sharing ratio for the associated
region to 0 or 1 respectively. For the simple linear contracts, this
means that the sharing ratio above and/or below the target is set
to 0 or 1. For three- and four-piecewise linear contracts, the upside
and downside accountability refer to the first and final segment.
For each of these types, the parameters which are not fixed due
to the nature of the contract type are varied, resulting in a varying
number of available instances per contract type, as listed in
Table 2. These parameters include the respective targets (C t ; Dt ; St ),
S
the bounds for the various regions (BCr ; BD
r ; Br ), the sharing ratios
C
D S
(sr ), the region valuation parameters (vr ; vr ), the nonlinear
S
C
D
S
C
incentive amounts and bounds (I Cmax , I D
max , I max , I min , I min , I min , UB ,
D
S
C
D
S
UB , UB , LB , LB , LB ), and lump sum duration incentive targets
and incentive amounts (Dtls ; I D
ls ). Each of these parameters is varied
across the complete relevant range, with a step size equal to 18 of
the total size of the range, including or excluding the bounds of the
range as is relevant for practical implementation. This results in a
total of 41,601 cost contract options, 1,195,488 duration contract
options, and 74,790 scope contract options. Note that the number
of duration contract options is substantially greater due to the
possibility of including lump-sum incentives related to a specific
deadline. Readers who desire more information on these datasets
are referred to the online resources accompanying this paper.
8.1.2. Trade-off models
In order to create instances of the trade-off model, the independent parameters (D; S; E) are spread across a range of size 1:
D A ½1; 2, S A ½1; 2 and E A ½0; 1 (i.e. The shortest possible duration
for the project is defined as 1, and the longest possible duration for
the project is defined as 2). For each of these dimensions, 11
equidistant discrete options were created within this range (n ¼10,
see Section 5). This results in a total of 1331ð ¼ ðn þ 1Þ3 Þ trade-off
points for each instance. The actual difference between these
instances is represented by the variation in the costs associated
with each of these trade-off points, which depends on the parameter settings used for the specific instance. These settings are
summarised in the first part of Table 3.
The generation procedure for the trade-off problems requires a
value for each of the parameter values listed in the first part of
Table 3. The generation procedure starts by simply selecting the
values for the three first parameter types: the slopes (j SD j , j SS j ,
j SE j ), the multiplicators (mDS, …, mES), and the minimal cost value
(C min ). Given these parameter values, a linear approximation of the
relation between each of the independent dimensions (duration,
scope and effort) can be made, for every possible value of the other
two independent dimensions (e.g. the relation between duration
and cost given a certain scope and effort level). These linear
approximations are then used in combination with the value for
the convexity magnitude metrics (CMD, CMS, CME) to determine a
convex curve which represents the impact of each separate
dimension on the cost. Practically, this convex curve is created
using a linear programming (LP) model which uses the linear
approximation as well as the relevant CM metric as an input. The
workings of this model are detailed in Appendix C. This means
that a total of 3 ðn þ 1Þ2 LP models are solved in order to model
the impact of the individual dimensions. The implementation of
this model was done using Gurobi 5.6 optimisation software,
which solved each of the instances in under a minute on a 2.5 GHz
Intel Core i5 machine. The result for the individual dimensions is
then combined by summing the cost increases (ΔC) for the
separate dimensions, resulting in ðn þ 1Þ3 costs (Cijk) corresponding
to every possible duration-scope-effort combination. Using this
methodology and the parameters listed in Table 3, a total of 380
trade-off models have been created.
8.1.3. Project evaluation models
The generation of evaluation model instances requires the
selection of the parameters which are shown in the bottom half of
Table 3. The majority of these parameters are expressed relative to
the total cost spread of the trade-off problem used, expressed as
the difference between the lowest attainable cost (C000) and the
Table 3
Environment dataset.
Model
Parameter
Symbol
Values
Trade-off
Basic slopes
Multiplicators
Minimal cost
j S D j , j SS j , j S E j
mDS, …, mES
C min ¼ C 000
Convexity
CMD, CMS, CME
{0.5, 0.75, 1, 1.25, 1.5}
{0, 0.1, 0.2, 0.3, 0.4}
1 1 1 1 1
ΔC nnn 0:10
; 0:20; 0:30; 0:40; 0:50
{0, 0.0625, 0.125, 0.1875, 0.25}
125
ΔC nnn f0:25; 0:375; 0:5; 0:625; 0:75g
f0; 0:05; 0:1; 0:15; 0:2g
ΔC nnn f0:5; 0:75; 1; 1:25; 1:5g
ΔC nnn f0; 0:05; 0:1; 0:15; 0:2g
ΔC nnn f0:5; 0:75; 1; 1:25; 1:5g
5
5
5
5
5
Evaluation
Max effort cost
Effort ROI
Time value
Deadline value
Scope valuation
cost
Em
ROIE
μD
μls
μS
Instances
125
125
5
Total
380
25
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
15
Fig. 8. Distance to the Pareto front for uni-dimensional experiments.
Fig. 9. The average spread obtained by different contract types for the cost, duration and scope dimensions. These are the outcomes for the situation where both a minimal
earning and a minimal range for the contractor is required.
highest possible cost (Cnnn): ΔC nnn ¼ C nnn C 000 . This is done to
ensure a consistent variation of the different parameters over
different trade-off models. As shown in Table 3, a total of 25 different evaluation model instances have been created, allowing for
a total of 9500 (25 380) different environments on which contract
performance can be tested.
8.2. Uni-dimensional experiments
The aim of the uni-dimensional experiment is to investigate the
relative performance of different contract types for the different
dimensions, as well as the impact of environmental factors on the
performance of these contracts. To do this, the 25 evaluation
model instances are combined with the 380 trade-off model
instances (see Table 3), resulting in 9500 problem environments
on which the different contract type instances (see Table 2) can be
tested. The nature of this experiment is uni-dimensional, which
signifies that only one type of incentive is tested per environment
(i.e. an environment is never subjected to both a cost and scope
incentive simultaneously).
Due to the difference in the number of parameter settings
between the contracts, the time needed to evaluate a single contract differs depending on the contract type. On a 2.26 GHz processor the evaluation of a single environment (i.e. a combination of
a trade-off and an evaluation instance) takes 27, 793 and 135 s on
average for the cost, duration and scope contract sets respectively.
Hence, the complete experiment takes approximately 2500 singlecore computation hours.
For every environment, the performance of the different contract types is judged by creating a number of efficient frontiers
containing only the contracts of a certain types. These local efficient frontiers are then compared to the global efficient frontier,
which includes contracts of all available types. The comparison
itself is made by calculating the averaged Hausdorff distance (Δp)
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
16
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
Fig. 10. The average impact of variation of environment parameters on contract
performance, measured by the slope coefficient of the linear regression. These are
the outcomes for the situation where both a minimal earning and a minimal range
for the contractor's earnings is required.
between the local and global frontiers as well as the spread of the
local frontiers.
This process is repeated for different types of sensible contract
design strategies (see Section 6.3). Whenever a specific contract
does not satisfy the criteria for sensible contract design, it is no
longer included in any of the local or global efficient frontiers. Four
different sensible contract design strategies have been used. For
the first type no restrictions whatsoever are included, all contracts
are considered in the efficient frontiers. The second type imposes
the restriction that the maximal incentive which can be earned by
the contractor cannot be negative. The third type requires that the
maximal incentive which can be earned by the contractor is at
least 2% of the average project cost.2 The fourth criterium extends
the third by also requiring that the range between the highest and
lowest incentive amounts which can be earned is at least 4% of the
average project cost. These constraints are similar to the values
observed in practice by other authors [1,83,77], see Section 6.3.
The results of the experiments will be presented using visual
representations rather than raw data tables to facilitate interpretation. Readers who would like the raw data behind these
graphs can download them online from the following website:
http://www.projectmanagement.ugent.be/?q¼ research/
contracting.
8.2.1. Performance of contract types
The first step in analysing the results of the uni-dimensional
experiment is measuring the (relative) performance of the contract types. Fig. 8 visualises the averaged Hausdorff distance Δp
performance measure, which represents the proximity to the
global efficient frontier. To facilitate comparing results the averaged Hausdorff distance was standardised within the range ½0; 1.
The second performance measure – the spread of the solutions for
the different evaluation dimensions – is shown in Fig. 9. Naturally
these results were also standardised within the range ½0; 1, based
on the best and worst values for each specific environment.
For the majority of contract types the fraction of contracts
which did not satisfy imposed restrictions for sensible contract
design (see Section 6.3) remained limited: in less than 1.5% of
cases violations were observed. Only the LOO contract, which
transfers all risk to the owner, was unable to satisfy any of the
imposed constraints, as can be seen from the results in Figs. 8 and
9.
Nonlinear and piecewise linear contracts outperform linear
types: Nonlinear and piecewise linear contract types generally outperform linear contract types in terms of proximity to the efficient
frontier, whilst showing average to good performance in terms of
spread for all metrics. Fig. 8 shows that the best performance in
terms of proximity to the efficient frontier (Δp) is always observed
to be either a nonlinear (N) or piecewise linear contract type. It can
also be noted that the best performing piecewise linear contracts
always share the upside potential, rather than allocating it completely to either party. The spread of these best performing types
is also consistently good, as shown by Fig. 9.
Avoid linear contracts which transfer all risk to a single
party: Linear contracts which transfer all the risk to either the
contractor3 (LCC) or the owner4 (LOO) perform worse in terms both
proximity and spread when compared to other linear contract types.
Moreover, due to the complete absence of value transfer from the
owner to the contractor when using the LOO contract type, the
minimum incentive and range conditions for sensible contract
design cannot be satisfied. The relevance of these observations is
validated by the continued extensive use of this type of contract,
as can be seen from Table 1.
Preferred types are robust to changing restrictions: Adding
restrictions to enforce sensible contract design does not change the
preferred contract type for any of the contract dimensions. For other
contract types imposing additional constraints can have a significant impact on the relative performance. Simple linear contracts seem particularly sensitive to the imposition of constraints
for sensible contract design.
Skewness persists within contract types: The alignment
skewness as measured by the MD persists within a contract type, as
indicated by the consistently low values for the standardised spread
for this metric (spr(MD)). Fig. 9 shows that the average spread for
the MD metric is low in both absolute and relative terms for all
types of contracts. Hence, it is likely that other contract types will
have to be considered in order to remove an undesired skew from
a contract.
Based on these observations, project owners are advised to use
piecewise linear or nonlinear contracts, rather than the traditional
linear contract archetypes. Especially linear contracts which
transfer all risk to the contractor or the owner, such as the traditional firm fixed price (FFP) or cost plus fixed fee (CPFF) contract
types, should be avoided. Moreover, when an undesirable skew of
the alignment (as measured by the MD indicator) is observed, it
may be beneficial to include other contract types in the analysis.
8.2.2. Impact of environmental factors on contract type performance
The properties of the environment in which the contract
operates can also have an important influence on its effectiveness.
Hence, the experiment design uses a large set of parameter settings for both trade-off and evaluation models. The impact of these
environmental factors on the average Hausdorff distance Δp is
measured by the slope of the linear regression line which estimates Δp as a function of the respective environment parameter
value: Δp parameter).
The key considerations with respect to the influence of environment parameters are the following: Firstly, which of the environmental parameters has the largest average impact on contract
performance? And secondly, which contract types are influenced
most by changes in the environment in which they operate (i.e. the
robustness of different contract types)? Note that impact in this
case can mean either a significantly positive or a significantly
negative slope of the linear regression line.
3
2
Measured as the average over all possible outcomes of the project.
4
Often dubbed a firm fixed price (FFP) contract in traditional literature.
Often described as a cost plus fixed fee (CPFF) contract in contracting literature.
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
17
Fig. 11. The average impact of variations in the environment for the different contract types. These are the outcomes for the situation where both a minimal earning and a
minimal range for the contractor's earnings is required.
Fig. 12. Average distance to the global Pareto front for multi-dimensional contract types (top panels), and the average spread obtained using different contract types for the
situation where both minimal earnings and range of the contractor's earnings is required (bottom panels).
Fig. 10 provides an answer to the former question by investigating
the impact of different environment parameters. An answer to the
latter question is provided by Fig. 11 which plots the average absolute
value of the scope coefficients for the various contract types.
Strong variation of impact across environment parameters: A
comparison of the impact of different environment parameters shows
that there is a clear distinction between parameters with a high
and low impact on contract type performance. These high-impact
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
18
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
Fig. 13. The average impact of variations in the environments for contracts of different compositions. These are the outcomes for the situation where minimal earning and
range contract design rules are enforced.
environment parameters can be identified in Fig. 10 by their large
positive or negative deviation from zero.
The results show that in situations where increasing the effort
has a larger impact on the other trade-offs (i.e. a high value for the
mED or mES multiplicators), the proximity to the efficient frontier
worsens for all dimensions. Contrarily, an increase in the convexity
of the relations between the cost and any of its drivers (duration,
scope and effort) has a generally positive influence on the proximity of contract sets of different types to the efficient frontier,
again for all dimensions.
The impact of environmental parameters on different contract
dimensions (cost, duration and scope) can also be substantially
different. An example of this are the convexity parameters (CMD,
CMS, CME), which have a substantially larger impact on cost
incentive contracts. Moreover, several other parameters show
opposite influences on contract types of different dimensions. An
example of is the cost of effort (Ecost
m ): an increase of this parameter
has a negative impact on cost incentive performance, but a positive impact on the performance of scope contracts.
After analysing which environment parameters have the largest influence on contract types in general, the inverse can also be
tested: which specific contract types are most susceptible to
changes in environment parameters in general? This impact is
expressed in relative terms for the various contract types in Fig. 11.
The vertical axis on these graphs represents the absolute value of
the regression slopes as they were used in Fig. 10.
Duration and scope contract types are more volatile when
faced with changes in the environment: Variations in the environment in which a contract type is operating have a greater average
impact on duration and scope contract types than on cost contract
types. Moreover, the relative impact of changes in the environment
differs little between different cost contract types, whereas more
significant fluctuations can be observed between duration and
scope contract types.
Preferred types are also robust to changing environments:
The preferred contract types (see Section 8.2.1) in general, and the
nonlinear contract types in particular show a remarkable robustness
to changes in the environment. Hence, the superior performance of
these types is likely to be valid across most types of projects.
Contrarily, several contract types show an above average volatility
when compared to the other contract types. Especially the LCS and
4PCS contract types for the duration and scope dimension
respectively, seem to be greatly influenced by the nature of the
environment. Other contract types which show above average
volatility in the scope dimension include the LSS, 3PPC and
4POO types.
Based on these observations, project owners are advised to pay
extra attention to the nature of the environment in which they are
operating when designing contracts for duration or scope
dimensions. Even more so when they opt for contract types different from the ones which were identified as most effective in
Section 8.2.1. Naturally, the environment parameters which were
identified as being most critical should have priority over the other
parameters when analysing the impact of the environment on
contract type performance.
8.3. Multi-dimensional experiments
The goal of the multi-dimensional experiments is to determine
how the performance of multi-dimensional contracts (i.e. contracts which combine cost, duration and scope incentives) compares to that of uni-dimensional contracts. Several authors have
highlighted the risk of contracts which focus on a single incentive
dimension [1,11,51], yet no extensive computational experiments
have been carried out to test these hypotheses.
Due to the exponential increase in computational complexity
when testing all possible contract combinations,5 these experiments were carried out using only a subset of the datasets which
were employed for the uni-dimensional experiments (see Section
8.2). The contract set used for this experiment is limited to the
linear contract types which are listed in Table 2, resulting in a total
of 189 cost contracts, 4536 duration contracts, and 225 scope
contracts. This means that a total of 193 million (189 4536 225)
multi-dimensional contract combinations are tested for each
environment.
The time needed to evaluate the performance of all these
combinations for a single environment is approximately 40 h
using a 2.26 GHz processor. Because of this, the number of environments on which the tests are carried out is also a subset of the
environments used in the uni-dimensional experiment. For both
the trade-off and evaluation datasets, one instance was initialised
using the average values for all parameters, plus for each parameter of the data set a high and low value instance with all other
parameters still at the average value was initialised. The values
used are simply the average, maximal and minimal values which
were mentioned in Table 3. The number of environments was
further reduced by always combining the trade-off and evaluation
models with the default instance of the evaluation and trade-off
5
Testing all possible combinations would take approximately 90,000 years on
a single core.
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
19
Table 4
Overview of model parameters.
Model
Contract model
Variable
Description
C; D; S
The observed cost, duration and scope at the end of the project
Cost, duration and scope incentive awarded
IC ; I D ; I S
Trade-off
C t ; Dt ; St
sCr
S
vD
r ; vr
Targets for cost, duration and scope as specified in the contract
S
BCr ; BD
r ; Br
The lower bound of cost, duration or scope region r in a (piecewise) linear contract
UBC ; UBD ; UBS
Upper bound of the region over which a cost, duration or scope incentive is spread using a nonlinear contract
LBC ; LBD ; LBS
Lower bound of the region over which a cost, duration or scope incentive is spread using a nonlinear contract
S
ICmax ; I D
max ; I max
Greatest incentive amount which can be awarded in a nonlinear cost, duration or scope contract
S
ICmin ; I D
min ; I min
Dlst
IlsD
Di ; Sj ; Ek
ΔDi ; ΔSj ; ΔEk
Greatest disincentive amount which can be awarded in a nonlinear cost, duration or scope contract
S
E
ΔC D
i ; ΔC j ; ΔC k
C min
SD ; S S ; S E
mab
Contract evaluation
Sharing ratio for (piecewise) linear cost incentive contract in region r
Region valuation parameter for piecewise linear duration/scope incentive
CM D ; CM S ; CM E
E½NOG
Elcost
Itot
l
NCGl
ROIE
NCGladj
NOGl
C l ; Dl ; Sl ; E l
μD ; μls ; μS
RNCGladj
RNOGl
MD
MAD
Itot
max
LBItot
max
RItot
DL
Target date associated with a lump-sum duration incentive amount
Incentive amount for a lump-sum duration incentive clause
The attainable values for duration, scope and effort as defined by a trade-off model
Attainable trade-off points for duration, scope and effort, defined as a distance to their lowest cost option
The impact on the cost of selecting duration, scope and effort mode i, j and k respectively
The lowest attainable cost for the project.
The slope of the relationship between the cost (dependent) and duration, scope and effort (independents)
Slope multiplicator, max impact of dimension b on the slope of the relationship between dimension a and the cost
The convexity magnitude for the relation between C (dependent) and D, S and E (independent) respectively
Expected net owner gain
Cost of effort
Total incentive awarded in scenario l
Net contractor gain for scenario l
Average ROI for effort investments by the contractor
Net contractor gain for scenario l taking opportunity cost into account
The value the owner derives from scenario l
The cost, duration, scope an effort associated with scenario l
The monetary valuation of time, deadline and scope of the owner
Relative net contractor gain: NCGladj rescaled to ½0; 1
Relative net owner gain: NOGl rescaled to ½0; 1
Mean deviation, a measure for the payoff alignment
Mean absolute deviation, a measure for the payoff alignment
The maximal attainable incentive amount for the contractor
A lower bound for the maximal incentive amount which can be earned by the contractor
The range of the incentive earnings by the contractor
External deadline relevant to the project owner
model respectively. This results in a total of 38 different project
environments, based on 27 trade-off models and 11 evaluation
models. Hence, a total of approximately 1520 single-core computation hours are needed to carry out this experiment.
The performance of contracts is evaluated by categorising them
into different types, and then comparing the Pareto front formed
by contracts of a certain type to the global Pareto front, which is
constructed by taking all possible contracts into consideration.
Similar to the uni-dimensional experiments, this is done for four
different strategies regarding sensible contract design: the
unrestricted case, the non-negative case, the minimum earnings
case and the minimal earnings and range case (see Section 8.2).
The results of this experiment will first be analysed in the context
of the relative performance of the different types of contracts in
Section 8.3.1. Next, the impact of variations in the environment is
discussed in Section 8.3.2.
8.3.1. Performance of contract types
The relative performance of different combinations of contract
types is visualised in Fig.12. To analyse the performance of these
multidimensional contracts, an number of new contract types are
defined, as can be seen from the horizontal axes on the figure. These
contract types can be interpreted as follows: A first set of contract
types focusses on the number of dimensions used in a contract, as well
as the nature of these dimensions. The n-dim nomenclature simply
indicates that the contract set contains incentives affecting n contract
dimensions out of a maximum of three (cost C, duration D and scope
S). When this name is followed by dimension names, this indicates
that the contracts belonging to this type have incentive clauses
exclusively for these specific types. For example the 2-dim, C&S contract type includes contracts which have both a cost and scope
incentive, but no duration incentive clause.
The second set of contract types refers to the inclusion of the
simple contract types as listed in Table 3 into a multi-dimensional
contract. The nomenclature is similar to the one used in Section
8.2. For example, the ( C LCC contract type represents all contracts containing an LCC contract for the cost dimension, regardless of any other incentives which may or may not be included.
This enables a comparison of the average effectiveness of different
types of contract clauses.
More dimensions yields better performance: Increasing the
number of dimensions of a contract has a positive effect on all metrics
for contract set performance. Looking at the performance of the
contract types which only specify the number of dimensions, it is
clear that the performance both in terms of proximity and spread
increases substantially when moving from a 1-dim contract to a 2dim contract, and from a 2-dim contract to a 3-dim contract (see
Fig. 12). Similarly, when looking at the types which also specify
certain contract dimensions to be used, an improvement can
always be seen when adding a contract dimension (e.g. moving
from a “1-dim, C” contract to a “2-dim, C&S” contract).
Duration 4 Scope 4 Cost: In case a 3-dimensional contract
cannot be implemented, the owner should opt to incentivise the
duration and scope dimensions in a bi-dimensional setup or the
duration dimension in a uni-dimensional setup, preferring the former
over the latter. The top left panel of Fig. 12 indicates that the performance in terms of proximity to the global frontier of a one and
two-dimensional contract is strongly dependent on the chosen
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
20
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
incentive dimensions. Specifically, the owner should prefer to
attach incentives to the duration and scope dimensions – in that
order. If the right incentive dimensions are chosen, the average
performance gap between contracts including more or less
incentives can be greatly reduced, although it still remains present.
Avoid contract components which transfer all risk to a single party: Multi-dimensional contracts which include components
which transfer all risk to one of the two parties (LCC or LOO) result in
suboptimal performance. The increased distance to the global
frontier when using such contracts (see the right panels of Fig. 12)
corroborates the undesirable behaviour of these contract types
which was observed in the uni-dimensional experiments.
8.3.2. Impact of environmental factors on performance
Fig. 13 shows how variations in the environment impact the performance of the tested multidimensional contracts. This performance
is measured as the slope of the linear regression line which estimates
the Δp as a function of the respective environment parameter.
Environmental robustness increases with dimensions: The
robustness to changes in the environment of contract types increases
as the number of incentivised dimensions in the contract increases
(see the left panel of Fig. 13). This is true for all but one case: when
moving from a one dimensional cost contract (1-dim, C) to a twodimensional cost and scope contract (2-dim, C&S), there is a slight
increase in the average sensitivity to changes in the environment.
This is due to the fact that incentivising the scope appears to be
highly sensitive to changes in the problem environment, as was
already observed in Section 8.2.2.
Preferred multidimensional types are relatively robust to
environmental changes: The most desirable multidimensional
contract types for each dimension identified in Section 8.3.1 are not
heavily influenced by changes in the environment. This confirms that
these managerial guidelines are valid regardless of the type of
project the owner is facing. Fig. 13 also shows that unidimensional
scope contracts are relatively unstable with respect to changes in
the environment parameters. Project owners should therefore be
cautious and verify the adequacy of such contracts in the specific
environment where they will be implemented.
Including certain components increases the environmental
sensitivity: The right pane of Fig. 13 reveals that using certain
components in multi-dimensional contracts can negatively influence
the robustness of the contract type. The greatest peak can be
observed for the ( C LCC contract type, which indicates that a
traditional firm fixed price contract is used for the cost dimension.
Again confirming preceding observations of the risks involved
when implementing this type of contract.
Based on these observations, a contract owner wishing to
construct a contract structure which is robust to changes in the
environment in which it operates is advised to use as many
dimensions as possible in the contract. In case it is impossible to
construct a three-dimensional contract, the combination of scope
and duration is on average most robust for a two-dimensional
contract. The best uni-dimensional alternative from a robustness
perspective is the introduction of a cost incentive, however given
that a uni-dimensional duration contract only slightly more sensitive and yields better performance on average (see Section 8.3.1),
we advise a uni-dimensional duration contract instead.
design of incentivised contracts. This model was also used to
conduct computational experiments, from which a set of managerial contract design guidelines have been derived (see summary in the following table).
The results of these experiments indicate that multidimensional
contracts with piecewise linear and/or nonlinear incentive clauses
are superior on all performance metrics. Moreover, good performing contract structures are generally more robust to changes in the
environment in which they operate, and can therefore be applied in
structurally different project environments.
Linear contracts which transfer all the risk to one of the two parties, such as the traditional firm fixed price (FFP) and cost plus fixed
fee (CPFF) contracts should be avoided in both uni-dimensional and
multi-dimensional incentive contracts. These contracts produce inferior results in terms of both solution quality and diversity, whilst also
being less robust to changes in the environment in which they operate, when compared to other contract alternatives.
Furthermore, when incentivising all dimensions is impossible
from a practical point of view, the owner's first aim should be to
implement a duration incentive, then a scope incentive in that
order. This opposes the traditional focus on cost incentives in both
literature and practice.
Several extensions of the problem can be considered relevant
for future research. A first extension would be to implement more
advanced optimisation techniques to optimise the contract parameters, rather than the full factorial approach taken in this study.
Secondly, the realism of the model could also be improved by
lifting the assumption of full information as well as the deterministic nature of the trade-offs. These conditions could be tested
within a game-theoretical setting which analyses the optimal
behaviour of both owner and contractor in both single and repeated games. A final area for future research would be the implementation of this model in real life case studies.
Experiment
Uni-dimensional
Contract
type
Nonlinear and piecewise contract outperform linear contracts.
Avoid transfer of all risk
to one party.
Preferred types are
robust to imposed
restrictions.
Skewness persists
within contract types.
Environment Strong variation of
impact across environment parameters.
Duration and scope
contracts are more
volatile.
Preferred types are
more robust.
Multi-dimensional
More dimensions
improve performance.
Duration 4 Scope 4
Cost.
Avoid contract components transferring risk
to a single party.
More incentivised
dimensions improves
robustness.
Preferred multidimensional types are
more robust.
Including certain components increases
sensitivity.
9. Conclusions
This paper discussed incentive contract design for projects
from the perspective of the project owner. Based on axioms
derived from an extensive literature review, a model consisting of
three subcomponents has been constructed. The model serves as a
framework which can be used by project owners to improve the
Acknowledgements
We acknowledge the support provided by the Bijzonder
Onderzoeksfonds (BOF) for the project with Contract no. BOF12GOA021. This work was carried out using the STEVIN Supercomputer
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
21
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
Infrastructure at Ghent University, funded by Ghent University, the
Flemish Supercomputer Center (VSC), the Hercules Foundation and
the Flemish Government department EWI. We would also like to
express our thanks to the anonymous reviewers and the editor of
Omega for their helpful comments.
can be determined by the linear approximation of the curve, and
the desired convexity of the curve (CM).
max ΔΔΔC min
s:t:
0 r ΔΔC 1 ;
ΔΔC i
Appendix A. Overview of notation
Table 4 presents an overview of all the notation introduced in
this paper.
ðC:1Þ
n
X
1r
i ¼ 1; …; n
ΔΔC i ;
ðC:2Þ
i ¼ 2; …; n
ðC:3Þ
ΔΔC i ¼ ΔC n
ðC:4Þ
i¼1
ΔΔΔC min r ΔΔC 1
Appendix B. Derivation of the CM metric
ΔΔΔC min r ΔΔC i ΔΔC i
The basic definition of the CM metric is as follows:
CM ¼
A
A þB
ðB:1Þ
The variable A can be eliminated by calculating the surface of
the triangle as follows:
AþB ¼
A¼
ΔD n Δ C n
2
ΔDn ΔC n
2
B
ðB:2Þ
And rewriting CM as
CM ¼
ΔDn ΔC n
B
A
2
¼
¼1
A þB ΔDn ΔC n
BþB
2
2B
ðB:3Þ
ΔDn ΔC n
The value of B can be calculated as
n
X
1
ðΔDi ΔDi 1 ÞΔC i 1 þ ðΔDi ΔDi
B¼
2
i¼1
ðC:5Þ
CM ¼ 1
2
1;
i ¼ 2; …; n
ðC:6Þ
3
ðC:7Þ
n
i 1
X
X
2
1
4
ΔΔC j þ ΔΔC i 5
n ΔC n i ¼ 1 j ¼ 1
2
Eq. (C.2) stipulates that the ΔC i curve should always be an
increasing function (see axioms 1–3). The convexity of the tradeoff curve is guaranteed by Eq. (C.3) which states that the consecutive steps have to be of nondecreasing magnitude. Eq. (C.4)
ensures that the final point of the convex trade-off curve coincides
with the linear approximation on which this curve is based, the
latter is defined as the parameter ΔC n . The value of the smallest
difference between the consecutive steps is assigned by Eqs. (C.5)
and (C.6). Finally, Eq. (C.7) guarantees that the resulting curve has
the desired convexity magnitude specified by the parameter CM.
References
Δ C i ΔC i
1 Þð
1Þ
ðB:4Þ
In case of generated convex curves it can be assumed that the
step size of the duration is always identical and therefore all equal
to ΔDn =n. This means the formula can be simplified to
n
ΔDn X
ΔC ΔC i 1
ðB:5Þ
ΔC i 1 þ i
B¼
n i¼1
2
Appendix C. Linear model for trade-off model generation
The objective of this model is to create the smoothest possible
convex curve which starts and ends at the start and end points of
the linear approximation curve respectively. The model uses the
variable ΔΔC i to signify the change in cost between two consecutive points on the trade off curve: ΔC i ¼ ΔC i 1 þ ΔΔC i . The
graphical interpretation of these variables is illustrated in the right
panel of Fig. 5. Hence, this variable is indexed i¼1,…,n. Since the
curve is nondecreasing and convex it is known that each of these
variables is positive (see Eq. (C.2)) and at least as large as the
preceding variable (see Eq. (C.3)).
The smoothness of the curve can be measured by the difference
between two consecutive ΔΔC i variables, which indicate the
change in cost caused by a change of an independent variable
(duration, scope or effort). To avoid having linear segments where
the scope is not increased, the minimal difference between these
ΔΔC i variables is maximised. Doing this guarantees that the
continual slope increase over the consecutive discrete steps is as
large as possible. This minimal difference is represented by the
variable ΔΔΔC min in the model. The input parameters required for
the linear model are the greatest potential cost increase (ΔC n ), as
[1] Abu-Hijleh S, Ibbs C. Schedule-based construction incentives. J Constr Eng
Manag 1989;115(3):430–443.
[2] Afshar A, Kaveh A, Shoghli O. Multi-objective optimization of time-costquality using multi-colony ant algorithm. Asian J Civ Eng (Build Hous)
2007;8(2):113–124.
[3] Al-Subhi Al-Harbi KM. Sharing fractions in cost-plus-incentive-fee contracts.
Int J Proj Manag 1998;16(2):73–80.
[4] Anvuur A, Kumaraswamy M. Promises, pitfalls and shortfalls of the guaranteed
maximum price approach: a comparative case study; 2010.
[5] Arditi D, Yasamis F. Incentive/disincentive contracts: perceptions of owners
and contractors. J Constr Eng Manag 1998;124(5):361–373.
[6] Bayiz M, Corbett C. Coordination and incentive contracts in project management under asymmetric information. Available at SSRN 914227; 2005.
[7] Berends K. Cost plus incentive fee contracting—experiences and structuring.
Int J Proj Manag 2000;18:165–171.
[8] Boukendour S, Bah R. The guaranteed maximum price contract as call option.
Constr Manag Econ 2001;19(October (6)):563–567.
[9] Bower D, Ashby G, Gerald K, Smyk W. Incentive mechanisms for project
success. J Manag Eng 2002;18(1):37–43.
[10] Bresnen M, Marshall N. Partnering in construction: a critical review of issues,
problems and dilemmas. Constr Manag Econ 2000;18(2):229–237.
[11] Broome J, Perry J. How practitioners set share fractions in target cost contracts.
Int J Proj Manag 2002;20(January (1)):59–66.
[12] Bubshait Aa. Incentive/disincentive contracts and its effects on industrial
projects. Int J Proj Manag 2003;21(January (1)):63–70.
[13] Chan D, Lam P, Chan J. A comparative study of the benefits of applying target
cost contracts between South Australia and Hong Kong. Proj Manag J 2012;
43(2):4–20.
[14] Chan DW, Chan AP, Lam PT, Wong JM. Identifying the critical success factors
for target cost contracts in the construction industry. J Facil Manag 2010;
8(3):179–201.
[15] Chan DW, Chan AP, Lam PT, Wong JM. An empirical survey of the motives and
benefits of adopting guaranteed maximum price and target cost contracts in
construction. Int J Proj Manag 2011;29(July (5)):577–590.
[16] Chan DW, Lam PT, Chan AP, Wong JM. Achieving better performance through
target cost contracts: the tale of an underground railway station modification
project. Facilities 2010;28(5/6):261–277.
[17] Chan JH, Chan DW, Lam PT, Chan AP. Preferred risk allocation in target cost
contracts in construction. Facilities 2011;29(13/14):542–562.
[18] Chapman C, Ward S. The efficient allocation of risk in contracts. Omega
1994;22(November (6)):537–552.
[19] Chapman C, Ward S. Developing and implementing a balanced incentive and
risk sharing contract. Constr Manag Econ 2008;26(June (6)):659–669.
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i
22
L.P. Kerkhove, M. Vanhoucke / Omega ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎
[20] Chen T, Klastorin T, Wagner, MR. Incentive contracts in serial stochastic projects.
Manuf Serv Oper Manag, http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/msom.2015.0528, in press.
[21] Choi K, Kwak YH. Decision support model for incentives/disincentives time
cost tradeoff. Autom Constr 2012;21(January):219–228.
[22] Choi K, Kwak YH, Yu B. Quantitative model for determining incentive/disincentive amounts through schedule simulations. In: Proceedings of the 2010
winter simulation conference (WSC); 2010. p. 3295–306.
[23] Cohen I, Iluz M. When cost-effective design strategies are not enough:
evidence from an experimental study on the role of redundant goals. Omega;,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2014.09.007, in press.
[24] Cukierman A, Shiffer Z. Contracting for optimal delivery time in long-term
projects. Bell J Econ 1976;7(1):132–149.
[25] Dayanand N, Padman R. Project contracts and payment schedules: the client's
problem. Manag Sci 2001;47:1654–1667.
[26] DeWit A. Measurement of project success. Int J Proj Manag 1988;6(3):
164–170.
[27] Ederer F, Manso G. Is pay for performance detrimental to innovation? Manag
Sci 2013;59(7):1496–1513.
[28] El-Rayes K. Optimim planning of highway construction under A þ B bidding
method. J Constr Eng Manag 2001;127(4):261–269.
[29] El-Rayes K, Kandil A. Time-cost-quality trade-off analysis for highway construction. J Constr Eng Manag 2005;131(april (4)):477–486.
[30] Gangwar M, Goodrum PM. The effect of time on safety incentive programs in
the US construction industry. Constr Manag Econ 2005;23(8):851–859.
[31] Ghodsi R, Skandari MR, Allahverdiloo M, Iranmanesh SH. A new practical
model to trade-off time, cost, and quality of a project. Aust J Basic Appl Sci
2009;3(4):3741–3756.
[32] Gibbons R. Incentives between firms (and within). Manag Sci 2005;51(1):
2–17.
[33] Herbsman Z. A þ B bidding method—hidden success story for highway construction. J Constr Eng Manag 4:1995.
[34] Herten H, Peeters W. Incentive contracting as a project management tool. Int J
Proj Manag 1986;4(1):34–39.
[35] Hiller J, Tollison R. Incentive versus cost-plus contracts in defense procurement. J Ind Econ 1978;26(3):239–248.
[36] Jaafari A. Twinning time and cost in incentive-based contracts. J Manage Eng
1996;4(62). http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)0742-597X.
[37] Jaraiedi M, Plummer RW, Aber MS. Incentive/disincentive guidelines for
highway construction contracts. J Constr Eng Manag 1995;121(March
(1)):112–120.
[38] Kandil A, El-Rayes K. Parallel genetic algorithms for optimizing resource utilization in large-scale construction projects. J Constr Eng Manag 2006;132
(May (5)):491–498.
[39] Kelley J, Walker M. Critical path planning and scheduling: an introduction.
Ambler, PA: Mauchly Associates; 1959.
[40] Keren B, Cohen Y. Optimising project performance: the triangular trade off
optimisation approach. Int J Eng Manag Econ 2012;3:152–170.
[41] Kerr S. On the folly of rewarding a, while hoping for b. Acad Manag J 1975;
18(4):769–783.
[42] Lee E, Thomas D. State-of-practice technologies on accelerated urban highway
rehabilitation: I-15 California experience. J Constr Eng Manag 2007;2
(105):133. http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)0733-9364.
[43] Lippman Sa, McCardle KF, Tang CS. Using Nash bargaining to design project
management contracts under cost uncertainty. Int J Prod Econ 2013;145
(September (1)):199–207.
[44] Love PE, Davis PR, Chevis R, Edwards DJ. Risk/reward compensation model for
civil engineering infrastructure alliance projects. J Constr Eng Manag 2010;
137(2):127–136.
[45] Mackley, A.R., 2012. Use of incentive/disincentive contracting to mitigate work
zone traffic impacts [Ph.D. thesis]. University of Missouri, Columbia.
[46] Markowitz H. Portfolio selection*. J Financ 1952;7(1):77–91.
[47] Marques G, Gourc D, Lauras M. Multi-criteria performance analysis for decision making in project management. Int J Proj Manag 2011;29(8):1057–1069.
[48] McAfee R, McMillan J. Bidding for contracts: a principal-agent analysis. RAND J
Econ 1986;17(3):326–338.
[49] McCall J. The simple economics of incentive contracting. Am Econ Rev
1970;1:28–29.
[50] Meinhart W, Delionback L. Project management: an incentive contracting
decision model. Acad Manag J 1968:427–435.
[51] Meng X, Gallagher B. The impact of incentive mechanisms on project performance. Int J Proj Manag 2012;30(April (3)):352–362.
[52] Mihm J. Incentives in new product development projects and the role of target
costing. Manag Sci 2010;56(8):1324–1344.
[53] Müller R, Turner JR. The impact of principal-agent relationship and contract
type on communication between project owner and manager. Int J Proj Manag
2005;23(5):398–403.
[54] Okabe T, Jin Y, Sendhoff B. A critical survey of performance indices for multiobjective optimisation. In: The 2003 congress on evolutionary computation
(CEC'03), vol. 2. IEEE; 2003. p. 878–85.
[55] Paquin J, Couillard J, Ferrand D. Assessing and controlling the quality of a
project end product: the earned quality method. IEEE Trans Eng Manag
2000;47(1):88–97.
[56] Perry JG, Barnes M. Target cost contracts: an analysis of the interplay between
fee, target, share and price. Eng Constr Archit Manag 2000;7(2):202–208.
[57] Pollack-johnson B, Liberatore MJ. Incorporating quality considerations into
project time/cost tradeoff analysis and decision making. IEEE Trans Eng Manag
2006;53(4):534–542.
[58] Ramón J, Cristóbal JS. Time, cost, and quality in a road building project. J
Constr Eng Manag 2009;135(11):1271–1275.
[59] Rosandich RG. Choosing the best contract type for a given situation: an agentbased simulation study. Technical report. Working paper. Department of
Mechanical and Industrial Engineering, University of Minnesota Duluth; 2007.
[60] Rose T, Manley K. Financial incentives and advanced construction procurement systems. Proj Manag J 2010;41:40–50.
[61] Rose T, Manley K. Motivation toward financial incentive goals on construction
projects. J Bus Res 2011;64(July (7)):765–773.
[62] Rose TM. The impact of financial incentive mechanisms on motivation in
Australian government large non-residential building projects [Ph.D. thesis].
Queensland University of Technology; 2008.
[63] Rosenfeld Y, Geltner D. Cost-Plus and incentive contracting: some false benefits and inherent drawbacks. Constr Manag Econ 1991;9:481–492.
[64] Ryan PJ, Henin CG, Gandhi DK. Financial incentives for cost control under
moral hazard. Omega 1986;14(January (3)):221–231.
[65] Sacks R, Harel M. An economic game theory model of subcontractor resource
allocation behaviour. Constr Manag Econ 2006;24(8):869–881.
[66] Sarker R, Coello CAC. Assessment methodologies for multiobjective evolutionary algorithms. In: Evolutionary optimization. New York City: Springer;
2002. p. 177–195.
[67] Schutze O, Esquivel X, Lara A, Coello Coello CA. Using the averaged Hausdorff
distance as a performance measure in evolutionary multiobjective optimization. IEEE Trans Evol Comput 2012;16(4):504–522.
[68] Shahsavari Pour N, Modarres M, Tavakkoli-Moghaddam R, Najafi E. Optimizing
a multi-objectives time-cost-quality trade-off problem by a new hybrid
genetic algorithm. World Appl Sci J 2010;10(3):355–363.
[69] Shr J, Chen W. Setting maximum incentive for incentive/disincentive contracts
for highway projects. J Constr Eng Manag 2004;130(1):84–93.
[70] Shr J, Ran B, Sung C. Method to determine minimum contract bid for A þB þ I/
D highway projects. J Constr Eng Manag 2004;130(4):509–516.
[71] Shr JF, Chen WT. A method to determine minimum contract bids for incentive
highway projects. Int J Proj Manag 2003;21(November (8)):601–615.
[72] Sillars DN. Establishing guidelines for incentive/disincentive contracting at odot.
Technical report. Oregon Department of Transportation, Research Unit; 2007.
[73] Song L, AbouRizk SM. Quantifying engineering project scope for productivity
modeling. J Constr Eng Manag 2005;131(3):360–367.
[74] Stenbeck T. Quantifying effects of incentives in a rail maintenance
performance-based contract. J Constr Eng Manag 2008;134(4):265–272.
[75] Stukhart G. Contractual incentives. J Constr Eng Manag 1984;110(March
(1)):34–42.
[76] Tang W, Duffield C, Young D. Partnering mechanism in construction: an
empirical study on the Chinese construction industry. J Constr Eng Manag 132
(March);2006:217–30.
[77] Tang W, Qiang M, Duffield CF, Young DM, Lu Y. Incentives in the chinese
construction industry. J Constr Eng Manag 2008;134(7):457–467.
[78] Tareghian H, Taheri S. On the discrete time, cost and quality trade-off problem.
Appl Math Comput 2006;181:1305–1312.
[79] Tavana M, Abtahi A-R, Khalili-Damghani K. A new multi objective multi mode
model for solving preemptive time cost quality trade off project scheduling
problems. Expert Syst Appl 2013;41(August (4)):1830–1846.
[80] Turner JR. Farsighted project contract management: incomplete in its entirety.
Constr Manag Econ 2004;22(January (1)):75–83.
[81] Van Veldhuizen DA. Multiobjective evolutionary algorithms: classifications,
analyses, and new innovations. Technical report. DTIC Document; 1999.
[82] Van Weele A, van der Puil J. International contracting: contract management
in complex construction projects. Singapore: World Scientific Publishing
Company; 2013.
[83] Veld JiT, Peeters W. Keeping large projects under control: the importance of
contract type selection. Int J Proj Manag 1989;7(August (3)):155–162.
[84] Walker DH, Hampson K, Peters R. Project alliancing vs project partnering: a
case study of the Australian national museum project. Supply Chain Manag:
Int J 2002;7(2):83–91.
[85] Wang X, Zhu Q, Cheng T. Subcontracting price schemes for order acceptance
and scheduling. Omega 2015;54:1–10.
[86] Ward S, Chapman C. Evaluating fixed price incentive contracts. Omega
1995;23(February (1)):49–62.
[87] Weitzman ML. Efficient incentive contracts. Q J Econ 1980:719–730.
[88] William IC, Ashley D. Impact of various construction contract clauses. J Constr
Eng Manag 1987;113(3):501–521.
[89] Zhang H, Xing F. Fuzzy-multi-objective particle swarm optimization for timecost-quality tradeoff in construction. Autom Constr 2010;19(December
(8)):1067–1075.
[90] Zhang J, Liu G, Zhang Q, Bai Z. Coordinating a supply chain for deteriorating
items with a revenue sharing and cooperative investment contract. Omega
2015;56:37–49.
[91] Zhang L, Wu Q, Chen C, Yue Y. Solution for the nonlinear multi-objective
model in construction projects using improved particle swarm optimization.
Res J Appl Sci Eng Technol 2012;4(19):3565–3573.
Please cite this article as: Kerkhove LP, Vanhoucke M. Incentive contract design for projects: The owner's perspective. Omega (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.09.002i