The state of world fisheries and
aquaculture 1998
FOREWORD
The idea of publishing The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture was conceived in
1995 in recognition of the growing demand for reliable information on the subject. Since
there was no periodical providing a global and comprehensive view of the sector and
covering policy issues, the FAO Fisheries Department decided to publish such a report
every two years. The State of the World Fisheries and Aquaculture 1996 serves as a
benchmark document, as it provides an initial overview of world fisheries and
aquaculture and places the sector in a longer-term perspective by examining trends from
1950 to the present, while also looking ahead to the year 2010.
While providing a similar overview, this issue of The State of World Fisheries and
Aquaculture examines developments in the sector from the perspective of sustainability
in fisheries and aquaculture. The report aims to shed light on the need for and effects of
good governance in fisheries and aquaculture, while also highlighting two closely related
issues: the establishment of an enabling environment for aquaculture activity and the
integration of fisheries into coastal zone management.
With regard to capture fisheries, matching fishing capacity with available resources and
managing by-catch and discards are the main points considered. Several other questions
are posed on a more general level. Are fisheries and aquaculture any closer to being
sustainably managed as a result of current changes in approach? Do these changes
increase the contribution of fisheries and aquaculture to sustainable development? Are
international initiatives to support this process helping to head the sector in the right
direction?
The need to promote implementation of the Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries,
especially in relation to the allocation of fishing rights, is made evident throughout The
State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 1998, which discusses existing practices in the
management of fishing capacity as well as new approaches being adopted by some
countries, such as individual transferable quotas (ITQs). A review of patterns in the
employment of fishers and an analysis of trends in the world fishing fleet add to the
report's value.
Updated information on past and present trends and expected future developments in
fisheries resources, production, utilization and trade is complemented by discussions of
major issues facing fishers and aquaculturists and a report on the most recent actions
taken in the area of fisheries.
The principal purpose of The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture is to inform
policy-makers, participants in fisheries and civil society in an accurate and objective
manner. Furthermore, by generating awareness of the global interaction inherent to the
sector, it seeks to encourage managers and other decision-makers to learn from the
experience of others. By doing so, we trust our report will contribute to national, regional
and global efforts in ensuring responsible practices and sustainable development in
fisheries and aquaculture.
Moritaka Hayashi
Assistant Director-General
Fisheries Department
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 1998 was prepared by FAO Fisheries
Department staff, led by a team comprising U. Wijkström, A. Gumy and R. Grainger.
General direction was provided by the department's management staff, including: J.
Caddy; I. Feidi; S. Garcia; M. Hayashi; J. Jia; B. Satia; J. Valdemarsen; G. Valdimarsson.
Texts for the first section of Part 1, The state of fishery resources: trends in production,
utilization and trade, were provided by J. Csirke (resources), R. Grainger (production,
capture fisheries), K. Rana (production, aquaculture) and H. Josupeit (trade).
Contributors to Part 2, Selected issues facing fishers and aquaculturists, included D.
Doulman (governance), R. Willmann (integrating fisheries), D. Greboval (fishing
capacity), G. Everett (by-catch and discards) and Z. Shehadeh (sustainable aquaculture),
whose original texts were coordinated by consultant M. Sanders.
In Part 3, Inland fisheries resources: their status and use was written by J. Kapetsky.
Texts for the section Fishers and fishing fleets were contributed by A. Crispoldi, R.
Grainger and A. Smith.
Part 4, Outlook: expected trends in supply and demand, was written by U. Wijkström.
Part 5, Fishery activities of country groupings, was written by A. Gumy.
Several staff as well as non-FAO authors have contributed texts on specific issues, and
they are cited in the relevant boxes throughout the publication. Data for the original
version of graphics were provided by S. Montanaro.
Most staff members of the FAO Fisheries Department have contributed in one way or
another to this year's report. Many, including staff in FAO Regional and Subregional
Offices, provided valuable input in the form of critical text reviews.
The Editorial Group of the FAO Information Division was responsible for the editing,
design and desktop publishing of The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 1998.
GLOSSARY
AFFP
Arab Federation of Fish Producers
AFMA
Australian Fisheries Management
Authority
AFTA
ASEAN Free Trade Area
AIS
automatic identification systems
ASEAN
Association of Southeast Asian
Nations
CAC
Codex Alimentarius Commission
CAP
Common Agricultural Policy (EC)
CARICOM
Caribbean Community and
Common Market
CECAF
Fishery Committee for the Eastern
Central Atlantic
CEPT
Common Effective Preferential
Tariff (ASEAN)
CET
common external tariff
CFP
Common Fisheries Policy (EC)
CFRAMP
CARICOM Fisheries Resource
Assessment and Management
Program
CIDA
Canadian International
Development Agency
CIDA
Inter-American Committee for
Agricultural Development
CITES
Convention on International Trade
in Endangered Species of Wild
Fauna and Flora
COFI
Committee on Fisheries (FAO)
COMESA
Common Market for Eastern and
Southern Africa
CPUE
catch per unit effort
DWFN
Distant-Water Fishing Nations
EC
European Community
EEZ
exclusve economic zone
EIA
environmental impact assessment
EIFAC
European Inland Fisheries
Advisory Committee
EPIRB
emergency position-indicating
radio beacon
EU
European Union
FFA
South Pacific Forum Fisheries
Agency
FIFG
Financial Instrument for Fisheries
Guidance (EC)
FRDC
Fisheries Research and
Development Corporation
(Australia)
GAA
Global Aquaculture Alliance
GEF
Global Environment Facility
GESAMP
Joint Group of Experts on the
Scientific Aspects of Marine
Environmental Protection
(IMO/FAO/UNESCO IOC/WMO/IAEA/UN/UNEP)
GIS
geographic information system
GMDSS
Global Maritime Distress Safety
System
GPS
global positioning system
GRT
gross registered ton
GT
gross tonnage or tonnage (abbrev.)
HACCP
Hazard Analysis and Critical
Control Point (system)
HP
horsepower
IAEA
International Atomic Energy
Agency
IATTC
Inter-American Tropical Tuna
Commission
ICCAT
International Commission for the
Conservation of Atlantic Tunas
ICLARM
International Centre for Living
Aquatic Resources Management
ICM
integrated coastal management
IMO
International Maritime
Organization
INMARSAT
International Maritime Satellite
Organization
IOC
Intergovernmental Oceanographic
Commission
ITQ
individual transferable quota
IUCN
World Conservation Union
LAES
Latin American Economic System
LIFDC
low-income food-deficit country
MAC
Management Advisory Committee
(Australia)
MAGP
Multi-Annual Guidance
Programme (EC)
MCS
monitoring, control and
surveillance
MLS
minimum landing size
MPN
most probable number
MSY
maximum sustainable yield
MTNs
multilateral trade negotiations
NACA
Network of Aquaculture Centres in
Asia-Pacific
NAFTA
North American Free Trade
Agreement
NEI
not elsewhere indicated
NGO
non-governmental organization
OIE
International Office of Epizootics
OECD
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development
OLDEPESCA
Latin American Organization for
Fisheries Development
PRA
participatory rural appraisal
RRA
rapid rural appraisal
SAARC
South Asian Association for
Regional Cooperation
SCRS
Standing Committee on Research
and Statistics (ICCAT)
SEAFDEC
Southeast Asian Fisheries
Development Centre
SPC
Secretariat of the Pacific
Community
SPF
South Pacific Forum
SPS Agreement
Agreement on the Application of
Sanitary and Phytosanitary
Measures
TAC
total allowable catch
TBT
Agreement on Technical Barriers
to Trade
TURFS
territorial use rights in fisheries
UNCED
United Nations Conference on
Environment and Development
UNCLOS
United Nations Conference on the
Law of the Sea
UNESCO
United Nations Educational,
Scientific and Cultural
Organization
UNEP
United Nations Environment
Programme
VMS
vessel monitoring system
WECAFC
Western Central Atlantic Fisheries
Commission
WHO
World Health Organization
WMO
World Meteorological
Organization
WRI
World Resources Institute
WTO
World Trade Organization
PART 1
World review of fisheries and aquaculture
FISHERIES RESOURCES: TRENDS IN PRODUCTION,
UTILIZATION AND TRADE
OVERVIEW
In 1995 and 1996 total world fish production expanded rapidly, reaching 121 million
tonnes in the second year. Aquaculture output grew dramatically during the biennium
while capture fisheries production registered a slight increase. Supplies for human
consumption increased considerably, rising from 14.3 kg per caput (live weight
equivalent) in 1994 to 15.7 kg in 1996. However, this increase was almost entirely due to
raised production reported for mainland China.1 Excluding mainland China, at 13.3 kg,
the average food fish supply for the world in 1996 remained close to the level recorded
during the first half of the 1990s but was somewhat lower than that of the 1980s. Catches
destined for the production of fishmeal and fish oil (reduction) contracted somewhat.
(These trends in production and utilization are shown in Figures 1 and 2 and Table 1.)
Trade increased during the 1996-1997 biennium, although at a slower pace than in the
previous two years, and the value of world exports of fish and fishery products reached
US$52.5 billion in 1996, with developing countries achieving a net trade surplus of
US$16.6 billion.
PRODUCTION AND THE STATE OF FISHERIES RESOURCES
Capture fisheries
Total capture fisheries production in 1996 amounted to 94.6 million tonnes. China, Peru,
Chile, Japan, the United States, the Russian Federation and Indonesia (in that order) were
the top producer countries in 1996, together accounting for more than half of world
capture fisheries production in terms of tonnage (Figure 3). Marine capture fisheries
continued to account for more than 90 percent of world capture fisheries production, with
the remainder coming from inland waters.
World marine capture fisheries production reached a new record of 87.1 million tonnes
in 1996 (Table 1). However, as in previous years, the rate of increase continued to slow
during the biennium. In the 1950s and 1960s, total world marine fisheries production
increased on average by as much as 6 percent per year, doubling from 17 million tonnes
in 1950 to 34.9 million tonnes in 1961, and doubling again in the following two decades
to reach 68.3 million tonnes by 1983. In the following decade, the average annual rate of
increase dropped to 1.5 percent and to a mere 0.6 percent during the 1995/96 biennium.
The Northwest Pacific remains by far the most important fishing area in terms of both
volume and value of landings (Figures 4 and 5).
TABLE 1
World fisheries production and utilization
1990 1992
PRODUCTION
INLAND
1994 1995 1996
(million tonnes)
19971
Aquaculture
Capture
Total inland
8.17 9.39 12.11 13.86 15.61
6.59 6.25 6.91 7.38 7.55
14.76 15.64 19.02 21.24 23.16
17.13
7.70
24.83
MARINE
Aquaculture
Capture
Total marine
4.96 6.13 8.67 10.42 10.78
79.29 79.95 85.77 85.62 87.07
84.25 86.08 94.44 96.04 97.85
11.14
86.03
97.17
Total aquaculture
13.13 15.52 20.77 24.28 26.38
Total capture
85.88 86.21 92.68 93.00 94.63
Total world fisheries 99.01 101.73 113.46 117.28 121.01
28.27
93.73
122.00
UTILIZATION
Human consumption
Reduction
92.50
29.50
1
70.82 72.43 79.99 86.49 90.62
28.19 29.29 33.47 30.78 30.39
Preliminary estimate.
For the world as a whole, therefore, landings of marine fish are continuing to level off.
This is also the general trend for most major fishing areas of the world, where fisheries
have evolved from a phase of increasing fishing effort and production to one in which
production has stagnated and in some cases declined (i.e. a senescent phase). Judging
from known fish stocks and resources of traditional fisheries, the total marine catches
from most of the main fishing areas in the Atlantic Ocean and some in the Pacific Ocean
would appear to have reached their maximum potential some years ago, and substantial
total catch increases from these areas are therefore unlikely.
The relatively stable marine capture fisheries production total for the last three years
masks some major fluctuations for individual species. Major increases in landings
between 1995 and 1996 were recorded for capelin, chub mackerel and Japanese anchovy,
whereas major decreases between 1994 and 1995 were observed for South American
pilchard and anchoveta as well as Japanese pilchard. In 1995, six species - anchoveta,
Alaska pollock, Chilean jack mackerel, Atlantic herring, chub mackerel and capelin accounted for 25 percent of total capture fisheries production (Figure 6).
Distant-water fisheries production2 has declined sharply since 1990 (Figure 7), mainly
owing to the demise of the state-sponsored fleets of the former USSR. Japan had the
largest distant-water fisheries production in 1996, with total catches of 668 000 tonnes.
This is Japan's lowest figure since 1963, as the country's distant-water production has
declined steadily since the early 1970s when it amounted to about 2 million tonnes.
State of marine fish resources. Overall, the state of exploitation of the main fish stocks
(in fisheries for which assessment information is available) has remained more or less
unchanged since the early 1990s. Recent reviews tend to confirm that, among the major
fish stocks for which information is available, an estimated 44 percent are fully exploited
and are therefore producing catches that have reached or are very close to their maximum
limit, with no room expected for further expansion. About 16 percent are overfished and
likewise leave no room for expansion; moreover, there is an increasing likelihood that
catches might decrease if remedial action is not undertaken to reduce or suppress
overfishing. Another 6 percent appear to be depleted, with a resulting loss in total
production, not to mention the social and economic losses derived from the uncontrolled
and excessive fishing pressure, and 3 percent seem to be recovering slowly.
Fisheries in the Northwest Atlantic, the Southeast Atlantic and the Eastern Central
Atlantic reached their maximum production levels one or two decades ago and are now
showing a declining trend in total catches. In the Northeast Atlantic, the Southwest
Atlantic, the Western Central Atlantic, the Eastern Central Pacific, the Northeast Pacific
and the Mediterranean and Black Seas, annual catches seem to have stabilized, or are
declining slightly, after having reached a maximum potential a few years ago. The
declining and flattening catch trends in these areas are consistent with the observation
that these areas have the highest incidence of fully exploited fish stocks and of stocks that
are either overexploited, depleted or recovering after having been depleted.
The main areas where total catches still follow an increasing trend and where, in
principle, some potential for increase still exists are the Eastern and Western Indian
Ocean, the Western Central Pacific and the Northwest Pacific. These areas tend to have a
lower incidence of fully exploited, overexploited, depleted or recovering fish stocks, with
relatively more underexploited or moderately exploited stocks. However, these areas are
also the ones with the largest incidence of stocks whose state of exploitation is unknown
or uncertain, and for which production estimates and stock assessments are consequently
less reliable.
BOX 1
Quotas for cod stocks: an update
The quotas for Atlantic cod in the Barents Sea were reduced by about
195 000 tonnes or approximately 22 percent from 1997 to 1998.
However, about 13 000 tonnes of the Norwegian 1997 quota was not
caught and the share of the Russian quota not caught is expected to be
even higher - approximately 40 000 tonnes. Consequently, the
decrease in catch from 1997 to 1998 might not be as large as the quota
indicates. According to Norwegian experts, the reduction is not
expected to be of the same scale in the near future.
Iceland has also increased its cod quota, raising it by 32 000 tonnes to
218 000 tonnes for the period from 1 September 1997 to 31 August
1998. By 1 January 1998, 144 000 tonnes of the Icelandic quota had
not been taken, which is about 30 000 tonnes more than the previous
year. The outlook for future output from Icelandic waters is also good,
although very weak results in the Barents Sea loophole1 in 1997
indicate a pause in the Icelandic cod fishery in this area. In the Pacific,
the major cod-catching country is the United States, and it is reducing
its quotas from 270 000 tonnes in 1997 to 210 000 tonnes in 1998.
1
An international fishing area surrounded by national EEZs.
Source: H. Josupeit. FAO Fisheries Department.
Inland capture fisheries production. Nominally, exploitation of inland fisheries
resources amounts to 7.6 million tonnes, equal to 8 percent of total capture in 1996.
Exploitation is mainly of finfish, although molluscs (7 percent) and crustaceans (6
percent) may be locally important. The production of reptiles, including crocodiles,
alligators and caimans, is recorded by number and reached slightly more than 1 million in
1996 (including cultured production).
Six of the ten top producers for inland capture fisheries are in Asia: China, with a
production of nearly 1.8 million tonnes, produces 23 percent of the world total and nearly
three times as much as the second largest producer, India. Altogether, the top ten
producer countries account for about 62 percent of world landings from inland capture
fisheries.
In Africa, the majority of freshwater fish landings consist of Nile perch, followed by Nile
tilapia, other tilapias, dagaas and silver cyprinid. These reflect both the importance of
large lake fisheries (Lake Victoria, at its peak, accounted for about one-fourth of all of
the inland catch from Africa) and the fact that more complete catch data are available for
these fisheries than for smaller water bodies.
Inland catches mainly consist of: cyprinids as a group, snakeheads and shads in Asia;
European perch, common carp, northern pike and roaches in Europe; of Azov Sea sprat,
freshwater bream, roaches and pike perch in the CIS and the Baltic states; of characinids
and freshwater siluroids in Latin America; and of lake whitefish, yellow perch, crayfish
and catfish in North America.
State of inland fish resources. Based on total inland capture for the period 1984-1996, it
is clear that increasing use is being made of inland fisheries resources. The average
annual increase is about 130 000 tonnes (about 2 percent per annum), and exploitation is
most intensive in Asia and Africa (Figure 8).3
Looking broadly at continental areas, neither the present state of nor the short-term
outlook for inland aquatic resources is encouraging. An increase in the loss and
degradation of land and forest resources and of biodiversity and habitat as well as the
growing scarcity and pollution of freshwater can be observed in Africa, Asia and the
Pacific, Latin America and the Caribbean and West Asia.4 Europe and the CIS and the
Baltic states are also experiencing increasing biodiversity loss and habitat degradation.
On the other hand, in North America, land degradation is decreasing.
Aquaculture
Aquaculture provided 20 percent of global fisheries production (and 29 percent of food
fish) in 1996. Most aquaculture production (15.1 million tonnes) originated in freshwater.
Of the remainder, 9.7 million tonnes were produced in marine environments and about
1.6 million tonnes in brackish water environments (Figure 9). These figures are excluding
the production of aquatic plants, which amounted to 7.7 million tonnes in 1996.
Global production of aquaculture continues to be dominated by China, which in 1996
accounted for more than 67.8 percent of world output (Figure 10). However, given the
relatively low value of carp and seaweeds, which dominate Chinese culture, its
contribution to the world value of aquaculture production was just 45.4 percent. Japan, on
the other hand, accounted for 4 percent of total world aquaculture production by weight
but for more than twice that share by value because of the high-value species cultured
(e.g. amberjack, scallops and oysters).
The dominant global aquaculture activity in 1996 continued to be finfish production,
accounting for about 49 percent of total aquaculture production by weight and 55 percent
by value (Figure 11).
As in previous years, freshwater finfish, in particular Chinese and Indian carp, accounted
for the greatest share (42 percent) of total aquaculture production. Aquatic plants, 70
percent of which come from China, were valued at nearly US$5 billion and represented
almost one-quarter of total production in 1996. A key factor in the rapid production
growth of some species of finfish and crustaceans is the increasing availability of
hatchery-produced seed, in turn a reflection of a wider diffusion of the expertise needed
for successful hatchery operations.
While finfish account for almost 99 percent of freshwater aquaculture production, they
account for less than 10 percent of culture in the marine environment (Figure 12).
In 1996 the production of kelp, Laminaria japonica, totalled just more than 4 million
tonnes (Table 2). In terms of volume, this production figure made it the most important
species in aquaculture for that year. In fact, two of the top ten aquatic species produced
through culture were plants. It is worth noting that all these top species are low in the
food chain, i.e. they are either primary producers, filter feeders or finfish that, in their
adult stage, are herbivores or omnivores.
TABLE 2
World cultured aquatic production: top ten species in 1996, ranked by
volume
Common name
Latin name
Kelp
Pacific cupped oyster
Silver carp
Laminaria japonica
Crassostrea gigas
Hypophthalmichthys
molitrix
Ctenopharyngodon
idellus
Cyprinus carpio
Aristichthys nobilis
Pecten yessoensis
Grass carp
Common carp
Bighead carp
Yesso scallop
Production
(million tonnes)
4.17
2.92
2.88
2.44
1.99
1.41
1.27
Japanese carpet shell
Crucian carp
Nile tilapia
Ruditapes
philippinarum
Carassius carassius
Oreochromis niloticus
1.12
0.69
0.60
Because of its high unit value, the giant tiger prawn tops the list of species ranked
according to the total value (ex farmgate) of production (Table 3). Nearly all giant tiger
prawn production is carried out in a tropical environment and the product exported to
developed economies. This particular activity therefore provides a significant
contribution to some Asian and Latin American economies.
TABLE 3
World cultured aquatic production: top ten species in 1996, ranked by
value
Common name
Latin name
Giant tiger prawn
Pacific cupped oyster
Silver carp
Penaeus monodon
Crassostrea gigas
Hypophthalmichthys
molitrix
Laminaria japonica
Cyprinus carpio
Ctenopharyngodon
idellus
Salmo salar
Pecten yessoensis
Ruditapes
philippinarum
Aristichthys nobilis
Kelp
Common carp
Grass carp
Atlantic salmon
Yesso scallop
Japanese carpet shell
Bighead carp
Value
(billion US$)
3.93
3.23
2.79
2.70
2.42
2.23
1.87
1.62
1.52
1.31
The other high-value species that is not among the ten with the highest production figures
is Atlantic salmon, which is grown in cold climates where a large share of it is also
consumed.
Although a few advanced economies such as Japan, Norway and the United States feature
among the top producers (Figure 10), aquaculture production is carried out predominantly
in low-income food-deficit countries (LIFDCs) .
By 1996, 27.9 million tonnes, or around 82 percent of world total finfish, shellfish and
aquatic plant production originated in LIFDCs. The contribution of this group of
countries to world production has increased sharply since 1990 (Figure 13). At 16.7
percent, between 1990 and 1996 the average expansion rate of the aquaculture sector
within LIFDCs was nearly six times that in non-LIFDCs, which recorded 2.9 percent
overall. Most of the production comes from six countries, with China accounting for
about 83 percent (Figure 14).
BOX 2
Monitoring hatchery production: at least 160 million fry
a day!
To improve the utilization of aquatic biodiversity, governments need
information on hatchery output. However, the collection of
information on this subject is not always systematic, since a central
mechanism for collating related data is often lacking.
At the request of FAO, therefore, member countries have recently
submitted hatchery production statistics, and these have been analysed,
revealing a total reported production for 1996 of 58 000 million fry
and/or fingerlings, i.e. almost 180 million juveniles per day! Of these,
99 percent were finfish. The majority of this reported hatchery
production was intended for "release to the wild".
The data supplied are most complete for those countries where inland
waters have traditionally been stocked for recreational fishing. The
most consistent data have been obtained from Australia, Belgium,
Croatia (since 1992), Cuba, Cyprus, Finland, France, Latvia, Malaysia,
Morocco, Panama, the Republic of Korea, South Africa (since 1993),
Switzerland and the United States.
Figures A and B show hatchery production of rainbow trout (for
Cyprus) and brown trout (for Finland) as examples of similar species
used for different purposes.
Source: A.J. Immink. Visiting scientist (aquaculture), FAO Fisheries
Department.
Numbers of fishers and fishing vessels
Information provided recently by FAO member countries on numbers of fishers5 and
fishing vessels6 indicates that, while the expansion of fishing fleets seems to be slowing
down, the number of fishers appears to be rising relatively fast. However, as the number
of fishers includes individuals engaged in aquaculture - and not separately identified in
most cases - the increase in the number of participants in capture fisheries is in fact
slower than the overall figures suggest.
Fishers. Recent information on the number of fishers7 is scarce, as few countries collect
and publish annual estimates. Among those that do are China, Iceland, India, Japan and
Norway, data for which are presented in Table 4. As can be expected, the figures show
that, while the numbers of fishers are shrinking in capital-intensive economies, they are
expanding in economies that are still predominantly labour-intensive.
TABLE 4
Number of fishers (including fish farmers) in selected countries1
Country
1970
China (number)
2
300 000
(index)
66
2
Japan (number) 549 357
1980 1990
2 950 3 460
344
345
85
100
457
242
380
990
(index)
243
188
100
Iceland (number) 4 895 5 946 6 951
(index)
70
86
100
India (number) 104 000 2 008 1 741
913
265
(index)
60
115
100
Norway (number) 21 000 19 425 20 475
(index)
102
95
100
1994
1995
4 740 5 071
483
940
137
147
202 000 193 000
1996
5 396
370
156
...
83
79
6278 5 661 5 635
90
81
81
2 045 2 394
...
701
1743
118
138
16 442 17 160 17 087
80
84
83
1
The data for Japan and Iceland include part-time fishers.
Japan's data for 1994 and 1995 do not include women engaged in fisheries and
aquaculture. These figures have been reported separately and are, respectively, 55 460
and 54 230.
3
Estimate (1995 data unavailable).
Note: ... = data unavailable.
2
Non-decked vessels. The numbers of non-decked fishing vessels, more than 90 percent of
which are found in Africa and Asia, have expanded only marginally since 1985.
Decked fishing vessels. Information provided by countries indicates that that the number
of decked fishing vessels - like marine fish landings - is increasing but at a declining rate
(Figure 15). This contrasts with a more rapid expansion witnessed during the period
1970-1989. The aggregate of the fleet tonnage (GT) has displayed a similar development.
Between 1980 and 1997, China's fleet of decked fishing vessels increased from about
60 000 to 460 000 vessels (Figure 16). Without this increase, the number of decked
fishing vessels in the world would have remained stable during the period.
A study of Lloyd's Register of Shipping8 reveals that fishing vessels above 100 GT have
decreased in number over the last seven years, as the decommissioning of vessels has
outpaced new constructions. In 1991, there were slightly fewer than 26 000 fishing
vessels of this class in Lloyd's Register; in 1997, the number was about 22 700, which is
below the number of vessels recorded for the year 1985. Of the vessels currently in the
register, more than 10 000 are 20 years old or more and are likely to be decommissioned
or scrapped over the next decade. However, given that Lloyd's Register has incomplete
statistics for Chinese fishing vessels, the known increase in the size of the world fishing
fleet (of vessels above 100 GT) is not evident in its records.
The register shows that there has been a long-term reduction in the building rate for
vessels of more than 100 GT, with construction at its lowest in 1997. According to a
provisional estimate, only 155 vessels were built in that year.
BOX 3
Tonnage measurement and fishing capacity
For a given type of fishing gear, a vessel's capacity to catch fish is
determined by a combination of several of its physical characteristics
as well as many intangibles such as the skill of the captain and crew.
While it may be theoretically possible to determine the fishing capacity
of one design relative to another, it may not be practical to do so in
consideration of the elaborate formula that would be required to give
proper weight to every characteristic or variable related to capacity.
Any survey aimed at determining the capacity of a fishing vessel or of
a fishing fleet would need to cover information on a number of vessel
characteristics, of which gross tonnage (GT), length and engine power
would be among the most important. Of these, GT is probably the
most significant single variable influencing fishing capacity and, in
many respects, it is a good compromise between having a perfect
measure or none at all.
Tonnage is often confused with the measure of displacement, or
weight, of a vessel. In fact it refers to the size of the vessel, and not to
its weight. Its origin dates back to the fifteenth century when a
standard-sized barrel, called a tun, was decreed in England for the
purpose of measuring ship capacity, eventually referred to as tunnage,
or tonnage. However, the method of tonnage measurement has since
evolved and differs considerably from country to country.
Unification of this unit of measure for large ships on international
voyages was a slow process. A number of international meetings held
since the 1930s concluded with the 1969 International Convention on
Tonnage Measurement of Ships (referred to as the London
Convention), which entered into force in July 1982. It applies to ships
undertaking international voyages, although ships of less than 24 m
(and warships) are exempt. Furthermore, GT as defined by this
convention only became obligatory for all vessels (more than 24 m
long and engaged in international voyages) after 18 July 1994. Until
then, the system of tonnage defined by the 1947 Convention for a
Uniform System of Tonnage Measurement of Ships (the Oslo
Convention) continued to be valid. This system applied the gross
registered ton (GRT) as the unit of measure.
An important point to note is that the GT of a given vessel can be
significantly greater than its GRT because, under the London
Convention, certain parts of the vessel (e.g. enclosed spaces above the
upper deck) are included in GT whereas they were previously excluded
from GRT. This means that many vessels that were below 100 GRT
prior to 1994 are now being classified above 100 GT. Therefore, as the
existing fleet is being reclassified, the size of the world fishing fleet
consisting of vessels "above 100 tons" will be increasing. Much care
must be taken not to confuse this increase in the number of vessels
with an increase in fishing capacity, as in reality the capacity has not
changed, only the measurement used.
Source: J. Turner. FAO Fisheries Department.
FISH UTILIZATION
Fish for food
In recent years, the volume of fishery products marketed in their fresh state has increased
not only in absolute terms but also as a percentage of all uses of fish. In 1996, about 33
percent of all fish was marketed fresh compared with 20 percent in 1986 (Figure 17).
The supply of frozen fish is growing in both developed and developing countries. The
production of frozen fish fillets, shrimps and prawns has increased in volume, as has the
supply of fish in the form of ready-to-eat meals and other convenience food products.
Fish for feed
After 1994, when nearly 32 million tonnes of fish (representing nearly 30 percent of the
total world fisheries production) were used for feed, there was a decrease in this usage in
1995. As a consequence of the El Niño phenomenon, the stocks of small pelagics in the
Eastern Pacific are expected to shrink and the volumes landed in the course of 1998 may
consequently be several million tonnes below those recorded in 1996.
TRADE IN FISH AND FISHERY PRODUCTS
Fish, shellfish and fishery products are widely traded, with no less than 195 countries
having exported part of their production and some 180 countries having reported fishery
imports of varying amounts in 1996. In parallel with the increase in production,
international trade has continued to grow, and at an accelerating rate in recent years. The
largest part of this growth is real in that it is linked to the expansion of the world's
economies and also reflects the increased availability - owing mainly to aquaculture
production - of species in high demand as well as the sustained demand for fishmeal.
Another part of the increase is fictitious, or nominal, as it is due to trade among countries
that were formerly part of one political entity.
Export volumes reached 22 million tonnes in 1996 (Figure 18), which is nearly three
times the volume traded in 1976 and, when reconverted into the estimated live weight
equivalent, represents 40 percent of overall fisheries production. This level has been
reached after a period of relative stability, with foreign trade accounting for around 30
percent of production.
In 1996, the export sector earned US$52.5 billion, representing 11 percent of the value of
agricultural exports and about 1 percent of total merchandise trade. The share of trade in
fish and fishery products in all agricultural trade has increased somewhat over the last
decade.
Although fishery trade is not prominent at the global level, in some countries its
contribution to foreign currency earnings is vital to the national economy; for example,
fish and fishery products represent more than 75 percent of total merchandise exports for
Iceland, the Faeroe Islands, Greenland, Maldives and Seychelles. In a further 20
countries, including Chile, Ecuador, Kiribati, Madagascar, Mauritania, Morocco,
Mozambique, Namibia, Peru and Senegal, fisheries exports account for between 75 and
10 percent of total merchandise exports. Despite the importance of fisheries to their
economies, none of the above countries accounts for a significant share of the world
market and, even taken together, their exports account for only 15 percent of the total. In
a further 38 countries, fishery exports in 1996 contributed between 9 and 2 percent of
trade receipts. Among these countries were Thailand, with net earnings of US$3.2 billion,
and Indonesia, with net earnings of US$1.6 billion.
In terms of value, fishery exports are almost entirely (95 percent) composed of food
products, although, in terms of volume, fishmeal and fish oil account for a much greater
share (Figure 19). In value terms, more than half of the fishery export trade originates in
developing economies and consists largely of imports into developed economies. While
Thailand was the leading world exporter of fish products between 1993 and 1996, at a
value of US$3.4 billion, Norway's fishery exports were the highest in 1997. Japan, with
US$15.5 billion worth of imports in 1997, is the leading importer while the United States
absorbs about 10 percent of world fish imports. These two countries and the European
Community (including the value of the intra-EC trade) import 75 percent (in value terms)
of internationally traded fishery products.
Shrimp
The shortage of shrimp on the world market continued in 1997. With an output of some
175 000 tonnes, Thailand continues to be the world's main supplier of cultured shrimp,
although this figure represents a substantial drop from two years earlier. Other Asian
suppliers also reported a lower output in 1997. By contrast, Ecuador's shrimp output is
growing and broke a new record during that year, as its production was helped by larger
amounts of larvae collected from the wild, a situation that was favoured by El Niño.
The United States shrimp market was very strong, owing to the country's expanding
economy and to the high value of the US dollar. A strong domestic demand, combined
with limited supplies on the world market, led to record prices. In only one year, prices
grew by 20 percent, with even higher increases experienced for large-sized shrimp.
United States imports expanded by 10 percent in 1997, allowing it to overtake Japan for
the first time as the world's major shrimp market. Asia as a whole maintained its share of
the United States market, as smaller exporting countries in the region, such as Indonesia
(12 800 tonnes, +29 percent) and China (12 900 tonnes, +68 percent), showed very good
performances in 1997.
Japanese imports of shrimp fell by 7 percent in 1997 to only 267 200 tonnes, the lowest
figure in nine years. A downward trend was apparent throughout the whole of 1997, not
only in the closing months when the economic crisis hit the country. Short supplies of
tropical shrimp, high prices and a weaker yen contributed to the decline in shrimp
consumption on the Japanese market.
In 1997, after 13 years, India again became the major supplier of shrimp to the Japanese
market. Indian shrimp exports to Japan increased by 6.6 percent to a record 59 100
tonnes. Some of this shrimp was redirected to Japan as a result of an EC ban on Indian
seafood, which started in August 1997. Indonesia lost its top position because of disease
in its shrimp farms, and its exports to Japan fell by 11 percent. Thailand experienced
similar problems in its farms, and its shrimp exports to Japan declined by 30 percent.
Tuna
In general, tuna catches continued to be low in 1997. In the Eastern and Western Pacific,
the El Niño phenomenon led to lower catches in the opening months of the year while, in
the Atlantic, catches were also low. The tuna fleets in the Indian Ocean were successful
in targeting skipjack.
Domestic landings of tuna in the 42 major harbours of Japan increased to 385 000 tonnes
in 1997, up from 340 000 tonnes in 1996 but still about 17 000 tonnes short of the 1995
result. This figure, however, only gives a partial indication of the overall performance of
the Japanese fleet, as another 300 000 tonnes of the catch are landed in other ports of
Japan or outside the country and sent directly to canneries in the United States and
Thailand. Apart from bluefin, higher landings were reported for all tuna species in 1997,
with strong increases for fresh skipjack and frozen albacore.
Japan is the world's major market for tuna products, of which its apparent consumption
exceeds 1 million tonnes or nearly 30 percent of world tuna catches. About 70 percent of
this consumption is accounted for by domestic production while the remainder comes
from imports.
In 1997, Japanese imports of tuna amounted to 311 000 tonnes, a 5 percent decline from
the 326 000 tonnes imported in 1996. Imports of yellowfin tuna dropped by 22 percent in
1997 and bigeye imports were also reduced. Taiwan Province of China continues to be
the main exporter of tuna to Japan, despite a 20 percent decrease to about 76 800 tonnes
in 1997. This is 47 percent below the maximum volume of Taiwanese tuna exports to
Japan, which was recorded in 1993.
The Republic of Korea is the second major exporter of tuna to the Japanese market.
Shipments expanded in 1997, almost regaining the levels recorded in the early 1990s.
Groundfish
The world market for highly priced, whitefish fillets is starting to accept cheaper
substitutes. There is already a growing acceptance of fillets of hoki from New Zealand
both in Europe and the United States. Since 1995, New Zealand hoki exports have
benefited from reduced EC tariffs, resulting in an increasing proportion being directed to
the European market. In the United States market, farmed whitefish, mainly catfish but
also tilapia, is increasingly replacing wild capture groundfish. However, in Europe, hoki,
catfish and tilapia are not fully accepted substitutes, and this is leading to higher prices in
the region, as has already been seen in the case of cod.
The composition of United States imports of frozen whitefish changed during 1997.
While the total volume of blocks and slabs was practically the same as in 1996, imports
of minced whitefish decreased by 17 percent in volume. Pollack remained the
predominant species, accounting for about 57 percent of total imports of frozen whitefish
blocks. However, imports of pollack block dropped by approximately 7 percent in 1997,
with most of this decrease accounted for by lower volumes from the Russian Federation.
Imports of cod blocks show the opposite tendency, having increased by about 40 percent.
Imports of flatfish blocks also increased, doubling in volume between 1996 and 1997.
A shift was evident in the United States market for frozen fillets and steaks in 1997. Cod
imports increased by about 9 500 tonnes, while Alaska pollock imports decreased by
approximately 6 000 tonnes. In general, imports of species and products from the North
Atlantic increased, while products derived from Alaska pollock decreased.
The market for traditional whitefish fillets and blocks is influenced by the market
situation for surimi and roe and also by the market for salted and dried whitefish. This is
because the raw material is the same and flexible production units can to some extent
change the production mix according to the current market situation. While Alaska
pollock traditionally has been the species utilized for surimi, most salted and dried
products are derived from cod. As a result of the financial crisis in Asia, the situation in
the surimi and roe market is somewhat turbulent but, nevertheless, the demand for salted
and dried groundfish is expected to be relatively stable or even to increase slightly.
Between 1996 and 1997, imports of Alaska pollock surimi into Japan decreased slightly
to 125 000 tonnes. However, imports of hake or cod surimi increased by about 53 percent
to more than 26 000 tonnes, with the United States supplying almost 95 percent of this
volume. Itoyori surimi imports increased by more than 30 percent to 37 000 tonnes, twothirds of which were supplied by Thailand. Imports of Patagonian toothfish (Dissostichus
eleginoides) fillets increased from 11 141 to 13 767 tonnes, with Chile as the main
supplier.
Fishmeal
Peruvian fishmeal production dropped to 1.66 million tonnes in 1997, about 0.3 million
tonnes less than in 1996, and Chile's production dropped by 0.2 million tonnes to 1.2
million tonnes. During the same period, fishmeal production in Europe increased;
production in Norway, Denmark and Iceland was 0.1 million tonnes greater than in 1996.
Despite lower production, however, Peruvian fishmeal exports increased in 1997, with
1.96 million tonnes exported - about 0.3 million tonnes more than in 1996. This record
export left the country with no fishmeal in stock at the end of 1997. Peruvian
consumption of fishmeal was halved during the year. In 1997, Chilean fishmeal exports
were 0.1 million tonnes below the volume reached in 1996. High fishmeal prices resulted
in increased export earnings for South American countries overall, despite lower
production. Prices touched a peak of US$721 per tonne in December 1997, when Peru's
fishmeal exports were valued at US$990 million.
Fish oil
Fish oil production in Peru declined sharply from 415 000 tonnes in 1996 to 280 000
tonnes in 1997. Nevertheless, exports of fish oil were higher in 1997 than in 1996,
expanding in value terms to reach US$95 million.
1
Chinese production statistics held by FAO for several species of molluscs have
undergone a major revision since the last issue of The State of World Fisheries and
Aquaculture, which was based on information available up to mid-1996. While the
numerical production data received from China had been understood to be in live weight
units (i.e. including shell weight), the data for some species of molluscs in fact reflected
meat weight. As FAO statistics on mollusc production are recorded on a live weight
basis, an upward revision has been made for all years. The revision mainly affects
aquaculture production statistics.
2
Distant-water fisheries production is defined here as catches taken in FAO fishing areas
that are non-adjacent to the flag state of the fishing vessel used.
3
The intensity of exploitation in this case is calculated in terms of capture in tonnes of
landed weight, contrasted with surface areas (km2) of the continents and their lakes and
swamps.
4
UNEP. 1998. Global State of the Environment Report 1997. Nairobi.
5
For details see FAO. 1997. Numbers of fishers. FAO Fisheries Circular No. 929. Rome.
6
For details see FAO. 1998. Bulletin of Fishery Statistics, No. 35. Rome.
7
For a review of trends in numbers of fishers over the period 1970-1990, see the section
Fishers and fishing fleets.
8
Information drawn from Lloyd's Register of Shipping is provided under exclusive
licence by Lloyd's Maritime Information Services (LMIS).
PART 2
Selected issues facing fishers and
aquaculturists
INTRODUCTION
Capture fishers and aquaculturists often come up against operational difficulties and
controversial issues which must be overcome if capture fisheries are to remain a stable
source of food and income and if aquaculturists are to meet the consumer demand for an
ever-increasing stream of aquatic products.
Access to and the use of natural resources are the main subject of controversy, in which
there are two basic points at issue:
•
•
The first concerns which natural resources humans may use (and, in doing so,
alter). Many civil society groups argue that there should be more "undisturbed"
natural resources reserved for "non-consumptive" uses, i.e. as an amenity. On the
other hand, the growing world population, in addition to its increasing mobility, is
progressively diminishing the earth's "wild" natural resources. In time, a greater
degree of non-consumptive use will leave even fewer resources available for
consumptive purposes.
The second point concerns the sustainability of consumptive uses of renewable
natural resources. In this case, civil society (and some participants in the fisheries
sector) maintains that certain fishery and aquaculture practices modify the
ecosystem to such an extent that it is no longer able to support the regeneration of
its natural resources. The production technologies adopted for such practices are
therefore deemed unsustainable. This argument is reflected, for example, in the
popular protest against overfishing, which is believed to lead to the permanent
destruction of marine aquatic life.
This review starts with the general and moves on to more specific aspects of the issues
discussed. The first topic to be considered is that of governance of the fisheries sector.
Here, governance is understood to be the legal and institutional framework designed to
guarantee that the role played by capture fisheries and aquaculture is considered
appropriate by society as a whole. Governance should also set rules to ensure that, within
the sector, competition is constructive and access to resources equitable.
The questions addressed under governance are discussed in more detail as part of the next
two issues which deal with the creation of an enabling environment for aquaculture, and
the integration of fisheries into coastal zone management. The final two issues - how to
match fishing capacity with available resources, and how to manage by-catch and
discarding - need to be resolved by the capture fisheries sector, although they have
attracted considerable attention outside the fisheries sector.
NATIONAL FISHERIES GOVERNANCE
THE ISSUE
Ninety percent of the global fish catch is taken within zones of national jurisdiction,
owing primarily to the higher productivity and proximity of the coastal and shelf areas. It
follows, therefore, that these are the areas where the bulk of fisheries management
problems occur.
Such problems are not a new development: for 50 years at least, recognition has been
given to the need for governments to be aware of the state of their fisheries, to implement
effective policies aimed at preventing resource depletion and the wastage of fisheries
inputs and, increasingly, to facilitate stock rehabilitation.
With about 60 percent of the main monitored commercial stocks considered to require
improved or new management, the current state of world fisheries indicates a need for
better governance. The challenge for governments is to manage fisheries in such a way
that ensures the optimum and sustainable use of resources as well as economic efficiency
and widespread social benefits. Furthermore, it is increasingly recognized that the
responsibility for management should not rest with governments alone but rather be a
shared responsibility, involving those operating in the fisheries sector as well as others
who consider they have a right to participate in decisions concerning humanity's natural
heritage.
In the 1980s, it was widely anticipated that fisheries governance would improve
substantially in parallel with the establishment of extended national jurisdiction under the
United Nations Conference on the Law of the Sea (UNCLOS). This was the case for
countries that were able and had the will to strengthen their governance. Very often they
were already engaged in exclusive economic zone (EEZ) fisheries or had readily
available capacity (e.g. trained fishers, investment capital and infrastructure) within the
sector to do so. Subsequent experience has shown that, even under the most favourable
circumstances, achieving good governance is a protracted process. Those governments
that now have soundly managed fisheries generally owe this achievement to 20 to 40
years of continuous effort and adjustment (see Box 4, The evolution of fisheries
management in New Zealand).
BOX 4
The evolution of fisheries management in New Zealand
Capacity problems in New Zealand's inshore fisheries began to
manifest themselves in the 1960s. The appearance of foreign fishing
vessels off the New Zealand coast had created the perception that
commercial opportunities for domestic fishers were being foregone.
Consequently, in 1963 the government removed the restrictions on
fishing effort applied to local fishers and, in 1965, provided guarantees
on loans for fishing vessel purchases. The country had accordingly reestablished open access as well as government encouragement of
increased fishing capacity.
While the intention was to base fisheries development on the offshore
resources, the fishing effort in the prime inshore fisheries also
expanded rapidly. In fact, by the early 1980s, overfishing of species in
these zones and overcapitalization within the inshore fleets had
become a problem. Measures aimed at restoring control in these
fisheries were introduced at this time. They included:
· a declaration designating these zones as controlled fisheries, a new
licensing regime that limited vessel numbers and a blanket moratorium
on new entrants to the inshore fisheries;
· the removal of "part-time" fishers from the inshore fisheries;
· enhanced powers, under the Fisheries Act 1983, in the regulation of
fisheries using management plans that would be formulated after
extensive public consultation and would identify the resources to be
managed and the regulatory controls (on fisheries inputs) to be applied.
The cumbersome nature of the consultation and planning process was
such that, while it was still under way, the inshore fisheries advanced
further into an overfished and overcapitalized state. In 1984, the
inshore harvesting sector was overcapitalized by an estimated $NZ 28
million (present value) and, where inshore fisheries were most
concentrated, overcapitalization was estimated to represent about 44
percent of the existing fishing capacity.
After an intense period of policy development, the government and
industry agreed to the introduction of total allowable catches (TACs)
to ensure stock conservation, and individual transferable quotas (ITQs)
to facilitate industry restructuring. This approach to controlling
capacity through controls on the outputs of fisheries was seen as the
most likely to succeed in meeting these two objectives. Furthermore, it
was accepted that the initial TACs and ITQs would be set so as to
effect a reduction in fishing activity. The main elements of the scheme
were:
· the allocation of a case history to each fisher, on a national basis
(with case history defined as the fisher's catch in two of the three years
of 1981, 1982 or 1983); and
· the buy-back of case histories to a level that is equivalent to the TAC
for each fishery.
The government ultimately spent $NZ 45 million (present value) to
buy out 15 800 tonnes of fishers' case histories. The important
outcome was that a viable and more sustainable future was secured for
the affected fisheries and the industry in general. The additional
advantages perceived by the fishers included the "right" to buy, sell or
lease their entitlements to engage in the fisheries without undue
government restrictions or the requirement of consent, and the ability
to shift their vessels throughout the year between different fisheries for
which they had quotas. The government benefited by being able to
purchase case histories at prices that did not reflect their full value,
owing to the absence of an established ITQ market at the time.
The introduction of ITQs followed extensive consultations with the
fishing industry to ensure their commitment. In this respect, the
involvement of industry representatives in the planning, development
and implementation of the quota management system was seen as an
important element in the successful introduction of ITQs.
By this process, ITQ management was established for 29 species,
including 21 inshore and eight deep-water species. Other species have
been included since 1986, and there are now 33 species managed under
ITQs. These represent about 80 percent of the total commercial catch
from New Zealand's EEZ. The Fisheries Act provides for additional
commercial species to be managed using ITQs.
There are approximately 117 species currently outside the quota
management system, and they are being managed by a system of
permits and regulations. For reasons of fisheries management, the
government's intention is to bring additional species into the quota
system as soon as possible. At present, a moratorium has been placed
on the issuing of new permits for non-ITQ species as a means of
controlling the fishing effort prior to these species' inclusion in the
quota management system.
The introduction of ITQs, together with the financial assistance to
restructuring, was designed to reduce fishing capacity. The initial
adjustment retired 15 800 tonnes of catch from New Zealand fisheries.
The reduction in the size of the fleets, whether it was due to this
assistance scheme or to the subsequent introduction of ITQs, was
dramatic. The number of vessels dropped by 22 percent between
1983/84 and 1986/87 and there was a further 53 percent reduction
resulting from the use of ITQs between 1986/87 and 1994/95. As this
rationalization primarily occurred in the country's inshore fisheries,
one of its effects was to redirect investment into deep-water fisheries.
Source: W. Emerson, Ministry of Fisheries, Wellington, New Zealand.
In many countries, governance has continued to languish for a variety of reasons,
including a scarcity of the human, institutional and financial resources required to devise
and implement management programmes; a lack of understanding, by both governments
and fisheries participants, of the potential benefits that good management can generate;
and the reluctance of governments to make unpopular decisions. Through aid and
financial assistance projects, the international community continues to direct substantial
efforts towards improving the capabilities of the fisheries institutions in such countries.
The countries with the poorest governance are those whose populations face more
pressing, fundamental problems such as war, civil disturbances, natural disasters and
weak government.
POSSIBLE SOLUTIONS
The prerequisites for good governance in the fisheries sector are generally well
recognized: the need for a strategy explicitly aimed at ecological, economic and social
sustainability; effective fisheries agencies and research institutions (producing, inter alia,
reliable and up-to-date information on the sector); a cooperative, organized and informed
fisheries sector; adequate laws and legal institutions, including deterrent monitoring,
control and surveillance (MCS); and linkages with the appropriate regional and
international bodies. Since the early 1980s, attention has been paid to giving the fisheries
sector joint responsibility with government in the management of fisheries. In many
instances, this has been recognized by law, as in the creation of statutory committees (e.g.
on management formulation, licensing and appeals) whose members include
representatives from the fisheries sector. In some countries, this has been extended to the
creation of semi-autonomous fisheries management authorities acting under joint industry
and government boards of control (see Box 5, Industry participation in management in
Australia).
BOX 5
Industry participation in fisheries management in
Australia
Responsibility for the management of fisheries in Australia is shared
among the commonwealth, states and territories. The Constitution
provides that the commonwealth is responsible for the management of
fisheries outside the three-nautical mile territorial sea, with states and
internal territories being responsible for fisheries in all other waters
adjacent to that state.
The administration of commonwealth fisheries in Australia involves
three bodies. The Australian Fisheries Management Authority
(AFMA) is responsible for managing commonwealth fisheries; the
Commonwealth Department of Primary Industries and Energy is
responsible for formulating policy (e.g. concerning foreign fishing
access rights, taxation rulings applicable to fisheries and the
environment); and the Fisheries Research and Development
Corporation (FRDC) is responsible for funding research and
development in the country's fisheries (both state and commonwealth).
The AFMA's responsibilities, objectives and functions in managing
commonwealth fisheries are defined under the 1991 Fisheries
Administration Act. The AFMA may determine a management plan
for a fishery after it has given public notice of its intention and both
invited and considered representations. Such a plan must set out its
objectives and the proposed methods for achieving its goals. It may
also include the amount of fish that can be taken, fishing concessions,
procedures for selecting persons to whom concessions may be granted
and the kind and quantity of equipment that may be used.
While the responsibility for determining management arrangements
lies directly with the AFMA, the 1991 Fisheries Administration Act
allows the establishment of management advisory committees (MACs)
to it "... in the performance of its functions and the exercise of its
powers in relation to a fishery". The AFMA can delegate functions to
the MACs, in which case the committees can hold the same level of
power as the AFMA. In these circumstances, the MACs must act in
accordance with policies determined by the AFMA and must comply
with its directions. Within the MACs, issues relating to a fishery are
discussed, problems identified, possible solutions developed and
recommendations made to the AFMA. MACs provide a forum for the
AFMA to consult with industry on its management arrangements, for
the industry to make its views known and for consultation between
researchers and industry.
The MACs consist of: an independent chairperson, the AFMA officer
responsible for the management of the fishery in question and up to
seven members determined by the AFMA after consultation with
states, industry, interest groups and researchers. In practice, in the last
category, the MACs have a number of industry representatives, usually
at least one member representing state fisheries organizations and one
from the fisheries research community. There is also an increasing
trend towards representation of conservation and recreational fishing
interests.
Despite the increased role of industry in management, many operators
feel that the AFMA does not consult sufficiently with the MACs, that
the MACs are not sufficiently representative and that consultation is
often superficial, with little real notice being taken of the views of the
industry. There have also been questions raised regarding the
appropriateness of the AFMA's objective of maximizing economic
efficiency in the exploitation of fisheries resources. It has been argued
that government management of fisheries should be restricted to
ensuring sustainability of the resource through the setting of
biologically safe reference points and that the industry, while adhering
to such conservation criteria, should be responsible for harvesting the
resource as it sees fit.
The present institutional arrangements place the AFMA at risk of bias
towards the fishing industry at the expense of other community
sectors. To counter this, the AFMA has given effect to its corporate
plan intention to broaden membership of the MACs to include
members from environmental, recreational and community groups.
Greater stakeholder involvement in the direct management of
individual fisheries would appear to be an inevitable and desirable
outcome of this development. Indeed, the provisions relating to MACs
(1991 Fisheries Administration Act, sections 56 to 67) clearly envisage
a gradual devolution of decision-making responsibilities to individual
MACs.
The Department of Primary Industries and Energy has a role in
monitoring the outcomes of fisheries management and has
implemented a programme of independent assessment of the AFMA's
management performance. Economic and sustainability indicators to
assess fisheries management (or indeed management of any natural
resources) are being developed for this purpose.
Source: T. Battaglene, Department of Primary Industries and Energy,
Canberra, Australia.
This joint management process has been facilitated by a number of important
evolutionary trends. In many countries, the fisheries sector has become better organized
and hence more effective in liaising with government and in representing collective
viewpoints. A more recent impetus has come from management regimes that establish
either real or quasi ownership "rights", such as the right to trade - buy, sell or lease - an
entitlement to engage in a managed fishery. In such circumstances, those with an
entitlement have more of a vested interest in good management, as the "monetary" value
of their entitlement will be directly influenced by the performance of the fishery.
Accordingly, titleholders have demanded a major role in the formulation of management.
Another important and related trend concerns the financing of fisheries research and
management. An underlying concept gaining wider acceptance is that financing should
come from those who benefit, including fisheries participants in the case of managed
fisheries. Again, there has been added impetus from the creation of "rights-based"
fisheries, where it would clearly be anomalous for governments - using funds from the
broader community - to be the sole financing entity. Accordingly, the joint financing of
fisheries governance has been most readily accepted in the case of rights-based fisheries.
As might be expected, fisheries participants have demanded a role in deciding how the
money is spent, leading to more focused spending and systems of accountability. The
consequence has invariably been better governance.
A recent trend in management-oriented research is for the scientific arm of management
to have more autonomy when providing advice and for there to be more transparency as
to what action is taken on the strength of that advice. There has also been a related move
towards "privatizing" certain functions of governance, a development that is most
advanced in the case of fisheries research institutions, which are becoming progressively
more reliant on non-government sources of finance. There have been rare instances in
which countries have hired out the functions of licensing and enforcement to private
sector entities, although the government has invariably taken a major shareholding in the
entities selected. This has met with mixed success so far, but probably reflects the
direction that governance will take in the future. Fisheries governance is now benefiting
from computer-assisted "networking", for example through e-mail and the World Wide
Web, which allows both researchers and managers ready access to the knowledge and
experiences of "outsiders". Although related to private sector services, this development
is not exactly part of privatization but rather a consequence of globalization.
These trends are most apparent in countries whose capacity for governance is well
evolved. The approaches nevertheless are globally applicable. A major constraint to their
wider application in practice is a lack of organization within fishing communities,
including an insufficient understanding of the potential benefits to be gained through
good management. The paradox for some countries is that systems of community-based
management, which provided cohesion in the past, have now disappeared. Aid and
financial assistance projects as well as other efforts are now aimed at reversing this
process, often through the conferring of "rights" exclusively on active members of the
community or on the community as a collective. Such an approach will be most
problematic - if not impossible in the short term - in areas where there is a high
population density and acute poverty because of the high social cost to those excluded
from fisheries. The priority in this event is to enhance the welfare of the wider
community (e.g. through job creation), and this is a task that requires intervention from
"outside" agencies, non-governmental organizations (NGOs) and the international
community.
RECENT ACTIONS
The promotion of traditional or community-based management practices has gained
momentum in artisanal and small-scale fisheries, which often involve thousands of
fishers, hundreds of fishing communities and a plethora of landing points. The
communities involved have very little mobility and are liable to be extremely
disadvantaged by the social and economic consequences of bad governance. Management
that is directed at safeguarding a community's welfare is most likely to be sensitive to
issues at the local level, and hence to the importance of improving benefits from fisheries
without causing undue social disruption. The community-based management approach
therefore seeks to build on existing customary and traditional practices, adopting the
concept of territorial use rights in fisheries (TURFS).
The Secretariat of the Pacific Community (SPC) is promoting the revival of traditional
marine tenure and resource allocation mechanisms in the region. As part of this effort,
SPC puts out an information bulletin dealing with traditional marine resource
management and knowledge. However, the pace of socio-economic change in the region
is such that it is uncertain what the need for fish resources will be when all population
groups have become urban wage earners.
Recent advances in the management of industrial fisheries at the national level have
focused on the conferring of rights. Most commonly, these rights have included the
ability to trade (buy, sell or lease) the entitlement to fish in a particular managed fishery.
In most cases, entitlements have been provided in the form of individual transferable
quotas (ITQs) or as a subset of a limited number of licences to fish. This strategy is being
introduced successfully in a growing number of countries, including Australia, Canada,
Iceland, New Zealand and the United States. The adoption of rights-based management is
also being encouraged by international institutions such as the World Bank.
Chile has introduced experimental ITQs in its deep-water shrimp and its toothfish
fisheries, making it the only country in Latin America to have a functioning ITQ system.
The government would like to expand the system to other fisheries but it faces resistance
from operators in the fisheries concerned.
A High-Level Panel of External Experts in Fisheries, which met at FAO headquarters in
January 1998, stressed the relevance of the Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries1
for governance. The participants concluded that the Code and its guidelines are
technically credible to fisheries experts and readily understood by non-experts and,
therefore, constitute an important reference for improved fisheries governance.
The 1996 annual meeting of the South Pacific Forum (SPF), held in the Marshall Islands,
recommended the development of comprehensive arrangements for the sustainable
management of the region's fisheries across the full geographical range of stocks,
including those of high seas. This recommendation reflects countries' increasing concern
about the governance of high seas resources.
Countries in the Pacific are working together with Distant-Water Fishing Nations
(DWFNs)2 to develop a mechanism for the conservation and management of highly
migratory fish stocks in the Central and Western Pacific Ocean. It is envisaged that the
negotiations will result in a commission for the management of the stocks concerned.
Southeast Atlantic countries are discussing, among themselves and with DWFNs, the
establishment of a regional fisheries organization to manage fish stocks in the high seas
of the Southeast Atlantic.
Members of the South Pacific Permanent Commission3 are negotiating how to conserve
and manage high seas resources in the Southeast Pacific.
GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE
The conclusion that the world's main commercial fisheries need more and better
management is neither surprising nor necessarily derogative of national governance
worldwide. Ultimately, all fisheries require management as, where it is lacking, wastage
of fish resources and fisheries inputs is inevitable. The benefits realized from good
governance are most obvious in the developed countries and this has been the case for
some time because their capacity for governance is more evolved. Furthermore, these
countries have much to gain from improved of fisheries performance. Much of the global
fishing capacity and most of the world's mature fisheries - with stocks near to being or
already fully exploited - are located in the fishing zones of these countries or in other
zones exploited by them.
With increasing fishing pressure and a better knowledge of stocks, the joint management
of shared stocks will become a priority in the future (see Box 6, Shared stocks - how to
improve management).
BOX 6
Shared stocks - how to improve management
There are more than 500 maritime boundaries in the world between
adjacent EEZs, and significant proportions of the world's fish stocks lie
across these boundaries and are fished by two or more nations.
Good examples are the four major stocks - salmon, cod, herring and
sprat in the Baltic, which are shared among the nine riparian states.
Other well-known shared stocks are: hake (Argentina, Uruguay);
North Sea herring (the Faeroe Islands, Iceland, Norway); Pacific
salmon (Canada, the United States); pilchard (Angola, Namibia); and
sardinella (Côte d'Ivoire, Ghana, Togo).
The vast majority of shared stocks are not managed jointly by
neighbouring states, despite a call for cooperation by the United
Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea. However, some are jointly
managed - a few successfully and some with moderate success, while
still others are the subject of almost permanent conflict. With fishing
pressure increasing, the need for the management of shared stocks will
increase. Effective systems for joint consultations and management
need to be formulated and, although there are no magic recipes, a good
start would be acceptance by the states concerned of the basic
principles and sequence for management development and
implementation described here:
Basic principles
i) Before engaging in international negotiation about shared stocks,
each state should establish the criteria for allocation of rights to the
shared resources in its own EEZ.
ii) Fish stocks must be managed as unit populations.
iii) No party should agree to a cooperative arrangement that will
provide it with less than it could achieve by acting alone, entirely noncooperatively.
iv) In spite of financial commitments made in the fisheries sector of
each nation, sharing arrangements cannot be "chiselled in stone" and
should be updated regularly to avoid losses to all parties.
v) Allocation mechanisms and the negotiation of shares need to be
addressed frontally, with clear rules established by negotiation,
possibly including the use of an independent arbitrator to assist in the
review of sharing and joint management arrangements.
vi) Recognizing the trade-offs between fisheries and other sectors may
be integral to a successful negotiation. A negotiated solution may be
achieved more easily if it is favourable to the state placing the highest
valuation on the fishery, in return for some form of compensation to its
neighbours.
Sequence for development and implementation
The development and implementation of joint management of shared
stocks generally proceed stepwise. Isolated stock assessments, carried
out for only part of the stock, and incompatible management measures
have little value, especially where resource life histories are migratory.
Thus, one priority consists in joint stock assessments and the sharing
of resource data among all states within whose jurisdictions the stock
is fished. The following sequence is often appropriate:
· cooperation in research and data gathering;
· initiation of cooperative management, first through technical
measures, then access and allocations;
· bargaining over management strategies and harmonized regulations;
· agreement over surveillance and control.
States may wish to negotiate an agreement specifying matters such as
the standardization of data collection and cooperation in research and
stock assessment. Joint training of personnel in standard management
procedures, common marking of vessels, the use of standard radio call
signs and the exchange of registries of vessels authorized to fish the
resource should follow shortly. Such an agreement could lead to
defining standard procedures to follow in the case of infringements by
fishers of the other party.
Even if an initial agreement does not lead to a fully effective
mechanism for management of common stocks, there are advantages
in going at least part of the way towards such a goal. The information
exchange can result in each party making management decisions in the
light of full knowledge of the situation of the fishery exploiting the
shared stock in the other country.
Source: J. Caddy, FAO Fisheries Department.
As developing countries are becoming major participants in global fisheries, the focus is
likely to shift to include improvements in their fisheries governance. This will require the
enhancement of technical and administrative capabilities, enabling the formulation and
implementation of appropriate fisheries management plans and assessments of the
outcomes and needs for follow-up action. A fundamental policy consideration in this
regard is capacity building and institutional strengthening within the fisheries institutions.
At the same time, it must be accepted that improved benefits will not be an immediate
outcome from better governance. The structural adjustments that are required in many
fisheries will take a long time to become effective. Fisheries management is a process
that evolves over time in response to changing circumstances.
In line with recent trends, the governance of fisheries will progressively include the direct
involvement of fisheries participants, the conferring of user rights, the devolution of
management functions away from government - without detracting from its stewardship
role - and the financing of governance from within the sector.
CREATING AN ENABLING ENVIRONMENT FOR SUSTAINABLE
AQUACULTURE
THE ISSUE
Few countries have appropriate legal frameworks and policies for aquaculture. Often,
comprehensive policies and associated legal frameworks have been overlooked because
development has been seen mainly in technical terms and support has been largely
focused on technical aspects of production. Also, policy-makers have often treated
aquaculture in isolation from other sectors, thus ignoring important linkages, including
externalities. The need to incorporate political, economic, social, environmental and legal
aspects has been neglected, usually with negative consequences for the sector. The recent
emergence of industrial aquaculture, the growing competition for resources and the
continuing rapid growth of the sector have focused attention on the need for policy
measures and regulatory frameworks.
It is essential for appropriate operational conditions to be established at all levels
(international, regional, national, local and farm) to make the exploitation of aquaculture
in a sustainable manner attractive to farmers, fishers and other entrepreneurs.
Governments need to create and maintain a suitable climate for sustainable growth of the
sector, i.e. they need to provide an "enabling environment". Such an environment
comprises economic, legal, social and physical components and should ensure, inter alia,
fair access to resources, mechanisms for conflict resolution and access to information,
credit and markets. This presupposes that there are functioning channels of
communication with institutions and representatives of other competing sectors of the
economy.
In creating an "enabling environment", it is essential to strike a balance between the need
for development and growth and the need for ecosystem conservation. In this context it is
necessary to recognize and deal with the increasing competition for resources. The
diminishing role of the public sector as a promoter of development and the globalization
of markets must also be taken into consideration.
POSSIBLE SOLUTIONS
The complex task at hand is to put the principles of the Code into operation; i.e. to clarify
how sustainability choices might work in practice; to incorporate the Code's principles
into development policies and plans; and to elaborate specific codes of responsible
practice containing norms, standards and guidelines agreed on by all stakeholders. Given
the diversity of aquaculture practices and of the political, social and economic conditions
in which they take place - not to mention the different perceptions of sustainability -
balanced and informed approaches are required to address developmental and
environmental issues effectively at any one location. Furthermore, the applicability of
various approaches needs to be assessed carefully, particularly where many small-scale
farmers are involved and also in view of the often highly decentralized nature of the
aquaculture industry.
Existing administrative and legal frameworks need to be reviewed and adjusted to
address the specific characteristics and needs of the sector and to set forth clearly the
privileges and responsibilities of aquaculturists. However, because aquaculture is
frequently regulated by many agencies under a variety of laws, developing a
comprehensive regulatory framework for the sector is often legally and institutionally
complex. Typically it involves drafting or amending legislation that addresses a variety of
issues and establishing institutional arrangements to ensure the cooperation and
coordination of many different institutions with jurisdiction over natural resources,
animal and public health, environment, etc.
Although new national laws to regulate aquaculture comprehensively may be desirable in
many countries, other options are now being explored because developing and passing
new comprehensive legislation often takes several years, while the prospect of rapid
development of the sector has created an urgent need for regulation. These options
include the enactment of regulations under existing legislation, and voluntary approaches
such as guidelines and codes of practice.
The formulation of appropriate regulations in many countries is constrained by a shortage
of information on the interaction of aquaculture production systems with the environment
and on the environmental and financial efficiency of alternative approaches to production
management. Even where information is available, reliable predictive models for
aquaculture-environmental interactions still require considerable improvement with
regard to their accuracy, general applicability and affordability.
There is also an associated need to strengthen institutional capacity to manage the sector
and to expand the knowledge base in order to enable sustainable development policies
and plans. There is a general recognition of the need for interdisciplinary and
intersectoral approaches to development and resource management in aquaculture.
Moreover, it is becoming increasingly clear that sustainable aquaculture development
cannot be regulated solely by governments but must involve many interest groups at the
national, regional and international levels, including new institutional arrangements and
partnerships (consultative frameworks). This is being highlighted by ongoing structural
change, namely privatization and the contraction of governments' role in development.
Consequently, there is a growing and urgent need to create new knowledge and to
synthesize information from a broad spectrum of disciplines so that decisions can be
based on a much broader perspective and understanding. It is also important to ensure a
flow of information among different sectors and interest groups.
International trade, including in aquaculture products, is governed, inter alia, by the
Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures (the SPS
Agreement). This agreement recognizes the right of World Trade Organization (WTO)
members to apply legitimate measures to protect the life and health of their populations
from hazards in food, but stipulates that these measures must not be unjustifiably traderestrictive. SPS measures must be based on risk assessment, taking into consideration the
techniques being developed by relevant international organizations. In regard to food
safety, the relevant international body is the FAO/WHO Codex Alimentarius
Commission (CAC); in regard to animal (including fish) health and disease, the relevant
organization is the International Office of Epizootics (OIE). International safety standards
and procedures specific to aquaculture products are increasingly being developed in the
context of these instruments. It is important to note, for example, that application of the
Hazard Analysis and Critical Control Point (HACCP) system to fish processing
operations is becoming mandatory in a number of countries. The application of the same
system to large-scale and/or intensive aquaculture production systems is currently being
explored and applied in some countries. However, use of the HACCP system in smallscale and subsistence aquaculture is far from a reality at present, as the application of
aquatic animal health and disease control regulations is constrained by poor diagnostic
capacity (including trained human resources, standardized diagnostic techniques and
infrastructure) in many developing countries as well as a lack of reliable information on
pathogens and diseases of concern to traded species.
In regional and international trade in aquaculture products, friction over differences in
environmental standards among countries is best attenuated through improved
coordination and harmonization. If environmental standards are to be raised over time,
countries - particularly those with less demand for environmental goods - will need to be
encouraged to raise their standards through a variety of appropriate support mechanisms,
for example guarantees for expanded access to the markets of countries with higher
standards.
The expected increase in competition for, and regulation of, natural resources clearly
calls for greater production efficiency and the conservation of critical inputs. This should
be a priority topic for systems research. Efficiency in resource use may also be achieved
by integrating aquaculture with irrigation systems and agriculture as well as by utilizing
inland surface waters and floodplains for certain forms of aquaculture production.
New forms of integrated aquaculture-agriculture systems as well as other innovative
systems that can effectively respond to resource and environmental challenges need to be
developed. In this connection, attention should be given to resolving the economic and
environmental challenges of stock enhancement and ranching as well as of offshore cage
culture.
The reduced role of government in financing fisheries and aquaculture has resulted in the
cessation of public support to resource-poor fish farmers, the negative effects of which
may be counteracted by special policy instruments designed to promote training and
equitable income distribution and to facilitate access to information, credit and inputs
needed in production.
RECENT ACTIONS
The Code is beginning to have a worldwide influence on the development of an enabling
environment for sustainable aquaculture; however, much remains to be done. More
progress can be expected as guidelines are developed on how to strike a balance among
economic, social and environmental concerns, how sustainability choices apply in
practice and how to analyse the economic cost of resulting actions.
Certain states have initiated national measures such as workshops to promote the Code
and some NGOs, including producer groups, have developed or are developing codes of
conduct and practice for particular aspects of aquaculture. Examples of these are: an
implementation plan for the code for marine fisheries and marine aquaculture in the
United States;4 a code of practice for mangrove protection by the Global Aquaculture
Alliance (GAA);5 a code of practice for Australian prawn farmers;6 codes of practice for
cage culture of finfish and pond culture of shrimp in Malaysia;7 and guidelines for
sustainable industrial fish farming.8
Over the last few years, there has been a growing interest in many countries to develop a
comprehensive regulatory framework for aquaculture that will protect the industry, the
environment, other resource users and consumers. This interest is being driven by a
variety of factors, including: greater political attention as the economic importance and
potential of aquaculture become more apparent; greater awareness that inappropriate laws
and institutional arrangements can significantly constrain the development of the sector;
evidence of environmental damage and social disruption as a result of rapid and largely
unregulated expansion of some high-value species in certain coastal areas; and a growing
emphasis on assuring the quality and safety of aquaculture products in international trade.
Some of these issues were debated at an FAO Technical Consultation on Policies for
Sustainable Shrimp Culture, held in Bangkok at the end of 1997.
Progress is also being made in the establishment of legal and regulatory frameworks for
aquaculture in individual countries. Among these are Bulgaria, Cyprus, Madagascar,
Malaysia, Mozambique, Papua New Guinea, Sri Lanka and Suriname. The Government
of India has set up an Aquaculture Authority, which will license the adoption of
improved technology for increased production and the establishment of new farms within
and outside the Coastal Regulation Zone. In India, the Tamil Nadu Aquaculture
(Regulation) Act of 1995 sets out conditions to improve siting and management of
aquaculture facilities and establishes an Ecorestoration Fund, supported by deposits from
aquaculturists, to remedy environmental damage caused by aquaculture farms.
Concerning quality and safety of aquaculture products, FAO is currently involved in
revising the FAO/WHO Code of Hygienic Practice for the Products of Aquaculture under
the auspices of the Codex Committee on Fish and Fishery Products. International
meetings continue to be held as part of efforts to develop risk analysis for food safety,
synthesize and disseminate information on food safety (including food production from
aquaculture) and address any related issues.9
Meetings focused exclusively on aquaculture have covered subjects such as the use of
chemicals,10 environmental impacts of coastal aquaculture11 and food safety issues
associated with products from aquaculture.12
In the United States, the industry and government have succeeded in developing
comprehensive HACCP plans for cultured catfish, crayfish and molluscs. A similar
approach is being introduced in Australia, Chile, New Zealand, Norway and Thailand.
The EC currently imposes detailed conditions on the handling, slaughter, inspection,
processing, packaging, identification and storage of fishery products,13 and applies
stringent controls to the animal health conditions applicable to the marketing of
aquaculture animals and products.14 FAO, the Network of Aquaculture Centres in AsiaPacific (NACA) and OIE are collaborating to develop guidelines on aquatic animal
quarantine and health certification to be applied in Asia when moving live aquatic
animals.
There is increasing interest and hence a growing experience in the incorporation of
aquaculture activities in resource management for coastal and inland areas. Integrated
resource management forces long-term planning (e.g. through the designation of zones
where different users will have priority), which provides predictability required for any
long-term investment while also reducing conflicts among actual and potential users. A
variety of tools are being used in the planning process, including: geographic information
systems (GIS); predictive systems for assessing carrying capacity (particularly for finfish
cage culture and mollusc culture); and environmental and social impact assessments.
An example of what can be done to integrate aquaculture into resource use plans is
provided by the Australian State of Tasmania. Under new legislation (notably the 1995
Marine Farming Planning Act and the 1995 Living Marine Resources Act), marine
farming development plans must be designed to cover areas rather than sites, and broad
community participation in the preparation of such plans is also provided for by laws. An
environmental impact assessment must be carried out and a marine farming zone
established before leases are granted to marine farms. (Box 7 provides an example of
environmental management of aquaculture in the Republic of Korea.)
Progress towards participatory planning has been reflected in the growing participation of
NGOs, farmers' associations, researchers and public officials in national, regional and
international fora, particularly for the development of codes of practice and conduct and
the formulation of regulations and legislation. There has also been progress in the
development and testing of participatory rural appraisal (PRA) and rapid rural appraisal
(RRA) methodologies, and of concepts and possible local structures for community
management of resources.
BOX 7
Managing the interactions between aquaculture and
the environment in the Republic of Korea
Since 1964, marine aquaculture has grown to become a widely
practised activity in the Republic of Korea. Production in 1996
included 538 990 tonnes of seaweeds, 306 738 tonnes of molluscs, 11
402 tonnes of finfish and 382 tonnes of crustaceans. The laver culture
is carried out by means of a pole and floating net system, while sea
mustard and kelp are cultured by long-line systems. Molluscs are
farmed using two different culture methods: a long-line system for
oysters and mussels and a bottom planting system for clams and
arkshells. Most of the culture of finfish - halibut, jacopever, yellowtail
and seabream - is carried out in floating net cages, while the culture of
prawns - oriental and karuma - is done in embanked ponds.
All aquaculture farms in the country require licensing by municipal
authorities. Additionally, all cage culture and other aquaculture
involving more than 1 000 m2 in surface area must be registered with
the Ministry of Environment and operated according to the Aquatic
Environment Protection Law.
Provisions seeking to minimize the pollution from cage culture
include: the use of low-phosphate foods with a sinking rate that does
not exceed 10 percent within a two-hour period; and the installation of
feed fences with a height of 10 cm above the sea surface to prevent the
dispersal of food outside the cages. Culturists are also required to:
prevent the difference in oxygen levels within and outside the cages
exceeding 20 percent; remove dead fish immediately and report
incidences of diseased fish to the local fisheries administrations; and
attach facilities to the cages in order to retain human faecal material.
The use of antibiotics and drugs for the control of fish diseases is also
regulated under the Aquatic Environment Protection law. Licensing
provisions require, furthermore, that the seabed under and immediately
adjacent to farms is cleaned - of debris - with dredges more than once
every three years.
The Regulations Governing Sanitary Control of Shellfish and their
Growing Areas, administered by the Ministry of Maritime Affairs and
Fisheries, also provide for the administration of water quality standards
and the control of water pollution arising from aquaculture. The
National Fisheries Research and Development Institute monitors water
quality within the shellfish culture areas as well as the incidence of
contaminants in the flesh of the aquaculture products. This entails
routine sampling of sanitary indicator bacteria, nutrient salts (to assess
eutrophication levels), pesticides and heavy metals. The median
coliform most probable number (MPN) of the water should be less
than 70/100 cm3, and not more than 10 percent of the samples taken
should have an MPN greater than 230/100 cm3 during the most
unfavourable hydrographic and pollutant conditions. The incidence of
red tides is also monitored in association with the early warning of
culturists when toxic species are identified.
The Environment Impact Assessment Law requires the preparation of
environmental impact assessment (EIA) prior to the construction of
city and industrial complexes, port development, land reclamation and
water resource development. The establishment of aquaculture
ventures is not currently subject to EIA, although this is planned in the
near future. The transport of aquatic animals and plants, including the
introduction of new species, the quarantining of imported species and
the prevention of infected or recessive exotic species into Korean
waters, are all subject to regulation by the Ministry of Maritime Affairs
and Fisheries. Regulations under the Marine Pollution Control Law
provide for government compensation to culturists in the event of
economic loss owing to abnormal environmental changes such as
harmful algal blooms. Compensation may also be sought from private
entities and public utilities arising from pollution (including oil spills),
reclamation and industrial activities.
Major pollution control and abatement measures under way or planned
since 1991 include: the classification of coastal areas according to
intended use (fisheries, recreational, agricultural and industrial); the
strengthening of water quality standards and the control of industrial
and municipal effluent into coastal waters; a national seawater quality
monitoring system (for which 280 sampling sites were designated in
1996); investment in treatment facilities for sewage, industrial
wastewater and excretion (for the equivalent of US$3.1 billion during
the period 1992-1996); the requirement to undertake EIA for all
coastal development activities; and the designation of special
conservation areas in which most development activities would be
prohibited.
Source: Hak Gyoon Kim, National Fisheries Research and
Development Agency, Republic of Korea, in FAO/NACA. 1995.
Regional Study and Workshop on the Environmental Assessment and
Management of Aquaculture Development (TCP/RAS/2253). NACA
Environment and Aquaculture Development Series No. 1. Bangkok,
NACA. (updated August 1998 by Seong-Kwae Park, Korea Marine
Institute, Seoul)
GLOBAL PERSPECTIVES
Sustainable development is the overriding strategic issue and challenge to all economic
sectors, including aquaculture, and will continue to be so in the foreseeable future. Issues
of sustainability can be expected to change our perceptions of desirable forms of
aquaculture development and management, and new ways of farming that strike a
balance between food security and the environmental and resource costs of production
will have to be adopted. In the future, and with the growing trend towards ecolabelling,
the longstanding goal of producing particular species at competitive prices is, in itself,
likely to be insufficient for realizing full market potentials. In the future, acceptable
sustainability credentials will probably be as essential as quality and safety standards are
today.
In the short term, the elaboration of legal and regulatory frameworks, particularly in
developing countries, will be the probable outcome of local social pressure and
environmental and public health standards associated with trade in aquaculture products
(e.g. in the case of shrimp and Atlantic salmon). This development will provide a window
of opportunity to begin the process of providing the sector with a specific identity in
national development - which could eventually be expanded to cover the entire sector.
Politically, food production will remain an overriding priority, and intensification as well
as diversification in food production will both constitute important approaches to
development. The move towards intensification in aquaculture is evident in many
countries, and this trend will probably continue. This will promote investment in
research, which will eventually lead to improved production efficiency, as in the case of
Atlantic salmon and American catfish. It will also enhance integration with agriculture
for the compatible multiple use of resources and for the utilization of by-products and
unconventional inputs in general. In industrialized countries, competition for quality
freshwater and suitable production sites will lead to an increased use of recycling systems
and to more intensive research in open sea aquaculture. The extent of the challenge to
aquaculture development will depend on the nature and magnitude of available resources
as well as on the existing competition for these resources and the aquaculture
development policies adopted at the national level. Finally, increasing privatization and
the contraction of the role of governments in development are likely to worsen the
situation of resource-poor artisanal and subsistence fish farmers.
INTEGRATING FISHERIES INTO COASTAL AREA
MANAGEMENT
THE ISSUE
The World Resources Institute (WRI) reported in 1996 that about 34 percent of the
world's coasts are at high potential risk of degradation and another 17 percent are at
moderate risk.15 As an estimated 90 percent of the world's marine capture fisheries
production is dependent on coastal habitats, the relevance to fisheries is obvious.
Moreover, coastal fishing communities are typically characterized by intense competition
for scarce resources (e.g. for access to and use of fishing grounds, water or land), which
is often associated with unregulated access to these resources.
The known consequences of habitat damage include a loss or lowering of productivity
and the associated threat to local food security; contaminated aquatic food products;
reduced economic viability; increased levels of conflict involving fishers; sometimes
physical displacement of communities; increased unemployment; and the loss of trade
opportunities. Heightened anxieties within the communities affected lead to frequent
disputes - and in extreme cases physical violence.
While fisheries is the sector that is most frequently disadvantaged, it is also a contributor
to environmental damage and to the exacerbation of conflict. The use of bottom trawls,
dredges and explosives and the careless anchoring of craft are examples of fisheries
practices that have a negative impact on aquatic habitats. They may negatively affect
bottom fauna such as sea grass beds and coral reefs. Likewise, some aquaculture
practices have caused negative environmental effects, such as the physical destruction of
ecologically sensitive habitat, excessive nutrient and organic enrichment of seabeds
owing to the release of wastes from cage and pond farms, and the introduction of harmful
alien species.
Conflicts over coastal fisheries resources occur between groups of fishers. A frequently
occurring example is conflict over the use of shrimp trawlers in the near-shore areas
frequented by artisanal fishermen using traditional methods. Apart from reduced catches,
the artisanal fishers risk damage to their gear. In such cases, their response may not
always be rational, as when they intensify their exploitation of juvenile fish in nursery
areas or employ destructive fishing methods to maintain their livelihoods.
Often, the fisheries sector and its institutions do not have the necessary economic and
institutional clout needed to guide and coordinate management. Many instances exist
where government agencies have insufficient expertise to undertake the necessary
integrative evaluations and planning. There may even be a lack of basic knowledge about
the fisheries in question.
However, as other economic sectors expand in the coastal zone, the relative economic
importance of fisheries declines, a process that may be speeded up as a result of damage
to habitat and spatial competition. Naturally, this acts to weaken further the influence of
the fisheries agencies in determining policy.
POSSIBLE SOLUTIONS
Integrated planning and institutional coordination are frequently listed as the primary
requirements for effective coastal management. In practice, both have proved difficult to
achieve and both entail significant costs. These difficulties relate to what are often
cumbersome bureaucratic structures and procedures of government agencies; the
complexity of the scientific, technical and economic issues involved; and the potentially
large number of informed decisions that need to be taken. Notwithstanding, there are few
coastal management schemes where the interests of the fisheries sector are not
considered.
Coastal management can be properly addressed through the formulation of soundly based
management plans, the provision and enforcement of appropriate environmental
legislation, a transparent consultative process involving users and potentially affected
groups and monitoring of the subsequent development impact. The role of fisheries
agencies should include participation in:
•
•
•
•
•
the planning and implementation of environmental impact assessment and
monitoring schemes;
the spatial planning process (e.g. coastal land use planning);
decisions concerning permits issued for construction, excavation, etc. (e.g. in the
case of port development);
the drafting of laws and regulations; and
relevant interagency and interdisciplinary fora.
The costs of a formal process of preparing a management plan are almost always
justified. However, as a rule it will be essential to strengthen expertise in environmental
impact assessment, the economic evaluation of alternative resources uses, rapid appraisal
techniques and ecological-economic modelling.
Experience shows that fisheries interests are best served when they are represented early
on in the coastal management process. Therefore, the delegation of responsibility to
elected bodies of lower government levels can also be important in ensuring greater
awareness at the local level (see Box 8, Participatory approach to the management of
lagoon fisheries in Benin). Ideally, municipal governments should have considerable
influence in matters relating to fisheries and aquaculture, in the way that they normally
do with respect to siting and specifications of any industrial, commercial or housing
structure. However, the municipal decision-makers will need to be provided with the
appropriate technical expertise and an understanding of fisheries matters - which is
something that can be done by specialist agencies, research institutions and NGOs.
BOX 8
Participatory approach to the management of lagoon
fisheries in Benin
Little more than 40 years ago, the lagoon fishers still observed the
simple rules for conservation of environment and fisheries resources
that their ancestors had established some three centuries earlier. Based
on taboos, these customary rules forbade all capture of fingerlings or
juveniles. They also designated rest days when no one was allowed to
fish for fear of incurring the wrath of the gods. There is still in fact a
section of the Ouidah coastal lagoon, between Hio and Avlékété,
called vodounto (a sacred lagoon traditionally inhabited by the deities
that is also a refuge for fish). Fishing in this area is strictly forbidden
so that stocks can recover. The area is guarded by dagbo hounon, the
chief fetisheer of the region, who inflicts heavy fines on offenders.
However, the advent of outside religions eroded the authority of the
traditional chiefs and upset the balance between increased number of
fishers and available fish resources: children follow their parents as
fishers in the lake and lagoon areas. The ecological equilibrium has
therefore been disrupted, and the rapid increase in fishing gear and the
employment of illegal practices have resulted in:
· a smaller size at recruitment for the main target species;
· the destruction of natural spawning grounds;
· a lower catch per unit effort;
· more disputes between fisher groups.
In 1992, recognizing that the legislative framework had not enabled
the fisheries board to bring about rational fisheries management, and
acting on the instigation of the local authorities, the government set up
some 20 Fishing Committees on an experimental basis in villages or
groups of villages bordering the lagoon of Porto-Novo. Each
committee is made up of fishers' representatives who are
democratically elected for a three-year term, which can be renewed in
the General Assembly. Each committee has nine to 15 members,
including an executive of five elected members who are briefed on
fisheries legislation by the administration and are expected to pass on
the information to the other fishers.
Committee members must be full-time fishers of sound character and
good social standing. They receive no payment. Each fisher in the
village has to pay a minimum monthly contribution of 150 CFA francs
(about US$0.3) towards the committee's operating costs. The basic
function of the committee is to see that the lagoon is used rationally for
the conservation of its resources and ecosystem. More specifically, the
Fishing Committee is expected to:
· raise awareness of fisheries rules and regulations;
· ensure compliance with traditional practices that are aimed at
protecting resources and the aquatic environment;
· in conjunction with the Fisheries Administration, ensure that the
regulations and the decisions reached in the fisher's general assembly
are applied;
· serve as a forum of discussion, analysis and conciliation for the
settlement of disputes;
· support any lagoon management and use programmes considered
necessary by the administration.
The Fisheries Administration gives its support to all the committees'
activities so long as these comply with regulatory provisions. The
committees cannot apply sanctions; their role is more to alert their
respective communities to the possible dangers of failing to observe
fisheries regulations.
In August 1996, in an effort to ensure sustainable fishing on Benin's
inland waters, the Fisheries Administration adopted a plan of
management with the following strategic thrusts:
· the implementation of institutional mechanisms for participatory
management;
· the management of fisheries resources within an appropriate legal
framework;
· the identification and promotion of activities to develop alternative
sources of income.
In 1997, the government issued Interministerial Decree No. 312 on the
institution, organization, functions and operation of the Fishing
Committees in the Republic of Benin in order to give them juridical
status. There are now 90 Fishing Committees involved in comanaging
the principal water bodies of three southern departments of Benin.
Source:Plan of Management of Inland Water Bodies of Southern
Benin, August 1996.
The process of management requires trade-offs between competing uses, with the
negotiation of trade-offs normally involving consideration of the respective contributions
from the competing users to national economic and social well-being. This in turn
requires consideration of the current and potential (i.e. optimally managed) economic
value of resources. It is important for all the potential impacts to be valued, not just those
that are easily determined. For example, those discharging untreated sewage into the sea
should bear the cost of associated catch losses to any nearby fishing community.
Some countries have enacted planning legislation that assigns priority to coast-dependent
development. Its application provides a first rationale for allocating scarce coastal
resources by giving added weight to uses (or sectors) that, by their very nature, are
dependent on the inherent attributes of the coastal zone. Capture fisheries and aquaculture
clearly fall within this category whereas many activities of other sectors may not.
RECENT ACTIONS
A major international workshop on integrated coastal management (ICM) in tropical
countries was held in 1996 in Xiamen, China, to discuss experiences with and lessons
drawn from ICM efforts. The workshop generated an overview of the processes of
formulating, designing, implementing and extending ICM within East Asia as well as
other regions. It also produced a set of Good ICM Practices.16 In addition, the
IMO/FAO/UNESCO - IOC/WMO/IAEA/UN/UNEP Joint Group of Experts on the
Scientific Aspects of Marine Environmental Protection (GESAMP) has provided
guidance on the role of science in coastal management. There has also been an
assessment of the current objectives of and methods for evaluating coastal management
projects and programmes that are funded by international donors.17
A group of experts recently compared the coastal management guidelines used by five
different international entities (the World Bank, the World Coast Conference, UNEP, the
World Conservation Union [IUCN] and the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development [OECD]) and subsequently wrote a "Consensus set of ICM guidelines".18
International concern for the management of coastal (and catchment) areas was given
formal recognition at the 1992 United Nations Conference on Environment and
Development (UNCED). In the same year, the International Conference on Responsible
Fisheries called for the development of a Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries. The
Code includes principles and provisions to encourage states and their agencies to consider
and implement legal, institutional, policy and economic measures. This is in order to
promote the proper integration of fisheries interests into coastal management planning
and development.
In its efforts to strengthen the capacity of governments, NGOs and the private sector in
coastal zone management, FAO has collaborated with a range of institutions, including
the International Centre for Living Aquatic Resources Management (ICLARM), NACA,
the United Nations Statistics Division, IUCN and other UN agencies sponsoring
GESAMP activities.
The joint initiatives mentioned have included the testing of alternative management
approaches through pilot projects and the publication of guidelines on managing the
environmental impact of aquaculture, integrated economic and environmental accounting,
objectives and strategies of coastal fisheries management and the application of scientific
methods to coastal zone management. There have also been jointly sponsored technical
consultations attended by stakeholders and other interested parties.
GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE
Where there is no constraint on levels of exploitation (i.e. in situations of open access),
the utilization of natural resources - whether by fishers or others - is inconsistent with
their sustainable use. In the case of fisheries, an emerging consensus is that sustainability
can be best achieved through the establishment of specific use or property rights. This is
valid despite the many difficulties in defining and enforcing rights-based management.
Some countries have modified fisheries law to accommodate the formal allocation of user
rights to fishing communities, and this trend is expected to continue, allowing such
communities greater control over the factors affecting their well-being.
In the absence of appropriate action by governments and users, the overexploitation and
degradation of coastal resources will increase further as a result of population pressure
and associated levels of economic activity. The greatest progress in coastal management
can be expected in the developed countries, as developing countries that suffer acute
poverty and unemployment within their coastal zones will need to strengthen their
national economies substantially before much attention can be paid to coastal
management.
CONTROL AND REDUCTION OF FISHING CAPACITY
THE ISSUE
Several of the world's most important fisheries are subject to excess fishing capacity, and
this a cause of growing concern. Excess capacity means that, in many of the world's
fisheries, fleets are not only larger than they need to be to catch and land (at the lowest
cost) the volumes of fish currently available, but they would also exceed the requirements
for fishing in the event of stocks being permitted to recover in size. Not only does this
threaten the sustainability of the fish stocks being exploited but it also constitutes a
potential threat to other stocks. This situation has resulted from investors purchasing
additional vessels to generate more returns - even when the fleet size is optimal from a
general socio-economic point of view. Excess fishing capacity is thus caused by a lack of
control over fishers' access to fish stocks. Additionally, in some countries, it is also
brought about by public funding of investments in new vessels and/or the rehabilitation
of old ones, although recent FAO studies on public funding of the fishing industry
indicate a declining trend in these expenditures.
Overcapacity is generally caused by excessive investments and an indiscriminate use of
fishing inputs. Two manifestations of excess capacity are poor economic performance, or
inefficiency, and biological overfishing. Overcapitalization in capture fisheries wastes
investment capital and therefore leads to high fishing costs. Similarly, overexploitation of
stocks wastes fish resources.
Attempts to control overfishing can be negated - at least partially - by the practical
difficulties associated with the measurement of fishing capacity, whether expressed as
inputs (fishing units) or output (potential catch). A lobster fishing vessel with 60 pots, for
example, has more effect, or fishing capacity, than a vessel with 20 pots; added to this are
factors such as the size of the pots and whether they are emptied more than once during a
shift. Subtleties such as these have made it difficult to control fishing capacity by
applying checks to fisheries inputs, and this has been one of several factors leading to an
increased interest in the control of capacity through limits on fisheries outputs, i.e. on
landings of fish (see Box 9, Capacity control in Australian prawn fisheries).
BOX 9
Capacity control in Australian prawn fisheries
The Northern Prawn Fishery of Australia produced about 8 500 tonnes
of prawns in 1997. Banana and tiger prawns are the main targeted
species. While the managed area is about 1 million km2, less than 10
percent of this area is trawled commercially. The commercial
harvesting of prawns began in the early 1960s, after which the fishing
effort rapidly increased. The fishery remained unrestricted until 1977,
when a limited entry regime was introduced and 292 vessels were
endorsed to participate in the fishery.
The fishing effort continued to increase because of improved
technology, bigger vessels and more fishing time, despite the control
on vessel numbers, and this raised concern over the future of the
fishery from an economic and biological point of view. Management
measures including strengthened vessel replacement policies, a
voluntary buy-back scheme, the permanent closure of prawn nursery
grounds, seasonal closures and gear restrictions were progressively
implemented from 1984. These proved to be only partially effective in
improving the performance of the fishery.
In 1984, operators were assigned saleable units based on the fishing
capacities of their vessels, with approximately 130 000 Class A units
allocated. Operators were endorsed to engage in the fishery provided
that they obtained the applicable number of Class A units and a Class
B unit. Class A units were determined according to the size of the
vessel and the engine, while Class B units permit operation in the
fishery. By 1985, nearly 300 vessels were authorized to operate in the
fishery.
Restructuring began in 1985 with the introduction of the voluntary
buy-back scheme, the aim of which was to reduce the number of
vessels and hence fishing capacity. This scheme was partly funded by
a $A 3 million government grant, with a further $A 5 million borrowed
from the National Fisheries Adjustment Scheme. The latter was to be
repaid from levies charged against the operators in the fishery.
Operators were invited to sell units under the scheme through the
lodging of tenders. While the initial tenders received were somewhat
inflated, 12 000 units were purchased by September 1986 at an average
price of
$A 200 per Class A unit and a total cost of $A 2.5 million. Further
purchases resulted in 100 000 Class A units and 222 vessels remaining
in November 1989.
In 1989, competition from farm produced prawns from Southeast Asia
caused a deterioration in prawn prices. This, together with advice from
the national research agencies, led to the government approving
another restructuring package in 1990. The new scheme was an
enhanced version of the earlier scheme. The government provided a
$A 5 million grant over three years and guaranteed up to $A 40.9
million to pay for units removed under the scheme. The borrowings
were to be repaid by the remaining operators over ten years. The
restructuring was conditional on the attainment of the target of 54 000
Class A units by 13 December 1992, to be followed by a compulsory
reduction of units across all unit holders before the start of the 1993
season if the target was not met.
The second scheme was less successful than the first, which can be
attributed to the fact that the buy-back prices offered by the scheme
were less than the open market value for Class A units. At 1 September
1992, there were 72 216 Class A units and 162 vessels remaining in
the fishery. By December 1992, the Northern Prawn Fishery
management plan was amended to provide for compulsory surrender
of Class A units. On 1 April 1993, 18 000 Class A units and 25 vessels
were retired from the fishery without compensation, leaving 54 000
Class A units and 137 vessels.
Although the legality of this action was challenged in the Federal
Court, an appeal confirmed the government's powers to reduce fishing
effort without the payment of compensation. This legal action resulted
in the industry focusing on the security of fishing access rights and
pressing for greater security over these rights. This and other aspects
were incorporated within a formal fisheries management plan
completed in 1995. In this, the previous fishing licences were replaced
by statutory fishing rights, which provide assurance to the owners of
long-term access to the fishery. This has created a more secure
environment for management, within which the owners can plan their
future operations and investments.
The large reduction in fishing capacity and the higher prices received
for prawns have resulted in a turnaround to substantial profitability for
the fishery. Estimates of pre-tax profit show an increase of $A 19
million per year for the fishery from the restructuring programme. In
order to maintain the economic benefits, it will be important for
management to contain the future expansion of fishing capacity. As it
is an input- controlled fishery, it can be expected that additional
reductions in the fishing capacity will be required in the future. The
AFMA (see Box 5) and the industry are investigating the use of gear
units rather than vessel units as a way of defining fishing capacity.
Conceptually, the use of gear units should provide more precision in
the control of fishing capacity; however, it remains to be seen whether
or not there are practical advantages. In December 1997, the AFMA
agreed that the fishery would move to a gear unit management system
in 1999, with the allocation of gear units being proportional to the
holding of Class A units.
Source: M. Harwood, former Assistant Secretary, Fisheries and
Aquaculture Branch, and T. Battaglene, Director, Commonwealth
Fisheries Policy, Australian Department of Primary Industries and
Energy, personal communication.
A fundamental problem for many countries is the lack of reliable data on the numbers
and characteristics of craft and gear. Also important is the extent to which the vessels
may be moved between fisheries, as action taken to reduce capacity in one fishery may be
the direct cause of overcapacity in another, owing to the rapid relocation of the excess
capacity. Unfortunately, this has been a common outcome in countries that have sought
to reduce capacity solely on a fishery-by-fishery basis. The problem has been recognized
in some countries, for example New Zealand, and country groupings, such as the EC,
which have chosen to reduce capacity concurrently in each fishery as well as globally at
aggregated fleet levels. The necessary precursor in these instances has been to undertake
an evaluation of capacity levels in all the relevant fisheries.
From a broader view, efforts made by some developed countries to reduce fishing
capacity have led to the relocation of vessels in the fisheries of other (usually developing
and least developed) countries. On a global scale, this does not constitute a reduction in
capacity. Furthermore, there are several reasons why these relocations might be
detrimental to many of the importing countries. For instance, the vessels are usually
purchased at a low price, and hence can be operated profitably (at least temporarily) even
when fish stocks are depleted - a situation that is conducive to the further depletion of
stocks. There have been many cases of local conflicts arising over the fact that such
imported vessels - which are usually of an industrial type - operate in direct competition
with artisanal fleets.
Fishing capacity is in excess in most regions of the world. For example, with increasing
fishing pressure in South Asia, many coastal pelagic and demersal fish stocks in the Bay
of Bengal, the Gulf of Thailand, and the South China Sea are fully exploited or
overfished. This is evident, inter alia, in the increasing proportion of low-value species
and juveniles of high-value species being caught.
The open-access nature of high seas fisheries creates a particularly difficult situation with
respect to the control of fishing capacity. In the 1982 United Nations Convention on the
Law of the Sea, in particular, the issue of fishing capacity is largely ignored. The 1995
UN Agreement19 reinforces the obligation of flag states to adhere to the management
regimes of the regional fisheries organizations, but does not empower the organizations
to deny the access of vessels from non-member states that agree to respect the
conservation and management measures in place and do not undermime the work of the
regional fishery organizations. Furthermore, there are important high seas stocks that do
not come under the purview of the existing regional organizations. In the event of any
future efforts to exert controls on the capacity of the high seas fleets, the collation of
vessel information at the global level, provided for under the FAO Compliance
Agreement, should prove useful.
POSSIBLE SOLUTIONS
Effective control of fishing capacity presupposes an understanding of its links with
related issues, of which the most important are: the impact of subsidies, the effects of
fleet mobility and the effects of the methods that can be used to regulate access to fish
stocks. While considerable experience has been acquired in the management of fisheries,
most of the methods or tools used control catch or effort, and not capacity per se. The
relative effectiveness of these methods in controlling fishing capacity is now better
understood, and it is clear that effective control needs regular assessments of stock
biomass and an understanding of fleet dynamics, based on a monitoring of the fleet size
and its use.
In the developed countries, considerable experience has been built up in the use of
alternative fisheries management methods to control fishing capacity. A consensus is
emerging in favour of using ITQ management where practicable. In its common form,
ITQ management entails limiting the number of fishing units (e.g. vessels), allocating a
quota (or share of the TAC) in respect to each and allowing the sale or lease of the right
to quotas. A virtue of this system is that it creates an incentive for the voluntary reduction
of excess capital by the vessel owners, as attention is drawn away from increasing
catches and focused more on reducing costs as the means of enhancing income. This
would occur, for example, if an owner purchased and merged the quota entitlements from
two boats, with one of the boats being retired. ITQ management can nevertheless prove
difficult, particularly when applied to mixed species fisheries, for which it is usually
necessary to have complex schemes to offset the increased incentive to discard by-catch.
Not all fisheries are amenable to quota management, however. The difficulties in
enforcing adherence to quotas can be substantial. The most frequent alternative has been
licence limitation, particularly as applied to controlling the number and power of the
fishing units. In most cases this has been done in association with allowing the sale or
lease of the rights to a licence. This is of relevance in the purchasing and retirement of
licence entitlements - through buy-back schemes - as a means to reduce fishing capacity.
It also facilitates (as in the case of ITQ management) the voluntary reduction of capacity
by vessel owners. This would occur, for example, when several gear entitlements are
merged into a single craft. Voluntary reductions in capacity are usually slow, however, so
some form of government intervention is usually required.
Where the control of fishing capacity is exerted through fisheries inputs, experience
suggests that capacity is likely to continue increasing, despite the best efforts of the
management agencies. This arises because, while it is not difficult to limit the number
and size of the units of fishing capacity, it is extremely difficult to control the fishing
power of the units. Fishers are continuously striving, often with success, to increase
fishing power. There are many examples where agencies have adopted - paradoxically management measures aimed at reducing the power of the fishing units to offset the gains
in fishing power achieved by fishers.
To handle this issue, the management body must monitor the development of technology
and its impact on fishing capacity, and do so in concert with the industry. Indeed,
management through control of fisheries inputs has been most successful and gained the
widest acceptance where the industry has participated in a substantial comanagement role
with government.
The majority of countries in the Asia and Pacific region have fisheries management
frameworks of varying degrees of efficiency. In general, they are in need of substantial
improvement (see Box 10, Improving fisheries management frameworks).
BOX 10
Improving fisheries management frameworks
A recent FAO study of the fisheries management frameworks of the
countries bordering the South China Sea concluded that there is a need
for strong political will on the part of governments to conserve
fisheries resources through improved and more effective fisheries
management systems. Governments must shift the aim of fisheries
management policies from that of maximizing production to
optimizing the net socio-economic benefits over the long term. They
must also emphasize the importance of preventing and controlling
environmental degradation. In addition, the study concluded that
governments could:
· for the benefit of the private sector, the fishing industry and fishers,
explain - in clear and simple terms - the existing laws and regulations
and management measures adopted by governments;
· use a precautionary approach, in both inshore and offshore fisheries,
when timely information and data are not available;
· emphasize research on the development of locally appropriate
resource assessment models, bio-economic analysis of exploited fish
stocks and the management of transboundary stocks;
· facilitate technology transfers through improving methodologies and
the capacity of staff in extension work and by encouraging closer
cooperation among administrators, scientific and academic institutions,
the fishing industry and fishers.
A number of key issues for improved management can be tackled at
the regional level, including: the strengthening of scientists' and
administrators' capacities; the development of timely and reliable
fisheries information and statistical data as well as the setting up of a
regional network; research and management considerations for shared
or transboundary fish stocks; the development of methodologies for
stock assessments; the prevention and control of degradation; and the
monitoring of large ecosystems such as the South China Sea or the
Gulf of Thailand.
Source: FAO. 1997. Fisheries management frameworks of the
countries bordering the South China Sea. Bangkok, Asia and Pacific
Fisheries Commission, FAO Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific.
It is in the highly populous countries suffering from acute poverty and unemployment
that controlling capacity is most problematic. In the case of artisanal fisheries, even when
fisheries agencies can establish that economic benefits would accrue from reduced
capacity, an appreciation of the negative social consequences has invariably prevented
such action being taken. A lack of alternative employment opportunities encourages the
attraction of fisheries as an employer of last resort, and it is in circumstances such as
these that fisheries agencies have shown interest in management that empowers the local
communities themselves - in particular through the allocation of user rights - to make the
difficult decisions concerning fishing capacity and the sharing of the benefits generated
by fisheries. This approach is now commonly referred to as "community-based
management". (See Box 11, Community-based management in the Negombo Lagoon, Sri
Lanka).
BOX 11
Community-based management in the Negombo Lagoon,
Sri Lanka
Negombo is a town located 30 km north of Colombo. Close to
Negombo is a lagoon encompassing an area of 31.64 km2. The catch
from the lagoon in 1997 was estimated to be nearly 1 700 tonnes,
including 538 tonnes of shrimp, and was valued at SL Rs 100 million
(US$1.7 million). Frame survey results have indicated a total of 1 305
vessels (non-motorized), crewed by about 2 000 fishers. The net
monthly remuneration per fisher is thought to be about SL Rs 4 000
(US$67).
Community-based management is well established at Negombo.
Perhaps the most interesting example concerns the use of stake nets
inside the entrance to the lagoon. These are trawl-like nets staked to
the lagoon bottom during outgoing tides at night. There are about 60
stations - the number varies slightly according to changes in the
topography of the entrance - and, at each, there are several sites that
can be fished. The stations are well known and gazetted in the fisheries
regulations. Fishing occurs in all months and, in 1997, involved the
use of about 200 craft, with two fishers per vessel (at least one fisher
on each vessel is required to be a society member), and a total catch of
308 tonnes, of which 211 tonnes were shrimps.
On the basis of several decades of traditional practice, the management
of the stake net fishery is principally undertaken by four independent
local societies. Nearly all the 60 stations are distributed among these
societies. The entitlements to operate stake nets at each station are
allocated among the society members at large annual gatherings
organized by each society. The initial process of allocation involves a
ballot, whereby the entitlements to fish at a station are distributed
randomly. This is followed by a bidding process - a form of auction
administered by each society - to determine the distribution of the sites
at each station. A member who is successful in the ballot but
unsuccessful in bidding for a productive site may choose not to take a
site known to be of low productivity.
As the number of members in the societies is greater than the number
of sites, each site is allocated to more than one member. In recent
years, the entitlement to a site has been allocated to an average of three
members, with access being rotated so as to allow each member to
occupy a site once every three days. Under this arrangement, each
member can engage in stake net fishing for ten days of each month as
well as being able to participate in different types of fishing on other
days. Only one member of a family may have membership, and the
transferral of membership - when a member dies, for example - is
hereditary. It may only be passed on to a male member of the
immediate family. Where there is no male member, the entitlement
lapses.
Additional memberships may be issued, although only to married
males between the ages of 18 and 50 years who are descendants of
stake net fishers and are Christian. They must also demonstrate that
they have access to the necessary craft and gear and are competent
fishers. The societies impose penalties in the case of breaches of the
rules. The church, which is allocated several sites, obtains a modest
revenue from the fishery and it uses this in local welfare activities.
This reflects its major role in the evolution of the current regime.
Most of the other examples of community-based management existing
throughout Sri Lanka in the past have now disappeared. The
contributing factors have included increased mobility of the fishers
owing to the motorization of vessels, the influx of displaced persons
from conflict-affected zones in the north of the country, and some loss
of cohesion within the coastal communities.
Sources: UNDP/Government of Sri Lanka/FAO Marine Fisheries
Management Project SRL/91/022; various published and unpublished
papers.
RECENT ACTIONS
A growing number of countries have acted to make substantial reductions in their fishing
capacity. In the EC, Multi-Annual Guidance Programmes (MAGP) have been in force
since the mid-1980s. Initially, they were designed to control and restrict fleet expansion;
more recently they have been designed to reduce capacity. The MAGP targets for fishing
capacity are set in terms of vessel tonnage and engine power which, between 1991 and
1996, were reduced by 15 and 9.5 percent, respectively.
In New Zealand, reductions in fishing capacity since the mid-1980s were undertaken in
association with ITQ management. In the subsequent decade, the number of vessels
engaged in the country's inshore fisheries was halved (see Box 4). The reductions in
fishing capacity achieved in Australia are more at the individual fishery level. Some
countries, in particular Japan, have strengthened regulations concerning fleet disposal and
access to high seas fisheries.
In Latin America, Argentina, Chile and Peru have recently introduced programmes aimed
at reducing fishing capacity. To date, however, these countries have met with
considerable resistance from industry associations, with which negotiations related to
these programmes are proving complex and time-consuming.
From 1995 to 1997, FAO undertook an assessment of the economic viability of selected
fleets (see Box 12) shows that fishing remains profitable in most major fisheries. This
would seem to indicate that reduced yields have been compensated by higher prices and
lower costs, the latter caused by technological improvements, but still in some cases
through transfers of public funds to the sector.
The longer-term objective for FAO is to develop, within the framework of the Committee
on Fisheries (COFI), an international Plan of Action for the Management of Global
Fishing Capacity. As a step towards developing such a plan, in April 1998 an FAO
Technical Working Group of international experts met in La Jolla, United States, to
review issues concerning fishing capacity.20 Countries considered the results of these
discussions at a meeting held at FAO headquarters from 22 to 24 July 1998.
BOX 12
Economic viability of marine capture fisheries
In cooperation with fisheries research institutions and agencies in Asia,
Africa, Latin America and Europe, between 1995 and 1997 FAO
carried out studies on the economic and financial viability of the most
common fishing vessels and gear combinations. At the same time,
information was also collected on the level of exploitation of the
associated resources as well as on government policies regarding
fisheries management, subsidies and fiscal policies.
The countries covered include Argentina, Cameroon, China, France,
Germany, Ghana, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, Peru, the Republic of
Korea, Senegal, Spain, Taiwan Province of China and Thailand.
Together, they accounted for about 50 percent of the total marine
capture fisheries production in South America, Europe, Africa and
Asia, which in turn accounted for 84 percent of global marine capture
fisheries production in 1995. FAO considers the studies a useful
empirical contribution to the discussion on the economic viability of
marine capture fisheries. They should be continued and expanded to
cover more countries, as recommended by the workshop, with a view
to validating the findings and monitoring changes that occur over time.
The findings of the studies were discussed at an interregional
workshop, held in Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia, from 15 to 18 December
1997. The general conclusion was that, in spite of fully and sometimes
overexploited fisheries resources, most marine capture fisheries are
economically and financially viable. In other words, they generate
sufficient income to cover costs - including allowances for
depreciation as well as the opportunity cost of capital, with adequate
levels of remuneration to the owners and crews and a surplus
remaining for reinvestment.
In the African countries studied, only small-scale encircling gillnetting
and deep-sea fish/shrimp trawling in Senegal generated a negative net
cash flow, while all other fishing vessel and gear combinations studied
generated a positive net surplus. In Latin America, large-scale trawling
in Peru had a negative net cash flow, while purse seiners generated a
positive net surplus. In Argentina, both trawlers and purse seiners
generated a positive net surplus.
In Asia, all fishing fleet segments covered in Malaysia, the Republic of
Korea and Taiwan Province of China generated a positive net surplus,
as did five out of the seven typical medium- and large-scale fishing
units in China, and seven out of the eight typical fishing units in
Indonesia. In Europe, out of the 23 types of small-, medium- and largescale fishing vessels studied in France and Spain, only two types of
deep-sea trawlers operating in France had negative net results, while
the other 21 types of vessels generated a positive net surplus.
It was also observed that the number of subsidies in developing
countries has been greatly reduced in recent years. The remaining
subsidies are for offshore fishing, artisanal fisheries and fisheries
cooperatives as well as for fishing operations in remote and
underdeveloped areas. They were mainly available in the form of
capital subsidies and reduced duty on fuel, and even these were in the
process of being further reduced.
Source: FAO. Economic viability and sustainability of marine capture
fisheries - Findings of a global study and recommendations of an
interregional workshop. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper No. 377. (in
prepa-ration)
GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE
Many developed countries and a small number of developing countries have successfully
taken the important and difficult steps needed to control and, where needed, reduce
fishing capacity effectively. Other countries can be expected to follow. Notwithstanding,
the reduction of capacity in some countries has not necessarily led to a reduction of the
global fishing capacity, owing to the relocation of capacity and the continuing expansion
of capacity in other countries. In the short term, the control of capacity will occur mostly
in EEZ waters other than those of the highly populous and least developed countries
where the control of fishing capacity will remain secondary to employment
considerations. In a few countries, commercial fisheries will be displaced as preference is
given to recreational activities and tourism.
Resolving the excess capacity in the high seas fisheries is bound to be a protracted
process because of the "open access" nature of these fisheries, the difficulty of adopting
and enforcing internationally (or regionally) agreed measures to control fishing capacity
and the need to establish additional regional management organizations for those fish
stocks outside the purview of existing regional fisheries management bodies. An
emerging issue stems from the increasing participation in high seas fisheries by coastal
states (e.g. countries bordering the Indian Ocean) that often use lower-technology vessels
and gear than the existing distant-water fleets. These countries
are unlikely to collaborate with attempts by regional organizations to control fishing
capacity while they are still in the process of establishing their offshore fleets. Ultimately,
they might seek to displace the distant-water fleets.
REDUCTION OF BY-CATCH AND DISCARDS
THE ISSUE
By-catch occurs because most fishing gears and practices are not perfectly selective for
the species and sizes being targeted and because target species exist in habitats occupied
by a wide range of other species. The target species themselves may be considered as bycatch if they are of the wrong size, the wrong sex or the wrong part of the animal. Shark
carcasses are an example of the latter when it is only the fins that are targeted. The
definition of "wrong" in these cases is determined either by the market or through
regulations applied to the fishery. Similarly, the by-catch of non-target species may be
either marketable or non-marketable. In most cases, unmarketable by-catch is discarded,
the key exception being where discarding is forbidden.
The discarding of by-catch has long been recognized as wasteful, although inevitable by
virtue of the nature of fishing. It constitutes a loss of valuable food, has negative
consequences for the environment and biodiversity and can be aesthetically offensive.
By-catch was propelled to the forefront of public debate in reaction to the incidental
capture of dolphins in tuna purse seine nets, turtles in shrimp trawls and marine
mammals, birds, turtles and fish in high seas squid driftnets. The outcome for all the
fisheries concerned was dramatic, and not always perceived as rational from the
viewpoint of fisheries interests.
An order of magnitude for the quantities of fish discarded was provided for the first time
in an assessment published by FAO in 1994.21 Annual discards from the world's fisheries
were estimated to range from 17.9 million to 39.5 million tonnes. A subsequent reevaluation of these estimates, together with adjustments allowing for subsequent
reductions in discarding, indicates that current levels are at the lower end of the range.
The most recent FAO estimate of 20 million tonnes, if correct, is equivalent to 25 percent
of the reported annual production from marine capture fisheries, which are those from
which most of the discards derive.
In the Pacific artisanal and subsistence fisheries, fishers generally discard very little of
their catch. Most discards in this region are generated by the tuna fisheries, particularly
the tuna long-line fisheries for albacore and, to a lesser extent, by the purse seine fisheries
for skipjack and yellowfin tunas.
In most respects, the decision by fishers to discard components of their catch is driven by
economic factors. In an unregulated fishery, fishers have an incentive to discard if the
expected net price, i.e. the real price less landing costs, is negative and if the resultant
costs incurred in landing are greater than those incurred by discarding. Furthermore, there
is an incentive to discard if the boat has a limited holding capacity. In such cases, fishers
tend to discard the low-value components and retain those of higher value, a practice that
is often referred to as "high grading".
Management involving the use of catch quotas commonly increases the incentive to
discard. This is particularly so in mixed species fisheries where several of the species are
subject to a quota. Three forms of discarding can be associated with quota management:
the discarding of catch taken in excess of the quota, high grading and price dumping. The
latter occurs where all or part of the catch of a species is discarded if a low price is
expected. This could occur on the return journey to port, for example, when a fisher may
decide to discard the day's catch so as to save the quota for a day when the price is
higher.
Discarding is a feature of any management system that does provide for its specific and
effective prohibition. In this event, there remains the issue of whether or not the added
cost of enforcement is justified in lieu of the benefits and who should pay. In fact, most
of the measures aimed at reducing the quantities being discarded carry substantial
implementation costs. The rational argument that is gaining general acceptance is that the
costs of implementation should be a cost against the fisheries and should therefore be
borne - directly or indirectly - by those who clearly benefit directly from those fisheries.
POSSIBLE SOLUTIONS
The incentives to discard do not change with the introduction of licence limitation.
Nevertheless, if the number of vessels is reduced as a result of licensing, there is likely to
be at least a short-term increase in the stock of the by-catch species. Minimum size
requirements would normally increase the discarding, particularly if enforcement is
carried out at the point of landing. The benefit from enforcement at the point of capture which is not always practical - is to "encourage" fishers to operate on grounds where
there are fewer undersized fish and to employ more selective gears and practices.
Restrictions applied to the number of days at sea can lead to less discarding. This may
occur simply as a consequence of reducing the fishing effort, in which case the effects are
the same as those brought about by reducing the number of vessels. Additionally, there
may be insufficient fishing time to enable the space to be filled with only the highervalue components of the catch, a situation that arises if storage space is limited. In such
cases, more of the less valuable components could be retained and hence discarding could
be reduced.
At the fishery level, the management measures that seek to reduce discarding fall into
two broad categories. The first achieves lower quantities of by-catch through the use of
more selective gears and practices, area and seasonal closures and increased by-catch
utilization. The second category includes measures aimed at reducing the discarding of
by-catch. These may be direct - such as when discarding is prohibited - or take the form
of economic incentives to alter discarding behaviour.
The measures to reduce discarding in fisheries under quota management have gained
increased prominence, as progressively more fisheries have been placed under ITQ
management regimes. They include allowing above-quota catch to be traded - i.e. sold to
those with unfilled quotas - as an alternative to discarding. Permissible levels of quota
overrun allow fishers to exceed quotas in one year in return for a reduction in quotas for
the following year. In New Zealand, permitted quota overruns are limited to 10 percent of
the original quota for all species. Also in New Zealand, fishers can land species for which
they do not hold a quota and record it against the quota held by other fishers. The
voluntary surrender of above-quota catch without penalty is another option. In this event,
the fisher may sell the catch in the normal manner, but must pay the "deemed" value (the
value realized in excess of the cost of landing) to the management authority.
Norway has imposed a system where the discarding of quota species - including sizes that
might otherwise have been discarded - is prohibited and all the catch is deducted from the
quota (see Box 13). Individual fishers are responsible for ensuring that they have
sufficient unfilled quotas to allow for any by-catch of quota species when targeting other
quota species. They are also required to leave a fishing ground if there is a perceived risk
of exceeding quotas or if there are abundant juveniles. This aspect of the Norwegian
approach has provided a strong incentive to develop and apply more selective gears. In
the United States, the North Pacific Fishery Management Council has resolved to prohibit
the discarding of walleye pollock, Pacific cod, yellowfin sole and rock sole. This has
commenced for the first two species and is to be phased in for the others over a five-year
period.
BOX 13
Controlling by-catch and discards: Norway's experience
A few decades ago, most fisheries in Norway produced a by-catch.
This was particularly so in bottom trawling for roundfish and pink
shrimp (Pandalus borealis). At the time almost no regulations dealt
explicitly with by-catch. However, both the quantity and composition
of the catch were influenced by regulations aimed at preserving the
target species. Such measures included (minimum) mesh size
regulations and a ban on retention onboard as well as landing of fish
below an established minimum size (minimum landing size [MLS]).
Thus, the management system in place made the practice of discarding
both target and non-target species unavoidable.
In 1983, a Marine Fisheries Act was adopted in parliament, then
regulated and applied. The intention behind the new act was to initiate
and promote a process leading to a lower volume of killed and
discarded fish. This applied to both target and non-target species. The
Act clearly states that any illegal catch should be thrown immediately
back into the sea to give the fish a chance to survive. However, the
time needed to bring the catch onboard and to sort it generally resulted
in most fish being out of the water too long to survive even if they
were not dead when first thrown back overboard.
It was soon recognized that the Act and its regulations had
shortcomings, and these have been addressed by several administrative
measures during the last 15 years. The purpose has been to regulate the
fishing, not the landings, and therefore to concentrate enforcement on
the fishing operation itself.
One of the first administrative measures was the introduction of a
surveillance programme in 1983/84. Chartered commercial fishing
vessels surveyed the most important fishing ground to monitor the bycatch of illegal-sized fish and species of which fishing was prohibited.
The surveillance programme was soon followed up by regulations
establishing specific criteria for a maximum allowable by-catch.
As these criteria were implemented by the Norwegian Coastguard, it
immediately became evident that the authorities would temporarily
have to close several productive fishing grounds. It is now standard
practice for the grounds to be closed for shrimp trawling if the catch
contains more than one individual juvenile cod and/or haddock per
kilogram of shrimp, or if undersized shrimp account for 10 percent or
more of its weight. Likewise, bottom trawl grounds are closed when
catches contain more than 15 percent (in number) of juveniles of the
target species. Purse-seining for saithe cannot be carried out when 10
percent or more of the saithe caught is below the MLS.
Other important measures introduced since 1983 include: i) an
obligation to leave the fishing grounds when the mixture of undersized
fish caught exceeds certain levels; ii) temporary closures of sensitive
areas; iii) the prohibition of onboard sorting machines (e.g. in the
mackerel fishery); and iv) a requirement to use more selective gears.
The most revolutionary step, however, is probably the ban on discards.
Norwegian fishers are obliged to land all catches of important
commercial species. Even if such fish are caught unintentionally, both
mature and undersized fish must be landed. This "illegal" catch should
be taken ashore and deducted from the TAC of the species concerned.
In general fishers support the ban on discarding, as experience has
taught that by-catches - particularly of juveniles - lead to fewer fish in
future years.
Fishers soon realized that, by using more selective gears and methods i.e. catching only individuals of the target species that are above the
MLS - they could fish while also abiding by the rules. The Norwegian
fishing authorities have shared this view and have been supportive in
terms of providing funds for developing selective fishing gear.
A grid system to avoid by-catch of fish juveniles in trawl fisheries as
well as of bigger non-target fish was developed in less than two years
and its use is now widespread in the North Atlantic. The grid is
mounted at 45 degrees in the trawl and set behind a guiding funnel. It
has proved to be an excellent selectivity device in shrimp fisheries.
More than 90 percent (in weight) of the by-catch in shrimp fisheries is
released, and the loss of shrimp is less than 2 percent. The device was
made compulsory for shrimp trawling in the early 1990s. Encouraged
by the positive results of selectivity work on shrimp trawls, grid work
on bottom trawls and seine nets was started. After several years of
voluntary use, in 1997 a grid system was made compulsory for vessels
using these gears in the Norwegian and Russian EEZs. At this stage,
the system was readily accepted, as most fishers were already
accustomed to using the grids.
Source: B. Isaksen, Norwegian Institute of Fisheries Research, Bergen,
Norway.
RECENT ACTIONS
The 1995 UN Agreement for the Conservation and Management of Straddling Fish
Stocks and Highly Migratory Fish Stocks seeks to minimize pollution, waste, discards,
catch by lost or abandoned gear and catch of non-target fish and non-fish species. This
should be achieved, inter alia, through measures such as the development and use of
selective, environmentally safe and cost-effective fishing gear and techniques. These
obligations were reiterated with reference to all fisheries in the Plan of Action produced
by the International Conference on the Sustainable Contribution of Fisheries to Food
Security, held in Kyoto, Japan, in 1995.
The Code specifically states that: "States, with relevant groups from industry, should
encourage the development and implementation of technologies and operational methods
that reduce discards. The use of fishing gear and practices that lead to the discarding of
catch should be discouraged and the use of fishing gear and practices that increase
survival rates of escaping fish should be promoted." Where selective and environmentally
safe fishing gear and practices are used, they should be recognized and accorded priority
in establishing conservation and management measures for fisheries.
The Technical Consultation on the Reduction of Wastage in Fisheries,22 held in Japan in
October 1996, provided an important forum for a discussion of this issue by international
specialists. The participants concluded that there had been significant reductions in
discarding worldwide during the past decade. This had come about as a result of less
fishing effort, time and area closures of fishing grounds, the use of more selective gears,
the utilization of previously discarded by-catch, enforced prohibitions on discarding, and
consumer-led actions. There were recommendations made with regard to information
gathering, the future estimation of discards, options for fisheries management, the
impacts on small-scale and recreational fisheries, gear selectivity and the utilization of
by-catch.
At the March 1997 session of COFI, several delegations reported on successful by-catch
reduction programmes. Papers23 presented at the international workshop on Solving ByCatch: Considerations for Today and Tomorrow, sponsored by the United States and held
in Seattle in 1995, provided many examples of by-catch reduction across a wide range of
fishing gears and practices. The by-catch and discard issue, particularly regarding the
collection of by-catch data, is being addressed by the regional fisheries organizations, for
example by placing observers (from member countries) on the offshore tuna fleets.
The Inter-American Tropical Tuna Commission (IATTC) is continuing its substantial
involvement in research on dolphin by-catches. The International Commission for the
Conservation of Atlantic Tunas (ICCAT) is increasingly active with respect to the bycatch of sharks (see Box 14).
BOX 14
International actions to reduce shark by-catch in the
Atlantic tuna and tuna-like fisheries
At the Ninth Meeting of the Conference of the Parties to the
Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild
Fauna and Flora (CITES), held in Fort Lauderdale, United States, in
November 1994, it was proposed that several shark species be listed in
the CITES Appendix as endangered species. The International
Commission for the Conservation of Atlantic Tunas (ICCAT) took
notice, as sharks are a major component of the by-catch of many tuna
fisheries. Sharks are also targeted from some tuna fishing vessels,
using slightly modified gears. CITES did not adopt the proposal;
however, it did pass a resolution on the Status of International Trade in
Shark Species.
At the 1994 meeting of the ICCAT Standing Committee on Research
and Statistics (SCRS), it was decided to conduct a survey to determine
the species of shark being caught as by-catch in the tuna fisheries. The
results were reported at the 1995 meeting of the SCRS. In the same
year, from an examination of its enabling International Convention for
the Conservation of Atlantic Tunas, ICCAT confirmed that it was
responsible for the collection of information on the catches of sharks
and other fish species caught coincidentally from fishing effort
directed at tuna and tuna-like species. It also agreed to assist in any
stock assessment of pelagic sharks, as the methodology is similar to
that used for tunas and the scientific expertise available is therefore
applicable.
In accordance with the CITES resolution, at its 1995 session, the
ICCAT Commission adopted the ICCAT Resolution on Cooperation
with FAO with regard to Study on the Status of Stocks and By-Catch
of Shark Species. This recognized that FAO should be the international
coordinating entity for disseminating data on shark catches and that all
other regional agencies should collaborate with FAO.
The 1995 ICCAT session also decided to:
· establish a Sub-Committee on By-Catch to guide research and data
analysis, and a Working Group on Sharks to deal with issues
concerning incidental and targeted capture of sharks;
· amend ICCAT's statistical database to include information on bycatch and encourage more comprehensive data collections;
· conduct stock assessments, with priority given to the pelagic sharks
(e.g. blue, mako, thresher, silky).
The first meeting of the ICCAT Working Group on Sharks was held in
Miami, United States, in February 1996. It finalized a list of the bycatch species associated with tuna fisheries and, after reviewing a
summary of the shark catch and trade data in the FAO database,
developed a plan for improving the data collection systems. It also
formulated a plan to collect and incorporate shark by-catch data into
the ICCAT statistical database as well as a new reporting format. An
important outcome was the endorsement of a data collection form for
reporting shark by-catch, and its distribution through the ICCAT
secretariat to more than 80 countries engaged in tuna fishing in the
Atlantic. The completed forms would be returned annually to ICCAT.
The second meeting of the Working Group on Sharks took place in
Shimizu, Japan, in March 1997 before the Tenth Conference of the
Parties to CITES. The Working Group focused on updating its list of
shark species caught by tuna fisheries, and reviewed additional data
provided to ICCAT on the catch and catch per unit effort (CPUE) of
shark for the Atlantic. The responses of other international bodies to
the request from CITES to collaborate in the collection of shark
research and trade data were also examined. This resulted in ICCAT
requesting CITES to seek improved collaboration among the regional
agencies and additional data from the tuna-fishing countries.
At its 1997 meeting, the SCRS developed mathematical equations, or
conversion factors, enabling the estimation of weight from length for
the major species of shark in the Atlantic. Such equations are
necessary for the conversion of different types of statistics being
provided for inclusion in the ICCAT database. Also in 1997,
implementation of the national observer programmes for tuna longliners, purse seiners and bait boats became binding on ICCAT
Contracting Parties. As reported in October 1997, observers were
being deployed on some tuna vessels by 11 Contracting and nonContracting Parties (Brazil, Canada, Chinese Taipei, France, Japan,
Italy, Mexico, Spain, the United Kingdom, the United States and
Venezuela).
Notwithstanding the progress, there are still difficulties impeding the
establishment of a comprehensive database for sharks. This includes
problems encountered in the collection of historical shark by-catch
data and the identification of species by fishers, with the result that
catches are often reported without species breakdown. Particular
difficulties are raised by the interest in shark-fin products, a subject
related to world trade. Sometimes the carcasses are discarded at sea
and only the fins are kept while, at other times, both may be landed but
sold in different markets. The latter can result in "double counting", for
example in cases where both the fins and the carcass weights are
converted in the estimation of whole weights. The trade of shark fins is
also complicated by the common practice in some countries of reexporting after importing.
Source: P. Miyake, ICCAT secretariat, Madrid, Spain.
GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE
The process of resolving the by-catch and discards issue will be driven by forces at
several levels. The community at large will continue to take offence, particularly where
the problem is widely publicized and includes species with a high "aesthetic" value. The
continued large-scale use of drift gillnets, for example, whether on the high seas or
elsewhere, can be expected to remain a target of dissent. The substantial challenge for
fisheries governance is to achieve balanced outcomes that are sensitive to community
values but avoid unnecessary losses of benefit from the fisheries themselves. This will
require the public to be correctly informed and those responsible for fisheries - including
fisheries participants themselves - to establish credibility through continued efforts to
reduce by-catch and discarding.
In the highly populous countries, particularly in Asia, where fisheries are characterized
by many gears and several species in catches, relatively little of what is caught is not
consumed or used as feed in aquaculture. Where wastage does occur, it is not so much the
consequence of discarding but rather of some species - possibly many - generating more
economic benefit when captured at a larger size. Where this can be established, the best
management approaches are likely to include area and time closures and more selective
gears. Nevertheless, this situation generally arises in countries where management is
intrinsically difficult because fisheries often act as the employer of last resort. Improving
the well-being of the fishers in one community would be a short-lived solution if there
was a consequential inward movement of fishers from the surrounding communities.
1
Adopted by the Twenty-eighth Session of the FAO Conference in October 1995, the
Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries is referred to throughout this publication as
"the Code".
2
The EC, Japan, Norway, the Russian Federation and the United States.
3
Chile, Colombia, Ecuador and Peru.
4
Government of the United States. 1997. Implementation Plan for the Code of Conduct
for Responsible Fisheries. United States Department of Commerce, National Oceanic and
Atmospheric Administration and National Marine Fisheries Service. 20 pp.
5
Anon. 1997. Global Aquaculture Alliance formed to guide industry toward
environmental sustainability. World Aquaculture, September 1997, p. 48.
6
D.J. Donovan. 1997. Environmental Code of Practice for Australian Prawn Farmers.
July 1997. 32 pp.
7
O. Pawaputanon. 1997. Manual for harmonization of good shrimp farm practice.
ASEAN Fisheries Network Project.
8
Anon. The Holmenkollen Guidelines for Sustainable Aquaculture. In Proceedings of the
Second International Symposium on Sustainable Aquaculture, Oslo, 2-5 November 1997.
Trondheim, Norway, Norwegian Academy of Technological Sciences. 9 pp.
9
See FAO. 1997. Risk management and food safety. Report of a Joint FAO/WHO Expert
Consultation, Rome, 27-31 January 1997. FAO Food and Nutrition Paper No. 65. Rome;
and FAO. 1998. Animal feeding and food safety. Report of an FAO Consultation, Rome,
10-14 March 1997. FAO Food and Nutrition Paper No. 69. Rome.
10
SEAFDEC/FAO/CIDA. Report and proceedings of SEAFDEC/FAO/CIDA Expert
Meeting on the Use of Chemicals in Aquaculture in Asia, 20-22 May 1996, Southeast
Asian Fisheries Development Centre, Iloilo, the Philippines. (in preparation)
11
FAO. 1997. Towards safe and effective use of chemicals in coastal aquaculture.
GESAMP Reports and Studies No. 65. Rome. 40 pp.
12
FAO/NACA/WHO. Food safety issues associated with products from aquaculture.
Report of a Joint FAO/NACA/WHO Study Group on Food Safety Issues associated with
Products from Aquaculture, Bangkok, Thailand, 22-26 July 1997. WHO Technical
Report Series No. 883. Geneva, WHO. (in press)
13
Directive 91/493/EEC as amended by 95/71/EC.
14
Directive 91/67/EEC as amended by Directives 93/54/EC and 95/22/EC.
15
WRI. 1996. World Resources 1996-1997. WRI/UNEP/UNDP/World Bank. Oxford,
UK, Oxford University Press. 365 pp.
16
International Workshop on Integrated Coastal Management in Tropical Developing
Countries: Lessons Learned from Successes and Failures. 1996. Enhancing the success of
integrated coastal management: good practices in the formulation, design, and
implementation of integrated coastal management initiatives. MPP-EAS Technical
Report No. 2. Quezon City, the Philippines, GEF/UNDP/IMO Regional Programme for
the Prevention and Management of Marine Pollution in the East Asian Seas/Coastal
Management Center.
17
J. Sorensen. 1997. National and international efforts at integrated coastal management:
definitions, achievements and lessons. Coastal Management, 25: 3-41.
18
B. Cisin-Sain, R.W. Knecht and G.W. Fisk. 1995. Growth in capacity for integrated
coastal management since UNCED: an international perspective. Ocean and Coastal
Management, 29(1-3): 93-123.
19
The Agreement on the Implementation of the Provisions of the United Nations
Convention on the Law of the Sea of 10 December 1982 Relating to the Conservation
and Management of Straddling Fish Stocks and Highly Migratory Fish Stocks.
20
See FAO Fisheries Department Report of the Technical Working Group on the
Management of Fishing Capacity, La Jolla, United States, 15 to 18 April 1998.
21
FAO. 1994. A global assessment of fisheries by-catch and discards. FAO Fisheries
Technical Paper No. 339. Rome.
22
I.J. Clucas and D.G. James, eds. 1997. Papers presented at the Technical Consultation
on Reduction of Wastage in Fisheries. Tokyo, 28 October-1 November 1996. FAO
Fisheries Report No. 547, Suppl. Rome, FAO. 338 pp.
23
Solving By-Catch: Considerations for Today and Tomorrow. Alaska Sea Grant College
Program Report No. 96-03, University of Alaska, Fairbanks.
PART 3
Highlights of special FAO
Over the past two years, inland fisheries resources and the state of the world's fishers and
fishing vessels have been studied closely by the FAO Fisheries Department. Highlights
from the analyses and assessments carried out are presented in the following two
sections.
INLAND FISHERIES RESOURCES: THEIR STATUS AND USE1
THE STATE OF INLAND FISHERIES RESOURCES
Our knowledge of the state of inland fisheries resources is poor. The main reasons for this
are the large number, dispersion, variety and dynamic nature of inland water bodies and
the diversity of their aquatic fauna. These characteristics mean that the collection of data
is costly. Some 11 500 fish species (41 percent of all fish) are exclusively freshwater and
about 300 (1 percent) are diadromous. To a large extent, therefore, existing knowledge
about resources is based on inferences derived from studies of inland water systems and
from the monitoring, where possible, of effort and yields in inland fisheries.
Inland water systems: type and magnitude
Fish and other aquatic resources are captured from a great variety of inland systems,
including perennial lakes,2 which have a combined surface area of about 1.7 million km2,
nearly 1 million km2 of which are accounted for by large lakes (>100 km2). North
America possesses by far the greatest large lake surface. Swamps, marshes and other
wetlands throughout the world amount to about 4 million km2, of which the CIS and the
Baltic states claim the greatest portion.
The world's main channel river lengths amount to about 269 000 km. The highest density
of rivers occurs in South America, the lowest in Oceania (Figure 20).
Fished artificial water bodies range from large hydroelectric reservoirs to multipurpose
community and family ponds, irrigation canals, rice-fields, borrow pits and even roadside
ditches.
Large reservoirs (>15 m dam height) generally date from after the Second World War.
Most are in China, and nearly 65 percent of the global total by number are located in Asia
(Figure 20). In all, there are 60 000 such reservoirs in the world, totalling 400 000 km2 in
water surface and about 6 500 km3 in volume.3 The construction of large dams in the
United States peaked in the 1950s and 1960s,4 while in Africa, where the reservoirs are
comparatively smaller, the peak was reached during the 1970s.5 The trend today is
towards smaller reservoirs. Nevertheless, it is remarkable that reservoir storage has
attained about seven times the standing stock of water contained in rivers.6
In addition to the larger, better-known systems, there are millions of small multipurpose
water bodies around the globe that are not always accounted for. Such systems could
make a greater contribution to food production if they were managed appropriately and in
a way that is compatible with their other uses.
Inland water systems: the aquatic environment
The state of inland fisheries resources is very much reflected by the state of the terrestrial
environment in general and by that of the aquatic environment in particular. There are
two major influences: climatic cycles and human-induced changes.
Climatic cycles, expressed as variations in rainfall, affect inland fisheries resources by
providing more or less living space, more or fewer nutrients via inundation and rainfall
runoff and higher or lower vulnerability to fishing as a result of concentration and
dispersal. For example, about 57 percent of the large inland water body surface in Africa
consists of systems that have quite widely varying surface areas, both seasonally and
interannually. In these systems, the availability of fishery resources for exploitation
varies greatly and the impact on food supply may be very serious in times of drought or
when especially high rainfalls cause extensive flooding.
Similarly, climatic cycles expressed as variations in temperature also affect inland
resources. For example, temperature can be a lethal factor. At sublethal ranges, it controls
metabolic rates. It affects not only the growth rate of fish but also their behaviour.
Temperature changes also trigger fish movements and fish reproduction.
These climatic effects manifest themselves in the amount of fish available for capture.
Therefore, long-term climatic changes, such as those brought on by global warming, are a
concern for the future of inland fisheries resources.
Human-induced changes to inland resources are manifold. In fact, the greatest threat to
the sustainability of inland fisheries resources is not overexploitation, but degradation of
the environment. As mentioned earlier (see State of inland fish resources), the global
situation regarding inland aquatic resources is not encouraging, mainly owing to land and
forest degradation, loss of biodiversity, the scarcity and pollution of freshwater and hence
the degradation and loss of habitats. Another measure of the state of the inland aquatic
environment has been provided by the analysis of the stress exerted in 145 large
watersheds around the world. Their combined land surface area accounts for 55 percent
of the total land surface, not including Antarctica.7 Stresses were found to be especially
severe in watersheds that were already substantially modified or degraded. In particular,
China, India and Southeast Asia stood out as areas where pressures on watersheds are
intensifying. This is a cause of concern, as they are the world's most important areas for
inland fish production. Other major watersheds such as the Amazon and the Congo are
less degraded. Nonetheless, these are also beginning to experience rapid change.
A worldwide study has been carried out on river basins that support a high level of
aquatic biodiversity. The study concluded that 30 of the basins should be managed very
carefully because they have a rich diversity of fish species but are highly vulnerable to
future pressures.8 Of these river basins, 39 percent (by total area) are in Africa, 35 percent
in Asia and 26 percent in Latin America.
Human-induced changes are also reflected in the composition of the inland fish fauna. In
fact, introduced species are relatively important in the capture of freshwater fish. For
example, Nile tilapia and other tilapias are important in Asia, Latin America and Oceania.
In Europe, Latin America and North America, common carp is important. According to
the FAO Database on Introductions of Aquatic Species,9 common carp, rainbow trout,
Mozambique tilapia, grass carp and Nile tilapia are the most frequently recorded
introductions. In the recreational sector, on average, non-native sport fish provided 38
percent of recreational fishery use in the United States.10
In conclusion, it is apparent that most freshwater fish faunas of the world are in serious
decline and in need of immediate protection. Among the heavily fished faunas, fish losses
appear to be highest in: i) industralized countries; ii) in regions with arid or
Mediterranean climates; iii) in tropical regions with large human populations; and iv) in
big rivers.11
EXPLOITATION OF INLAND FISHERIES RESOURCES
Inland fisheries resources are exploited for food and other products - mostly by fishers
earning a living from their activity - and for pleasure by recreational fishers.
Recreational fisheries
The use made of fishery resources by recreational fishers is underreported. Of almost 200
countries and territories approached by FAO, only 30 responded with recreational capture
estimates. These amounted to 476 500 tonnes in 1990.12 Total recreational catch,
however, may be in the order of 2 million tonnes.13 Two examples reported more recently
indicate the importance of recreational fisheries:
•
•
Among 22 European countries, there are an estimated 21.3 million anglers.14
In the United States, 29.9 million anglers paid US$447 million for fishing licences
in 1996.15
Recreational fisheries are not confined only to developed countries. In fact, the promotion
of recreational fishing as a national and international income-generating activity is being
contemplated or is already practised in many developing countries, among them Brazil,
Malaysia and Zimbabwe.
Fisheries for food
In 1996, recorded landings16 - mostly commercial or artisanal - of inland fisheries
resources amounted to 7.6 million tonnes, equal to 7.8 percent of total capture. Landings
consisted mainly of finfish, although molluscs, crustaceans and aquatic reptiles may be
locally important (see Inland capture fisheries production).
The contribution of inland fisheries resources to food production is certainly greater than
that reported because of the dispersed and informal nature of many fisheries. For
example, official Brazilian inland capture fisheries statistics in 1991 reported a
production volume of 193 000 tonnes from all of the country's waters. However, an
independent study commissioned by FAO for the same year suggests a production figure
of about 319 000 tonnes for the Amazon Basin portion of Brazil alone.17 Similar results
have been found for Paraguay. These studies confirm already published FAO estimates
that, for the world as a whole, actual harvests of inland fisheries resources may be at least
twice those reported to FAO.18
In contrast to marine fisheries, in which substantial fisheries are pursued exclusively for
the purpose of providing raw material for animal feeds, inland fishers - whether artisanal
or commercial - target food fish. There are very few discards, as fishing gears are
generally stationary and more selective than those used in marine fisheries and virtually
all the catch is for direct human consumption. This is often - but not always - facilitated
by short distances between the place of capture and the consumer. Thus, disregarding the
obvious underreporting for inland fisheries, inland capture fisheries in 1996 accounted for
nearly 12 percent of the fish provided by all capture fisheries for direct human
consumption.
Species groups and capture by country
Species naturally vary with the region of production. The section Inland capture fisheries
production lists the dominant species produced in Africa, Asia, Europe, the CIS and the
Baltic states, Latin America and North America. As is also mentioned in that section, six
of the top ten producer countries are in Asia, together accounting for about 62 percent of
world inland capture (Figure 21).
THE FUTURE USE OF INLAND FISHERIES RESOURCES
Trends in use
Based on total inland capture for the period 1984-1996, it is clear that increasing use is
being made of inland fisheries resources. The average annual increase is about 130 000
tonnes (about 2 percent per annum).
Asia is by far the most important continent for inland capture fisheries (Figure 22), and it
is here that the largest increase in inland resource use has been occurring. Since 1992, an
average growth rate of more than 8 percent per annum has been recorded. In Africa, the
second most important region, the overall trend is for a very slight annual increase.
In contrast, inland capture is decreasing in the CIS and the Baltic states and in North
America. In the first group of countries, this decline is due to overexploitation (e.g. of
Caspian Sea sturgeon) and loss of habitat (e.g. in the Aral Sea) and is also linked with the
region's political and economic changes that call for new approaches to resource
management. In North America, the declining trend may be indicative of the continued
displacement of commercial fisheries by recreational fishing. The recent trend for Europe
is for an increase, while South America and Oceania have been fairly stable over the long
term.
An FAO study19 was undertaken recently to characterize inland fishery enhancements by
type and species in Africa, Asia and the Pacific and Latin America. Preliminary results of
the study suggest that stocking and introductions are by far the most important
enhancements being employed and that the most frequent objective is to produce food
and income. Although incomplete, data submitted to FAO show that, over the period
1984-1995, the highest numbers of world stocks were for coregonids, salmonids and the
common carp.
Extent and intensity of use
The shares of inland capture production by continent do not relate closely to the relative
amounts of land and water present in the same continents (Figure 8). For example, Asia
produces nearly 65 percent of inland capture but has only a 20 percent share of the total
continental area; a 23 percent share of swamps, marshes and other wetlands; a 7 percent
share of lake area; and an intermediate index of river density. However, it does have a
relatively large number of reservoirs (Figure 20).
A variety of factors are responsible for Asia's disproportionate share of inland capture;
however, much is due to the heavy exploitation of virtually all the available water surface
and the widespread use of fishery enhancements, mainly stocking, to increase food
fishery yields. A large part of the water surface in North America and the CIS and the
Baltic states is in cooler regions. Furthermore, in contrast to Asia, inland fisheries
resources in much of North America and Europe are managed to produce game fish, not
food fish. Other differences can be explained by cultural attitudes towards inland fish.
For example, in South America only a relatively few species of large-sized inland fish are
appreciated on urban markets.
Trends in inland fisheries management
There are a number of clear trends that will affect the exploitation of inland fisheries
resources in the medium term, including the following:
•
•
•
•
•
an increasing use of enhancements, mainly stocking, to improve yields;
increasing attention to environmental impacts on fisheries and to the impacts of
fishery enhancement on biodiversity;
the increasing importance of recreational fisheries and of conflicts over the
allocation of resources between food and sport;
increasing community-level responsibility
for management in general and control of access in particular;
an increasing awareness of the value of inland fisheries resources and the need for
fisheries to be included in cost-benefit analyses of multiple uses of water
resources.
FISHERS AND FISHING FLEETS20
EMPLOYMENT IN THE FISHING AND AQUACULTURE INDUSTRIES
During the past three decades at least, employment in fishing and aquaculture worldwide
has grown faster than employment in agriculture. At the same time, the share of
agriculture in employment is generally declining: in terms of their share in the
economically active population, those employed in agriculture accounted for 67 percent
in 1950, 56 percent in 1970 and 49 percent in 1990.21 However, employment in fishing
and aquaculture has accounted for an increasing share of the employment in the
agricultural sector22 as a whole. In 1970, fishing and aquaculture accounted for 1.5
percent of those employed in the agricultural sector. In 1990, the 28.6 million people who
found employment in capture fisheries and aquaculture accounted for about 2.3 percent
of all of those earning a living in the agricultural sector.
In many parts of the world, fishing is a seasonal or part-time occupation, peaking in the
months of the year when coastal and offshore resources are more abundant or available,
but leaving time for other activities in seasonal lows. For this reason, when reporting on
employment in the fishing industry, FAO distinguishes between full-time and part-time
fishers. 23
In the 20 years from 1970 to 1990, the number of full-time fishers and aquaculturists
grew faster than the world's population, and the number of part-time fishers grew even
faster (Table 5). As a result, numbering 11.8 million, full-time fishers accounted for 41
percent of all fishers in 1990, down from 51 percent in 1970.
TABLE 5
Number of fishers and aquaculturists in the world
Category of
fisher/aquaculturist
Full-time fishers
Index
Part-time fishers
Index
Other fishers1
Index
Total
Index
1970
1980
1990
6 108
100
3 659
100
2 639
100
12 406
100
(thousands)
7 988
131
4 784
131
3 792
143
16 564
134
11 896
195
9 708
268
6 977
264
28 511
230
1
Occasional fishers and aquaculturists as well as fishers whose occupation has not been
further specified.
It is worth noting that, for all categories of fishers, the increase in numbers was much
more rapid during the 1980s than during the 1970s. The reasons for this are not clear. In
part, it may simply reflect a view that the oceans were one of the few natural resources
that had not yet been fully exploited as a source of food and employment. Therefore, a
prime concern in many parts of the world at the time was increased production, not the
control of existing fishing capacity. Although the employment data for the period 19901995 are incomplete, the data that are available indicate a slower increase in the numbers
of fishers. FAO estimates the number of fishers and aquaculturists in 1997 to have been
about 30 million.
Closely reflecting the distribution pattern of the world's population, 84 percent of fishers
and aquaculturists in 1990 were active in Asia (Figure 23), and the vast majority of them
in China. However, India, Indonesia and Viet Nam also reported more than 1 million fulltime fishers in 1990.24
While the number of people employed in fishing and aquaculture has been growing
steadily in most low- and middle-income countries, in industrialized economies the
numbers of fishers have been declining or are stationary. In Japan and Norway the
numbers of fishers were halved between 1970 and 1990.
Although employment cannot be taken as the sole indication of the importance of
fisheries to the national economy, it is noteworthy that, in 1990, fishers represented more
than 5 percent of the economically active population in the agricultural sector of 38
countries, in 15 of which the percentage was above 10 percent.
Between 1970 and 1990, the number of fishers expanded faster in Asia than anywhere
else. In 1970, Asian fishers accounted for 77 percent of the world total; in 1990 they
accounted for 83 percent. During the same period in Africa, where artisanal fisheries still
dominate, the number of fishers also grew but at a slower rate than in Asia. African
fisheries accounted for some 6.5 percent of the world total in 1990. South American
fishers accounted for about 3 percent of the world total throughout the period whereas, in
Europe, there were more fishers in 1970 than in 1990. In the last year they accounted for
only 1.4 percent of the world total. However, the number of European fishers increased in
absolute terms between 1980 and 1990 owing to the emerging aquaculture industry. In
Oceania, the numbers of commercial fishers are considerably fewer than 1 percent of the
world total. On the other hand in the smaller islands they often account for a significant
part of the economically active population.
It is also worth noting that the number of part-time fishers has grown more rapidly than
the number of full-time fishers for the world as a whole: in 1990, for every ten full-time
fishers, there were nine part-time fishers. Twenty years earlier, the relationship had been
six part-time to ten full-time fishers.
However, this is largely an Asian phenomenon. For the rest of the world, the increase in
part-time fishers between 1970 and 1990 was relatively small. The data for Asia support
the view that fisheries may indeed have been an occupation of last resort during this
period.
The rapid increase in the number of fishers in Asia, together with the growing proportion
of part-time workers, also explains to some extent why the average productivity per fisher
(all categories) in terms of total production volume declined from just above 2 tonnes per
year in 1970 to less than 2 tonnes in 1990 (Table 6).
TABLE 6
Average fish production per person employed in fisheries and
aquaculture
Continent
1970
Africa
Asia
North America
Latin America
Europe
Oceania
Global total
2.71
2.23
11.59
28.47
26.61
4.42
4.97
1980
(tonnes per year)
2.72
2.28
12.69
15.19
33.59
1.86
4.36
1990
2.76
1.90
11.35
18.40
29.35
5.20
3.47
It would seem that the global economic growth during the 1970s and the 1980s did not
result in the increased productivity of those employed in fisheries and aquaculture.
Average physical productivity declined from nearly 5 tonnes per caput per year in 1970
to about 3.5 tonnes in 1990. This relatively large fluctuation is mainly explained by the
decline in the average productivity per fisher and aquaculturist in Asia. However, the
situation in Asia is complex. The downward trend there is a result of diminishing yields
for capture fishers, the growing share of part-time fishers and an expansion of
aquaculture production and employment. The diminution for the rest of the world, which
has been less pronounced, is largely the result of a drastic drop in the availability and
catch of small pelagic species, and hence it affects a relatively small number of fishers.
Among countries in Asia, there are of course wide variations in fishery labour
productivity, partly as a consequence of differences in the amount of capital available to
each fisher. There are highly industrialized and often capital-intensive fisheries in the
region, particularly in Japan and the Republic of Korea, resulting in a high tonnage per
person employed. There are also fisheries that produce less than 1 tonne per fisher per
year.
Among the continents, Europe shows the highest productivity, recording a higher rate
than Japan in volume terms. However, there are also noticeable differences across
Europe. For instance, in 1995 each of Iceland's 5 000 fishers produced an average of 280
tonnes of fish, whereas an annual rate of 6 tonnes or less per fisher is true for the fishers
of all Mediterranean countries other than France and Italy.25 Part of this difference is
explained by the importance of high-volume, low-value fisheries for small pelagics that
provide raw material for fishmeal industries in Iceland.
THE WORLD FISHING FLEET
In 1995 the world fishing fleet numbered about 3.8 million vessels. About one-third of
these were decked26 vessels, the remaining two-thirds were undecked vessels, generally
less than 10 m in length. While almost all decked vessels are motorized, only about one
undecked vessel in three is equipped with an engine.
Most of the world's fishing vessels are operating in Asia. The proportion of nonmotorized vessels is higher in Africa (about 80 percent) than in any other continent, while
Europe has the highest proportion of decked vessels (about 70 percent in 1995). In the
Asian fleet, slightly fewer than 40 percent are reported to be decked vessels.
The average size of decked vessels in 1995 was about 20 GT. Those larger than 100 GT
(or longer than 24 m) amounted to about 37 000 or just about 1 percent of the world
fishing fleet. China has approximately 40 percent (15 000) of these vessels, while no
other country has more than 10 percent of this fleet and about 20 countries together
account for 50 percent of the total.
The world fleet is not likely to have grown as fast as the number of fishers (Figure 24),
although this cannot be established with certainty because the various employment
categories used for reporting statistics include both capture fishers and aquaculturists.
Nevertheless, there has been an upgrading of the fleet inasmuch as the proportion of
decked vessels increased from about one in four in 1970 to about one in three in 1990.
Undecked fishing vessels
The number of undecked vessels increased in the 1980s, mainly as a result of higher
numbers in Asia. However, this increase was followed by a levelling off (Figure 25)
during the first part of the 1990s.
The vast majority of undecked fishing craft in Asia and Africa are not powered by
engines (Figure 26). Given that decked craft are relatively few in Africa, the typical
African fishing vessel is undecked and non-motorized. In Asia, the typical vessel is
different, as the proportion of decked fishing craft is comparatively high.
Decked fishing vessels
Following two decades of rapid growth, particularly in Asia (Figure 15), growth in the
number of decked fishing vessels has been slow since 1990. In fact, had it not been for
the increase in the fleet of decked fishing vessels in China (Figure 16), the number of
decked fishing vessels in the world fleet would have remained stable between 1980 and
1995.
Instead, there is some evidence of an increase in terms of average tonnage of vessels
since 1990 (Figure 27), although it is not certain whether this increase is real. It may be
the result of reporting vessel size in GT instead of GRT. This change in the system of
measuring vessel size inflates the tonnage estimate, as the resulting numeric estimate of
size almost invariably is higher when stated in GT. Therefore, the increase in tonnage of
the fleet resulting from this reclassifiction of vessels does not necessarily reflect an
increase in the fishing capacity of the same fleet (see Box 3).
In line with the Chinese policy to develop offshore and distant-water fisheries, the
average tonnage of decked Chinese vessels has increased. In fact, the proportion of
Chinese vessels of more than 24 m in length increased from about 1.5 percent in the late
1980s to about 3 percent in 1996, which is three times the world average. China's fishing
fleet, totalling about 6 million GT (in 1996), is now by far the largest in the world. It is
followed by the fleet of the Russian Federation, with a tonnage of about 3 million GT.
Gillnetters and vessels fishing with lines account for a considerable proportion of the
world fleet of decked vessels (Figure 28). Trawlers tend to be larger and more powerful
vessels and they dominate in terms of tonnage, accounting for about 40 percent of the GT
of the fleet (Figure 29).
DECKED FISHING VESSELS ABOVE 100 GRT
The global fleet
Vessels of 100 GRT or more are approximately equivalent to vessels of 24 m or more in
length. They are generally capable of fishing on the high seas but it is estimated that at
least half of this fleet never does so. Detailed information on individual vessels in this
category is maintained by Lloyd's Maritime Information Services (LMIS), which obtains
data under exclusive licence from Lloyd's Register of Shipping.
In 1997, fishing vessels in Lloyd's Register of Shipping numbered 22 668. However,
LMIS databases contain virtually no information on vessels registered in China, the
Democratic People's Republic of Korea or Taiwan Province of China. For the remaining
countries, they record about 80 percent of the number of vessels reported to FAO by
member countries.
Mainland China reported 15 000 vessels in this category in 1996. Thus, the fishing
vessels in this category are likely to have numbered between 43 000 and 45 000 in 1997.
The fleet reported in Lloyd's Register
Eight states had 500 or more fishing vessels constituting 65 percent of the fleet. The
remaining 35 percent of the fleet was shared by 164 other flag states (Figure 30) in 1997.
More than half were trawlers of various types, about 10 percent were seiners and the rest
were line and trap fishing vessels (Figure 31).
The conventional wisdom is that the average tonnage and horsepower (HP) of the world
fleet of large vessels are increasing. However, an analysis of the fleet of vessels above
100 tons by their date of construction does not support this hypothesis (Figures 32 and
33). In fact, the average tonnage of vessels built during the last three years has been
below the 30-year average (621 GRT). In terms of horsepower, the last three-year
average is 1 265 HP compared with the 30-year average of 1 151 HP, a mere 9 percent
increase.
The world fleet of vessels of 100 GRT or more, as recorded by LMIS, grew until 1991
and has declined since then (Figure 34). This is probably representative of the world
industrial fishing fleet, with the notable exception of China whose fleet has grown
steadily during the same period.
The overall decline has been brought about by a slowdown in construction as well as by
the ageing of the fleet, which results in a growing number of vessels being denied
certificates of seaworthiness and consequently having to cease fishing activities.
Construction. As reported in Part 1, Numbers of fishers and fishing vessels, LMIS
databases indicate a long-term slowdown in the building rate for vessels of more than 100
GRT. Only 155 vessels were reported to have been built in 1997, although this is a
provisional estimate and the final number is likely to be nearer to 200.
With respect to new fishing vessels, more than 50 percent of the 155 constructions in
1997 were reported from four countries - Japan (28), Spain (23), Peru (20) and Chile
(10). It is worth noting that Japan and Spain both reduced their fleets during this period,
reflecting active restructuring policies that include the replacement of their existing fleets.
The new vessels built for Peru and Chile were mainly purse seiners built to replace a
rapidly ageing fleet. Purse seiners, beam trawlers and shrimp trawlers formed a
disproportionately high percentage of the new constructions relative to their numbers in
the existing fleet, which would indicate that the fisheries using these vessel types are
expected to remain - or become - more financially viable than other fisheries.
Decommissioning and losses. As a rough estimate, vessels removed from Lloyd's
Register of Shipping before they are 20 years old are likely to have been lost at sea,
whereas vessels older than 20 years have probably been scrapped if they are no longer
listed. Figure 35 shows that vessels tend to be removed from the database owing to
scrapping at just under 30 years, although there are about 1 266 vessels in the register that
were built before 1960. A large part of these have wooden hulls, which are easier to keep
up to safety standards than steel hulls of older vessels. Vessels removed from the register
- whether lost at sea or scrapped - amount to more than 5 percent of the vessels in the
total fleet.
This suggests that, in order to take losses into account, the overall expected life cycle of a
vessel has been about 20 years. Countries aiming to maintain stable fleets in terms of
numbers will need to replace, on the average, 5 percent of their fleet every year.
CHANGES IN THE FLEETS OF MAJOR FISHING COUNTRIES
In 1997 there were four countries with more than 1 000 vessels reported in Lloyd's
Register: Japan, the Republic of Korea, Spain and the United States. The countries of the
CIS and the Baltic states, when taken together,27 also fall into this category (Figure 36).
The increase in the Republic of Korea's fleet since 1994 is believed to be due to vessels
that were previously flagged under open registers being reflagged under their national
flag.
Contrary to the development of these five fleets, those of some major fish producers
among the developing countries have been expanding. This is true for several countries in
Latin America, for India, Indonesia, Morocco and the Philippines (Figure 37). In many
cases, a substantial part of the buildup has been due to older vessels being bought from
developed countries.
Several European countries had fleets of between 100 and 600 vessels above 100 GRT in
1997. In many cases, these European fleets have shown a substantial decrease as a result
of the EC's decommissioning policies (Figure 38). The United Kingdom's fleet was also
augmented by vessels owned in Spain and the Netherlands being reflagged to the United
Kingdom as part of the so-called "quota hopping" exercise.
The fleets of the main Latin American fishing countries continued to increase, with
Mexico being the main exception (Figure 39).
The number of vessels flagged under open registers or "flags of convenience" has
continued to increase, albeit at a slower rate than in the early 1990s. Although the number
of fishing vessels registered in Panama and Honduras has decreased, there has been a
continued increase in registrations in Belize (158 in 1997), Cyprus (32), St Vincent and
the Grenadines (139) and Vanuatu (35). Of the fishing vessels built in 1997, only three
were entered in an open register.
Possible developments in the world fleet of vessels above 100 GRT
The future size of the world fishing fleet of vessels above 100 GRT will be determined by
the rates of decommissioning, losses and construction of new vessels.
Decommissioning and losses. Figure 40 shows the age structure of the present fleet of
fishing vessels above 100 GRT in Lloyd's Register of Shipping. Thus, in 1997, the
databases recorded 11 675 vessels that were more than 20 years old, most of which can
be expected to be scrapped in the next ten years, while a smaller number will be lost at
sea (about 200 per year).
Construction. It is more difficult to estimate future rates of construction. There will of
course be a tendency to replace old ships, which will be strengthened or weakened
depending on the investors' view of the state and prospects of the fishery concerned. The
history of the Peruvian fleet illustrates this situation, with the peaks in additions to this
fleet (Figure 41) clearly being linked to the availability of fish stocks (Figure 42),
especially anchoveta, and the need to replace a rapidly ageing fleet over the last few
years.
The future
Will large vessels be replaced with other large vessels? Are large vessels in fact needed,
or are those used for fishing at present simply a legacy of the pre-UNCLOS era?
Certainly, in the foreseeable future, high seas tuna fishing will be conducted from vessels
of 100 GT or more. Likewise, in the case of fisheries stocking small pelagics, fishing
activities conducted inside the EEZs will be carried out using large vessels. Fisheries that
are situated far from processing facilities will also need very large vessels.
On the other hand, some of the fisheries off the coasts of Africa that are currently
exploited as part of distant-water fishing activities could also be fished from Africa itself,
thereby allowing the use of smaller vessels. In some parts of West Africa, however, the
absence of port facilities, including shore infrastructure for servicing fishing vessels, is a
constraint to the introduction of semi-industrial fleets (comprising vessels of about 100
GRT or a little smaller). Since the construction of port facilities and associated
infrastructure is a drawn-out process, it is probable that relatively large vessels (i.e. above
100 GRT) will continue to be in use for some time.
In many fisheries - particulary in those of developing countries - the cost involved in
replacing old vessels is such that there will be a tendency either to use smaller vessels or
to continue to buy second-hand larger vessels. However, given the disappearance of
wood as a building material for the hulls of these larger vessels, together with the annual
loss of at least 1 800 to 2 000 steel-hulled vessels by scrapping,28 the supply of secondhand vessels of 100 GRT or more will be small.
An extrapolation of all the present trends (decomissioning, losses and construction) to the
present fleet of between 43 000 and 45 000 vessels suggests that, in ten years' time, the
world fleet of fishing vessels above 100 GRT will number about 27 000 craft. That
implies a reduction of about 40 percent, which is unlikely to eventuate. In reality, the
number will most probably drop to somewhere between 27 000 and the present level.
1
Main contributor: J.M. Kapetsky, FAO Fisheries Department.
FAO. 1998. Geography and constraints on inland fishery enhancements. By J.M.
Kapetsky. In T. Petr, ed. Inland fishery enhancements, p. 37-64. FAO Fisheries Technical
Paper No. 374. Rome.
3
A.B. Avakyan and V.B. Lakovleva. 1998. Status of global reservoirs: the position in the
late twentieth century. Lakes and Reservoirs: Research and Mangement, 3: 45-52.
4
M. Collier, R. Webb and J. Schmidt. 1996. Dams and rivers. A primer on the
downstream effects of dams. United States Geological Survey. Circular No. 1126.
5
Kapetsky, op. cit., footnote 2.
6
C. Vorosmarty, K.P. Sharma, B.M. Fekete, A.H. Copeland, J. Holden, J. Marble and
J.A. Lough. 1997. The storage and aging of continental runoff in large reservoir systems
of the world. Ambio, 26(4): 210-219.
7
C. Ravenga, S. Murray, J. Abramovitz and A. Hammond. 1998. Watersheds of the
world. Ecological value and vulnerability. A joint publication of the World Resources
Institute and the Worldwatch Institute, Washington, DC.
8
World Conservation Monitoring Centre. 1998. Freshwater biodiversity: a preliminary
global assessment (Draft only).
9
See also D.M. Bartley, L. Garibaldi and R.L. Welcomme. 1997. Introductions of
Aquatic Organisms: a global perspective and database. Paper presented at the American
Fisheries Society Symposium on Impacts, Threats and Control of Introduced Species in
Coastal Waters, Monterey, California, USA, 28 August 1997.
10
Horak, D. 1995. Native and nonnative fish species used in state fisheries management
programs in the United States. American Fisheries Society Symposium, 15: 61-67.
11
R.A. Leidy and P.B. Moyle. 1998. Conservation status of the world's fish fauna: an
overview. In P.L. Fiedler and P.M. Kareiva, eds. Conservation biology, 2nd ed., p. 187227. New York, Chapman and Hall.
12
FAO. 1992. Coordinating Working Party on Atlantic Fishery Statistics. Recreational
fisheries. CWP-15/10. 6 pp. Cited in the Report of the Fifteenth Session of the
Coordinating Working Party on Atlantic Fishery Statistics. FAO Fisheries Report No.
473. Rome.
13
D. Coates. 1995. Inland capture fisheries and enhancement: status, constraints and
prospects for food security. Paper presented at the Government of Japan/FAO
International Conference on Sustainable Contribution of Fisheries to Food Security,
Kyoto, Japan, 4-9 December 1995. C/FI/95/TECH/3. Rome, FAO. 82 pp.
14
P. Hickley and H. Tompkins, eds. 1998. Recreational fisheries. Social, economic and
management aspects, Table 1.1, chap. 1. Oxford, UK, Fishing News Books. 310 pp.
15
BRIEFS, 26(5): 5 (Newsletter of the American Institute of Fishery Research
Biologists).
16
Only about 100 fish species or species groups are listed in FAO statistics on inland
capture. Therefore, most species are not identified in FAO production statistics and about
45 percent of the inland catch is reported as unspecified freshwater fish, 7 percent as
unspecified freshwater molluscs and 6 percent as unspecified crustaceans.
17
FAO/World Bank Cooperative Programme in collaboration with the Fisheries
Department. 1998. Fisheries and aquatic biodiversity management in the Amazon. Desk
Study. Report No. 98/055 CP-RLC. 2 September 1998. 55 pp.
18
Coates, op. cit., footnote 13.
2
19
B. Born. An overview of inland fishery enhancements from a global perspective. FAO.
(in preparation)
20
Main contributors: A. Crispoldi, R. Grainger and A. Smith, FAO Fisheries Department.
21
Source: ILO. Economically active population, 1950-2010, 4th ed., December 1996. (on
diskette)
22
The agricultural sector is referred to here in the broad sense, i.e. including fisheries and
forestry.
23
Those deriving at least 90 percent of their income from fishing or aquaculture are
classed as full-time fishers, whereas those deriving between 30 and 89 percent of their
income from fishing or aquaculture are classed as part-time fishers. Readers should be
aware that the data provided to FAO often do not meet the required specifications.
Overall, trends appear to be more reliable than the absolute data.
24
For details see FAO. 1997. Numbers of fishers. FAO Fisheries Circular No. 929. Rome.
25
FAO. 1997. Les pêches en Méditerranée: éléments d'information sur le contexte
halieutique et les enjeux économiques de leur aménagement. By C. Breuil. FAO Fisheries
Circular No. 927. Rome.
26
A decked vessel is one with a fixed structural deck covering the entire hull above the
deepest operating waterline.
27
Data are aggregated in order to permit comparisons with the situation in the 1980s.
28
This calculation is based on an extrapolation from the fleet reported in Lloyd's Register
of Shipping to the fleet as a whole.
PART 4
Outlook: expected trends in supply and
demand
OVERVIEW1
SHORT-TERM OUTLOOK
The slowdown in the growth of fish supplies that started in 1997-1998 is likely to
continue for a few years. The main reasons for this are the stable or decreased landings
from marine capture fisheries and a slower rate of growth in aquaculture production than
that recorded for the early 1990s. The negative impact of El Niño on capture fish
production was already evident in 1997. In 1998, landings are likely to have declined
even further, and production is expected to take some time to recover. Supplies particularly those from aquaculture - will be affected by a drop in demand over the next
two to four years, particularly in Japan and in other Asian economies. The production of
high-value aquaculture products will stagnate, as will international trade in those
products.
MEDIUM-TERM OUTLOOK
The State of World Fisheries and Agriculture 1996 predicted increasing real prices for
fish2 over the next 15 years. This projection was based on exploratory calculations of
supply and demand for fish in the year 2010, using data from 1992.
A review of these projections in 1998 shows that the pressure for increased real prices for
fish in the coming decade is decreasing. It seems clear that demand will not grow as
rapidly as foreseen in mid-1995, while supply has been increasing more rapidly than
expected and, after a few years of relative stagnation, may resume growth in the early
years of 2000-2010. The slowdown in demand is due to a slower population growth rate
than that predicted, projections of slower economic growth and, possibly, the increased
competitiveness of poultry and pork.
Supply projections for fish have improved mainly on the strength of the continued and
rapid expansion of aquaculture production but also because improved capture fisheries
management means there is less likely to be a decline in capture fisheries production.
GLOBAL FOOD SUPPLIES AND FISH
The growth rate of world agricultural production is slowing down. From an anuual rate of
about 3 percent in the 1960s, it dropped to about 1.6 percent during the decade 19861995 (mainly because of the drastic production decline in countries formerly comprising
the USSR) and is expected to be in the order of 1.8 percent for the period 1990-2010.
Furthermore, since the 1950s, the average real price of agricultural products has declined
globally.
A different situation is true for the fisheries sector, as both production and real prices
have increased over the past three decades. Production increased at a compound rate of
3.4 percent per year in the period 1960-1990, and this growth rate has been maintained
over the past decade. During the last 15 years, this growth has essentially been a result of
the rapid increase in aquaculture output, which recorded an annual increase of 11.8
percent in the period 1984-1996. Although information on prices is weak, indications are
that prices have increased somewhat in real terms. This has occurred in parallel with a
slow increase in per caput supplies, supporting the idea that fish generally falls into the
category of preferred food items along with other livestock products, in particular poultry
and pork.
Thirty to 40 years ago, developing countries as a group were significant net exporters of
food. The situation has since changed and, by early next century, developing countries as
a group can be expected to become net importers of food. For the poorest of these
countries - most of which are found in sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia - the financing
of food imports will be a high priority, and capture fisheries and aquaculture will come
under strong pressure to provide exportable products.
DEMAND FOR FISH AND FISHERY PRODUCTS
The future demand for fish will basically be determined by the number of consumers and
their eating habits and disposable income as well as by prices of fish.
DISPOSABLE INCOME
The economic and financial crisis that has engulfed Asia and is also being felt in other
parts of the world has led to a downward revision of economic growth projections for
most Asian countries as well as for a growing number of countries elsewhere. In fact,
some of the larger Asian economies are expected to contract over the next two to three
years. An unavoidable consequence in the immediate future will be a reduction in the
demand for fish in Japan and in emerging Asian economies, and fish exports to the latter
will most probably decrease in volume. At the same time, the fisheries sectors of
developed Asian economies will face increasingly stiff competition from developing
economies whose currencies have undergone devaluations.
In Africa and Latin America, too, consumers will experience stagnation and, in some
cases, a decline in their disposable income. This will reduce demand for fish and fishery
products. However, the decline will be small in absolute terms, as consumption is
relatively modest at present. Consumption in North America is sensitive to economic
growth and, even with a degree of growth in disposable income, there may be room for
some expansion in the immediate future - at least in quantity terms. European demand
will not change much under the predicted slow economic growth scenario.
Projections of demand made by FAO in 1995 for the year 2010 assumed that economic
growth would have only a slight influence on the per caput consumption of fish in Africa,
Europe, Latin America and Oceania; in Africa because of slow - or zero - per caput
growth, and elsewhere because changes in income were not seen to have a major
influence on demand. For Asia and North America, the assumptions were different. The
average per caput consumption had been projected to grow considerably owing to
expected growth in disposable income. By late 1998, there was still no global consensus
on when the economic fortunes of Asia would improve. However, for the purpose of
developing a supply and demand scenario for the year 2010, it is assumed that growth
will resume early in the next decade.
DEMAND
In the first few years of the next century, the demand for fish in Europe and North
America is likely to shift downwards as competing livestock products - particularly
poultry and pork - become significantly cheaper. This is expected to come about as a
consequence of projected modifications to the European Community's (EC) Common
Agricultural Policy (CAP). The modifications are aimed, inter alia, at reducing grain
prices and subsequent livestock production costs. Given that poultry and, in some areas,
pork are preferred food products, it seems likely that consumers in Europe and North
America will eat less fish than they would have done in the absence of a modified CAP.
This shift in consumer demand will occur gradually after the year 2000.
NUMBERS OF CONSUMERS
In October 1996, the UN projected that the world's population in the year 2010 would be
about 140 million (i.e. 2 percent) less than it had predicted two years earlier. This
downward revision is the consequence of lower population growth rates, particularly for
Asia which accounts for a reduction of about 100 million in the revised projections. In
brief, the effect of a slower population growth in the short term will be a decline in
demand for high-priced aquatic products, although some of this demand may be shifted to
lower-priced fish products.
It also seems prudent to revise downwards the medium-term projections of world demand
for food fish. Based on a scenario of modest reductions in the per caput demand in
Europe (down by 6 percent compared with 1995), North America (-4 percent) and Asia (8 percent), and incorporating the effect of a smaller population, the demand for food fish
in 2010 may be 105 million to 110 million tonnes (live weight equivalent), whereas
FAO's 1995 prediction was 110 million to 120 million tonnes.
SUPPLY OF FISH AND FISHERY PRODUCTS
AQUACULTURE
The supply of cultured finfish, crustaceans and molluscs has continued to expand rapidly,
and growth has been much faster than was envisaged only a few years ago (Figure 43).
Asia continues to dominate production, with its growing share in total world output
reaching 55 percent (in volume terms) in 1996, up from 51 percent in 1994. Within Asia,
China is by far the largest producer; in volume terms, its finfish production accounted for
a major share of the world total. Almost all of China's production is for domestic
consumption, however. In terms of export revenue, the culture of penaeid shrimps is the
most important aquaculture activity in Asia, with shrimps accounting for 26 percent of
the value of the region's fish exports in 1996.3
Chinese aquaculture production started to increase rapidly in the mid-1980s in response
to very precise policy measures intended to stimulate production. Households were given
the authority to manage their own aquaculture activities, prices for high-value
aquaculture species were freed and the government supported farmers through research
and extension. It is generally believed that production will continue to increase, although
in some parts of the country it will change in nature as farmers attempt to generate more
value-added products from their plants - possibly by selecting more expensive species. In
the northern and inner parts of China, production will probably increase mainly through
the expansion of carp culture.
There are several reasons why Chinese aquaculture should be able to withstand the
present slowdown in the world economy. First, since consumption is predominantly
domestic, exports play a relatively small role and hence the sector is little affected by
world market forces. Furthermore, consumption patterns observed during the recent
period of economic growth indicate that fish (and livestock) products are strongly
preferred food items. Technologically, Chinese aquaculture activities are self-reliant and
use few imported inputs. Although the country has become a major importer of fishmeal,
a share of which is used in aquaculture, access to imported fishmeal is not likely to be an
obstacle for the bulk of Chinese aquaculture in the medium term. It is most likely,
therefore, that Chinese aquaculture production will continue to grow in volume and that
the culture of higher-priced marine products will also develop.
Carp
Culture provides more than 90 percent of the world's carp supplies and carp account for
about 14 percent of all finfish produced by both culture and capture fisheries. China
produces more than four-fifths of this amount. In China, as is the case elsewhere, carp is
consumed locally. With a few exceptions, producers of Chinese and major Indian carps
have been unable to find markets outside Asia. In fact, carps as a group are not traded
globally to the same extent as shrimps and salmon.
Carp culture in China, but also in India and countries of the CIS, will probably continue
to increase steadily - at least in the near future - in response to population growth. In the
long term, a substantial increase in the culture of Chinese and major Indian carps will
depend on the development of carp products for which there is a demand in world
markets.
Tilapia
Among the finfish produced in aquaculture, tilapias seem to be assured a future owing to
their specific production characteristics. First, there are several different culture
technologies available for these species, some of which permit farmers to produce tilapia
at a relatively low cost. Second, the flesh of tilapia is generally white and can be used to
produce white fish fillets, one of the basic products in the international fish trade. Third,
tilapia has spread outside Africa and is common in Asia, Latin America and the
Caribbean.
Tilapia has an established and rapidly expanding market in the United States and is also
being sold in Japan and in European countries. World cultured production has risen
steadily (at an average annual rate of 12 percent4) for the past 12 years (Figure 44). The
expansion of tilapia production can be expected to continue for the following reasons:
•
tilapia can be produced by most developing countries with tropical or semitropical climates, without reliance on imported inputs;
•
•
•
•
•
several developing country producers have become more competitive in the
course of 1998 as their currencies have lost value relative to those of Japan, the
United States and European countries - a development that is not likely to be
reversed in the coming decade;
tilapia has the most potential to replace marine fish in some white fish products;
as long as precautions are taken to preserve biological diversity where possible,
there need not be significant environmental externalities or costs associated with
the culture of tilapia;
tilapia species can be farmed in various aquatic environments using a number of
different technologies;
selective breeding is already showing positive results.
These arguments apply not only to the present major tilapia producers in Asia but also to
prospective producers in Africa, where production may expand rapidly if conducive
macroeconomic environments prevail. Furthermore, both developed and developing
economies will provide markets for tilapia and its products. In 1996, tilapia accounted for
about 5 percent of all cultured finfish; this share is very likely to increase significantly
over the next ten years.
Salmonids
The culture of salmon and trout is mostly carried out in Europe and in the Americas. The
volume of cultured salmons and trout is now catching up with landings of these fish in
capture fisheries, although the rate of expansion in farmed production is slowing down.
The industry is advanced, both technologically and commercially, and in many countries
is making systematic efforts to open new markets and stimulate further demand in
existing ones. Production costs are likely to be further reduced and the industry is also
likely to develop different products for new markets. Consequently, there is likely to be a
continued expansion of production.
Shrimps
Shrimps are an important source of income and hard currency in many developing
economies; they are less significant as a source of food. The total volume of cultured
penaeid shrimps is now close to half that produced by capture fishers. In volume terms,
the increase in production is tapering off in Asia and Latin America, while production in
Africa - although still small - is expanding fast.
There are, however, reasons to believe that growth in the immediate future will slow
down significantly and might even come to a halt. The main reason is the short-term
prospect of no economic growth occurring in Japan, the world's largest market for
shrimps, as well as the slow economic growth expected in the other developed
economies. In addition, management of shrimp culture is not at a uniformly high level.
Production from areas that have recovered from disease is invariably offset by losses
resulting from disease problems affecting other areas - a pattern that is not likely to
change for some time. Furthermore, the emergence of stringent environmental regulations
will slow down the expansion of shrimp culture, although production should recover and
output should start to expand significantly early in the period 2000-2010.
Molluscs
Mollusc culture is almost always destined for sale, and culture for household needs is
very rare. A large part of molluscs are sold to markets located near to the place of
production. However, some producers such as Canada, New Zealand and Spain depend
on international markets, and international trade in mollusc products is in fact growing.
Nevertheless, for mollusc culture - as is also true for carp culture - the economic
conditions within the producer country are an important factor. On the whole, it seems
that mollusc culture in Asia will not be affected much by the present economic downturn
and will continue as a source of growth in aquaculture production.
Conclusion
In the near future, the present economic crisis will probably curb the rate of growth in
aquaculture worldwide. This is in line with already established trends - excluding those
relating to China. Asian production will grow moderately for products consumed in
internal markets, which absorb the bulk of the output volume. The projected stagnation and even decline - of certain aquaculture products that are traditionally exported to
developed economies will effect the value of global aquaculture production much more
than its volume.
Judging from the situation at the end of 1998, aquaculture seems more than likely to
show sustained growth in the medium term. In the light of previous studies5 and recent
trends, it seems quite probable that total world aquaculture production will have reached
between 35 million and 40 million tonnes of finfish, crustaceans and molluscs in the year
2010.
CAPTURE FISHERIES
Global capture fisheries production in 1996 was slightly greater (+1.6 million tonnes)
than in 1995. The preliminary estimates for 1997 are for a contraction of about 0.9
million tonnes (Table 1), mainly owing to the decline in stocks of small pelagic species
off the west coast of South America (see Box 15, El Niño: the consequences for
fisheries). Between 3 and 5 percent of the reduction in global landings by marine capture
fishers can be attributed to the El Niño phenomenon.
BOX 15
El Niño: the consequences for fisheries
The El Niño phenomenon of 1997-1998 is considered to be the second
strongest "warm event" in the tropical and subtropical Pacific Ocean
this century. At the time of its maximum strength, it was not as strong
as the 1982-1983 event, but it lasted a little longer and had two peaks
of maximum warming - one almost immediately after its onset, during
May-September 1997, and another in January-April 1998. It was
preceded by a cold episode in the Eastern Pacific, lasting from the end
of 1995 to the beginning of 1997. To some extent, this turnaround
from a cold to a warm episode might have magnified the negative
impacts that this latest El Niño has had on certain fish resources.
From the point of view of fisheries, the Eastern Pacific, and
particularly the area off western South America, is the area that is most
negatively affected by El Niño warming events, and this case was no
exception. Rising coastal sea temperatures and a weakening of the
upwelling enrichment process caused a severe decline in biomass and
total production of small schooling pelagics and other coastal
resources that are otherwise readily available off the western coast of
South America. This has caused, and is still causing, large losses to the
fisheries sectors in the area and a worldwide shortage of fishmeal and
fish oil.
Anchoveta fish stocks have declined to very low levels in Peru and
Chile. The main direct causes of this decline are: recruitment failure,
with at least two consecutive year classes either missing or being much
less abundant; poor somatic growth, with a significant loss in average
weight; and a possible increase in fishing and natural mortality. The
region's anchoveta populations might take several years to recover. In
the same area, important sardine stocks were already declining before
the onset of the El Niño phenomenon and, although slightly warmerthan-normal conditions are known to favour sardines in this area,
prospects of a recovery are likely to have been offset or even lowered
owing to the extreme strength of this warming event.
Total production of horse mackerel has also been much lower in
1997/98 than in previous years. This is probably due to an offshore and
poleward displacement of existing concentrations, but an actual
decline in the total biomass of horse mackerel as a result of heavy
fishing, together with the prevailing environmental conditions, cannot
be excluded.
So far, the 1997-1998 El Niño is known to have produced a 10 to 20
percent decline in total production from this area in 1997. This is a
significant drop, as the region usually produces nearly 20 percent of
total world fish landings. An even larger decline is foreseen for 1998.
Catches of other small and medium-sized pelagics, coastal demersals
and other species (including salmon, tuna and some invertebrates) have
also been affected throughout the Eastern Pacific, from Canada to
Chile. While heavy rain and flooding, caused by El Niño in some
areas, have resulted in reduced shrimp culture activities and smaller
landings of otherwise abundant and common fish species, catches of
other, more tropical, pelagic species (e.g. dolphin fish, tropical sharks
and tuna) have increased in the tropical and subtropical Eastern
Pacific. This is because stocks experienced a poleward displacement at
the onset of El Niño. Both types of effect have retreated or are
expected to retreat more rapidly with the phasing out of the event.
In some areas, total production of some wild shrimp stocks and
shellfish has also increased as a result of the warmer temperatures. In
other regions of the world, minor or less dramatic negative effects of
El Niño have been reported, for example coral bleaching in the Indian
Ocean and the tropical and Western Pacific. Even though declines in
the production of some tropical fish stocks might be compensated by
an increase in production in other areas, a possible reduction of 5 to 10
percent in total marine fish capture could be attributed to the 19971998 El Niño.
Source: J. Csirke and A. Bakun, FAO Fisheries Department.
However, since most of the reduction will be absorbed by the fishmeal industry, supplies
for human consumption are expected to have increased by more than 3 million tonnes in
1997, which means that the average per caput supply (including aquaculture) would have
risen to a new maximum of about 16 kg. This peak would not have been reached had it
not been for the sharp rise in reported Chinese fish production. The world's capture
fishery production has probably contracted further in 1998 owing to the ongoing effects
of El Niño.
The expansion of fishing capacity, as measured by number of vessels and fishers, slowed
during the first part of the 1990s (see the section Fishers and fishing fleets). The change
was most noticeable in Asia, with the exception of China where fishing capacity recorded
a sharp increase in the same period. There are several plausible reasons for a slowdown in
the buildup of fishing capacity in Asia, the most significant being: employment
opportunities generated outside fisheries and agriculture by past economic growth; the
general realization that available wild stocks in Asia are being reduced through
overfishing; and governments' efforts to provide appropriate management frameworks for
capture fisheries (see the section National fisheries governance).
The present economic crisis might possibly lead to fisheries again becoming a source of
employment for those without work as well as the logical source of livelihood for young
members of fishing communities. If the economic crisis persists over the coming years,
managers and management structures will come under increasing pressure to allow and
facilitate an expansion of fishing capacity. It is also possible that, after giving a small
initial boost to production, such expansion will result in reduced capture fishery landings
for developing economies by 2010.
In the developed economies, fisheries governance should improve, making it easier to
maintain stocks at a level that permits the maximum sustainable yield (MSY) to be
harvested. Furthermore, better fisheries management (a direct result of improved
governance) will be supported by technological developments (Box 16,
Telecommunications: benefits for capture fisheries). In some developed economies,
cheap fish imports are likely to contribute to a reduction in fishing effort. These imports
will originate in developing economies whose currencies are losing value vis-à-vis those
of OECD countries. However, by 2010, better management should have resulted in
economically sounder fisheries and improved catch levels in most developed economies.
This may lead to strong pressure from national industries for the application of trade
measures to control fish imports. On the other hand, several countries are making a
parallel effort to promote freer trade in fish and fishery products (Box 17, Agreements
regulating international fish trade).
BOX 16
Telecommunications: benefits for capture fisheries
As is the case for many other industries, progress in
telecommunications technology has had, and will continue to have, a
radical influence on the fishing industry. When the potential impact of
satellite technology on marine communications was realized, the
international community's initial response was to set up the
International Maritime Satellite Organization (INMARSAT). To begin
with, the fishing industry was slow to take advantage of the benefits
offered but, in recent years, there has been an exponential increase in
the number of fishing vessels fitted with satellite communications
systems. According to one service provider, there were 2 000
installations in 1996 and 7 500 in 1998. Following are the main
benefits accruing to the fishing industry:
i) Increased safety from the Global Maritime Distress Safety System
(GMDSS). Unlike conventional radio communications systems, which
are highly dependent on atmospheric conditions, the GMDSS virtually
guarantees a response to any vessel distress message regardless of the
circumstances. Even after a vessel has sunk, a distress message can
still be transmitted via an emergency position-indicating radio beacon
(EPIRB), which floats free from the vessel as it sinks.
ii) Better fisheries management through improved monitoring of the
position of fishing vessels using vessel monitoring systems (VMS).
The periodic reporting of the position of a fishing vessel assists in the
MSC of all vessels at a central control point. Future systems are likely
to incorporate catch reporting in an electronic format that will allow
real-time fisheries management decisions to be made.
iii) Information systems linking fishing vessels and fish markets will
allow more informed decisions as to where and when to land fish. This
will increase vessels' revenue and will avoid any one fishing port
having more landings than it can handle on any particular day.
iv) By using global positioning systems (GPS), which are an integral
component in most satellite communication systems, messages can be
sent to specific users (e.g. information that is of relevance to a given
area is sent only to vessels located in that area). When brought down to
the level of individual vessels, when a patrol ship wishes to interrogate
a fishing vessel in a particular position, the satellite communications
system on that vessel will automatically respond with details of the
ship and its fishing authorization. This will avoid what are sometimes
dangerous and time-consuming boardings by fisheries inspectors at
sea. Similar systems, known as automatic identification systems (AIS),
are already in operation in the merchant fleet as part of Traffic
Separation Schemes. The use of free-standing GPS is well established
in larger vessels, but the introduction of hand-held GPS now means
that this important navigational aid will also be available to much
smaller vessels.
Source: A. Smith, FAO Fisheries Department.
BOX 17
Agreements regulating international fish trade
Fish and fishery products are the most international of all foodstuffs.
Annually, between 35 and 40 percent of fisheries production is traded
internationally, reaching a value - as traded - of about US$50 000
million. Developing countries currently account for half of this
exchange and, in 1996, derived a net surplus (value of exports minus
value of imports) in the order of US$17 000 million.
International rules and regulations play a major role in governing the
fish trade, especially for developing economies. Two recent
international agreements of particular significance are the Agreement
on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures (SPS) and
the Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT). These
agreements were concluded under the Uruguay Round of multilateral
trade negotiations (MTNs) and are binding on all members of the
WTO.
· The SPS Agreement specifies, inter alia, when food safety concerns
are a valid reason for exceptions to the principle of non-discrimination
in international trade. The agreement encourages WTO members to
use international standards and, in the area of food safety, refers to the
Codex Alimentarius. A country's requirement that internationally
traded fish products be produced using the HACCP system must only
be enforced in a manner that respects the SPS agreement.
· The TBT Agreement sets out rules for technical regulations that are
not directly related to health. It is intended to ensure, inter alia, that
requirements related to quality, labelling, methods of analysis, etc., are
applied to internationally traded goods in a manner that does not
mislead the consumer or discriminate in favour of domestic producers
or between goods of different origin. Thus, the TBT Agreement would
apply to a country intending to impose the use of ecolabels on
internationally traded fish products.
Discussions have started concerning the possible coverage of future
MTNs, which may begin towards the end of 1999. Whether these
discussions - which will also concern the WTO Agreement on
Agriculture - will include fish and fishery products is not certain.
However, to be prepared for such an eventuality, several countries
have studied a form of subsidy that is channelled to the fisheries
sector. At present, the trade effects of such subsidies can be addressed
by WTO under its Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing
Measures, as fish and fishery products are not included in the WTO
Agreement on Agriculture.
The generally reduced tariff rates for fishery products under the
Uruguay Round have resulted in a reduction of the relative tariff
concessions granted by the EC under the Lomé IV Convention to a
large number of developing countries. Discussions about if and how
the effects of this erosion of benefits may be remedied have begun
between the EC and the countries concerned.
Source: E. Ruckes, FAO Fisheries Department.
Diverging trends in inland capture fisheries are evident for the different regions. With
regard to food fisheries, the rapid expansion in Asia is likely to continue, while growth in
other regions is expected to be slower. In the CIS and the Baltic states, this is because of
political and economic difficulties; in Latin America because of a lack of demand; and in
Africa because of financial, administrative and logistical difficulties. Recreational
fisheries are gaining importance mainly, but not exclusively, in North America and
Europe. In most regions, the practice of stock enhancement will continue and probably
become more widespread. In all regions, inland fisheries yields are being negatively
affected by environmental degradation, with Europe and North America also having
experienced significant negative impacts in the past.
In conclusion, by about 2010, there should be a slight increase in capture fisheries
production as fisheries in developed economies exploit recovered stocks in a more
sustainable manner and make increased use of small pelagics, both for human
consumption and reduction to fishmeal. The use of small pelagics should be facilitated by
advances in electronic technology and artificial intelligence systems that enable the size
and species of fish targets to be identified using echo-sounders and sonars. Such systems,
which establish more accurately the probabilities and confidence limits of species, will
allow skippers to assess their expected catch, by-catch and discards as well as to estimate
the profitability of fishing in a particular area before deploying their fishing gear.
Ultimately, this increased efficiency should also reduce wastage.
Thus, for 2010, it is not unreasonable to estimate a modest increase in landings from
inland and marine capture fisheries to between 95 million and 100 million tonnes.
During the 1990s about 30 million tonnes of total finfish supplies have been converted
annually into fishmeal and fish oil. In 1997/98, reduced supplies were mainly a
consequence of difficulties in obtaining the raw material. The present downturn in the
world economy will reduce growth of the livestock sector (a main user of fishmeal), and
the production of fishmeal could well fall below the present level for some years. Early in
the period 2000-2010, European livestock producers will probably increase their use of
grains slightly, as real grain prices are expected to fall. Fishmeal and fish oil production
is likely to recover when stocks of small pelagics again become plentiful off the west
coast of South America and fishmeal prices regain competitiveness. In the medium term,
it is assumed that about 30 million tonnes of fish will continue to be converted into
fishmeal and fish oil.
TOTAL SUPPLIES
Total fish supplies will probably remain below or at the level of 125 million tonnes for
the next three to four years and then increase towards the end of the period 2000-2010. At
that time, supplies may be in the order of 135 million tonnes, of which 105 million tonnes
would be available as food fish and the remaining 30 million tonnes for the production of
fishmeal and fish oil.
CONCLUSION
It is clear that both supply and demand in capture fisheries will remain stagnant in the
near future. On the supply side, a low availability of major pelagic stocks is exerting a
negative influence. Also in the near future, some export-oriented aquaculture industries
will reduce their production in response to weak markets.
The medium-term prospects are somewhat better for both supply and demand. Total
demand for capture fisheries was estimated to be between 105 million and 110 million
tonnes in 2010. As supplies are estimated to be 105 million tonnes, the demand-induced
upward pressure on prices will be weak, especially since the world population is not
expected to top 7 billion by 2010. A supply of 105 million tonnes of fish in that year
would in fact imply the stagnation of per caput supplies at about 15 kg per year.
This scenario is dependent on several crucial assumptions, with the main one hinging on
developments in the world economy. The basic assumption is that the present economic
crisis will continue into the next century and will also affect the more developed
economies. Technology is another important factor: while it has been assumed that
capture fisheries - particularly in developed economies - will benefit from developments
in modern communications and electronic technologies, no similar assumption has been
made for aquaculture. This may be unduly pessimistic. For example, genetic
improvements in salmon, tilapia, catfish, carp and oysters have already been successful in
raising production, and work in this area is likely to continue to yield positive results.
Furthermore, on-farm management should improve, in both the areas of business and
technology. It is not inconceivable, therefore, that the developments in aquaculture
technologies will allow production to have increased further by 2010 even without the
stimulus of higher real prices.
1
Main contributor: U. Wijkström, FAO Fisheries Department.
Including finfish, crustaceans and molluscs.
3
Including intra-Asian trade.
4
Tilapias and other cichlids as a group.
5
J.F. Muir. 1995. Aquaculture development trends: perspectives for food security. Paper
presented at the Government of Japan/FAO International Conference on Sustainable
Contribution of Fisheries to Food Security, Kyoto, Japan, 4-9 December 1995; and FAO.
1997. Review of the state of world aquaculture. FAO Fisheries Circular No. 886, Rev. 1.
Rome.
2
PART 5
Fisheries activities of country groupings
ASSOCIATION OF SOUTHEAST
ASIAN NATIONS
The Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) was established on 8 August 1967
with the signing of the Bangkok Declaration. At present, its members are Brunei
Darussalam, Indonesia, the Lao People's Democratic Republic, Malaysia, Myanmar, the
Philippines, Singapore, Thailand and Viet Nam.
In 1992, the ASEAN heads of government adopted the Singapore Declaration and the
Framework Agreement on Enhancing ASEAN Economic Cooperation, which included a
decision to establish the ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA) within 15 years. It is now
expected that the free trade area will be established by the year 2003. Member countries
are gradually implementing the provisions of the Agreement on the Common Effective
Preferential Tariff (CEPT) Scheme, which is the main instrument of AFTA.
TABLE 7
ASEAN: fisheries and aquaculture production and trade
Aquaculture production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries and aquaculture
production
Combined total ('000 tonnes)
1984
1988
1992
679
16.0
234
8.6
852
11.9
326
7.1
1 050 1 193
11.2
7.6
592
715
9.7
6.6
984
16.9
6 680
923
939 1 058
14.8 15.0 14.0
7 878 9 405 10
390
9.6
11.8 11.9
9.3
8 576
9 980 11 986
1996
13
357
Percentage of world total
Trade in fishery commodities
Total imports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
Total exports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
10.1
471
2.7
1 320
8.1
9.9
11.8
11.0
1 142 1 904 2 072
3.2
4.2
3.6
3 446 5 777 7 703
10.8 14.4 14.7
FISHERIES: PURPOSE AND ACTIVITIES
The ASEAN Ministerial Understanding on Fisheries Cooperation, signed in Singapore on
22 October 1983, identified areas subject to cooperative action among member countries.
The areas identified included: the management and conservation of fishery resources; the
transfer of technology to improve the socio-economic status of fishers; raising
aquaculture production and fish farmers' incomes; production and marketing; postharvest technology; the promotion of fish marketing and trade; and the promotion of a
common understanding on regional and international matters in fisheries.
The 15th meeting of ASEAN Ministers of Agriculture and Forestry, held in Bandar Sri
Begawan, Brunei Darussalam, 28 to 30 October 1993, agreed on a medium-term
programme of action for ASEAN cooperation in food, agriculture, fisheries and forestry.
The programme is aimed at strengthening food security in the region and is compatible
with the Ministerial Understanding on Fisheries Cooperation.
COOPERATION WITH FAO
There is no formal cooperation between ASEAN and FAO in the area of fisheries.
However, member countries of ASEAN and its fisheries group do cooperate closely with
FAO through the FAO Regional Office in Bangkok.
CARIBBEAN COMMUNITY AND
COMMON MARKET
The Caribbean Community and Common Market (CARICOM) was established by the
Treaty of Chaguaramas on 4 July 1973, with the principal purpose of enhancing, through
cooperation, the economic, social and cultural development of the people of member
countries. CARICOM's members are Antigua and Barbuda, Bahamas, Barbados, Belize,
Dominica, Grenada, Guyana, Jamaica, Montserrat, Saint Lucia, Saint Kitts and Nevis,
Saint Vincent and the Grenadines, Suriname and Trinidad and Tobago.
TABLE 8
CARICOM: fisheries and aquaculture production and trade
1984
Aquaculture production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries and aquaculture
production
Combined total ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Trade in fishery commodities
Total imports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
Total exports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
1988 1992 1996
0
0.0
0
0.0
2
0.0
0
0.0
3
0.0
0
0.0
4
0.0
1
0.0
1
0.0
72
0.1
2
0.0
82
0.1
2
0.0
98
0.1
2
0.0
102
0.1
74
0.1
86
0.1
103
0.1
108
0.1
55
0.3
51
0.3
57
0.2
80
0.3
52
0.1
105
0.3
84
0.1
140
0.3
FISHERIES: PURPOSE AND ACTIVITIES
In fisheries, CARICOM aims to "promote the development of the fisheries subsector in
member states with a view to optimal exploitation of their resources on a sustainable
basis". It intends to do this by strengthening the legal and institutional framework, in part
through the formulation and implementation of a common CARICOM Fisheries Policy
and a CARICOM Regional Fisheries Mechanism.
The CARICOM Fisheries Resource Assessment and Management Program (CFRAMP)
was initiated in 1991 with joint funding from the Canadian International Development
Agency (CIDA) and 12 participating member countries of CARICOM. The primary goal
of CFRAMP is "to promote the management and conservation of the fisheries resources
of the CARICOM countries and to permit the exploitation of these on the basis of
sustainable yield". The four major components of CFRAMP are the enhancement of
national fisheries management capabilities, training, resource assessment and the
establishment of a permanent regional fisheries mechanism, which on completion will be
the successor to CFRAMP.
COOPERATION WITH FAO
CARICOM and FAO have cooperated closely over the past decades on various aspects of
fisheries, including policy and legal matters. FAO has provided specific technical
assistance to CFRAMP since its inception in 1991 and, over the past two years, the two
have collaborated in implementing joint technical activities through the Western Central
Atlantic Fisheries Commission (WECAFC). Such activities have included training in
stock assessment and the assessment of major fish stocks (e.g. spiny lobster, penaeid
shrimps) in the WECAFC region.
COMMON MARKET FOR EASTERN
AND SOUTHERN AFRICA
The treaty establishing the Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA)
was signed on 5 November 1993 in Kampala, Uganda, and was notified on 8 December
1994 in Lilongwe, Malawi. Its member countries are Angola, Burundi, the Comoros, the
Democratic Republic of the Congo, Djibouti, Eritrea, Ethiopia, Kenya, Lesotho,
Madagascar, Malawi, Mauritius, Namibia, Rwanda, Seychelles, Somalia, the Sudan,
Swaziland, Uganda, the United Republic of Tanzania, Zambia and Zimbabwe. The aims
and objectives of COMESA are to:
•
•
•
•
•
•
attain sustainable growth and development of the member states by promoting a
more balanced and harmonious development of its production and marketing
structures;
promote joint development in all fields of economic activity and the joint
adoption of macroeconomic policies and programmes to raise the standard of
living of its peoples and to foster closer relations among its member states;
cooperate in the creation of an enabling environment for foreign, cross-border and
domestic investment, including the joint promotion of research and adaptation of
science and technology for development;
cooperate in the promotion of peace, security and stability among the member
states in order to enhance economic development in the region;
cooperate in strengthening the relations between COMESA and the rest of the
world and the adoption of common positions in international fora;
contribute towards the establishment, progress and the realization of the
objectives of the African Economic Community.
To enable COMESA to sustain member countries' development efforts, structural and
institutional weaknesses in member states should be removed and resources pooled.
TABLE 9
COMESA: fisheries and aquaculture production and trade
1984 1988 1992 1996
Aquaculture production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries and aquaculture
production
Combined total ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Trade in fishery commodities
Total imports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
Total exports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
28
0.7
0
0.0
56
0.8
0
0.0
70
0.7
3
0.0
79
0.5
10
0.1
1 025 1 268 1 271 1 251
17.6 20.3 20.3 16.6
205 340 627 605
0.3
0.4
0.8
0.7
1 258 1 664 1 970 1 945
1.5
1.7
1.9
1.6
205
1.2
38
0.2
208
0.6
94
0.3
188
0.4
144
0.4
307
0.5
501
1.0
FISHERIES: PURPOSES AND ACTIVITIES
Article 130 of the treaty establishing COMESA contains the following explicit objectives
and activities with regard to fisheries:
•
•
•
•
the harmonization of agricultural policies of the member states with a view to
having a common agricultural policy;
the development and utilization of land and water resources, particularly shared
river and lake basins;
the exploitation and surveillance of the EEZs with regard to marine fisheries
development;
the marketing and stabilization of agricultural commodity prices, bearing in mind
internal agricultural and exchange rate policies in individual member countries.
The agenda is overarching and its implementation will have an impact on fisheries and
aquaculture in terms of the investments, production, trade and fish consumption of
member states. COMESA aims to deepen and broaden the integration process among
member states through the adoption of comprehensive trade liberalization measures, such
as the complete elimination of tariff and non-tariff barriers to trade; the free movement of
capital, labour, goods and the right of establishment; standardized taxation rates
(including value-added tax and excise duties); promoting the adoption of a single
currency and the establishment of a monetary union; and the adoption of a common
external tariff (CET).
COOPERATION WITH FAO
The COMESA secretariat has entered into arrangements with FAO in the specialized
field of agriculture and fisheries.
COMMONWEALTH OF
INDEPENDENT STATES
The Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) was established in December 1991. It is
a voluntary association consisting of the following states: Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus,
Georgia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Moldova, the Russian Federation, Tajikistan,
Turkmenistan, Ukraine and Uzbekistan. The main purpose of the Commonwealth is to
develop and strengthen cooperation and to serve the cause of peace and security.
FISHERIES: PURPOSE AND ACTIVITIES
To date, no common fisheries policy among countries of the CIS has been elaborated.
Coordination is achieved through bilateral and multilateral agreements among the
member countries, which can be divided into two groups: i) states that have inland water
fisheries and aquaculture activities only (Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Kazakhstan,
Kyrgyzstan, Moldova, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan); and ii) states that have
a well-developed distant-water fisheries sector (Russian Federation, Ukraine and - to a
certain extent - Georgia).
Most CIS countries have concentrated on the restructuring of their fleets and on the
processing and marketing sectors under structural adjustment schemes.
TABLE 10
CIS: fisheries and aquaculture production and trade
Aquaculture production
Inland production ('000
tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000
tonnes)
1984
1988
1992
1996
...
307
219
99
...
...
4.3
0
2.3
1
0.6
2
Percentage of world total
Fisheries production
Inland production ('000
tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000
tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries and aquaculture
production
Combined total ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Trade in fishery
commodities
Total imports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
Total exports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
...
0.0
0.0
0.0
...
679
437
310
...
...
10.9
8 952
7.0
5 706
4.1
4 852
...
10.9
7.1
5.6
...
...
9 939
9.9
6 363
6.3
5 263
4.3
...
...
...
...
0
0.0
0
0.0
35
0.1
826
2.1
500
0.9
1 877
3.6
Note: ... = data not available.
COOPERATION WITH FAO
To date there is no agreed policy within the CIS countries concerning their cooperation
with FAO. Each state acts independently in fisheries matters.
ECONOMIC COMMUNITY OF WEST
AFRICAN STATES
The treaty establishing the Economic Community of West African States (ECOWAS)
came into force in June 1975. At present, the following countries adhere to the treaty:
Benin, Burkina Faso, Cape Verde, the Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Côte
d'Ivoire, Liberia, Mali, Mauritania, the Niger, Nigeria, Senegal, Sierra Leone and Togo.
The ECOWAS treaty specifies the Community's objective as being the promotion of
cooperation and development in all fields of economic activity. Cooperation in the
development of agriculture, forestry, animal husbandry and fisheries is one of its primary
aims. The first stage in this cooperation entails the harmonization of internal and external
policies, the second stage envisages the adoption of a common agricultural policy.
FISHERIES: PURPOSE AND ACTIVITIES
Based on the recommendations of the Industry, Agriculture and Natural Resources
Commission at its meeting in Cotonou, Benin, in April 1980, ECOWAS organized a
conference of experts in Dakar, Senegal, to develop national policies to ensure better
management and surveillance of waters under the jurisdiction of its member states and
also to ensure the conservation of fisheries resources in the region. Several
recommendations were made concerning research, surveillance, the harmonization of
fishing agreements and legislation, trade in fish and fishery products, data collection, etc.
Since then, member countries have made progress in implementing such
recommendations.
TABLE 11
ECOWAS: fisheries and aquaculture production and trade
1984
Aquaculture production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries and aquaculture
production
Combined total ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Trade in fishery commodities
Total imports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
Total exports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
1988 1992 1996
7
0.2
0
0.0
11
0.2
0
0.0
314
5.4
877
1.2
333
5.3
995
1.2
17
0.2
1
0.0
19
0.1
0
0.0
331 395
5.3
5.2
1 228 1 272
1.5
1.5
1 198 1 340 1 577 1 687
1.4
1.3
1.6
1.4
280
1.6
323
2.0
343
1.0
505
1.6
358
0.8
499
1.2
336
0.6
842
1.6
COOPERATION WITH FAO
ECOWAS' formal relationship with FAO is based on an exchange of letters between the
Director-General of FAO and the Executive Secretary of ECOWAS. A Cooperation
Agreement was established with FAO in December 1984, since which time FAO has
been cooperating with the Community in various fields. However, as an organization,
ECOWAS is not a member of any of the FAO statutory bodies.
In the mid-1990s, at the request of ECOWAS, FAO carried out a study entitled Economic
development of fisheries, which made special reference to aspects of fisheries by foreign
vessels off West Africa. In its conclusions, the study emphasized the necessity and the
opportunities for regional cooperation in support of fisheries management and regional
food security. Furthermore, FAO regional fisheries projects have been cooperating with
ECOWAS member states, especially in promoting fisheries management in the artisanal
subsector.
EUROPEAN COMMUNITY
The Treaty of Rome established the European Economic Community (EEC) in 1957. In
1993, the Treaty of Maastricht established the European Union (EU) as a broader
framework which retained the EEC, now the European Community (EC), as a legal
entity. The aims of the EC include the abolition of restrictive trading practices and the
free movement of capital and labour within the union. A single market with free
movement of goods and capital was established in January 1993. The following countries
are members of the EC: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece,
Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden and the United
Kingdom.
TABLE 12
EC: fisheries and aquaculture production and trade
Aquaculture production
Inland production ('000
tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000
tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries production
Inland production ('000
tonnes)
1984
1988
1992
1996
154
198
227
251
3.6
622
2.8
713
2.4
685
1.6
907
23.0
15.6
11.2
8.4
122
111
103
123
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000
tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries and aquaculture
production
Combined total ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Trade in fishery commodities
Total imports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
Total exports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
2.1
6 797
1.8
7 040
1.6
6 563
1.6
6 319
9.5
8.5
8.2
7.3
7 696
9.1
8 061
8.0
7 577
7.4
7 599
6.3
5 363 12 261 17 270 19 352
31.2
34.8
38.2
34.0
3 117 6 400 8 580 11 015
19.2
20.1
21.4
21.0
FISHERIES: PURPOSE AND ACTIVITIES
The Common Fisheries Policy (CFP) of the EC came into existence in 1983, although the
first elements of this policy had already been introduced in 1970. Since then, it has been
developed and adjusted continuously in accordance with international developments and
changes within the EC itself. The CFP covers access to resources, the conservation of fish
stocks and the monitoring of fishing activities as well as the marketing of fishery
products and research.
The main objective of the CFP is the sustainable conservation and management of the
resource. Within this framework, an important element is the structural policy, the main
components of which are the Financial Instrument for Fisheries Guidance (FIFG) and
PESCA. Since 1993, these structural measures have been integrated into the EC's system
of structural funds. PESCA has been designed to strengthen, develop and diversify the
economies of regions dependent on fishing. The FIFG can help finance: i) adjustments in
fishing effort; ii) fleet withdrawal and modernization of vessels; iii) investment in
aquaculture; iv) fishing port facilities and the processing and marketing of products; v)
other measures such as the promotion of new outlets for products, the management of
fishing quotas by a producers' organization or temporary withdrawals, etc.
In 1997, within the framework of the Multi-Annual Guidance Programme (MAGP IV),
targets for fleet capacity reductions were agreed for each EC member state. Targets were
expressed as a reduction in tonnage volume (in GRT) and engine power (in kW).
In 1998, the implementation of the CFP entailed the following main measures:
•
•
the development of responsible fishing through the conservation of resources;
the matching of fishing capacity with resources through the multi-annual guidance
programmes for the period 1997-2002 (MAGP IV);
•
•
•
the control of fishing activity through the introduction of satellite-based vessel
monitoring systems;
enhanced international cooperation through negotiation of fisheries agreements
and participation in regional fisheries organizations;
the promotion of European fisheries research.
COOPERATION WITH FAO
The EC is a full member of FAO. The EC is also a member of most FAO regional
fisheries bodies and participates in the work of the European Inland Fisheries Advisory
Committee (EIFAC) and the Fishery Committee for the Eastern Central Atlantic
(CECAF).
In the course of 1998, the EC provided funds to FAO for the formulation and negotiation
of international agreements and plans of action for improved global management of
fishing capacity, shark fisheries and incidental catch of seabirds in longline fisheries.
LATIN AMERICAN ECONOMIC
SYSTEM
The Latin American Economic System (LAES) is a regional intergovernmental
organization that groups 27 Latin American and Caribbean countries: Argentina,
Barbados, Belize, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Cuba, the Dominican
Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Grenada, Guatemala, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Jamaica,
Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Suriname, Trinidad and Tobago, Uruguay
and Venezuela. LAES was established on 17 October 1975 by the Panama Convention.
The objectives of LAES are to promote a system for consultation and coordination
aiming to achieve consensus in the form of joint positions and common strategies for the
region on economic issues. The common strategies may be for individual countries or
groups of countries. LAES also serves to promote cooperation and integration among the
countries of the region.
FISHERIES: PURPOSE AND ACTIVITIES
The Action Committees of LAES are flexible cooperation mechanisms and are set up
when more than two member states voice their interest in promoting joint programmes
and projects in specific areas. These committees are dissolved once their objectives are
fulfilled, otherwise they may become Permanent Bodies of the System.
TABLE 13
LAES: fisheries and aquaculture production and trade
1984 1988 1992 1996
Aquaculture production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries and aquaculture
production
Combined total ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Trade in fishery commodities
Total imports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
Total exports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
43
1.0
82
3.0
60
0.8
150
3.3
99
1.1
247
4.0
141
0.9
422
3.9
434
7.5
11
481
16.0
497
7.9
15
722
19.1
467
7.5
17
413
21.8
463
6.1
21
066
24.2
12
040
14.2
16
430
16.4
18
226
17.9
22
091
18.3
269 358 472 1 039
1.6
1.0
1.0
1.8
2 118 3 139 4 243 6 615
13.1 9.9 10.6 12.6
COOPERATION WITH FAO
There is a long record of cooperation in technical activities between FAO and LAES.
Initially, the forum for this cooperation was the Action Committee of Sea and Freshwater Products. When this action committee was dissolved, the Latin American
Organization for Fisheries Development (OLDEPESCA) was established, and this
independent body has now become the centre of cooperation. FAO usually attends the
annual OLDEPESCA conferences of Fisheries Ministers.
LEAGUE OF ARAB STATES
The League of Arab States, more generally known as the Arab League, was founded in
March 1945. It comprises Algeria, Bahrain, the Comoros, Djibouti, Egypt, Iraq, Jordan,
Kuwait, Lebanon, the Libyan Arab Jamahiriya, Mauritania, Morocco, Oman, Palestine,
Qatar, Saudi Arabia, Somalia, the Sudan, the Syrian Arab Republic, Tunisia, the United
Arab Emirates and Yemen.
The broad objectives of the Arab League are to develop cooperation and strengthen
complementarity among the member states in economical, cultural scientific, social and
military fields. To do so, the League has set up several specialized agencies. Those of
interest to FAO are: the Arab Bank for Economic Development in Africa (Khartoum, the
Sudan); the Arab Centre for the Study of Arid Zones and Dry Lands (Damascus, the
Syrian Arab Republic); the Arab Fund for Economic and Social Development (Kuwait);
the Arab League Educational, Cultural and Scientific Organization (Tunis, Tunisia); the
Arab Organization for Agricultural Development (Khartoum, the Sudan); the Arab
Academy for Science and Maritime Transport (Alexandria, Egypt); and the Inter-Arab
Investment Guarantee Corporation (Kuwait).
FISHERIES: PURPOSE AND ACTIVITIES
The League of Arab States has no subsidiary body or institution that deals exclusively
with fisheries matters.
TABLE 14
League of Arab States: fisheries and aquaculture production and
trade
Aquaculture production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries production
Inland production (`000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries and aquaculture
production
Combined total ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Trade in fishery commodities
Total imports (US$ million)
1984
1988
34
0.8
0
0.0
63
0.9
1
0.0
1992 1996
75
0.8
4
0.1
84
0.5
10
0.1
164
222
210 237
2.8
3.5
3.4
3.1
1 065 1 364 1 319 1 472
1.5
1.7
1.7
1.7
1 263 1 650 1 608 1 803
1.5
1.6
1.6
1.5
284
248
261
359
Percentage of world total
Total exports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
1.7
385
2.4
0.7
833
2.6
0.6
900
2.2
0.6
1 152
2.2
COOPERATION WITH FAO
FAO has participated in several meetings organized by subsidiary bodies of the Arab
League. The Organization has attended and partly sponsored meetings of the Arab
Federation of Fish Producers (AFFP), which is a subsidiary of the Council for Arab
Economic Union. In 1998, FAO was represented at the Conference on the Development
of Marine Fisheries in the Arab World, organized by the Council.
NORTH AMERICAN FREE TRADE
AGREEMENT
Canada, Mexico and the United States of America are members of the North American
Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). NAFTA´s main aims are to: contribute to the
expansion of world trade; create, expand and secure markets for the goods produced in
their territories; reduce distortions to trade; create new employment opportunities and
improve working conditions and living standards in their respective territories; and
address related environmental and conservation issues
Because of the extent of NAFTA´s market, it is a trading block with a global reach. It is
also innovative, as it establishes linkages between economies with different levels of
economic development. Current discussions envisage the linking of existing subregional
integration schemes, of which NAFTA is one, into a Free Trade Area of the Americas
(FTAA).
FISHERIES: PURPOSES AND ACTIVITIES
NAFTA does not carry out any specific activities concerned with fisheries.
TABLE 15
NAFTA: fisheries and aquaculture production and trade
Aquaculture production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
1984
1988
1992
1996
201
254
304
312
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fishery and aquaculture
production
Combined total ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Trade in fishery commodities
Total imports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
Total exports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
4.7
190
7.0
3.5
198
4.3
3.2
214
3.5
2.0
229
2.1
218
269
239
190
3.8
4.3
3.8
2.5
6 793 8 287 7 432 7 134
9.5
10.1
9.3
8.2
7 402 9 008 8 188 7 865
8.8
9.0
8.0
6.5
4 084 6 021 6 785 8 321
23.8 17.1 15.0 14.6
2 712 5 087 5 985 6 178
16.7 16.0 14.9 11.8
COOPERATION WITH FAO
To date, there is no cooperation between NAFTA and FAO on fisheries matters. NAFTA
member countries deal individually with FAO in this field.
SOUTH ASIAN ASSOCIATION FOR
REGIONAL COOPERATION
The South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation (SAARC) was established in
1985 by the heads of state and government of Bangladesh, Bhutan, India, Maldives,
Nepal, Pakistan and Sri Lanka. SAARC's main goal is to accelerate economic and social
development in member states through joint action in certain agreed areas of cooperation.
To achieve this objective, SAARC seeks to:
•
•
promote the welfare of the peoples of South Asia and improve their quality of life;
accelerate economic growth, social progress and cultural development in the
region, and provide all individuals the opportunity to live in dignity and realize
their full potential;
•
•
•
•
promote and strengthen collective self-reliance among the countries of South
Asia;
promote active collaboration and mutual assistance in the economic, social,
cultural technical and scientific fields;
strengthen cooperation with other developing countries;
strengthen cooperation among themselves in international fora on matters of
common interest, and cooperate with international and regional organizations with
similar aims and purposes.
TABLE 16
SAARC: fisheries and aquaculture production and trade
1984 1988 1992 1996
Aquaculture production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries and aquaculture
production
Total ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Trade in fishery commodities
Total imports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
Total exports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
631
14.8
10
0.4
1 045
14.6
21
0.5
1 605
17.1
42
0.7
2 103
13.5
91
0.8
1 152
19.8
2 440
3.4
1 006
16.1
2 611
3.2
963
15.4
3 450
4.3
1 415
18.7
3 831
4.4
4 232 4 683 6 060 7 441
5.0
4.7
6.0
6.1
26
0.1
529
3.3
38
0.1
765
2.4
61
0.1
1 012
2.5
76
0.1
1 490
2.8
FISHERIES: PURPOSES AND OBJECTIVES
The Integrated Programme of Action is the key component of SAARC´s activities. It now
includes 11 areas of cooperation, each covered by a Technical Committee: Agriculture;
Communications; Education; Culture and Sports; Environment and Meteorology; Health
and Population Activities; Prevention of Drug Trafficking and Drug Abuse; Rural
Development, Science and Technology; Tourism; Transport; and Women in
Development. SAARC also has a Technical Committee on Aquaculture.
COOPERATION WITH FAO
SAARC does not cooperate formally with FAO in fisheries or aquaculture.
SOUTH PACIFIC FORUM
The South Pacific Forum (SPF), consisting of heads of government, was established in
1971. It provides an opportunity to discuss a wide variety of South Pacific and
international concerns and issues common to members, including the promotion of a free
trade area in the South Pacific region. In 1998, the members of the SPF and its affiliated
agencies were: Australia, Cook Islands, Federated States of Micronesia, Fiji, Kiribati,
Marshall Islands, Nauru, New Zealand, Niue, Palau, Papua New Guinea, Samoa,
Solomon Islands, Tonga, Tuvalu and Vanuatu. The SPF has a secretariat (Forum
Secretariat) which promotes regional cooperation among members on important
economic issues.
TABLE 17
SPF: fisheries and aquaculture production and trade
1984
Aquaculture production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries production
Inland production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Marine production ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Fisheries and aquaculture
production
Combined total ('000 tonnes)
Percentage of world total
Trade in fishery commodities
Total imports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
1988 1992 1996
1
0.0
19
0.7
2
0.0
39
0.9
2
0.0
66
1.1
3
0.0
95
0.9
19
0.3
475
1.0
22
0.3
595
0.2
23
0.4
819
1.0
19
0.3
748
0.9
513
0.6
658
0.7
910
0.9
865
0.7
306
1.8
415
1.2
482
1.1
584
1.0
Total exports (US$ million)
Percentage of world total
671
1.8
1 095 1 372 1 711
1.2
1.1 1.0
FISHERIES: PURPOSE AND ACTIVITIES
The South Pacific Forum Fisheries Agency (FFA), established as a specialized agency by
the SPF in 1977, facilitates and coordinates cooperation and mutual assistance among
members of the Forum in fisheries policy matters while seeking to secure the maximum
benefits from the region's living marine resources for Pacific Islanders. The SPF, the
Forum Secretariat and the FFA maintain close working relations with important
intergovernmental and non-governmental organizations. The FFA is mandated by its
Convention, inter alia, to collect, analyse, evaluate and disseminate relevant information
to members. Within its mandate, the FFA facilitated the coordination of its members in
negotiating the Multilateral Treaty on Fisheries between the Governments of Certain
Pacific Island States and the Government of the United States of America.
The FFA has brought important economic and social benefits to its members. The small
developing island states have benefited in particular through regional cooperation and the
adoption of regional minimum standards. Regionally agreed measures to limit fishing
effort (e.g. in the purse seine tuna fishery) have also been of tangible benefit to FFA
member countries.
COOPERATION WITH FAO
The FFA has formal relations with FAO and the two agencies cooperate on a range of
technical issues, including such matters as joint training exercises and exchanges of
technical information. FAO participates in the annual FFC meeting as an observer. In
close cooperation with the FFA and its members as well as the DWFNs, FAO also
participates as an observer in the Multilateral High Level Conference on the Conservation
and Management of Highly Migratory Fish Stocks in the Central and Western Pacific
(MHLC).
The FAO Subregional Office for the Pacific is expected to participate in the Marine
Sector Working Group of the South Pacific Organizations Coordinating Committee,
which is being convened by the Forum Secretariat and its members (comprising relevant
Pacific regional organizations). The Working Group was established to facilitate the
coordination of activities in the development of a regional strategy for the marine sector.