“This book...is an important resource for everyone who is
working to alleviate poverty.” — Former President Bill Clinton
48104
Success from
the Bottom Up
Deepa Narayan
Lant Pritchett
and Soumya Kapoor
MOVING OUT OF POVERTY, VOLUME 2
Success from the Bottom Up
About the Series
The Moving Out of Poverty series presents the results of new comparative
research across more than 500 communities in 15 countries on how and
why poor people move out of poverty. The findings lay the foundations for
new policies that will promote inclusive growth and just societies, and move
millions out of poverty.
The series was launched in 2007 under the editorial direction of Deepa
Narayan, former senior adviser in the World Bank. She earlier directed the
pathbreaking Voices of the Poor project.
Titles in the Moving Out of Poverty series:
Volume 1
Volume 2
Volume 3
Volume 4
Cross-Disciplinary Perspectives on Mobility
Success from the Bottom Up
The Promise of Empowerment and Democracy in India
(forthcoming)
Rising from the Ashes of Conflict (forthcoming)
Moving
Out of
Poverty
VOLUME 2
Success from the Bottom Up
Deepa Narayan,
Lant Pritchett, and
Soumya Kapoor
A COPUBLICATION OF PALGRAVE MACMILLAN
AND THE WORLD BANK
©2009 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank
1818 H Street NW
Washington DC 20433
Telephone: 202-473-1000
Internet: www.worldbank.org
E-mail:
[email protected]
All rights reserved
1 2 3 4 12 11 10 09
A copublication of The World Bank and Palgrave Macmillan.
PALGRAVE MACMILLAN
Palgrave Macmillan in the UK is an imprint of Macmillan Publishers Limited, registered in England,
company number 785998, of Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire, RG21 6XS.
Palgrave Macmillan in the US is a division of St Martin's Press LLC, 175 Fifth Avenue, New York, NY
10010.
Palgrave Macmillan is the global academic imprint of the above companies and has companies and
representatives throughout the world.
Palgrave® and Macmillan® are registered trademarks in the United States, the United Kingdom, Europe
and other countries.
This volume is a product of the staff of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The
World Bank. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this volume do not necessarily
reflect the views of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they represent.
The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries,
colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgement on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or
acceptance of such boundaries.
Rights and Permissions
The material in this publication is copyrighted. Copying and/or transmitting portions or all of this work
without permission may be a violation of applicable law. The International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development / The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and will normally grant permission to reproduce portions of the work promptly.
For permission to photocopy or reprint any part of this work, please send a request with complete
information to the Copyright Clearance Center Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA;
telephone: 978-750-8400; fax: 978-750-4470; Internet: www.copyright.com.
All other queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the Office
of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2422;
e-mail:
[email protected].
ISBN: 978-0-8213-7215-9 (softcover)
ISBN: 978-0-8213-7836-6 (hardcover)
eISBN: 978-0-8213-7216-6 (softcover)
DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-7215-9
ISSN: None
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data has been applied for.
Cover design: Drew Fasick
Cover photograph: Brice Richard
Printed in the United States
Dedication
To the thousands of women, men, and youths who took the time
to share with us their experiences, their hopes, and their dreams
and
To Charles Tilly (1929–2008)—adviser, guide, and friend
Contents
Foreword
Study Team and Acknowledgments
About the Authors
Abbreviations
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
xiii
xv
xix
xxi
2
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
50
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
86
I Believe I Can
126
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
180
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
222
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
280
Concluding Reflections
332
Appendix 1 Researchers and Institutions Involved
in Country Studies
Appendix 2 Technical Note on Household Regressions
Appendix 3 Data Collection Methods
Appendix 4 List of Variables for Household Regressions
Appendix 5 Weights for the PCA-Constructed Indexes,
by Study Region
Appendix 6 Regression Results Tables for MOP and MPI
References
Index
343
349
369
375
379
387
399
411
Tables
1.1
Sample ladders of life from two villages in Andhra Pradesh
and Uganda
14
vii
viii
Contents
2.1
All villages in Afghanistan report hard work as a factor in moving
out of poverty
2.2 Movers in India take more initiative, but chronic poor take about
as much initiative as never poor
3.1 Over half of households moved up or down at least one step on the
ladder of life over 10 years
3.2 Movements up and out of poverty are only one part of overall
poverty dynamics
3.3 Various measures of well-being dynamics are associated with local
(village-level) factors in four states of India
A3.4 On average, the poor and nonpoor in the same villages moved up
together across study regions
4.1 Poor people distinguish four different types of power
4.2 Path deviation in youth: Youths whose parents are in agriculture
or the informal sector want to do something else (start a business,
get a job)
6.1 People in study communities in Malawi associate democracy first
and foremost with freedom
6.2 Economic opportunities can create positive spillovers
7.1 Migration and multiple hands at work trigger upward movement
in Mexico
7.2 Collective entities replicate some but not all characteristics of
successful families
A.1 Countries in the MOP study stratified by income, growth,
and governance
A.2 Choosing locations within study regions
A.3 Desired distribution of households across mobility groups
60
66
93
97
117
122
132
156
230
270
288
297
351
352
356
Figures
1.1
1.2
1.3
1.4
1.5
1.6
1.7
1.8
More than half of all households were classified as poor in 2005
Movers most frequently cite initiatives as reasons for their move
out of poverty
Gambling, drugs, and alcohol are rarely cited as reasons for falling
The never poor and movers score themselves higher in power
and rights
Communities where governments became more responsive were
likely to report increased presence of services over last 10 years
Families are rated the most important institution for asset
accumulation by all mobility groups in Indian study regions
Collective action helps people cope in Bufkaro, Uganda
Initiative and opportunity interact to produce upward movement
16
20
21
27
35
40
44
46
2.1
2.2
2.3
2.4
2.5
2.6
2.7
3.1
3.2
3.3
3.4
3.5
3.6
3.7
3.8
3.9
4.1
4.2
4.3
4.4
4.5
4.6
Contents
ix
Majority of all households have high aspirations for their children
Movers and never poor have higher hopes, but even chronic poor
and fallers have high aspirations for their children
Movers and never poor support their agricultural initiatives through
purchase of assets, while chronic poor rely on hard work
Fallers and chronic poor are more likely to be unhappy
Respondents in India rate initiative as most important trigger for
accumulating assets
Initiative features prominently, luck hardly at all as reasons for
moving up
Ladder from Saré Ogicol, Senegal: Destiny matters for moving up
at the top
Community mobility matrix from Fateh Garh, Uttar Pradesh,
shows types and magnitude of household mobility
Community mobility matrix from Fateh Garh, Uttar Pradesh,
shows household movement out of poverty, within poverty,
into poverty, and among the nonpoor
Narrow escalator model illustrates moving out of poverty with all
households retaining their relative rankings
Broad staircase model illustrates moving out of poverty with
households changing both their absolute and relative rankings
$1-a-day international standard appears to underestimate poverty
compared to focus group estimates
Rising, falling, and net prosperity indexes show large variations both
across study regions and across communities within regions
Movement out of poverty and mobility of the poor indexes show
large variations both across study regions and across communities
within regions
On average, the poor and nonpoor moved up together across
study regions
Association is much weaker between net upward movements of
the poor and nonpoor than between their gross upward movements
Movers place themselves modestly higher on power and rights
10 years ago compared to the chronic poor
Fallers place themselves modestly lower on power and rights 10
years ago compared to the never poor
Movers report control over all or most decisions, while chronic
poor and fallers report less control
Personal agency has an association with moving out of poverty
Movers had higher hopes for their own future than did the
chronic poor
Individual aspirations are a robust correlate of moving out
of poverty
55
56
59
63
66
67
70
90
91
94
96
104
108
110
112
114
146
147
148
151
154
155
x
Contents
4.7
Households with more control over decisions report ownership
of more assets
4.8 Households with greater increase in power are more likely to have
acquired a house
4.9 Households with greater increase in power are more likely to have
met a local politician
4.10 Fallers and chronic poor report more health shocks than movers
4.11 Households with less control over decisions report more health
shocks and poorer current state of health
4.12 Households with lower aspirations for their children report more
health shocks
5.1 Comparison of spells of growth and poverty reduction shows that
the pace of poverty reduction is strongly associated with growth,
but with variation around this pattern
5.2 Although inequality may help or hinder poverty reduction, its
contribution to poverty reduction over long episodes tends to be
less than that of growth
5.3 Poor entrepreneurs face obstacles in gaining access to credit
5.4 A majority of chronic poor borrow for regular consumption
purposes
5.5 Land titling is strongly associated with perceived strength of local
economy
5.6 Public works projects are not strongly associated with perceived
strength of local economy
5.7 Big increases in corruption were reported in communities where
opportunities have expanded
6.1 Quality of health and education improved more where
governments became more responsive
6.2 Roads were more likely to be present in communities where
governments became more responsive
6.3 Communities where governments became more responsive were
more likely to report an increase in levels of safety and peace
6.4 Responsiveness of local democracy has a significant association with
moving out of poverty, particularly in South Asian study regions
6.5 Responsiveness of local democracy to some has negative spillovers
on others
6.6 More than half of households across study contexts believe that
most or almost all government officials in the country engage in
corruption
6.7 Corruption has a mostly negative association with moving out
of poverty
7.1 Finance/credit/saving groups are more common than livelihood,
health, education, religious, or ethnic groups across all study regions
161
161
163
165
169
170
184
185
210
211
215
216
218
235
237
237
239
242
245
248
302
Contents
7.2
7.3
7.4
7.5
Saving and credit groups are more common in Andhra Pradesh,
Uganda, Bangladesh, the Philippines, and Thailand
Community’s propensity for collective action has mostly negative
association with movement out of poverty
Change in access to networks has mostly negative association with
movement out of poverty
Different combinations of bridging ties and state functioning
result in different outcomes
xi
303
305
306
325
Boxes
2.1
3.1
4.1
7.1
7.2
7.3
7.4
7.5
What is freedom? Voices from the field
Poverty lines and people’s perceptions of poverty lines
Changes in women unsettle men in Bangladesh
Giving up everything to send children to school
Solidarity in time of war
Richard’s story: Friends to the rescue
Looking forward: Collective action emulating markets
Community policing in Malawi: From protection to abuse
78
103
135
284
289
300
319
321
Foreword
T
he global Moving Out of Poverty study is unique in several respects.
It is one of the few large-scale comparative research efforts to focus
on mobility out of poverty rather than on poverty alone. The study draws
together the experiences of poor women and men who have managed to
move out of poverty over time and the processes and local institutions that
have helped or hindered their efforts. It is also the first time that a World
Bank report draws on people’s own understanding of freedom, democracy,
equality, empowerment, and aspirations—and how these affect poor people
in different growth, social, and political contexts. By giving primacy to
people’s own experiences and how they define poverty, the study provides
several new insights to develop more effective strategies to reduce poverty.
I want to draw attention to two striking findings that will help focus our
approach to poverty reduction. First, half of the people who participated in
the study show some mobility either up or down the socioeconomic ladder.
By dampening downward mobility, we can dramatically affect poverty rates.
In Malawi, for example, while 10.4 percent of people moved out of poverty,
10.6 percent fell into poverty, completely netting out all upward movement.
Two important reasons for falling into poverty were declining local levels of
economic prosperity and health shocks. These findings have important policy implications. Reducing vulnerability is critical. We must help people build
permanent assets to reduce their chances of being thrown back into poverty
by unexpected shocks such as food and fuel price increases, illness, natural
disasters, or loss of jobs. We must provide basic social safety nets, including
provision of basic health services to prevent setbacks from becoming catastrophic events. And we must expand local-level economic opportunities so
that poor people have fair access to jobs and markets.
Second, the study finds that poor people take lots of initiative, in many
cases even more than those who are better off. There are millions and millions of tiny poor entrepreneurs. The investment climate of these tiny entrepreneurs has not been a centerpiece of poverty strategies. Too often, poor
xiii
xiv
Foreword
people do not face a level playing field. Despite the micro credit revolution,
poor people remain outside of most financial services; and large lenders
remain reluctant to lend to microenterprises and microentrepreneurs. New
institutional models and financial instruments are needed to serve poor
people’s financial needs and give them the capital they need to expand their
businesses and connect to markets.
The book will be of interest to all who care about ending poverty. We
hope you will be inspired to take action by the voices of 60,000 poor or
recently poor men and women in Sub-Saharan Africa, Latin America, and
East and South Asia.
Danny Leipziger
Vice President and Head of Network
Poverty Reduction and Economic Management
The World Bank
Study Team and Acknowledgments
T
his book draws on the contributions of many people who supported
the Moving Out of Poverty research project at different stages. We
first want to acknowledge the governments, the research institutes, and the
60,000 people who participated in the global study.
The project was led and managed by Deepa Narayan, who served from
2002 through 2008 as senior adviser in the Poverty Reduction and Economic
Management (PREM) Network of the World Bank, first in the Poverty Reduction Group and subsequently in the vice president’s office within PREM.
The project would never have started if not for the insistence of John
Page, then director of the Poverty Reduction Group, and Gobind Nankani,
then vice president of PREM. Successors to both continued their support,
including Luca Barbone and Ana Revenga, directors of the Poverty Reduction
Group; Sudhir Shetty and Louise Cord, sector managers in the Poverty Reduction Group; and Danny Leipziger, vice president of PREM. We also gratefully
acknowledge Lyn Squire and his successor, Gobind Nankani, of the Global
Development Network for their support throughout the project.
The team was split between Washington, DC, and New Delhi. Deepa
Narayan was based in New Delhi but traveled to and fro. Lant Pritchett served
as economic adviser to the study and provided stimulating overall guidance
particularly on the quantitative data analyses. In Washington, Patti Petesch
ably served as the project coordinator until the end of 2006. A succession of
young research analysts provided valuable management and research support, including Bryan Kurey, Sarah Sullivan, Sunita Varada, Mohini Datt,
Emcet Oktay Tas, Katrinka Ebbe, Kyla Hayford, and Sibel Selcuk. Four students from Stanford University—Jeremy Gordon, Nithya Rajagopalan, Rahul
Shaikh, and Sumeet Bhatti—provided able support during their stints with
the project. Others who worked for short periods included Ursula Casabonne,
Katy Hull, Kazuhiro Numasawa, and Elizabeth Radin. Administrative support
was provided by Oykiao Koo Tze Mew, Nelly Obias, and Jae Shin Yang.
In the New Delhi office, Soumya Kapoor was involved in the entire
project and coordinated the South Asian studies. The office was successively
xv
xvi
Study Team and Acknowledgments
supported by Kaushik Barua, Divya Nambiar, and Mohini Datt. Administrative assistance was provided by Sunila Andrews, who held us all together.
A range of local and international research institutes headed the country
studies. Without their collaboration there would have been no study. Their
contribution is so vital that we have listed them separately in appendix 1. We
also gratefully acknowledge the teams who led the pilot studies conducted in
Ethiopia, India, Peru, the Philippines, and Romania.
The project was supported by a loose network of advisers, all of whom
provided valuable guidance and encouragement at different stages of the
project. They included Stefan Dercon, Alan Gelb, Ashraf Ghani, Naila Kabeer,
Ravi Kanbur, Steen Jorgensen, Praful Patel, Amartya Sen, Rehman Sobhan,
Eva Tobisson, and Ashutosh Varshney. Charles Tilly was an invaluable adviser
in so many ways. He was brave enough to join us in a technical workshop
held in St. Petersburg, Russia, in January 2006, that guided our analyses. His
untimely death in April 2008 remains a loss to us all.
Several World Bank staff members and others helped us initiate the country studies or provided technical guidance or both. They included Kathleen
Beegle, Louise Fox, Johannes Hoogeveen, Jennie Litvack, Antonio Nucifora,
and Quentin Wodon (Africa); Nisha Agarwal, Jehan Arulpragasam, Gillian
Brown, Tim Conway, Scott Guggenheim, Mia Hyun, Priyanut Piboolsravut, and Kaspar Richter (East Asia); Jairo A. Arboleda, Gillette Hall, Harry
Anthony Patrinos, Jaime Saavedra, and Maximo Torero (Latin America); and
Nilufar Ahmad, Christine Allison, Maitreyi Das, Elena Glinskaya, Stephen
Howes,Valerie Kozel, Rinku Murgai, Ashish Narain, Ambar Narayan, V. J. Ravishankar, Shonali Sardesai, Binayak Sen, and Tara Vishwanath (South Asia).
We are also grateful to all the World Bank country directors who extended
their support to the study, particularly Michael Carter, without whose support
the large India study would not have been possible.
Data analysis was a huge task. The quantitative data analyses were guided
by Lant Pritchett and Deepa Narayan and involved several researchers over
time. These included Nina Badgaiyan, Kalpana Mehra, and Denis Nikitin, with
support from Jeremy Gordon, Kristin Himelein, Flora Nankhuni, Kazuhiro
Numasawa, Saumik Paul, Rahul Sheikh, and Sunita Varada.
The huge qualitative data set was analyzed partially by the ACNielsen
team in India and by other researchers over time, including Kaushik Barua,
Nandita Bhan, Chester Chua, Mohini Datt, Chris Gibson, Reema Govil,
Soumya Kapoor, Huma Kidwai, Molly Kinder, Mahima Mitra, Divya Nambiar, Yukti Pahwa, Brice Richard, Manzoor Ali Sait, Niti Saxena, and Gitima
Sharma.
Study Team and Acknowledgments
xvii
The design of the research project evolved through brainstorming workshops held at different points in the project. We want to thank participants in
the workshops and particularly the following people, who played key roles:
Ian Bannon, Bob Baulch, Louise Cord, Stefan Dercon, Raj Desai, Francisco
Ferreira, Gary Fields, Christiaan Grootaert, Johannes Linn, Kai Kaiser, Phil
Keefer, Stuti Khemani, Stephen Knack, Caroline Moser, Giovanna Prennushi,
Binayak Sen, Lyn Squire, Anand Swamy, Ashutosh Varshney, Quentin Wodon,
and Michael Woolcock.
We are particularly grateful to Ravi Kanbur, T. H. Lee Professor of World
Affairs at Cornell University; Frances Stewart, Director, Centre for Research on
Inequality, Human Security and Ethnicity at the University of Oxford; Louise
Cord, sector manager, Poverty Reduction Group; and Nora Dudwick, senior
social scientist, Poverty Reduction Group. They reviewed the entire manuscript and provided feedback that was tremendously helpful. Pratap Bhanu
Mehta, President, Centre for Policy Research, New Delhi, provided invaluable
guidance on the democracy chapter. Internal reviewers of individual chapters included Robert Chase, Anis Dani, Shanta Devarajan, Alexandre Marc,
Andy Norton, and Michael Woolcock. We owe a deep debt of gratitude to all,
though any errors remain our responsibility.
The study was financed by several governments and donors. We especially
wish to thank the government of Sweden, which provided untied funds to
support the project. In addition, we gratefully acknowledge generous grants
from the governments of Denmark, Finland, Luxembourg, the Netherlands,
Norway, Thailand, Uganda, and the United Kingdom, as well as the United
Nations Development Programme and the World Bank. In addition to the
support through PREM, World Bank assistance to the project included a grant
from the President’s Contingency Fund under Jim Wolfensohn and a grant
from the Post-Conflict Fund to the Global Development Network.
We thank the team at the World Bank Office of the Publisher, including
Mary Fisk, Pat Katayama, and Nancy Lammers, who managed publication
of the Moving Out of Poverty series. We deeply appreciate Cathy Sunshine’s
meticulous editorial work and eye for detail that helped us through successive
drafts and resulted in this book.
About the Authors
Deepa Narayan is project director of the 15-country World Bank study titled
Moving Out of Poverty: Understanding Freedom, Democracy, and Growth from
the Bottom Up. From 2002 through 2008, she served as senior adviser in
the Poverty Reduction and Economic Management (PREM) Network of the
World Bank, first in the Poverty Reduction Group and subsequently in the
vice president’s office within PREM. She has development experience in Asia
and Africa while working across sectors for nongovernmental organizations,
national governments, and the United Nations system. Her areas of expertise
include participatory development, community-driven development, and
social capital, as well as use of these concepts to create wealth for poor people. Her recent publications include Moving Out of Poverty: Cross-Disciplinary
Perspectives on Mobility (World Bank 2007); Ending Poverty in South Asia: Ideas
That Work (with Elena Glinskaya, World Bank 2007); Measuring Empowerment: Cross-Disciplinary Perspectives (World Bank 2005); Empowerment and Poverty Reduction: A Sourcebook (World Bank 2002); and the three-volume Voices
of the Poor series (Oxford University Press 2000, 2001, 2002).
Lant Pritchett is professor of the practice of economic development at
the John F. Kennedy School of Government at Harvard University. He is also
a nonresident fellow of the Center for Global Development, a senior fellow
of BREAD (Bureau for Research and Economic Analysis of Development),
co-editor of the Journal of Development Economics, and a consultant to Google.
org. He held a number of positions at the World Bank between 1988 and
2007, working in Indonesia and India as well as in Washington, DC. He has
been part of the teams producing many World Bank reports, including World
Development Report 1994: Infrastructure for Development; Assessing Aid: What
Works, What Doesn’t, and Why (1998); Better Health Systems for India’s Poor:
Findings, Analysis, and Options (2003); World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for Poor People; and Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning
from a Decade of Reforms (2005). He has authored or coauthored more than
50 papers published in refereed journals, as chapters in books, or as articles.
xix
xx
About the Authors
His monograph, Let Their People Come: Breaking the Gridlock on Global Labor
Mobility, was published by the Center for Global Development in 2006.
Soumya Kapoor is a consultant in the Social Development unit of the
World Bank in India, where she works on issues of social exclusion and environment as they relate to poverty reduction. She was a key member of the
Moving Out of Poverty study team between 2003 and 2008. Before joining
the World Bank, she worked as a corporate banker with a leading bank in
India and as a credit analyst with an arm of Moody’s. Her research interests
center on social exclusion and participatory development and on how private enterprise can help reduce poverty while increasing profits. In addition
to her writings for the Moving Out of Poverty project, she is the author of a
chapter (with Deepa Narayan) in Assets, Livelihoods, and Social Policy (World
Bank 2008).
Abbreviations
ACE
AIDS
BNS
BPS
BRAC
BREAD
CASEN
CDA
CDD
CEPA
CFAF
CGAP
CILSS
CNEF
CONGUATE
CONIC
CPL
CRECE
ECHP
EDI
EHM
EIHS
ENAHO
ENEU
EPH
ERHS
ESRF
EU
EU-15
EUHS
FENACOAC
FMHS
aggregate consumption expenditure
acquired immune deficiency syndrome
Bangladesh Nutrition Survey
Statistics Indonesia
Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee
Bureau for Research and Economic Analysis of Development
National Socioeconomic Characterization (Chile)
community development assistant
community-driven development
Centre for Policy Analysis
Communauté Financière Africaine Franc
Consultative Group to Assist the Poor
Côte d’Ivoire Living Standards Survey
Cross-National Equivalent Files
Coalition of Guatemalan Immigrants
National Indigenous and Campesino Coordinating
Committee
community poverty line
Centro de Estudios Regionales, Cafeteros y Empresariales
European Community Household Panel
Economic Initiatives
Household Sample Survey (Venezuela)
Egypt Integrated Household Survey
National Household Survey (Peru)
National Survey of Urban Employment (Mexico)
Permanent Household Survey (Argentina)
Ethiopia Rural Household Survey
Economic and Social Research Foundation
European Union
pre-2004 members of the European Union
Ethiopia Urban Household Survey
Federación Nacional de Cooperativas de Ahorro y Crédito
(Guatemala)
Farm Management and Household Survey (Côte d’Ivoire)
xxi
xxii
Abbreviations
FODIGUA
GDP
GUATENET
HACE
HBS
HDI
HHP
HIES
HIV
HTA
ICRISAT
IDB
IETS
IFAD
IFLS
IFPRI
IHS
INS
IOM
IRCA
IRNet
KHDS
KICS
KIDS
LAC
LDF
LMI
LOM
LPM
LSMS
MFI
MIF
MK
MOP
MPI
NASFAM
NCAER
NGO
El Fondo de Desarrollo Indígena de Guatemala
gross domestic product
National Congress of Guatemalan Organizations in the
United States
headcount measure of absolute expenditure
Household Budget Survey (Poland)
Human Development Index
Hungarian Household Panel
Household Income and Expenditure Survey (Bangladesh)
human immunodeficiency virus
hometown association
International Crops Research Institute for the Semi-Arid
Tropics
Inter-American Development Bank
Instituto de Estudos do Trabalho e Sociedade (Brazil)
International Fund for Agricultural Development
Indonesia Family Life Survey
International Food Policy Research Institute
Integrated Household Survey (Uganda)
Immigration and Naturalization Service (United States)
International Organization for Migration
Immigration Reform and Control Act (United States)
International Remittance Network
Kagera Health and Development Study (Tanzania)
Kenyan Ideational Change Survey
KwaZulu-Natal Income Dynamics Study (South Africa)
Latin America and the Caribbean
Local Development Board
Local Knowledge Management Institute
leave-out means
linear probability model
Living Standard Measurement Survey
microfinance institution
Multilateral Investment Fund (of the IDB)
Malawi Kwacha
Moving Out of Poverty
mobility of the poor
National Smallholder Farmers’ Association
National Council of Applied Economic Research (India)
nongovernmental organization
Abbreviations
NPI
OBC
OECD
OI
OLS
PCA
PDS
PIDI
PREM
PSID
Q
REDS
RHS
RIMCU
RLMS
Rs
SACCO
SC
SES
SEWA
SHGs
SLID
ST
TAMPA
TAOs
TPDS
UNDP
UNHS
UPPAP
USAID
VLSS
WMS
WOCCU
xxiii
net prosperity index
other backward castes
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
original interviewee
ordinary least squares
Principal Components Analysis
Public Distribution System (India)
Integrated Child Development Project (Bolivia)
Poverty Reduction and Economic Management
Panel Study of Income Dynamics
quetzal
Rural Economic Development Survey (India)
Rural Household Survey (China)
Research Institute for Mindanao Culture (Philippines)
Russian Longitudinal Monitoring Survey
rupees
Savings and Credit Cooperatives
scheduled caste
socioeconomic status
Self-Employed Women’s Association
self-help groups
Canadian Survey of Labour and Income Dynamics
scheduled tribe
Tegemeo Agricultural Monitoring and Policy Analysis Project
(Kenya)
Tambon Administrative Organizations
Targeted Public Distribution System (India)
United Nations Development Programme
Uganda National Household Survey
Uganda Participatory Poverty Assessment Project
U.S. Agency for International Development
Vietnam Living Standards Survey
Welfare Monitoring Survey (Kenya)
World Council of Credit Unions
Note: All dollar amounts are U.S. dollars.
xxiv
Abbreviations
Study Regions
Abbreviation
Country or state
Policy focus
AFG (Conf)
AP (SHG)
ASSAM (Conf)
BAN (Empow)
COL (Conf)
INDO (Conf)
MAL (Infra)
MEX (Ethn)
MOR (Mig)
PHI (Conf)
PHI (Panel)
SEN (Infra)
SRI (Conf)
TAN (Ruv)
THAI (Ineq)
UGA (Panel)
UP (Caste)
WB (Landdist)
Afghanistan
Andhra Pradesh
Assam
Bangladesh
Colombia
Indonesia
Malawi
Mexico
Morocco
Philippines
Philippines
Senegal
Sri Lanka
Tanzania
Thailand
Uganda
Uttar Pradesh
West Bengal
Conflict
Self-help groups
Conflict
Women’s empowerment
Conflict
Conflict
Infrastructure
Ethnicity
Migration
Conflict
Panel study
Infrastructure
Conflict
Ruvuma
Inequality
Panel study
Caste
Land distribution reforms
Indexes
MOP
Moving out of poverty index
Measures extent of upward mobility by the poor across the CPL in a
community.
MOP = initially poor who move above CPL ÷ initially poor.
MPI
Mobility of the poor index
Measures extent of upward mobility by those who were initially poor.
MPI = initially poor who move up ÷ initially poor.
MRI
Mobility of the rich index
Measures extent of upward mobility by those who were initially above
the CPL (nonpoor or “rich” by the study’s definition).
MRI = initially rich who move up ÷ initially rich.
FI
Falling index
Measures extent of all downward mobility in a community.
FI = all households that move down ÷ total number of households.
Abbreviations
xxv
FPI
Falling of the poor index
Measures extent of downward mobility of the initially poor.
FPI = initially poor who move down ÷ initially poor.
FRI
Falling of the rich index
Measures extent of downward mobility of the rich.
FRI = initially rich who move down ÷ initially rich.
FRIP
Falling of the rich into poverty index
Measures extent of downward mobility of the rich across the CPL.
FRI = initially rich who move below CPL ÷ initially rich.
NPR
Net poverty reduction
Measures changes in the share of poor over study period.
NPR = % ending poor – % initially poor.
NPI
Net prosperity index
Measures extent of net upward mobility (upward less downward) in a
community.
NPI = (all households that move up – all households that move down)
÷ total number of households.
NPP
Net prosperity of the poor index
Measures extent of net upward mobility (upward less downward) of
the initially poor.
NPP = (initially poor who move up – initially poor who move down)
÷ initially poor.
PI
Prosperity index
Measures extent of all upward mobility in a community.
PI = all households that move up ÷ total number of households.
Variable Prefixes and Suffixes
h
c
a
b
r
T
m
f
household questionnaire
community questionnaire
current (at time of study, about 2005)
initial (approximately 10 years ago, about 1995)
variable was recoded
total number of groups
male focus group discussion
female focus group discussion
MOVING OUT OF POVERTY, VOLUME 2
Success from the Bottom Up
The Moving Out of Poverty Study:
An Overview
Poverty is a dark stain that darkens the
whole world.
—M EN ’ S
DISCUSSION GROUP ,
Villa Rosa, Colombia
The longer I live the more convinced
am I that—except in purely abstract
problems—the statistical side must never
be separated even for an instant from
the nonstatistical.
—A LFRED M ARSHALL ,
English economist, 1906
1
C HAPTER
T
he goal is clear: to end poverty. And to do that we must begin by
answering the question of why poor people are poor. Beliefs about
the poor and the underlying causes of poverty determine the actions that
development practitioners pursue, the policies that national politicians
devise, and the actions that we as concerned citizens take. Our assumptions
about the underlying causes of poverty, therefore, will play a part in whether
families living in communities in Mississippi, Malawi, Manchester, Mexico,
or Morocco will have a chance to move out of poverty. Our unspoken,
unexamined, and often unconscious beliefs about poor people are critical,
as these determine whether poverty is defined as a problem at all. And if it
is a problem, whose problem is it? Is it their problem or is it our problem?
Beliefs about the nature of poverty and “the poor” can motivate action—or
rationalize inaction.
Our book is not about ideology, whether right or left. It is not about
bleeding heart liberalism or rugged individualism. It does not take a position
for or against free markets or big government. It is not pro-globalization or
anti-globalization. It is not about a clash of civilizations or about Protestant
values as opposed to Catholic, Islamic, or Hindu values. It is not about paradigm shifts.
Our book is about local realities, and about the urgent need to develop
poverty-reducing strategies informed by the lives and experiences of millions
of poor people in communities around the world. To do so, we must put
aside our assumptions. When we look closely at the local realities of communities rather than at countries, we see movement, not only stagnation.
Despite the odds, some poor people in places from Bangladesh in South Asia
to Mexico in Latin America are moving up and out of poverty. At the same
time, others in the same communities are stuck in poverty or falling down.
We set out to find out why and how.
3
4
Success from the Bottom Up
We begin with the lives of three individuals from different parts of the
world who either moved out of poverty or remained stuck in poverty.
Meet Three People . . .
Ayesha from Bangladesh
Forty-year-old Ayesha lives in the farming village of Pirjadi in Narshingdi
district in Bangladesh. A divorcee, Ayesha has been reviled and derided by
people in her village for her marital status. She has fought hard to achieve
what little she has today. Unlike other women in the community, she now
owns the small mud-brick house she lives in, and she has a small poultry
farming business. She lends money to her neighbors.
It was not always this way. About a decade ago, Ayesha recalls, “My condition was very bad. I did not have food, and I used to stay in others’ houses.
I passed my days covering my body with this sack.” (She points to a soiled
jute gunny bag). “But those days are gone. Now I am fine.”
Ayesha is illiterate, and her mother died three days after she was born.
Married at 15, she was stuck in an abusive marriage, with her husband frequently “going to other girls.” She left him when she was about 20 and started
working as a maid in a neighbor’s house. She received no salary for the first
six years and worked only for food and clothing. After prodding from others, she asked for a salary and started receiving 50 taka a month (about 75
cents). She also worked as a wage laborer and sold the rice that her employers
provided for her evening meal. “For three years, I did not have rice at night,”
she says proudly. With her miniscule wages and the money she received from
selling her food, Ayesha saved bit by bit and was able to buy a chicken and a
goat and some clothes for herself.
At the age of 32, Ayesha applied for a small job at the union parishad
(local council) office. She worked there for four years and received 1,200
taka (about US$18) each month. At the time our field team met her, Ayesha
had substantial savings from her union parishad job—savings that she had
invested wisely. She had returned to Pirjadi, where she reared and sold ducks
and chickens; she had her own house and her own piece of land that she
bought to cultivate rice. She says that she feels lonely with no family of her
own: “Nobody is with me. If I lie down in this room for the whole day,
nobody will call me.” Yet she is proud of what she has achieved. “I have my
own house,” she says. “That is why I have been able to entertain you, no? I’ll
tell you my secret: unity, courage, and hard work.”
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
5
Mamba from Malawi
Mamba is a 35-year-old farmer who lives in chronic poverty in the village
of Kalugeni in Dowa district in Malawi. He loves his country, his village, his
people, and his family and has no desire to leave his village, despite droughts
and periods of acute hunger.
Mamba started his education late, at the age of 15, and he had to leave
school two years later because his family could not afford his school fees and
uniform. He started farming maize and groundnuts and later added sweet
potatoes, which he raised both for consumption and for sale. But in 1998
Mamba stopped growing sweet potatoes because the cuttings for the crop
dried out due to improper storage. He got new cuttings from a friend in 2000,
but he did not manage a good crop. “There was hunger in the land at that
time. I was spending a lot of time doing ganyu [farm day labor]. As a result,
my garden was neglected and the harvesting was affected.”
The next two years were a period of widespread hunger in the community. Villagers ate sugarcane waste and wild roots that had to be boiled three
times to make them edible. Some people died. Farm work became increasingly difficult to find, and Mamba went from place to place looking for work
and food. He survived by molding and selling bricks. In 2002 the government started a fertilizer and seed distribution program for poor families, but
Mamba’s village received only 28 starter packs for more than 400 families.
“The big programs that top leaders make do not reach us here,” Mamba says.
From 2002 to 2004 Mamba toiled on his garden, but yields were low due to
poor rains. His break finally came in 2005, when he secured employment on
a road maintenance project.
Looking back at his life, Mamba sees that he has not been able to accumulate any assets except for a chair that he had bought for visitors; it had
broken and he pointed to it, hanging from the roof. “Never in my life have I
been able to hold money. There have always been ups and downs. I cannot
afford fertilizer because it is too expensive. The government is not helping us
by controlling its price. If this is hard, then they should restore farm clubs so
that we can obtain fertilizer loans from them. Maybe if the starter packs were
to be distributed to all people in the village, things would have been better,
but they just distribute it to only 20 or 15 people.”
Mamba has suffered many losses, including the deaths of two sons, who
died from hunger and lack of medical care. His friends are his lifeline. They
extend help when needed, from giving him a hoe for farming to stitching his
clothes for free. Despite all he has endured, Mamba feels confident. “I am an
6
Success from the Bottom Up
energetic man, and I believe that if I have fertilizer I can do better. This confidence has been growing, since I am a man who has a family. I have failed to
move forward in well-being, yes, but the way I see it, the respect that I receive
within my family has increased over the last 10 years. This is because I do
not love to do a lot of things like chasing skirts, drinking beer, and smoking
tobacco. I just love to play football. . . .” And he smiles.
Adolfo from Mexico
In the small mountainous community of Guadalamoros in Oaxaca, Mexico,
Adolfo, age 29, is busy in his tiendita, his small store. Thanks to the store, Adolfo
is “economically independent,” according to his friends. But things were not
always so. After he completed secondary school, Adolfo had to help his father
in the fields, for which he received no pay. To escape the drudgery, he decided
to migrate to the United States, and at the age of 20 he crossed the border,
undetected, for the first time. “I suffered a lot,” he recalls. “At 3 p.m. we left
Tecate walking, and we walked for an entire day. We had nothing to eat.”
Adolfo began working in a restaurant in California. He knew no English,
but his brother, who worked in the same restaurant, helped him. “It was easy
because my brother worked there so I didn’t need to know the language.” But
the separation from his family was hard. “Migration splits the family and it is
not with money that you can cure the effects [of the separation].”
He returned to Mexico two years later with some savings, but they soon
ran out. “I lasted a year and a half in Guadalamoros, and then I had to return
to California again because I needed more money. There is no money, no jobs
here in Guadalamoros,” he says. In 2000 Adolfo, now age 24, went back to
California. This time the border crossing was more difficult. He first tried to
cross at Mexicali but was caught and sent back. The Mexican border patrols
treated him very badly (he does not say how). He finally crossed at Tijuana.
“Tijuana is the saddest city. You have to protect yourself against our government and authorities. Instead of helping migrants, they hurt them.”
A year later Adolfo returned once more to Guadalamoros—this time, he
says, for good. He used savings from his work in California to set up his store.
He prefers living in Mexico, but he also recognizes that without migration he
would not have been able to go into business. “I pray to God that I will never
have to return. Not for fear of work, but for fear of leaving the family and for
fear of the risks you have to take to cross the border.” Adolfo insists that it
is not “correct” to leave one’s country for good and that he could never live
outside Mexico permanently. “Mexico is my land, my country, my people”
(México es mi tierra, mi país, mi gente).
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
7
One study . . . thousands of narratives
The lives of poor people like Ayesha, Mamba, and Adolfo push us to look
beyond simplistic ideological divides or economic formulas. We are forced
to come to terms with our flawed and discipline-constrained diagnosis of
why there are still so many poor people in our prosperous world. As we trace
backward to root causes, we see that the underlying assumptions and residues of ideologies about poverty have left deep imprints on policy choices.
Confronting these assumptions leads us to a series of questions. Are poor
people dysfunctional or are the contexts in which they live dysfunctional? Is
poverty the result of lack of initiative among the poor, or is the problem lack
of opportunity?
We build our case from the bottom up. Our “data,” our “case material,”
are narratives from 60,000 people: poor or formerly poor women, men, and
youths in over 500 communities across 21 study regions in 15 countries of
Africa, South Asia, East Asia, and Latin America.1 Some of these people have
escaped poverty over the last decade even as others in their communities have
remained poor or have fallen into poverty; a few have never been poor. We
learn from thousands of discussions—some animated, some angry, some tearful, some filled with laughter. We start with questions, not theories. We use an
inductive approach to gradually aggregate, life story by life story, discussion
by discussion, the threads that tie these experiences together. In doing so, we
lose some of the rich details of each local context, but we gain insights into
the underlying processes by which people either escape poverty or remain
stuck in chronic poverty.2 These insights guide our concluding reflections on
policy and action that call for innovations on a large scale by civil society,
businesses, and governments, informed by poor people’s realities.
This opening chapter now turns to a brief discussion of the principles
grounding our study and the multiple methods, both qualitative and quantitative, that we used to understand people’s lives over time. We then summarize seven key sets of findings that emerge from our inductive analyses.
These findings frame the structure of the book. We end this chapter with a
discussion of the conceptual framework that evolved as we pored over thousands of pages of field notes, reflecting primarily on individuals’ life stories
and group discussions.
Principles and Methods
The Moving Out of Poverty study is a follow-up to the earlier Voices of the
Poor study (Narayan et al. 2000, 2001, 2002). Its purpose is to explore
8
Success from the Bottom Up
from the bottom up how people move out of poverty. Our approach builds
upon and has been influenced by the work of many colleagues, some of
whom contributed to the first volume in the Moving Out of Poverty series
(Narayan and Petesch 2007). This second volume is based on new qualitative
and quantitative data gathered for this study.
Individual voices, local context, and change
over time
Three principles guided this study. First, each individual is the expert on her
or his own life. Poor people are no different. Hence, we give primacy to the
voices of thousands of people, living primarily in rural communities, who
shared their life experiences and insights with us. This is not methodological naiveté. We are well aware that subjective data, especially subjective data
about the past, are subject to a variety of distorting factors. These include
biases in recall (Gibbs, Lindner, and Fischer 1986; Withey 1954), the ways
in which individuals frame narratives about themselves (Tilly 2006; Bertrand
and Mullainathan 2001), sensitivity of responses to the research method
and questions (Krueger and Schkade 2007; Kahneman and Krueger 2006),
social context and power structures (Chambers 2002), and just plain errors.
An additional concern in poverty studies is the incentive facing poor people
and poor communities to give answers that “please” in the hope of gaining
funds and programs. Our data are not immune to any of these problems. At
the same time, we believe that how people recount their own experiences is
intrinsically of interest. Moreover, we believe in methodological pluralism,
in the need to investigate a phenomenon from multiple perspectives using
multiple methods. This study is meant to complement and not substitute
for the enormous body of existing quantitative and qualitative work on the
topic of poverty.
The second principle is that local context matters. Hence, we locate individuals and households in their community contexts and go beyond the exclusive focus on individual or household characteristics that is typical of poverty
surveys. We pay particular attention to the rules, regulations, informal norms,
and expectations that govern the local social, economic, and political institutions with which poor people interact.
Third, our interest is in change over time, in the dynamics of poverty
mobility. Most studies present a snapshot, a static picture of individuals frozen in time. We want the movie. We seek to understand in some depth the
processes through which people rise out of—or fall into—poverty.
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
9
Study sites
The study was conducted in 15 countries:
• In Africa: Malawi, Morocco, Senegal, Tanzania, and Uganda
• In South Asia: Afghanistan, Bangladesh, India (the four poorer states
of Assam, Andhra Pradesh, Uttar Pradesh, West Bengal), and Sri
Lanka
• In East Asia: Cambodia, Indonesia, the Philippines, and Thailand
• In Latin America: Colombia and Mexico
While for convenience we refer to our results by country—for example,
the results in Senegal or in the Philippines—we never take these results to
be representative of the whole country (or in the case of India, of the state).
We sacrifice national representation to study in depth a smaller number of
communities in order to reveal relationships and processes that lead to poverty outcomes. Altogether we conducted 21 studies. In several countries—the
Philippines, Sri Lanka, and Tanzania—we conducted two studies, each with
its own focus. As a reminder that our studies are not nationally representative,
we mostly refer to results by study region.
Selection of study regions within countries took into account the availability of local research institutes with the interest and capacity to carry
out the multidisciplinary study. In addition, the study team held intensive
dialogues with government and civil society representatives, academics, and
World Bank staff to identify specific policy questions that were of interest. In the Philippines, for instance, two study regions were identified. The
Bukidnon study built on a panel data set to examine the role that physical
assets, human capital, and governance play in mobility. In the region of
Mindanao, however, the focus was on local-level conflicts to investigate
how conflict in different growth contexts affected people’s ability to move
out of poverty.
We did more intensive study of a small number of communities, 8–20
in every study region (except in the four Indian states, where the number of
communities ranged from 50 to 110). Communities were chosen through
stratified randomized sampling with purposive stratification that depended
on the regional context. In some regions stratification was based on high- and
low-growth regions, in others on high or low availability of infrastructure, in
still others on conflict (see appendix 2, table A.2, for a list of study regions
and selection criteria for communities).
10
Success from the Bottom Up
Data collection methods
We used 10 different data collection methods, in part to overcome by triangulation potential distortions. Sometimes we probed the same issue with
the same people using different methods, such as a questionnaire followed
by a life story interview. At other times we asked different people to discuss
the same issue, presenting the same question, for example, to separate focus
groups of men, women, and youths. Our core tools include individual life
stories, the ladder of life exercise, focus group discussions on various topics,
and household interviews using questionnaires. All 10 methods are summarized in appendix 3.
Individual life stories. We examined over 5,000 life stories from more than
500 communities in the 15 countries. The individual life story is an openended interview that complements the household questionnaire. Its purpose
is to gather people’s own perceptions of key events in their lives over time. We
graphed people’s life histories along five dimensions: their migration history;
their occupational history; their economic history; their social, cultural, and
psychological history; and their education. People discussed the impact of
each event on their well-being and identified the turning or tipping points.
These discussions and graphs made visible to them and to us the sequencing
and interaction of factors over time. Most people loved talking about their
lives; invariably the interviewer rather than the storyteller was the one to
gently bring the session to a close.
Ladder of life. We conducted nearly 1,000 discussions to obtain local definitions of poverty and wealth and causes of mobility with focus groups of men
and women. These discussions used a tool called the ladder of life, described
in more detail in the next section. The groups clarified local understandings of
how someone moves out of poverty or falls into poverty and why some people
in the community are rich and others poor. The focus groups then categorized
actual households in their community according to their well-being status at
the time of the study (2005) and a decade earlier (1995), allowing us to see
the extent of upward and downward movement in the community.
Focus group discussions. We conducted more than 1,500 discussions to
understand key events that helped or hindered community prosperity. We
also held more than 2,000 focus group discussions on the topics of livelihoods, democracy, freedom, and power.
Household interviews. We conducted approximately 9,000 household interviews using questionnaires that investigate a household’s economic, political,
and social life. These interviews provide most of our quantitative data.
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
11
Use of these various tools generated a massive body of evidence spanning multiple contexts. Analyzing this diverse data set has taken time. Although
we use statistics and statistical analyses even of the qualitative data obtained
from life stories and group discussions, these are located in the “thick” descriptions gathered. These narratives were systematically analyzed over thousands of
hours, both manually and using an anthropological software package, Nudist.
We struggled with letting individuals express themselves while at the same time
starting the process of aggregation to allow common themes to emerge.
Most important, we let poor people and those no longer poor speak for
themselves. We are fully aware that such individual narratives are inevitably
complicated by the social interaction of the interview and by people’s natural desire to present themselves in ways that are positive and consistent with
their social ideals. But by the same token, the ways in which people choose
to describe their experiences reveal a great deal about how they think their
worlds are ordered and how they think their worlds should be ordered. Of
necessity, we also bring in the literature—the perspectives of technocrats, policy makers, world leaders, economists, political scientists, philosophers, and
anthropologists who have influenced the poverty debates. But while expert
representations add an important dimension to our overall understanding
of poverty, we do not focus on them, because these voices have already been
heard. We present them sparingly, as needed. They should not drown out the
voices of the poor.
What Is Poverty? Who Is Poor?
Poverty is timeless.
—Women’s discussion group, Tecamín, Mexico
Poverty is a cruel wild animal. If you doze, it eats you up. So people are not
sleeping; they are working to prosper.
—Kevina, a 60-year-old female farmer, Bukwaime, Uganda
If one is to understand poor people’s lives and how they move out of
poverty, poverty has to be defined and measured. When the World Bank
dreams of a world free of poverty, the World Bank defines poverty. When
heads of state gather at the United Nations to pledge an attack on poverty,
the U.N. defines poverty. In our study, we do not define poverty. We let local
people define poverty for themselves.
12
Success from the Bottom Up
The ladder of life
We use a tool called the ladder of life to establish each community’s own definition of poverty and wealth and determine who in the community qualifies
as poor. A typical ladder of life discussion group has 6–15 participants who
are purposively selected to represent different social and economic groups in
the community. The discussions last from two to four hours; where possible,
they are held separately with men and women.
The activity starts with an icebreaker exercise in which the group discusses
the most important factors that have facilitated and hindered prosperity in
their community. Participants then create a figurative ladder of well-being, with
the bottom step representing the poorest or worst-off people found in that
community and the top step the wealthiest or best-off. Participants discuss and
describe the household characteristics that define each step of the ladder and
the typical ways in which households can move up or down the ladder.
The group then sorts up to 150 households in the community onto the
ladder steps. They identify each household’s placement initially (approximately 10 years ago, around 1995) and currently (in 2005). Based on these
rankings, we develop a community mobility matrix that shows which households moved up or down the ladder or stayed at the same step over the 10-year
study period. Examples of the mobility matrixes are presented in chapter 3.
After sorting the households, the focus group identifies a community
poverty line (CPL). The CPL is drawn between two steps of the ladder:
households at steps below the line are considered poor and those at steps
above the line are considered not poor. Just as different focus groups create
ladders with different numbers of steps (usually four to six), they can set the
poverty line wherever they think is appropriate for their own community.
In the example shown in table 1.1, the focus groups set the line between
steps 2 and 3 in a village in Andhra Pradesh and between steps 4 and 5 in
a village in Uganda.
The mapping of households onto the community mobility matrix allows
us to categorize them in terms of their poverty mobility or lack of mobility during the study period. Households may have moved up or down or
remained stuck at the same step of the ladder. Those that have moved may or
may not have crossed the community poverty line. Throughout the book, we
refer to four mobility categories:
• Movers: households that were poor in 1995 but had moved out of poverty
by 2005
• Chronic poor: households that were poor in 1995 and remained poor in
2005
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
13
• Never poor: households that were not poor in 1995 and remained not
poor in 2005
• Fallers: households that were not poor in 1995 but fell into poverty by
2005
Thus throughout our study, the terms “poor people” and “poverty” refer
to households identified by the ladder of life focus groups as poor. No more.
No less. Each discussion group’s definition is what it is. Mobility status is not
assigned by the outside researchers, nor is it assessed by the household itself.
Poverty is a problem of the many, not the few
There is no economic inequality here. Everyone is poor.
—Men’s discussion group, Chakax, Mexico
When you give a person that much [income at the official poverty line],
also prepare a prison for him or her, because after a few hours she or he
will already start stealing.
—Discussion group, Chubaka, Kagera, Tanzania
Construction of the ladder of life and the community mobility matrix
allows us to gain an overall picture of poverty and wealth in a community.
Using the community-created definitions of poverty, there is no question
that poverty is perceived as a problem of the many, not the few. In a typical
country or study region, more than 60 percent of households were classified as currently in poverty, and in every single study region, the fraction of
households classified as poor was more than 40 percent (figure 1.1).3 And as
the focus groups recall it, things used to be even worse: in the typical country
more than 70 percent of households were poor 10 years ago, in 1995.
These poverty percentages are much higher than those that would result
from applying the “$1 a day” measure often used in international circles
as the poverty line. Our focus group perceptions often aligned fairly closely
with a standard based on $2 a day—sometimes higher, sometimes lower, but
nearly always closer than to the $1 a day standard.
Is this expansive definition of poverty reasonable? The key debate is around
two alternative conceptions of poverty. One defines poverty down: the poor are
the destitute, the wretched, those on the fringes of society, the poorest of the
poor. This characterization makes the poor seem different from the rest of us
and casts poverty as a problem of the few. Some (but not all) focus groups did
associate such characteristics with the households at the very bottom step of
the ladder of life. That is, in some villages the focus groups reserved the bot-
14
Success from the Bottom Up
TABLE 1.1
Sample ladders of life from two villages in Andhra Pradesh and Uganda
Ladder constructed
in Kamalapur,
Andhra Pradesh
% of
households
Ladder constructed in
Bufkaro, Uganda
% of
households
Step 6
Landlords: Employ
servants to cultivate
their lands, own
huge buildings,
and command high
respect in the village.
Only 2 families in
the village are at this
step.
4
They can pay for a
piece of land worth
400,000 shillings in
one day. They have
permanent, wellfurnished, beautiful
houses, a means of
transport, and at least
5 cows. Their friends
are also rich and can
give them loans if they
get into a problem.
1
Step 5
Big farmers: Own
15–25 acres of
ancestral property
plus 4–5 houses,
motorbikes, fans, and
cattle. Land gives
good yields. Cultivate
crops like cotton,
chilies, soybeans.
Banks provide loans.
Educate their children
and can live without
working.
6
They own painted
cement houses, a
bicycle, and livestock,
including 2 cows, 2
goats, and 3 sheep.
They can afford to buy
a bar of soap every
week. Even when their
children are sent away
from school, they are
able to pay the fee
next morning.
6
Step 4
Medium farmers:
Own 5 acres of
land. Some have
government jobs.
Own houses with
cement walls, cattle,
borehole wells,
televisions, fans,
and cots. Eat fine
rice. Women wear
gold ornaments and
children study in
good schools. Banks
provide loans.
25
They save money to
educate their children
above primary 7. All
household members
sleep on mattresses,
and the house has
furniture. They own
livestock—about 3
goats, 1 cow, and
a chicken. But they
are forced to sell off
the animals because
they have no land for
grazing them.
14
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
Step 3
Small farmers: Own
3–5 acres of land.
Own houses and
cattle but do not
have wells. Their lives
depend on rainfall.
During periods of
drought, they migrate
to towns or work as
agricultural labor.
They are a little bit
educated.
28
They own about 1.5
acre of land, which
they cultivate. They
have iron-roofed
houses, mattresses,
and blankets. Each
member of the family
can afford at least 2
shirts, 2 trousers, and
1 coat. People at this
step also do manual
labor. Parents are able
to educate children up
to senior 2, but after
that the school sends
the child away for
want of fees. Children
at this step dress in
secondhand clothes
and shoes.
48
Step 2
Laborers with small
landholdings: Own
1–2 acres of land.
Land is rarely fertile
and they have to do
wage labor; some
serve as bonded
labor. Don’t have
proper houses. They
are illiterate and
belong to backward
and scheduled
castes. Every day is a
struggle.
26
They usually sell their
land so they can build
a house and have a
decent place to stay.
Most people do not
have shoes. They eat
meat only on big days
like Christmas and
Easter. Most children
complete primary
7, but with a lot of
struggle. They are sent
away from school for
want of uniforms.
29
Step 1
Landless laborers:
Lack proper food,
proper clothes, and
proper houses. Don’t
find work regularly
and are able to work
only 12–15 days
a month. They are
usually illiterate,
and their children
cannot attend school
because they have to
work.
11
The “unplanful”:
They work as casual
laborers for others.
They are unemployed
and have no money.
They do not care
about cleanliness and
have only one pair of
clothes that they rarely
wash. When paid
money for labor, they
use it to buy alcohol.
2
Source: Male ladder of life focus groups in Kamalapur, Andhra Pradesh, and Bufkaro, Uganda.
Note: Bold lines indicate the community poverty line.
15
16
Success from the Bottom Up
100
90
80
80
74
74
70
70
66
59
60
52
50
58
56
52
51
40
66
64
50
42
42
30
20
10
fra
N
SE
G
U
uv
(In
(R
AL
M
TA
N
)
(In
f
r
a
A
(P )
a
U ne
P
l
BA (C )
N ast
e
(
W Em )
po
B
w
(L
an )
dd
AP ist
)
(
PH SHG
I(
)
P
TH ane
l)
A
(
M Ine
EX q)
CO (Eth
n
AS L (C )
SA o
M nf)
(C
PH on
I ( f)
C
SR onf
I( )
IN
C
D on
O
f)
(C
on
f)
0
)
% below community-defined poverty line
FIGURE 1.1
More than half of all households were classified as poor in 2005
Study region
Source: Ladder of life discussion groups.
Note:
AP (SHG) = Andhra Pradesh, Self-help groups
ASSAM (Conf )= Assam, Conflict
BAN (Empow) = Bangladesh, Women’s
empowerment
COL (Conf) = Colombia, Conflict
INDO (Conf) = Indonesia, Conflict
MAL (Infra) = Malawi, Infrastructure
MEX (Ethn) = Mexico, Ethnicity
PHI (Conf) = Philippines, Conflict
PHI (Panel) = Philippines, Panel study
SEN (Infra) = Senegal, Infrastructure
SRI (Conf) = Sri Lanka, Conflict
TAN (Ruv) = Tanzania, Ruvuma
THAI (Ineq) = Thailand, Inequality
UGA (Panel) = Uganda, Panel study
UP (Caste) = Uttar Pradesh, Caste
WB (Landdist) = West Bengal, Land distribution
reforms
tom step for those with problematic behaviors (e.g., too much drinking) or
physical disadvantages (e.g., disability) or social stigma (e.g., widows with no
sons). But this category, where it existed, was usually very small, many times
containing only one or two households. As seen in table 1.1, people in the bottom category in Bufkaro, Uganda—some of whom spend their meager wages
on alcohol—represented just 2 percent of all households. They were a small
minority even of those considered the bottom poor.
In the alternative definition of poverty, the poor are those who have
some things but lack enough of the important things that they are considered poor. This is clearly the concept of poverty that, by and large, the focus
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
17
groups used. They typically did not single out the bottommost group as “the
poor,” but rather included several categories on the lower end of the ladder
as collectively experiencing poverty.
Table 1.1 shows ladders of life constructed by men’s focus groups in two
sample villages in Uganda and Andhra Pradesh. Both groups created ladders
with six steps. As people move up the ladder, they accumulate more assets
and no longer engage in casual or bonded labor. Vulnerability declines. There
are some discontinuities, particularly in relation to owning permanent housing, but overall there are few sharp distinctions just below and just above
the poverty line. The groups distinguished households by some mix of six
characteristics:
• Occupation and land ownership. In Kamalapur, Andhra Pradesh, the step
just below the CPL includes laborers with small landholdings of 1–2
acres. Just above the CPL are small farmers with 3–5 acres, who may also
do wage labor during periods of drought. The bottom category consists
of landless laborers who do not find regular work.
• Assets and savings. In Bufkaro, Uganda, households just below the CPL
own mattresses and some furniture. They also have a few animals—
“three goats, one cow, and a chicken”—but often have to sell them off.
Those just above the CPL own more livestock, typically two goats, three
cows, and three sheep. In Kamalapur, households below the CPL don’t
have proper houses; those above the CPL own houses, which become
larger and finer as one moves up the ladder.
• Consumption. In Kamalapur, those at the bottom of the ladder “lack
proper food” while those two steps above the CPL “eat fine rice.” In
Bufkaro, lack of clothing partly defines those low on the ladder. Those at
steps 1 and 2 have just one soiled set of clothes and no shoes, but at step
3 each person can afford at least two shirts, two trousers, and one coat,
although children are clad in secondhand clothes and shoes.
• Education of household head and children. In Kamalapur, people at step 1
are illiterate, and their children cannot attend school because they have
to work. By step 3, just above the CPL, people are “a little bit educated,”
and at step 4 their children “study in good schools.” In Bufkaro, step
2 households can give their children seven years of primary schooling,
but it is a struggle. At step 3, children can go up to “senior 2” but cannot
progress further because families cannot afford school fees. Households
at step 5, above the CPL, have no problem paying the fees. The desire to
educate children appears in all categories; what varies is the ability to
send children to school.
18
Success from the Bottom Up
• Behavioral characteristics. Households in the very lowest category in
Bufkaro “when paid money for labor . . . use it to buy alcohol.” Apart
from this, there is no mention of behavior.
• Social status. High status and respect is only mentioned in the very top
categories. Households at step 6 in Kamalapur “employ servants” and
“command high respect in the village.” In many other village ladders, the
top category consists of bosses and landlords, those who can tell others
what to do.
Across our study sites, as in Kamalapur and Bufkaro, there is decreasing
vulnerability as people rise up the ladder and accumulate assets. Although
some of our focus groups identified a small category of destitute and dysfunctional households on the very bottom rung of the ladder, this is not their
overall view of poverty. Rather, they see poverty as a condition that affects the
majority of the population—and is a risk to nearly all.
One women’s discussion group in Assam described people just below
the poverty line this way: “Their behavior is good. They work hard and have
food daily. They also have 2–3 bighas of land. Their houses are usually made
of mud walls with a tin roof.” A similar description would apply to many,
perhaps most, of the households in our study communities. For the overwhelming majority of people in these communities, then, the definition of
poverty can be summed up in a few words: the poor are us.
Key Findings
Seven key findings emerge from our research. These findings, highlighted here
and discussed in depth in subsequent chapters, link to our conceptual framework that defines mobility largely as the interaction between two concepts:
the initiative poor people take to move out of poverty and the opportunity they
have to do so, facilitated or constrained by local-level social, political, and
economic institutions.
Poor people are not trapped in a culture of poverty
People want to work, want to improve. They’re getting organized. Isn’t that
something good?
—Doralis, a poor woman, Villa Rosa, Colombia
Poor people have aspirations but they are not met. Rich people have aspirations that can be achieved.
—Suka, a 45-year-old woman, Tattantok, Indonesia
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
19
I couldn’t have come to this position if I hadn’t labored, dealing in rice
and paddy. You have to maintain prestige and at the same time work hard.
Doing both, I have been able to get my children educated. That’s the best
achievement in my life.
— Abdus Salam, a male mover, Satgailijhara, Bangladesh
Three ideologies have long shaped thinking about poverty and “the
poor.” The first two can be traced back to the Industrial Revolution, when
large numbers of poor people emerged in the cities of England. The Victorian
view is that people are poor because of their character deficits and moral failings; hence charity combined with uplifting moral instruction is the appropriate solution. Marxists, by contrast, argue that the system is stacked against
the poor, and thus the poor can be helped only by changing the system. Poor
people are rightly fatalistic, by this logic, and their own initiative has no
role to play. Although these two worldviews differ radically, both deny poor
people their agency.
In the past century, American anthropologist Oscar Lewis posited a
“culture of poverty” (1959, 1966). He described it as a complex of many
characteristics including alienation, passivity, laziness, feelings of powerlessness and unworthiness, and low aspirations, not to mention addictions,
alcoholism, and crime. These cultural deficits, he argued, are passed from
generation to generation within families. His views have informed debates
and policy making on welfare in the United States. There is still a persistent
belief, though it may be vehemently denied, that poor people have no one to
blame but themselves for their plight. Most recently, Charles Karelis (2007)
uses cultural factors to explain the persistence of poverty in the United States
and around the world.
In our study, we find very little evidence that poor people are trapped
in a culture of poverty. Even in the desperately poor country of Malawi or
conflict-torn communities in Indonesia and the Philippines, poor people seldom seem apathetic. Instead, they take initiatives, often pursuing many small
ventures simultaneously to survive and get ahead. Some do manage to move
out of poverty. In country after country, when we asked movers to name the
top three reasons for their move out of poverty, the answers most frequently
emphasized people’s own initiative in finding jobs and starting new businesses (figure 1.2). The distribution is very similar when we examine the
reasons given for any upward movement by the chronic poor. This picture,
detailed in chapter 2, is far removed from a culture of laziness, passivity, and
criminality.
20
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 1.2
Movers most frequently cite initiatives as reasons for their move out of poverty
Increased
community
Illegal
prosperity,
activities,
1.6%
0.1%
Functioning
NGO
of government,
assistance,
Lottery/luck,
3.4%
0.3%
0.0%
Hard work,
5.5%
Other,
7.1%
Asset
accumulation,
4.7%
Individual initiative
(nonagriculture),
60.1%
Individual initiative
(agriculture),
17.4%
Source: Authors’ analysis of household survey; all study regions; N = 3,991 movers.
Note: Figures are percentages of reasons cited by movers when asked to name the top three reasons for
their movement out of poverty. “Individual initiative (nonagriculture)” includes finding jobs, investing in
business, adding new sources of income, and migration.
Such initiative taking is common even among people who do not succeed in moving out of poverty. In India, where we did detailed analyses of
2,700 life stories, we find the chronic poor taking as many initiatives as the
rich. Yet they have stayed poor. We find little evidence that poor people are
poor because of laziness, drunkenness, or disinterest in work and saving. On
the contrary, a refrain heard in country after country was the importance of
hard work and of a healthy body to do hard work. A men’s discussion group
in Bufkaro, Uganda, summed up by saying, “The capital of a poor person is
his physical strength. He uses his strength.”
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
21
FIGURE 1.3
Gambling, drugs, and alcohol are rarely cited as reasons for falling
Functioning of
local democracy,
2.6%
Gambling, alcohol,
drug addiction,
0.7%
Other,
8.7%
Decreasing national/local
prosperity,
22.3%
Job loss/
unemployment,
7.4%
Failure of
initiative
(nonagriculture),
6.0%
Asset
depletion,
9.3%
Family
problems/expenses,
11.6%
Health/death shocks
and natural disasters,
19.4%
Failure of
initiative
(agriculture),
12.0%
Source: Authors’ analysis of household survey; all study regions; N = 3,661 (all four mobility groups).
Note: Figures are percentages of reasons cited by respondents in all mobility groups when asked to name
the top three reasons for their downward movement.
Poor people are not saints. In a few communities in every country, and
particularly in the conflict-affected contexts, we do find a few of the households at the lowest step afflicted by alcoholism, drugs, family disintegration,
and hopelessness. But such severe problems affect a very small percentage of
those who are poor. Gambling, drugs, and alcohol are seldom mentioned as
reasons for falling by any group (figure 1.3). Instead, declines in national and
local economic prosperity, health and death shocks, and family expenses play
the most important roles in the downward slide.
22
Success from the Bottom Up
The majority of poor people in our study do not lack confidence,
although confidence is reinforced by the positive experience of moving up.
Even in conflict-affected contexts, people display courage, tenacity, and goal
orientation. Pedro, a 32-year-old who lives in the crime-ridden barrio of
Santa María in Colombia, says, “I feel confident because I like setting goals
for myself. I like moving on, overcoming obstacles.”
Self-confidence and initiative should go hand in hand with high aspirations for the future. Indeed, we find that 78 percent of all households interviewed believe that their children will be better off in the years to come.
Strikingly, more than 90 percent of households in the low-income contexts of
Bangladesh, Senegal, Afghanistan, and Andhra Pradesh had high aspirations
for their children’s future. Clearly, most poor parents are not transmitting
expectations of poverty to their children.
These findings have three important implications for poverty reduction
strategies. When countries experience mass poverty—when more than 60
percent of the nation is poor, as in Zambia, or half the nation, as in Malawi,
or one-third of the nation, as in India—this cannot be the result of large numbers of people engaging in bad conduct. Charity-oriented and other paternalistic programs may ease the pain for a few in the short run, but they are totally
inadequate to lift entire nations or communities out of poverty.
Poverty assessments, the main diagnostic tools used by organizations
concerned about poverty reduction, also focus on measuring the characteristics of the poor in the bottom quintiles and measuring and describing how
they differ from the better off. Implicitly, they assume that poor people’s
characteristics are the problem. Instead, studies should focus much more
on understanding the contextual constraints to poor people’s initiatives and
how to expand economic opportunity at the local level.
When economic prosperity is low and half the population is poor, redistributive programs that are supposed to give everyone a little may help poor
people cope. But they rarely build permanent assets that reduce vulnerability: the resources they provide are often tiny, and they seldom reach everyone. In Malawi, a discussion group described a food-for-work program in
their village. “It has brought social inequality because in the whole community, they only chose two people. . . . Development work is not supposed
to choose. . . . You only get two people. How are these two people going to
improve the whole community?”
Such programs cannot lift large numbers of people out of poverty. Social
protection programs should be generous enough to enable poor people to
survive shocks and build assets to lift them out of poverty. Moreover, the
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
23
focus has to shift to increasing local-level economic prosperity, unblocking
opportunity, providing business know-how so that poor people’s initiatives
pay off, and stopping the bleeding from health shocks. Chapter 2 explores
these findings in greater depth.
Poverty is a condition, not a characteristic
My father’s illness is our family problem, because I even fear to imagine
what our life would be without our father, in whom lay all our hopes and
aspirations.
—Munmi, a female youth, Thengal Gaon, Assam
A poor person is like a prisoner. Circumstances deny him freedom to join
others in doing things. He is always anxious about how he will get food
and clothing to cover his body. . . . It’s not like dressing to look better, but
dressing just to cover up the body because his clothes are dirty.
—Men’s discussion group, Matdombo, Malawi
Is being poor more like being left-handed or like having a cold? This
question may sound a little crazy, but that is the point. The question describes
two different aspects of the human experience. One consists of stable, permanent characteristics like our biological sex, or our adult height, or lefthandedness. These characteristics tend to be integral to our identity, although
that is not always the case. The other consists of short-term, contingent situations or conditions that people experience, like wearing a red shirt or having a
cold. They may persist for a long or short time, but they are not by definition
permanent and they do not define our identity.
There are now hundreds of organizations seeking to address the problem
of poverty. There is more and more talk of “the poor.” Who are “the poor”?
Where do “the poor” live? How will “the poor” be affected by globalization?
But the term “the poor” is itself misleading, because it lumps together individuals who may have nothing more in common than a transitory experience
of poverty.
There is nothing intrinsically wrong with creating an empirical category
based on a characterization of the fraction of the population having a certain
experience. For example, statisticians can, and do, identify the fraction of
people who were pregnant at the time of a household survey. This group,
“the pregnant,” would share some demographic characteristics (they would
all be women, in a limited age bracket), and they would probably tend to
have certain social characteristics and behaviors (in a marriage/partnership,
24
Success from the Bottom Up
sexually active) in common as well. Yet no one would think of “the pregnant”
as identifying a stable set of individuals. We all recognize pregnancy as a transitory condition that is an experience or situation of individuals at certain
points in their lives.
Using our analysis of the community mobility matrixes in the study villages and the qualitative data in the life stories, we find, most boldly stated,
that poverty is not a problem of “the poor.” That is, although there might be a
small group of people for whom “poor” is a stable ascriptive identity, for most
people, poverty is a situation. Poverty is not, by and large, a permanent characteristic of households. It is a condition, something households experience.
How do we know this? Our analysis yielded three key insights, all of which
point to poverty as an experience. One, people in our study communities do
not see being poor as an identity. Two, there is lots of movement up and down
the ladder. Three, there are strong location effects; that is, which community
you live in matters. Chapter 3 explores these findings in greater depth.
There is no evidence that poor people or others in local communities see
being poor as an identity. In the ladders of life, described above, there were
typically more similarities than differences between households just above and
households just below the poverty line. This is not consistent with the notion
of being poor as an identity. Moreover, if poverty were a socially constructed
identity—either self-ascribed or imposed by society—then one could not talk of
escaping it through individual effort. Yet when asked how one could move out
of poverty, nearly all groups, including disabled people, emphasized individual
effort, self-reliance, and initiative. These are pathways out of a situation, not an
identity. In life stories too, people clearly identify periods of poverty—but they
emphasize that this was a situation to be coped with, not a permanent fate.
If “the poor” were in poverty because of some stable, permanent characteristic (such as being illiterate), we wouldn’t have seen them experience
any upward climb in the short run without a change in that characteristic. Yet
our evidence suggests that there is considerable upward movement of people
in poverty within localities in rural areas. This is not to say that there are no
“poverty traps,” only that most people currently in poverty are probably not
in a poverty trap because of their personal characteristics. In the typical study
region, almost half of all households that began in poverty moved up by at
least one step on the ladder of life. The average proportion of households
moving out of poverty altogether was almost a quarter.
Statistics of net reduction or increase in poverty levels at any point in
time hide two opposing effects: movement out of poverty and movement
into it. To find the net reduction in poverty, we must count those who move
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
25
out of poverty less those who fall into poverty over the given period. Our
sampled communities in Malawi, for instance, registered a marginal increase
in net poverty of less than 1 percent. But this stagnation did not mean calm.
Looking more closely, we see that 10.2 percent of all Malawi households
sorted for the ladder of life exercise had moved out of poverty. At the same
time, nearly 10.6 percent of households fell into poverty. The extent of falling
thus negated the positive news on upward movement.
Across study regions, our evidence suggests very high levels of mobility,
both up and down. In the typical study region, three times as many people
moved up or down as the net number of people who moved out of poverty.
This fluidity of households is important for policy. If “the poor” were a fixed
group, then they could be identified and reached by narrowly targeted transfer programs. But with so much rising and falling, the underlying vulnerabilities of large numbers of people have to be addressed. Poverty-reducing
strategies have to help people build permanent assets and livelihoods to help
them cope with fluctuating life circumstances in tight economies.
No one doubts that living in a country with sustained, rapid economic
growth improves one’s chances of moving out of poverty. But absolute poverty
reduction at the national level often hides enormous local variability. Our data
suggest that local conditions do matter significantly for poverty mobility. Two
key findings support this result. First, we find large variation across villages
both in prosperity levels and in upward movement from poverty. There are
communities in which a majority moved out of poverty and communities in
which almost nobody did. Second, the differences seem to be largely local. In
fact, a simple analysis of variance across communities shows that only 25 percent of the variation in upward movement of the poor can be attributed to the
study region or country; the remaining 75 percent depends on the community
of study within a country. When community-level effects are so strong, poverty
is clearly not just an individually determined characteristic.
Economic, social, and political factors make a difference to community
mobility. Positive factors that favor movement out of poverty include overall
economic prosperity (especially ease in finding jobs), the physical presence
of markets in a village, and proximity to cities and roads. Local government
responsiveness also makes a positive difference. On the other hand, mobility
is hindered by the presence of a large proportion of poor people in a village
and by deep social divisions, which impede fair access to markets, facilities,
and services. Somewhat less obviously, propensity toward collective action
is also negatively related to mobility. Our qualitative evidence shows that
in highly socially stratified communities—as in caste-dominated India, for
26
Success from the Bottom Up
example—poor people are excluded from the networks of the rich and pursue collective action with each other to cope and survive because they are
poor; hence the negative sign.
Together, our findings belie the notion that poverty is a permanent or
semi-permanent characteristic of individuals. If people were permanently
trapped in poverty because of some stable identity, we wouldn’t have observed
large upward movements out of poverty. Nor would we have observed such
high levels of movement of households up or down (churning). Finally, if
mobility from poverty were largely an individual or country-of-residence
phenomenon, village-level differences wouldn’t matter.
The search for solutions should thus go below the national level to focus
on local communities. The emphasis needs to shift to contextual efforts to
increase local prosperity by providing roads and markets, improving local
government attentiveness, and working to smooth social inequalities, including through organizations of poor people. Diagnostic tools to aid poverty
reduction need to take into account local contexts and the factors that facilitate community prosperity. They should seek to answer the question that
arises next: If poverty is a temporary condition, what determines whether
households escape poverty or not?
In general, as our study in Kagera, Tanzania, demonstrates, existing economic models are better at predicting falling than at predicting movement out
of poverty.4 Our study seeks to do a better job of explaining which people move
out of poverty, and how they do it, by examining local processes in depth and
locating individuals within these local contexts. Our analysis is guided by a
conceptual framework that examines the interactions between poor people’s
initiatives and opportunities within the context of local-level institutions. We
examine the extent to which social stratification conditions poor people’s access
to economic and political opportunities, either individually or collectively. The
framework is discussed in greater detail at the end of this chapter.
Power “within” can help a person move up
What restricts me is just the amount of money I get. But I am not confined
inside. I think big.
—Milward, a man in chronic poverty, Guluteza, Malawi
Power is capability. Every person who has capability is able to be in command of everything. For example, though we are poor, if we have strong
will then we can do anything.
—Discussion with young boys, Patobako, Indonesia
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
27
In thousands of conversations with men and women in our study, inner
strength and confidence emerge time and again as a key factor in moving out
of poverty. Moreover, self-confidence increases quickly as poor people experience some success. In fact, poor people soon start looking very similar to the
rich in their sense of confidence and inner strength.
During the household interviews, we asked people to rank themselves
on a 10-step ladder of power and rights, with a ranking of 1 meaning they
feel totally powerless and a ranking of 10 meaning they feel powerful and in
control. We use this measure as a proxy for self-confidence, defining those
on the top seven rungs as feeling empowered and those on the bottom three
rungs as feeling powerless (figure 1.4).
Three patterns are striking. First, it is the fallers, those who were not poor
10 years ago but who are poor today, who feel the least confident and power-
FIGURE 1.4
The never poor and movers score themselves higher in power and rights
100
% households with higher power and rights
90
82
80
74
70
60
50
43
40
33
30
20
10
0
Never poor
Movers
Chronic poor
Fallers
Source: Authors’ analysis of household survey; all study regions where data were available; N = 8,319.
Note: Households with “high” power and rights were those that rated themselves at 4 or above on a
10-step ladder of power and rights in 2005.
28
Success from the Bottom Up
ful. Only 33 percent of the fallers feel empowered, compared to 43 percent
of the chronic poor.
Second, while the chronic poor on average rate themselves lower in
power than movers and the never poor, almost half do feel empowered. This
makes it difficult to argue that there is a generic lack of confidence among
“the poor.”
Third, confidence appears to be dynamic and related to experience. We
see this when we compare people’s rankings 10 years ago and today. Ten
years ago, when they were not yet poor, nearly 60 percent of the fallers felt
empowered; only 33 percent feel empowered today. Conversely, only 42
percent of the movers scored themselves as empowered 10 years ago, when
they were still poor; now that they have escaped poverty, nearly 74 percent
feel empowered. This implies that the well-off lose a sense of power as they
experience a decline and the poor gain confidence as they move up. There
are no inherent differences in confidence between the poor and rich; it is
a matter of circumstances. A men’s discussion group in Boodanpur, Uttar
Pradesh, confirms the virtuous cycle of poverty escapes: “People start feeling more powerful after coming out of poverty because their relations with
other people start improving. There is a common saying: a hungry man only
invites further drought and is not welcome anywhere. A rich man, however,
is welcome everywhere.”
Chapter 4 highlights the importance of self-confidence and personal
agency in movement out of poverty. Our evidence emerges both from multivariate regression analysis and from life stories. In the regression analysis,
our measure for a household’s movement out of poverty is constructed using
the community perception, not the household’s own rating of its status. This
reduces the potential bias that could arise from regressing a person’s own
declaration of mobility against his or her perception of a host of other factors, including psychological well-being. We construct a measure of power
and control by combing the self-ratings on power and another question on
extent of control over daily decision making. We make no claims of causality;
for that, we turn to the life stories. These chronicle and sequence events over
a person’s lifetime, with particular attention to the last 10 years.
Our results from multivariate regression analyses suggest strong associations between self-rated power and mobility in several countries, even
after controlling for 22 or more other community and household variables,
including education and assets. The orders of magnitude are illustrative. In the
Indian states of Uttar Pradesh and Assam and in Bangladesh, Indonesia, and
Uganda, the association is strong and positive. In Bangladesh, for instance, a
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
29
2-unit increase in individual control is associated with a 15 percent increase
in the probability of moving out of poverty. We find even stronger and more
consistently positive associations for another psychological variable, aspirations for the future, in 10 of the 15 study regions for which we have quantitative data. In West Bengal, a 2-unit increase in aspirations is associated with a
35 percent increase in the probability of escaping poverty.
Milward, a chronic poor man in Guluteza, Malawi, emphasizes the
importance of personal agency. “I have struggled over the years and have been
able to pass through. This has increased my confidence. Now I depend on no
one. Whenever there is anything to be solved in our family, I do it alone with
my wife. I have to mention here that having my wife at my side increases my
confidence.” Milward’s self-confidence has expanded as he has gained social
standing and respect in the community. He was recently chosen to be the clan
overseer in his village. “I sit down and think how people can have confidence
in me like that. And I think to myself what I should do so people take me to
be responsible enough? Then I put on more courage.”
Paradoxically, while poor people sometimes describe poverty as a python
squeezing the breath out of them, they simultaneously express strong belief
in their own ability to overcome the odds. As 60-year-old Gudelia from Los
Rincones, Colombia, says, “We don’t think in negative terms, and that is why
we are able to bear our situation.”
Yet poor people are not naïve about the environment in which they live
or the amount of influence they have. During group discussions, they draw
a clear distinction between good power and bad or coercive power. They are
aware of inequality but for the most part accept a certain amount of inequality as a given. Across countries, one of the most common metaphors about
inequality uses the hand and fingers: “See my hand. Are the fingers equal?
No, one will always be tall.”
Poor parents contain their fears and mostly do not transmit them to their
children. In discussions with youths about their aspirations, we found that
most young people do not see themselves as locked into their parents’ occupation. They have big dreams of doing better than their parents—by starting
businesses, becoming lawyers and doctors, having salaried jobs, modernizing
their farms, and fighting for justice in their communities.
A range of assets and capabilities can facilitate or hinder the exercise of
personal agency. One of the biggest hindrances is health shocks, which lead
to reduced earnings, additional expenditures, and sometimes the death of
the main breadwinner. A greater sense of control, not surprisingly, is associated with lower incidence of health shocks, as well as with more household
30
Success from the Bottom Up
assets, house ownership, and an educated head of household. People who
scored high on the ladder of power and rights were also more likely to have
engaged in political activities, such as by contacting their local politician for
a personal favor.
Our findings on personal agency are also important for how development is done. Development interventions should be carried out in ways that
respect and increase—rather than detract from—people’s confidence in themselves and their families. Participatory and community-driven approaches
reinforce people’s own sense of agency. Entrenched gender inequalities can
be addressed in part through investment in organizations of poor women.
Steps to increase material assets, particularly permanent housing, can reinforce poor people’s self-confidence and give them an economic foundation
to build on. Equally important are strategies to prevent and buffer health
shocks. Finally, it is crucial to direct poor people’s initiatives to activities for
which there are markets.
Belief in self can take people far, but it cannot make up for lack of economic opportunity and blocked access to opportunity in the communities
where poor people live. Skewed opportunity structures thwart poor people’s
initiatives. Unblocking these opportunity structures requires changes in three
basic institutions: markets, local democracies, and poor people’s collective
groups. These changes are taken up in the remaining chapters of the book.
Equal opportunity remains a dream
There is a ditch in front of us and a well behind us.
—Women’s discussion group, Govindapalle, Andhra Pradesh
The rich are moving very fast because they have many economic opportunities. When you buy a matchbox from the rich person’s shop, you are adding
him with more money and as for you, you lose. The poor are moving slowly,
because there is limited economic change for them. The rich do not want
to share with the poor.
—Discussion with men, Bupungi, Uganda
Poor people face agonizingly limited economic choices, very different from the gilded choices of the rich. We probed opportunity sets, or the
choices available to the rich and poor within communities. In most places,
even those where the local economy is booming, we find that equal opportunity remains elusive.
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
31
Let us compare two life stories from Bangladesh. Nobi is a 51-year-old
man who has never been poor; indeed, by the standards of his community
he is rich. Rahimuddin, age 50, has always been poor. Both men live in the
relatively prosperous village of Pirjadi, where 3 out of 10 people moved out
of poverty in our study, higher than the average for Bangladesh (2/10).
Nobi’s father owned about 22 acres of land in Pirjadi. “He spent money
like anything,” says Nobi. “With so much land, it was possible to live with luxury.” Nobi’s father enrolled him in school at the age of six but Nobi dropped
out at 14, saying studying did not interest him. Nobi joined a local theater
company and toured with them until he was 25. His father tried to stop him,
but Nobi resisted. “We were in a good position, and there was no scarcity in
the house,” Nobi says. “Money was not as important as entertainment.”
Nobi did start farming, at the age of 17. He tried sugarcane, then vegetables. He invested in machinery and a tubewell for irrigation and then
diversified into other businesses. He bought and supplied insecticides, he
opened a nursery to sell saplings, he started cultivating pineapples, and he
tried farming fish. At the time of the interview, Nobi had successfully sent
one of his sons to Saudi Arabia, which he called the highest point in his life.
“Sending my son was a question of respect and honor,” he adds. “If someone
stays abroad then the house develops automatically.”
Nobi also provides financial support to his two other sons, neither of
whom turned out to be a great worker. His life has been relatively free of
shocks. Two years prior to the interview, he suffered a stroke, but he was able
to afford treatment in a good hospital in Dhaka. Reflecting on his good fortune, Nobi adds, “I know I inherited a lot of property. But proper utilization
of inherited property is also important.”
Rahimuddin’s life unfolded much differently. He was born in another
village to a destitute family, and his father died before he was born. His
mother begged alms to raise him. Unlike Nobi, who had the choice of going
to school, Rahimuddin is illiterate. He says, “In this life, I have no idea what
is a school. My mother fed me by begging. How could I get educated?”
His first job was at the age of five, when he worked as a domestic servant
to a middle-class family in his village. “I stayed at my employer’s house. I
worked there for years for food in lieu of wages. I was in a good condition
there. My mother would also stay with me. My employer would give me 70
taka in a year, which I would give to my mother. I would do all kinds of work:
rearing cows, weeding land, doing errands, everything.”
Rahimuddin continued to work as hired help until he turned 21. He
married in 1976 and migrated a year later to Pirjadi to work as a daily wage
32
Success from the Bottom Up
laborer. He tried other work as well: he made hand fans from grass and grew
chilies on a sharecropping basis. But his income didn’t increase. “There is no
income. People buy one fan in a year. Some people don’t even buy that. Still,
I make them if someone wants them,” he says of the only skill he knows. Of
chilies, he says, “I have leased two gondas of land. I give half of the crop to the
landowner. The soil is not good for cultivating paddy [rice] so I grow chilies
in it. I don’t even get 100 taka by selling it.” He also thinks the landowner
mixes powdered husk into the chilies.
To supplement his meager income, Rahimuddin’s wife now cleans other
people’s houses. His elder son works as a tailor in a nearby town. Both he
and his wife are constantly ill, but they cannot afford to see a doctor. He
hears insults from the relatives with whom he lives because he does not own
a home. He cannot marry off his daughter because he cannot afford a dowry.
He concludes sadly: “I feel like going somewhere, leaving everything behind.
But where should I go? Wherever I go, I’ll have to work as a day laborer for my
stomach. . . . There is no upward movement. My 50 years of life is entirely a
loan. There is no capital. There is no way to repay. If I die now, I will be buried
in someone else’s land. People will even have to donate my shroud.”
Rahimuddin lives in a community with a growing economy. But given all
his disadvantages and lack of any sort of capital, he has stayed poor despite a
lifetime of work. Clearly, if one is poor, it is better to live in a prosperous area
than in a generally poor area. But local prosperity offers no protection against
exploitation. Even poor people in booming economies may find themselves
cycling through a series of low-value, dead-end activities.
In the coffee-growing area of Ngimyoni, Tanzania, traders often cheat
poor producers while weighing the coffee brought to the market for sale.
Such trickery even has a name, masomba, which means making the coffee as
weightless as a sunflower. So the small farmer who hands over 60 kilograms
of coffee may be paid for only 50 kilograms. Stretched thin, small coffee cultivators in Ngimyoni often borrow money from the better-off in their community, but here too they may be cheated. Before giving the farmer a loan,
the lender may force him to sign an agreement saying he has borrowed three
times the amount actually lent.
Poor cultivators across study regions, with their one bag of coffee or
clutch of bananas, find themselves in no position to negotiate with bigger
buyers. Their immediate cash needs often force them to accept the miserable
prices offered or cave in to exploitative terms when taking a loan. Farmers in
Bamlozi, Malawi, noted that “the small easily suffocate. It is very easy to eat
up the little capital you have due to food insecurity in the home.”
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
33
Chapter 5 discusses interventions to increase prosperity at the local level
and make markets work more fairly for poor people’s tiny enterprises. The
business climate for poor people is very different from the one that large businesses enjoy. We call for liberalization from below. This includes removing
restrictive government regulations; expanding access to markets, especially by
providing connectivity through roads, bridges, and telephones; and integrating poor people’s businesses on fairer terms in new business models. Poor
people’s economic organizations and business know-how are very important
in helping them overcome problems of scale and move up the value chain
in order to get higher return for their labor. Collective action is so important
that we have devoted an entire chapter to this issue, chapter 7, where we
also discuss moving toward poor people’s corporations. We also offer two
important insights about credit from our data. One is that the tiny loans usually provided under microcredit schemes do not seem to lift large numbers
of people out of poverty. Poor people need credit that enables them to go
beyond meeting immediate consumption needs and build permanent assets.
Second, credit is more likely to be used productively when it is combined
with improved local infrastructure, particularly rural roads, and with help in
connecting to and producing for markets.
When new economic possibilities open up, whether through construction of roads, liberalization of markets, or introduction of new commercial
crops, for approximately two years there seems to be a period of openness to
social change. During this time it is possible to increase equality of opportunity and effect change in social relations across lines of caste, ethnicity, or
religion. Eventually, however, new elites emerge—and new cycles of suffocation begin.
Responsive local democracies can help reduce poverty
Democracy is like a pond. In the pond there are several kinds of fish. The
pond has not only the fish, but also other animals like frogs and snakes.
The snakes catch the frog, while the big fish eat the small fish. Democracy,
too, is a pond where man eats man. People elect a leader. But later, this
leader becomes corrupt and exploits the people.
—Discussion with men, Raja Pukhuri, Assam
We have not been forgotten by God. We have been forgotten by
politicians.
—A 38-year-old man, Guadalamoros, Mexico
34
Success from the Bottom Up
Local democracies work imperfectly. Corruption abounds. Despite these
imperfections, most poor people value democracy, which they equate with
the freedom to vote, to think, to speak, to move, to protest, and to work.
“Democracy and freedom are the same,” said women in a discussion group
in San Dogon, Philippines. “We cannot experience freedom if there is no
democracy.”
We focus on the effectiveness of democracy at the local level, irrespective
of the state of democracy at the national level. At the local level, we find that
there is much more variation within countries than across countries; indeed,
93 percent of the variation in the quality of local-level democracy is explained
by within-country variation. Hence, the importance of understanding how
local politics affects poor people’s efforts to move out of poverty.
In theory, responsive local governments can play a significant role in
shaping opportunities for movement out of poverty. They do so through
two channels—one community-wide, the other individual. They can provide essential community services like health and schooling, secure law and
order, and make and enforce rules and regulations that favor livelihoods
and poor people’s initiative. Local officials also distribute government aid to
households, including food, agricultural inputs, houses, and land. They may
provide skills training through a variety of agricultural extension and nonagricultural training programs.
We set out to learn whether the practice of democracy lives up to this
promise. We wanted to find out whether there is an association between local
democracy that is viewed as responsive and the likelihood of poverty escapes.
We combine several measures to gauge responsiveness. Do people trust their
officials? Does the local democracy take into account citizen concerns? Are
people able to contact their local democracy and influence its actions? Are
they satisfied with their local democracies?
Our evidence, presented in chapter 6, suggests that responsive local
democracies may help people move out of poverty. We find that communities with more responsive local governments do in fact have better access to
clean water, schools, doctors and nurses, and public health clinics (figure
1.5). Furthermore, the quality of education and health services also registers more improvement in these communities, as does the incidence of
roads and the level of community safety. Communities where local government is responsive also have much lower corruption. The association with
individual poverty escapes is more mixed: strongly positive in some of the
South Asian contexts and negative in some of the conflict-affected sites. To
examine these processes, we turned to communities that had experienced a
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
35
FIGURE 1.5
Communities where governments became more responsive were likely to
report increased presence of services over the past 10 years
Clean water
43
Lower secondary
school
54
57
35
Upper secondary
school
65
19
80
Technical or
vocational school
0
35
Doctor
25
27
Nurse
13
More responsive
Less responsive
27
Public health clinic
19
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
% increase in access
70
80
90
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from the community questionnaire with key informants and
responses to the question: “Compared to 10 years ago, does the local government now pay more, about
the same, or less attention to what people like you think when it decides what to do?” N = 420 communities.
dramatic improvement in responsiveness of local democracy over the previous decade.
The village of Mintang in Bukidnon, Philippines, was among those that
experienced a shift in democracy, from being nonresponsive 10 years ago to
being responsive, just, and accountable to the residents of the community
today. The turning point was the election of a good leader. Nora, a woman
in Mintang, said of the village head, “Before, only the relatives of the officials
were privileged to work with them. But now, even if he [the leader] is my
cousin, I am still obliged to submit an application. He levels down to the
people. He is one of us.” Andresa added, “We just have to approach him and
ask for help, even for personal reasons. Other politicians are not similar to
him. They think only of themselves.”
36
Success from the Bottom Up
Officials at higher levels of local government were also credited with
bringing projects such as health programs and solar dryers for farming
that increased community prosperity. A male discussion group in Mintang
spoke of the role they had played. “The number one factor that helped
Mintang improve is the implementation of different projects by the barangay officials. Also, it is the style of leadership shown by the politicians in
the higher government such as the governor and the senator. They are the
ones who provided our place an opportunity to improve. If they ever press
us down, we will suffer.” The women continued, “If the current barangay
chairman goes to Manila for a seminar, he never misses to report to the
people the purpose and result of his trip. Now we often conduct assembly
meetings.”
Elections in Mintang were reported to be free and fair. In a discussion
group, men claimed, “There is no coercion. We vote for someone dictated by
our conscience.” Assembly meetings were regular and transparent, with open
discussions around issues like budgets. “The budget is shown to us during
assembly. We have access to it any time,” the men said. High levels of collective action and associations within Mintang supported democracy. Women
praised the unity, mutual understanding, and respect within the community.
“Just like a broomstick. A broomstick symbolizes unity. The midribs should
be bound together to create a broomstick. If cooperation and unity are evident among people, there is democracy.”
Villages like Mintang, while they exist, are hardly typical. Far more commonly, poor people find themselves facing political institutions that are captured by the elite. Becoming a local politician or affiliating oneself with the
right political party is a sure way to riches. The makeup of the elite in any
community changes over time, but the system of political clientelism and corruption persists. Both the rich and the poor flock to the powerful for favors.
The poor typically have to wait outside, and wait longer.
In the village of Mpusola in Malawi, drought and floods brought widespread hunger between 2002 and 2005. To avoid mass starvation, the government undertook a food distribution program. The distribution of maize and
targeted inputs was conducted by a government marketing agency that has
since been shut down. Discussion groups all agreed that poor farmers were at
a disadvantage as they could not afford to fill the pockets of officials in order
to obtain the grain. They described how corrupt staff sold the maize that was
intended for distribution, leaving a shortage in the depots. “There were times
when the maize did come to the depots. Strangely enough, the maize would
be sold at night using back doors. By the next morning, there was no maize
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
37
stock in the depots. People could starve even with money in their pockets.
Many people mixed sawdust with maize flour in order to have enough to
meet the demands of the entire family.”
A male youth group explained how political and economic alliances
worked in the village. As in politics at higher levels, political alliances determined who gained membership to powerful committees and who chaired
them. The stakes were smaller than at the national level but could still mean
the difference between survival and starvation for poor people. “There is
oppression here,” said the youths. “One person is chairing eight committees.
We do not have freedom of speech. When something comes to the village,
the village headman and his close friends make sure that they are the first
beneficiaries. We just hear later that a particular organization came to the
village and it has gone.” They added, “The friends and relatives of the village
chief do not get intimidated as they have the law on their side. The chief is
the law! Why will they be afraid?” The group went on to say that because of
preferential treatment in the distribution of government programs, the community has lost interest in “community participation.” They concluded, “The
chief chooses only those people whom he sees will remember him when that
person gets some materials. The chief is also fond of calling just those people
who he is used to in making deals to form a committee. . . . Then all you will
hear the next day is that ‘we are in such and such committee.’ All done to
continue their fraudulent ways.”
Government largesse in poor countries can be extremely limited, and
elite capture—as in Mpusola—often leaves little for the poor. Under such
circumstances, moving ahead becomes a zero-sum game: if I win, you lose.
Thus, it should not be surprising that we find poor people at times locked in
struggle with each other in a fight over limited resources. We found evidence
of this in both our qualitative and quantitative data.
There are, fortunately, ways of uncapturing local democracy. One-third
of the communities visited reported that their local government had become
more responsive over time, suggesting that change is possible. Mechanisms
included having good leaders; holding free and fair elections; providing
access to information, particularly about local government activities; and
promoting people’s participation and demand-side pressure through poor
people’s organizations. Local leaders can play a particularly important role
in expanding local economic opportunities and supporting liberalization of
economic rules and regulations that unbind from below.
The most important implication of our findings is simply that poverty
reduction strategies cannot ignore local politics, and that when they do, poor
38
Success from the Bottom Up
people are the losers. If one is to understand democracy, the focus has to be
on the local level. Demand-side pressures through self-help groups and other
organizations of women, men, and youth, even when their members are illiterate, help make local politicians more accountable. Availability of information at the local level, particularly about local politicians and government, is
key to making democracy work for all.
Collective action helps poor people cope but not get ahead
How good are these loans? We have to repay them in installments each
week. The amount they give finishes off quickly.
—Asiya, a poor woman, Hasanbagh, Bangladesh
People have developed well with the help of women’s self-help groups.
They have more knowledge. They are becoming partners in politics. They
want to know about government programs and form good, bad opinions
on parties.
—Discussion with men, Bestharapalle, Andhra Pradesh
I place a lot of importance on relations with my neighbors. They are my
only capital in life.
—Aziza, a woman in chronic poverty, Abzif, Morocco
Poor people in a community frequently come together to pool their
labor or their cash or their skills. This pooling involves tiny, tiny resources.
The paradox of this collective action is that while it may enable poor people
to cope and survive, it typically does not help them move out of poverty. Even
though it involves thousands of poor people helping each other in groups,
since the groups are scattered rather than connected or aggregated, they have
not been able to achieve the advantages that come with scale. We discuss ways
out of this deadlock in chapter 7.
Ironically, the real benefit of poor people’s collective action is to society.
Working together in small groups creates unity, trust, social cohesion, and a
sense of social belonging to units larger than the immediate family. It fosters
a sense of citizenship essential to functioning, stable, and cohesive democratic societies. This is the beginning of civil society.
In Mbata, Ruvuma, Tanzania, women came together in nsango groups to
survive the economic crisis that followed the dismantling of government-run
coffee cooperatives. Each group has 10–15 members who contribute a small
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
39
sum each week to a collective savings pool. The contributions are primarily used to buy clothes for group members and their children or to support
tiny businesses. Women may buy wheat to bake a few loaves of bread, or
sorghum to make a local brew. If the business takes off, women are able to
help others, save, and meet daily household needs. Salome says, “The money
enables us to help one another in case of an emergency. For example, when
one of the group members has a problem, she would be the first to receive
the contributions. Men do not have such groups because they own property
like livestock.”
People in Ruvuma also form collective labor groups called ngoro. These
consist of 5 to 15 men or women who help each other cultivate the region’s
steep and infertile slopes. With no cattle to provide manure, people pool their
effort to dig pits (ngoros) that are used to compost grass, weeds, and crop residues. Crops are rotated so soil fertility can be maintained. All members work
on one member’s farm for an agreed number of days, then move to another
member’s farm, and so on, until all of their farms are cultivated.
We found several instances of small, spontaneous groups like the nsango
and ngoro across our study regions. Although helpful, such groups on their
own did not lift people out of poverty. Poor people as a group lack cash,
assets, education, market know-how, and connections with the rich and powerful. When poor people associate only with each other, they bring only their
own meager resources to the table. Poor people understand these constraints
and affirm that “there is a limit to how much one hungry man can feed
another.” The challenge is to extend these positive local traditions of mutual
help so that they reach across social lines to involve those who can bring in
new resources, ideas, and skills.
This is difficult, however, and in practice, most people rely on the institution closest to them: their family. In the 2,700 life stories from India, the
family was the most frequently mentioned institution that helped people
accumulate assets. People rated help from family as more important than
help from public institutions like the government, more important than help
from civil society, and more important than engagement with the private sector (figure 1.6). This was true for all four mobility groups: the movers, fallers,
chronic poor, and never poor.
Given the universal dependence on kin, we analyze the characteristics of
successful families and discuss how other types of organizations, from small
groups to cooperatives to equity firms owned by poor people, might mimic
some of their features. We discuss a few large-scale successful efforts such as
Grameen Bank in Bangladesh, the women’s self-help movement in Andhra
40
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 1.6
Families are rated the most important institution for asset accumulation by all
mobility groups in Indian study regions
Never poor
81
Fallers
88
Chronic poor
85
Movers
82
0
20
40
60
80
% contribution to asset accumulation over lifetime
Family
Public
Civil society
100
Private
Source: Narayan, Nikitin, and Richards (2009), using coded data from life stories gathered from the
Indian study regions; N = 2,700 life stories.
Pradesh, and the community-driven development program that has spread to
over half the villages in Indonesia.
Nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) are hardly mentioned as a support in moving out of poverty. NGO assistance accounts for only 0.3 percent of the reasons cited for poverty escapes (figure 1.2). This does not mean
that NGOs are not present or doing important humanitarian work. It means
either that NGOs affect only a small number of people or that their work is
not perceived to have a direct effect on poverty. Collective action that involves
federated organizations of poor people has the potential to transform lives by
connecting poor producers to markets and involving them in economic activities higher up the value chain. But creating such organizations takes time
and financial resources and does not produce immediate returns; as a result,
this is an area of investment failure on a massive scale. Such a transformation
in thinking and practice is not easy. It requires the coming together of people
who understand local realities and community organizing, on the one hand,
with people who possess capital, business skills, and market access, on the
other. As long as these two groups, civil society and private business, remain
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
41
at war, poor people will remain excluded from markets, and important innovations, including poor people’s corporations and changes in mainstream
business models to ensure fairer returns, will not be achieved.5
Poverty reduction should be guided by lessons from poor people
Freedom means having opportunities.
—Discussion with women, Chinxe, Mexico
In sum, our evidence suggests that poor women, men, and youth doing
day labor like Mamba, tending tiny plots like Ayesha, and working in small
businesses like Adolfo do not lack the drive to do well and improve their
lives. Some, like Adolfo and Ayesha, are successful; others, like Mamba, are
not. Yet the great majority of those who are stuck in poverty do not give up;
they continue to aspire to better lives, for themselves and for their children.
Chapter 8 provides our ideas on creating poverty-reducing strategies that
build on poor people’s agency and reflect what we learned from them about
how people escape poverty.
The people we met defy the various Victorian, cultural, and Marxist interpretations of poverty that classify “the poor” as a group unable to help themselves. Poor people are not in any collective sense lazy, drunk, or stupid. They
work hard to eke out a living and seize opportunities as they arise. Indeed, a
major finding of the study is that there is no such fixed group as “the poor.”
Poverty is a condition, not a permanent identity.
Given the inadequacies of existing approaches to poverty reduction, in
our concluding reflections we offer three principles that should guide future
efforts. These principles are based on lessons from poor and recently poor
people themselves—the thousands who participated in sharing their experiences with our field teams.
The first principle is that all actions should seek to expand the scope for
people in poverty to utilize their agency, in both the public and private spheres.
Poor people have needs but reducing people to just their needs robs them of
their aspirations, dreams, ambitions, and skills—in short, of their ability to
help themselves. Poor people’s agency is important at the individual level and
also the collective level through organizations of the poor. When these organizations gain some scale and connect with markets and the public sector, poor
people become important players in decisions that impact their lives.
Across the study regions, we were struck by the faith poor people still
place in the marketplace. Faced with enormous barriers there, they still believe
42
Success from the Bottom Up
that markets will work, and they want to do business on an equal and fair
footing. Thus, the second principle is that actions should seek to transform
markets so that poor people can access and participate in them fairly. There are
several keys to expanding fair access: scaling up and linking poor people’s
livelihood activities; providing “connectedness” through roads, telephones,
electricity, and irrigation; easing access to loans that can be used for production; and providing information, business know-how, and skills to connect
to mainstream markets.
Similarly, poor people still believe that governments and their local
democracies can do good, and they want to participate in them. Freedom and
democracy are of both intrinsic and instrumental value. The third principle,
therefore, is that well-functioning local democracies can help people move out of
poverty. We saw many examples of poorly functioning local democracies. Governance at the local level is all too often a zero-sum contest for spoils, marred
by pervasive corruption that creates opportunities for some and barriers for
others. But the combination of good local leaders, fair elections, improved
access to information, participation, and collective action can enable poor
people to demand accountability from local leaders. Local leaders can do
much to liberalize and expand economies from below.
The Conceptual Framework
We started our research with broad questions. What are the processes that
result in some poor people moving out of poverty while others in the same
community remain stuck in poverty? What is the role of social relations in
moving out of poverty? How important are psychological factors and personal agency? Does local democracy make a difference? We deliberately did
not adopt any particular conceptual framework because we knew that early
marriage to concepts and measuring tools limits what you see. We wanted to
explore before we started limiting.
We deliberately collected too much data, using 10 different measuring
tools to probe the whys and hows of poverty escapes and stagnation. We
expected that this would create an enormous challenge in data analysis, and it
did. We are not recommending this as a research strategy to everyone, but we
think it is important in poverty studies to cast a wide net and to look beyond
what one might first assume to be the correct explanation.
Our data analyses proceeded in three stages. In the first phase, which
took six months, we used an inductive approach to develop a coding system
for the analysis of life stories. We let the data speak to us. After reading 200
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
43
life stories, we developed categories that would “catch” most of the information emerging from people’s descriptions of the key events in their lives and
the processes that facilitated or hindered their accumulation of assets.
In the second phase, we analyzed 60 community pairs. The communities in each pair were selected to vary in terms of one particular variable:
social stratification or democracy, collective action, and economic opportunity. In one pair, for instance, community A might differ from community
B only in levels of social stratification, holding other variables constant. We
analyzed these communities using a variant of the SOSOTEC technique that
we learned from Robert Chambers during the Voices of the Poor study.6 We
read reports, interviews, and descriptions, cut them into strips, and sorted the
ideas, gradually compiling them into subsets and larger sets and diagramming the relationships between them. Given our huge data set, this process
also took several months. The diagrams became very elaborate as our teams
mapped relationships across communities and country contexts. This technique appears disorganized and time-consuming but surpasses all others in
“letting voices emerge” during the analysis phase. In particular, it delays the
imposition of expert concepts until much later.
Figure 1.7 shows one such diagram created by our team, for the village of
Bufkaro in Uganda. In this predominantly poor community, villagers cultivate sorghum, beans, and sweet potatoes. Poor people have limited options to
invest in business opportunities, and credit is hard to get. “It is not feasible to
start a retail shop because one cannot afford to buy the items for the fear that
the loan acquired to start the business may be wasted,” explained one discussion group. The local government is not helpful. “No government programs
operate in this village because our leaders are not serious at all,” lamented
another discussion group. “No community meetings are held between the
community members and the local council authorities.” Lack of such meetings is cited as one of the reasons why the community does not receive timely
information about development programs.
While poor people struggle with daily wage labor, the handful of rich
people in the village face very different opportunity sets. They own shops
and vehicles and have money to invest in other profitable ventures to expand
their sources of income further. Their friends are other rich people who can
loan them money if the need arises. One discussion group said, “When you
are rich, you are more powerful because people respect you so much. If a poor
person is going to a rich person’s house, he fears to talk to the rich person.”
Poor people in Bufkaro come together to cope with their circumstances,
sometimes among themselves and sometimes in community-wide groups.
44
FIGURE 1.7
Collective action helps people cope in Bufkaro, Uganda
Economic opportunities
Positive links
Negative links
Local government
Lack of government programs
for employment and credit
Individuals as well as
groups are better able to
access/engage in income
generation
Agency
At the community level:
• Improved social participation
• Social cohesion and togetherness
• Reduction in gender inequality
• Collective efforts to improve living
• AIDS awareness
• Groups mitigate shocks
Credit
groups
Credit
groups
• Participation in decision making discouraged
• Corruption, lack of transparency
• Relation between government and the community
is top-down, no reported instances of participation
At the household level:
• Women work at home and outside
• Multiple earners
• Education of children
• Asset accumulation
Empowerment of individuals
and groups in the community
Development
schemes and NGOs
The poor move up, but most do not
cross poverty line
Empowerment of individuals
and families in the community
Collective action:
Community groups in Bufkaro
Youth
groups
Funeral
groups
Digging
groups
The
church
Gathering people in
church for announcing
development schemes
and political campaigns
and sharing other
information
Success from the Bottom Up
Moving out of poverty
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
45
Some of these groups are supported by NGOs. They include mutual aid and
burial societies that use contributions of money and labor from members to
transport sick people to health facilities or organize funerals. “Before the association, the bereaved families would sleep on an empty stomach; sometimes
they would even sell part of their land for [funeral] celebrations,” recounted
a group of women. “Now when a member loses someone, the burial groups
use the money to buy food, a coffin, and other requirements for the funeral.”
Women also join digging societies, working land for the well-off households
in the community and using the money to buy household items and pay
school fees. The local church serves as a vital source of information about
development schemes and community programs.
“If you do not belong to any group in this village, then you cannot survive,” said women in a ladder of life discussion. Group activities help poor
people in Bufkaro cope with few resources, but they do not seem to help
them move out of poverty. While some poor people manage to move up,
most do not cross the poverty line.
Is movement out of poverty in Bufkaro low because poor people, for
whatever reason, lack initiative? Or do poor people fail to escape poverty
because their initiatives meet resistance and are blocked? Or are poor people
simply excluded from the economic, social, and political opportunities that
the well-off enjoy? How does collective action by the rich and poor block or
facilitate economic and political opportunities?
The interplay of factors revealed in the community diagrams eventually
led to the conceptual framework adopted for the quantitative analyses carried
out in the third year. This conceptual framework, described below, guided
the third and final phase of our data analysis, which was quantitative. This
included multivariate regression analyses to test the role of local-level institutions in the movement out of poverty while taking into account other community and household features.
Key concepts: Initiative and opportunity
In studying hundreds of diagrams from individual communities, the two
overarching concepts that emerge are initiative and opportunity. The interaction between these two largely structures the movement out of poverty (figure
1.8).
In studying these movements, we can make an analogy with flows from
physical systems. If we see that a weak flow of electric current is causing a bulb
to glow faintly, it could be either because the power source is weak or because
46
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 1.8
Initiative and opportunity interact to produce upward movement
Moving out of poverty
Material well-being
Power and rights
Economic opportunity
National
policies
Local
economy
Economic
fairness
Democracy
National
elections
Local competitive
politics
Collective action
Collective action
Collective and
cooperative endeavors
Social capital and
civic engagement
Social stratification
Political
fairness
Social stratification
Individual agency, aspirations,
and initiatives
the resistance to the flow of power is high, so the power is dissipated in heat.
Or if we see a trickle of water flowing past us, it could be because there was
little water at the source or because obstacles are blocking the flow.
We start with poor people. At the source of poverty reduction are the
initiatives that millions and millions of individuals and households take to
better their lives.7 Such initiatives may involve growing new crops, using new
agricultural techniques or equipment, accessing new markets, starting a business, getting a job, or migrating for employment. People take initiatives based
on their self-confidence, agency, aspirations, and empowerment—their sense
that what they do matters and has the potential to succeed.
Initiative can also be embedded in collective action, from pooled labor
or savings to cooperation in marketing to fully cooperative firms. Both the
poor and the rich can act collectively, either through formal organizations
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
47
or through informal groups and networks. Both usually associate with their
own kind—the rich with the rich and the poor with the poor. At times, the
interests of the rich and poor may converge, as when everyone wants to solve
a community-wide problem. At other times, the rich and poor compete for
influence and access to limited resources. Collective action by the poor will
then meet with resistance from the rich.
It is a reality that most societies are divided, most often along lines of
caste, ethnicity, gender, religion, or wealth. Economic, social, and political
organizations and networks fissure along the same social divides, leading
to “durable inequality” between social groups (Tilly 1999). Across all study
regions and all topics, we find social stratification to be a conditioning factor
that affects both initiative and opportunity.
Whether economic initiative, either individual or collective, leads to
upward movement depends on the opportunities available and access to
them. We consider three aspects: national policies, local economies, and economic fairness. As detailed in chapter 5, there is no question that progress in
overall national prosperity has an enormous influence on the pace of poverty
reduction. But our study is not primarily about the link between national
policies and poverty, a field of inquiry for which our techniques are not well
suited. Instead, we focus on the local level. How do opportunities at the very
local level (as small as the village) structure the movement out of poverty?
How does the fairness of economic opportunity—whether individuals from
all walks of life are able to effectively participate in the economy—influence
poverty reduction, at the local level and hence also at the national level?
In the political sphere too, people participate both individually and
collectively. We acknowledge the importance of electoral democracy at the
national level in framing political freedom. But our focus is again at the local
level. It is participation in open, competitive, local political processes that
determines access to and influence over local governments and governmentfinanced programs. Poor people can participate individually through elections. But organized collective action is just as important, as the ability to
express common interests is key to successful participation and representation, especially among marginalized groups. Moreover, the structures of
political opportunity strongly influence whether local politics helps or harms
poor people in their efforts to improve their well-being. We are concerned
with the efficacy of electoral accountability, the presence of political clientelism, and the extent of fairness in opportunities to participate in public
decision making. An important aspect of the latter is the degree of discrimination against women.
48
Success from the Bottom Up
In reality, of course, the boundaries between the political and economic
are blurred and contested. Political power can thwart or create economic
opportunity, and economic success can increase power and influence in the
political sphere. We stress these interconnections throughout the book.
We have written this book to give voice to thousands of poor people—
women, men, and youths—who shared their life experiences, their hopes,
and their dreams with us. Ayesha, Mamba, and Adolfo in our opening stories
seized whatever tiny opportunities they could find. And there are millions
and millions of others just like them.
Poor people do not give up. They try again and again. Poor people are
ready to work with businesses, NGOs, foundations, students, concerned citizens, governments—with any of us—to innovate and invest in their lives and
communities. Can we find the courage and imagination to try again with
them?
Notes
Epigraph: The letter from Marshal to Arthur Lyon Bowley is from The Correspondence of
Alfred Marshall, Economist, vol. 3, Towards the Close, 1903–1924 (New York: Cambridge
University Press, 1996).
1. So this book could protect the privacy of individuals, all local-level communities
in the study (villages, barrios, etc.) are identified by pseudonyms in this book.
Higher-level entities (blocks, districts, provinces, regions, states, and countries)
are identified by their real names. To increase readability when we use materials
from the 21 country studies commissioned for the Moving Out of Poverty project,
we reference only the name of the village and country. The names of the team leaders for the country studies and researchers are in appendix 1. The country reports
can be found on the Moving Out of Poverty study Web site at http://go.worldbank
.org/8K2Q8RYZ10.
2. Forthcoming volumes in the Moving Out of Poverty series will probe specific contexts in greater depth. Volume 3 will focus on India, and volume 4 on
conflict-affected communities.
3. The ladder of life discussion was not conducted in all study communities. For
instance, some studies that built on existing panel data sets (Kagera in Tanzania,
and Cambodia) did not use the ladder of life exercise and instead identified
household mobility status using information in the panel. Only qualitative data
were gathered for the Sri Lanka tea estate and Morocco studies. While discussions around the ladder were held in the Afghanistan study sites, the households
sorted for the community mobility matrixes were too few to be quantified. Figure 1.1, therefore, is based on ladder of life data from 16, not 21, study regions.
4. The study in Kagera, based on a panel data set and led by Joachim De Weerdt,
found that although 78 percent of the fallers were predicted correctly, only half
of those who were predicted to move out of poverty actually did so.
The Moving Out of Poverty Study: An Overview
49
5. An increasing number of experiments are attempting to create new partnerships
between NGOs and businesses and new financial instruments that allow poor
people to scale up their businesses and move higher up in the value chain. The
Clinton Global Initiative has mobilized US$30 billion in commitments since
2005, and it is effectively bringing many different actors together across political
and ideological divides to innovate on a large scale on behalf of poor people (see
http://www.clintonglobalinitiative.org).
6. SOSOTEC stands for Self-Organizing System on the Edge of Chaos. The exercise
is done in groups.
7. We often use the terms “individual” and “household” interchangeably, although
we recognize that complicated gender dynamics inside the household can keep
the household from acting as a single unit.
Stories of the Poor,
Stories by the Poor
The African peasant only knows the
eternal renewal of time, rhythmed by the
endless repetition of the same gestures
and the same words. In this imaginary
world where everything starts over and
over again, there is no place for human
endeavor or for the idea of progress.
—N ICOL AS S ARKOZY , PRESIDENT OF F RANCE ,
lecture at the University of Dakar, Senegal, 2007
I did not sit idle. I started the business
of baking bread and selling it in the
village market. To increase our income,
we were also selling extra food crops
from our food harvest and selling coffee
from the farm. Sometimes I also worked
in the factory as a casual laborer.
—A LTENZIA ,
A
42- YEAR - OLD PEASANT WOMAN ,
Ngimyoni, Ruvuma, Tanzania
2
C HAPTER
W
e start our exploration of underlying assumptions about “the
poor” and causes of poverty with the 18th-century Scottish
economist Adam Smith. In his seminal work The Wealth of Nations, Smith
(1776) wrote:
By necessaries I understand not only the commodities which are indispensably necessary for the support of life, but what ever the customs of the
country renders it indecent for creditable people, even of the lowest order,
to be without. A linen shirt, for example, is, strictly speaking, not a necessary of life. The Greeks and Romans lived, I suppose, very comfortably,
though they had no linen. But in the present times, through the greater
part of Europe, a creditable day-laborer would be ashamed to appear in
public without a linen shirt, the want of which would be supposed to
denote that disgraceful degree of poverty which, it is presumed, nobody
can well fall into, without extreme bad conduct.
This brief excerpt suggests several conclusions about the nature of poverty.
One is that the definition of poverty is a social construct: it varies depending on
the particular context and time. People must have the commodities and conditions that their own society deems essential in order to be considered decent,
to belong, and to walk without shame. More recently, Amartya Sen (1999) has
argued for an expansion of the notion of poverty from one based on commodities to one based on a broader set of human capabilities and freedoms.
But there is another important message in Adam Smith’s text: that not
having what is customary is cause for shame and is evidence of bad behavior.
Smith implies that poverty is a disgrace because it can be avoided. If opportunities to avoid poverty are widely available, then it follows logically that
one cannot fall into a “disgraceful degree of poverty” except by “extreme bad
conduct.” His remark is a wonderfully concise statement of the view that
being poor is a poor person’s fault.
51
52
Success from the Bottom Up
Today’s free market proponents espouse a similar ideology. Since markets provide ample and equal opportunity, as they contend, then the cause of
poverty must lie with a lack of initiative on the part of poor people. This could
be due to a lack of self-confidence or to a belief that action is futile and will
not pay off in results. It could reflect a vicious cycle of behavioral pathologies
such as laziness, drug addiction, and crime. Whatever the cause, there is a
“culture of poverty” and the culture of poverty is the cause of poverty. Poverty
is poor people’s fault.
The exact opposite stance is that there is no opportunity for the poor: the
poor are caught in a structural trap not of their own making and from which
their own efforts cannot extract them. Proponents of this view also believe
in a culture of poverty, but they see it as effect rather than cause. People who
must cope with inexorable poverty create a culture of poverty as a defense. In
this fatalistic view, poor people’s supposed low aspirations and reluctance to
take initiative are rational responses to the world as they find it. This plays
out in political life as well, where the poor are trapped in political structures
that exclude them.
Few people would admit to holding either of these views so starkly
expressed. Among many economic elites there is a sense that opportunity
is not sufficiently equal. In a historical irony, several countries with Marxist
governments such as China and Vietnam now offer a wide array of marketbased opportunities for the poor. Nevertheless, like old ghosts, these notions
still rattle around upstairs and it is useful to bring them out into the open
and exorcise them.
Let us examine the stories that people tell or have heard about “the
poor”—and the contrasting stories poor people told us themselves. Stories,
myths, and legends reside deep in the human psyche and often persist despite
facts to the contrary. These tales of a culture of poverty are harmful and should
be dismissed; they limit our imagination about the potential of poor people
and strategies for ending poverty. Poor people are not the obstacles to poverty
reduction. Rather, they are the most important actors and contributors to
meaningful change.
Is Poverty Poor People’s Fault?
I feel confident because I like setting goals for myself. I like moving on,
overcoming obstacles.
—Pedro, an internally displaced poor man, age 32,
Santa María, Colombia
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
53
At age 15, I began work, breaking rocks. Later, I rented land to grow
tobacco. The first time I planted tobacco, I just copied the way others did it.
But it rained, so I didn’t produce anything. Even now the biggest obstacle
is rain. If the tobacco is good, it sells. I can eat.
—Dul, a man in chronic poverty, Tattantok, Indonesia
The term “culture of poverty” is strongly associated with the work of
American anthropologist Oscar Lewis, who first advanced the notion in
his 1959 work on five families in urban Mexico. That ethnographic study
proposed 70 characteristics that Lewis believed were frequently found in
members of the “underclass.” They included no sense of history, short time
horizons, no savings or future orientation, low aspirations, an unreliable
work ethic, unstable families, and unwed mothers. Children of the poor, he
argued, are socialized into believing that they deserve to be poor, leading to
low aspirations, low effort, and an inability to escape poverty.1 Lewis further
elaborated his theory in an ethnographic study of Puerto Ricans (1966). His
ideas have persisted in the popular imagination for decades, but they have
often been misunderstood: many have cited the “culture of poverty” as a
cause of poverty, rather than as an adaptive response to and consequence of
persistent poverty, as Lewis proposed.
Some scholars have extended Lewis’s theory from the household to the
country level, suggesting that entire societies are caught up in a culture of poverty. In their edited volume Culture Matters, Lawrence Harrison and Samuel
P. Huntington (2000) link lack of economic progress in many developing
countries to religious and cultural values. In his foreword, Huntington contrasts Ghana and South Korea: they had the same per capita income in the
1960s but diverted dramatically by the 1990s, when Ghana had one-fifteenth
the gross national product of South Korea. He concludes that the critical
difference is that Koreans “valued thrift, investment, hard work, education,
organization, and discipline” while Ghanaians had “different values” (xiii).
Several contributors to the volume offer typologies of values that supposedly
distinguish a dynamic culture from a stagnant one. Harrison lists 10 values
related to time, work ethic, frugality, education, community orientation, justice, authority, and secularism. Mariano Grondona offers a similar list of 20
characteristics presumed to be absent in societies that remain economically
backward. These and similar lists resonate depressingly with the concept of
a culture of poverty.
At the country level, it is easy to deconstruct these cultural explanations as
the ex post rationalizations they often are. Country economic growth acceler-
54
Success from the Bottom Up
ates and decelerates, sometimes almost overnight. Intellectuals derided India
for its “Hindu rate of growth” and China as a nation of communist ideologues. Such cultural explanations can hardly account for the transformation
of India and China from basket cases in the 1960s and 1970s to the “dancing
giants” that are already shaping the 21st century (Winters and Yusuf 2007).
But perhaps there is a culture of poverty at the individual or household
level? If so, we did not find it.
Amid poverty, high aspirations
I am expecting to make my kid progress in life. He wants to be an industrial
engineer, and his goal is my goal.
—Sara, a 35-year-old displaced woman, Villa Rosa, Colombia
It was in 2004 that Joy gave birth to our son. The feeling was unexplainable when I first saw him. That was the time that I told myself that I have
to work harder for the future of my son and for our family.
—Naem, a 27-year-old man, Bakimati, Philippines
At the end of the household interviews, we asked people about their expectations for themselves and for their children. We use this question as a proxy
for aspirations. A majority of all respondents, 66.5 percent, said that they hope
to be better off in the future, while 22 percent expect to remain in a situation
similar to their current one. Only 11.5 percent expect to be worse off.
There were no noteworthy differences between study regions in South
Asia, Africa, and Latin America, nor did the conflict-affected sites differ significantly from others. Compared to other settings, higher percentages of
households in two African contexts, Uganda and Ruvuma, Tanzania, expect
to be worse off. However, in the African country of Senegal, 94 percent expect
to be better off. Also expressing hope for a better future were 92 percent
in poverty-stricken Bangladesh, 81 percent in war-torn Afghanistan, and 77
percent in Uttar Pradesh, one of the poorest states of India. Even among the
chronic poor, 60 percent across the study contexts hold positive expectations
for their own future. Despite bone-grinding hard work and privation, people
manage to remain optimistic.
People have even higher expectations and aspirations for their children
than for themselves. Overall, 77 percent of households feel that their children
will be better off in the future. Another 15 percent say their children will be in
a similar situation to their own, and only 8 percent are pessimistic about their
children’s future. No major differences were observed across study regions.
55
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
Over 90 percent of parents in Bangladesh, Afghanistan, Senegal, and Andhra
Pradesh have positive aspirations for their children. People in the African
study regions other than Senegal, though, are slightly less optimistic (figure
2.1). These findings mirror results from wider surveys such as the one undertaken by the Pew Global Attitudes Project (2007).
More importantly, we found very little evidence that parents were transmitting expectations of poverty to their children. A large majority of the
chronic poor, 69 percent, had positive expectations for their children’s future
(figure 2.2). This was close to the average for all four mobility groups. Not
FIGURE 2.1
Majority of all households have high aspirations for their children
100 96
90
95
82
80
% households
93
91
77
82
76
70
74
62
60
62
73
71
57
50
50
40
31
30
20
10
2
1
3
5
14
9
2
13
2
6
9
8
BA
N
SE
N
(In
f
(E ra)
m
po
AP w)
(S
U HG
P
)
(C
M aste
EX
)
(E
TA thn
)
W N(
Ru
B
(L
v
an )
dd
M
AL ist)
U (Inf
G
A ra)
(P
PH ane
I ( l)
P
AF ane
l)
G
IN (Co
D
nf
O
)
(C
CO on
f)
AS L (C
o
SA
M nf)
(C
PH onf
I( )
Co
nf
)
0
13
29
Study region
Expect children to be better off
Expect children to be worse off
Source: Authors’ analysis of household survey; all study regions where data were available; N = 8,298.
Note:
AFG (Conf) = Afghanistan, Conflict
AP (SHG) = Andhra Pradesh, Self-help groups
ASSAM (Conf )= Assam, Conflict
BAN (Empow) = Bangladesh, Women’s
empowerment
COL (Conf) = Colombia, Conflict
INDO (Conf) = Indonesia, Conflict
MAL (Infra) = Malawi, Infrastructure
MEX (Ethn) = Mexico, Ethnicity
PHI (Conf) = Philippines, Conflict
PHI (Panel) = Philippines, Panel study
SEN (Infra) = Senegal, Infrastructure
TAN (Ruv) = Tanzania, Ruvuma
UGA (Panel) = Uganda, Panel study
UP (Caste) = Uttar Pradesh, Caste
WB (Landdist) = West Bengal, Land distribution
reforms
56
Success from the Bottom Up
unexpectedly, there were some group differences: movers and never poor
were slightly more optimistic, chronic poor and fallers slightly less so.
Not only do people aspire for a better future for their children, but also
they actively take steps to ensure it, especially by sending them to school if they
can. Poor men and women across the study regions spoke of how education
was the only inheritance they could leave for their children. In ranking levels of
well-being, ladder of life focus groups drew clear distinctions based on people’s
ability to educate their children. In Kramrrak, Indonesia, for example, people
at step 1 (teri) were described as the unemployed, “Those whose children have
to start working after finishing elementary education.” Those at step 2 (tongkol)
are usually fishermen who are able to send their children to senior high school
but cannot afford to send them to college. Those at step 3 (kakap) are large
landowners and rice traders. Their children are college graduates.
FIGURE 2.2
Movers and never poor have higher hopes, but even chronic poor and fallers
have high aspirations for their children
100
90
86
81
80
69
% households
70
64
60
50
40
30
20
10
15
5
8
10
0
Movers
Never poor
Expect children to be better off
Chronic poor
Fallers
Expect children to be worse off
Source: Authors’ analysis of household survey; all study regions where data were available; N = 8,298.
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
57
In a female discussion group in Ponky Kda, Cambodia, young girls said,
“Education is the most important asset in the world. An educated person
never fears facing financial insecurity because he or she gets a permanent job,
even if it is as a worker in a garment factory. Those who have no education
do not have such fortune. They become mobile laborers, a more risky job.”
Across the oceans, young Habiba in Ferjama, Morocco, agreed. She wanted
to start her own folk dance group but felt she lacked the education to do so.
“I am illiterate. It limits my thoughts and capacities.”
Despite overwhelming optimism, a sense of anxiety persists. People fear
becoming ill and losing family members to illness. Health and death shocks
were cited as one of the most common reasons for falling into poverty. Social
shocks like divorce or marital separation or a rift in the family also affected
mental well-being. People spoke about the loss of tangible assets such as
health but also about a range of intangible assets, including happiness and
peace of mind.
Anxiety about war is common in conflict-affected contexts. Sivapakyam, a
woman who returned to Sri Lanka after the ceasefire between the government
and rebel troops there, still feared the war. She said, “I hope that the war won’t
restart, and we will not have to go through the same experiences again. We live
in fear always. We sometimes question why we came back. Is there a purpose in
living like this? Now we are afraid and panic at the sound of firecrackers.”
Hard work as a route out of poverty
The capital of a poor person is his physical strength. He uses his strength.
—Men’s discussion group, Bufkaro, Uganda
People do not recognize any exhaustion. Never let go of any chances. If
fishermen still have time after seafaring, they will use the time to do other
things.
—Men’s discussion group, Kramrrak, Indonesia
Eat whatever namak [salt] and roti [bread] you get through your own hard
labor, but don’t extend your palm toward others begging.
—A poor woman, Shekh Dahir, Uttar Pradesh
There is sometimes an interesting confluence of diametrically opposing political viewpoints. Many people argue that the reason for poverty is
that poor people do not work hard. Of those who believe this, some say the
problem is the deficient attitude of the poor themselves—that they are lazy.
58
Success from the Bottom Up
Others say that poor people do not work hard because they believe the system is rigged against them and therefore hard work will not pay off. In other
words, poor people do not try, and they are right not to try; they are right to
be fatalistic. Using data from the World Values Survey, Alesina, Glaeser, and
Sacerdote (2001) report that twice as many Americans as Europeans think the
poor are lazy (60 percent versus 26 percent). Europeans tend to place more
credence in the existence of poverty traps.
These beliefs are mirrored in policy choices. U.S. tax rates and social
spending are sharply lower than those in Europe, reflecting the notion that
everyone will work harder and prosper more if there is less government help
to fall back on. Although the average employee in the United States works
1,600 hours a year compared to 1,200 hours in Europe (Alesina and Angeletos 2005), hours worked by the bottom quintile are comparable in both settings (Alesina and Glaeser 2004). And although Americans are more likely
than Europeans to believe that hard work pays off, actual mobility out of
poverty is higher in Germany and the Scandinavian countries than in the
United States (Bénabou and Tirole 2006).
What do people in poverty say? The primary refrain we heard in story
after story, in discussion group after discussion group, and in country after
country was the importance of hard work and persistence as a means to move
out of poverty. Even rural people surviving on next to nothing in some of the
poorest countries in Africa—the sample includes Malawi, Senegal, Uganda,
and remote regions of Tanzania—voiced strong belief in the importance of
hard work and tenacity. This theme also emerged repeatedly in communities
beset by conflict, as in Afghanistan.
Across the study regions, hard work emerges as important even when
people are working for next to nothing. Poor men and women almost everywhere report working for a pittance in order to get a start. In Chakax, Yucatán,
Mexico, 46-year-old Tomás said, “You have to work hard to move ahead.
When I began, I earned 60 pesos a week, and in the end I earned up to 300
pesos.” In Upper Deuri, Assam, a men’s discussion group insisted that if daily
wage laborers, whom they placed at the lowest step of the ladder, want to
move up, they have no choice but to take any job available. “The laborers
have to work hard and concentrate. But most importantly, they should have
a sense of responsibility and consciousness for any work. They have to do
whatever work they get. Otherwise their families would starve.”
In other places, too, people emphasize the importance of a good work
ethic. Poor men and women who engage in vegetable trading or have small
grocery kiosks need to have what the men in Upper Deuri called “a conscious-
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
59
ness not to be a slave to laziness.” A men’s discussion group in Galalolo,
North Maluku, Indonesia, said, “A good work ethic is displayed by a person
who works well and becomes trusted by his boss and business associates. This
includes working promptly, being punctual, and doing high-quality work
to get repeat orders.” Interestingly, it is only when people become well off
that special importance is given to having a “a good moral character,” which
involves an ethic of helping others. For example, government employees in
Upper Deuri who are classified as nonpoor can progress if they have “good
human qualities and help others.” Selfishness or lack of altruism is looked
down upon. The men said, “If they engage in illegal work, corruption, and
don’t help others, their position will move down in society.”
The importance of hard work among poor people who are resourceconstrained also emerges in the quantitative analyses of life stories from India.
The inputs that go into supporting agricultural initiatives reveal an interesting
pattern (figure 2.3). Compared to the never poor, the chronic poor more often
FIGURE 2.3
Movers and never poor support their agricultural initiatives through purchase
of assets, while chronic poor rely on hard work
35
% asset accumulation events in agriculture
attributed to initiative-taking
32
30
28
27
25
Movers
Never poor
Chronic poor
31
23
23
20
15
11 10
10
7
5
0
New business
Purchase of asset/new
technology
Hard work
Source: Narayan, Nikitin, and Richards (2009), using coded data from life stories gathered in the Indian
study regions; N = 2,700 life stories.
60
Success from the Bottom Up
start new businesses. However, in the absence of capital to invest in new technologies and equipment, poor people’s primary input is “sheer hard work.” In
other words, the capital-constrained chronic poor invest more of their labor—
this is almost the only input that their circumstances allow. In contrast, the movers and especially the never poor support their agricultural initiatives by adopting
new technologies and purchasing new assets like threshers and combines.
Those people who are worst off, affected by displacement, drought, or
conflict, seem to work the hardest, a finding that goes against the predictions of
the “culture of poverty” theory. In Villa Rosa, Colombia, people displaced from
their homes do anything they can to survive. Esteban, age 78, said, “I’m very
old, but if they were to give me work, I would do it.” Displaced men with skills
find themselves doing hard unskilled labor, often hurting themselves, lugging
heavy construction lumber or pushing carts in the sun all day. In a men’s ladder
of life discussion group in the Moroccan community of Abzif, Mohamed said,
“After successive years of drought, agriculture changed so deeply. I decided to
work in the quarries, even if this will cause me to die under the stones of these
caves, without leaving any insurance for my children. I only thought to make a
small saving that I exploited in partnership with my friends to buy a cow.”
In all the war-ravaged communities visited in Afghanistan, hard work was
the most important factor that could help a household progress on the ladder
(table 2.1). Not working hard enough was cited as one of the main reasons that
TABLE 2.1
All villages in Afghanistan report hard work as a factor in moving out of poverty
Village
Factor
K1
K2
N1
N2
H1
H2
Score
•
•
•
•
•
•
6/6
Support from children
•
•
•
•
•
•
6/6
Remittances from abroad
•
•
•
•
•
•
6/6
Support from government
•
•
•
Hard work
Hard work
Support
•
Support from the community
•
Support from NGO
•
Support from others
4/6
1/6
1/6
•
1/6
Assets
Ownership of a house
Access to (more) land
•
•
•
•
•
•
6/6
•
•
•
3/6
61
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
Village
Factor
K1
K2
N1
N2
H1
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
H2
Score
Financial
Savings
Investment
5/6
•
3/6
Access to credit
•
1/6
Sound management of domestic economy
•
1/6
Employment
Work for NGO
•
•
Find work regularly
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
Promotion at work
•
Migration to Saudi Arabia, United Arab
Emirates, Iran
5/6
3/6
3/6
•
•
2/6
•
•
4/6
•
•
Agriculture
Better access to agricultural inputs
•
Improvement in markets
•
Poppy cultivation
•
Increased land productivity
•
•
•
4/6
2/6
•
•
Access to storage
2/6
•
1/6
Education
Education
•
•
Skills improvement
•
•
•
•
•
•
4/6
2/6
Other
Overall economic growth
Economic diversity
•
•
3/6
•
2/6
Good relations in the government
•
1/6
Luck
•
1/6
Source: Ladder of life focus group discussions.
Note: K1, K2 = Kabul province villages; N1, N2 = Nangarhar province villages; H1, H2 = Herat province
villages.
people remained stuck in poverty. Sabera, a 38-year-old female carpet weaver in
Shazimir, said, “It is difficult to move from one step to the other if people are
not interested in working hard. If they work hard, it is not difficult.”
Clearly, then, poor men and women realize the importance of hard work,
and they believe in passing on a strong work ethic to their children. In the
community of Preysath, Cambodia, when we asked a men’s discussion group
what the term “power” meant to them, they said, “It is advising children to
62
Success from the Bottom Up
work hard and earn money.” Young people below the age of 20 also focused
on the importance of developing a good work ethic. In Kramrrak in East Java,
Indonesia, young men said, “Get experience from people who are already
successful; work hard; be disciplined with time and prepare yourself mentally
to carry out change.” The final word comes from a men’s discussion group in
a poor indigenous community in Guapa del Mar in Oaxaca, Mexico. “Laziness, if you allow it to take possession of you, you limit yourself. You will stay
at the first step. . . . You shouldn’t worry about obstacles, you just have to find
out how to get around them.”
Self-confidence and empowerment
If someone does not have self-confidence, it will be difficult to develop
ideas. If there is initiative without any self-confidence, it will fail. That is
why self-confidence is needed. Self-confidence is the capital.
—Suno, a 53-year-old man, Patobako, Indonesia
I can perform any work if I try. Having this confidence is power.
—Discussion with young girls, Bahana, West Bengal
In his recent book Poor People, William Vollmann (2007) gives graphic
accounts of poor people he has met in his travels around the world. Like
Henry Mayhew 150 years earlier, Vollmann trains his gaze on the prostitutes,
drunks, drug addicts, and beggars who inhabit the streets. When he asks these
people, “Why are you poor?” they tell him it is destiny, accidental, or in God’s
hands. Vollmann concludes that “poor people’s answers are frequently as
impoverished as their lives.” The poor in his book come across as broken
and desolate, beset by feelings of worthlessness. This view of “the poor” is
not uncommon; it often underpins charitable efforts that seek to change poor
people in order to change poverty.
Our data suggest that among poor people themselves, this view of poverty is limited to a very small group. In the thousands of conversations with
poor men and women, we found that most have confidence and believe in
themselves. It is true that those stuck in chronic poverty rate themselves as
lower in power and confidence than others. But we also find strong evidence
of dramatic shifts in ratings of power and self-confidence as the poor move
out of poverty and experience some success. In fact, in this regard they very
quickly start looking similar to the rich.
During the household interviews, we asked people to rank themselves
on a 10-step ladder of power and rights, with those at step 1 feeling totally
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
63
powerless and those at step 10 feeling powerful and in control. We use this
measure as a proxy for their confidence in themselves, defining those on the
top seven rungs as feeling “empowered” and those on the bottom three rungs
as feeling “powerless.” The results show that feelings of empowerment are
dynamic and situational. Nearly 74 percent of movers but only 33 percent of
fallers place themselves at step 4 or above on the ladder of power and rights.
The poor gain confidence as they move out of poverty, and the rich lose confidence as they experience a decline. There are no inherent differences between
the poor and the nonpoor in this regard; it is a matter of circumstances.
Unhappy people are usually lower in confidence, so we also examined
happiness ratings, using a similar 10-step scale (figure 2.4). A similar pattern emerges: while 64 percent of the fallers put themselves in the bottom
three happiness categories, only 49 percent of the chronic poor, 19 percent
of the movers, and 16 percent of the never poor do so. So while about half of
the chronic poor are unhappy, their unhappiness drops dramatically as they
move out of poverty.
Although not all poor people are happy or confident, many express a
spirit of self-confidence and grit even in the face of adversity. Wilmar, an
internally displaced person who ended up in a violent barrio in El Gorrión,
Colombia, said, “I believe in myself, because I have proved to myself that I
am capable. My self-confidence has increased, because even though I fall, I
FIGURE 2.4
Fallers and chronic poor are more likely to be unhappy
% households with lower happiness
70
64
60
49
50
40
30
19
20
16
10
0
Fallers
Chronic poor
Movers
Never poor
Source: Authors’ analysis of household survey; all study regions where data were available; N = 8,295.
64
Success from the Bottom Up
am able to pick myself up. If I fall 10 million times, 10 million times do I pick
myself up, more now than ever before.”
An abundance of initiative
It fell to me to do work that I never thought I would do. I worked as an
odd-jobs man in order to survive, lugging wood to the point of drawing
blood from my shoulders. When I arrived here, I ended up being a helper
to a bricklayer, something I had no knowledge of.
—Milciades, a displaced man, Villa Rosa, Colombia
Those who want to get educated are doing farming to raise money to pay
for school fees. Those who want to run a business have already started running small businesses like selling fried fish. Those who want to be farmers
have already started farming but on a smaller scale; they are growing cabbage, tomatoes, and some vegetables in the river banks.
—Group of young men and women, Guluteza, Malawi
Just as we find poor people’s laziness to be a myth, we find very little evidence that poor people in general are passive, fatalistic, and lack initiative. The
life stories of Ayesha, Mamba, and Adolfo, recounted in chapter 1, were among
the thousands we gathered that showed poor people’s enterprise and resourcefulness. Poor people take risks, migrating to foreign shores to earn and save
money. They emerge as diligent entrepreneurs, managers of a diversified portfolio of assets. But the rewards to their initiatives are constrained by limited
capital, limited knowledge of and access to markets, and, at times, by limited
exposure to ideas beyond what they see in their immediate environment.
Consider the life of Beauty, a mover from the village of Mirabari in Kurigram district in Bangladesh. Married at the age of 13, she is illiterate. Yet she is
very astute when it comes to decisions regarding her business and livelihood.
Early in the marriage, her mother-in-law forced Beauty and her husband
Rashid to move out of their home. “I had nothing but a single thatched house.
I had nothing to sleep on, nothing to cook.” Beauty worked to support her
husband so they could improve their income. At first she helped him in his
rice business. “He used to buy paddy, and I would dry it in our neighbors’
houses because we did not have sufficient space in our home. Then I would
husk it in the machine. After that, my husband would sell the rice in the
market. But this business was laborious, with minimum profit. So I suggested
to my husband that we shift to vegetable selling. He would buy a variety of
vegetables, I would wash and dry them, and then he would take them to the
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
65
market. My husband would sell the vegetables on market days and on rest
days he would pull a rickshaw. On days when the market was closed, I would
sell vegetables from my home.” Recalling those years, Beauty said, “I worked
very hard. At that time I woke up at 4 a.m. and slept at 1 a.m. For this reason
I could improve my economic situation.”
When her husband fell sick and could no longer pull rickshaws, Beauty
suggested that they open a tea stall, as there was none in the village. “Keeping
a chair, table, and two benches in front of our house, my husband started a
tea stall. He sold only tea and biscuits at that time. Now from oil to soap to
all necessary goods are available in our shop,” she said with much pride. A
loan from Grameen Bank helped. Beauty now manages the tea stall herself.
Following their example, five other tea stalls have opened in the village. In the
past, people spoke down to her for being a woman and sitting in the open
without purdah. “Now everybody says that due to Rashid’s wife his family is
leading a better life now.”
Beauty is not alone. Striking evidence of poor people’s initiative emerges
from the 2,700 life stories from India, which we analyzed to identify the
triggers for accumulation of assets. Every life event was coded into one of
four primary categories: inheritance, initiative, institutions, and infrastructure. Initiative emerged as the most frequent trigger through which people
accumulated assets—more than help from institutions, informal or formal,
more than inheritance, and more than accumulation using publicly available
infrastructure (figure 2.5).
It is possible that these results are prone to psychological bias. Success
is hailed as a result of one’s own effort while failure is blamed on others.
(Certainly this is how most of us behave!) If this is true, we should expect to
find that the never poor and movers report taking more initiative than the
chronic poor and fallers.
But we do not find that. On average, there are no significant differences
between the chronic poor and the never poor in the rate of reported initiative
taking as a trigger for asset accumulation (table 2.2). It seems likely that the key
difference is not the frequency of initiative taking but the nature of the initiatives
taken. Lacking capital, poor people keep trying different low-capital activities
in often saturated markets. They cook and sell food, raise chickens or goats, sew
clothes, make and sell charcoal, pull bicycle rickshaws, or fashion mud pots,
brooms, or grass fans for sale. Compared to the resource-endowed endeavors of
the better off, these are marginal activities with low rates of return.
Individual initiative features prominently in the explanations that households give for their upward movement over the past decade (figure 2.6). The
66
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 2.5
Respondents in India rate initiative as most important trigger for accumulating
assets
Inheritance
(e.g., wealth, caste),
4.2%
Infrastructure
(e.g., location,
roads, markets),
0.2%
Initiative
(e.g., hard work, persistence,
self-confidence),
53.4%
Institutions
(e.g., family, public,
private, civil society),
42.2%
Source: Narayan, Nikitin, and Richards (2009), using coded data from life stories gathered in the Indian
study regions; N = 2,700 life stories.
Note: Figures are percentages of asset accumulation events in life stories, broken down by primary trigger. N = 35,076 events across 2,700 life stories, all four mobility groups (one life story may have multiple
asset accumulation events).
TABLE 2.2
Movers in India take more initiative, but chronic poor take about as much
initiative as never poor
% of asset accumulation events
where initiative taking was primary trigger
Mover
Never poor
Chronic poor
Fallers
Uttar Pradesh
State
53.9
52.1
46.0
45.3
West Bengal
59.3
46.6
45.7
42.1
Assam
55.1
52.3
52.2
45.9
Andhra Pradesh
57.6
58.1
60.9
64.2
Source: Narayan, Nikitin, and Richards (2009), using coded data from life stories gathered in the Indian
study regions. N = 35,076 asset accumulation events across 2,700 life stories, all four mobility groups
(one life story may have multiple asset accumulation events).
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
67
FIGURE 2.6
Initiative features prominently, luck hardly at all as reasons for moving up
Individual initiative
(agriculture),
17.9%
New/multiple
sources of income,
10.5%
New
business,
9.7%
Hard work,
5.6%
Jobs,
22.2%
Migration/
remittances,
2.8%
All other,
28.1%
Functioning of
government,
4.0%
Housing
improvement,
3.3%
Higher
education,
0.9%
Women stepped
out to work,
2.3%
Increased
community
prosperity,
2.5%
Loan/credit,
2.1%
Community groups,
1.0%
Other,
5.6%
Legal title,
0.6%
Inheritance,
0.5%
Family factors,
8.1%
Illegal activities,
0.1%
NGO assistance,
0.3%
Lottery/luck,
0.1%
Source: Authors’ analysis of household survey; all study regions; N = 8,966 from all four mobility
groups.
Note: Figures are percentages of reasons cited by respondents when asked to name the top three reasons
for an upward move.
68
Success from the Bottom Up
great majority credit some initiative that their household has undertaken in
either agricultural or nonagricultural activities. Agricultural initiatives include
attempts to diversify crops or improve yields through better seed, technology,
or fertilizer (17.9 percent). Nonagricultural initiatives include getting a job
(22.2 percent), starting a new business (9.7 percent), or juggling multiple
livelihood activities (10.5 percent). Overall, only 0.5 percent of households
relate their upward movement to inheritance.
The limited role of luck
To take birth as a poor man itself is a big punishment.
—Discussion with men, Appilepalle, Andhra Pradesh
People seldom cite luck or fate as a principal cause of upward or downward movement. Luck (or the lottery) was mentioned only seven times as a
reason for moving up. It was one of the top three reasons only 0.1 percent of
the time (figure 2.6). Among the movers, those who started poor and escaped
poverty, only one person attributed his success to good fortune. Across the
study regions, luck was mentioned more frequently in describing the reasons
for moving from step 4 to 5, the top step in some communities. In Saré
Ogicol, Senegal, for instance, destiny was more important for the rich than
for the poor (figure 2.7). In this village, bad luck hardly featured in people’s
explanations of moving out of poverty or falling into poverty.
Although luck is seldom mentioned as a reason for movement up or
down, people are aware of the disadvantages of being born into a poor family. Those of humble birth lament especially the fact that they could never
become educated, but must work to contribute to the family pot. Conversely,
the never poor are aware of the advantages they enjoy by birth. Rama, a man
from Konapuram, Andhra Pradesh, explained, “When I was born in 1970,
our family conditions were good. We had a very good yield of cultivation
and were reckoned to be rich. Love and affection and good filial relations
prevailed in our family.” In Nachni Ghat, Uttar Pradesh, Arshad stated, “The
reason of remaining rich for me is that my parents are rich. My forefathers
had good agriculture. We have always done hard labor and never did any
wrong work. We always had the grace of God.” Similarly in Riah Khillaw,
Afghanistan, 40-year-old Sediqa described the affluence into which she was
born, surrounded by family land, gardens, and animals. She then married an
educated man with his own lands and gardens who got a government job.
Poor people are exposed to a series of misfortunes from which they have
little protection. Prominent among these are widowhood and accidents or
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
69
illness that leave people disabled. For people who have no savings and live
in countries with few social protection policies, such shocks can plunge them
into destitution. Across the study regions, the bottom step of the ladder of
life includes widows, disabled people, victims of stroke and accidents, and
the blind.
There is almost universal agreement that the lives of widows are very
harsh. “Widows have no power because they don’t have a husband,” said a
group of female youths in Mexico. In Lamraab, Morocco, the household of
Aziza, 38, dropped from step 6 to step 1 on the ladder after her husband’s
death. Her husband’s prolonged illness exhausted the family savings, and
Aziza, who knew nothing of her husband’s business, had to sell his truck to
pay the debts. Earlier, she “never lacked anything.” Now, when she crosses
paths with her husband’s friends, they ignore her. “Nobody likes the poor,”
she concluded. In Cambodia, households with widows live in huts made of
palm leaves and rely on collecting flowers such as morning glory and insects
for sale and for food.
In villages in Africa, divorce and separation from husbands is as damaging as becoming a widow. A 42-year-old woman in a village in Kagera, Tanzania, got nothing after she separated from her husband. Because traditional
laws exclude women from inheriting land, houses, and livestock after their
father’s death, she could rely only on her brothers after her separation. Initially, she moved in with her younger brother, taking care of his farms, but
she had to move out again after he married. At the time of the interview, she
was living with the widow of one of her other brothers. She realized that she
could be thrown out at any time. “When my brother’s children grow up and
get married, they have the right to eject me. So does their mother.”
Possibilities for the disabled vary with the nature of the disability and
presence of services. “The worst lameness is being blind, but if one has one
hand or one leg crippled, one can work self-reliantly,” said Mussa, a disabled
farmer in Namdenye, Ruvuma, Tanzania. So important is the health of the
body, particularly among the poor, that people often describe power in the
physical sense. In West Bengal, poor youths said, “Those who have physical
strength have power.”
Mahesh, born into poverty and still poor in Raipat village in Assam, did
not lose his spirit even after many misfortunes. He related, “My mother died
in 1995. I was overpowered by sorrow after her death. I had no money to
perform her last rites and so I borrowed 3,500 rupees from a savings group
[self-help group] in the village. I still have to return a part of that money. In
1996, my house was blown away by a devastating cyclone. In 1997, my wife
70
FIGURE 2.7
Ladder from Saré Ogicol, Senegal: Destiny matters for moving up at the top
From step 4 to 5: They
rise because of their
destiny. They diversify
their income sources
through agriculture,
cattle breeding, and
remittances. Cultivation
of groundnuts and sale of
cattle are used to pay the
costs of emigration.
From step 3 to 4: Success
of adult children and
diversification of income
sources explain their rise.
They have enough
laborers and farming
materials to cultivate
large areas. Successive
good harvests bring them
additional income.
Step 5: Gallo or “bosses”
• Are usually big agricultural producers with more than 100 animals
• Have farming materials (sower, hoe, barrow, cart) and farm or exploit wide
areas
• Easily build houses with zinc roofing and have transportation means
• Have some members of the household who draw a monthly salary
• Have families that eat good food (three meals a day)
• Are able to cure their illnesses
• Regularly provide their families with good clothing
• Have nice skin and complexion
• Help people with gifts and loans
Step 4: Keb-do or “owners”
• Cultivate their fields with the help of the poor
• Own at least 10 nanny goats, 10 sheep, 10 chickens, 1 horse, and 2 donkeys
• Own a barrow, a sower, and a cart
• Live in houses so good that the bosses can visit or even sleep there
• Get enough to eat (three meals a day)
• Can afford medicines and take care of illness without reliance on bosses
• Can provide their wives with special clothes for feast days
• Are well-educated and open-minded; trust veterinarians if livestock fall sick
Reasons for moving down
From step 5 to 4:
Excessive practice of
usury payable with
interest can lead to
complaints and sanctions
by authorities. Stealing of
cattle, serious diseases,
death of the household
head, and numerous
divorces can also cause a
decrease in well-being.
From step 4 to 3: A failure
to honor debt commitments to the bosses can
lead to a fall, for the latter
can seize their properties.
Death of a household
head can lead to sharing
of properties. Serious
diseases may also cause a
fall.
Success from the Bottom Up
Reasons for moving up
From step 1 to 2: Before
they can progress, they
must meet their food
needs by obtaining
farming materials and a
sufficient workforce. The
support of children and
relatives can fill the gaps.
Step 2: Fouddi ma hebde or “one who is moving up from poverty”
• Possess 5 to 10 chickens
• Have at least one daily meal regardless of the quantity
• Have women who cook without caring about the taste of the meals
• Usually rely on their social solidarity to satisfy needs such as health
Step 1: Basso
• Cannot practice agriculture well because they lack materials
• Work in other people’s fields
• Don’t have a comfortable hut
• Rarely eat daily, and if they find rice, they cannot make sauce for it
• Cannot take care of their family illnesses; rely on other people’s help
• Know that the richest people will not grant them a loan because they have no
guarantee
• Have wives who cannot afford to braid their hair
Source: Discussion with men, Saré Ogicol, Senegal.
From step 3 to 2: Death
of the household head
can break up the family
and lead to division of
properties. The heirs are
often forced to sell part
of their inheritance to
meet their needs.
Disabling diseases and
divorces can also cause a
fall.
From step 2 to 1: Big
family size, death of the
household head, and
laziness of children can
cause a fall.
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
From step 2 to 3: They
borrow farming materials
to meet their food needs
and have additional
sources of income such
as flexible jobs.
Step 3: Ko-fokkiri or “he has moved”
• Work in the fields of rich people; their own fields are neglected and have low
yields
• Own a donkey or two, possibly some nanny goats, a sheep, and some chickens
• Can mortgage their donkey and small livestock to meet expenses
• Eat two meals a day; have good huts and a good bed; can afford shoes and
clothes
• Send their ill to the clinic and can borrow money from the bosses to cope with
illness
• Are more open-minded and literate than they were 10 years ago, therefore, are
more competent to manage their properties and meet their needs
71
72
Success from the Bottom Up
suffered from typhoid. I thought she would die but she survived. I had to
spend a good amount of money on her treatment. In 2000, one of my hands
was fractured due to an accident when I was plying a [bicycle] rickshaw. A
Maruti car knocked me down and I was injured. I couldn’t work for four
months. Now I am sometimes able to earn 60 rupees a day as many Tata
Sumos [vans] and tractors are also plying the same route.”
Although the poor are buffeted by risks and shocks of all kinds, even the
chronic poor people in our sample reject the view that they are poor because
of personal misfortune. Not even Mahesh, who has suffered a cyclone, his
wife’s typhoid, and being hit by a car, said he was poor because he was
unlucky.
Bad behavior as a cause of poverty
The lack of work and the emptiness of their lives lead young people to take
drugs and do bad things.
—Women’s discussion group, Tindyata, Morocco
I donated blood in a blood donation camp, and I was pleased mentally
because I have not much ability to do something for our society. But this
donation of blood could help our society, so I was happy.
—Nisit, a chronic poor man, Anakha, West Bengal
A pernicious belief that surfaces in all societies from time to time is that
“the poor” as a group are immoral and prone to addictions and drunkenness.
Such people are incapable of taking any initiative, it is said, except to feed
their addictions. Work for them has no meaning, and economic opportunity
is irrelevant. Thus, the poor deserve what they get and are unworthy of support except for morally uplifting charity.
This myth traveled around the world with colonizers and has proved
resistant to extinction. During the Victorian era of the late 19th century, social
observers in England cast poverty as a moral and social problem to be met
with charity, social works, and compassion. The focus was on the deviant
behavior of the poor.2 In one of the earliest such studies, Henry Mayhew
(1851) described the rough underclass of London, the street performers, beggars, and prostitutes of the city’s streets. His dramatic descriptions captured
the popular imagination and came to dominate perceptions about all poor
people. Toward the turn of the century, Charles Booth (1889) conducted the
first serious investigation into the lives of the London poor. He distinguished
between four classes that together made up nearly a third of the population.
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
73
Lowest on the ladder was a small “hereditary” class made up of criminals,
barbarians, beggars, and bullies. The “very poor” were more numerous: while
in a state of chronic want, they seldom worked and were prone to drinking.
The “poor,” by contrast, were not in want, but they had irregular employment
and struggled to make ends meet. They were “not worse morally than any
other class though shiftless and improvident.” Above them were those with
regular employment but low wages—“decent steady men, paying their way
and bringing up their children respectably (45–50).” Speaking of the top category, Booth recommended that governments target this “deserving” group
in an effort to reduce poverty. The very poor were viewed as a lost cause, even
as a dangerous influence on others.
The belief that poverty had a moral underpinning was reflected in economic thinking as well. Alfred Marshall, in his classic Principles of Economics
(1890), defined poverty as a state of “physical, mental, and moral ill health.”
Marshall also suspected a hereditary “taint of vice” in poor people.
A century later, studies of American poverty still reveal a widely held
notion that the poor are morally flawed. In a 2001 survey of Americans
by National Public Radio, the Kaiser Family Foundation, and the Kennedy
School of Government at Harvard University, 70 percent of those polled rated
drug abuse as a major cause of poverty in their country.3 A recent book, The
Persistence of Poverty (Karelis 2007), identifies five causes of poverty in the
United States and other places: drinking, crime, low education, not working,
and lack of savings.
Do these stories and beliefs about poor people being drunks, addicts,
and deviants hold true for poor men and women in countries like Malawi,
where a large proportion of the population lives in abject poverty? No matter
which data collection tool we consider, drunkenness, drug abuse, and prostitution do not emerge as defining characteristics of the poor people in our
study. Nor does vice figure as a central reason for falling into or remaining
stuck in poverty. The ladder of life discussions reveal community perspectives
on the characteristics of both the poor and the nonpoor. Drinking and drugs
are only associated with the very poorest people, and even in this group there
are many other reasons for poverty, including low education, widowhood,
disability, physical weakness, and old age.
Poor people are aware of the dangers of drinking, drugs, and promiscuity. Parents warn children and friends remind friends to keep away from such
“evil.” There is a recognition that these behaviors can lead to falling down
into poverty or being left behind. Around a bonfire lit at night during the
field visit to the community of Maguli in Ruvuma, Tanzania, young boys and
74
Success from the Bottom Up
girls danced and sang about how HIV/AIDS and immoral behavior could
“messy me up.”
In the household questionnaire, people were asked to name the three
most important reasons for their downward movement over the last decade.
Among those who had fallen into poverty, gambling or addiction to alcohol
or drugs was mentioned among the top three reasons only 1.1 percent of
the time. Instead, the primary triggers of falling were economic conditions
in the community or country (high inflation, a worsening economy) and
health and death shocks to the family. The distribution of reasons was very
similar when considering all downward movement among the poor and
nonpoor.
In many communities people describe drinking as a consequence of prolonged poverty and unemployment rather than as the initial cause of poverty.
In the village of Butmuli in Uganda, 46-year-old Mbualamoko had no land
and survived as a casual laborer. His only asset, his house, had washed away
in torrential rains, and his second wife left him. Frustrated, sick, and weak,
he said, “I know I drink. I know my marriages failed because of my excessive drinking. But each time, I return home more frustrated than I went. I
hate myself, feel cursed, and resort to drinking to cover my feelings. I drink
waragi and other types of alcohol only to force sleep when poverty bites.”
Mbualamoko had to surrender his two goats to creditors in settlement of
accumulated debts soon after the interview.
Women sometimes take a less benign view of male drinking. They often
report that men’s dysfunctional behavior—alcohol or drug abuse, domestic
violence, extramarital affairs—leads to income declines and family breakups.
In the village of Welumbe in Sri Lanka, a woman stuck in chronic poverty said
her husband’s alcoholism made it difficult for her family to improve its condition. A bus driver, he spent about three-fourths of his income on drink. The
family survived by doing odd jobs—the mother and daughter rolled cigars
and the son worked as a mason. In Pothupana, Ampara, Sri Lanka, women
said, “If people are falling it is because of gambling and alcohol. It is only
those at the bottom steps that waste money this way. Men drink alcohol
saying that it is all because of depression or because they are tired. But this
increases the women’s grievances even more.”
In conflict-affected areas, alcohol abuse is mentioned more frequently.
In some communities in Sri Lanka, community members express concern
that drinking among adults sets a negative example for young men. Drinking the local brew and smoking marijuana sometimes cycles from generation to generation, reducing the possibility of moving out of poverty in the
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
75
long term. In Cambodia, increasing drug addiction among youth is rapidly
turning into a security concern. Drug users in several communities engage
in gang fighting, theft, and violence, particularly against women. In a group
discussion in Sastaing, young girls voiced their fears. “The use of drugs is very
popular now in our country. Therefore, the criminal has been created. Nowadays if you ask the question between humans and ghosts, which one do you
fear? I will answer that I am more afraid of humans because the ghost cannot
cause me any problems while humans can.”
Drug abuse among youth is linked to unemployment. In a discussion
group in Tindyata, Morocco, women said, “Our children don’t find a job.
Even those that have a diploma in their pocket don’t manage to find jobs.
They become disappointed and they begin to sniff drugs and we are not
able to control them.” Young men in the poor rural community of Lamraab,
Morocco, agreed, but said they had no other diversions to occupy them. In
one Moroccan community, a young doctor was credited with keeping local
youths away from alcohol and drugs. His solution was simple: he played soccer and basketball with them every night.
Abstinence from unsafe sexual behavior is a critical concern, particularly
in the African communities hit hard by HIV/AIDS. In Namdenye, Ruvuma,
Tanzania, mothers are derided for sending their young daughters to bus
stands to solicit men. When youths in Guluteza, Malawi, were asked what
they were doing to prepare for the future, they said, “We are taking care of
ourselves by abstaining from immoral practices. When you get infected with
this disease [AIDS], then it can be very difficult to say that you are preparing for the future. Because getting this disease means you are dooming your
whole future.”
Even when they are hungry, poor people often display what Adam Smith
calls “sympathy” and sentiments for their fellow human beings. In one way or
another, many people spoke about the importance of having “a good nature,
good will, and good heart.” A discussion group in Chintada, Hyderabad,
Andhra Pradesh, defined freedom as “sharing our happiness with others and
being friendly to everyone; cooperation with community members to share
their problems. . . . Freedom lies with the good-hearted people.” From some
of the poorest villages in conflict-affected Assam come accounts of caring for
others and doing good works. Ahmed, from Barbakara, Assam, who grew up
in abject poverty, spoke about helping maintain the local mosque and plastering the floor. Betha Ram, who started life as a daily wage laborer, donated
two fans to the hospital. Bhuwaneshwar makes and donates wood images of
gods to the local temple, without any payment.
76
Success from the Bottom Up
In West Bengal, Ali, age 60, talked about the joy of helping his neighbors when they fell ill by rushing them to the nearest hospital. Many people
reported donating blood, as this is one commodity that even poor people
have to give. Anup, a chronic poor man from Tola, West Bengal, summed up
the fellow feeling displayed by many poor people across the study regions.
“I am a daily laborer. When men give me work, I earn 62 rupees a day. To be
alive, we should live well and in a good way with everyone. I am not involved
with social work. But if there is any blood donation camp or any cultural
program, then I spend what I can. For this I get mental peace.”
Our evidence suggests that falling into poverty is first and foremost a
consequence of economic conditions, poor health, death in the family, and
failed enterprises, causes that affect large numbers of people. Only 1–2 percent of poor people, it seems, are poor primarily because of personal character
deficits or bad behavior. Poverty is, therefore, not a moral problem. Poverty
is an economic problem. Poverty is a political problem. The proper policy
response is not charity or moral uplift, but broad-based action to improve
and unblock the economic opportunity sets available to poor people including young girls and boys.
The Hunger for Freedom
Freedom is an element of development, and to some extent development
is an element of freedom. Is it possible to develop without being free?
Freedom is a sign of development. That is why we women who are always
ranked below men cannot say we are developed. When you have developed,
you have freedom. You can hardly have a free non-developed person. Development is part of freedom.
—Mixed discussion group, Kijuronga, Kagera, Tanzania
Freedom is . . . the freedom to choose and work out your dream.
—Len, a 34-year-old woman, Baroygor, Philippines
The notion that the people of developing nations lack the capacity for
freedom and self-rule pervades European and American political history.
Speaking in the British Parliament in 1833, Lord Macaulay justified the role
of the East India Company in India as saving people who had sunk to the lowest depths of slavery and superstition. British rule, he claimed, would make
them worthy of the privileges of citizens. In 1899, Rudyard Kipling wrote The
White’s Man Burden to urge the United States to wield imperial power in the
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
77
Philippines, extending a paternalistic rule over natives that Kipling described
as “half-devil and half-child.” The era of Manifest Destiny was built on the
belief that racial superiority gave white Americans the right and obligation to
rule over and “civilize” poorer lands.
A common theme in these colonial and imperial rationalizations was
that people do not need freedom if they live in conditions of want. Our
study emphatically refutes this notion. It is true that many poor people are
hungry and that finding food, work, and money is a pressing concern. But
this does not mean that they no longer care about dignity, goodness, community, or rights. Across the study regions, poor men, women, and especially
youth made clear that they value and long for freedom. Echoing the Universal Declaration of Human Rights, poor people defined freedom as the
right to choose what they truly value (Nussbaum 2000; Alkire 2002; Moser
and Norton 2001). For them, freedom has both intrinsic value, as a way to
live with dignity, and instrumental value, as a means to access and profit
from economic opportunity. Their comments evoke the work of Amartya Sen
(1999), who describes freedom as having both constitutive and instrumental
importance for development.
Freedom as an intrinsic value
Five key concepts emerged in people’s ideas of freedom as an intrinsic value.
They are freedom of mind; freedom of choice; freedom to live with dignity
and respect; freedom from fear and oppression; and freedom of movement
(box 2.1).
Freedom of mind. Poor people, like all human beings, value the freedom
to think without restriction and to speak their mind. In discussions, they said
freedom of mind is primary since one has to think before one speaks. Poor
people are aware that their ability to speak up is constrained by their dependence on others to make a living. Cleopatra, a 17-year-old farmer in a village
in Tanzania, said, “When you walk with your own head without wearing the
other’s head then you have freedom.”
Freedom of choice. Everywhere, women, men, and youths express a longing
for autonomy—the freedom to choose big and small things on their own and
to live according to their beliefs and desires. Small, simple, everyday acts give
happiness. Tentulia, a woman in Kismopara, Bangladesh, defined freedom as
“listening to music or going to work at my own will.” For Lovely, a woman in
the same village, “planting trees at my own free will” is freedom. For Rinu, a
woman in Upper Deuri, Assam, “weaving my own cloth on my handloom and
wearing it” is freedom. Cory, a 42-year-old in Baroygor, Philippines, said, “You
78
Success from the Bottom Up
BOX 2.1
What is freedom? Voices from the field
Freedom of mind
Freedom is to express your opinion and to express ideas.
—Discussion with women, Sian-Ha, Mexico
Freedom means we dare to talk. We have rights to express our opinion
on what is right and what is wrong. But if we have no money, our voice
becomes bullshit.
—Discussion group, Kdadaum, Cambodia
Freedom to think, freedom to tell a story.
—Discussion with women, Galalolo, Indonesia
A poor person has spaces to be free. Your thoughts surround you, and then
you struggle.
—Neftali, a 49-year-old man, Los Rincones, Colombia
Freedom of choice
You need to be the boss of yourself, otherwise this is nonfreedom.
—A woman, Kijuronga, Kagera, Tanzania
Freedom is to live independently and having handful of work and eyeful of
sleep.
—Discussion with men, Chedulla, Andhra Pradesh
To be free is to always have the choice to decide what we need.
—Discussion with men and women, Sindar, Morocco
Freedom to live with dignity and respect
You do not have a hundred shillings to buy a Panadol [fever medicine] for
your dying child and you say you are free. . . . You will start begging, and
there your freedom ends.
—Discussion with men and women, Nyakahora, Kagera, Tanzania
For me, what becomes important in freedom is doing something with selfassurance, and at the end nobody opposes me and disturbs what I have done.
Otherwise, I just become a slave.
—A man, Bugokela, Kagera, Tanzania
To live a life of dignity and respect: that is freedom.
—Harinath, Mondal, Kathalbari, West Bengal
Freedom from fear and oppression
To protest against injustice is freedom.
—Aditya, a poor man, Nababpur, West Bengal
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
79
BOX 2.1 continued
People now know their rights, the rights of their partner, of their neighbors.
Once people know their rights and are free to express themselves, freedom
becomes automatic.
—Discussion with men, Kodola, Uganda
I was asleep. A local guard came in my home and commanded me to go and
transport bricks on my head in order to build a school. Am I free? Am I not a
slave in my own community and country?
—A poor man, Bugokela, Kagera, Tanzania
Freedom is peace, nondisturbance, no threats, and love.
—Discussion with men, Bugokela, Kagera, Tanzania
I live with courage. That is my freedom.
—A man, Donekal, Andhra Pradesh
Freedom of movement
To be free is to move, to travel, without restrictions.
—Discussion with women, Mbata, Ruvuma, Tanzania
Freedom is the ability to work in the fields without my husband’s permission,
the ability to go to market without my husband’s permission, and the ability
to visit my father’s house at will.
—Discussion with women, Digbari, Bangladesh
are happy because you are free to get whatever you want, to dream whatever
you want, and to live the kind of life that you want.” Not being able to do what
one feels like doing leads to feelings of oppression. “Chained” is how Vanyen, a
woman in Baroygor, described it. “It is as if you are being controlled from doing
what you want because somebody had already set a plan.”
Some people feel that poor people have more freedom than others
because they have nothing to lose. Men and women in a discussion in Nyakahora, Kagera, Tanzania, said, “Sometimes poor people are the freest; they do
not worry about anything but their lives. A rich person worries a lot more.
What is the difference between this man [a rich man] and the one who is
in prison? That this one has chosen to imprison himself rather than being
imprisoned by the police.” Others feel that poor people have no freedom
because they need to be constantly looking for work and money. Everywhere,
people qualified freedom by saying that it permits actions that are within the
bounds of law and that do not hurt or disturb others. Freedom to choose
which God to worship was mentioned in every country.
80
Success from the Bottom Up
Freedom to live with dignity and respect. People want to enjoy self-respect
and to be respected by others, even when they must depend upon or work
for others. Poor people express their yearning for dignity in simple terms. For
Sergine in Ndagiel, Senegal, “Freedom is to have sufficient for daily expenses
so others respect you.” For Kam, a woman in Mexico, “Freedom is how we
are now: nobody beats us.” And women in Rajapurmalhua, Uttar Pradesh,
suppressed for decades in a highly patriarchal society, long for freedom in the
form of “respect and honor for our voice.”
Freedom from fear and oppression. To be free is to live in peace and security, to
have the right to protest and to vote. Discussions on this aspect of freedom were
often long and involved. Poor people treasure their right to vote, even when
they perceive clearly the mismatch between their own interests and the interests
of the political elite. They express great vulnerability in the face of wrongdoing
and frequently lament their helplessness to protest against exploitation. But
they express both hope and frustration about the ability of the justice systems
of their countries to protect them. People’s knowledge of their rights appears
to be increasing; armed with this knowledge, poor people sometimes feel free
to speak out against injustice. In Kaludoma, Ruvuma, Tanzania, young girls
defined freedom as “being free to enjoy one’s citizenship without a problem
such as being jailed, being free in life without being anguished, humiliated,
beaten, or interrogated at one’s home.” In the conflict-affected state of Assam,
people called frequently for freedom from abuse and threats by the police and
army. In Kandulimari, a village in the state, men defined freedom as “the justice
of the government and freedom of mind. On the contrary, the threatening of
the army, the police to innocent people is not called freedom.”
Freedom of movement. Geographic mobility is important to both men and
women. For men it is linked to looking for work wherever they can find it.
For women, freedom of movement implies a loosening of the restrictions and
controls imposed by husbands and society. This yearning to move, to come
and go, emerges everywhere. A group of men in Gabunazi, Kagera, Tanzania,
explained, “Freedom is when you can go out without asking for permission
or bidding farewell. I feel free because I can go out and I am sure that I shall
come back. I do not need anybody to escort me.”
Across a wide swath of societies, from India, Afghanistan, and Bangladesh to Mexico, Malawi, and Tanzania, women express anger at restrictions
on their movement. Some compare their experience to living like “a bird in
a cage.” In Surjana, Uttar Pradesh, a group of women said, “We should have
freedom to unveil our face, because when an elder man is present in the
house, we have to cover our face. We have to be closeted in one room. We
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
81
cannot move about. We should have freedom from these customary regulations.” In Afghanistan, some women said that not wearing a chador is freedom; many more spoke about the desire to walk along a road alone, without
anyone’s permission and without being accompanied by anyone. In Chiksisi,
Malawi, women spoke of their desire to wear high heels and trousers but said
they would be chastised if they did. “If you wear a trouser, your husband is
going to ask you whether you want the household to have two men!”
Women who breach customary restrictions often are ill treated by their
husbands, so women’s desire for freedom of movement is linked to their
desire for freedom from domestic violence. Women in Chakax, Mexico, spoke
of the abuse they face; for them, marriage is the opposite of freedom. Fear
of abandonment also restricts women. Nasima asked, “Where is your peace
of mind, considering that you sleep in this house and your husband leaves
you?” In Pueblo de León, Mexico, one woman who was not abused declared,
“I go out all the time and talk with everybody, and my husband does not hit
me. I am free.”
Instrumental freedom for economic opportunity
In addition to being an intrinsic good, freedom has an instrumental value,
making it possible for people to find and seize economic opportunity. Both
men and women hanker for the freedom to find good work, to control their
money, to conduct business freely, to own property and goods with no legal
hassles, and to sell their property whenever and to whomever they choose.
For men across the study regions, freedom means practicing the livelihoods they want without restrictions. In Kramrrak, Indonesia, people feel free
when they can “work in any fields; nobody commands; nobody obstructs.”
Men also talked about “freedom of selling, freedom of getting a loan from
banks, and freedom to be fishermen and teachers.” In Patobako, another
village in Indonesia, men spoke about the “freedom of running a business;
freedom of looking for a loan from a bank because many people here need
financial capital but can’t find it because they are on the blacklist.”
The ability to establish a business without restrictions is a valued freedom in the African study states too. Freedom to pursue economic activities
“without interference in whom one transacts with and where” is important
in Ruvuma, Tanzania. In Uganda, people are concerned with the freedom
“to pursue activities that generate income,” and in Malawi, “to transact in
the market without bureaucratic harassment.” In Butmuli, Uganda, a man
explained, “I do whatever I want with my cow as compared to the past, when
we used to give a share to the village chairman.”
82
Success from the Bottom Up
Engagement in Family and Community
Losing adult children is very painful. It is like a pot breaking when you
have already washed your hands to eat. He [an orphan she raised] is like
a son. He grew up with me, he cares for me. It is a consolation, the only
thing that keeps me alive.
—A woman, Kakyango, Kagera, Tanzania
Sometimes young people come together to help each other but most of the
times, we just meet to have fun, play sports, or celebrate an event, a wedding, a holiday.
—Discussion with female youth, Zakwak Ulya, Afghanistan
The flip side of the myth that poor people are too fatalistic to take advantage of economic opportunity is the myth that they are too obsessed with
subsistence to care for their families, participate in their communities, or
play a role in the broader society. These myths often affect the design of
government and charitable programs that treat “the poor” not as agents of
their destiny but as the objects of actions by others—as “beneficiaries” but
not participants. Our findings, by contrast, show poor people to be engaged
in their families and in their communities as well.
An assumption often made about poor people is that they have broken
homes and chaotic family lives. But nearly every life story told to us—by movers, chronic poor, never poor, and even fallers—depicts people striving to create
better lives for their families, particularly their children. The love of family is
palpable everywhere, and it motivates men and women to keep on against the
odds. Life stories are filled with expressions of joy at the birth of children, particularly boys, and grief at the illness or death of kin. A woman in Glikati, Philippines, said, “I was so depressed when my mother died because I felt so empty.
It was the same feelings that I had during the time that my children died.”
In a remote community in Mexico, Victor, a 35-year-old man stuck in
chronic poverty, called his family the most important relationship in his life.
“The family, my children, that’s who you think about in order to make the
family move ahead a little.” His daughter fell ill and needed to be hospitalized, but he had no savings. He said, “You have to fight. You have to make an
attempt to solve the problems.” A chronic poor man in Assam described how
his father had insisted on his schooling despite their poverty. “In that season,
he got no work. There was no fire in our house. Three or four days we lived
in hunger. One piece of chappati [bread] was not in our luck. My mother had
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
83
died during my birth time. . . . My father loved me too much. He introduced
me to school.” Men rejoice when after years of savings, they can buy clothes
for their children, a sari and gold jewelry for their wives. Pramod, a 34-yearold man in Atkona, Uttar Pradesh, recalled, “In 1997, when I bought clothes
for all the members of the family by my own earnings, it gave me happiness
and a lot of satisfaction.”
For poor men and women across the study regions, family emerges as the
central economic institution in their lives. Families manage their portfolios
of assets jointly. All family members, including children, typically contribute
to the household’s support, whether by working to earn money or by getting
an education to prepare for future work. The frequent decision to educate
sons rather than daughters is based in part on a calculation of economic
returns, since until recently girls could not work outside the home. Diversification of income is based on deploying different members of the household
in different activities, sometimes in different places. Families often arrange
for one or more members to migrate, either to a city in the same country
or to another country; the remittances sent home by the migrant become a
crucial part of the extended family’s livelihood portfolio. In the ladder of life
discussions, the top step of the ladder often includes people who have adult
children working overseas.
Poor people’s sense of belonging and solidarity extends beyond the family to the larger community. The importance of getting along with others
and living together amicably emerges time and again. Men in Korrapadu,
Andhra Pradesh, define freedom as “living together happily, mixing up
with unity, without having any hurdles or hindrances and without causing
inconvenience to others.” In Devupuram, another village in the same state,
a men’s group said, “People enjoy freedom when they maintain good relations with people. They are admired by society. People who never maintain
good relations with people have less freedom.” Social discrimination and
marginalization, whether based on caste or some other criteria, is painful.
In Jambugumpala, Andhra Pradesh, a group of men said, “Restraining the
backward classes of people from moving about this way or that, asking them
to speak with folded hands, further keeping them penniless and in a helpless
state, is negative freedom and against freedom.”
Celebration of festivals reaffirms identity and social ties (Rao and Walton 2004a; Banerjee and Duflo 2006). Poor youths in our study emphasize the importance of festivals in bringing people together across caste
and income groups and enabling them to forget their misery for a day.
In Chintada, Andhra Pradesh, a village with low social stratification along
84
Success from the Bottom Up
caste lines, young people said, “We all come together during festivals like
Bhathukamma or Dusshera. We just can’t express the happiness we get in
those days.” In Bhosi, also in Andhra Pradesh, festivals provide youths with
their only diversion. “On these days, we groom ourselves in new clothes
and enjoy our time with friends. We also come to help each other, do
some small works.” In Bangladesh, almost every community reported celebrations to mark graduations, weddings, the Muslim holiday of Eid, and
independence day. In Mexico, patron saint celebrations include basketball
games for youth. In Morocco, people participate in folk groups that entertain during weddings and the summer festivals.
Living in contexts of little government support for childrearing, education, illness, old age, or death, poor people are keenly aware that their survival depends on others. In African communities, especially, many people
belong to mutual aid groups such as savings and credit groups and burial
societies. People across the study contexts describe community solidarity and
unity as a lifeline. A discussion group in Saré Ogicol, Senegal, said, “In the
village, there is solidarity. The men have an informal grouping, and Sellou is
the president. They have collective activities, and they club together. With the
incomes they get from these activities, they have started to build a mosque
in the village.”
Having a circle of friends is important. Mamba, a chronic poor man in
Malawi, recounted with great joy and affection his list of friends. “Ezekiel is
a friend of mine who helps me when I am in need of money to buy soap. He
also assisted me with maize seeds last year. When he has Irish potatoes he
gives me. Innocent, this one has a vegetable garden and he assists me with
money for maize milling. He gives us vegetables for he says we can’t buy
them.” About Blessing he says, “When my child is sick, he helps me with
money for transport. He also gives me medicine which he gets from a private
clinic. Chiwengo, this one has a sewing machine, and he sews my clothes for
free.” About Meke, he says, “This friend is like the others; we do help each
other. There was a time in 2004 that I had no hoe, and he gave me one. We
also advise one another not to go in the way of chasing skirts.”
The importance of belonging and staying together becomes even more
evident in crises, such as periods of conflict or mass displacement and relocation. Rubiela, a 40-year-old woman in El Gorrión, Colombia, described the
solidarity that developed in the process of reconstruction of their neighborhood. “Something remarkable is respect. We all used to sleep in the same
bed, live in the same house, just separated by a piece of canvas. We learned
to love each other. The other thing is the understanding. We learned to know
Stories of the Poor, Stories by the Poor
85
our needs. When someone got sick we used to take care of each other. We
watched so no one would get into our territory.”
The absence of a mutual support network is associated with privation.
A women’s ladder of life focus group in Satgailijhara, Bangladesh, said,
“There are six categories of people in our village. At the bottommost step
are the Huduirra or Humainna, those who have no friends to turn to and no
resources to fall back on.”
Conclusion
Poor people are neither saints nor villains, neither victims nor superheroes.
There are few differences between the poor and the nonpoor in their aspirations for themselves and their children, in their belief in hard work as a
means of getting ahead, in their initiative, or in their morals. Poverty is not an
affliction of the few but a condition of the many. In almost half the countries
in our study, 50 percent of the population is poor. These hundreds of millions of people cannot all be drunken, lazy, criminal, or unable to imagine
and plan a future for themselves and their children.
Myths about poor people and about the causes of poverty have led to
policy choices that have not helped those in poverty. Our research reveals the
wretched opportunities that confront poor people in contrast to the gilded
choices that the rich enjoy. To break out of poverty, poor people need the
same opportunity sets as the rich. This requires fresh thinking and new mindsets about poor people and the scale of poverty.
The problem is us, not poor people. We have to change. If only we can
make the world look like what poor people think it really is—a place where
hard work pays off, where there is equality of opportunity—we will see mass
poverty reduction in our time. Imagine a world in which we listen to poor
women, men, and young people, and fix what they think isn’t right.
Notes
1. There is a vast psychological, anthropological, and sociological literature on this
subject. See Lane (1959), Lerner (1982), Boudon (1973), Bourdieu and Passeron
(1970), Appadurai (2004), and Rao and Walton (2004a).
2. For one of the best overviews of this time period, see Himmelfarb (1992).
3. See “Poverty in America,” NPR Online, http://www.npr.org/programs/specials/
poll/poverty.
Poverty Is a Condition,
Not a Characteristic
I know that if one had a small job, one
could slowly save and in the future
be able to meet any emergencies or
make the most of whatever opportunity
presented itself. One knows that it is
better to teach a person to fish than to
hand out a fish. But the state has left us
abandoned!
—A LICIA ,
A DISPL ACED WOMAN ,
Villa Rosa, Colombia
With my earnings from agriculture, I
bought 10 used bicycles and a sewing
machine. I repaired them myself and
sold them. Then I bought a radio,
15 goats, and pigs. I also bought a car,
though an old one, to make my life
better. But my ambition is not fulfilled.
—O DWIN ,
A
52- YEAR - OLD MALE MOVER ,
Ngimyoni, Ruvuma
3
C HAPTER
T
here is a story, possibly apocryphal, about a researcher measuring the
size of rats’ bodies. The study concluded that the largest rat body was
six inches long. A colleague, looking over his paper, thought for a while and
then asked, “How big is your largest trap?” “Six inches. We don’t need them
any larger as that is the size of the biggest rat” was the researcher’s confident
reply.
All scientists know that the tools used to observe the world limit and
structure what we observe and even shape our concepts. Using multiple tools
to measure the same phenomenon broadens our understanding. The most
common tool for investigating poverty has been a household survey, usually
administered to a sample chosen to be representative for the nation (and perhaps also for a subnational unit like state or province). This tool does two
things well. First, it can answer this question: “What is the current level of a poverty measure for the national (or state or provincial) population?” An attempt
to determine whether poverty has gone up or down strains the tool of the
household survey to its limits, because comparability issues are so bedeviling.1
Second, the household survey can compare differences between “the poor” and
“the nonpoor” in the specific characteristics—age, sex, occupation, education,
household size—that a large-scale survey can capture. The World Bank has carried out hundreds of poverty assessments using these tools to present poverty
profiles showing levels of poverty and the characteristics of “the poor.”
However, while the household survey as a tool has proven its value and
has deepened the understanding of poverty in some ways, it also presents two
conceptual dangers.
The first danger lurks in the very words “the poor.” At any point in time,
individuals can be described in an infinite variety of ways, some of which are
relatively permanent characteristics. Persistent characteristics can be fixed in part
by biology, like height (for adults) or being left-handed, or they can be chosen
87
88
Success from the Bottom Up
by individuals (political party affiliation), or they can be some mix of choice
and circumstance (like religion or ethnicity). But the descriptions of specific
individuals at a given point in time also include current but perhaps temporary
conditions that people are experiencing, like having a cold, or wearing a red
shirt, or being tired. A snapshot cannot distinguish between characteristics and
conditions. A cross-sectional survey cannot tell whether an individual who is
counted as one of “the poor” is experiencing permanent poverty (like being
left-handed) or temporary poverty (like having a broken right hand).
Our study has used a different collection of tools to examine poverty.
Local community-based focus groups were asked to construct a ladder of
well-being categories for their community, called the ladder of life. The groups
then subjectively ranked each household in their community, placing it on a
step of the ladder according to its current status and, based on recollection,
its status 10 years ago (in 2005 and 1995). The findings from this exercise
strongly confirm the conclusion that has emerged from the increasing use of
surveys that track the same individuals over time: poverty is a condition, not
a characteristic. Although one can talk about the collection of people who
are experiencing an episode of poverty as “the poor,” this should not lead us
to the dangerous assumption that for most of these people, being poor is a
relatively permanent characteristic (like being left-handed or tall) or even a
stable ascriptive identity (like ethnicity or religion or party affiliation).
A second limitation of the household sample survey is that it pays attention exclusively to large units—nations, states, provinces (although recent
work constructs local snapshots using survey and census data).2 This leads to
the conceptual danger that one may rely exclusively on national policies and
programs in addressing poverty. As we get dressed on a January day in the
United States, the average nationwide temperature doesn’t matter much—it
may be a bitter 7 degrees Fahrenheit in Duluth, Minnesota, but a balmy
70 degrees in Phoenix, Arizona. How heavy a coat we put on depends on
where we are. Locality matters.
Our study sampled communities, not nation-states. Within each community, we then produced rankings of the changes in prosperity and poverty of
all (or nearly all) households. We show that locality matters: villages in the
same country have very different experiences in poverty reduction. Even in the
countries with rapid economic growth, some villages were stalling, and even in
countries where poverty was increasing, some villages were thriving.
This comprehensive approach to measuring mobility at the community
levels means we could also examine inequality at the local level, attempting
to discover to what extent the fortunes of the (relatively) rich and poor within
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
89
the same village move together. We show that the degree to which the poor and
nonpoor move together varies widely across the study regions.
The findings of this chapter, showing that individual- and locality-specific
features are an important part of the overall experience of poverty, give rise to
the questions addressed in the rest of the study: What are the conditions of
households and localities that facilitate moving out of poverty?
Household Dynamics and Poverty
We constructed a community mobility matrix (CMM) for each village on the
basis of the focus group rankings of households on the steps of the ladder of
life.3 For each of the communities in the 18 study regions for which we have
sufficient data, we have a community mobility matrix like the one shown for
Fateh Garh village in Uttar Pradesh (figure 3.1). The steps on the ladder in
this village go from step 1, the poorest, to step 6, the richest (recall that each
village creates its own ladder and defines the steps). Each number in any cell
represents a particular household (the household numbers are just arbitrary
labels). A household’s placement in the matrix is determined by its position
on steps of the ladder now and 10 years ago, as perceived by the focus group.
The community mobility matrix thus reveals the stability or mobility of
households over time. In figure 3.1, for example, the household (arbitrarily)
numbered 1 remained at step 1 in both periods, while household 107 moved
up from step 1 to step 3. Household 34 made the amazing rise from step 1
to step 6 over the 10-year period. Some households fell: household 2 moved
from step 4, well above poverty, to the lowest rung.
Adding the community-defined poverty line to the matrix enables us to
see which households moved out of (or into) poverty. In the example from the
village of Fateh Garh, the community poverty line was set between steps 3 and
4 of the ladder of life, so the focus group considered households on steps 1, 2,
or 3 of the ladder to be in poverty (figure 3.2). The dark gray region in figure
3.2 shows the “movers”—households (like 34 or 20 or 78) that started out
poor but moved up sufficiently to escape poverty (moving out of poverty, or
MOP). The light gray region shows poor households (like 23 or 107) that experienced some upward mobility but not enough to cross the community poverty
line. Both gray shaded regions together show “upward movement of the poor”
(mobility of the poor, or MPI)—initially poor households that experienced any
upward mobility, irrespective of whether they crossed the poverty line. Finally,
the striped region identifies households (like 74 or 18) that were initially nonpoor but fell into poverty (falling of the rich into poverty, or FRIP).
90
FIGURE 3.1
Community mobility matrix from Fateh Garh, Uttar Pradesh, shows types and magnitude of household mobility
1
10
years
ago
Now
1
2
3
4
5
6
Total
1, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 10, 11, 12,
13, 15, 19, 21, 22, 24, 25,
26, 27, 28, 29, 30, 32, 46,
47, 48, 49, 51, 53, 56, 57,
83, 84, 85, 110, 112, 113,
114, 116, 117, 118, 123,
124, 125, 126, 128, 133,
134, 135, 139, 149, 150
14, 23, 33, 50, 59, 64,
108, 109, 119, 120,
122, 129, 130, 131,
132, 137, 138
107
20, 76, 82,
86, 87,
136
93
34
78
42, 44, 45, 67, 95, 111, 140,
141, 145, 145, 147, 148
9, 16, 17, 38, 39, 40,
41, 43, 54, 58, 65, 66,
68, 69, 70, 71, 72, 73,
80, 89, 94, 127, 142,
143, 144
36, 37, 52, 55,
60, 61, 62, 63,
75, 103, 104,
115
81, 88
78
79
53
2
3
35
4
2, 106, 121
5
18, 31
6
Total
69
74
1
91
Households discussed as
examples in the text
43
14
9
92
6
77
3
4
90, 96, 97, 98,
99, 100, 101,
102, 105
9
11
150
Success from the Bottom Up
Steps
FIGURE 3.2
Community mobility matrix from Fateh Garh, Uttar Pradesh, shows household movement out of poverty, within poverty,
into poverty, and among the nonpoor
Steps
2
3
4
5
6
Total
1, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 10, 11, 12,
13, 15, 19, 21, 22, 24, 25,
26, 27, 28, 29, 30, 32, 46,
47, 48, 49, 51, 53, 56, 57,
83, 84, 85, 110, 112, 113,
114, 116, 117, 118, 123,
124, 125, 126, 128, 133,
134, 135, 139, 149, 150
14, 23, 33, 50, 59, 64,
108, 109, 119, 120,
122, 129, 130, 131,
132, 137, 138
107
20, 76, 82,
86, 87,
136
93
34
78
42, 44, 45, 67, 95, 111, 140,
141, 145, 145, 147, 148
9, 16, 17, 38, 39, 40,
41, 43, 54, 58, 65, 66,
68, 69, 70, 71, 72, 73,
80, 89, 94, 127, 142,
143, 144
79
53
4
2, 106, 121
74
5
18, 31
1
2
MPI
MOP
3
36, 37, 52, 55,
60, 61, 62, 63,
75, 103, 104,
115
81, 88
78
91
92
35
1
77
FRIP
6
Total
69
6
43
14
9
4
3
90, 96, 97, 98,
99, 100, 101,
102, 105
9
11
150
91
Note: Bold lines indicate the community poverty line. FRIP = falling of the rich into poverty; MOP = moving out of poverty; MPI = mobility of the poor.
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
10
years
ago
Now
1
92
Success from the Bottom Up
In the next two sections, we use the CMM to examine both the overall
mobility of households and how the movements in measured poverty rates
over time are related to household mobility.
Household dynamics on the ladder of life: Mobility and churning
Using the CMM, we calculate the “mobility index” that shows how many
households moved up or down at least one step on the ladder of life over the
10-year period.4 If all households remained in exactly the same category, the
mobility index would be 0, while if every single household moved (either up
or down), then it would be equal to 1.
The extremely high level of mobility is striking (table 3.1). The proportion of households that moved at least one step either up or down over the
past 10 years was more than half in 10 of the 18 study regions and above
40 percent in all but three regions. Movement across the categories is thus
very fluid. Note that this mobility index does not itself distinguish direction.
In some regions, mobility is primarily upward, as in Indonesia, where 46.3
percent moved up but only 6.6 percent moved down. In others, it represents “churning” as households rise and fall, as in Malawi, which had almost
the same amount of upward (38.1 percent) and downward (34.8 percent)
movement.
Two visual metaphors can help distinguish different notions about the
process of moving out of poverty.
Imagine a narrow escalator on which people are standing. All riders move
up at the same rate and hence retain their relative rankings. In this metaphor
of poverty reduction, an individual’s progress is determined by the pace of
the escalator he or she is on.
An alternative metaphor is a broad staircase. On these stairs, many people
are headed in both directions, moving at different speeds. Some are running
up, and some might be inching up, while others are headed down. Measured
poverty reduction or net upward movement over time is the result of both net
movement and churning as people go up and down.
These two metaphors can be used to illustrate a hypothetical example
involving 10 people in which poverty reduction is 20 percent in both cases.
Figure 3.3 shows people on a narrow escalator, with all households retaining their relative rankings and movement out of poverty entirely a matter of
the uniform upward movement common to all households. In the escalator,
everyone moves up one step at the same time. Poverty falls from six people to
four people, with no churning. The proportion of initially poor is 60 percent;
upward movement of the poor is 100 percent (all six of the initially poor move
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
93
TABLE 3.1
Over half of households moved up or down at least one step on the ladder of
life over 10 years
Study
region
Average
households
ranked in
CMM per
village
Mobility
index:
movers
up plus
movers
down
(%)
Movers
up (%)
PI a
Movers
down
(%)
FI b
Net
upward
movement:
movers up
less movers
down (%)c
Churning
index: ratio
of total
movers to
net upward
movement
Uganda
62
76.0
48.8
27.3
21.5
3.5
Malawi
54
72.9
38.1
34.8
3.3
21.9
Colombia
108
71.5
66.9
4.6
62.3
1.1
Tanzania
111
69.6
46.5
23.1
23.4
3.0
Senegal
68
69.5
43.0
26.5
16.5
4.2
Mexico
80
68.8
65.5
3.3
62.2
1.1
143
55.8
37.9
17.9
20.1
2.8
Bangladesh
Afghanistan
96
55.4
41.3
14.2
27.1
2.0
Indonesia
144
52.9
46.3
6.6
39.7
1.3
West
Bengal
150
52.3
36.9
15.4
21.6
2.4
Thailand
106
49.4
40.2
9.2
31.0
1.6
Morocco
111
47.5
28.4
19.1
9.3
5.1
Andhra
Pradesh
148
44.4
32.2
12.2
20.1
2.2
Philippines
(conflict)
145
43.0
26.4
16.6
9.8
4.4
Sri Lanka
(conflict)
99
42.1
32.6
9.6
23.0
1.8
Uttar
Pradesh
153
36.9
25.1
11.8
13.3
2.8
71
30.0
25.2
4.8
20.4
1.5
Assam
146
28.0
16.7
11.3
5.4
5.2
Median
109
52.6
38.0
13.2
21.0
2.6
Philippines
(Bukidnon)
Source: Authors’ calculations from ladder-of-life data.
a. Prosperity Index (PI) = gross proportion of all households that moved up.
b. Falling Index (FI) = gross proportion of all households that moved down.
c. Net Prosperity Index (NPI) = net proportion of all households that moved up less households that
moved down.
Period 2
Mr. J
Mr. H Ms. I Mr. J
Ms. G
Ms. I
Mr. F
Mr. H
Mr. E
Ms. G
Mr. F
Mr. D
Mr. E
Mr. C
Mr. D
Ms. B
Mr. C
Mr. A
Ms. B
Mr. A
Poverty line
Poverty line
Moved out of
poverty
Success from the Bottom Up
Period 1
94
FIGURE 3.3
Narrow escalator model illustrates moving out of poverty with all households retaining their relative rankings
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
95
up); movement out of poverty is 33 percent (two of the six initially poor cross
the poverty line); upward movement of the nonpoor is 75 percent; and net
poverty reduction is 20 percent.
Figure 3.4 shows a broad staircase with households churning in both
their absolute and relative status. In the staircase, three people moved out of
poverty, and one person fell into poverty. As in figure 3.3, the proportion of
initially poor is 60 percent. Upward movement of the poor is 67 percent (Ms.
B, Mr. C, Mr. D, and Mr. F moved up). Downward movement of the poor is
17 percent (Mr. E fell). Movement out of poverty is 50 percent (Ms. C, Mr. D,
and Mr. F moved out of poverty). Upward movement of the nonpoor is 50
percent (Mr. G and Mr. H moved up). Downward movement of the nonpoor
is 50 percent (Mr. J and Ms. I fell).
The community mobility matrix can distinguish gross mobility (how
many people moved up or down) from net prosperity—the net proportion
of households that moved up. Table 3.1 shows very different dynamics across
the study regions. Contrast the study regions in Mexico and Malawi (again,
neither region was chosen to be typical of the entire country). They have
similar indicators of mobility, with roughly 70 percent of households having moved on the ladder of life. In the small sample in Mexico, nearly all
households moved up, so this is like the narrow escalator model; there was
very little churning. Malawi, however, illustrates the broad staircase model.
There is a lot of movement, but most of it consists of households churning
up and down on a stationary stairway: 38 percent of households moved up,
35 percent of households moved down, and hence the net upward movement
was only 3 percent of households.
The “churning index” is the ratio of total moves to net upward moves.
The lowest this number could be is 1 (because a net upward move is a total
move), but if upward and downward moves are similarly balanced, it can be
very high. In Malawi, the churning index is 22—meaning 22 times as many
people changed places as the net number of people who moved up—because
the net upward movement was so small. Repeated household surveys would
see only that overall well-being was “about the same”; this would miss the
huge upward and downward movements that households experienced.
Poverty dynamics: Rising out of poverty and falling into poverty
Now that we have discussed general household mobility, let us turn to mobility in and out of poverty. Table 3.2 shows the relationship of household
movements to the community poverty line in each study region. This table
reveals three key points.
Period 1
Mr. J
Ms. G
Mr. F
Ms. I
Mr. H
Mr. J
Mr. H
Mr. C
Ms. G
Mr. D
Mr. F
Ms. B
Fell into
poverty
Mr. E
Ms. I
Mr. D
Moved out
of poverty
Mr. E
Mr. C
Ms. B
Fell down
Moved up
Mr. A
Mr. A
Poverty line
Poverty line
Success from the Bottom Up
Period 1
96
FIGURE 3.4
Broad staircase model illustrates moving out of poverty with households changing both their absolute and relative rankings
TABLE 3.2
Movements up and out of poverty are only one part of overall poverty dynamics
%
starting
poor
69.8
63.3
76.2
59.6
87.6
62.6
66.7
72.4
63.4
82.9
85.2
63.9
73.9
69.2
71.1
89.1
61.6
76.2
70.5
Movers as
% of total
households
22.4
18.8
23.3
27.4
44.2
22.2
12.8
12.5
10.6
16.3
25.4
19.3
18.0
9.6
6.8
11.3
10.7
10.2
17.2
Fallers as
% of total
households
10.2
7.8
4.2
9.8
0.6
2.9
5.5
10.5
3.5
6.7
4.5
8.5
10.1
6.4
5.4
3.8
2.0
10.6
5.9
Net
change in
poverty a
(%)
–12.2
–11.0
–19.1
–17.6
–43.6
–19.3
–7.4
–2.0
–7.1
–9.6
–20.8
–10.8
–7.9
–3.2
–1.4
–7.4
–8.7
0.4
–9.1
% of all
poor who
moved up
at least
one step
47.5
44.5
54.1
52.3
70.9
51.3
31.7
32.9
38.0
53.9
53.7
57.4
46.9
34.6
20.0
67.1
29.3
43.5
47.2
% of poor
who moved
down at
least one
step
7.4
7.9
0.8
1.8
2.3
2.1
5.7
6.4
6.7
15.4
9.5
16.3
15.9
11.2
6.0
2.7
1.3
24.7
6.6
% of
nonpoor
falling into
poverty
33.9
21.1
17.5
24.1
5.0
7.7
16.5
38.1
9.6
39.5
30.7
23.6
38.7
20.8
18.7
35.1
5.1
44.7
22.4
Churningb
3.2
2.9
1.9
2.5
1.7
1.8
3.2
16.7
3.8
6.5
2.7
5.8
7.9
11.6
14.7
8.8
2.8
164.3
3.5
Source: Authors’ calculations from ladder of life community mobility matrixes.
97
a. Figures in this column show poverty reduction.
b. Churning is defined as movers out of poverty plus movers into poverty plus movers within poverty (up and down) over the net reduction in number of poor.
c. MOP is based on the subsample of households that started out in poverty.
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
% of initial
poor who
moved out
Study region
of poverty c
Bangladesh
32.1
West Bengal
29.7
Indonesia
30.6
Afghanistan
45.9
Mexico
50.5
Thailand
35.4
Uttar Pradesh
19.2
Philippines—conflict
17.3
Andhra Pradesh
16.8
Tanzania
19.6
Sri Lanka—conflict
29.8
Uganda
30.3
Senegal
24.4
Morocco
13.9
Assam
9.6
Colombia—conflict
12.6
Philippines—Bukidnon
17.3
Malawi
13.4
Median
22.0
98
Success from the Bottom Up
First, over this period, there was considerable upward movement of people who began in poverty. In the typical study region, almost half (47.2 percent) of all households that began in poverty moved up by at least one step
on the ladder of life, and almost a quarter (22 percent) of the initially poor
moved out of poverty altogether.
This is not to say that poverty traps do not exist—only that most of the
people currently in poverty are probably not in a poverty trap. One needs
to distinguish, as in chapters 1 and 2, between the very small percentage of
poor people who have personal characteristics (such as chronic illness, alcoholism, or physical disability) that may keep them in extended episodes of
poverty, and the much larger number who are poor at a given point in time.
There are poverty traps, but not all poverty is a trap.
Recent studies have emphasized this point in different ways. For instance,
Carter and Ikegami (2007) emphasize that poverty mobility can be affected
by poor people’s endowments of assets and capabilities. These models can
lead to substantial poverty dynamics even while there are “intrinsically
chronically poor” who “lack the ability or circumstance to achieve a nonpoor
standard of living in their existing economic context” (5).
The Chronic Poverty Research Centre (2008), in its current report on
chronic poverty, estimates that 1.2 billion people were in absolute poverty
(below $1 a day) in 2002. Between a quarter (320 million) and one-third (443
million) of those in absolute poverty were trapped in “chronic poverty”—an
episode of poverty that lasts for many years, often a lifetime. The report attributes chronic poverty traps to five factors that correspond to many of the
same issues our study explores:
• Insecurity. Insecurity of assets and income may be caused by conflict,
economic crisis, and especially health shocks.
• Limited citizenship. This factor includes lack of voice and participation in
governance and service delivery.
• Spatial disadvantage. People are disadvantaged by living in chronically
deprived countries (identified based on per capita gross domestic product,
child mortality, fertility, and undernourishment). Even in countries that
are otherwise progressing, some locations may be unfavorable because
they are remote and politically marginalized, have poor agricultural and
natural resource endowments, or are not well connected to infrastructure
like roads and markets.
• Social discrimination. Important social divisions include those along lines
of gender, race, and caste.
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
99
• Poor economic opportunities. Even where there is local economic growth,
economic opportunities may be inaccessible to some people.
The recent chronic poverty report and ours are strikingly consistent on
some points. There is enormous fluidity in poverty: only a fraction (by their
estimates, from a quarter to a third) of those who are in an episode of poverty
at any point in time are in an extended episode of poverty. Even for those in
chronic poverty, their plight has less to do with individual characteristics than
with the opportunities—and the barriers to opportunities—that households
experience.
A second point that emerges from the analysis of poverty mobility is that
similar net reductions in poverty in the different study regions can mask very
different poverty dynamics. For instance, in West Bengal about 30 percent of
those who began in poverty moved out, while only about 17 percent of the
initially poor moved out of poverty in Andhra Pradesh. But the net reduction in poverty was only 4 percentage points larger in West Bengal. Why?
Because in West Bengal, 21.1 percent of the nonpoor moved into poverty, and
in Andhra Pradesh, this movement was only half as large. The dynamics of
the nonpoor matter for poverty reduction as well.
The extent of falling into poverty is particularly striking in Africa. Malawi’s communities registered a marginal increase in poverty (less than 1 percent). But this apparent stagnation does not mean there was no movement.
In Malawi, 45 percent of the households that were classified as nonpoor 10
years ago were considered poor today. Equally impressively, 43.5 percent of
those in poverty moved up at least one step—but 25 percent of those already
in poverty moved down. The lack of net increase in poverty hides enormous
churning in economic status among households.
Similarly large fractions of the nonpoor are falling into poverty in other
parts of Africa and, not surprisingly, in the conflict regions we studied. In
Ruvuma, Tanzania, and in Senegal, 40 and 39 percent of nonpoor households were reported to have fallen below the community poverty line. In
those study regions that sampled households affected by conflict, nearly a
third of nonpoor households fell into poverty. It is interesting that in the
conflict-affected region of the Philippines, 38 percent of the nonpoor fell
into poverty, but only 5 percent did in the nonconflict Bukidnon region of
that country.
This attention to movement into poverty is important. In designing
poverty reduction strategies, one might be tempted to consider only how
the economy and programs affect those who are now poor. But as the study
100
Success from the Bottom Up
regions show, how the nonpoor fare can be just as significant for the evolution of the overall poverty rate.
Third, the final column of table 3.2 shows very high levels of churning.
In the typical study region, the number of people who moved at all is three
times the net number of people who moved out of poverty. So, setting methodological issues to one side, a repeated household survey would have been
able only to identify a net reduction in poverty of, on average, 9.1 percent of
households over this 10-year period (shown in column 6). What would have
been missed is everything else—repeated surveys examining poverty headcounts would have missed the fact that 22 percent of poor households moved
out of poverty, but 22 percent of nonpoor households moved in. It would
have missed that 47 percent of the poor moved up (so roughly twice as many
moved up as moved out). It would have missed that 6.6 percent of people
already in poverty moved down.5
Our examination of the community mobility matrix is a new method,
but it confirms what has been found almost whenever economists have been
to able produce data linking households over time (often called “panel”
data). These studies have measured massive income mobility, very fluid
poverty dynamics, and high levels of vulnerability to episodes of poverty.6
Using data from Indonesia, Pritchett, Suryahadi, and Sumarto (2000) find
that transitions into and out of poverty mean that almost twice as many
households have at least one episode of poverty as do those who are poor at
any given point in time. Even over very short periods, measures find very large
transitions. For instance, when Dercon and Krishna (2000) compared two
surveys in Ethiopia less than a year apart, they found that only 32.8 percent
of households were in the same quintile in measured consumption expenditures. Even over that very short time, 13.7 percent had moved out of poverty
and 16.4 percent moved into poverty.7
Implications of household poverty dynamics
Are these metaphors of escalators and staircases really relevant for thinking
about poverty programs and policies? Indeed.
One direct policy consequence of these high levels of churning is that
programs that attempt to target benefits to “the poor” are unlikely to succeed
on any static criteria. If the poor were a fixed group (either absolutely or relatively), then they could be accurately identified and reached by transfers or
income generation programs. Poverty is a condition, a situation households
find themselves in, and the households in this situation turn out to be very
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
101
fluid; hence, “the poor” today are not “the poor” of tomorrow. The poor
today are just those households currently experiencing an episode of poverty;
they are a mix of the chronically destitute, those moving up, those with a
temporary spate of bad luck, and lots of people who fall between categories.
A classic study by Jalan and Ravallion (2000) followed the same households
in China over six years and found that a precise identification of those who
were poor in the first year did not help improve targeting much compared to
a simple uniform transfer to all households.
A second consequence of churning is that it shapes how one thinks
about distributional issues during episodes of reform. Ravallion (2004)
introduced the important distinction between changes in vertical inequality and changes in horizontal inequality.8 This distinction draws on a traditional distinction in the economics of public finance between vertical
equity (that richer households pay as much or more in taxes than do poorer
households) and horizontal equity (that people who are similarly situated
are treated similarly). He argues that much of the confusion in the discussion about globalization stems from the fact that pro-globalization advocates focus on vertical equity, claiming that globalization has been good for
absolute poverty reduction, while anti-globalization advocates focus on the
fact that there are winners and losers—that people who before were equal
are made unequal by change. As Ravallion points out, if one person moves
up and another down, the aggregate measures of income and inequality
might remain exactly the same. But the political and political economy
consequences would be very different, as this churning “is unlikely to go
unnoticed by the people involved” (20).
Kanbur (2008) points out that focusing only on the “snapshots” and
ignoring the movie may give rise to particular concerns about economic
transformations and policy change:
Consider a country where major structural changes are under way. These
will, in general, create winners and losers, in the short run and in the long
run. If the poor are all winners, or if there are some poor winners and
no poor losers, poverty will of course decline. But measured poverty may
also decline even if a significant number of the losers are poor, because
their losses are outweighed by the gains of the other poor. The anguish of
increasing poverty among some, perhaps a sizable number, of the poor,
will not be captured by the national level of decline in poverty. There will
be a disconnect between those who focus on these official statistics, and
those whose focus is on poor losers.
102
Success from the Bottom Up
The churning that our study reveals and emphasizes shows just how
important these considerations are empirically. Across the study regions, on
average, for each person who moved out of poverty there were three people
who moved either up or down. And even in cases like Bangladesh, where
the focus groups reported a net poverty reduction of 12 percentage points,
7 percent of the initial poor saw their fortunes worsen.
But more important than the consequences for targeting or design of narrowly conceived “poverty” programs are the broader implications for poverty
strategies. The broad conceptualization of poverty by the respondents in our
study translates into high rates of poverty; at the same time, we found high fluidity of transitions into and out of poverty. This finding has three implications.
First, attempts to characterize “the poor” as different are mostly misconceived. The people who either are in poverty, will be in poverty, or are at
risk of an episode of poverty make up a large share of the population. As our
study respondents conceive of it, the poor are us.
Second, a poverty strategy needs to facilitate what already happens.
Rather than attempting to rescue individuals from a poverty trap, poverty
strategies need to facilitate the aspirations and initiatives of those now poor
so they can escape their condition. Thus, a broader effort to unblock opportunities should substitute for a focus on intensive individual interventions.
Third, vulnerability is a fact of life. Given the massive numbers who fall
into poverty, effective poverty reduction strategies cannot focus only on helping the poor move up; they must also help those who are up stay up.
Defining poverty down
The very high level of upward mobility and churning of the poor that our
study documents is of course fundamentally related to how one defines poverty. If one insists on more and more penurious standards for poverty, then
perhaps one will find less mobility, and a higher fraction of the “poor” at any
point in time will be those in long-term episodes of poverty (poverty traps).
Moreover, as fewer and fewer people are regarded as “poor,” they will in some
senses appear more like an identifiable group. But at the levels of poverty that
the community focus groups identify, poverty is initially a very large fraction
of the population (typically around 70 percent). At these higher levels of
poverty, there is more fluidity up, down, and out of poverty.
The levels of poverty that our focus groups report are very different
from what might have been obtained in our study regions had we used a
US$1 a day standard that the World Bank uses in some global measures of
poverty (box 3.1) or other income-based technocratic definitions of pov-
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
103
BOX 3.1
Poverty lines and people’s perceptions of poverty lines
The present-day idea of a poverty line goes back a century to Charles Booth’s
work in 1889. Booth developed the first quantitative classification of poverty
based on income, with the “line of poverty” set between 18 and 21 shillings per week. However, the measures below and above the line of poverty
remained vague. It was Benjamin Seebohm Rowntree (1901), inspired by
Booth, who offered more precise income categorizations and who consistently used the term “poverty line” in his study of poverty in York, England.
This was the beginning of the tradition of measuring poverty by income and
focusing solutions on redistributing or increasing incomes (see Himmelfarb
1992 on the evolution of thinking about the poor and poverty).
Today, the US$1 a day standard, adjusted to local currency using purchasing power parities (PPPs),10 is widely used to track trends in global poverty.
The World Bank’s World Development Report 1990 was the first to employ a
universal poverty line to compare and aggregate poverty statistics across countries. Using constant 1985 PPP prices, the report proposed two poverty lines:
US$275 per person per year for the extremely poor and $370 per person per
year for the poor. The range was chosen to span the poverty lines estimated for
a number of countries with low average incomes: Bangladesh, Egypt, India,
Indonesia, Kenya, Morocco, and Tanzania. The lower limit of the range coincided with a poverty line commonly used in India. The international poverty
line was later revised in 1993 PPP terms and set at US$1.08 a day (Chen and
Ravallion 2000). The threshold was set using the median of the 10 lowest poverty lines in the set of countries used by World Development Report 1990 and
Ravallion, Datt, and van de Walle (1991). To gauge the sensitivity of poverty
indicators, a line twice this value—US$2.15 per day—was also used.
Since 2000, the World Bank has based its global poverty and inequality
measures on these two poverty lines. The poverty rate calculated using the US$1
a day line is usually treated as a conservative estimate because aggregate poverty
in the developing world is defined by perceptions of poverty rates in the poorest countries (World Bank 1990; Ravallion, Datt, and van de Walle 1991; Chen
and Ravallion 2000). Drawing on new International Comparison Program survey
data for 2005 to calculate new PPPs, Ravallion and Chen have just repeated this
process, calculating the average poverty line found in the poorest 10 to 20 countries at US$1.25 a day per person. Some national poverty lines are below this
line and some are above. For example, the national poverty lines used in both
China and India are closer to US$1 a day at 2005 prices. However, better-off
countries tend to have higher poverty lines than the frugal US$1.25 standard. In
discussing poverty in middle-income countries, the higher US$2 a day standard
is more appropriate. This is the median poverty line for all developing countries.
104
Success from the Bottom Up
erty. As figure 3.5 shows, the focus groups reported that poverty rates were
typically 20 to 30 percentage points higher than the $1 a day headcount
poverty rates (in making the comparison, we matched as best we could the
regions of the country—we used rural estimates only prior to the revision
of the poverty level to US$1.25 a day—and time of the survey).
Our focus group perceptions often aligned fairly closely with a standard
based on US$2 a day—sometimes higher, sometimes lower, but nearly always
closer than to the $1 a day standard.
FIGURE 3.5
$1-a-day international standard appears to underestimate poverty compared to
focus group estimates
100
% population in poverty
90
82
80
74
68
70
74
66
60
59
58
50
44
40
56
40
52
40
52
51
42
40
42
30
22
20
20
20
10
1
(C
as
te
)
AP
(S
H
W
G
B
)
(L
an
dd
ist
U
)
G
A
(P
an
el
)
PH
I(
Pa
ne
l)
TH
A
(In
eq
)
M
EX
(E
th
n)
3
U
P
)
(In
fra
)
N
po
w
SE
fra
(E
m
BA
N
(In
AL
M
TA
N
(R
uv
)
)
0
Study region
Community focus group ranking
US$1 a day standard
Source: Authors’ estimates using ladder of life data and data from PovCal (World Bank); closest match
on year and using rural estimates only.
Note:
AP (SHG) = Andhra Pradesh, Self-help groups
BAN (Empow) = Bangladesh, Women’s
empowerment
MAL (Infra) = Malawi, Infrastructure
MEX (Ethn) = Mexico, Ethnicity
PHI (Panel) = Philippines, Panel study
SEN (Infra) = Senegal, Infrastructure
TAN (Ruv) = Tanzania, Ruvuma
THAI (Ineq) = Thailand, Inequality
UGA (Panel) = Uganda, Panel study
UP (Caste) = Uttar Pradesh, Caste
WB (Landdist) = West Bengal, Land distribution
reforms
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
105
The point is not to dispute the World Bank’s numbers (as our study is not
representative), but rather to point out that there is no reason to expect the $1
a day standard and people’s everyday notions of poverty to correspond. Any
definition of poverty is a social convention, and social conventions are agreements about meanings among the actors involved in a given discourse around
a given purpose. The actors involved in the discourse about the $1 a day poverty
line are those who are interested in making international comparisons and
monitoring global progress toward the first Millennium Development Goal
focused on poverty.
Since attempts to define poverty are explicitly and unavoidably social
and political, one should not confuse “technical” with “better.” There is no
neutral, objective, “scientific” definition of poverty that has priority over
subjective and qualitative definitions of poverty. The principal difference
between the official poverty lines that use technically demanding techniques
and the community poverty lines based on the responses of individuals and
focus groups is not that one is “subjective” and the other is “objective;” rather,
the difference is in where the subjectivity is exercised and by whom. In one
case it is exercised by a technocrat who asserts a convention about what is an
“appropriate” food basket for the poor to consume—a once and for all assertion that allows the state to “see” poverty reduced to a single administratively
controlled measurement (Scott 1998). In the other case, the subjectivity is
exercised by the affected individuals in ordering their own reality.
Obviously, this is not meant to argue against the virtues of official global
or national poverty lines for some uses. They clearly have their merits, particularly in terms of providing a common poverty criterion for comparisons
across countries or across regions within a country, or perhaps for tracking
progress over time.9 But each definition and measure of poverty is appropriate
to its own sphere of discourse, and there can be no suggestion that technical
measures have exclusive rights—or even primacy—in the conceptualization,
definition, or measurement of poverty. Claims about “the poor” or “poverty”
based on standards that define poverty down by setting very stringent criteria
are no more or less reliable than any other social convention.
How Important Are Local Factors?
We have shown that the large churning in poverty status, as people move up
and down the ladder, belies the notion of a fixed and distinctive category of
people who are “poor.” Let us now ask: How much movement out of poverty
is due not just to the country where people live but to the locality within the
country? To extend the escalator metaphor, while the country’s overall pros-
106
Success from the Bottom Up
perity escalator may be fast or slow, people live in localities that have escalators of their own. A key question is how much difference there is between
the speeds of the local escalators. It could be that all are synchronized and
hence the average speed is also very close to the speed in each village, or it
could be that the countrywide average speed masks tremendous variation in
local speeds.
This is another area where tools have determined results. Household
survey sampling does not produce reliable estimates of village-level poverty
because sample sizes are typically far too small. Hence, most of the attention
in poverty research has gone to the change in poverty at the national level
(focusing only on net movement) and its relation to overall economic progress, to changes in inequality, and to the correlates of poverty at the household
level (as in the standard poverty profiles). Less attention has been paid to the
variation in poverty at the local level and its potential determinants.11
While our results on the poverty dynamics of individuals add to a growing literature, on the topic of local level variation, our technique is unique
and gives new insights. Since the community mobility matrix ranked the
entire population of a village or neighborhood, we have essentially censuslike estimates of the levels of well-being and their changes for a small locality.
These estimates allow us to examine the extent of difference between the various measures of prosperity and poverty reduction across these localities.
There are two main findings. First, the variation across villages in their
perceived movement out of poverty is much larger than expected. Even within
prosperous economies there are villages that are lagging, and within stagnant
economies there are villages with rapid poverty reduction. Second, while the
poor and nonpoor within villages tend to move together, there is heterogeneity in the extent to which local prosperity is shared.
Prosperity
We begin with an examination of the indexes of “prosperity.” Figure 3.6
contains box-whisker plots that illustrate the central tendency and dispersion of the prosperity index (PI, the gross proportion of all households that
moved up), the falling index (FI, the gross proportion of all households
that moved down), and the net prosperity index (NPI, the net proportion
of all households that moved up less households that moved down) across
communities in the study. The box and whisker plot is a graphic device
that shows both the central tendency and dispersion of data. In the graphs
for each study region, the line in the middle of the box is the median (the
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
107
50th percentile of the data) while the left edge of the rectangular box is the
25th percentile and the right edge is the 75th percentile.12 The lines extending from the box (the “whiskers”) illustrate the more extreme values. This
graphic device shows the order across study regions in their typical value.
For example, the box plot on the prosperity index is ordered from top to
bottom by the study region median value of PI (so study regions higher
had more upward movement). At the same time, one can see the variation
across villages/communities within the study regions by the width of the
boxes (and “whiskers” from the boxes). (These statistics comparing distribution of outcomes across communities are not exactly the same as the corresponding statistics for households in the study region, as the number of
households in each community varied.)
There is a wide range of outcomes across the study regions. Net prosperity over a decade varies from only about 3 percent of households in Malawi to
more than 60 percent in (the sampled regions of) Mexico.13 Also interesting
is that much of the difference in prosperity is due to the proportion falling,
not just the proportion rising. So, for instance, in many African regions with
low net prosperity, many households moved up—but many more moved
down. In Malawi, 43 percent of poor households and 21 percent of nonpoor
households moved up; these figures were similar, 44 percent and 24 percent,
for West Bengal. But net prosperity is only 3.3 percent in Malawi versus 21.6
percent in West Bengal. The difference is entirely in the falling: in West Bengal 8 percent of poor and 28 percent of nonpoor households fell over this
period, while in Malawi 25 percent of poor and fully 67 percent of nonpoor
households fell.
The advantage of having estimates for each community is that we can
show the variation in prosperity across sampled villages. The box plots show
that it is enormous: in fact, the variations across communities in the study
regions are nearly as large as the cross-region differences. For instance, Thailand is one of the study regions with highest net prosperity—but the bottom
25 percent of Thai villages have an NPI lower than all but six of the study
region medians. Conversely, Malawi has the lowest NPI of any country, but
the top 75 percent of villages have NPI similar to West Bengal or Senegal (at
the cross-region median). So even well-performing countries have lagging
communities, and lagging countries have thriving communities.
If one does a simple analysis of variance of NPI (net prosperity), one
finds that 73 percent of the variation across villages in the entire study is
variation across villages within the study regions. This finding suggests that
while overall national context is important to poverty reduction, there are
108
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 3.6
Rising, falling, and net prosperity indexes show large variations both across
study regions and across communities within regions
Prosperity Index (PI)
COL (Conf)
MEX (Ethn)
INDO (Conf)
TAN (Ruv)
UGA (Panel)
SRI (Conf)
THA (Ineq)
WB (Landdist)
SEN (Infra)
AFG (Conf)
MAL (Infra)
BAN (Empow)
AP (SHG)
MOR (Mig)
PHI (Conf)
UP (Rural)
PHI (Panel)
ASSM (Conf)
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
PI
Falling Index (FI)
MAL (Infra)
UGA (Panel)
MOR (Mig)
TAN (Ruv)
PHI (Conf)
WB (Landdist)
SEN (Infra)
BAN (Empow)
AFG (Conf)
ASSM (Conf)
SRI (Conf)
AP (SHG)
UP (Rural)
INDO (Conf)
THA (Ineq)
PHI (Panel)
MEX (Ethn)
COL (Conf)
0
0.2
0.4
FI
0.6
0.8
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
109
FIGURE 3.6 continued
Net Prosperity Index (NPI)
COL (Conf)
MEX (Ethn)
THA (Ineq)
INDO (Conf)
TAN (Ruv)
AFG (Conf)
SRI (Conf)
UGA (Panel)
SEN (Infra)
WB (Landdist)
AP (SHG)
PHI (Panel)
UP (Rural)
BAN (Empow)
MOR (Mig)
PHI (Conf)
ASSM (Conf)
MAL (Infra)
– 0.5
0
0.5
1
NPI
Source: Authors’ calculations with ladder of life community mobility matrixes.
also locality-specific trajectories that, over a decade, make a big difference to
the individuals in those places.
This is a new finding. While many have emphasized the obvious—that
there are rich and poor places within countries—this finding is about the
speed of poverty reduction and shows that there are very different paces in
local prosperity.
Movement of the poor
What about those who start initially poor in the distribution—the population group of most interest in our study? Figure 3.7 summarizes the MOP
(fraction of poor who moved out of poverty) and MPI (fraction of poor who
moved up) indexes for all study regions. The box plot on MOP shows large
differences across regions: a great deal of movement out of poverty in Mexico,
much less in conflict-affected Colombia and Assam.
Again a major finding is the large variability across the villages within
each study region. The box plots show that the movement up of the poor
110
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 3.7
Movement out of poverty and mobility of the poor indexes show large
variations both across study regions and across communities within regions
Moving Out of Poverty Index (MOP)
MEX (Ethn)
AFG (Conf)
BAN (Empow)
THA (Ineq)
SRI (Conf)
WB (Landdist)
INDO (Conf)
UGA (Panel)
SEN (Infra)
TAN (Ruv)
PHI (Conf)
UP (Rural)
MOR (Mig)
PHI (Panel)
MAL (Infra)
AP (SHG)
ASSM (Conf)
COL (Conf)
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
0.8
1
MOP
Mobility of the Poor Index (MPI)
MEX (Ethn)
COL (Conf)
UGA (Panel)
AFG (Conf)
THA (Ineq)
TAN (RUV)
SRI (Conf)
SEN (Infra)
WB (Landdist)
INDO (Conf)
BAN (Empow)
MAL (Infra)
MOR (Mig)
PHI (Conf)
AP (SHG)
UP (Rural)
PHI (Panel)
ASSM (Conf)
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
MPI
Source: Authors’ calculations with ladder of life community mobility matrixes.
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
111
is not primarily a “study region phenomenon”: that is, a household’s likelihood of moving up from poverty was related to its village of residence at
least as much as to the study region the village was in. The simple analysis
of variance finds that 75 percent of upward movement of the initially poor
(MPI) was variation across villages within study regions and only 25 percent
depended on the study region.
The large differences between villages in the changes in overall rankings
of perceived household well-being suggest that there may be locality-specific
elements of poverty experiences to be explained. In this sense, these findings set the stage for qualitative exploration—of processes and interactions
among factors that may explain mobility or lack thereof in different contexts.
If all of poverty progress depended either on the characteristics of individuals
or on national characteristics (or on some combination), then studying local
factors would be of little interest.
Co-movement of the nonpoor and poor
How does movement out of poverty relate with net prosperity across study
regions and communities? Do the poor and nonpoor move up together? Do
initial poverty levels matter? This section graphs relationships between some
of the indexes derived from the community mobility matrix to address these
questions and the policy debates they entail. Does growth or net prosperity
matter for movement out of poverty or movement of the poor?
Figure 3.8 shows how the fortunes of the poor and nonpoor moved
together across villages. Each graph (one per study region) shows for each
community the MPI (fraction of people who began poor and moved up)
and the MRI (fraction of people who began nonpoor and moved up). This
comparison allows one to visualize how the fortunes of poor and nonpoor
in the same communities were associated as the graph shows a 45-degree line
(equal movement of poor and rich) and a best-fit line through the villages
(which are sometimes very few). This figure and the accompanying regressions of MPI on MRI village by village suggest three points.
First, as discussed earlier, almost three-quarters of the variance in net
prosperity in the study regions consists of differences between villages in the
same study region. When this village mobility is broken down for poor and
nonpoor within each village, it appears that, on average, the poor and nonpoor
moved up together across the study communities (in addition to figure 3.8,
see the regression results in annex 3.1).14 This is not to suggest that upward
movement of the nonpoor causes upward movement of poorer households.
Rather, the findings suggest that there are large positive and negative village-
112
FIGURE 3.8
On average, the poor and nonpoor moved up together across study regions
ASSM (Conf)
BAN (Empow)
COL (Conf)
INDO (Conf)
MAL (Infra)
MEX (Ethn)
MOR (Mig)
PHI (Conflict)
PHI (Panel)
SEN (Infra)
SRI (Conf)
TAN (Ruv)
THA (Ineq)
UGA (Panel)
UP (Rural)
WB (Landdist)
Total
0
.5
1
MPI
0
.5
1
0
.5
1
AP (SHG)
Success from the Bottom Up
AFG (Conf)
0
.5
1
0
0
.5
1
0
.5
1
0
.5
MRI
Source: Authors’ calculations with ladder of life community mobility matrixes.
1
0
.5
1
.5
1
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
113
specific shocks to prosperity and that these usually affect the movements of
both poor and nonpoor households similarly. But in some cases they are
affected equally, while in other cases the shocks seem to have benefited either
the nonpoor or the poor disproportionately.
This co-movement of the poor and nonpoor across villages is an important background to the entire Moving Out of Poverty study. It suggests that
there are large “shocks,” positive and negative, that affect the prosperity of
villages; these are not specific to households, but neither are they national
in scope (or statewide in the case of India). Moreover, these shocks are not
specific to the poor but affect poor and nonpoor alike, though to differing
degrees. One important agenda of the broader study is to identify the correlates of local prosperity—are they economic conditions, infrastructure, functioning of local democracy, social conditions?
Second, though the increases in well-being of the poor and nonpoor
tended to move together across villages, the extent of their co-movement differed across regions. As seen in figure 3.8, in the four Indian states the movement was essentially one for one. However, the other regions display different
patterns. Annex 3.1 uses statistical techniques to identify different patterns in
the degree to which the prosperity of the poor and nonpoor moved together.
The important point is that the relationship itself seems quite different across
regions. In the context of the larger Moving Out of Poverty study, this heterogeneity across regions is also of great interest as it suggests that determinants
of the upward movement of the nonpoor and poor are not uniform.
Third, the large variation across villages in the extent of movement of the
poor and nonpoor is itself of interest. This raises the question of whether these
differences across villages in “shared prosperity” result from identifiable features of the economic, political, and social structures of the villages or from
positive and negative economic shocks to those villages. At the economic level,
different types of shocks will reward different types of assets and have different
impacts—to cite just one example, economic changes that increase demand for
labor (which is equally shared) will have a different impact than will economic
changes that increase returns to land. Exploring and perhaps explaining these
differences is an important agenda of the overall MOP study.
Positive and negative shocks are not necessarily symmetric. In fact, the
association between falling of the poor (FPI) and falling of the nonpoor (FRI)
is much weaker than the association between MPI and MRI. Hence, as illustrated in figure 3.9, the co-movement across villages of net prosperity of the
poor (NPP) and nonpoor (NPR) is much less than their co-movement of
upward mobility.
ASSM (Conf)
BAN (Empow)
COL (Conf)
INDO (Conf)
MAL (Infra)
MEX (Ethn)
MOR (Mig)
PHI (Conflict)
PHI (Panel)
SEN (Infra)
SRI (Conf)
TAN (Ruv)
THA (Ineq)
UGA (Panel)
UP (Rural)
WB (Landdist)
Total
–1 –.5 0 .5 1
–1 –.5 0 .5 1
NPP
–1 –.5 0 .5 1
AP (SHG)
Success from the Bottom Up
AFG (Conf)
114
FIGURE 3.9
Association is much weaker between net upward movements of the poor and nonpoor than between their
gross upward movements
–1 –.5 0 .5 1
–1 –.5
–1 –.5
0
.5
1
–1 –.5
0
.5
1
–1 –.5
0 .5
NPR
Source: Authors’ calculations with ladder of life community mobility matrixes.
1
–1 –.5
0
.5
1
0
.5
1
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
115
This may reveal asymmetries in gains versus losses, but it may also be
a mechanical effect of a ladder of life that is “bottom-coded.” That is, those
on the very bottom step of the ladder of life cannot move further down the
ladder, even if their well-being has fallen. Therefore, villages with large proportions of the nonpoor falling may not see similarly large falls among the
poor, because many of them began and ended on the bottommost step. For
instance, in table 3.2 one sees that in Tanzania, Uganda, and Senegal, the fallers among the initially poor were about 15 percent while the fallers among
the nonpoor were about 50 percent (and about 30 to 40 percent of the fallers among the nonpoor fell into poverty). Almost certainly, the “truncation”
effect of the ladder of life approach makes it more difficult to observe common falls than common rises: the “top coding” problem is much less severe,
given that far fewer people were in the uppermost category in either period.
Examination of Local Determinants
of Moving Out of Poverty
Let’s start with a poor person who is working hard to build her assets. What
helps? What hinders? Our hypothesis, as detailed in the conceptual framework developed in chapter 1, is that her ability to increase her well-being is
influenced by the opportunity structure she faces, which, in turn, is defined
by the broader institutional, social, and political context of the society where
she lives. We are concerned with two main types of institutions at the local
level: markets or available economic opportunity on one side and institutions of local democracy on the other side. These institutions influence the
rate of return an individual is able to get on her assets as well as the claims
on those assets.
Social divisions and social inequality, however, can reinforce inequality
in access to political and economic opportunities (Tilly 1999; Rao and Walton
2004b). Hence, when thinking about mobility of the poor, a third set of variables becomes important—and these have to do with agency of the poor.
Agency can operate at the individual or collective level. At the individual
level, it is measured by a sense of self-confidence, power, and self-efficacy. The
belief that “I can make a difference” can be an important precursor to action
(Bandura 1995, 1998). Capacity to aspire also motivates a person to action
and can lead to different and better futures (Appadurai 2004). For the most
marginalized people, their collective agency in organization, representation,
voice, and identity is critical in overcoming social discrimination that leads
to economic, social, and political exclusion and inequality. Without this col-
116
Success from the Bottom Up
lective capacity to negotiate, control, and bargain, individual initiative on its
own may not be sufficient. Taken together, individual and collective agency
can modify or create direct access to new economic opportunities, or it can
work through democracy, leading to greater mobility.
If we take the example of a rural farmer in Tanzania, any one of the above
correlates can influence the channels that lead to a change in income. Economic
opportunity and local growth can lead to better prices for her produce, reduced
costs of fertilizers, or a new market space that makes it profitable to engage in
additional activities (such as livestock rearing, selling milk, etc.). If the farmer
knows, however, that local government officials will expropriate the gains from
her produce, she will have little incentive to produce. Self-confidence and a
sense of “I can do it” can also positively affect her productivity, as can collective
action. She will also have more incentive to produce if she receives fair prices
on her products or expects to be given credit when applying for a loan.
Examination of local conditions and poverty reduction
We have shown that there are large differences in reported poverty reduction across villages, even within study regions. This raises the question of
which local characteristics are associated with the villages that experience
more rapid poverty reduction.
Before presenting some multivariate regressions that address this question, we should first mention three reasons we do not put more emphasis
on using the cross-village variation to examine effects. First, while we gain
benefits from allowing members of each village to define their own steps on
the well-being ladder and their own definition of poverty, we also lose direct
comparability. This means that even if two villages report the same change in
net prosperity in terms of the net proportion of households moving up, we
cannot be sure that these are equivalent movements, as the steps could have
been set farther apart in one village than in the other. Second, as explained
next, we want to emphasize context, which means we do not anticipate that a
linear regression pooled across purposively different contexts (e.g., sampling
in conflict areas) that forces numerical identical associations among variables will be a particularly fruitful research strategy. Third, regressions cannot answer questions about causal structure, so this study is not designed to
test questions about underlying economic models of behavior or economic
structure.
All that said, for the villages from the four states of India, we did pool
the data and examine the correlations (table 3.3). We did this analysis for
TABLE 3.3
Various measures of well-being dynamics are associated with local (village-level) factors in four states of India
Variable
MOP
MRI
FPI
FRI
FRIP
NPR
−.0208*
.0078**
.0241***
.0081
−.0099**
7.70E-04
−.0267
.0099
.0032
−1.80E-04
−.0057
−.0019
−.252***
−.0294
−.135***
−.171***
.3873***
288
.35
−.0013
−.0023
−.012**
−.0043
.005
−6.90E-04
.067*
−.0165
.0058
6.2e-04**
.0027
−.0032
.0976***
−.0274*
−.033*
−.0236*
.0595*
288
.12
.0047
−.0062
.0012
−.0012
−.0098
−.0015*
.0664
−.0123
−.0022
1.00E-04
.0222*
−.0143
.1426**
−.0215
−.0538
−.0369
.2287***
288
.14
.0132
−.0072**
−.0157
−.0084
−.0071
−.002***
.0841
−.0207
7.80E-04
4.30E-04
.0318***
−.0074
.219***
−.0394
−.051
−.005
.0944
288
.21
−.0167**
.0047*
.0047
.0276*
−.0085*
−2.20E-04
−.0244
.0078
−.0012
−9.30E-05
.0043
−7.90E-04
.0425
−.0424**
−.078***
−.0478**
.0566
288
.12
Source: Narayan, Petesch, and Paul (2009).
Note: A positive coefficient with MOP, MPI, and MRI means it helps upward movement; a negative coefficient with FPI, FRI, and FRIP means it prevents downward
movement.
*p < .10 **p < .05 ***p < .01 (White heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors)
117
MPI
−.0266**
.0102**
.0469***
.0527**
−.0259***
.0025**
−.1382**
.0418***
.008
−.0014***
.018*
−.0364***
−.1578**
.0022
−.1759***
−.1412***
.4366***
288
.32
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
Difficulty of finding private employment
−.031***
Difficulty of employment economic access
.0101***
Improvement of market outlets in the community
.0445***
Government attention
.0694***
Government attention political participation
−.028***
Women membership in community council
.0015
Presence of private health center
−.0691
Private health center access to social network
.0181
Educational opportunities
.0033
Distance from the nearest city
−9.2e-04**
Irrigation facility
1.10E-04
Collective action to solve water problem
−.0227**
Share of initially poor population
−.3426***
Andhra Pradesh dummy
−.0259
Assam dummy
−.1113***
Uttar Pradesh dummy
−.0847***
Constant
.4223***
Observations
288
R2
.43
118
Success from the Bottom Up
measures of upward mobility of the poor (such as MOP and MPI) and of the
nonpoor, and separately for rises and falls (as there is no reason to impose
symmetry to upside and downside factors).
The results are consistent with several narratives. First, reassuringly, availability of employment is associated with greater reductions in poverty. The
association of employment expansion and prosperity should not come as
a surprise; what is interesting is that the larger poverty-reducing effects are
associated with greater equality of opportunity—with the presence of more
jobs to which access is relatively uniform.
The results also suggest that greater expansion of markets is associated
with moving out of poverty (and moving up of the nonpoor). Clearly, cause
and effect could run both ways, as one would expect new markets to open up
in prospering villages.
The “attention of the government” seems to be associated with upward
movement for the poor, but not for the nonpoor.
At the same time, there are puzzling correlations. Having a private health
center is associated with less upward movement of the poor. More collective
action to solve water problems also, curiously, is associated with less upward
movement of the poor. We discuss these negative signs in chapter 7 on collective action.
Overall, the simple regressions are consistent with the view of large differences in outcomes across villages. Some village characteristics raise the
mobility of both the poor and nonpoor, while others affect poor and nonpoor differently. But regressions do not identify causal links or economic
structure and must be interpreted simply as identifying patterns that need to
be explained.
Context is important in understanding local influences
Like all phenomena, poverty can be usefully viewed from many different angles
and through many different lenses. We can view a forest from an airplane
10,000 feet up, and each leaf will meld into a green blur; or we can examine a
tree with the naked eye and see many individual leaves; or we can put one leaf
under a microscope so powerful that the forest, the tree, and the leaf all disappear and only the underlying cells are visible. As one moves closer, aspects that
seemed the same are revealed to be full of specificity and texture.
So too, villages that appear exactly alike on a census or poverty map turn
out to be full of local texture when scrutinized up close. The appropriate
lens for viewing depends on the question being asked. In this study, we use
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
119
empirical analysis like the regressions in table 3.3 to examine broad patterns,
but we keep in mind that these regressions necessarily smooth over local
texture and context.
Consider the cases of Dhampur and Malkapur, two villages located in
the Adilabad district of Andhra Pradesh. Both communities share a history of
economic shocks caused by persistent droughts and unexpected rainstorms
that have adversely affected agriculture, the main source of livelihood. Both
communities report multiple additional factors contributing to their poverty,
including family feuds leading to land division, irregular work opportunities leading to indebtedness, lack of proper roads and transport leading to
problems of communication, and irregular power supply leading to failure
of electric irrigation pumps. Both villages have had a similar sequence of
infrastructure development and delivery of basic services. Collective action is
a significant feature of both: Dhampur has 22 self-help groups and Malkapur
18. Yet the two communities diverge in their accounts of who gained and
who lost the most in the face of crises and opportunities.
Over the past 10 years, social stratification seems to have declined sharply
in Malkapur, and at the time of data collection the community was characterized by solidarity and unity. People attribute this change to the efforts made
by the state-sponsored Janmabhoomi program in 1997, which encouraged
greater community participation.15 In the decade between 1995 and 2005,
access of lower-caste groups to temples and schools in Malkapur improved,
leading to feelings of cohesion. Self-help groups in Malkapur engaged people from different socioeconomic backgrounds, bridging distances between
groups. In addition, people believed that their ability to contact government
officials and leaders had increased, with the political environment in 2005
conducive to active participation in decision making.
In contrast, social stratification is pervasive in Dhampur. Groups are
demarcated strictly on the basis of their caste membership (untouchables,
lower castes, backward castes, and upper castes) as well as their religious
identity and education levels. “We are not treated properly,” complained
a discussion group of men and women from lower castes. “They [higher
caste people] do not even give us water as they consider us untouchables.
We have to drink water with our hands only. We are not allowed into the
temples. Even if we push ourselves into the temples, we have to pay a fine
in the panchayat.”
Caste inequalities run parallel to economic inequalities in Dhampur,
with the higher castes also occupying higher positions on the ladder and the
untouchables ranked the poorest. These inequalities translate further into
120
Success from the Bottom Up
political differences in rights to contest elections or speak in matters of local
governance. The lower castes said, “All of us never participate in the decision
taking process of the village. Lambadis [upper castes] are the rulers in the village. They have more land. They alone contest in the elections and they forbid
others to participate in the elections. We can never compare ourselves with
them. They have economic strength and manpower as well.”
Worse, state action to distribute land to lower castes in Dhampur has
resulted in garrisoning among the better-off groups against the poor. The
upper castes in Dhampur felt threatened and complained about a government law that gave only the lower castes the power to buy and sell land in
the community. A discussion group of men from lower castes said, “There
is a rule that all of us lower-caste people should obey those from the higher
castes. We cannot deny them. If we do so, we are not given any work, without
which we cannot live. If we see anyone belonging to the higher caste in the
bazaar, we have to take our slippers in our hand and walk. Even now, if they
get to know that we are talking about such things to strangers, we would be
punished.”
While self-help groups in both Malkapur and Dhampur function in a
similar manner, groups in Dhampur have begun to dwindle. Members attributed the decline to the higher monthly saving commitment fixed by the economically better off in their groups, with no thought given to the economic
capabilities of poorer members.
The indicators for mobility among both the poor and rich are indicative
of the social context of the two villages. Although both communities had
an identical share of poor people moving up (MPI of 41 percent), Malkapur had a higher percentage of people moving out of poverty (MOP of 29
percent compared to Dhampur’s 17 percent). Moreover, prosperity seemed
to be unequally shared in Dhampur, with nearly 44 percent of the nonpoor
experiencing upward movement (MRI) and no decline.
The experience of Dhampur suggests that inequalities embedded in
social structures may prevent poor people from gaining access to opportunities. On the other hand, as the case of Malkapur suggests, a good local democratic structure, cooperative local leaders, and active self-help groups may
help ameliorate caste differences and open up opportunities to all.
These case studies show that pro-poor government policies and growth in
economic opportunities can have different impacts on poor people depending on the way these policies and opportunities interact with other features
in the local environment—inequalities based on wealth, social class divi-
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
121
sions, political connections, and responsiveness of local government, among
others.
Conclusion
The Moving Out of Poverty study, by looking at the phenomenon of poverty
with several different tools, is able to illuminate different aspects of transitions out of poverty.
First, we find that poverty is a transitory condition and that there is enormous fluidity of households into and out of poverty. Speaking of “the poor”
as if they constituted a distinct set of people is just not a fruitful approach to
poverty reduction in poor countries. Poverty is a condition, not a characteristic. This then frames the question: How does one facilitate transitions by
households out of the condition of poverty?
Second, by using rankings of entire communities, we can rank the
importance of local conditions for poverty reduction. We find that although
national (or regional) differences are certainly important, empirically more
important are locally specific changes that affect both poor and nonpoor.
Third, we used our village-level data to launch an empirical analysis of
the conditions that determined changes in poverty. This motivates much of
the subsequent study, as we examine the local conditions in both economics (chapter 5) and politics (chapter 6) that are associated with greater local
prosperity and movements out of poverty.
122
Success from the Bottom Up
Annex 3.1 Associations in the Upward Mobility of Poor
and Nonpoor across the Study Regions
Table A3.4 shows the results of regressing the net upward movement of the
poor (MPI) on the net upward movement of the nonpoor, first across all villages (first row) and then for each study region.
The ordinary least squares (OLS) results show that there is a strong
association but that it appears to be well less than one for one. But before
concluding that growth is typically not shared and before discussing the
heterogeneity of results across countries, we should note that measurement
error in MRI would bias downward the regression estimate of the association between MPI and MRI results (an attenuation bias toward zero). When
we adjust for the potential bias from measurement error, we find that the
data typically are consistent with one-for-one co-movement of the poor and
nonpoor.16
Examining the country-by-country results, table A3.4 shows a set of five
study regions. In the first group, the Indian states show roughly one-for-one
movement of poor and nonpoor.
The second group (Thailand, Bangladesh, Mexico, Philippines, Sri
Lanka) statistically rejects that the association of MPI and MRI is zero across
villages, but it also estimates the association to be significantly less than one
for one. In the villages of these regions, as the proportion of nonpoor households moving up increased, the proportion of poor households moving up
increased by less, presumably resulting in an increase in inequality. However,
if one examines the “reverse regression” results, the lack of one-for-one association in these cases could be the result of measurement error.
In the third group (Uganda, Senegal, Indonesia, Morocco), the co-movement of poor and nonpoor appears to be quite small, as OLS regressions
using this data cannot reject the hypothesis that the association is zero (but
can reject that it is one for one).
In the fourth group (Malawi, Tanzania, Afghanistan, Colombia), the
number of villages was too small for the analysis to have any statistical power.
For instance, the point estimate for Malawi is 0.43, but the precision of the
estimate is so low that neither zero nor one can be statistically rejected.
123
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
TABLE A3.4
On average, the poor and nonpoor in the same villages moved up together
across study regions
Study
region
Pooled
(with fixed)
N
471
OLS
coefficient
0.54
Std.
error
R2
0.05
0.32a
1/coeff
from
reverse
regression
2.26
t-test
H0:
b=0
t-test
H0:
b=1
11.93
10.29
Regions that reject zero association and fail to reject a one-for-one association
Uttar
Pradesh
111
0.84
0.15
0.36
2.35
5.77
1.13
West
Bengalb
81
0.76
0.11
0.35
2.20
6.94
2.16
Andhra
Pradesh
57
0.79
0.13
0.29
2.72
6.10
1.65
Assam
51
0.83
0.21
0.40
2.06
3.88
0.81
Regions that reject zero association but reject a one-for-one association
Thailand
33
0.49
0.21
0.24
2.08
2.39
2.45
Bangladesh
17
0.50
0.12
0.38
1.31
4.14
4.12
Mexico
13
0.39
0.18
0.27
1.44
2.17
3.42
Philippines
11
0.60
0.08
0.60
1.00
7.55
5.01
Sri Lanka—
conflict
7
0.50
0.23
0.50
1.02
2.20
2.17
Regions that fail to reject zero association but reject a one-for-one association
Uganda
18
0.27
0.18
0.11
2.46
1.55
4.10
Senegal
16
0.32
0.23
0.15
2.20
1.42
2.98
Indonesia
11
−0.18
0.44
0.01
−12.99
−0.41
2.68
Morocco
10
0.29
0.25
0.14
2.11
1.14
2.87
Regions that fail to reject either zero association or a one-for-one association
Malawi
9
0.43
0.37
0.08
5.68
1.17
1.56
Tanzania
7
0.07
0.79
0.00
67.11
0.08
1.18
Afghanistan
7
−0.10
0.65
0.00
−14.71
−0.15
−0.14
Colombia
4
0.57
0.29
0.52
1.11
1.96
1.46
Source: Authors’ calculations with ladder of life community mobility matrixes.
a. This is the R2 of the bivariate regression of MPI on MRI excluding the study region fixed effects. With
fixed effects, the R2 increases to .422.
b. West Bengal is included in this category even though the t-test using OLS rejects one for one on the
basis of the instrumental variable results in which the association is one for one for West Bengal (see
note 16).
124
Success from the Bottom Up
Notes
1. If exactly the same survey is conducted, the household survey can also be used
to compare changes in poverty—but a major lesson of the past two decades of
poverty research is just how hard it is to conduct exactly the same survey and how
even small changes in questionnaire design or survey technique can lead to large
changes in measured poverty.
2. This is an exercise in “poverty mapping” that attempts to use a combination of
census data and household surveys to produce very fine-grained estimates of
poverty.
3. We refer to a “village” even though in some urban areas it was a neighborhood,
and in cases of a large village, it may have been a smaller unit of the village. In
the latter case, the subunit does not necessarily correspond to the political or
administrative jurisdiction called a village, but it is often closer to what people
think of as their “village” in a social and spatial sense.
4. It should be kept in mind that because the mobility matrixes are not comparable
across villages, we do not know whether two steps in one village represents
a smaller or larger movement than one step in another village. One methodological concern is that some amount of the differences between villages or study
regions in measured churning may be due to these differences between villages
in numbers of well-being categories. If one took the same underlying mobility in
consumption expenditures and divided it up into smaller and smaller categories
(e.g., quartiles to deciles), then for exactly the same mobility in expenditures,
one would observe more mobility across categories. However, careful examination of the data from the four states of India, which have larger numbers of
villages than the other study regions, did not suggest this was the case. The measured mobility index was not systematically higher for villages with more ladder
of life categories (with the possible exception of certain villages in Uttar Pradesh
that had only four or five steps on their ladders and showed lower mobility).
5. The “poverty gap” measures can measure movements within poverty—for example, an increase in the poverty gap implies that those who are poor are further
from the poverty line. But they are also net measures and cannot distinguish
uniform moves of households from churning.
6. These include studies by Grootaert and Kanbur (1995) on Côte d’Ivoire; Pritchett, Suryahadi, and Sumarto (2000) on Indonesia; Carter and May (2001) on
South Africa; Baulch and McCulloch (2002) on Pakistan; Deininger and Okidi
(2003) on Uganda; and B. Sen (2003) on Bangladesh. Studies of vulnerability,
poverty transitions, and income mobility using short-run panels include Pritchett, Suryahadi, and Sumarto (2000) in Indonesia; Dercon (2004) in Ethiopia;
Glewwe and Hall (1998) in Peru; and Carter and May (2001) in South Africa.
7. Of particular note are the multiround surveys that cover long periods with
multiple observations on each household (and its splits), such as the Indonesia
Family Life Survey (IFLS), the NCAER India panel used by Bhide and Mehta
(2004) and Munshi and Rosenzweig (2005), the China panel used by Jalan and
Ravallion (2002), and a panel data set from Kagera, Tanzania, used by Beegle,
de Weerdt, and Dercon (2006). Baulch and McCulloch (2002). They show that
while transient poverty can be addressed through income-smoothing measures,
Poverty Is a Condition, Not a Characteristic
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
125
addressing chronic poverty may require more income-growth policies such as
investment in households’ productive earning capacity. Some of the earliest
work on panel surveys of households, the work on Côte d’Ivoire in the 1980s,
concluded that measurement error in income in rural settings was so large as to
make the estimates of income changes virtually meaningless. Even with a switch
to the use of consumption expenditures as a proxy for long-run income, the
measurement error problem remains serious.
For a good discussion of horizontal inequality, see Stewart (2001).
We do not dwell on the many methodological difficulties in doing these tasks
reasonably well. Other studies (e.g., Deaton 2004) have examined discrepancies
in their calculation due to the infrequent updating of PPP exchange rates; some
recent very large shifts in cross-national measures of poverty are due exclusively
to these adjustments. Other difficulties involve correctly adjusting for regional
price differentials and maintaining comparability of poverty lines over time
given changes in relative prices.
PPP estimates are necessary to make international comparisons of income/consumption welfare. PPP is a conversion rate for a given currency into a reference
currency (such as US$) that aims to ensure parity in terms of purchasing power
of commodities—both traded and untraded—between countries.
The emergence of the “poverty mapping” agenda (e.g., Lanjouw et al. 2007) has
to some extent changed this view, because it links household survey data (which
tend to have less than 20 household observations per primary sampling unit)
to census data (which have complete household observations and detail at the
community level).
Not all data is symmetric, so there is nothing that dictates that 25th and 75th percentiles would be equidistant (many people assume this because they are used to
having mean plus/minus a standard deviation, which assumes symmetry).
Again, because the samples are not representative of the country and there are
only 12 study villages in Mexico, some of the cross-country differences represent
sampling phenomena rather than countrywide phenomena.
The pooled regression across all villages (with fixed effects for each study region)
shows a coefficient of .54 and an incremental R2 of .32 (not including the fixed
effects).
The Janmabhoomi program was a government initiative that dealt with issues
of caste inequality, encouraged participation in local governance by empowering
the gram sabhas (village assemblies), and promoted formation of more self-help
groups. Some observers of local government feel that the program bypassed the
local panchayats, thus weakening them.
A second technique for addressing measurement error is to use an instrumental
variable. Fortunately, the male and female focus groups in India ranked the
households independently, so we have a classic instrumental variable of repeated
measurement. If one performs the same regressions using the women’s estimates
of MRI as the instrument for the men’s estimates of MRI, one gets estimates that
for each of the Indian states are very close to 1, as the estimates are higher by
a magnitude that suggests measurement error is 10 to 20 percent of the total
observed variation in MRI.
I Believe I Can
If you fall 10 times, you have to stand
up 10 times, no matter what happens.
—G RACIELA ,
A
53- YEAR - OLD DISPLACED WOMAN ,
El Mirador, Colombia
I think I can face anything; it is just a
matter of self-discipline.
—L OIDA ,
A
35- YEAR - OLD FEMALE MOVER ,
Kilaluna, Philippines
A strong breeze can break branches.
A whirlpool in the ocean waters can
sink boats. But a strong willpower
can give you courage, and even if your
destination is a thousand miles away,
you can be successful.
—A MIT , A YOUNG MAN ,
Jigna, Uttar Pradesh
4
C HAPTER
A
s our field team approaches, Oy looks up from her cassavas. The
researchers introduce themselves and mention the purpose of the
visit. She smiles and says, “My life has changed for the better over the past
13 years. We are able to have things we never had; we are very proud and
happy.”
Thirty-nine years old and a native of Klong Pud, a small farming community in Thailand, Oy is identified as a mover out of poverty. She has two
young children in school and a loving, hardworking, and supportive husband with a steady job. The family lives in a proper house and farms their
own land, selling the produce in the market.
Conditions were not always so good for Oy and her family. Born to a
family of laborers and married to a craftsman, she worked under harsh conditions from a young age, at one point migrating to another village to work
on a ginger farm. She and her husband lived in a small shack with walls of
woven bamboo and grass on a piece of land belonging to their relatives.
Their fortunes began to improve in 1991, when Oy started selling vegetables
at a nearby market that was also close to Bangkok. She began sales with a
traditional Thai melon that her uncle cultivated. “I did not buy them,” she
says of the melons. “I just took them at first, put them in a cart that could
be attached to a motorcycle, and sold them in the city.” The response was
encouraging, and Oy started selling other vegetables as well. She gathered
them from people, sold them in the market, and split the proceeds with the
producers. “I was the only person who would buy the vegetables and sell
them outside. I would get up at 2 or 3 a.m. each morning. Wholesale trade
started in the market around 2 or 3 a.m. with retail trade at 4 a.m. I had to be
there until 8 a.m. each day.”
The business gradually picked up. Saving bit by bit over the years, Oy
bought land, a pickup truck to transport the vegetables, and a car. She also
127
128
Success from the Bottom Up
built a proper house for the family. “Our house was a shack earlier. This gave
me more willpower. I would wake up very early. I was committed to building
a permanent house like other people.” Her husband’s fortunes changed, too,
when he landed a job in the highway department. Oy now cultivates corn,
cassavas, bananas, and fruit on her land and has bought additional land as
an asset for her children.
Movement up has not been without sacrifice. Oy recalled her early days
in the business: “My husband had to get up early to take the vegetables and
me to the market, and later in the day he would pick me up and take me
home. I had to leave my children with my relatives. I was sleep deprived and
tired each day. Truthfully speaking, I felt ashamed selling in the market. But
when things were difficult, the shame just disappeared.”
Asked about the secret to her success, she says, “All we had was perseverance and physical labor. Being poor gave us the perseverance to better ourselves. The changing point was selling vegetables. It was as if we had
found the right channel. Everything we touched made money. From having
nothing at all, we were able to have everything that we wanted. This was possible because of our commitment, ability to economize, and knowing how to
save. I thought only that this is what I have to do today, and I did it. It is we
who cause change.” She recalls, now with tears in her eyes, “When we were
still poor, when we were living in a shack, people looked down on us. They
would not talk to us at all. They would talk badly of us to other people. Some
committee members, when they had news, would not tell us. Nowadays they
talk to us.”
Oy concludes, “I have more confidence. When I put my heart into doing
something and think that I can do it, and then am able to do it, there is more
confidence. I was able to build up my status so my confidence gradually
increased.” She shares her wisdom with our team: “Don’t do things halfway
or in between. When you are committed to doing something, do it. Some
people do trade half-heartedly and quit. To be in trade, one needs determination, concentration, perseverance. If there is no perseverance, there will
be nothing left. You cannot stop. Another thing that helps is confidence in
children. They should be better than us.” She glances at her children who are
playing nearby, a wistful look in her eyes.
Halfway around the world from Thailand, Santa María is an urban,
crime-infested informal settlement on the outskirts of Cartagena, Colombia. The crowded shantytown is home to many people displaced by internal
conflict. The settlers typically survive on activities like informal vending,
bricklaying, and casual labor; a fortunate few own and run small businesses.
I Believe I Can
129
A small agricultural group called the Ambarema Peasants Association helps
people find work on nearby farms to supplement their income from informal sales and labor.
Our team walks through the settlement looking for Pedro, a 32-year-old
man who lives in poverty. They find him laying bricks. One of the first things
that he speaks of is how much he misses his home in the countryside, from
which he was displaced. “That was a good time,” he reminisces. “We were
never hungry. There was always food—raising a pig, raising a hen, and eating it. Here even if we have money, we do not eat.” Pedro has been laying
bricks since the age of 17, and this work has given him an additional source
of income besides farming. He learned the skill from his brother-in-law. “I
had to learn. The masters in the work taught me. I learned thanks to others.
But I set my own goals.”
Upon arriving in Santa María, Pedro engaged in petty vending, the only
work immediately available. He thinks this work helped him face a difficult
period of his life, although he says his economic recovery would have been
easier if he had had a formal job. “That was the one giving me the rice,” he
says of informal vending. “But for me there is no bad job. There are only
desires and dreams.”
His bricklaying skills came to his aid when he received an offer to become
assistant to a neighborhood engineer. “The engineer saw that I knew how to do
things, and he promoted me to the post of an officer. That is how I got some
contacts and started meeting people.” Since 2001, he has been connected to
the Ambarema Peasants Association. “When I run out of work, I go looking for
maraña [casual labor]. In the time that I don’t have to harvest, I go out and sell or
look for any way to find some rice. The work in the [land] parcel has been there
since 2001. They gave me the terrain because people know I like agriculture.”
For Pedro, working on the farm represents a connection to the activity he grew
up with and lost because of the displacement. “There is no possibility of going
back to the place where I had my lands,” he says. “But I feel confident, because I
like setting goals for myself. I like moving on, overcoming obstacles.”
Belief in Self
The stories of Oy and Pedro resonate with their belief in themselves, with
the confidence to set goals and pursue them relentlessly, overcoming obstacles. Noted scholars and thousands of grassroots practitioners have argued
the importance of putting people and their agency at the center of development.1 Amartya Sen argues that agency—a person’s ability to act on behalf
130
Success from the Bottom Up
of what he or she values—is both intrinsically valuable and instrumentally
effective in reducing poverty. Policies supporting poor people’s agency call
for an expansion in their capabilities, which Sen defines as the freedom to
achieve valuable “beings and doings” (1985, 1992, 1993). This capability set,
according to Sen, is much wider than the traditional utilitarian or asset space
and consists of material, human, social, and political assets and even a psychological sense of self-efficacy (confidence, imagination, aspirations). These
capabilities allow every human the freedom to function as she wishes.
In chapters 1 and 2, we argued that poor people are capable of being
agents on their own behalf and that they have high aspirations for themselves
and for their children. In this chapter, we dig deeper in our data to show how
the flow of household effort and initiative depends first and foremost on the
individual’s personal agency, empowerment, aspirations, and sense of control over his or her own destiny. Our focus is to understand how power within
a person can help in the movement out of poverty.
We start our analysis by examining poor people’s own definitions and
understandings of power. These reflect Lukes’ (1974) classic division of
power into “power to” and “power over.” Poor people also talk about what
feminist scholars have called “power with.” Poor people have tremendous
belief in themselves, but they also have a deep understanding of the prevailing inequality in distribution of resources and power. This inequality negatively affects relations between the poor and the rich, because people respond
with jealousy, resentment, and “weapons of the weak,” and also the relations
among poor people themselves.
Against this backdrop of inequality, people in our study repeatedly
stressed the importance of personal agency. Over and over, they said that
self-confidence, a sense of control over one’s own decisions, and a sense of “I
can do it” are what allows a person to move up.
This sense of personal agency appears to precede the acquisition of other
valuable assets, such as education, money, or a house. People see these as
reinforcing their internal efficacy, which has to come first. Oy says simply,
“If there is no perseverance, there will be nothing left.” In other words, poor
women and men agree with what psychologists have long said—that external
conditions or resources are necessary for empowerment but not sufficient
(Diener and Diener 2005). A discussion group of women in Satgailijhara, Bangladesh, put it this way: “What if a woman has a lot of money and education
but she doesn’t have the capacity to use it? How can she get empowered?
The poor have power too. They have enthusiasm. The rich, who have money,
sometimes don’t have enthusiasm.”
I Believe I Can
131
Another psychological dimension, the capacity to aspire, to imagine a
better future for oneself and for one’s children, is importantly linked to moving out of poverty. The dreams and aspirations of young people do not seem
to be limited by their parents’ occupations.
If these psychological capabilities are so important, what can help or hinder them? We focus particularly on personal agency and end the chapter by
looking at several factors that can increase personal agency—material assets,
education, and political connections—and an important factor that decreases
it, namely health and death shocks. This sets the stage for the following chapters that discuss how personal agency, assets, and capabilities interact with
the broader opportunity structure to affect movement out of poverty.
What Is Power?
Power is in having and being. Some people see power as only having. Some
people see power as something internal: my values; my abilities.
—Ernesto, a 20-year-old man, El Mirador, Colombia
Power is nothing but to go ahead in life with courage.
—Discussion with men, Khatara, Assam
Men and women interviewed for the study define power using simple
terms and language from their everyday lives.2 Yet their definitions echo
definitions of power also found in the social, psychological, and political
literature.3 People describe power first and foremost as “power to”—as the
capacity to act on their own behalf, to take initiative, to be autonomous, to
influence their environment. They feel that the main sources of such power
are confidence and determination within themselves and support from their
families. “Power with” is the power that comes from associating with others,
both within the family and in groups. Poor women in particular emphasize
the importance of associating with one another; they see this as helping them
overcome many barriers that they could not possibly scale as individuals.
People also understand another form of power, “power over,” meaning
control over people and resources. Like sociologists, people in the study speak
of this kind of power in relational terms: certain people in their communities have more power while others have less. At times, these definitions mirror
J. K. Galbraith’s (1983) in the way they distinguish between power achieved
through use of various resources (usually money) and power based on force.
Akin to the ideas of Lukes (1974) is people’s belief that power over others is
132
Success from the Bottom Up
TABLE 4.1
Poor people distinguish four different types of power
Scope of control
Resources:
education,
assets, money
Opportunities,
rules, and laws
Self, family
No
No
Poor people
Self, family,
groups
No
No
Power
over
(positive)
Well-off people,
government, civil
society, local leaders
Love, authority,
social respect,
morals
Yes
Yes
Power
over
(negative)
Goons, elite,
local leaders, law
enforcement
Authority, fear,
force, coercion,
money
Yes
Yes
Type of
power
Who
Sources
Power to
Poor people
Power
with
exercised not only through the formal institutions of the state, but also through
the informal influences of social, cultural, and religious norms and beliefs.
“Power over” is further broken down into good power and bad power.
Power over someone can conceivably be used for the individual or common
good. But it can also be used to oppress others, and we encountered innumerably more instances of bad power than good power in our data. Inequality of
resources is always at the root of such bad power. Table 4.1 summarizes poor
people’s perspectives on each of several different types of power—who wields
it, its sources, and the scope of control that it confers.
“Power to”
I never say, “I can’t.” I say, “I can, but I just don’t know how.”
—Jainer, a 29-year-old man, El Gorrión, Colombia
Confidence in one’s own abilities and a determination to improve conditions for oneself and one’s family together lead to the power to do things. This
capacity to act on one’s own behalf—by managing a small business, farming,
migrating, or sending one’s children to school, for example—is important to
poor people in all the study regions. Men in Nelutanga, Sri Lanka, defined
power as “our personal strength.” Raghubir, a young man in Booti, Uttar
Pradesh, said, “Our hands are our power because we can do labor and earn
money from them.” In Kagera, Tanzania, power is “to execute your decisions
and targets that you have put for yourself.” In several Cambodian communi-
I Believe I Can
133
ties, people defined power as the “power to act independently, the power to
manage and control one’s family, and the power to earn a living.” For women
in Kagera, Tanzania, and in Manivali, Sri Lanka, power lies in “the ability to
execute thoughts, decisions, and targets.” And for women in Choudhuri Pum, a
village affected by conflict in Assam, power means “doing work without fear.”
For poor people like Oy and Pedro, their determination to persist without
giving up hope is often the most important dimension of their power. Such
persistence is especially emphasized in certain places like the barrios where
internally displaced people live in Colombia. Evicted from their homes by
armed conflict, people relied on their self-confidence and determination to
move ahead. When asked about power, Alfonso, another displaced man in
Santa María, said, “Power is in suffering. We have to hang on, resist, work,
and move on.” Liz, a young woman in El Mirador, Colombia, thought that it
is possible to be powerful even if one is poor because “you can be powerful
in your actions and decisions.”
“Power with”
My family is my power, you know.
—Usman, a 60-year-old man, Patobako, Indonesia
In addition to drawing on their own internal qualities, poor people gain
power in their associations with others, particularly their families and, to
some extent, other members of their communities. The power that derives
from such bonds can be called “power with.” Many people said that power
lies in the love, unity, and comfort that families offer. “No matter if we are
poor, if we have the love of our family, we are powerful,” commented Julio, a
19-year-old in Villa Rosa, Colombia.
In the South Asian context, large joint families are commonly seen as
sources of power. Parveen, a woman in Satgailijhara, Bangladesh, explained,
“Suppose I have five children; they will protect me if someone tries to hit me.
I have no power if they are not behind me.”
In addition to their families, poor women and men sought power in the
unity of their communities, friends, neighbors, and social groups. Several
poor people in the barrios of Colombia described community solidarity as
a critical resource that gave them the power to survive. “Real power comes
from poverty, united people,” exclaimed Wilson, a young man in El Mirador,
Colombia. Roshan, a man in Ashikabad, in rural Uttar Pradesh, concurred.
“The meaning of power is unity. If there is a single stick, anyone can break it.
But if the sticks are tied in a bundle, then nobody can break the bundle.”
134
Success from the Bottom Up
A single poor woman’s voice drowns in silence. Although women
within households are generally seen as having less power than men, they
can sometimes gain power when they join hands with other poor women in
groups. This was particularly evident in Bangladesh and in Andhra Pradesh,
where microcredit and self-help groups are strong. In these villages, not surprisingly, women relate power to working together in groups. But such change
can also lead to tensions within households because men have to adjust to
women’s empowerment.
Microfinance organizations have been active for decades in Bangladesh,
organizing women into credit groups. Unlike many women in the other
study regions, who said that they felt powerless, inferior, or trapped, women
in the Bangladesh study villages often appeared confident and assured. They
dressed well, spoke up, participated in household decisions, and stepped
out of the house to markets. Some felt confident enough to enter the public
sphere, marching to local politicians to speak out against injustice. These
changes in women also forced the men in their communities to change. Some
applauded women’s empowerment, but others appeared anxious and resentful. They longed for bygone times when the rules were simple and women
did what they were told (box 4.1).
“Power over”
To be powerful means to be a tyrant, to be oppressive in the way you are
ruling. It also means that people do things under pressure; they don’t have
freedom. All they need to do is just obey and do whatsoever whether they
want it or not.
—Discussion with men, Matdombo, Malawi
People also equated power with having control or authority over someone or something. Youths in Butmuli, Uganda, defined power as amaani,
meaning having authority over something. In Ferjama, Morocco, youths
described power as lakham, meaning authority or the one who takes irrevocable decisions. In Chikwanje, Malawi, power usually meant “authority where
you have people that you can control.” In Lumyana, Malawi, youths equated
power with “the boss, because he has got some people that he controls. If he
says do this, they do it, and so he has power over them.”
Even within families, there are obvious hierarchies of power and
authority. Usually the elder adults, in particular the parents, command more
respect and have more power than younger family members. According to
Ngagane in Ndagiel, Senegal, “You can be rich and live in the same house
BOX 4.1
Changes in women unsettle men in Bangladesh
In Bangladesh, we used a tool called the ladder of empowerment to explore
with women and men the steps in women’s empowerment. Men’s and women’s discussion groups in each community created their own ladders, with
women at the bottom step having the least power and women at the top step
having the most. Men and women sometimes differed dramatically in their
descriptions of women’s status. Indeed, the ladders drawn by men’s and women’s groups in the villages of Mirabari and Nurpur, summarized next, were so
dissimilar that it was hard to imagine that they described the same women. In
general, men described women at the top step as clever but also as quarrelsome, interfering, and disobedient. Women described this same top category
of women as intelligent, as behaving well, and as respected by others.
Men expressed deep ambivalence about women’s empowerment. The
men in Nurpur, for example, are proud and supportive of the intelligent women
at step 3, yet they feel that there is less harmony between a couple when the
woman is at this level. In Mirabari, a man named Osman summed up: “I think
the ordinary women are the best. They don’t need to become clever women.
The clever women have more power, but they command less prestige from us.”
Men’s discussion group, Mirabari
Step 3 (clever women): They demand good saris. They take whatever they
need from the husband. If there is a dispute between two parties, they get
involved, and they often quarrel with people. They don’t follow the codes
of Islam: they go out without a veil, and they wear short saris in a way that
shows the belly. They hold jobs or do income-generating activities. They do
the shopping themselves. Some have gone through secondary school. They
don’t listen to their husbands and can even physically assault men. They don’t
obey the judgments of the village court. They are not scared of anything.
Step 2 (ordinary women): They remain neutral during any dispute. They
give people good suggestions and protest against any injustice. They know
the difference between good and bad. Some wear the veil and some don’t.
They develop the family. They help the husband cultivate vegetables; they are
skilled at handicrafts and teach others. They have studied up to class 8 or 9.
Step 1 (simple women): They don’t do any harm to others even if someone does harm to them. Some of them are educated, but some are not and
can only sign their names. They wear the veil when they go out, but they
don’t go out much. They do handicrafts and raise poultry. They have more
peace in the family.
Women’s discussion group, Mirabari
Step 3 (intelligent women): They educate their children. They dress well and
live well even during famines. They provide good advice to the husband and
(continued)
135
BOX 4.1 continued
keep financial accounts properly. They behave well with the husband, inlaws, and other relatives. Most people appreciate their good qualities. They
can count up to 100.
Step 2 (somewhat knowledgeable women): They have little education. They try to earn money, but what they earn is not very much. They can
run the family satisfactorily. When their husbands become angry, they also
become angry.
Step 1 (foolish women): They do not earn any income because they do
not have the intelligence to do any work. They sit around idle. They cannot
keep accounts of expenditures. People call them foolish.
Men’s discussion group, Nurpur
Step 3 (intelligent women): They have education, know how to earn money,
and give intelligent advice to the husband on how to earn money. Husbands
follow their advice. They educate their children and make their families solvent. But there is less agreement between the husband and wife. The wife
says, “Do I understand less?”
Step 2 (moderately intelligent women): Their education is up to the primary
level, and they are eager to educate their children. They can manage their families well and understand accounts of income and expenditure. They earn some
income and give their husbands good advice. Their courage is moderate; they
are shy. They do not want to go to marriages and other parties because they do
not want to be seen by other men. They enjoy life very little, have little entertainment. They say, “The husband supplies food; he earns money. I shall obey his
words.” The relationship between husband and wife is very close and intimate.
Step 1 (unintelligent/foolish women): They have no education or knowledge. They cannot bring up their children properly because they cannot control them. They cannot make themselves understood when speaking; they do
not know how to behave with others; they have no sociable qualities. They
do not even understand that there is a profit in making a fan by investing 10
taka. The family survives on what the husband brings in.
Women’s discussion group, Nurpur
Step 3 (self-reliant women): They have money, jobs, education. They are
active; they have full power and freedom. They are not punished if they do
wrong. They do not care about anything, even if society speaks ill of them.
Step 2 (moderately powerful women): They have education but they do
not hold full-time jobs; their husbands prevent them because of religious
orthodoxy. They depend on the man; they cannot do everything independently. They look after their families and children. They get respect.
Step 1 (powerless women): They have no freedom and are weak physically. They have no education. They are idle. They have no land.
136
I Believe I Can
137
as your elder brother; you can also meet all the needs of your household;
but you cannot take any decision without his permission.” In communities
like Ndagiel, the traditional laws of primogeniture (right of the first-born
son to inherit) specifically give older family members positions of power.
In Indonesia, cultural norms of showing respect for parents place mothers
like 32-year-old Sanah in positions of power. She said, “In the house, I have
power and authority to manage my own household, because in the house
the mother has power.”
Like Weber (1947, 1968), our respondents distinguished between coercive power and the authority that is based on charisma, social traditions,
values, and laws. In Colombia, even though the rich have more resources
and the guerrillas have weapons, poor women and men value the authority gained through social respect above the coercive power wielded by those
groups. Mónica, a 16-year-old girl in Villa Rosa, said, “There are some rich
people who have no power. Some things cannot be bought with money, for
example, love and respect.” Because social respect conveys power, it is possible for even poor people to be powerful. Pablo, a young man in Villa Blanca,
said that a while a rich man’s money gives him power, “for us, power is the
humility and respect we earn through our actions.”
Power and authority based on morality, ethics, and social traditions is
seen as more acceptable than power based on coercion and force. When it
comes to power over others, people make a sharp distinction between “good
power” and “bad power.”
Good power
Across contexts, people spoke of three qualities that allow a person to gain
“good power.” These are love, respect, and moral leadership. In the community context, people show their love through a spirit of altruism, by being
available and willing to help others. In Satgailijhara, a flood-prone village in
Bangladesh, a men’s discussion group described the powerful as those who
are “affectionate to the poor and help them in times of need.” In Laskarpur,
West Bengal, Tilak said, “There are a few households that are powerful in our
village because of their good work. They help the villagers with money at the
time of marriage of their daughters. This is power.”
The second way to earn good power is by being respectful, showing a
willingness to consult and listen to others. “If you are going to lead a group
and you don’t have respect for your people, then there is a tendency that
your power will weaken,” reasoned a group of youths in Aludonay, Philippines. “Eventually your followers will go against you if you lead them without
138
Success from the Bottom Up
respect.” Youths in Klong Pud, Thailand, said, “Power is not browbeating
other people and speaking to others nicely.”
Finally, people stressed the importance of exercising moral leadership
and setting a good example. Parents and traditional or religious leaders typically gain power and authority in this way. In Thailand, parents have power
because they act as a “good model for the family” and because children
are “grateful and loyal to parents.” Similarly, men in Lupotogo, Indonesia,
referred to power as “having honor and being respected by one’s children.” In
many communities in Africa, community elders and religious leaders enforce
moral codes. “The elderly people have a lot of knowledge,” said Agatha, a
65-year-old farmer in Gogoba, Uganda. “They give advice to their family
members and also guide and direct the youth in the village to restrain them
from bad behavior and maintain the value and norms of the community.” In
Mbassina, Senegal, youths described power as “the ability [of imams] to heal
illness thanks to the Koran.” Priests are the most powerful in some communities in Kagera, Tanzania, because “they can listen to your sins and have Godgiven powers.” In Banjoydup, Bangladesh, religious leaders called matbors
are placed at the top of the community ladder because even “millionaires
come to them for justice.”
Bad power
While such “good power” was praised, poor people talked even more about
“bad power”—power over others as a means to repress and oppress. It doesn’t
matter much how such power is acquired, whether through wealth, education, political connections, social membership, or sheer force. What matters
is the total control over others, often exercised arbitrarily. Women in Mpusola, Malawi, said, “The powerful people are called chiphanzi [big foot]. The
term is taken from a popular song that talks of a person in authority who
oppresses those below him. It means stepping on them.” Such oppressive
power is sometimes exercised in defiance of the law, but often the law or
at least the police permit or even abet the abuses. In Kdadaum, Cambodia,
young women said that the rich people who control the logging business
work hand in glove with the police, who have the “power and authority to
cut and carry wood and make others pay.”
Kesarbai, a woman in Nagara, Uttar Pradesh, gave a graphic description of
bad power in her community. “The powerful can suppress others, beat them,
and bully them,” she said. “It is like a lion tasting blood after which he eats
only flesh.” So feared are the holders of bad power that even a gesture or a
glance is often sufficient to make others obey. In Lomamoli, Philippines, men
I Believe I Can
139
and women defined power as “mala ayka gus, meaning a certain eye or hand
movement that can make people follow and show respect.” In Kadonga, Assam,
men spoke of powerful people as “those who can make others go up and down
by the signal of the finger.” And in Batamara, another study village in Assam,
power is exercised by “talking down, pointing fingers at someone else’s eyes.”
Different people are powerful in different local contexts. While landlords
are the most feared in several of the study villages in Andhra Pradesh, it is government officials in the Philippines, who in enforcing laws have “the power to
create and to destroy.” What remains consistent is the use of power to dominate
others. Juan Pablo, a 62-year-old man in San Feliz, Colombia, said, “To exercise
power correctly, we have to [act] the same as if we had nothing. Money damages the heart and the reason.” Mercedes, a woman in Los Rincones, Colombia,
concurred. “You know, in our environment it is not good to be powerful,” she
remarked to our field team. “It is not something to be proud of.”
Sources of power
A man without money is like a bird without feathers.
—Ibrahim, a 70-year-old man, Lomamoli, Philippines
Run, hit, and kill—that is power
—Discussion with young men, Pittupur, Uttar Pradesh
Power, good or bad, derives from various sources, according to the people in our study. Two of the most important are money and brute force.
Money is perhaps the most ubiquitous and universally recognized source
of power. Money allows one to get what one wants through purchase or
bribery. “With money, one can buy people,” said Alaka, a young woman in
Gangua, West Bengal. In Satgailijhara, Bangladesh, young men said, “If you
entertain 10 persons with 10 cups of tea, they will be in your favor. Then
you can be a powerful man. But that means if someone wants to entertain
10 people with tea, he must be a rich man. A poor man cannot afford this.”
Money also enables people to control other resources and thus make even
more money. Speaking in local proverbs, youths in Riah Khillaw, Afghanistan, stated, “Money makes money and the lack of money makes a headache.” In Kdadaum, Cambodia, the rich control forest resources and profit
through logging. “The poor work for the rich and do not have power as they
dare not argue against or bargain for good remuneration,” lamented young
men in Kdadaum. “The rich control the loans to the poor.”
140
Success from the Bottom Up
Those with money can voice their opinions and command social respect,
even claim political leadership. “If the powerful speak, people abide by it
without any judgment,” said a men’s group in Kadonga, Assam. In Ibrahimpur, Uttar Pradesh, young men voiced similar sentiments. “No one cares for
a poor person in society. The people with money consider a poor man no
more than a pest.” Moral judgments are often suspended for rich people. In
Malkapur, Andhra Pradesh, rich landlords wield such power that no one can
question their immorality and ill-doings. “If a rich man falls on the road in a
drunken state, people say that he must have fallen down because he hit something. But if a poor man falls on the road, everyone will call him a drunkard,”
complained men in a discussion with our field team. And in the village of
Sapsa, Uttar Pradesh, men said, “Brother, power is obtained through money.
Everyone worships the rising sun, but no one worships the setting sun.”
An extreme form of domination is the use of physical coercion. On a disquieting note, men, women, and youths in some of our study regions spoke
at length about the power of brute force. Not surprisingly, this understanding
of power is more evident in the study regions affected by conflict. In Barangay
Tucampo in the southern Philippines, Japar said, “Power for me is the capacity
to arm oneself. During my time, the armed men easily beat the defenseless. You
are powerful when you carry guns.” Men and women in the conflict-affected
villages of Assam and in the barrios of Colombia also spoke of the power of
weapons. In Assam, the army and the local militant groups are seen as the most
powerful, while in Colombia it is gang members and guerrillas. Adolfo, a man
in La Soledad, Colombia, gave an example of how the power of weapons is
abused. “When the guerrillas were here they said, ‘there is a meeting,’ and we
had to be there if we did not want to be shot, no matter if we were sick.”
Inequalities in power
Inequality is carrying a sack of sugar throughout the whole year without
tasting it.
—Men’s discussion group, Chanpasha, Bangladesh
Poor people know that they live in an unequal world. They have deep
knowledge of the structural and social factors that lead to “durable inequalities” (Tilly 1999).4 Across the study regions, poor people define inequality as
restricting their opportunities and choices. Whether it is the opportunity to
participate in markets, to access government aid, or to speak up in community decision making, poor women and men face unequal terms of engagement. The dice are loaded particularly heavily against poor women.
I Believe I Can
141
Poor people lack clout in the marketplace, often because of the small
scale of their transactions (see chapter 5). They must buy high and sell low.
Cory, a woman in Baroygor, Philippines, remarked, “If we are going to buy
fertilizers, we will find it very hard on our pocket, but if it is our turn to sell
our products, they are sold at low prices.” Added Ling, “As corn owners, we
cannot say that our corn will be sold at 10 pesos a kilo. No, we cannot do
that. Instead, we are the ones asking the buyers, ‘How much is the current
price of our product?’ There seems to be no equality. The farmers depend
on the traders.” Like the farmers in Baroygor, the fishermen of Kismopara,
Bangladesh, depend on the powerful few who own ponds in the community.
“The canal belongs to them,” said Rahima, a woman in the village. “No one
can fish there or bathe cattle.”
In some of the African study contexts where government and donor aid
is a crucial form of support, there are stark differences between those villages
and households that can access aid and those that cannot (see chapter 6).
This form of inequality is acute in Malawi. Men in the village of Mzaponda
described inequality as “denying others from getting any type of fortune or
luck. When donors give assistance to organizations but no assistance comes
to the village, that is inequality.”
Besides leading to lost opportunities, inequalities result in poor women
and men losing voice and control. “A rich man can fool you the way he
wants,” said a group of women in Kodola, Uganda. “You can dig for him,
and he can tell you to come tomorrow for money. He has the money, but
when you go tomorrow, he can again tell you to come the next day. As a poor
man, you will have nothing to do but to follow what he tells you. The poor
are always looked down on and despised.” And in Shantakalia, Bangladesh,
women remarked, “Those who are powerful scold us when we talk to them
because we are powerless.”
Even among poor people themselves, opportunity sets differ for men
and women. Women across our sample often reported that their husbands
restrict them to the kitchen, where they exhaust themselves in menial household chores. “We have less energy because we do quite a lot,” said a group of
women in Kagera, Tanzania. “In fact, it is not that we have less energy, but our
energy is finished due to a lot of work that we do during the day and at night.
Many men do not appreciate this and what they do at the end of it all is to
beat you up.” The women who managed to step out of the house spoke of
receiving far lower wages than men despite bone-grinding labor. In addition,
they have no freedom to spend these wages. “We cannot spend our earnings
as we like,” said Sarola, a woman in Khetaswar, Assam. “The men rebuke us.
142
Success from the Bottom Up
We cannot even buy a sari of our choice.” Women in Surjana, a village in Uttar
Pradesh, agreed. “If we want to get training for stitching work or embroidery,
the men scold us and ask us to stay in the house. If we insist on getting trained,
they avoid us, saying they cannot afford it, whereas they themselves waste our
money on their paan” (a betel leaf mixture for chewing and smoking).
Everyday resistance
When poor people are unable to confront unequal power directly, they often
resort to what Scott (1985) calls “weapons of the weak,” using tactics such
as sarcasm to cope with their situation and subtly rebel. People often used
metaphors to talk about their lives indirectly. In some villages in West Bengal,
poor youths laughingly compared their situation to that of a weak football
(soccer) team. “Two teams are playing football and only one team can win,”
said Kaushik, a young boy in Ranigar. “Players on one team are powerful so
they won. The less powerful have less opportunity to score because they cannot run fast enough.”
In a village in Kagera, Tanzania, at the end of an animated discussion on
the ladder of life, the researchers introduced the official poverty line. At first
there was total silence, and then people erupted with sarcastic comments
amid great laughter. “Is that a baby you mean to have live on that much
money?” “When you give a person that much, prepare a prison for him,
because after a few hours he will start stealing!” “The person with so little is
already dead.” “If you are old, yes, you can live on less because your stomach
has wrinkles on it.” “Those people [officials who set the poverty line] look
down on us. Why should they think that we should live on less than that,
while they themselves live on a lot more?”
Resistance sometimes goes beyond words to actions. In several villages in
Tanzania and Uganda, poor people reported withholding their participation in
the political process and in meetings to protest the abuses of political leaders.
Jealousy of others’ gains
If a rich person becomes arrogant and happy, this will make neighbors and
other members of the community resentful, emotional, and spiteful.
—Men’s discussion group, Barumangga, Indonesia
While belief in self is important, poor people can also turn on each other
in the fight for limited resources in an unequal world. One person’s rise is
assumed to be at the expense of others, and people not infrequently attempt
I Believe I Can
143
to thwart their neighbors’ efforts to get ahead. A beer brewer and seller in
Kiwgazi, Uganda, related his story: “A man came to my home and expressed
surprise when he asked for beer and I gave it to him. He said he had met a
friend who told him that there was no beer at my place. Clearly this man [the
friend] did not wish that I sell my beer. He was envious that if I sold my beer,
I would improve at a faster speed than him.”
While jealous actions usually amount to no more than slights, in some
cases, jealousy motivates petty theft, destruction of property, and even murder.
The victims, as described by the study participants, are not just the rich but also
poor people who are beginning to accumulate assets. In Malawi, for instance,
people often sleep with their livestock so no one can harm their animals. “Just
yesterday, someone killed my two goats by giving them a poisonous substance,”
lamented a man in Madkumba village. “They are trying to reduce what I have,
but I can say that they will fail and I will still continue to improve.”
Destruction of private property, such as the burning of houses and poisoning of wells, was reported in a few places. A slightly better-off man in a
village in Assam reported that someone had poisoned his fish. “I have two
fisheries—one is near the house; the other is on the hillside. In the fishery
on the hillside, somebody gave poison in jealousy. I have lost about 30,000
rupees of fish.” In the fishing community of Kramrrak, Indonesia, some
fishermen reportedly threatened their more successful peers. “One of them
threatened to burn my house,” said a fisherman our team met. “I said please
do. I’ll give you the gasoline. But if you want to do it, do it after terawih [night
prayer in a fasting month], so nobody can see you. Turned out they didn’t
have the guts.” Destruction of public property was occasionally mentioned as
well. In Sirkona, Uganda, a women’s discussion group reported the sabotage
of drinking water pipes. “One rich man was bringing water, but the pipes
were cut by the community members. Consequently, there is no safe water in
the whole village, which exposes people to high health risks.”
In some African and Indonesian communities, people who had suffered
sudden misfortunes sometimes attributed them to acts of witchcraft carried
out by jealous parties. A comparatively well-off woman in Kagera, Tanzania,
told the field team, “In 2002, I suffered a strange disease. I later realized that
my neighbor had bewitched me. I cannot tell you more than this, but it is all
due to people being jealous of what we and our children have achieved.” The
killings of successful individuals were reported in a few places, although it was
unclear who the guilty parties were. In Welumbe, Sri Lanka, a woman said that
her father had been targeted and killed by those who were jealous of him. “We
were doing really well in those days. People couldn’t stand that at all.”
144
Success from the Bottom Up
Resentment against the successful has been observed and explained in
different ways. Hirschman and Rothschild (1973) speak of the tunnel effect.
When cars are stuck in a multilane tunnel, any movement in the next lane
leads to initial happiness as drivers assume that their lane is about to move as
well. But if movement continues in the next lane while traffic remains stuck
in their own lane, drivers quickly become frustrated—even more frustrated
than if no lanes were moving at all. So, too, in the economic sphere. Failure
to fulfill one’s own aspirations is surely a frustrating experience (Ray 2006),
and it may become even more frustrating when others are seen to be enjoying
success. Such jealousy can eventually give rise to conflicts.
Social mores also come into play. In parts of Africa, a successful person
may be criticized if he or she fails to redistribute resources to others, particularly the extended family. For those who would move up, this change creates
a fundamental tension. To get ahead, they need to accumulate, save, and
reinvest, but doing so violates traditional social norms that call for sharing
(Ashforth 2005; Ferguson 1999; Pottier 1988). Those who appear to be leaving others behind have been the targets of accusations and even attacks.
Rich people also jealously guard their monopoly position and are not
above sabotaging the efforts of poor people to move out of poverty. In the village of Ibrahimpur, Uttar Pradesh, a lower-caste farmer explained, “The small
farmers do not have any engines so they take water from the big farmers.
Therefore, they can grow only one crop. If some farmers try to cultivate another
crop, then the [upper-caste] Thakurs let their animals loose in their fields [to
eat the crops].” Youths in Chamgotia, Bangladesh, said, “The upper-class people always resist the poor if they want to attain their prosperity through good
jobs. Say, for example, if a rickshaw puller wants to purchase an auto-rickshaw
[small taxi], the richer section of people, being jealous, misguide him.”
Power, Personal Agency, and Mobility
When someone comes out of poverty, people start respecting him. He is
considered powerful.
— Ibrahim, a 56-year-old man, Shazimir, Afghanistan
Poverty winds around people like a python so much so that they are unable
to breathe properly.
—Men’s discussion group, Gobordia, Assam
Poor men and women make a direct link between power and moving out
of poverty on the one hand and between powerlessness and stagnation on the
I Believe I Can
145
other. Poor women and men can see that their agency is restricted by social,
political, and economic structures that limit their control over resources and
opportunities. The rich hold all the aces: they use their political and social
connections, their education, and their assets to climb even higher on the ladder. As Dyrberg states in his Circular Structure of Power (1997, 28), “The ability to make a difference is itself constituted by the making of differences.”
For those stuck in unequal power relations, unable to breathe, it may
seem ludicrous to suggest that belief in oneself is a powerful weapon for
getting ahead. Yet, that is precisely what many poor people in our study suggested. Their only hope for escaping poverty is to hold onto their spirit and
not give up, come what may. “The most important thing is the family union
and the desire to keep on living, moving on, will. Without that, there is nothing,” summed up Adriana, a woman in San Feliz, Colombia.
Psychologist Albert Bandura (1995) has demonstrated experimentally that
when beliefs about self-efficacy are manipulated independent of performance
or external conditions, they affect future performance. Thus a person’s internal
sense of efficacy plays an independent causal role. Reviewing the psychological
literature, Bandura (1998) concluded: “People’s beliefs that they can produce
desired effects by their actions influence the choices they make, their aspirations, level of effort and perseverance, resilience to adversity, and vulnerability
to stress and depression.” Hoff and Pandey’s (2004) experimental study with
middle-school children in India reveals the power of identity labels in reducing
self-confidence and reproducing inequality in an environment that is expected
to be prejudicial. Among children in mixed-caste groups that were given the
task of solving mazes, the performance of the “untouchable” children dropped
dramatically when their low-caste status was identified publicly.
Quantifying personal agency
In our study, we use two quantifiable measures to understand the role of personal agency. One is a measure of internal power and rights based on how an
individual rates herself or himself on a 10-step ladder of power and rights 10
years ago, at the beginning of the study reference period (1995). The second
is a measure of a person’s sense of control based on whether she or he experienced any change over time in control over everyday decision making.
The movers in nearly all study regions on average self-identified themselves at a modestly higher position on the ladder of power and rights 10 years
ago compared to the chronic poor (figure 4.1). It is interesting to note that both
movers and chronic poor (together making up the initial poor set) in the African study regions placed themselves slightly higher on the ladder of power and
146
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 4.1
Movers place themselves modestly higher on power and rights 10 years ago
compared to the chronic poor
Average step on ladder of power and rights
7
5.9
6
5 4.7 4.6
4
4.3
4.0 4.0
3.7 3.7
3.6 3.4 3.4
2.9 2.4
3
3.3 3.2
2
1
SE
N
(In
TA fra
)
N
(
M Ru
v)
A
BA L (I
n
N
f
(E ra)
m
p
PH ow
)
I(
U Pan
G
A el)
(P
an
M
EX el)
W
(E
B
t
(L hn)
an
dd
ist
U
P
)
(C
as
AP te)
(S
CO HG
)
L
(C
AF on
f)
G
(C
o
PH nf
)
I
IN (Co
D
nf
O
)
AS
(C
SA on
f)
M
(C
on
f)
0
Study region
Movers
Chronic poor
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from household survey; all study regions where data were available; N = 7,916.
Note:
AFG (Conf) = Afghanistan, Conflict
AP (SHG) = Andhra Pradesh, Self-help groups
ASSAM (Conf )= Assam, Conflict
BAN (Empow) = Bangladesh, Women’s
empowerment
COL (Conf) = Colombia, Conflict
INDO (Conf) = Indonesia, Conflict
MAL (Infra) = Malawi, Infrastructure
MEX (Ethn) = Mexico, Ethnicity
PHI (Conf) = Philippines, Conflict
PHI (Panel) = Philippines, Panel study
SEN (Infra) = Senegal, Infrastructure
TAN (Ruv) = Tanzania, Ruvuma
UGA (Panel) = Uganda, Panel study
UP (Caste) = Uttar Pradesh, Caste
WB (Landdist) = West Bengal, Land distribution
reforms
rights than their counterparts elsewhere. We can speculate that poor people in
our African communities may emphasize self-belief because they have little
else to rely on. It is also notable that perceptions of power and rights appear to
peak in conflict-affected Colombia.5 Our Colombian respondents emphasized
that one needs strong belief in oneself to survive destruction and displacement.
“Yes, it has risen,” said Alejandra, a woman in Villa Rosa, referring to her selfconfidence. “I have done things I did not know I was going to do. I did not
I Believe I Can
147
know I was going to develop, coming to an office, explaining to someone my
rights as a displaced person and fighting for them.” Graciela explained, “We,
the displaced, have been moving up step by step. We are barely standing up and
if we fall, we will not be able to stand up again.”
Except in a few study regions, people who had fallen into poverty reported
that they had started lower on the ladder of power and rights compared to
those who had not fallen (the never poor). Starting with more self-belief thus
seems to help people move up and to avoid falling down (figure 4.2).
On the second measure, control over everyday decision making, most
movers (nearly 74 percent) thought that they currently had control over all or
most of the decisions in their daily lives. Less than half (46 percent) of those
stuck in poverty believed they had such control (figure 4.3). Success in moving out of poverty, it seems, strengthens self-confidence and inner efficacy.
FIGURE 4.2
Fallers place themselves modestly lower on power and rights 10 years ago
compared to the never poor
Average step on ladder of power and rights
8
3.7
7
6
6.1
5.6 5.4
5
4.9
5.0
4.8
5.1 5.1
4.7
4.3 4.0
4.3
4.6
4
3.3
3
2
1
A
)
W L (I
nf
B
r
(L
a
an )
d
PH dis
I ( t)
Pa
U nel
P
)
(C
a
TA ste
)
N
(R
M
u
EX v)
(E
U
th
G
n)
A
(P
an
AP el)
(S
AF HG
G
)
AS
(C
SA on
f)
M
IN (Co
D
nf
O
)
(C
PH onf
I( )
C
CO on
f)
L
(C
on
f)
fra
(In
M
N
SE
BA
N
(E
m
po
w
)
0
Study region
Never poor
Fallers
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from household survey; all study regions where data were available;
N = 7,916.
148
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 4.3
Movers report control over all or most decisions, while chronic poor and fallers
report less control
% households reporting control over decisions
100
90
80
70
60
50
44
39
40
30
32
28
14
18
Chronic poor
Fallers
20
30
10
27
0
Movers
Never poor
All decisions
Most decisions
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from household survey; all study regions; N = 8,945.
This finding should not be surprising. As poor people manage to accumulate resources and move out of poverty, it reinforces their self-respect and
wins them respect from others. Men in Boodanpur, Uttar Pradesh, summed
up the virtuous cycle: “People feel more powerful after coming out of poverty
because their relations with other people start improving. There is a common
saying that a hungry man only invites further drought and is not welcome
anywhere. A rich man is welcome everywhere.”
A couple of words of caution. One, it is possible that movers, basking in
the glow of their success, may recall themselves as more confident 10 years
ago than they really were. Two, it is possible that in telling their life stories
to interviewers, respondents attributed success to their own agency while
blaming failures on external factors. In an early methodology workshop for
the study, the late Charles Tilly, an adviser to the project, cautioned that we
should interpret life stories with these caveats in mind. “Every life history is a
I Believe I Can
149
retrospective moral tale which has an account of self in it,” he said. “[People
emphasize their] own agency and frustration at what restricted them from
exercising it. Detect these moral accounts.” Anthropologists, ethnographers,
and sociologists, including Tilly and others, have warned of the biases inherent in such self-eulogies. In his book titled Why? (2006), Tilly shows that
social relations shape the accounts that people give to others to explain particular events. In particular, he argues that people have the tendency to limit
the number of actors and actions in their narratives, situating all causes in the
consciousness of the actors and elevating the personal over the institutional.
In our study, the fact that mobility status is not self-assessed but assessed
by the community reduces the potential for these biases. The designation of
households as movers, chronic poor, never poor, or fallers is based on the
community mobility matrixes, which are derived, in turn, from focus group
rankings of households on the ladder of life. It is striking, then, to see people
who were independently identified as movers by their peers also self-identify
themselves as having been at a higher position on the ladder of power and
rights 10 years ago.
Association with upward mobility
To test the association between these subjective factors and an individual
household’s ability to move out of poverty, we ran multivariate linear regressions on our quantitative data from the household surveys. We used individual household mobility as the dependent variable and examined its partial
association with several other independent variables. As noted, our measure
of a household’s movement out of poverty is constructed from community
perceptions, not from the household’s own recall or ranking of its mobility. This approach was to reduce potential bias arising from regressing own
perception of mobility against own perception of a host of factors, including
subjective well-being. People who ranked themselves as having moved out of
poverty might also be more likely to say they were more self-confident, just
because they have generally positive attitudes.
Our dependent variable is whether or not members of a household moved
out of poverty (MOP) over the 10-year study period or, at times, whether they
moved up at all (MPI), irrespective of whether they crossed the poverty line.
This approach limits the sample to those who began in poverty, and hence
the regressions show the association between several variables and whether
one was a mover or remained stuck in poverty (chronic poor).
Although our dependent variable is binary and there are more sophisticated estimators that are statistically more efficient, we use a linear prob-
150
Success from the Bottom Up
ability model. This method has the advantage that the coefficients are easy
to interpret, as the difference in probability of being a mover versus chronic
poor associated with the factors included as independent variables (conditional on all of the independent variables).
We used roughly the same specification for all study regions. Although
we could have improved the fit by adding or dropping variables for each
region, we were interested as much in the heterogeneity of the results across
regions as in creating the statistically “best” model. This also limits the scope
for data mining to search for “statistically significant” associations.
The specification includes a range of variables that we feel represent various elements of our framework, mainly economic, social, and political institutions as well as several standard household characteristics. All of the results
reported in subsequent chapters are based on the same regressions with a full
set of co-variates (we do not do regressions for each variable); the results are
integrated into the respective thematic chapters. The full specification and
results are reported in appendix 6.
We often had several items in a questionnaire that plausibly measured
the phenomenon of interest (such as personal agency). Rather than run
“horse race” analysis to see which measure fit best with the dependent variable, we used principal components to combine the variables into a single
measure. We did the principal components analysis (PCA) region by region
with the same variables (when available) but allowing the weights to differ.
Although there are many limitations to principal components analysis as a
data reduction technique, it has the advantage of not referring to the dependent variable in the construction of the measure of the independent variable
and hence is not data mining.
The results are reported based on coefficient standard errors that are
robust to within-cluster correlation. Although we have many household
observations, we have relatively few communities, and hence we should
expect rather large standard errors on the community variables. Also, some of
the community variables are based on “key respondents” who were selected
to answer the community survey (based on the community classification)
but were not necessarily representative of the village. Hence, the pure measurement error in assessing community-level variables is likely to be large.
Finally, we want to emphasize that we see the regressions as a data summary tool—not as the “test” of a model, nor as estimates of “coefficients”
or “parameters,” nor as indicating causality in any way. But regressions are
useful in pointing to partial associations, and we use them as just another
technique to grapple with the masses of data and information to under-
151
I Believe I Can
stand the complex reality at hand. We hope the reader will take them in
that spirit.
We created a personal agency index using principal components analysis. The index is based on our two questions mapping subjective well-being
or internal power/self-efficacy: position on the ladder of power and rights
10 years ago and change experienced in control over everyday decision
making.
Figure 4.4 reports the association between the personal agency index and
household movement out of poverty. The single dots represent the coefficients: the higher they are, the higher the magnitude of the estimated association. The bars around the coefficient represent the one and two standard error
bounds. The more tightly clustered the bounds, the lower the standard error
and, for any given magnitude of the estimated association, the more likely a
test that the association is zero would be rejected. We report the data in this
way because given the data descriptive nature of the exercise, we do not want
to become t-statistic fetishists and confuse low-powered and high-powered
failures to reject. So we show the magnitude of all estimated associations
and their standard errors so that readers can see for themselves the general
FIGURE 4.4
Personal agency has an association with moving out of poverty
Coefficient and Standard Errors: MOP and Personal Agency
PHI
Propensity to move out of poverty
0.2
0.1
COL
BAN
UGA
UP
WB
AP
MAL SEN
THAI
MEX
AFG
INDO
ASSAM
PHIC
0
–0.1
–0.2
Study region
Source: Multivariate linear regression analysis using data from household survey and community questionnaire (see appendix 6).
152
Success from the Bottom Up
tendencies in terms of sign and magnitude as well as infer the likely p-levels
associated with the coefficients. In all the graphs reporting regression results,
we follow the same order of study regions: India, South Asia, Africa, East Asia,
Mexico, and conflict-affected regions.
Figure 4.4 shows that feelings of self-efficacy, power, and control have a
significant association with movement out of poverty in Uttar Pradesh and
Assam and in Bangladesh, Uganda, and Indonesia (the standard error bounds
are much tighter around the coefficient). This finding means that people
who had a higher sense of power in 1995 and who perceived an increase in
their control over everyday decision making over the 10-year period in these
regions were also those who moved out of poverty. Interestingly, when we ran
the same specification with FRI (when the rich fell by one or more steps) as
the dependent variable, we found that the association between our personal
agency index and falling was mostly negative. In fact, it was significantly negative in Uttar Pradesh, Assam, and Bangladesh, suggesting that starting with
a higher sense of power is associated with lower chances of falling. While we
do not claim causality, it is striking that there is an association between individuals ranked by their community as fallers and the fallers’ own ranking of
their initial power and rights.
It is illustrative to look at the relative magnitudes of association in a
couple of countries. In Bangladesh, where this association is significant, a
2-unit increase in the control that an individual exercised over her everyday
decisions (1 = less control, 3 = more control) is associated with a 15.5 percent
increase in the probability of moving out of poverty. This is higher than the
effect that a unit increase in the index of assets or owning a house could have:
each increased the likelihood of mobility from an initial state of poverty significantly by 12 percent.
Uganda is another study region where the index has a significant association with mobility from poverty. Breaking it down into its component
variables, we find that a 2-unit increase in control over decision making is
associated with a 9 percent increase in the exit rate from poverty. In comparison, the association with assets in influencing chances of escape is lower (7
percent) and insignificant. This is not to argue that assets are not important.
They play a significant role in enhancing capabilities, including psychological
capabilities such as internal power and self-confidence to take action. However, in their own self-assessments, movers seem to place more importance
on internal empowerment than on assets. The former, as our qualitative evidence suggests, has to come first, although clearly internal power and control
increase with success in moving out of poverty.
I Believe I Can
153
Capacity to Aspire
I was obliged to work as a farm laborer to augment the income of my
husband. When he died, my motivation doubled because I had to feed my
family and send my children to school.
—Gloria, a 57-year-old widow, Kilaluna, Philippines
The capacity to imagine a future that is different and better is an important
motivator to overcome the difficulties of the present. People across the study
regions expressed strong aspirations to secure a better future for themselves
and their children. As reported in chapter 1, nearly 77 percent of households
hoped that their children would be better off in the future. Gloria, a widow
in Kilaluna, Philippines, recalled, “Even though my husband left us a farm,
I still work as a farm laborer, especially during off seasons and while waiting
for our harvest.” When our team met her, Gloria was described as someone
who had successfully moved out of poverty, overcoming all odds.
Success in achieving one’s aspirations leads to even greater faith and confidence in oneself. Not surprisingly, movers out of poverty exhibited higher
aspirations for their own future than did the chronic poor. On average, 80
percent of the movers felt that they would be better off in the future, compared to 56 percent of those stuck in poverty. Still, 56 percent reflects considerable optimism, given the obstacles that the chronic poor face. Moreover,
when it came to aspirations for their children, an astonishingly high 70 percent of the chronic poor across study regions expected their children to be
better off. While they had modest aspirations for themselves, they held high
hopes for the next generation.
Figure 4.5 shows the differences in aspirations of the movers and the
chronic poor for their own future by study region. In all but two regions,
movers had higher aspirations than did the chronic poor. The exceptions are
the households interviewed in Bangladesh and Colombia. In the former, a
sense of empowerment through microcredit groups had spread through the
ranks of those in poverty, raising their aspirations. In Colombia, our sample
was specific to very poor communities largely occupied by displaced people
who had lost everything. These people could only look up in hope of better
times. “My desire to improve my situation is the biggest desire I have,” said
Humberto, a poor man in the El Gorrión barrio. “I set a goal for myself every
day. When I got here, I thought how difficult it would be for me to move
on. Before, I used to ride a bicycle, but I had the hope and goal of having a
motorcycle and now I have one. The idea is setting goals.”
154
Success from the Bottom Up
% households optimistic about own future
FIGURE 4.5
Movers had higher hopes for their own future than did the chronic poor
100 96
90
93
90
83
80
87
83
80
74
70
71
71
62
60
70
58
52
50
40
30
20
10
m
(E
BA
N
SE
N
(In
fra
)
po
U
P w)
(C
M ast
AL e)
(In
AP fra)
W
(
B SHG
(L
an )
d
TA dist
)
N
(
U
G Ruv
A
)
(P
an
M
e
l)
EX
(
AF Ethn
G
)
AS
(C
SA on
f)
M
IN (Co
D
nf
O
)
(C
on
PH
f)
I(
CO Co
n)
L
(C
on
f)
0
Study region
Movers
Chronic poor
Source: Authors’ analysis of household survey; N = 5,260 (movers = 2,431; chronic poor = 2,829).
To test whether aspirations are associated with an individual household’s
ability to move out of poverty, we created an index of aspirations that included
questions about aspirations for self and for children.6 The index was then
included along with other independent variables driven by our conceptual
framework in a multivariate linear regression model with household movement
out of poverty as the dependent variable. Even more than personal agency, aspirations on the whole tended to have a positive association with the likelihood of
moving out of poverty—significantly so in three Indian states, in Uganda, and
in Afghanistan (figure 4.6). When we ran the same specification with falling as
the dependent variable, we found that higher aspirations were also significantly
associated with lower chances of falling, especially in the Indian states.
Take the case of West Bengal, where aspirations have a significant association with an initially poor household’s ability to move out of poverty 10
years later. Considering the individual components of the aspirations index,
we find that a 2-unit increase in beliefs about one’s own future (1 = worse
off; 3 = better off) corresponds to a 35 percent increase in exiting poverty. A
I Believe I Can
155
FIGURE 4.6
Individual aspirations are a robust correlate of moving out of poverty
Coefficient and Standard Errors: MOP and Aspirations
Propensity to move out of poverty
0.3
WB
AFG
0.2
UP
0.1
UGA MAL
BAN
0
SEN
TAN PHI
ASSAM
PHIC
INDO
MEX
COL
AP
–0.1
Study region
Source: Multivariate linear regression analysis using data from household survey and community questionnaire (see appendix 6).
corresponding 2-unit increase in aspirations for the future of one’s children
(1 = worse off; 3 = better off) is associated with an even higher probability of
exiting poverty, 38 percent. In orders of magnitude, the association between
aspirations—both for oneself and for one’s children—and moving out of
poverty is higher than the effect of assets. A 1-unit increase on the assets index
increases the chances of escaping poverty in West Bengal by only 5 percent.
Similarly, in communities torn by war and death in Afghanistan, a strong
belief that the future will be better has a striking association with mobility,
more so than assets, education, and ownership of livestock, all of which emerge
as insignificant in our multivariate linear regressions for the study region. A
2-unit increase in beliefs about one’s own future increases the likelihood of
escape from poverty by 21 percent; a concomitant 2-unit increase in aspirations
for one’s children nearly doubles the probability of exit to 42 percent.
Our findings build on the work of scholars like Appadurai (2004), who
shows the importance of “capacity to aspire.” Poor people’s aspirations do
not seem to be confined to their own reference group.7 Where aspirations are
lacking, generating this capacity to envision a different future should become
an integral part of poverty interventions and solidarity movements among
poor people.
156
Success from the Bottom Up
Aspirations and dreams of youth
My professors tell me: Abdul Kalam was also a village boy. Now he has
served as the president of India. His genius was not suppressed within the
village. You should also try your best in the same way, so that you may
achieve your goal.
—Sutunu, a young boy, Kantipur, West Bengal
Whenever our teams traveled to the field, they came back highly energized
on the days that they engaged with youth. Across study regions, young people
were eager to talk. They gave inspiring accounts of their future plans and provided the most frank insights into the way social relations, democratic structures, and economic opportunities actually worked in their communities.
Young men and women have visions for themselves that often go far beyond
the occupations of their parents. This is true especially for youths whose parents
are engaged in agriculture or informal work. Table 4.2 reports the occupations
desired by youth (boys and girls together), broken down by the primary source
of income of their parents. In both mover and the chronic poor families, children of parents engaged in casual labor, sale of livestock or forest products, and
TABLE 4.2
Path deviation in youth: Youths whose parents are in agriculture or the informal
sector want to do something else (start a business, get a job)
Youth aspirations (percentages)
Regular
employment
Business
Regular employment
69.7
26.9
3.0
0.4
Business
36.1
56.7
6.3
1.0
Agriculture and allied
activities
47.8
48.5
3.3
0.4
Informal work
39.8
44.5
14.8
0.8
Regular employment
66.9
27.3
4.3
1.4
Business
38.8
57.4
1.9
1.9
Agriculture and allied activities
44.8
49.4
3.7
2.1
Informal work
43.8
37.2
15.6
3.5
Parental source of income
Agriculture and
allied activities
Informal
work
Mover parents
Chronic poor parents
Source: Authors’ analysis of household survey (a section of which was conducted with youth in the household); all study regions; N = 2,113 (children of movers = 1,070; children of chronic poor = 1,043).
I Believe I Can
157
other nonagricultural sources of income wanted to do something else; most
wanted to start their own business or get a job. However, there was path dependence if parents already held a regular job or had a business.
Among chronic poor households where the parents were engaged in
farming, half of the children wanted to open small businesses such as copy
machine centers, telephone kiosks, and clinics. Another 45 percent aspired
to salaried jobs in government or the private sector. Only 4 percent wanted
to work in agriculture. Youths in Dapi Toube, Senegal, explained why: “Our
parents have always practiced agriculture, and yet they are still poor.”
As in Senegal, youths in West Bengal complained that agriculture was
stagnant. Even if they planned to continue farming, they hoped to have an
additional, nonagricultural source of income such as a business. “I would
like to start wholesale business of potato because I know that in this business
profit is good,” said the son of a farmer in Anakha. Unemployed and the son
of a casual laborer, Mohammed in Bhuinadi wanted to start a business of
“bringing readymade clothes from the city to sell them in the village market.”
Young people apparently realized very early the importance of diversification, which the field research in West Bengal found was crucial for mobility.
Salaried jobs, particularly government jobs, were prized for the regular
income and pension benefits they afforded. Utpal, a young woman in the
village of Leteku Gaon, a community affected by the separatist insurgency in
Assam, summed up the majority view. “In the future, I want to do a government job for its security. After my death, at least my dependent will get a pension or other facilities. Besides, it will ensure a regular monthly income.” But
most youths found themselves incapable of pulling the necessary strings or
bribing their way to secure a job. A higher proportion of children whose parents were already in a salaried job aspired to one, perhaps believing that their
parents might be able to afford the bribe or make the necessary connections.
Frustration with the slim prospects of finding a job sometimes led youth to
turn their sights to business. According to 21-year-old Lucky from Barbakara,
Assam, “Now we do not get any government jobs. I do not want to lose time
in searching for one. I think I will profit more by investing that amount of
time in business. I want to be a construction contractor. I am presently working as a temporary worker for a construction company. With this experience,
I will certainly be successful in business.”
Some youths did want to engage in farming. “It is wrong if anybody
thinks that one can earn only by getting educated,” said a group of young
boys in Andhra Pradesh. “We can earn by doing agriculture also. This is also
God’s grace. We should be gifted enough to serve Mother Earth. I want to
158
Success from the Bottom Up
serve the people by supplying food grains.” Interestingly, wherever youth
opted for farming or associated activities like fish breeding, they also spoke
of adding value to agriculture by purchasing equipment like tillers, irrigation
pumps, and fishing equipment.
Hardly anyone aspired to work in the temporary informal sector. Those
who did not choose salaried employment, business, or farming mentioned a
variety of other occupations. Some young boys, especially in the African study
regions, spoke of joining the army. Damson, who was in secondary school in
Chiksisi, Malawi, wanted to become a soldier “to maintain peace in the country, to go on peacekeeping missions for the United Nations, and to get a lot of
money in retirement benefits and a special respect, which I badly want.”
The occupational choices of many youths were driven by a desire to do
social good. Being a nurse was a preferred occupation for the girls in Damson’s
village. “There are few nurses in our country, and this is causing many deaths
in hospitals,” said a group of girls. “We would therefore like to work as nurses
and assist the country in saving people’s lives. We’ll also be able to assist our
families.” Erupakshi, a young boy in Appilepalle, Andhra Pradesh, held an
ambition of becoming a lawyer. “So I am studying well,” he said. “I want to
become an advocate and help poor people fight for justice.” Padma, a girl in
Virupapuram, Andhra Pradesh, was studying to “become a good doctor who
could serve the poor free of cost. Serving the people is equal to serving God.”
For women though, the choices were often restricted. Most young girls
opted for home-based occupations like sewing or for jobs where they could
return home early, such as teaching. Several said they expected only to be
good mothers and good wives. “What does the future mean for us?” asked a
group of girls in Dayabhara, Bangladesh. “The responsibility of thinking rests
on our male counterparts. They think of everything. To be married means the
end of all hopes and aspirations.”
Youths across study contexts worked hard to achieve their dreams, as
did their parents. Some children went to night school while working as day
laborers. Parents often sold off their assets to finance their children’s education. Poverty, however, remained the most important obstacle to realizing
these dreams. Some youths like Sattar in Chanpasha, Bangladesh, simply
gave up. “I had great hopes in life, but none of them have been fulfilled,” he
said. “I was studying in a madrassa [a religious school], but I had to discontinue the studies. It was my hope to become an established moulovi [religious
teacher], but I could not become so. It is now out of fear that I do not nurture
any hope. Whatever Allah wishes, I shall be so.” Some youths persevered.
Narasimha, a young man from Gopepalle, Andhra Pradesh, was one of them.
I Believe I Can
159
He said, “Where there is a will, there is a way. I am now studying for a bachelor degree in science. I want to become a lecturer in organic chemistry. My
parents encourage me by saying not to worry about the expenses incurred on
education. So, I want to study well and reach my goal. I believe that anything
can be achieved if we have confidence in ourselves.”
What Facilitates and Hinders Personal Agency?
Because psychological dimensions are so important, it is useful to understand the factors that strengthen these dimensions. We focus here on the
individual assets and capabilities that strengthen a person’s agency to take
action on his or her own behalf. Our quantitative data combined with the
stories we heard from people suggest several factors that can either help or
hinder poor men and women in their efforts to become effective agents in
moving out of poverty. Quantitatively, we tried to do this by using multivariate regression techniques. Our measure of individual agency (the personal
agency index) became the dependent variable. On the right-hand side, we
used independent variables that we believed could explain higher or lower
personal agency. The framework and variables used for the exercise are listed
in annex 4.1, followed by the results in annex 4.2.
In this section, we highlight a few key factors that either facilitate or hinder
personal agency—ones that were most frequently mentioned in the qualitative
data or that emerged in the quantitative data. On the positive side, we examine
ownership of assets, education, and political activism and connections. On the
negative side, we focus particularly on the effects of health and death shocks.
Assets and education
Although he is uneducated, 55-year-old Mir is one of the successful few who
has been able to move out of poverty in Afghanistan. In 1981, he moved
with his family and his parents to Shazimir, close to Kabul. Together father
and son set up a small shop and built a house. “At that time, the markets
were good, and we were able to save some money in three to four years.” In
1993, with the fighting raging between mujahideen groups, Mir’s business
collapsed. At around the same time, his father fell sick and died. Since then,
however, Mir has been able to reopen his shop, and his two sons have also
started a carpet-weaving business. The family now lives comfortably. Mir still
wonders what his situation would have been had he not had the advantage
of having a house and shop as assets to build on.
160
Success from the Bottom Up
Across study contexts, people are unequivocal about the importance of
starting out with or acquiring some assets. In India, land is of paramount
significance: those who began in poverty and later moved out of it almost
always made investments in land, both for income generation and as an asset
that could be sold should the family suffer a shock in the future. In the East
Asian study regions, people invest in assets that can help them in farming or
small business, like carabaos (water buffalo) for tilling in the Philippines, or
motorcycles that could be used as kepaks (small taxis) in Indonesia. Those
who started out with some assets, perhaps bequeathed by parents, found it
easier to acquire more assets than those who started out with nothing.
In some Cambodian villages, people see assets as making the crucial difference between transitory poverty and permanent destitution. A discussion
group in Salvia Prey explained, “The destitute have no assets, no lands or
draft animals—nothing except their unskilled labor. [Destitute households]
are often headed by a widow with small children and a disabled husband.
They live in cottages made of palm leaves and rely on collecting morning
glory, insects, and so on. Unlike the merely poor, the destitute cannot go fishing because they do not have fishing equipment.”
Besides providing an economic foundation on which to build, poor
women and men said that assets give them confidence to move ahead. This
association between asset ownership and confidence was confirmed in our
quantitative data: our measure of initial asset ownership was positively and
significantly associated with our personal agency index in several study contexts (annex 4.2).8 Those with more control over their decisions were also
more likely to report a higher average asset score. In figure 4.7, the y-axis plots
the difference between the current mean asset index score for households with
control over all decisions and that of households with control over no or few
decisions. Notice the responses of the never poor: those who reported control over all decisions on average had a considerably higher mean asset score
(1 unit higher) than those who had control over no or few decisions. Even
among the chronic poor and the fallers, those with more control were likely
to have a higher asset score.
Similarly, households that experienced a higher increase in their position on the 10-step ladder of power and rights were also more likely to report
acquisition of a house. In figure 4.8, those who reported more increase in
power (tercile 3) also experienced a greater increase in house ownership compared to those who reported a lower increase in power (tercile 1).
Besides assets, education is a significant confidence booster. Again, in
our regression analysis, we find a positive association between education and
I Believe I Can
161
Difference in average asset score
between households with control
over all decisions and households
with control over no/few decisions
FIGURE 4.7
Households with more control over decisions report ownership of more assets
1.2
1.00
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.51
0.46
0.36
0.4
0.2
0
Movers
Never poor
Chronic poor
Fallers
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from household survey; all study regions; N = 8,973.
FIGURE 4.8
Households with greater increase in power are more likely to have acquired a
house
14
% change in household ownership of house
12.4
12.1
12
10
9.3
8
6.4
6
5.0
4
2.4
2
0
–0.5
–2
–4
Movers
Never poor
Most gain in power
Chronic poor
–2.1
Fallers
Least gain in power
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from household survey; all study regions; N = 8,822.
162
Success from the Bottom Up
personal agency, significantly so in Andhra Pradesh, Mexico, Indonesia, and
Thailand. In the qualitative data, too, both adults and youths spoke of the
importance of being educated. When asked what was the most important thing
she had ever bought, Aklima, a 27-year-old mover from Bakimati, Philippines,
replied, “My education, which was given to me by my parents. If my parents
did not spend for my education, then maybe I would not have been able to
finish my studies. This is the only wealth that was given to me by my parents,
which could not be taken from me or sold. My life has become better because
of the education that I have. If I was not able to finish my studies, I could
have been working as a laundry woman or a farm laborer.” Young women in
Cambodia remarked, “Education is the most important asset of people in this
world. Being well educated, one can find a good job with a high standard of
living. With good education, one can manage to have a better life or set a clear
goal. The educated person never fears facing financial insecurity because he
or she has a permanent well-paid job. For example, a literate adult woman is
able to find a good job in the garment factory. Those who have no education
cannot find such fortune and become mobile laborers, a more risky job.”
Political connections
To gain success in business, political favor is needed. To export eggs, chicken,
and meat, or to import seedlings, you need a good connection with politicians to get permission and to get the legal documents ready.
—Mohammed, a 25-year-old man, Banjoydup, Bangladesh
Knowing a political figure is often as important for building selfconfidence and power as owning assets or even being educated. We found
a significant association between our measure of political connectedness—
whether a household had met a local politician—and personal agency, as
shown in annex 4.2. Figure 4.9 shows how our study respondents related
the two. With the exception of the movers, households that had experienced
greater increase in power (tercile 3) were more likely than households that
had experienced less increase in power (tercile 1) to report that they had met
a local politician during the study period.
Connections with political leaders are seen to be particularly useful in
the South Asia region. In West Bengal, joining the ruling party cadre is seen
as the surest way to acquire power and move out of poverty. In the town of
Masaru, youths without such connections lamented their inability to start a
business. Shyamal, who wanted to be a businessman, said, “Only the people who are close to the panchayat get permissions. So poor people cannot
I Believe I Can
163
FIGURE 4.9
Households with greater increase in power are more likely to have met a local
politician
30
% households that met local politician
27.6
25.7
25
23.6
20
16.1
17.1
18.4
15
13.7
11.9
10
5
0
Movers
Never poor
Most gain in power
Chronic poor
Fallers
Least gain in power
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from household survey; all study regions; N = 8,822.
acquire power. However, if poor people can save some money and be engaged
in politics, they can acquire power.”9
People routinely use “political privileges” as a means to gain power
and move ahead. Often such connections are acquired through relatives or
friends. Lily, age 30, was employed in the municipal offices of Bakimati, a
community in Lanao de Sur, a conflict-affected region in the Philippines. A
university graduate, she offered a role model to young women in the village.
However, an interview with Lily revealed that the key trigger to her upward
movement was help she received from the mayor, who happened to be Lily’s
sister-in-law. Immediately after graduating in 2000, Lily joined the mayor as
her campaign manager. She also doubled up as a maid in the mayor’s office,
a job she described as humiliating. “I was living in their house at that time,
and I even had to do the household chores. I didn’t like what I was doing
because I felt like a maid and that was not the job that I was applying for. I
was earning only 500 pesos a month, but I had to do that because she [the
mayor] promised me that I would have a position in the municipal office.”
164
Success from the Bottom Up
Lily was finally accepted as a municipal clerk in 2001, a position she held at
the time of the survey. She felt she could ask the mayor for assistance at any
time. “There were times that I was able to ask for some personal favor from
her, considering that she is my husband’s sister.”
Besides moving up through connections, bribing government officials is
a useful strategy. Lily studied for a year at Shariff Kabunsuan College, but then
decided to transfer to a different college “because a friend told me that I could
pass all my subjects if I would pay the instructor.” In Philippines-conflict,
respondents associated corruption in local government with an increase in
their power. In Uganda, Senegal, and Colombia, too, we found a positive and
significant association between corruption and our personal agency index.
People typically initiate contacts with political leaders to seek individual favors rather than to press collective requests. However, in some places
where people’s organizations have become strong—some communities in
the Colombian barrios, or villages in Andhra Pradesh where women’s selfhelp groups are thriving—these organizations have been able to get the attention of politicians to address community-wide issues. In some cases, this has
improved both the targeting and implementation of government programs.
Death and illness: Putting lives on a downward spiral
My situation has worsened. I am ill; my shop business has collapsed and I
have no income. He who does not move forward moves backward.
—Samba, a 43-year-old man in chronic poverty,
Maurikoube, Senegal
You can assist a bird only when it still has some strength.
—Discussion group in Chubaka, Kagera, Tanzania
One of the biggest obstacles poor households face when they attempt to
improve their well-being is the serious illness or death of someone in the family. Health and death shocks are a primary reason for falls into poverty, and
indeed the incidence of health shocks was higher among fallers and chronic
poor than among movers in virtually all the study regions (figure 4.10).10
The only exception is Mexico, where more movers than fallers reported experiencing an illness. The association of health shocks with falling is strikingly
high in the African study regions. Nearly 85 percent of fallers in Uganda, 79
percent in Malawi, and 73 percent in Ruvuma, Tanzania, had experienced a
health shock in the decade prior to the survey.
I Believe I Can
165
FIGURE 4.10
Fallers and chronic poor report more health shocks than movers
% households reporting health shock
90
86
79
80
73
70
69
67
60
58
56
51
50
52
50
50
46
40
40
30
25
24
20
10
)
el
(In
(P
an
AL
M
A
G
U
TA fra
)
N
(
PH Ruv
)
I(
Pa
TH ne
l)
BA A (I
ne
N
q
(E
m )
po
AP w)
(S
U HG
P
)
(C
M aste
E
)
W X (E
B
th
n)
(L
AS and
SA dis
t)
M
(C
o
PH nf
)
I
IN (Co
D
nf
O
)
(C
CO on
f)
L
(C
AF on
f)
G
(C
on
f)
0
Study region
Fallers
Chronic poor
Movers
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from household survey; N = 8,058.
Sometimes treatment is available, and poor households cannot afford
it. Just as often, there is a complete lack of health services or the services that
exist are too far away or are of extremely poor quality. This is a common
situation in the African study regions: health services are either too remote
to access or are captured by corrupt practitioners. In Zokwaza, Malawi, the
nearest hospital is 65 kilometers away. “We have to pay high fares in order to
get there,” said women and men in the community. “Otherwise, we have to
cycle from three o’clock in the morning and arrive there in the afternoon.”
But cycling is not an option if one has to transport a sick person or a woman
in labor. “Women in labor can force you to sell your land and animals to
get a taxi,” said a discussion group in Bukwaime, Uganda. “This inevitably
interferes in one’s plans to invest his money into development projects which
could have made an improvement in one’s well-being.” In Bamlozi, Malawi,
people could go to a government hospital, but they reported that at the hos-
166
Success from the Bottom Up
pital “there are no essential drugs, while the same drugs bearing Malawi government marks can be found in abundance in private hospitals.”
In such circumstances, many poor people go to quacks or traditional
healers or simply die in pain. In Leteku Gaon, Assam, a state that recorded
the highest incidence of health shocks among the four Indian states in our
sample, a teacher reported that malaria had ravaged the village in the absence
of proper health facilities. “In 2004, our village was badly affected by malaria
and cerebral malaria. About 12 people died. Before cremating one body, we
had to prepare for another.” The ladder of life discussion with women confirmed the epidemic and its effects: “A shadow of sorrow prevailed in the village. Even those who did not die became angry and mentally disturbed. The
villagers lost interest in work.”
In the Malawi study communities, people described falling ill because
of hunger. Women in Madkumba said, “The men had swelling in their legs
because of too much walking in search of food. The women were consuming
wild roots at home, waiting for food to be found.” Besides hunger, the threat
of HIV/AIDS is a daily reality for a majority of respondents in Malawi and
in some other African regions in our sample. People in Chikluzi, a village in
Malawi with high HIV prevalence, described how the pandemic had affected
them. “Intelligent people are dying. When so many people die, development
declines,” said one. “I left for one week in 2003, and by the time I came back
eight people had died. The day I arrived, another person died. Sometimes you
go to the graveyard to bury someone, but before you come back, you just hear
that someone else has died.” In Kamlondo, Uganda, nearly every household
had lost a member to HIV/AIDS. Young people were dying at the highest rate,
depriving the community of their strength. “This has greatly led to the loss of
productive people,” said men in the community. “If they were still around,
we would have been very developed.”
People identified four types of shocks caused by death or illness. First,
the death or disappearance of a family member, particularly the breadwinner, can set entire households on a downward spiral into poverty. Across
study sites, widows and orphans are placed at the bottommost step on the
well-being ladder. Miriam is a 50-year-old chronically poor woman in Riah
Khillaw, Afghanistan. Her husband migrated to Iran in 1997 during the Taliban’s rule, and by 2005 she had had no news of whether he was alive or dead.
Miriam and her four children had been living off handouts from neighbors
and relatives. Her eldest son worked as a laborer, and her second son, 12
years old, was contemplating doing so as well. Miriam herself tried tailoring,
but anxiety about her husband gradually weakened her. “I do not have good
I Believe I Can
167
health,” she told the field team. “My nerves are weak, and my eyes do not
work well. I have a stomachache. I cannot sleep without medicines. We do
not have our own house; we live in my husband’s sister’s house. They are in
Iran at present, and when they return to Afghanistan, we will be shelterless
and our life will get worse. I worry about my children. They live with hardship
and humility. I have no hope for their future.”
Second, deaths, illnesses, and accidents typically force big expenditures
that result in dissaving. People have to sell off precious assets to cope with
medical treatment or funeral expenses and often go deeply into debt. Jahangir, a chronic poor man in Uttar Pradesh, had labored for years to accumulate three assets that he believed would enable him to move out of poverty: a
bicycle, land for farming, and a permanent house instead of the flimsy kutcha
hut that sheltered his family. Juggling work as a daily wage laborer and a vegetable seller, Jahangir had saved bit by bit for these assets, and he did manage
to buy a bicycle. But the untimely death of both his parents in 1990 threw
Jahangir, then 25 years old, off the saving track. He had to borrow from a village moneylender to finance the funeral expenses. Eight years later, Jahangir’s
family still lived in the hut; his wife and two young boys had joined him as
wage laborers to pay the loan from the moneylender. In 1998, just when he
had saved enough to construct a proper house, the wall of his kutcha hut
fell down, breaking Jahangir’s hands and legs. “I had to give up my job as
a vegetable seller. I spent about 10,000 rupees [approximately $250] for my
treatment, which I took from a moneylender in the market. I still haven’t paid
this back. Both my sons and my wife do labor and organize to get some provisions back home. I took another loan to construct the house because after the
accident, we put up a temporary polythene roof. We were constantly attacked
by monkeys. I had to take a loan from a village moneylender to construct a
room where we could all stay.”
Buried under debt, Jahangir tried to work as a laborer, but with his disability, he was paid less than others. The third shock occasioned by illness
and accidents, as in this case, is the loss of earning power. For the chronic
poor, many of whom are daily wage laborers, their bodies and hands are
precious assets, and disabilities and sickness spell devastation. Moreover,
having a sick or injured person in the family to care for can reduce the
earning power of other household members. In Zokwaza, Malawi, a key
informant described HIV/AIDS as one of the most important factors in the
community’s decline. “People are spending more time attending to patients
and funerals instead of working in the fields or doing other income-generating activities.” Youths in Kabkore, Uganda, added, “Once one is infected
168
Success from the Bottom Up
with AIDS, she or he becomes very weak and can’t dig much land to move
out of poverty.”
Finally, and perhaps most importantly, encounters with death and illness can kill confidence in oneself and dreams for the future. Jahangir, in
Uttar Pradesh, summed up the impact of his misfortunes: “Now I am losing trust.” Adults spoke of severe anxiety and mental illnesses like depression after the death of their spouses or children. Peter, a 22-year-old stuck
in chronic poverty in Tulma, Philippines, resorted to drinking when his first
child died. “It was a big blow,” he said to our field team. “I was always drunk.
I lost my interest to work. It seemed that I had gone insane in my thoughts.”
Zamada, a woman in poverty in Glikati, Philippines, had a similar experience when her three children died. Seven days after the last death, Zamada
herself fell ill. She said it was primarily because she was not able to express
her feelings. “I got so sick after the deaths. My relatives would tell me that I
should talk about them because they had seen that all through, I had been
awfully quiet.” The final blow came with the death of her mother in 2006,
the year our team interviewed her. Zamada also became sick then and lost
the confidence to work.
Heartbreakingly, children often gave up their hopes and aspirations to
do better when their parents died. In Kibtuntula, Uganda, several youths we
met were grieving parents lost to HIV/AIDS. As orphans, they had no money
to finance their school fees and had given up hope for the future.
Simple cross-tabulations between the incidence of health shocks and
one of our measures of personal agency—control over everyday decision
making—revealed that households that reported less control over their everyday decisions compared to 10 years ago were also more likely to report a
health shock during the survey period (figure 4.11). For instance, only 35
percent of movers who said they had more control now than earlier also said
they had suffered a health shock over the 10-year period. In comparison, 44
percent of movers with less control had experienced such a shock. Similarly,
those who suggested that they had control over all their decisions also ranked
themselves higher on a four-step scale corresponding to their current health
(4 = excellent health; 1 = very bad health).
Households with lower aspirations for their children were also more
likely to report experiences with sickness or illness (figure 4.12). Only about
35 percent of movers who expect their children to be better off said that they
had experienced a health shock. However, nearly 57 percent of those who
expect their children to be worse off cited a brush with illness. That health
I Believe I Can
FIGURE 4.11
Households with less control over decisions report more health shocks and
poorer current state of health
58.7
% households reporting health shock
60
51.6
50
51.3
49.8 48.5
44.4
40
37.7
35.1
30
20
10
0
Movers
Never poor
Chronic poor
More control
Fallers
Less control
Mean score of current health conditions
Excellent 4
3
3.1
3.1
2.8
2.8
Fairly
bad
2.9
2.8
2.5
2
1.9
Very bad 1
Movers
Never poor
Control over all decisions
Chronic poor
Fallers
Control over no/few decisions
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from household survey; all study regions; N = 8,973.
169
170
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 4.12
Households with lower aspirations for their children report more health shocks
59.8
60
57.4
56.7
56.3
% households reporting health shock
51.9
48.6
50
40
34.9
33.6
30
20
10
0
Movers
Never poor
Expect children to be better off
Chronic poor
Fallers
Expect children to be worse off
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from household survey; all study regions; N = 8,058.
shocks lower confidence and personal agency across study contexts was reaffirmed by the negative association between health shocks and our personal
agency index in virtually all study regions in our model (annex 4.2).
It isn’t surprising, then, that poor people greatly fear illness. Julieta, a
woman in El Mirador, Colombia, remarked, “God give us some health for
moving on, to keep on fighting. I do not want to get sick.” In the remote village of Katugende, Uganda, Ruth, a widow in chronic poverty agreed: “Unless
sickness strikes, there is always a chance of developing further if I work hard.”
And when asked if anyone in her community was safe from falling into poverty,
Miro, a farmer in Ramili Qali, Afghanistan, replied in the negative and added,
“Not if a bad incident takes place, for example, death or an incurable disease. We have a proverb which says that if both arms break, a person may be
able to work, but if the heart breaks, he will not be able to work.” For poor,
vulnerable women and men, one incurable disease or one death is often the
thin line that divides their ability to work and move out of poverty from their
giving up hope and heart.
I Believe I Can
171
Conclusion
Poor people have a deep and immediate understanding of power and power
relationships. They know their own powerlessness in the context of deeprooted inequalities in economic, social, and political structures. Despite the
strangulation they sometimes feel, or perhaps because of it, poor people display a strong internal sense of power, self-confidence, and will to persist, no
matter what.
Our evidence clearly indicates that poor men and women can act as agents
on their own behalf. With few assets, limited or no education, and few if any
social or political connections, they still aspire and strive to move out of poverty. The life stories suggest that psychological self-efficacy is often the most
important precursor to action, and the magnitude of effects reflected in our
quantitative data confirms the importance of personal agency and aspirations
in poverty escapes. Yet these psychological dimensions have been ignored
almost completely in international development programs, which rarely transcend the vague rhetoric of “putting people at the center of development.”
These results obviously do not mean that we need self-esteem schools
for the poor. They do call for a change in how development is done. Development programs and strategies must be designed and carried out in ways that
uphold people’s dignity and reinforce their sense of self-respect; this is true
even in conflict contexts where people are frightened and have lost everything
and in the most impoverished communities where they may be nearly starving. This change can be done through participatory development programs
in which participation does not become another tax, but instead generates
positive returns to participants.
Deeply entrenched gender inequalities can be addressed by focusing on
“power with,” through investment in collective action by poor women. The
success of the microcredit movement in Bangladesh and of women’s self-help
groups in Andhra Pradesh has shown that forming groups of socially marginalized women can help. Over time, as these spread and become social movements, they can change deeply entrenched social norms. In Andhra Pradesh,
for example, meetings start with rituals, songs, and prayers to help women
break through old barriers and begin to recognize their self-worth. The focus
is on addressing priority needs first through collective strength. In both programs, when women are asked about the most important difference in their
lives, they most often first talk about the loss of fear.
Steps to increase material assets, particularly permanent housing, can go
a long way in reinforcing poor people’s self-confidence and giving them an
economic foundation to build on.
172
Success from the Bottom Up
Health shocks bleed people’s resources and destroy their hopes and
dreams. No matter which data we examine, whether from life stories, group
discussions, or questionnaires, the critical role of health shocks as a cause of
destitution emerges with heartbreaking regularity. Provision of affordable,
quality health care is one of the most important things that can be done to
save lives and livelihoods.
As important as personal agency is, it is only one side of the equation.
Strategies to boost self-efficacy cannot succeed as long as skewed opportunity structures thwart poor people’s initiatives. Economic, social, and
political inequalities in their environments keep poor people down even
though they dream of rising. Thus, two people with the same level of confidence and aspirations may end up with different levels of power, depending
on their individual capabilities and on the economic, social, and political opportunity structure within which they pursue their interests (Kabeer
1999; Narayan 2002b, 2005; Petesch, Smulovitz, and Walton 2005; World
Bank 2006; Rao and Walton 2004b).11 This opportunity structure is embedded in institutions, and in the next three chapters we tackle the three main
types of institutions with which poor women and men interact: markets,
local democracies, and their own collective groups.
I Believe I Can
Annex 4.1 Factors Associated with Personal Agency
Asset index, 10 years ago
• PCA index of assets owned with current weights (10 years ago, rh201 i–xiiib)
Social assets
Personal access to networks and associations
• Number of groups household belonged to (10 years ago, h406Tb)
• Extent of linking social capital (currently, h410)
Community access to networks and associations
• Change in access to networks and associations (rc919: focus group discussion)
Participation in local government
• Change in participation in community (over 10 years, rc916)
Political assets
• Voting in state/national elections (currently, rh508)
• Meeting local politicians (over 10 years, rh503iii)
Education
• Education of household head (currently, h106)
Health shocks
• Health shocks (over 10 years, rh305)
Violence against women
• Violence against women within households (10 years ago, h609b)
Household access to information
• Trend in access to information about local government (over 10 years, rh515b)
PCA index of corruption
• Corruption in government officials in village (c506b)
Elite capture
• Officials act in their own or public interest (over 10 years, h507)
Extent of social divisions
• Differences between people based on ethnicity, caste, etc. (c414b)
PCA index of ethnic/religious/gender discrimination in schools
• Trend in ethnic/religious discrimination in schools (over 10 years, c305b)
• Trend in gender discrimination in schools (over 10 years, c304b)
PERSONAL AGENCY INDEX
PCA index of current personal agency using household-level data
• Current position on ladder of power and rights (h707)
• Current control over everyday decisions (rh501a)
Note: See appendix 4 for explanation of codes.
173
174
Success from the Bottom Up
Annex 4.2 Full OLS Regression Results with Personal
Agency as Dependent Variable
UP
Caste
Asset index, 10
years ago (PCA
rh201 (i–xiii)b,
with current
weights)
Number of
groups household
belonged to,
10 years ago
(h406Tb)
Extent of linking
social capital
(h410)
0.324
[10.77]***
0.069
[2.98]***
0.387
[2.99]***
WB
Landdist
0.216
[5.11]***
ASSAM
Conf
0.284
[6.03]***
AP
SHG
0.232
[5.76]***
BAN
Empow
0.512
[4.51]***
0.032
0.145
0.003
0.063
[0.78]
[2.56]**
[0.10]
[2.32]**
0.037
−0.161
−0.152
[0.31]
[1.47]
[2.69]***
0.26
[2.74]***
UGA
Panel
MAL
Infra
0.215
0.144
[2.75]***
[1.53]
0.084
[0.24]
Change in access
to networks
(rc919)
−0.042
0.078
−0.017
[1.35]
[1.19]
[0.43]
Change in
participation in
community (rc916)
−0.067
−0.057
−0.043
0.027
0.119
[1.93]*
[0.80]
[1.00]
[0.27]
[1.36]
Voting in elections
(rh508)
−0.029
−0.014
0.473
0.858
0.137
0.258
−0.196
[0.16]
[0.10]
[1.78]*
[2.49]**
[1.76]*
[1.60]
[0.79]
0.14
0.103
Meeting local
politicians
(rh503iii)
Education of
household head
(h106)
Health shocks,
over 10 years
(rh305)
Violence against
women, 10 years
ago (h609b)
Access to
information on
government
programs (rh515b)
0.067
[5.45]***
0
[0.01]
0.072
[2.62]***
0.09
[4.77]***
[8.93]***
[2.54]**
0.008
−0.013
0.012
[1.83]*
[0.72]
[1.95]*
[4.34]***
−0.21
−0.186
−0.438
−0.138
−0.159
−0.131
−0.48
[3.78]***
[2.28]**
[5.01]***
[1.74]*
[2.71]***
[1.25]
[1.67]*
0.106
−0.101
−0.002
[2.22]**
[1.38]
[0.03]
0.036
[0.80]
0.452
[5.84]***
0.106
0.183
[3.41]***
0.024
[0.35]
0.398
−0.148
[3.29]***
[0.79]
0.038
0.166
0.06
0.107
[0.86]
[1.62]
[0.90]
[0.46]
Note: Blank cells mean that either the variable was not available or had to be dropped because of high
multicollinearity with other variables. School inequality included only for India regressions.
I Believe I Can
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
AFG
Conf
0.069
0.047
0.278
[0.70]
[0.67]
[3.10]***
0.201
[2.70]***
INDO
Conf
0.098
0.104
[1.01]
[1.53]
COL
Conf
0.12
[2.28]**
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
0.146
0.056
0.238
[1.88]*
[0.40]
[5.88]***
0.055
0.034
−0.05
0.012
0.029
[0.72]
[0.83]
[0.17]
[0.74]
0.281
−0.085
0.224
[1.44]
[0.44]
[2.50]**
0.256
0.653
−0.023
[0.85]
[0.17]
0.163
0.211
−0.063
0.007
[0.76]
[1.85]*
[0.25]
[0.09]
−0.03
0.206
−0.111
0.202
[0.12]
[1.17]
[0.18]
0.028
0.035
−0.177
[1.31]
[0.95]
[1.65]*
0.281
[3.03]***
−0.095
0.252
0.2
[1.20]
[1.24]
0.31
0.149
−0.151
0.155
−0.003
[0.42]
[1.59]
[1.27]
[0.85]
[0.29]
[0.01]
0.073
0.066
0.041
0.076
0.04
0.023
[1.39]
[1.82]*
[1.01]
[1.41]
[1.16]
[0.75]
[2.13]**
0.076
[0.08]
MEX
Ethn
[0.77]
[2.27]**
0
PHI
Conf
175
0.157
[2.69]***
0.103
[3.41]***
[2.11]**
−0.106
−0.022
−0.008
−0.024
−0.283
−0.015
−0.45
[0.61]
[0.17]
[0.08]
[0.37]
[2.67]***
[0.12]
[3.44]***
[0.73]
0.215
0.071
0.24
0.005
0.175
−0.083
−0.036
−0.21
−0.085
[1.55]
[1.44]
[0.04]
[1.30]
[1.27]
[0.62]
[1.02]
[0.96]
[2.42]**
0.044
0.022
0.179
[0.33]
[0.23]
[0.72]
0.385
[4.47]***
0.075
0.016
0.151
0.146
0.061
0.012
[0.13]
[1.44]
[2.42]**
[0.40]
[0.15]
(continued)
176
Success from the Bottom Up
UP
Caste
Corruption in local
government, 10
years ago (c506b)
WB
Landdist
ASSAM
Conf
−0.015
−0.01
0.01
0.025
0.036
0.063
[0.61]
[0.25]
[0.24]
[0.48]
[1.14]
[1.85]*
0.054
−0.277
−0.158
0.001
−0.004
[3.17]***
[1.76]*
[0.01]
[0.07]
Household
perception of
change in elite
capture (h507)
[1.69]*
Extent of social
inequality in
community
(c414b)
0.064
0.038
[2.44]**
[1.03]
Extent of
discrimination
in schools (PCA
c304b, c305b)
Constant
Observations
R2
−0.08
[2.13]**
AP
SHG
0.152
[2.23]**
BAN
Empow
0.143
UGA
Panel
0.152
[3.57]***
0.181
−0.089
[1.83]*
−0.165
−0.424
0.235
−2.287
−0.949
−0.63
[0.61]
[1.15]
[0.66]
[4.58]***
[4.52]***
[2.57]**
839
862
683
0.19
0.23
0.22
[3.57]***
[1.70]*
0.007
0.18
−0.355
0.088
[0.23]
746
[2.60]***
[1.90]*
0.038
1192
−0.19
[2.61]***
[1.14]
1635
MAL
Infra
0.16
0.15
0.736
[1.31]
106
0.21
Note: Cluster-robust t-statistics in brackets. Blank cells mean that either the variable was not available
or had to be dropped because of high multicollinearity with other variables. School inequality included
only for India regressions.
*p < .10 **p < .05 ***p < .01 (White heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors)
For key on codes and abbreviations, see appendixes 2 and 4.
I Believe I Can
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
0.227
0.017
−0.05
−0.062
[2.39]**
[0.39]
[0.17]
[2.25]**
0.042
−0.045
−0.007
0.192
0.056
[0.35]
[0.56]
[0.05]
[1.40]
[1.09]
0.536
−0.008
−0.015
−0.22
[2.26]**
[0.06]
[0.24]
[2.62]***
177
PHI
Conf
COL
Conf
MEX
Ethn
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
0.061
0.248
0.106
0.009
0.018
[1.88]*
[2.31]**
[0.94]
[0.17]
[0.24]
−0.119
0.017
−0.29
−0.029
[0.88]
[0.18]
[2.71]***
[0.22]
0.164
−0.363
−0.12
0.101
[1.39]
[1.48]
[1.51]
[1.70]*
−1.45
−0.97
−0.62
−2.012
−0.22
−0.959
−0.39
1.05
−0.36
[1.61]
[2.02]**
[1.35]
[2.82]***
[0.58]
[2.40]**
[0.88]
[1.37]
[0.52]
263
0.12
292
0.13
83
0.22
315
0.16
300
0.1
218
0.19
291
0.12
163
0.07
497
0.1
178
Success from the Bottom Up
Notes
1. See, for example, A. Sen (1985, 1993, 1999), Nussbaum (2000), and Alkire
(2008). The roots of community development, participatory development,
cooperatives, and the “people first” concept all are based on the premise that
poor people’s active agency is central in their movement out of poverty.
2. This response was to a question in a focus group exercise on livelihoods, freedom, power, and democracy that was conducted separately with women, men,
and youth in each community. The participants in each group were asked, “What
does power mean? What does it mean to have power? What does it mean to be
powerful? What are the local definitions, terms, or sayings that capture the concept of power?” The question was left open ended, although the word used to
introduce power was predetermined in training workshops before the investigators went out into the field.
3. There is a vast social science literature on power, starting with Weber and Marx.
Some of the most influential works include those of Steven Lukes, James Scott,
Anthony Giddens, Antonio Gramsci, Charles Tilly, J. K. Galbraith, and Alvin Toffler, and from the grassroots perspective Robert Chambers, Naila Kabeer, John
Gaventa, and Ainsur Rahman, among many others.
4. In Durable Inequality, Charles Tilly argues that much of the inequality previously
attributed to differences in individual ability and characteristics is instead a
consequence of factors that generate categorical inequalities. These systematic
inequalities between categories of people give certain types of people advantages from the start, allowing the persistence of categorical divisions in the
future. Categorical inequalities are usually established through exploitation and
opportunity hoarding. Over time, however, emulation and adaptation to social
inequalities exacerbate social divisions, contributing to their persistence in the
long run.
5. The difference in African observations (more power and rights than elsewhere)
may also reflect the fact that within many African countries, some societies are
historically less hierarchical than those in other parts of the world. The other
study region where power levels were high among the poor is Bangladesh. This
probably reflects the considerable increase in women’s empowerment due to
interventions by NGOs (box 4.1).
6. The technique of principal components analysis was used to create the index.
7. Boudon (1973) postulated that most individuals evaluate their performance
against some “reference group” that they are part of. People belonging to a lower
class have a lower reference point and, therefore, are prone to being easily satisfied and less motivated to reach positions in the upper class.
8. The asset index was created using the technique of principal components over all
assets.
9. Interestingly, our measure of political activities in West Bengal showed an insignificant association with personal agency in the regressions (annex 4.2).
I Believe I Can
179
10. There is an extensive body of literature that suggests that illness and death are the
most common triggers for declines into poverty. For more details, see Anirudh
Krishna’s studies on reasons for upward movement out of and decline into
poverty in the Indian states of Rajasthan, Andhra Pradesh, and Gujarat (Krishna
2004, 2006; Krishna et al. 2005).
11. See Rao and Walton (2004b) for an excellent discussion on inequality of agency
and the role of culture. For issues in measuring empowerment, see Ibrahim and
Alkire (2007), Alsop and Heinsohn (2005), Narayan (2005), Kabeer (2001), and
Mayoux (2003).
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
There is a ditch in front of us and a well
behind us.
—W OMEN ’ S DISCUSSION GROUP ,
Govindapalle, Andhra Pradesh
Lot owners need water for their lots, and
farmers also need water for their farms.
Hundreds of hectares of rice farms rely
on one lake. Our good government never
shouts at the lot owners, who usually
drain water from the lake to their lots.
But they very often shout at us.
—D ISCUSSION
WITH YOUTHS FROM POOR FAMILIES ,
Preysath, Cambodia
Getting a permit is tough. You must
have contacts and money.
—D ISCUSSION WITH WOMEN ,
Villa Rosa, Colombia
There is no problem in doing business.
All can do it. But where there is no
light, no bridge, and no roads, what
business will you do?
—D ISCUSSION WITH WOMEN ,
Biralipara, Assam
5
C HAPTER
F
or the most part, women and men in poverty are willing to work hard,
take initiative, and persevere to realize their aspirations. But it is by
no means ensured that hard work and initiative will translate into upward
mobility. This chapter examines how national and local conditions, particularly market conditions, can constrict or expand opportunities to move out
of poverty.
If all individuals were born with equal life chances, and if there truly were
equal opportunity for everyone, then the just desserts of a free market really
would be just. But we all know that the world we live in is not a world of equal
opportunity. Some of us are born in rich countries, some in poor countries.
Within countries, some people are born in booming regions and some in
regions suffering long-run decline. Some are born male, some female; some
are born into the favored social class, racial group, or caste, and some are not.
Some are born to wealthy parents and some to parents with few assets.
These multiple, often interacting, layers of geographic, social, and economic inequalities create unequal access to markets and opportunities. Our
study found that most poor women and men would be more than happy
to participate in markets on fair terms, but when they try to do business,
they often lose out in state-regulated or collusion-dominated markets that
are anything but free. The opportunity sets they face for obtaining credit, for
purchasing inputs, for selling outputs, and for meeting the tax and regulatory requirements of the state are very different from those that the well-off
enjoy. Thus the “invisible hand” of the free market is instead a very visible
hand of markets that are rigged against the poor. What poor people in our
study mainly asked for is a level playing field, where they would have equal
opportunities to use their assets and initiative to get ahead.
The conventional approach to poverty consists of national policies to
promote rapid growth along with safety net or targeted programs to mitigate
181
182
Success from the Bottom Up
the consequences of poverty, combined with some measure of investments in
human capital for future generations. We would argue that expanding poor
women’s and men’s economic opportunity sets requires more. National policies, including those to promote overall economic growth, undoubtedly play
an enormous role in the reduction of aggregate poverty, and we review that
evidence. However, local conditions significantly shape the opportunities
available within communities. Even when a country is on a rising tide, local
conditions will affect whether households are able to sail out of poverty or
confront choppy seas. Government interventions to improve opportunity
sets within communities—by building infrastructure, connecting producers
to new markets, facilitating more and better credit, and ensuring a favorable
climate for small business—can go far in allowing people to use their assets
and initiative to move up.
Economic Growth: The Rising Tide
Growth may be everything, but it’s not the only thing.
—Joseph Stiglitz, Foreign Affairs, November/December 2005
Although our study was not framed to contribute to debates about the
relationship between national economic growth and poverty reduction, the
topic is too important to ignore. Let us start with a clear question: How is
growth in measured aggregate consumption expenditures (ACE) related to
reductions in the headcount measure of absolute consumption expenditure
(HACE) poverty?1
This question can be reduced arithmetically to growth and a distributional adjustment, which itself has two components. First is the growth in
aggregate consumption. The distribution effect is both whether the poor got
more or less proportionally of the increase/decrease than their initial share in
the total and how many people were near the ACE poverty threshold to start
with. The relative magnitude of the two effects (growth and distribution) in
the proximate explanation of poverty reduction is an entirely empirical question. If differences in (distribution-adjusted) growth across countries are large
and changes in distribution over time are small, then differences across countries in poverty reduction will be mostly attributed to differences between
countries in their growth. Moreover, if the distribution of income changes
a great deal over time and differences in medium or long-term growth rates
are small, then the opposite conclusion—that distribution mattered most—
could emerge.
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
183
Kraay (2006) uses household data sets covering medium- to long-run
spells of 5 to 10 years and finds that around 90 percent of the variation across
80 countries in the pace of HACE poverty reduction in the 1980s and 1990s
can be attributed to growth (figure 5.1). Many other studies, such those by
Ravallion (1995, 2001), Ravallion and Chen (1997), and Fields (2001), also
confirm the strong correlation between poverty reduction and aggregate economic growth. In addition, the review by Cord (2005) of the experiences
of 14 countries during the 1990s shows that more rapid growth is strongly
associated with more rapid poverty reduction.
Understanding three stylized facts can help us both grasp Kraay’s results
and understand what the findings do and do not imply. The first stylized fact
is that the differences across countries in economic growth are enormous.
If we examine the growth rate of gross domestic product per capita across
all developing countries over a decade and compare high performers (those
in the top 10 percent) to low performers (those in the bottom 10 percent),
the difference is around 6.5 percent per year. The second simple fact is that
while countries differ in their level of consumption and income inequality—
for example, South Africa and Brazil are very unequal and Hungary is very
equal—changes in inequality tend to be small. When Deininger and Squire
(1996) first assembled data that allow an investigation of changes in inequality, they found that with a few exceptions (notably China), equal countries
stayed equal and unequal countries stayed unequal. A third stylized fact is
that, at least in recent data, the pace of economic growth and the changes in
inequality are roughly uncorrelated. It is not the case that countries growing
more rapidly tend to have bigger increases in inequality (Ravallion 2004).
If you combine the three basic facts—that growth rates differ greatly
across countries, that changes in the distribution of consumption within
countries over time tend to be small, and that these changes are unrelated
to growth—it arithmetically must be the case that most of the cross-national
differences in poverty reduction can be attributed to differences in growth.
One common confusion in the debates about growth and poverty is
about the role of inequality. If, for the same increase in total growth, the
measures of inequality worsen because of changes in the lower tail of the distribution, then it is possible that poverty reduction will be less than it would
have been otherwise. But this change does not mean that “increased inequality is bad for poverty reduction” in a causal (not arithmetic) sense. From
1978 to 2000, China experienced the most impressive reduction in absolute
poverty in the history of mankind. At the same time, it experienced the largest
recorded increase in inequality. The growth in China was sufficiently rapid
184
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 5.1
Comparison of spells of growth and poverty reduction shows that the pace of
poverty reduction is strongly associated with growth, but with variation around
this pattern
0.20
Average annual growth in headcount poverty
ETH (95–00)
0.15
Falling incomes,
rising poverty
Rising incomes,
rising poverty
0.10
CIV (85–95)
BWA (85– 93)
–0.20
–0.15
– 0.10
– 0.05
0.10
– 0.05
0.15
CHN (90–98)
– 0.10
PHL (85– 00)
– 0.15
– 0.20
Falling incomes,
falling poverty
– 0.25
Rising incomes,
falling poverty
VNM (93– 98)
Average annual growth in survey mean income
Source: Adapted from Kraay 2006.
Note: ETH = Ethiopia; CIV = Côte d’Ivoire; BWA = Botswana; CHN = China; PHL = Philippines;
VNM = Vietnam.
that those at the bottom of the distribution, getting a smaller and smaller
share of a larger and larger pie, ended up with much more pie. The question
of whether increased inequality was “bad” for poverty reduction in China
depends on whether the same rapid economic growth could have been produced without the increasing income inequality. Perhaps yes, perhaps no, but
this is a counterfactual question. One can compute what poverty reduction
“would have been” if growth had stayed the same while inequality increased
less, but just because one can compute a counterfactual does not mean that
the assumed levels of growth and inequality would have been feasible.
Cord (2005) separated poverty reduction into a growth component and
a distribution component in 10 countries for which data were available. She
found that sometimes growth and redistribution worked together (e.g., in Brazil and Bolivia); sometimes growth was positive, but increases in inequality
led to less poverty reduction than would have occurred had (counterfactually)
185
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
20
10
0
–10
–20
–30
Growth component
a
bi
m
Za
ia
Ro
m
an
ia
liv
Bo
Br
az
il
na
ha
G
ne
ga
l
a
Se
isi
de
la
ng
Ba
Tu
n
a
nd
ga
U
na
Vi
et
sh
–40
m
Percentage points change in headcount poverty
FIGURE 5.2
Although inequality may help or hinder poverty reduction, its contribution to
poverty reduction over long episodes tends to be less than that of growth
Redistribution component
Source: Cord 2005.
the growth been distribution-neutral (e.g., in Vietnam and Bangladesh); and
sometimes growth was negative, but distribution improved (e.g., in Romania).
But Cord’s data, shown in figure 5.2, are striking in two respects. First, the
differences in poverty reduction due to the growth component were typically
much larger than those due to the distribution component, even for episodes
shorter than a decade. Second, in these 10 countries, one sees that in the five
countries with the most rapid poverty reduction, inequality increased (Vietnam,
Uganda, Bangladesh, Senegal, and Ghana). In the two countries where poverty
increased (Romania and Zambia), inequality decreased or stayed the same.
Growth is good. A sufficiently large rise in the tide will lift nearly all
boats. This change implies that if national policies are able to speed up economic growth significantly, this will almost certainly facilitate rapid poverty
reduction. Our study acknowledges this important role, and it is not designed
to provide new information on either the role of growth or on what policies,
if any, might succeed in accelerating economic growth.
186
Success from the Bottom Up
But, as discussed in chapter 3, poverty reduction is about much more
than the upward speed of the national economic escalator. First, the extent
to which growth provides opportunities for individuals to improve their
income—through new jobs, new crops, or new business initiatives—varies
greatly, depending on the sources of growth but also on how economic
opportunities are either facilitated or limited by policy. Second, the national
picture does not reveal the dynamics of localities, and these can easily get lost
in national aggregates.
The Geography of Opportunity
If you want to get information on your pension or receive medical services,
you have to first walk for 4 kilometers.
—Discussion with men, Chakax, Mexico
Policy makers increasingly recognize that location and geography are
important for development. There has been a revival in the branches of economic thinking concerned with which economic activities and opportunities
are located where, and why. The impact of “location, location, location” is
visible in our data. In the two study regions in Tanzania (Kagera and Ruvuma)
and in Malawi, where the subsampling was done based on distance to markets or roads, the results show most clearly that proximity to towns and access
to markets over roads improve economic opportunity.
For instance, the Kagera study found that a household’s initial endowments of assets (like land and education) matter much more for upward
mobility in communities that are isolated and remote than in those that are
well connected. The difference lies in the opportunities available. In remote
villages, agriculture is the only route out of poverty, so starting with sufficient land matters much more. By contrast, in economically well-connected
villages, households can engage in trade and business, and even those with
small amounts of initial wealth can move up.
This importance of economic remoteness emerged in both the quantitative and qualitative data gathered by the study team. Quantitatively, the Kagera study was based on revisiting a set of households, spread over 51 villages
in the region, that were surveyed in 1993 and again in 2004. Regression analysis was used to explain household outcomes in 2004 using characteristics
measured in 1993, including age, sex, education, health, characteristics of the
household head, household demographic characteristics, network characteristics, initial assets position, and community fixed effects. The results were
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
187
striking. The model predicted falling down much better than it predicted
moving up and out of poverty. Seventy-eight percent of the people whose
assets were predicted to drop did in fact see their assets drop. In other words,
for nearly four-fifths of the households that fell, this drop was predictable in
1993 based purely on observed characteristics. Upwardly mobile households
were much harder to pinpoint: only about half the households that were
predicted to rise did in fact do so. This finding suggests that the processes that
keep people in poverty were relatively well captured by the regressions, but
not the processes by which they move out of poverty.2
Next, the team turned to the qualitative data to examine the variation
in upward mobility unexplained by the regressions. To do so, it picked life
stories of individuals with similar predicted outcomes but different actual
outcomes.3 A key conclusion of this “matching” analysis was that the interaction of locality connectedness with an individual’s starting position (land,
education, etc.) was strongly associated with the different paths. In remote
communities, 71 percent of “surprise risers” (those who were predicted to
fall, but in fact rose) had better initial household conditions. But in communities that were well located and connected (close to the border, connected
with roads, etc.), the household’s initial conditions added little to explaining
the surprise risers, accounting for only 31 percent of unexpected movement
of the matched households.
Two examples from Kagera, Tanzania, illustrate the point. Located in the
northern part of Kagera, Kamsoni is close to the Tanzania–Uganda border and
is a major center of trade. A high-quality tarmac road, built in 2003, links the
village to the regional capital of Kagera on one side and to the Ugandan border
and Kampala on the other. Public transportation is available at least 10 times
a day in both directions. Residents of Kamsoni engaged in various businesses,
exporting agricultural produce, loading trucks, changing currency, and so on.
A woman in the village spoke of the expanded set of choices that her community’s location offered her. “During the harvest, I can sell crops to either country. Things like clothes and other assorted goods are cheaper here compared to
other areas in Bukoba Rural District. A lot of people are seen coming here to
purchase these goods. This gives me the feeling that in other places such goods
are expensive, though I have never been there to compare.”
As the crow flies, Ntogo is not far away from Kamsoni. It is by Lake Victoria, also close to the Ugandan border. The location offers residents some
advantages: a large majority of them depend on fishing as a source of income
and also engage in cross-border trade. However, residents have mixed opinions
on the benefits of being so close to the lake. A man explained, “We get fish
188
Success from the Bottom Up
from the lake, which is delicious food. But the lake is also hindering our progress, because Ugandan leaders are not visiting us regularly. Tanzanian leaders
do not care about us, because for them we are at a location in Uganda.”
Unlike the good tarmac road serving Kamsoni, a dirt road leads to Ntogo.
It ends abruptly at a swampy area prone to flooding, near the outlet of the Kagera river into Lake Victoria. From there the only way to travel on to Uganda is
in small boats. A respondent from the village lamented, “If the road connected
us to Uganda directly, say in the absence of the lake, transport and business
with Uganda would be easier. Now traveling to Uganda involves engine and
rowboats to cross the lake, but crossing the lake in a rowboat is risky.”
The importance of roads is reflected in the growth and mobility patterns
of the two clusters. In Kamsoni, it was possible to move up even from the
bottom step on the ladder by dint of one’s initiative and hard work. “You do
not need capital to grow; being trustworthy is more important,” commented
one respondent in Kamsoni. The influx of money through trade created
opportunities for new income-generating occupations such as brewing and
distilling, running small shops, and changing money, which in turn reduced
dependence on agriculture and initial wealth. Traders brought in new ideas,
exposing people to life outside the village.
In contrast, agriculture was the only way out of poverty in Ntogo. Those
with insufficient land, occupying the bottom three steps of the village ladder
in 1993, found it difficult to move up. Most people who had been at step 1
in 1993 were reported to have died. The few who survived had stayed at the
bottom step over the past 10 years. The discussion group stated that the only
reason these step 1 people were even alive was that they had been helped by a
charitable organization. Of those who had been at step 2 in 1993, most were
reported to have either fallen further down or stagnated. It was only at step
3 and up that some people—although a minority—had risen through their
own efforts, combined with support from the government.
The important effect of location for moving out of poverty emerges in
many other study regions as well. Poor women and men with low initial
wealth in India, for instance, find it difficult to access markets, get information on government programs, and move up if they live in communities far
from the district headquarters. Displaced households in Colombia find it
doubly hard to move out of poverty if they ended up in a remote barrio, far
removed from jobs and services in the city centers. Those who resettled in
the El Gorrión barrio, for instance, rued their inability to find work there.
Given the scant employment opportunities, a job applicant’s characteristics
like age, appearance, and lack of references become cause for discrimination.
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
189
Job training sessions take place in the city center, making it difficult for El
Gorrión residents to participate.4
In sum, we found that initial household conditions matter less when
communities are well connected and when economic opportunity sets
expand. When the economy is booming and buzzing, who you are and where
you start becomes less important. We also found that there is less discrimination and greater tolerance in more connected regions (see chapter 6).
Rich and Poor in the Marketplace
The rich have more power. They have power to control the local market
price.
—Discussion group in Somrampi, Cambodia
Even in favorable locations where people have physical access to markets
and livelihood opportunities, it can be very difficult for poor people to use
these opportunities to move up.
In the village of Somrampi, Cambodia, a majority of households grow
rice for their own consumption. But the soil is not very fertile, the crop is
entirely rainfed, and less than 10 percent of growers can produce enough rice
to feed their families. As a result, about 85 percent of the households in the
village also engage in ocean fishing for fish, shrimp, crabs, and small marine
creatures such as snail eggs. The export market for these products has been
expanding since the 1990s. Our team met with a group of elderly people in
the village who served as key informants about livelihoods in Somrampi. Of
fishing, they said, “It is our breath of life here.”
But poor fisherwomen and fishermen in Somrampi are not able to
exploit the potential of fishing as readily as the richer ones, some of whom
are the big fish traders in the village. Poor villagers recognize the success of
those who have used fishing to move out of poverty, and they long to emulate them. But they face many obstacles, beginning with their lack of assets.
Most poor households do not have boats or the necessary fishing equipment
or the money to buy them. Some work for those who do have boats, earning
just enough for daily survival. Others collect crabs along the shore. A few
poor people, especially in households where no male adult is present, buy
crabs from the village market and pick them at home so they can sell the
crabmeat.
Even when they have products to sell, poorer households in the village
face hurdles in markets and those imposed by the government, a function
190
Success from the Bottom Up
of the power structures in Somrampi. Those who manage to overcome these
obstacles usually have a personal connection to the traders or to the government officials who control fishing. A group of households that had fallen
into poverty explained their disadvantage:
Rich middlemen who buy crabmeat and sell it at the Kampot market are
also people who have the ability to control economic opportunity in this
village. As of now, there are three middlemen in Somrampi village, and
all of them are classified rich and have multiple business activities. The
price of crab depends on these middlemen. If they give us 10,000 riels per
kilogram of crab meat, it’s okay, and if they give us only 8,000 riels for the
same weight it’s also okay. They can help us, and they can also cause us
problems by reducing the price. We are so poor, and we don’t have enough
productive assets such as fishing tools, agriculture tools, and so forth;
hence we have to borrow money from them to buy all these instruments.
Because we borrow money from them, when we get something from the
sea such as marine fish, crabs, and shrimp, we have to sell to them at
locally set prices. There is no choice for us to select our buyers according to
what we want.
They add as an afterthought, “If we think deeply, prices are different
between those offered by middlemen in the village and prices in the market.
But the difference is acceptable because we earn very little output from time
to time, so if we go to sell it in the market, we have to spend for motor taxi
and time of selling there.”
Those who have escaped poverty in Somrampi have often been able to
exploit their personal connections to negotiate a better deal for themselves.
A group of women told one person’s story:
Mr. Kounn was poor 10 or 12 years ago, but now he is one of the best off
in the village. He dared to take risks in raising crabs, though he did not
have any money in the beginning. Around the early 1990s, he contacted
some traders whom he knew in Phnom Penh and borrowed thousands of
dollars for this business. He also had another job: renting other people’s
lands for collecting oyster skin for pearls. He would sell a sack of such skin
for a dollar. For a piece of land that he rented for 3 damloeung of gold, he
could make 20–30 damloeung of gold from oyster skin. He could do that
because he knew some traders and where to sell the oyster skins. How can
poor people like us do the same thing as him? We do not know any traders or persons whom we can make a deal with like Kounn or high-ranking
officials that can help facilitate such businesses. We are too small to do
things like Kounn. That’s why our living conditions remained the same
over the past 10 years.
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
191
Corruption on the part of local authorities also favors the rich and thwarts
the efforts of the poor. Some fishermen in the village use kraleng tang, a very
fine fishing net, to catch small marine creatures. The use of the net is illegal
and carries harsh penalties, but well-connected households manage to avoid
the fine. Even though staff members of the government fisheries department
monitor the village once or twice a month, “Those engaged in the illegal practices have good connections with the fishing authority . . . and can, therefore,
continue to operate without any concern.” If poor people try to use the illegal
net, the hand of the law comes down hard. “If the fishery authorities arrest
us, we dare not argue against them, but just pay the money according to what
they demand,” said a discussion group of women. “If we do not pay them,
we cannot get our nets back. It’s difficult to make any complaint to the court
without any corruption.”
The police apparently work hand in glove with the more powerful,
restricting opportunities for the powerless. “The police demand money at
many checkpoints along the road,” continued the women. “People have no
power to make any complaint. Even if they do, no one listens to them.” A
female trader in the village confirms, “They say they are the police and/or
fishing authority, but when there are marine robberies and then we report to
them for intervention, they say it is beyond their responsibility and try not to
listen to us. We don’t know what their roles really are.”
The women concluded by reflecting on how some people in their community and not others had been able to use fishing to move out of poverty.
“The poor are normally the followers. They have no savings, so they have
to take time to carefully observe others’ success first. But when they step in,
then there are many people already in the business while demand has not
increased. In 1993 we were not so different. At that time, we all had around
5 plonn [half a hectare] of rice land that was given by the government. We
were about the same. There is now a huge difference. The rich are reaching for
the clouds, and the poor are deepening under the earthworms’ shelter. The
haves lend out money and make a profit, whereas the have-nots get worse off
and sooner or later sell out all their land.”
This narrative from Cambodia is just one story, but it resonates with
the message that emerged from countless visits to all the countries in our
sample: poor people are not able to access markets on an equal footing with
the rich.
Economic inequality is the most predominant axis of difference. Poor
people are aware that they get unfair prices for their produce, but given their
small scale of operations and neediness, they have little bargaining power.
192
Success from the Bottom Up
They remain dependent on rich traders, who bail them out in times of distress but also exploit them. Poor rice farmers in Chakboeng, Cambodia,
reported, “They [rich traders] purchase rice from us farmers at the same low
price. We have limited options to sell our produce. It is hard to say that they
put pressure on us, because many of us normally seek their help to buy farm
inputs on credit. We can sell our rice to whomever we prefer, but in the end
they will not listen to us when we need help from them.”
Besides inequality due to wealth, our study respondents also perceive
inequalities based on political connections and caste membership. In our
sampled communities in India, for instance, one needs to pull strings in order
to gain access to government employment programs and licenses. Evidence
from communities in Uttar Pradesh suggests that political leaders manipulate
government economic schemes to benefit households from their own caste
or religious affiliation. In the village of Darogapur, Uttar Pradesh, the lowercaste groups are stuck in low-wage occupations like hand-rolling cigarettes
and doing manual labor. The rich often do not pay them for work performed
in their fields. Religious and caste divisions also affect business opportunities
in the village. According to a focus group of young girls, “If a Muslim opens
a shop of edibles, then the Hindus do not eat anything at that shop. Among
Hindus too, if a Harijan [Dalit or untouchable] opens a shop, then the Muslims, Brahmins, and people of other castes do not eat anything at that shop.”
Ethnic and religious identities are also important for accessing opportunities during or after civil conflicts. The conflict between Christians and
Muslims in Lupotogo, a community in North Maluku, Indonesia, meant
that Basrum, a Muslim resident of the village, could not work any longer
in the nearby port area because many of the laborers working there were
Christians.
Fair Access to Markets: Is the Hand Really Invisible?
In The Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith (1776) famously alluded to the power
of the market as the “invisible hand”:
Every individual . . . neither intends to promote the public interest, nor
knows how much he is promoting it. . . . He intends only his own gain,
and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention. Nor is it always the worse
for the society that it was no part of it. By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really
intends to promote it.
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
193
Smith’s invisible hand, in modern contexts, roughly translates into
decentralized market economies where markets are free from government
controls and where private buyers and sellers can participate on a fair and
equal footing. Fair prices are supposed to be set purely by the impartial forces
of demand and supply.
But Adam Smith also knew that participants in real markets would organize with a visible hand to grab whatever they could: “People of the same trade
seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion, but the conversation ends
in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise prices.” Our data
suggest exactly such elite collusion. Poor producers and consumers in these
countries lament that liberalization, rather than bringing fair prices set by supply and demand, has created rigged markets where the rich use their power to
tilt both prices and scales in their favor. Poor people find themselves disproportionately affected by market changes, whether an increase in fertilizer costs
in Senegal or Malawi or a fall in the price of coffee in Tanzania or tobacco in
Indonesia. Moreover, even in liberalized and supposedly free markets, poor
people find their efforts to participate further hampered by government intrusion that often seems to end up reinforcing the unfair market advantage of the
rich and well connected.
Poor people in free markets: Problems of scale, influence,
and resilience
Competition from big shops such as supermarkets that are able to produce
on large scale and at lower cost means that a small retailer is not able to
offer the customer attractive prices.
—Discussion with men, El Mirador, Colombia
If a rich person sees one of his businesses fail, there are still others that can
help him bounce back.
—Sotero, a 51-year-old man, Newsib, Philippines
Consider a small farmer in Malawi—let us call him Charles—who has a
maize farm. Let us assume that his annual production of maize is about 500
kilograms. The production requires about 50 kg of fertilizer. Assume now
that Charles sells his maize for MK5 (5 Malawi kwacha) per kilogram for a
total of MK2,500, and the fertilizer costs him MK750, resulting in a profit of
MK1,750. Now consider Richard, a large landowner who lives in the same
village as Charles. Richard’s annual maize production is 5,000 kg. Because
he has links with big traders in the market, he can sell his maize for MK7 per
194
Success from the Bottom Up
kilogram. Richard makes MK35,000 in sales and spends MK7,500 on fertilizer, resulting in a profit of MK27,500.
Let us now suppose that over the next two years, fertilizer prices increase
from MK750 to MK1,500 for a 50 kg bag. Charles’s profit drops to MK1,000
and Richard’s to MK20,000, as long as the price of maize and the productive
of their farms remain unchanged. In another two years, fertilizer prices rise
still more to MK3,500 per bag. Charles is now deep into losses, but Richard
is still solvent, although just barely.
The example illustrates three problems that poor producers and consumers face while selling or buying in free markets. The first is a problem of
scale. Poor people buy and sell in small quantities. Thus even a small change
in fixed costs—in the price of inputs, say, or the cost of transportation—has
a much higher impact on them. If the charges of commuting between the
village and an outlying market double, a small farmer will think twice about
taking her one basket of bananas and traveling to the market, even though
she knows her bananas would fetch a better price there than in the village.
Her neighbor, who has a huge banana farm and can afford to hire a truck
to take his produce to the market, and who expects to sell many baskets of
bananas while there, may still make the trip.
Small scale, in turn, leads to the other two problems—those of influence and resilience. In the above example, Richard is able to charge MK7 per
kilogram for his maize, 2 kwacha more than the price charged by Charles.
Why? Because Richard produces 10 times more maize than Charles and consequently has the influence and bargaining position to negotiate for a higher
price with maize buyers. Richard also has resilience. Even after fertilizer prices
increase fivefold, he is able to avoid losses without increasing the rate he
charges for his maize. Charles, a smaller farmer, is disproportionately affected
by the change in fertilizer prices and goes under relatively quickly.
The exorbitant price and unavailability of fertilizer was cited as a common reason for falling down or being unable to move out of poverty in our
sample sites in Malawi. At the time of the survey, some communities reported
that fertilizer cost as much as MK4,000 for a 50 kg bag on the black market.
“Our soils are disabled. They need fertilizer,” said a discussion group of men
in Bamlozi. “People really worked hard in their gardens, but what they harvested was so little that they could not afford fertilizer.”
Poor people’s lack of influence in the marketplace was also evident in
Ruvuma, Tanzania, where the coffee industry was in distress. After liberalization of the coffee market, the selling price of coffee was usually set by
wholesale traders. The price of coffee fell while the price of fertilizer increased
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
195
more than fourfold between 1995 and 2005. Across our study of communities in the region, small coffee producers spoke of their lack of control over
coffee prices. In Chiwolo, farmer Jyazint declared, “Do we see a free market
after liberalization or a disorganized market? The traders and buyers have
killed the coffee industry in our community. Traders are not for the interest of
farmers, nor do they think of committing some of their resources to improve
the quality of coffee so that they will be able to buy good coffee during the
successive crop seasons.” The plight of small coffee producers was similar in
other communities in Ruvuma. In Ngimyoni, where 75 percent of all households cultivated coffee, liberalization led to an initial increase in coffee prices
but also to increased price volatility. Smaller farmers, who had been protected
from a rise in the price of inputs by state subsidies, were no longer shielded,
as the private traders offered no protective mechanism in times when fertilizer prices rose or coffee prices dropped.
To make matters worse, the big coffee traders in Ngimyoni reportedly
used unfair practices like fraudulent scales that helped them buy more coffee
for less money. They engaged in a practice known locally as masomba, meaning
sunflower (because the coffee became as weightless as a sunflower). A plastic
container known as a dumla, which when full contains 2 kg of dried coffee
beans, was equated to only 1 kg of coffee by the agents. Using the dumla,
traders would overfill a 50 kg bag of coffee so much that it weighed at least
60 kg. The farmer was paid for only 50 kg, while the agent got 10 kg free.
Even though the government abolished masomba in 2001, better-off villagers still exploit poor women and men by making loans to them, in cash
or in kind. Before handing over the money or goods, the lender may force
the borrower to sign an agreement attesting that he or she has borrowed
more money or materials than is actually the case. For instance, for a loan
of 10,000 Tanzanian shillings (T Sh), the borrower may be forced to attest
that she or he had borrowed T Sh 30,000—three times the actual amount.
Yokim, a 48-year-old man, spoke of his experience. “I borrowed a bull worth
T Sh 50,000 for the ceremony to end the mourning period of my late mother,
but I had to pay T Sh 80,000 three months later.” Yokim had been above the
community’s perception of a poverty line, but he fell into poverty during the
study period.
Some of the communities in Kagera, Tanzania, have given up coffee
farming entirely. The fall in the price of coffee was dramatic over the five
years between 1995 and 2000, as much as 90 percent in some communities.
In Nyakahora in Kagera, women said they could no longer plan for their
income. “Much as we sell coffee, we are not happy. And then coffee until
196
Success from the Bottom Up
when? After all, it is a men’s business. We need alternatives for women too!”
At this point our field investigator asked what would happen if the prices
of coffee did not go up in the next 10 years. “Nothing,” the women replied.
“Actually, we have even uprooted a good number of coffee plants.”
Poor cultivators across study regions—with their one bag of coffee,
tobacco, groundnuts, or maize—find themselves in no position to negotiate
with bigger buyers. In Biralipara, Assam, a group of men pointed out, “The
number of farmers has increased, and there is only one market. There are
more people who come to the market to sell than to buy. Knowing this, traders buy the goods at low prices.” Women in Afghanistan have few options for
selling dresses that they have stitched at home. They cannot go to the local
bazaar and have to rely on traders to collect and sell their products. Khori
Gul, a tailor in Nasher Khan, Nangarhar, reasoned, “The price we get for one
dress is not very fair. We make one dress in three or four days, and the price
we get is around 300 Afghanis [about US$6]. But when it goes to market, the
shopkeepers sell that dress for 1,800 Afghanis [US$36].”
Farmers know that their produce might fetch a better price if they take it
to market themselves, but they have to consider the high costs of transportation. Even small increases in charges to transport produce to markets hurt
small producers. Dorothea, a village farmer in Ruvuma, explained, “Farmers
fail to trade in Mbinga town because of lack of reliable transport. One trip to
Mbinga per person is 6,000 shillings plus 2,000 shillings per bag of maize of
90–100 kilograms. Farmers fear the expenses involved and the unreliability
and uncertainty of the market. If you take your maize to Mbinga and find the
selling price is low or there are no customers, what would you do?”
Another problem lies in competing with large-scale manufacturers
or imported goods sold in the supermarkets. “If the government bans the
import of fruits and cereals from Iran, Pakistan, and China, farmers can move
up, because right now all kinds of fruit come from Iran and we cannot compete with them,” said Sher Ahmad, a farmer in Zakwak Ulya, Herat, Afghanistan. For fruits and vegetables, the competition from foreign countries also
depends on the exchange rate. Several farmers our field team met in Herat
complained that they have to sell their products at an unprofitable price. A
few farmers have started adding value to the products to close the gap; for
instance, women in Zakwak Ulya turn figs into jam. But among small producers, such value addition is typically done on too small a scale to yield
significant returns.
As in Afghanistan, small shopkeepers in the barrios of Colombia cannot
keep pace with the products introduced in local supermarkets. In El Mirador,
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
197
a local supermarket called El Potrerillo has been a source of employment in
the community, but it has also displaced many small businesses. The closure of businesses is also attributed to the influx of foreign goods that have
replaced domestically produced goods, a problem that at least one respondent blamed on globalization. On the other hand, in El Gorrión, where there
is no supermarket, a focus group of men acknowledged that buyers go outside the community to find supermarkets “in order to save that little bit, even
if it is just 50 pesos.” Some small shopkeepers in the community have been
forced to close down as they can no longer afford to sell cheaply.
Disadvantaged by their small scale and lack of market clout, poor producers often spiral downward into economic distress that they are ill equipped to
weather. Botisi, a 55-year-old man in Matdombo, Malawi, stared at his empty
granary with grief. “Look at my harvest,” he told our investigator. “It is only
four bags—just enough for me and my family. When I get fertilizer, I split the
bag into two—half for the maize garden and the other half for the tobacco
garden. It is not enough. I don’t have any livestock, not even chickens. My
granary is empty, and this is just the beginning of the year.”
Botisi and several other Malawian farmers who had fallen into poverty
over the study period blamed the rise in fertilizer prices in large part for their
downfall. Some took desperate measures to remain solvent. They begged
their friends for fertilizer, tried growing other crops that were not fertilizerintensive, even undertook ganyu (daily wage labor) to feed their hungry children. Yet these measures were seldom enough.
In Guluteza, Malawi, men described how those who are better off want
to lend fertilizers to their friends. “But then another person tells them,
‘Do not dare give him fertilizer; he is a crook and he will not give it back.’”
Some households have shifted from maize to other crops like vegetables
or groundnuts that require less fertilizer. In Zokwaza, women started cultivating groundnuts as a cash crop. Local people noticed that the women
were making more money, and soon a majority of households in the village
started farming groundnuts. Due to the increase in the number of people
going to sell groundnuts in the nearby market, bus services to the market at
first improved. Eventually, however, the government-operated bus services
stopped, and more private transporters entered the area, wanting to cash in.
A woman farming groundnuts in the village explained how this change had
affected her margins. “Now, if one is using the matola [private transport], they
are more expensive. People pay 250 kwacha for transporting a bag of groundnuts. In the past, on the government buses, we could even get katundu boys
who would assist passengers loading and off-loading their goods on the bus.
198
Success from the Bottom Up
But now people have to incur all these costs, even paying those who assist
them in putting their luggage on the bus.”
Stretched thin, several small farmers in our study communities in Malawi
have taken up ganyu. But with the rise in the number of households willing
to do ganyu, not many people are actually able to find work. In the community of Lumyana, a men’s discussion group said, “Poverty is just rampant
here. People who can afford to hire ganyu workers are just three. Yet there are
over a hundred people who are looking for ganyu.”
It doesn’t help small farmers that prices of other essential goods in
Malawi have increased with devaluation of the currency over the years. “Necessary commodities are becoming more and more expensive,” said one participant in a discussion group in Bamlozi. “It is as though you keep a certain
amount of money to buy an item the following day, but then you are told
that the money is not sufficient to buy that commodity because its price
has increased.” Food prices are the most severely affected. As in Bamlozi,
households in Matdombo were facing food scarcity at the time of the field
team’s visit. “A farmer struggles to grow crops like tobacco amidst high prices
of fertilizer. But when it comes to selling these crops, he finds that the prices
have gone down. People depend on these businesses to buy food, soap, salt,
and sugar. And because they are small, they easily suffocate. It is very easy to eat
up the little capital you have due to food insecurity at home.”
This is not to say that currency devaluation or ending general fertilizer
subsidies are not at times necessary measures in difficult macroeconomic
situations—only that the transitions are so much more difficult for the poor
to accommodate. When relative prices change, this eliminates some opportunities and opens others. But people must be able to take advantage of these
new opportunities if they are to avoid pain. When people are already on the
margins, as poor women and men often are, the resilience necessary for reallocation isn’t there.
How government rules and regulations restrict opportunity
When people think of investing their money, they see only annoyances and
hassles ahead.
—Discussion group in Kagera, Tanzania
Even in supposedly the freest of markets, our study found, governments
intervene in various ways seemingly designed to appease and reward the
more powerful interest groups. We discuss here three primary ways in which
government intervention in markets can restrict economic opportunities for
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
199
the poor: through licensing of livelihoods and occupations, through rules
and regulations around use of common property resources, and through allocation of benefits like jobs, credit, and inputs for agriculture.
Licensing. Governments can interfere in households’ ability to expand
their portfolio of activities into business. According to the World Bank’s
Doing Business report for 2008, acquiring licenses for a business in India is
not easy. It takes 20 procedures and 224 days on average—and costs over five
times the annual income per capita (World Bank 2007).
In the Colombian barrios, small business owners have to pay a vacuna,
an illegal but ubiquitous tax. Poor people there and in other study sites complained that even small-scale activities like hawking and peddling require
licenses from the local government—licenses that are selectively awarded. In
the barrios the field teams visited in Colombia, for example, there are restrictions on permits for vending in the city center. “Getting a permit is tough,”
said a group of women in Villa Rosa. “You must have contacts and money.
For fruit vendors, it is not a problem in the barrio, but they [the local government] don’t let them sell in the city center. The vendors need a permit to
sell, and to get the permit one has to speak to the syndicate of vendors and
the municipality and have 200,000 pesos to give for the permit. We need the
freedom to work.” Permits for small businesses are also reportedly difficult
to come by in some barangays in the Bukidnon region of Philippines. In
Kitlong, the women reported that the zubirri, a local leader, distributes permits and loans “only to those who already have big businesses. That’s unfair
to those like us who want to put up a business.”
Barriers around use of common property resources. Many poor people live
by selling firewood that they gather from a nearby forest or fish they catch
in a nearby lake. They thus depend for their survival on common property
resources to which they have no secure access or tenure rights. Especially with
respect to forest resources, government policies and regulatory frameworks
often create barriers for poor women and men who live from these resources
(Molnar, White, and Khare 2008). In Central and West Africa, large areas have
been designated as community forest but only a fraction of this land has been
allocated to communities for their use (CIFOR 2005).
In our study, we found that communities in poor rural areas of Cambodia and Africa experience such barriers intensely. Villagers in Kdadaum and Koh
Phong, Cambodia, are afraid of forestry authorities for the fines they charge.
“Sometimes we meet them while carrying wood and we have to spend 200,000
riels [US$50] to not be arrested. If we don’t, then our cart is kept at the provincial office, and we are put in custody.” In Lumyana, Malawi, a recent ban on
200
Success from the Bottom Up
charcoal burning along with restrictions on access to a nearby forest reserve has
hurt the livelihoods of the poorest villagers. And in Kamsoni, Kagera, Tanzania,
poor households that had regularly visited a nearby forest to gather firewood,
timber, and materials for weaving mats lost their livelihoods when the government closed the forest to prevent deforestation. A man in the village said, “It is
now scary that all guys who were laborers in the forest are turning into bandits.
Those who owned the timber-cutting projects are now competing for money
changing.”
Rigged distribution of jobs and government schemes. Finally, governments
can intervene positively by offering poor women and men credit and other
inputs at subsidized rates, which can give them the initial impetus to produce
and compete in markets. Or they can offer them employment opportunities in public work programs and elsewhere that guarantee precious regular
income. While we found evidence of both types of assistance, it didn’t always
result in the desired outcomes. Stratification along social and economic lines
in communities usually led to distribution of economic opportunities offered
by local governments among a privileged few.
Though no longer a concern at the time of the survey, households in
Indonesia reported that government jobs during President Suharto’s regime
had been allocated along party lines. “At that time if you were looking for
work, you were questioned. If you were an NU person [supporting the opposition party], you weren’t hired, but if you were a Golkar person [a ruling
party supporter], you were,” reported a woman in Patobako, East Java. In
some communities in Malawi, it was possible to receive inputs such as seeds
and fertilizers on loan from the government. But our respondents spoke of
considerable inequality in access. “We can register our names with the agricultural adviser in order to get fertilizers and maize seeds on loan,” said a group
of men in Matdombo. “But after the exercise someone can sneak around and
influence the adviser to delete some of our names, saying that we are very
poor and would not pay back the loan at the end of the growing season. This
causes inequality since some people can get more fertilizer while others like
the poor cannot get anything and remain in poverty.”
Discretionary behavior on the part of the local government was commonly seen in the Indian study communities that are divided along caste, religious, and political lines. Benefits of government schemes for credit, jobs, and
housing are perceived to accrue to those who belong to the ruling party’s caste
or religion. Even so-called public goods are not entirely free from capture.
Infrastructure projects, for example, are reportedly allotted to contractors close
to the local panchayat, often resulting in poor construction quality. A group of
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
201
women our team interviewed in Langpuria, Assam, spoke of bribe taking in
their village. “The contractors pocket 95 percent of the amount sanctioned for
such works and spend only 5 percent of the amount for development,” they
said. “They construct bamboo bridges in place of concrete roads.”
Programs that do help are usually either those that result in the provision
of some quasi-public goods, like roads or irrigation works, that can benefit
everyone, or programs that are specifically targeted toward poor people. But
even targeted subsidies and transfers are often distributed discriminately—
and not necessarily to those most in need.
In sum, our evidence suggests a very visible distortion of the market in
favor of dominant groups and against poor people. Sometimes there is a
deliberate attempt by the elite to capture a larger share of the gains available, for example through the practice of masomba. Poor people often lack
the scale, influence, and resilience needed to get a toehold in markets and to
negotiate a better return for their produce. In some cases, this problem has
been an inadvertent outcome of efforts by governments to open up markets,
as these efforts sometimes result in markets with little competition and greater
volatility of input and output prices.
How Does One Expand Opportunities and Unrig Markets?
Markets and government rules about markets could be unrigged and opportunity sets expanded for all. Although each local situation is different and
requires different interventions, poor people in our study suggested five general approaches that could help: construction of roads; promotion of access
to new markets; investments in inputs like water, electricity, and telecommunications; provision of more credit; and easing of access to land, land titles,
and business licenses. In all these cases, the manner in which government
services are delivered—whether the government is responsive and fair to all,
or corrupt and captured by a few—can either enhance opportunities or curb
them. Economic organizations of poor people, whether self-help groups or
associations, also can help them boost their bargaining power in markets.
This important issue is discussed in detail in chapter 7.
Roads: Making crucial connections
Earlier, people would cross the river with their vegetables by a ferry boat.
The bridge has been very helpful for them. Now a truck can directly go to
the gardens. There has been a vegetable revolution in the village.
—Discussion with key informants, Chamgotia, Bangladesh
202
Success from the Bottom Up
In his bestseller The Tipping Point, Malcolm Gladwell (2000) spoke of the
pivotal role of “connectors”: individuals who “act as conduits . . . helping to
engender connections, relationships and ‘cross-fertilization’ that otherwise
might not have occurred.” Although Gladwell was talking about human connectors, our data suggest that roads are among the few policy tools that can
serve as connectors in regions where poor people live. They create links between
people in remote rural areas and the outside world, and between small farmers
and traders looking for a good crop. They promote cross-fertilization of ideas—
about planting new seeds, using new technologies, producing new products to
meet new demands. Moreover, unlike Gladwell’s connectors, roads require no
prior knowledge or personal relationship for change to spread. Roads are the
most impersonal mechanism that makes a difference, and almost universally so,
across our sample of communities in different study contexts.
Roads serve as catalysts for new occupations. Villages in the study sites
in Cambodia with good roads are generally more dynamic, with thriving
small businesses. In Chakboeng, a village that received a road in 2000, a
group of young men described the change: “The number of village shops
selling groceries, secondhand or new dresses, and household commodities
has increased remarkably since 2000.” In Chamgotia, Bangladesh, a newly
constructed bridge on a nearby river and an 11-kilometer tarmac road have
changed the lives of about 120 families in the village who used to depend
on daily wage labor for a living. They now work as van drivers and rickshaw
pullers, earning much more than before. Lower transport costs have also considerably lowered the costs of selling for those cultivating rice and vegetables
in the village. As in Kagera, Tanzania, farmers in Chamgotia can easily transport their produce to nearby towns on the road instead of carrying it on their
heads or ferrying it by boat across the river.
Finally, roads save time on travel. This time can then be spent on other
economic activities, leading to diversification of income sources and mobility. In Shazimir, a community near Kabul in Afghanistan, our respondents
discussed how the newly constructed road was helping them. “You know
what they say: Time is gold. Shopkeepers very frequently lost time on the way
to the city center. Thanks to this road, they save at least half an hour to go to
the bazaar. It took usually one hour; now it takes 30 minutes.”
Communities not connected to passable roads face severe challenges. In
Langpuria, Assam, people spoke of destroying their own crops because buyers cannot reach them. Women in the village lamented, “Vyaparis [businessmen] from nearby towns do not come to buy our produce because of the bad
communication system. As a result we are not getting the expected price for
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
203
our produce. Some cultivators are forced to damage their produce themselves
because of nonavailability of customers. No one is ready to buy vegetables
even at 20 paisa [less than 1 cent] per kilogram.” In an isolated village in
Kagera, Tanzania, a bunch of bananas sells for only half as much as it would
fetch in a nearby trading center. But the only way to reach the trading center
is on foot. Our respondents noted, “Although this trading center is only 4
kilometers away, the path going there is very steep and traverses a cliff, making transport of bunches of banana on foot very difficult.”
In addition to facilitating economic opportunities, roads are also seen to
be agents of small but definite social changes. They make it easier to reach hospitals and schools. Young girls who were earlier wary of traveling long distances
to learn said they are now enrolling in school. Women in communities with
roads spoke of how they can now frequent markets and return home in a timely
manner. A 32-year-old woman in Kamsoni, Kagera, praised the new tarmac road
as she can now “go to town without informing my husband because I am sure
of coming back and cooking, even before the children return from school.” At
times, the very presence of a road elevates the status of those living in the village.
A group of men in Rahamat, a village in rural Uttar Pradesh, noted that cars can
now easily reach their village for social ceremonies like marriages. “Having a
road has improved the social status of the villagers,” they said.
In addition to roads connecting communities to the outside world, paved
roads within villages are also important. In India, our respondents described
how muddy earthen tracks in their villages are health hazards and barriers
to movement. Interviewees in Darogapur felt that the brick soling of tracks
within the village has helped. “[Earlier] there was mud in the rainy season.
It was difficult for the animals to move. People had to carry their crops and
fodder for animals on their heads, and they were always fearful of slipping.
After brick soling, the road has become wider and the streets of the village
are now dry. Now motorbikes, bicycles, and jeeps can easily come into the
village. People can easily carry their can of milk on their bicycle and go to the
market. There is prosperity in the village.”
Markets: Engines of change
During the season we sell our fruits at a very cheap price and in a very
short time because we don’t have cold storage to keep them and we can’t
reach different cities in Afghanistan. The lack of access to market will
cause [farmers] to fail.
—Discussion with men, Zakwak Ulya, Herat, Afghanistan
204
Success from the Bottom Up
In today’s seamless, borderless world markets, competition from all parts
of the world determines metal, bullion, and stock prices. But in small, rural
communities such as those in our sample, the physical marketplace remains
the focus of exchange. In his Principles of Economics, Alfred Marshall (1890)
argued that small neighborhood markets were best suited to certain types of
trade—“things which must be made to order to suit particular individuals,
such as well-fitting clothes; and perishable and bulky goods, such as fresh
vegetables, which can seldom be profitably carried long distances.” Men and
women in our communities in some ways justify Marshall’s rationale for the
local market. They can barely carry crops like bananas profitably over long
distances to a big, wholesale market, so they depend on their local market
to sustain sales.
The establishment of a new marketplace, however small, is considered a harbinger of increased economic opportunities within a community. Across our sample, nearly 28 percent of communities where people
believed that economic opportunities had improved over the study period
also reported the presence of a daily or weekly market. In contrast, only
about 9 percent of communities where economic opportunities had supposedly contracted over the same period had a market. Having a market
within a community implies multiple benefits. It provides space for people
to set up their own shops, allowing them to diversify and increase their
sources of income. It usually leads to better returns for farmers and small
traders, who no longer have to bear the heavy costs of transportation to
distant markets. And it spurs consumer dynamism within the community,
creating virtuous circles in which new shops open to satisfy increasing
demand.
In Purani village, Uttar Pradesh, a weekly market was set up in 1995. It
functions every Wednesday and Saturday, and traders looking to buy agricultural produce from farmers in Purani visit the market on those two days.
Farmers who previously were forced to carry their produce long distances
to district markets now only need to display samples of their wares. Only
when satisfied with the price do they invite the traders to collect the crop
from their fields. A men’s discussion group on livelihoods explained, “The
difference is that earlier [when they took their crop to distant markets], the
traders paid us as per their choice. As we had to carry the crop all the way,
we did not want to carry it back, so we sold it at whatever price we received.
Now there are traders in the village itself. We show a sample of the yield to
them, and if we like the rates we sell it to them and they carry the product
from our houses.”
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
205
Support to production: Water, electricity, telephones, and farm inputs
Now we can keep the vegetables we buy at the weekly souk [market] for
the entire week. We can prepare fresh salads, as they do in cities. We have
now begun to live as human beings instead of living to the rhythm of the
hens—going to bed early and rising early.
—A man in Lamraab, Morocco, on benefits of receiving electricity
Farming is still our main source of income. But we recently added another
income-generating business like e-load and cell phone charging. It helped
us a lot because it is where we get the money to buy formula milk for our
only child. My wife also helped by selling cooked food in the school.
—Mohama, a 30-year-old chronic poor man, Glikati, Philippines
Besides roads and markets, creation of infrastructure such as assured
water supply, electricity, and telephone networks can greatly enhance economic opportunities within communities. Equally important is the provision
of affordable inputs and technical support for farming.
Water. Water is a crucial resource, especially since agriculture is the main
source of livelihood in nearly 94 percent of the communities where we could
gather community-level data. Communities that depend on the rains for
farming are at a disadvantage compared to communities where permanent
irrigation structures ensure a year-round water supply. Fifty-nine percent of
communities that reported an improvement in economic opportunities also
reported improved availability of irrigation inputs. In comparison, only 32
percent of communities where economic opportunities had narrowed over
the study period reported an improvement in irrigation facilities.
Two communities in West Bengal illustrate the difference. A majority of
the population of both villages is engaged in the cultivation of rice. However, in one village, Parasya, water is available all year through canals from a
nearby dam. These canals were dug in 1998 through the combined efforts of
the West Bengal irrigation division and the local district council. They were
designed to channel water from the dam to as large an area as possible, and
they have greatly boosted the community’s production of rice, a water-intensive crop. The constant water supply has also helped farmers grow vegetables.
Our team met farmers in the village who identified the system of canals as the
main reason for their prosperity.
Compare this to the scenario in Gutri village. Also dependent on rice
farming, Gutri has the advantage of being close to a river. Yet that does farm-
206
Success from the Bottom Up
ers no good, because no working canals exist to bring water from the river
to their fields. In 1998, people in Gutri asked their local authorities to repair
and further excavate an old canal that had linked fields in the village to the
river and also helped reduce the overflow of water during the rainy season.
The canal had not been reexcavated for a long time and was practically unusable. Despite their pleas, at the time of the survey in 2005, the canal was yet
to be repaired.
Men and women in Gutri described their plight: “Earlier, agriculture was
the way to development. But now it depends on rainwater. Farmers are able
to manage only one crop a year, while years ago we could cultivate two. Farmers are now facing losses due to low yields, as are the agricultural laborers,
because their work is now confined mainly to the sowing and harvesting
period. They get work for only two months in a year. For the rest of the time,
they sit idle. If floods occur in the river, the situation becomes worse. Then
there is no work for even these two months. Moreover, the extra rainwater
does not pass due to blockages in the canal.” The village has four primary
schools and received electricity a year before the survey, but as one of our
respondents said, “For people who cannot afford even two square meals a
day, education means nothing at all. Electricity is of no use to them. The
first important thing for them is to perform work from which they can earn
and get food. The people from the labor class are now almost dying and the
panchayat has not paid any attention to the repair of the canal.”
In Ramili Qali, Afghanistan, a grape-farming community that lost its irrigation structures in the war, villagers judged the reconstruction of the irrigation
siphon in 2005 to be the most positive recent event for the prosperity of the
community. Key informants noted, “When the intake was rebuilt, all our fields
started being irrigated again. Of course, the grapevines did not immediately
regrow and produce, but it allowed our farmers to grow other things, like wheat,
maize, and poppy. Nowadays, the grapevines are growing again. It might take up
to seven years to get back to the level of production we had before the war.”
In contrast, the village of Namdenye in Ruvuma, Tanzania, was suffering a
severe water crisis that villagers described as one of the most important factors
causing a decline in their well-being. The village never had access to tap water,
depending instead on water from shallow wells, most of which were nonoperational at the time of the study team’s visit. The closest river is 27 kilometers away.
The government took steps to address the problem by constructing three shallow wells, but these only worked for two months. Villagers blamed the failure
of the project on poor workmanship: the wells apparently were dug during the
rains when the water table was high, and when the rains ended, they went dry.
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
207
Lack of water constrains prosperity in Namdenye in several ways. Villagers remain dependent on the rains to grow their crops. They cannot build
more permanent, burned-brick houses, as such construction requires a significant amount of water. With no local water supply even for drinking, people risk their lives to fetch water from ponds in a nearby wild game reserve.
Women and girls waste precious productive hours searching for water. When
found, it is often not safe for human use, and the village has seen an increase
in waterborne diseases such as cholera, typhoid, and dysentery.
Electricity. Although less vital for survival than water, electricity is a precious resource for poor women and men. It helps even the poorest set up
small cottage industries at home, something especially useful for women.
Women across our study regions—especially in East Asia, where more villages are electrified—spoke of how they can make pickles, jams, and other
foods at night and sell them in the market the next day.
San Dogon, a barangay in Bukidnon, Philippines, is a good example
of how electricity can have multidimensional impacts on prosperity. Households in the barangay said that the arrival of electricity has opened a number
of new livelihood opportunities for them, such as selling ice candy, which they
stored in their electric refrigerators. Women with electric sewing machines
can earn money sewing at home. Farming, too, received a boost as residents
now operate electric irrigation pumps that ensure a regular supply of water.
One person said, “The residents were overjoyed to see an abundant supply
of water. Our forefathers did not have that opportunity before. It spells the
difference in our lives. Some people are into backyard gardening. They were
able to plant vegetables and flowers even during the dry season because we
are assured of water supply.”
In other study sites too, women spoke of how electricity had eased their
lives. In the remote community of Rancho San Juan, Oaxaca, Mexico, where
livelihood choices are limited, women can weave sombreros at night and earn
some additional money. They exclaimed with delight that they can now get news
over radio and television and grind corn in electric grinders to make tortillas.
Finally, well-lit streets after sunset contribute to better law and order in a
community. Women find it easier to step out of their homes at night. So do
older people, who can walk without fear of falling into ditches or being bitten
by animals and snakes.
Telephones. While electricity is bringing change to barangays in the Philippines, rural villages in Bangladesh are being transformed by cell phones.
Satgailijhara is one of the villages in our study sample that gained from the
construction of a Grameen Phone telephone and telegraph tower. Although
208
Success from the Bottom Up
the tower was only built in 2003, the benefits are already plain to see. Those
who have gained most are small traders looking to start a new business in the
community. Abdul explained the advantages of having a cell phone. “Earlier,
one had to travel a long distance and carry rice and pulses for either selling or
personal consumption. Now one need not travel with goods. Earlier people
spent 200 taka for carrying goods; now they only need to spend 10 taka for
making two phone calls. Those who have poultry farms, for example, need
to make only a few phone calls. The parties would rush to them to take the
delivery of poultry birds.”
A few people in Satgailijhara have opened shops selling mobile phones
and are making good profits. Women have started operating cell phones on
a hire basis, bringing in additional income to their families. For some poor
people, the phones have allowed seamless flows of credit and finance that
were previously difficult to access. Mohammed said, “The Grameen tower
has contributed a lot. When I urgently need money for purchasing land, I
telephone my brother who is working in the city. What a big advantage!”
The brother then wires money via his cell phone to the local bank, which
Mohammed can collect the next morning. Mohammed’s experience corroborates the benefits of mobile banking innovations under way in other developing countries, such as South Africa’s “virtual bank” and Kenya’s M-PESA.
The reduction in transaction costs for wiring money through cell phones—as
Mohammed’s brother did—is dramatic.
In our study, communities that reported an increase in economic opportunities over the study period were also ones where the presence of public
phone networks had more than quadrupled since 1995. By contrast, in the
communities where opportunities had decreased, phone connectivity was
only 1.5 times greater than it had been a decade earlier.
Inputs and technical support for farming. Better agricultural techniques and
access to affordable inputs can make a big difference to agricultural productivity. In 66 percent of the communities that reported an improvement in
economic opportunities, respondents also reported improvement in access
to agricultural inputs. Access to such inputs improved in only 39 percent of
communities where economic opportunities had reportedly decreased.
In villages in Kagera, Tanzania, government officials are credited for
improvements in farming skills and for a shift to production of crops like
tomatoes. Households that have moved out of poverty in both villages are
thankful for the training provided by agricultural extension officers. A mover
in Kamsoni said, “I got advice from a government farmer extension worker
in 1994 on how to produce tomatoes. Afterwards, I have been cultivating
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
209
tomatoes which have contributed to my income. I have managed to keep my
family and build a house.”
The importance of agricultural innovation is evident in our sampled
communities in Uttar Pradesh, West Bengal, and Bangladesh. In the latter two
regions, cultivation of high-yielding varieties of rice has brought dividends
for farmers. The harvest period for these varieties is much smaller, and their
yield is higher.5 In Uttar Pradesh, cultivation of cash crops such as sugarcane
and peppermint is reported to have improved the fortunes of entire villages.
In Shekhapur village in Sitapur district, moving out of poverty is seen to
be a process of gradual accumulation through investment in cultivation of
sugarcane. This investment includes purchase of higher-yielding varieties of
seeds and agricultural equipment. Most movers in sugarcane-growing areas
attempted to add value to their commercial crop by purchasing equipment
(threshers, tractors, and cane crushers) and by sowing high-yielding varieties
of cane.
Credit: Boost to initiative
The organizations themselves are the main obstacles for expanding business activities, because they provide lower amounts of loans. That is why
many people do not become members, though they need the loan. They
need bigger loans.
—Discussion with men, Pirjadi, Bangladesh
While roads, irrigation networks, and markets help open opportunities, obtaining affordable credit is often the key that allows people to take
advantage of these opportunities to start a business or improve their farming.
In Galalolo, a community in North Maluku, Indonesia, farmers who had
benefited from lower interest on formal credit provided under the Kecamatan Development Program summed up: “Having capital means having no
difficulties.”
The importance of credit is reflected in our quantitative data. Communities that rated their economies as strong or very strong at the time of the survey were also more likely to rely on government banks as a source of credit.
Almost 40 percent of the economically strong communities, but only about a
quarter of the economically weak communities, said that government banks
were among the top two sources of credit in their area. Households in local
economies rated weak or very weak were more likely to rely on friends, relatives, and moneylenders than on banks for their financial needs.
210
Success from the Bottom Up
The mere presence of formal credit facilities, however, isn’t enough. For
several reasons, poor people in many communities find it difficult or impossible to obtain adequate loans on good terms from these sources. Figure 5.3
sums up the hurdles poor people face in accessing credit.
One of the first constraints identified by poor people across communities is that the loans offered by different organizations—civil society or the
government—are simply not large enough to be transformative. Despite the
popularity of microfinance, tiny loans seldom allow people to build more
productive, permanent assets, so they remain trapped in low-total-return
activities. Alam, a man in the village of Digbari, Bangladesh, expressed discontent with the size of loans granted by microfinance institutions in his
community. “I think NGOs have been the beneficiaries. What has happened
to the millions they have collected? This is our money. Yet we get only 3,000
taka as loans while they earn millions of taka.”
FIGURE 5.3
Poor entrepreneurs face obstacles in gaining access to credit
Government sources of credit
NGO sources of credit
Bribery, corruption,
tedious paperwork
High interest rate,
strict repayment shedule
FAIRNESS IN ACCESS
Access to information
Access to collateral
Access to connections
LOANS
Consumption, major expenses
Building asssets, business
Policy implication:
Policy implication:
More credit, not less
More credit, not less
Market know-how for
livelihoods
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
211
The tendency is for these small loans to be used not for production but
for daily consumption and pressing household needs. A sudden expense such
as a marriage in the family, a funeral, an illness, or even abject hunger can
force a poor family to use a loan toward nonproductive ends. Across study
regions, households stuck in chronic poverty were far more likely than movers to borrow for regular consumption purposes (figure 5.4).
Under such circumstances, servicing loans becomes a financial drain on
households. In Chanpasha, one of the Bangladesh communities that has witnessed a surge in microcredit, men admitted, “Loan facilities have become
easier than in the past. However, many are taking loans for business but
spending them in unproductive sectors of the family. So they are unable to
repay their loan installments in due time. Loan repayment, therefore, is playing a major role in the increase of their expenditure.”
In Korrapadu, Andhra Pradesh, men and women recognized that the
state-led initiative on self-help groups is providing them with valuable credit.
FIGURE 5.4
A majority of chronic poor borrow for regular consumption purposes
% households that borrowed money in past year
for regular consumption
100
90
87
80
77
72
70
62
60
50
40
29
30
20
31
27
15
10
0
India
Source: Household questionnaire.
Africa
Conflict
Movers
Chronic poor
All
212
Success from the Bottom Up
But they added that the loans only help them cope. “We continue to work
hard. But if an unplanned event happens, we are left with a big problem. We
seek loans for weddings, constructing houses, treatment, and deliveries.” In
Mzaponda, Malawi, women agreed: “Our businesses are failing to expand
just because the operating capital is very minimal. [We overuse credit] in trying to solve our own problems like buying food and other things that may
need money to be addressed. . . . If our capital had been big, then this would
not have been happening.”
The second constraint poor people face in the credit market is fair access.
Even in communities where formal loan facilities are present, poor men and
women find themselves excluded for three reasons: they lack information
about credit; they are unable to offer collateral demanded by formal lending
organizations; and they lack the political connections to be approved for
loans or, alternatively, the wherewithal to bribe loan officers.
“We hear from other places like Mbinga that there are credit facilities,”
said Yusta, a woman in Chiwolo, a village in Ruvuma, Tanzania. “But we
do not know how to access them, and nobody has come to explain this
to us.” Households in Maguli, another community in Ruvuma, also cited
lack of information as the primary reason for their inability to tap credit
schemes. Alex, a 50-year-old farmer and fisherman our team met in Maguli,
said people are organizing savings and credit cooperative societies as an
alternative to more formal credit sources. But it is difficult for people to
join the societies, he said, because they have not been trained in how to use
financial services.
At other times, getting credit is hard because of poor women’s and men’s
inability to offer collateral. Not all farmers in Abzif, Morocco, have benefited
from the local agricultural credit bank. A discussion group in the community
explained why. “The majority of the inheritance here is nonconsigned, that is,
without deeds. The farmers therefore lack legal title of ownership and cannot
guarantee a repayment to the bank.” This problem is particularly intense for the
displaced households our team interviewed in Colombia, who have no land,
no property, and no guarantee from anyone to offer as collateral. A discussion
group with women in Villa Rosa, a barrio of displaced people, said, “The local
credit organization lends money at 2 percent. But you have to have a small
business for more than a year, and bring documents showing you own a property that is in good condition. If you don’t have that, you must have a guarantor
and bring an account of expenses and an inventory.” The displaced people in
El Mirador, Colombia, face a similar dilemma. “Banks demand papers showing property rights to a building,” said a discussion group of men. “Credit
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
213
organizations demand licenses and guarantors, which the people cannot produce, and if they get money, it is only a fifth of what they had asked for.”
The constraint of political patronage and corruption is particularly strong
in the South Asian context. Women in Hasanbagh, Bangladesh, reported that
“no loan can be obtained without giving money to the officers of the local
bank. . . . The officers receive both an official salary and a bribe.” In Donekal,
Andhra Pradesh, women agreed: “If we go to the banks for loans, they ask us
to bring this paper and that paper. If we go to the mandal [block] office for
statements, it is difficult. They talk in a careless manner. Things do not work
out properly. We incur a lot of expenditure. Bribes have increased, and work
is delayed.”
The third constraint consists of high interest rates and strict installment
schedules enforced by organizations offering loans. This is particularly true
of civil society organizations. In Kamlondo, Uganda, people fear taking loans
from NGOs after a poor experience with an organization that offered short-term
loans at 25 percent interest with a seven-day repayment period. Several borrowers have had their properties attached because of failure to repay. Many communities in Bangladesh also complained of the high interest rates and frequent
installments they have to pay to microfinance institutions. Men in Shantakalia
said, “If we take a loan of 15,000 taka, we have to pay back 30,000 within nine
months. If we fail to repay, then we have to sell our land for repayment.”
Lending organizations in some communities restrict credit to certain
types of production, effectively constraining poor people from following the
livelihood of their choice. In Guluteza, Malawi, Andrea, a 52-year-old chronic
poor man, was forced into farming tobacco as no organization in his village
would provide fertilizer on credit to farmers who grow any other crop. “I had
a very bad experience with joining these groups,” said Andrea in his life story
interview. “I started tobacco farming, and at that time, I joined the tobacco
farmers club through which I could get fertilizer loans. But after realizing very
little from my tobacco sales, I still had to pay about 9,000 kwacha for fertilizer and another 8,000 kwacha for some club charges and credits, and I only
got 11,000 kwacha from my tobacco sales. This was a very bad experience for
me, and from then on, I made up my mind never to join any group dealing
with monetary issues. I realized that credit is very painful.”
Finally, even where credit is available, many poor entrepreneurs feel they
lack the skills to make productive use of the loan. In Hasanbagh, Bangladesh, Barku said, “The societies give loans for small grocery shops, vegetable
business, purchase of rickshaws, etc. But then, after giving loans, they do not
monitor the ways the loans are used. Even if someone throws the money into
214
Success from the Bottom Up
the pond, they would not care. People are using the loans for family purposes. Some are constructing houses, buying cows, and repaying debts with
the loan money.” In Aludonay, Philippines, getting a loan is “not a guarantee
that one would succeed, especially if you don’t know how to run a business.”
Residents of the community long for comprehensive livelihood programs.
“They should come up with livelihood projects for farmers so that they will
no longer take loans,” suggested a discussion group of men. “Loans would
only add to debts for farmers.”
Land titling and business licensing
Authorizations are not distributed fairly, but are based on corruption and
clientelism. If you give money, you will receive your permit in two days. If
you don’t, you’ll be sent from one department to another until you give up
your project or pay the bribe.
—Discussion with women, Izrane, Morocco
Legal and financial reforms undertaken by governments can bolster
people’s ability to take economic initiative in several ways. For farmers,
opportunities for land titling can be key facilitators of greater success. For
traders, reasonable legal requirements for starting a business, obtaining
licenses, employing workers, registering property, getting credit, trading
across borders, and paying taxes can aid profitability.
Land reform and land titling. For poor people, gaining legal title to their
land is crucial on two counts: it gives the household some semblance of food
security and permanence, and it opens doors to other opportunities, including access to credit. Our study found that even in communities where credit
sources are present, having a land title is usually the only way to qualify
to receive loans from banks. This is a particular problem in communities
that consist mainly of immigrants or people resettled from other places. In
the Colombia sample, for instance, most communities reported that banks
demand papers proving land ownership, which the displaced are unable to
produce. In other study regions too—Kagera in Tanzania, rural communities
in Afghanistan, and the states in India, among others—documents showing
ownership of land are a necessary condition for obtaining loans.
Moreover, people without title can be booted off their land. Households
in Biralipara, Assam, for instance, live each day under the threat of eviction.
Located on the border of another Indian state, Nagaland, and a forest reserve,
the land and all the houses in the village are the property of the forest depart-
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
215
ment. “People are insecure because anytime they could be asked to leave this
place, as they do not have ownership over this land,” remarked a discussion
group. “One week earlier we heard that the entire village would be taken over
by the government. We feel very insecure and helpless. We cannot imagine
what our condition will be if we have to leave our houses. We do not have any
idea where we will go with our little children.” A few other communities in
Assam are in a similar position; more than 80 percent of households in some
of them do not have land titles in their name.
One-time land reforms initiated by local governments in some communities have reduced initial inequalities in ownership of assets and spurred
individual initiative in farming and business. Land titles also provide poor
people with valuable collateral against which they can access credit. Nearly
30 percent of communities where opportunities had expanded over the study
period also witnessed a land reform program during this time, whereas land
reform had taken place in only 13 percent of communities where opportunities had become fewer. The association between land titling and strength
of the local economy in our communities is revealing. In communities with
strong or very strong local economies in 2005, nearly 86 percent of households reported holding legal title to land, but in communities with weak or
very weak economies, only 58 percent did (figure 5.5).
FIGURE 5.5
Land titling is strongly associated with perceived strength of local economy
% population in community
holding land titles
100
90
85.6
80
70
58.1
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Strong/very strong
local economy
Weak/very weak
local economy
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from the community questionnaire with key informants and
responses to the question “How strong is the local economy at the present time? Very strong, strong,
medium, weak, or very weak?” N = 452 communities.
216
Success from the Bottom Up
Although there is evidence that public works projects can help local prosperity, the association of public works with local economic strength is not as
marked. There is only a slight difference between communities with stronger
and weaker local economies in the incidence of public works projects (figure
5.6). If public works are well targeted, there should be more of them in less
prosperous communities.
Licensing. Abzif, a community in Beni Mellal province in Morocco, was
among those in our sample where economic opportunities had improved
considerably over the study period. In large part, this improvement was
due to the ease with which the local government in Abzif provided licenses
to start projects and small businesses. A discussion group of women in the
community said, “The authorizations are easily given. The small activities
have proceeded without problems: phone boutiques, sewing shops, hairdresser shops, and electricians. Ten years ago people didn’t have the same
odds of accessing economic opportunities. The authorizations for projects
were the privilege of some categories of the community: big rich families
who were close to politicians. People were also not safe or immune from
FIGURE 5.6
Public works projects are not strongly associated with perceived strength of
local economy
50
49.6
44.0
% communities with
public works projects
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
Strong/very strong
local economy
Weak/very weak
local economy
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from the community questionnaire with key informants and
responses to the question “How strong is the local economy at the present time? Very strong, strong,
medium, weak, or very weak?” N = 452 communities.
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
217
some injustices. Now the situation has improved a little: the authorizations
are accessible, and the concerned authorities support the people who have
projects in agriculture, cooperatives, handicrafts, shops, or sewing.”
As in Abzif, it seems that local governments elsewhere, if they wanted,
could make the process of setting up businesses easy. In fact, the ease with
which local governments make business licenses available was an important
factor distinguishing high-performing communities from those where the
local economy was considered weak. But it was disheartening to find that in
most communities, people seeking licenses had resigned themselves to a long
and costly process.
In India, where acquiring a license often takes seven months and costs
five times the annual income per capita (World Bank 2007), poor entrepreneurs seem to take the process for granted. For our respondents in Uttar
Pradesh—a state where bribe taking and corruption are more widespread
than in any of the other Indian states in the sample—the practice of giving
bribes to get a license is a way of life. In Rahamat, a prospering community
in the state that has benefited from roads and improved irrigation structures,
people spoke of being forced to give bribes to start any business. “You need
a license to start a big business. The licenses are distributed at the district
level, and middlemen make money for giving the license. This is common.
For example, meat shops, poultry rearing—all need a license,” said Shabbir,
a village resident. In Doola Mau, corruption is so widespread that nothing
can be done without giving a bribe. “Those who pay more can get their work
done faster,” women said. “Because the poor don’t have money to give bribes,
their work is never done.” Nor can poor people in most communities rely
on law enforcement to deter bribe taking. The police in Dinapur, a farming
community in Uttar Pradesh, are reported to collect levies regularly. Women
spoke of how “the police inspector comes every month and people have to
give to him . . . whatever you call it, tax or expenses.”
Worse, our quantitative data suggest that corruption around procedures
is more prevalent in communities where the opportunity sets have reportedly
expanded. Those trying to take advantage of new opportunities find themselves swimming against a current of increasing corruption rather than propelled along by a pro-business stream (figure 5.7). At the time of our survey,
in 2005, 50 percent of such communities reported that “most or almost all”
local government officials are corrupt; only about 21 percent recalled this
extent of corruption at the start of the study period 10 years earlier. In comparison, only 42 percent of communities where opportunities decreased over
218
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 5.7
Big increases in corruption were reported in communities where opportunities
have expanded
% communities reporting most/almost all
local government officials corrupt
60
50.2
50
42.5
40
36.1
30
20
20.8
10
0
Communities with increased
economic opportunity
Start of study period
Communities with decreased
economic opportunity
End of study period
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from the community questionnaire with focus group discussions and
responses to the question “Compared to 10 years ago, do people in the community have more, about
the same, or fewer economic opportunities?” N = 450 communities.
the study period reported that a majority of local government officials are
corrupt, not much higher than the 36 percent that thought so 10 years ago.
Thus the perceived jump in corruption was markedly higher in communities
where more opportunities had become available.
Our qualitative data suggest that as communities gradually climb the
ladder of prosperity, they create spaces for more rules and regulations around
licensing and other processes that can be twisted to serve the interests of local
officials. Households in our sampled villages give in to bribery because they
believe that giving eventually means receiving.
Conclusion and Policy Recommendations
People in poverty want economic opportunity. When opportunity sets expand
in a dynamic local economy, people can take initiative and move up or out
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
219
of poverty. All too often, however, people find channels of upward movement blocked and their initiatives thwarted. There is nothing in our study to
gainsay the key role of rapid economic growth in creating the conditions for
poverty reduction, but there is clearly more that can be done—in environments of slow or rapid growth—to expand opportunity and unblock paths
to mobility for poor people.
Location matters, and so does connectedness. Within national economies,
there are large variations between localities in the rate of progress. One
important reason is disparities in infrastructure and in ease of connection to
the outside world. Thus, a powerful lever for increasing economic dynamism
and opportunity is the provision of quasi-public goods like permanent roads,
physical market spaces, irrigation waterways, telephone networks, electricity,
and cheap, reliable transport. Roads, in particular, improve villages’ access
to markets, credit sources, schools, and health services. Remote communities not reached by passable roads are at a large disadvantage, unable to tap
markets and attract service providers. Connecting communities with roads
also has positive spillover effects in the social domain. Our evidence suggests that as communities get connected with the larger society, the hold of
the traditional elite usually weakens and patron-client relations become less
important for survival.
Fair access to markets is key. Conversations with chronic poor and movers
in the various study sites reveal the many ways in which equal opportunity
at the local level remains a myth. Rather than being guided by an invisible
hand, markets are often rigged by visible hands in ways that disfavor poor
producers and consumers. Poor people typically lack both the scale and the
expertise needed to overcome these obstacles. At the mercy of big players in
the formal marketplace, poor producers often operate on the fringes, in an
informal economy of petty trading, micro-agriculture, and sharecropping. A
focus on expanding opportunities for poor people requires analysis of the
business climate not just for large, formal producers but for tiny and small
entrepreneurs at the bottom and for those moving up.
Our study highlights the potential of liberalization from below.6 Even
where the opening up of markets has had an initial positive impact, as in
some communities in Tanzania, this effect quickly wanes, because poor people must deal with high prices for inputs and low prices for their produce.
Liberalization from below is different from liberalization that helps only the
rich or middle class. In China, for example, the big surge in poverty reduction came soon after agricultural markets were liberalized in such a way that
even poor, small farmers could buy and sell surpluses on their own terms. In
220
Success from the Bottom Up
rural communities, opening up procurement chains and markets, increasing
local grain storage capacity, and improving access to information on prices
are some measures that can usher in better returns to poor people. Economic
organization of poor people can play a critical role. The initiative to bring
about change can come from any institution—government, civil society, or
the private sector.
ITC, a private sector company in India, is placing computers in villages to
facilitate its agribusiness. In less than five years, the program has connected
more than 3 million medium farmers in India to markets through villagebased Internet kiosks called e-choupals.7 After checking prices at no charge
on the ITC computers, farmers can choose to buy or sell through ITC or go
to local markets instead. Efficiency improvements in transactions have led
to increased revenues both for farmers and for ITC. Only 10 percent of the
farmers using e-choupals are poor, however, and ITC is now setting up partnerships with poor people’s organizations to increase coverage. Collective
action and economic organizations of poor people are very important and
are discussed in chapter 7.
Poor entrepreneurs need more and better finance. Poor people often cannot
access formal credit facilities or do not have the collateral to obtain loans.
Many depend on moneylenders for credit. Even when poor households manage to access formal credit, they typically receive small loans at high rates of
interest. These are used relatively quickly for everyday consumption and do
little to improve a household’s productive capacity. Debt repayment itself
becomes a major part of household expenditure. Poor people need larger
loans, new and innovative financing arrangements for small enterprise, and
support in making best use of credit.
Local governments can either block or spur economic dynamism. Strong local
democracies that ensure property rights and a positive business environment
are critical for ensuring that the benefits of opening up markets are more
equally shared. However, land titling, business licensing, and other economic
policies adopted by local democracies often help only the socially dominant,
wealthier class. Corruption in local institutions affects poor people more
negatively than rich people, who have the capacity to either control or bypass
such institutions. Hence, attempts to help poor women and men improve
their economic lives have to take into account the local dynamics of social
and political power.
In sum, when our lens shifts to conditions at the local level, we can better
understand how to expand opportunity sets for poor people and help facilitate their own initiatives to improve their lives.
The Dream of Equal Opportunity
221
Notes
1. The usual question about the relationship between “growth” and “poverty” leads
to methodological debates, because growth is typically measured with national
accounts data whereas poverty is typically measured with household data. Under
such circumstances at least some of the divergence between growth and poverty
in the data will have nothing to do with income distribution, but will simply
reflect the fact that these two data sources disagree on the magnitude of the
change, even in conceptually equivalent measures.
2. For more details, see the Kagera synthesis report by Joachim De Weerdt on the
Moving Out of Poverty Web site.
3. The methodology was close in spirit to propensity score matching.
4. Proximity to borders and cities did not necessarily help in all conflict-affected
regions. In the Indian state of Assam, for instance, communities bordering other
states exhibited higher levels of violence due to problems of infiltration.
5. High-yielding varieties of rice were introduced in the early 1970s in West Bengal.
However, the benefits from their cultivation were waning by the time of the survey. Our respondents spoke more about agricultural diversification and expansion into nonfarming business activities as a means to move out of poverty.
6. This term was first used almost a decade ago by Ela Bhatt, founder of the Self
Employed Women’s Association (SEWA) in India. SEWA has over 700,000 members working in more than 70 trades in seven states across India. It fights to build
assets for its members by seeking fair wages and benefits and upgrading their
skills.
7. Choupal is the Hindi word for a rural gathering place where people can sit down
together to talk.
All Politics Is Local:
How Better Governance
Helps the Poor
When people have freedom, the
community is practicing democracy.
Democracy and freedom are the same
because we cannot experience freedom
if there is no democracy. Without
democracy there is chaos. How can a
community prosper in that case?
—D ISCUSSION WITH WOMEN ,
San Dogon, Philippines
When you have no power, stop
dreaming; you will have no freedom, no
equality, and democracy will remain a
story to you.
—D ISCUSSION WITH MEN AND WOMEN ,
Kijuronga, Kagera, Tanzania
The rich man in the village is the head
of the village; the poor man is the head
of the burial ground.
—M EN ’ S DISCUSSION GROUP ,
Govindapalle, Andhra Pradesh
6
C HAPTER
C
onsider two communities in two different countries. Let us call them,
for the moment, country A and country B.
In country A, the village of Tindyata is poor and is perched on a mountain
slope, where it is prone to flooding. Despite its precarious location and its
poverty, the village enjoys what appears to be an idyllic political climate. Elections in 2003 were a turning point. “The elections were equitable and open,
everybody participated, and the result was our will,” said women in the village.
“Currently, there is more freedom of speech, so the viewpoints of the officials
are beginning to change. Now they are asking for our opinions in matters concerning our interest.” The men agreed: “The elections were a very important
victory for our community. People are proud to be represented at the local
council. They are happy to have somebody who helps them obtain administrative forms and documents. The elected official is our spokesman. He has
brought us hope.” Women praised the official for being “always willing to lend
a sympathetic ear to our problems,” and both women and men affirmed that
people participate more in decision making than they did 10 years ago. Women
noted that the official had actively participated in the creation of an association for community development, which acts as a watchdog on government
activities. Besides the association, improved access to information through the
media has helped strengthen official accountability.
By most accounts, these improvements in people’s ability to contact and
influence the local government have not brought any concrete benefits to
the community. Tindyata remains what people called a “forgotten city.” Residents blame centrally designed laws and rules that disregard local realities
and hamper people’s efforts to improve their situation. Regulations regarding
the construction industry are a case in point. The rules permit construction
only on presentation of a clear construction plan to the municipality. Local
people said that the rule is bizarre, given that there are no architects locally
223
224
Success from the Bottom Up
available to approve such plans. One of the men in a discussion group admitted, “The elected official is with us, but he can’t do anything.”
Even so, most people our team met in Tindyata cherished their newfound democracy and sense of liberty. They felt it was intrinsically valuable
to be able to make their voices heard through their elected official. And they
felt a sense of liberty and security. A woman in a discussion group exclaimed,
“Now you can sleep in the street forever without anybody disturbing you.”
Far away in country B, Anakha is an agricultural village of rice and potato
farmers where nearly 70 percent of the population was stuck in chronic poverty in 2005. While Anakha’s poverty is roughly on par with Tindyata’s, it
seems to be politically illiberal. A single political party rules through fear
and dominates the economic, social, and political lives of poor people in
the community. Unlike in Tindyata, elections in Anakha are alleged to be
rigged.
“When one party makes any mistake, other parties used to protest against
it. But now the ruling party has all the power. There are not many people here
to speak against them. They fear for their lives,” reported men in the village.
Villagers described the “muscle power” of local politicians and the power of
the gun that could “stop mouths.” The ruling party is said to ignore people’s
opinions in decision making. “People appear in the meeting only as a show,”
a woman lamented. “All decisions are taken by party leaders. Those who are
party supporters get more benefit than the common people.” Even a 20-yearold woman was ironic in describing local politics: “We are enjoying the mockery of our party leaders. We are enjoying the mockery of democracy.”
A person’s ability to climb the economic ladder in Anakha is said to be
entirely a function of political contacts and membership in the ruling party.
Those without such affiliations are considered doomed. All economic strategies to move out of poverty—by getting a job, obtaining credit to set up a
small business, or improving agricultural productivity—are only available
to party members. Distribution of benefits from government programs for
the poor and elderly are either misused or distributed along party lines. Men
said matter-of-factly, “To get benefit here, people have to join the ruling party
after leaving opposition parties.” Party members can access credit without
mortgaging their land, get plots of land allotted to them without documentation, even secure government jobs. “Since 1996, most of the people who
have been getting land have not been worthy of it. The list was made by our
village head and some party members. The government officers had even
rejected the names of several people who got land. The really needy people
are, therefore, getting deceived from getting land.”
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
225
Party membership improves social rank in the village as well. A young
woman spoke candidly of the differences. “Common people who are not
party supporters do not get much importance during social occasions. They
are treated in a way as if they were not people of this society.” Social alienation
extends to the youth. Young men who are party supporters get to participate
in festivals and sports. Even in youth clubs, party supporters are regarded as
having more power.
Poor people aspire to join the party, but most cannot. Forced to work
in the fields every day to survive, most cannot spare the time to attend party
meetings or afford monthly donations. Observing the party’s stranglehold
on opportunities—and the fact that over the past decade, only 5 percent of
poor villagers in Anakha have moved out of poverty—many young people
conclude that the only way to get ahead is to become a politician. A 24-yearold was clear about his goals: “I would like to join the party in the future
because one can improve his condition here after joining the party. My father
is a cultivator, and my mother a local cigarette maker. They cannot improve
their condition. So I have a future plan to live differently.” Others concur:
“If one is to get freedom and money, party support is more important than
education.”
Country A is Morocco; the village of Tindyata is in the province of
Chichaoua. Country B is India, and the village of Anakha is in the state of
West Bengal. These contrasting community stories remind us that to understand how democracy plays out in the lives of poor people, we need to look
beneath broad national labels to examine specific local realities.
Morocco’s movement toward a more open system started in the 1990s.
The reforms, guided by King Hassan II and his son Mohammed VI, included
greater respect for human rights, more opportunities to form civil society
associations that could openly discuss issues like corruption in government,
and introduction of a new family code that gave women more rights. The
reforms also opened up the Moroccan parliament to universal suffrage and
gave elected members more power to question the executive. Despite these
advances, political scientists think Morocco exemplifies a “competitive electoral authoritarian” regime. Experts of this democratization have criticized it
as a top-down process that reflects the monarchy’s attempt to appear modern.
The king remains the executive head of state, military chief, and religious
leader; he can veto parliament decisions and hire and fire entire government
bodies. In that sense, the reforms appear to be “a quest for modernization,
not for popular participation and government accountability” (Ottaway and
Riley 2006). But realities on the ground appear more nuanced. Although not
226
Success from the Bottom Up
all communities in Morocco reflect the same degree of satisfaction in their
young democracy as Tindyata, people in most villages we visited are satisfied
with their local elected representatives.
The state of West Bengal is widely acknowledged as among the first in
India to have successfully created democratic structures at the local level. Its
experience of nearly 25 years of electing village panchayats is evidence of the
state’s commitment to grassroots democracy. A stable, leftist state government has held office for more than three decades, with an absolute majority.
Scholars have attributed the party’s continued electoral success to its actions
to reduce rural poverty through measures such as land reform. Given this
long track record of local democracy, one would expect considerable engagement of local populations in community-level decision making in West Bengal. The discussions in Anakha, however, suggest otherwise. Although there
are many communities in West Bengal where people praised their local leaders, in 21 percent of the communities visited in the state, people complained
of “muscle men and goons.” Clearly, even in the largest democracy in the
world, India, the intrinsic freedom that democracy supposedly brings is not
guaranteed.
These experiences in Morocco and India are emblematic of what we
found in the other countries visited for the Moving Out of Poverty study.
Democratic functioning in local communities varies widely and does not
always reflect the national image or label. Across our sample, we found that
93 percent of the variation in the extent to which local political leaders pay
attention to citizens is explained by within-country variation. In considering
the effects of democracy on poverty, therefore, we should keep in mind the
well-worn precept that “all politics is local.”
Food or Freedom: A False Dilemma
In Morocco and in villages across Africa, South Asia, East Asia, and Latin
America, poor men and women engaged in deep discussions about the nature
of democracy and freedom. They debated the effectiveness of democracy as
practiced in their communities—what democracy does and does not deliver,
and how it could be improved. They attached intrinsic value to the practice of
democracy, no matter its flaws. Even in Morocco, with its recent and incomplete democracy, a group of men told the field team, “With democracy, we
have become aware of many things. We have left our caves and have become
more open to the world.” People spoke of the intrinsic worth of freedom:
freedom to think, to speak, to protest, to dream, to live with dignity and
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
227
respect. At the same time, they attached an instrumental importance to freedoms that allow them to work, to move around, and to choose occupations
and assets that can help them bring food to the table.
We found very little evidence to suggest that poor people want to trade off
democracy and freedom for food. They feel they have a right to both. Nor do
poor men and women believe they must fulfill their basic needs before they
can meaningfully exercise democratic rights and freedoms.1 In Development as
Freedom, Amartya Sen (1999) critiques the tendency of those in privileged positions to create a hierarchy of needs for those who have less. The oft-repeated but
misleading question, according to Sen, is “What should come first—removing
poverty and misery, or guaranteeing political liberty and civil rights, for which
poor people have little use anyway?” To this question, he replies:
Is this a sensible way of approaching the problems of economic needs and
political freedoms—in terms of a basic dichotomy that appears to undermine the relevance of political freedoms because the economic needs are
so urgent? I would argue, no, this is altogether the wrong way to see the
force of economic needs, or to understand the salience of political freedoms. The real issues . . . involve taking note of extensive interconnections
between political freedoms and the understanding and fulfillment of economic needs. The connections are not only instrumental . . . but also constructive. Our conceptualization of economic needs depends crucially on
open public debates and discussions, the guaranteeing of which requires
insistence on basic political liberty and civil rights. (147–48)
The notion that freedom and liberal democracy are luxuries that should
be considered only after basic needs such as food have been met has its origins
in Western history. In Western Europe, democracy emerged after the Industrial
Revolution had already brought growth in incomes and basic education, and
this history still informs thinking about the correct sequencing of economic
growth and democracy. Some suggest that poor countries should “grow first,”
gain from “development dictatorships,” and later embrace democracy (Huntington and Nelson 1976). This concept is reflected in the celebration of
the East Asian miracle, in which Korea, Indonesia, Singapore, and Taiwan
suppressed human freedoms but achieved spectacular economic growth
accompanied by poverty reduction (Barro 1994; Przeworski et al. 2000). This
thinking is also captured in the India–China debates. Some observers believe
that democracy, with its endless debates and need for political consensus on
policy reform, has slowed India’s growth, while others make a case for a longterm democracy dividend, with democratic India being “a tortoise to China’s
hare” (Varshney 2007).2
228
Success from the Bottom Up
The survival of democracy in India challenges the basic assumptions of
many political scientists that literacy and middle-income levels are necessary
preconditions for democracy. Defying democratic theory, India’s lower classes
have participated in elections at a higher rate than its middle and upper classes
since the early 1990s. In fact, the “lower the caste, income, and education of an
Indian, the greater the odds that he will vote” (Varshney 2007). Although the
fact that poor people vote to a greater extent than rich people could be interpreted as a sign of desperation among the poor to make their voices heard, the
fact that they do vote is an indicator of a healthy electoral democracy.3
India is not alone. By the end of the twentieth century, democracy became the
preferred way of organizing political systems. There is still wide variation in types
of democracy, ranging from liberal democracies to illiberal pseudo-democracies
to electoral authoritarian regimes (Diamond 2002, 2005). Nonetheless, most
political scientists agree that the essence of democracy is competitive politics
through free and fair elections and a responsive government that is accountable
to all its citizens—in brief, contestation and participation (Dahl 1989; Varshney
2005). Democracies encompass civil liberties to different degrees. These liberties include the right to vote, the right to information, the right to protest and
form associations, the right to own property (still weakly defined in many polities), and the right to participate in politics and in society.
Most of the debate about democracy is at the national level; in fact, there
has been an obsession with formal national elections. Although they are an
important precondition for democracy, the presence of elected representatives at the national level does not guarantee a functional democracy, nor
does it guarantee freedoms for poor people in their communities.
We concentrate, therefore, on understanding people’s interactions with
democracy at the local level. We focus on the demand side and not on factors
that affect the supply side, such as rules that govern political parties and election finance. We are particularly interested in the interactions between local
people and their elected officials and in the responsiveness and accountability of politicians to citizens, especially poor people.4 Clearly, variations in
the history, age, and depth of political democracy across countries matter,
and this detail should be kept in mind in examining the country-specific
results.5 We do not seek to evaluate the impact of decentralization per se, but
we do examine the relationship between local political structures and the
likelihood of moving out of poverty.6
We start with poor people’s own definitions of democracy, its constituent elements, and its functioning at the local level. We consider associations
between local democracy and community prosperity and gains at the house-
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
229
hold level to examine who benefits from local democracy, looking in particular at two phenomena—corruption and elite capture—that can serve to
channel the benefits of democracy to a few. Finally, we examine the factors
that can lead to local democracy becoming more pro-poor.
What Does Democracy Mean to Poor People?
Democracy means to appreciate opinions. It means musyawarah mufakat
[deliberations to reach consensus].
—Discussion with young women, Kacokerre, East Java, Indonesia
No democracy exists in this country, or fair judgment in the court. Those
who have money, the judgment is in favor of them.
—Discussion with men, Shantakalia, Bangladesh
Most poor people in our sample associate democracy first and foremost
with the freedom to control their own lives, to do whatever they wish as long
as it does not hurt others.7 Democracy is an aspiration. In Afghanistan, for
example, democracy means “entire freedom: shaving your beard, wearing any
kind of clothes you want, listening to a radio cassette, and swimming in the
warm weather.” Freedom of expression and of worship were also mentioned
across study sites. In conflict-affected countries, people value freedom from
fear and freedom of physical movement. For women everywhere, democracy
connotes freedom in both the domestic and public spheres (see chapter 2 for
a discussion of people’s views on freedom).
Table 6.1 summarizes the definitions of democracy from one study
region, Malawi. Like people in other regions, the study participants in Malawi
went far beyond the common, limited understanding of democracy as centered on elections. Although multiparty politics were mentioned, freedoms
of various types topped the list.
Nowhere is the identification of democracy with freedom more evident
than in Afghanistan, where the nascent democracy, with all its uncertainties,
is associated with release from the restrictions the Taliban imposed. In 2006,
when field work was conducted, the end of Taliban rule and the beginning of
democracy had improved security, which in turn allowed greater freedom of
movement, especially for women and children. Omra, a 50-year-old woman in
the community of Morlaw Ghano in Nangarhar province, described the change:
“Democracy is working better now than in the past. All our children can go to
school—even girls—and everyone feels freer to look for a job, to go to Jalalabad.”
230
Success from the Bottom Up
TABLE 6.1
People in study communities in Malawi associate democracy first and foremost
with freedom
Understanding of democracy
No. of times mentioned
Freedoms (of expression, worship, association, etc.)
Having power or being given a chance to lead for development
22
9
Multiparty politics (ruling and opposition parties)
8
Participatory decision making
5
Everybody ruling/ability to elect and remove people in power
3
Security
2
Working together (e.g., the chief and his people)
1
Gender equality
1
Living in harmony, without discrimination
1
Source: Focus group discussions on livelihoods, freedom, power, and democracy.
In Shazimir, near Kabul, women relished the freedom to go to the bazaar and to
work outside the home as teachers and office workers. For a woman in Zakwak
Ulya, Herat, the improved security brought simple pleasures to be cherished:
“Everyone wants to have democracy, to pray, and to go to the cinema.”
Deliberative versus representative democracy
For democracy to function there must be freedom to appreciate the aspirations and opinions of every person.
—Young woman, Yasapira, North Maluku, Indonesia
Across study regions, the right to vote was cited as an important dimension of democracy. When asked to define democracy, poor men and women
in Uttar Pradesh, the Indian state with the largest population and parliamentary seat share, summed it up in two words: “our rule.”8 But people across
study sites defined democracy as going beyond voting, a right they often
seemed to take for granted. They identified three features they considered
essential: voice, participation, and justice.
In this sense, poor people in our sample seem to support scholars who
conceptualize democracy as participative, deliberative, and direct, rather than
as merely representative. The essential distinction, according to Cohen and
Sabel (1997, 321), “is not the level of participation, but the topic of agenda:
direct democracy requires decisions on substance, whereas representative
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
231
democracy involves choice on legislators who decide on substance” (see also
R. Chambers 2003; Fung and Wright 2003).
People across study regions said that meaningful democratic participation is not possible without voice, the freedom to express themselves both
individually and collectively. They value discussion and consensus building.
Young women in the village of Yasapira, North Maluku, Indonesia, interpreted democracy as the “freedom to express all aspirations without being
restricted by norms or regulations. For democracy to function, there must be
freedom to appreciate the aspirations and opinions of every person. Opinions will emerge if people are free to express them. But without this freedom of expression, a discussion will not reach mutual agreement.” People
in Afghanistan also recognize the importance of voice. “It means that one
can freely give their opinions,” said Tahir, a young farmer in Morlaw Ghano,
Nangarhar. “If you cannot express your ideas, how can you be free?”
Freedom of expression includes the freedom to protest. Zair, another
villager in Morlaw Ghano, noted, “Freedom of speech is more important
than other types of freedom because one can express one’s ideas about injustices and violation of rights in the government or in the community.” In
Delapong, Philippines, people defined democracy as the right to organize an
antigovernment rally. Young women in Tulma, also in the Philippines, said
democracy gives people “the right to vote; you have the right to choose.” But
they added, “You also have the right to protest the laws or policies passed for
implementation. You can go for a rally or a signature campaign.”
Poor people’s discussions of voice and participation reflect two important
theoretical and empirical insights. First, discussion groups and our quantitative data suggest that underlying norms of trust, solidarity, unity, and tolerance provide the essential foundation for participation and voice in decision
making. Nearly 45 percent of those who said that their local democracy now
pays more attention to their concerns also reported improvement in trust levels in their village or neighborhood. Only 22 percent said that trust levels
had deteriorated. In Sri Lanka, a women’s discussion group said that participation entails a spirit of “unity, togetherness, and participation of each and
every one.” In the village of Appilepalle, Andhra Pradesh, people concurred:
“Democracy means all of us living together. We do our own work, but we live
together. We are friendly with our neighbors and we live happily.”
Second, the most important participation is collective, and participation
itself reinforces norms of belonging and unity. Participation in collective
efforts generates what economist Vijayendra Rao (2008) calls symbolic public goods (see also Mosse 1997; Turner 1982).9 Communities in Andhra
232
Success from the Bottom Up
Pradesh, a state with large numbers of women’s self-help groups, defined
democracy “as a system whereby people participate collectively, with unity
and in harmony, for village development and for collective problem solving.”
“Democracy means to join with people to rule ourselves,” concluded a discussion group in the village of Bestharapalle. “It is to achieve what is required
for the village through groups.”
The emphasis on norms of trust, unity, and participation in discussions
of democracy partly reflects the deep inequalities in our study regions and
communities. Poor people, women, and other marginalized groups confront
many barriers to making their voices heard in decision making (Fung and
Wright 2003; Kaufman 1968).10 Thus, the third essential feature of democracy is justice. In discussions about democracy, poor people spoke about the
importance of equal rights, equality before law, equality between men and
women, and equality between different ethnicities, castes, and religions. They
emphasized the need for protection of individual rights under law even when
they did not expect to be able immediately to claim all their rights.
In the community of Izrane, Morocco, justice is considered to be the most
important feature of democracy, even more than liberty and equality. People
emphasized that justice must be impartial and independent. A discussion
group of men stated, “The judge must not receive telephone calls that dictate
to him what he must do. Without pressure, he must fully apply the law. The
oppressor must be judged, and the innocent must be acquitted. There must
be liberty of speech. I declare, I denounce, or I write to newspapers what I
observe as anomalies. The liberty of critique must be protected by law.”
Concepts of equality and justice differ depending on the local context.
Participants in Afghanistan stressed gender equality; they hoped that the turn
to democracy would mean that women could move around more freely than
they could under the Taliban. The importance of economic equality was mentioned frequently in West Bengal, perhaps reflecting the state’s four decades
of communist rule. Finally, in caste-stratified Andhra Pradesh, people focused
on the ideal of equality between different caste groups. Male youths in Bestharapalle, for example, defined democracy as a state where “people of different castes and religions are treated equally, and equal justice is done to all
people. Then we can say that there is democracy in our village.”
How Local Democracy Makes a Difference
Democracy means an easier life [yombalal] or progress [yokoute].
—Discussion group, Geona, Senegal
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
233
Democracy brings development to the community. When there is democracy, things like water, schools, and hospitals will be available to the village, which are otherwise hard to get.
—Men in a discussion group, Kabtito, Uganda
Democracy can bring development, but at present it does not do so. Our democracy is made up of the politics of promises. Democracy wastes time. People go
on talking about politics endlessly, and there is no more time for work.
—Men in a discussion group, Bugokela, Kagera, Tanzania
We encountered several forms of local democracy in the countries we
visited. In Afghanistan, the local democratic structure is the shura, a council
of elders responsible for resolving disputes in the community. It is headed
by a malek, a title that traditionally was passed from father to son; in the
post-Taliban era, the malek is elected by the people. In the Indian context,
local democratic bodies include the gram sabha, or village assembly, and the
panchayat, an executive body whose five members are chosen by the gram
sabha. The panchayat implements government schemes in the community
and oversees provision of basic services like local roads, drinking water, electricity, and sanitation. A similar role is played by the village executive committee in Tanzania and the barangay in the Philippines. What interests us is
not the form of local democracy, but how well these democratic structures
are functioning.
Democracy as an ideal is cherished, but the practice of democracy in
any particular setting may be deeply flawed, in part as a result of deep social
divisions. In theory, local elections, competitive politics, and equality under
the law should lead to responsive local governance. Whether they do so is
an empirical question. We developed a measure of responsiveness based on
four indicators: people’s ratings of the extent to which local elected officials
take into account citizen concerns, their ratings of whether they have any
influence on the actions of local officials, their ratings of the extent to which
they trust these officials, and finally whether they are satisfied with the way
democracy works in their local government.
We first test whether there is any relationship between our measure of
responsiveness and improved community-level outcomes, including delivery
and quality of basic services, presence of roads, and public safety. We then
turn to benefits to individuals across our sample of countries. Finally, we pose
the question of whether individual gains for some may imply costs to others
in the same community.
234
Success from the Bottom Up
Community outcomes
Because of electricity, now we are watching TV, we are getting news of our
own country and abroad, and we are living our life happily. Because of
street lights, females can go anywhere at night. There is electricity in the
mass education center, so everyone is studying as well.
—Men’s discussion group, Khalsi, West Bengal
Security has started improving, maybe it is a change in the government. . . .
Nowadays when a person is taken to jail, you don’t see that person coming
back and giving you a greeting.
—A woman in a mixed discussion group, Bamlozi, Malawi
Djatick is a Wolof village of 654 inhabitants in a rural district of Senegal. Life has been tough in this isolated, agriculture-dependent community over the past few years. Drought and devastating locust invasions have
slashed yields of the main commercial crop, groundnuts. Lack of rain has
resulted in culling of cattle herds, and people move for days looking for
pasture. As a result, more people have fallen into poverty than have escaped
it. Since 1995, 70 percent of the nonpoor have plunged into poverty and
43 percent of those who were already in poverty have fallen further down.
Only a few have managed to move out of poverty. Most people in Djatick
still live in mud-brick huts with no electricity, relying on kerosene lanterns
for light. Many households survive only by sending their children to work
in a nearby town.
Our team was surprised, then, to find when they arrived in Djatick that
its people were optimistic. Lamine Top, a successful son of the village, had
put his job in the Ministry of Education on hold and returned to be elected
president of the local rural council. People sang his praises. Since his election in 2002, he had raised the council budget and invested heavily in basic
infrastructure, which included drilling a borehole as part of the national rural
infrastructure program. Previously, women had walked to a well six hours
away, spent the night there, and come back in the morning with water. So
excited were the villagers about the borehole that they contributed 180,000
CFA francs toward the project, and the transparent management of the borehole led to the repayment of a CFAF 350,000 loan. Other improvements
included the reopening of a health post built in 1990 and the addition of
classrooms to a primary school. Meetings involving representatives of all 25
villages in the local council area are sometimes held in Djatick, easing feelings of marginalization and isolation among residents. Although they remain
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
235
poor, people were proud of their leader and of their role in electing him. A
men’s discussion group noted, “If a local representative does not perform
well, we can get rid of him through the ballot box.”
Provision of basic services and infrastructure. The experience of Djatick
does not appear to be unique. We asked people across study sites a variety of
questions about local services and much later in the discussion switched to
the quality of their interaction with local government. We specifically asked
whether local government paid more or less attention to their concerns today
compared to 10 years ago. Overall, one-third of the communities experienced
some improvement in local government responsiveness by this measure.
We then compared these responses to changes in community services.
When we look at our results across countries, the pattern is striking. Communities where local governments had become more responsive had better
access to clean water, schools, doctors, nurses, and public health clinics than
communities where responsiveness had decreased. The quality of education
and health services also showed more improvement (figure 6.1).11
FIGURE 6.1
Quality of health and education improved more where governments became
more responsive
20
18
18.2
% change in quality
16
14
13.1
12
10
8
6
5.3
4
2
0.6
0
Improvement in quality
of education
More responsive
Improvement in quality
of health
Less responsive
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from the community questionnaire with key informants and responses to the question: “Compared to 10 years ago, does the local government now pay more, about the same,
or less attention to what people like you think when it decides what to do?” N = 412 communities.
236
Success from the Bottom Up
The presence of roads, too, is closely associated with changes in local
government responsiveness (figure 6.2). Communities where responsiveness
had increased were much more likely to have a passable road to the nearest urban center than those where responsiveness had decreased (81 percent
compared to 58 percent). A new road in the village of Kabtito, Uganda, was
built on the direct initiative of the district local government. Similarly, in
Changsari, Assam, a village road was built using grants made by a local member of the legislative assembly. Both roads had improved market access and
employment options for village residents.
Maintenance of law and order. We were also interested in whether greater
government responsiveness was associated with better security in communities. At minimum, people expect their local elected officials to maintain law
and order. We found that improvement in levels of peace and safety was
greater in communities where local governments are more responsive (figure 6.3). Communities with a more responsive local government reported a
16 percent improvement in peace levels, compared to a 10 percent increase
reported by communities where responsiveness had worsened over the study
period.
Individual outcomes
When, in our village, a [housing] colony was made in 1986 and we got a
house [from the government], I was really happy. I felt the same happiness
as a hungry man gets on eating food or a naked man on getting clothes.
—Prem, a young poor woman, Sapsa, Uttar Pradesh
In the village of Sapsa, Uttar Pradesh, Prem’s life changed when she benefited from a centrally sponsored but locally delivered government program called
Indira Vikas Yojna that gives land to poor households. Prem was the youngest of
12 children and the only girl. She received no formal education and was married
at the age of 12. As our team sat on the floor of her immaculate home, she said,
“We were so poor that we lived in a small hut, and when it rained, the roof used
to leak. When, in our village, a [housing] colony was made in 1986 and we got
a house, I was really happy. Exactly two years later under the Indira Vikas Yojna,
we got land. Now instead of working for other people, I can make a small living. I can farm on my land and earn for myself. Earlier we were landless; now
we are called farmers.” She supplements her farm income with money her husband earns selling fruit in Delhi. “In 2003, we converted our hut into a proper
house. This change created much happiness too. Because the money that you
have earned is in your hand, [you can] do whatever you want.”
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
237
FIGURE 6.2
Roads were more likely to be present in communities where governments
became more responsive
% communities with
passable road to nearest city
100
90
81
80
70
58
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
More responsive
Less responsive
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from the community questionnaire with key informants and responses to the question: “Compared to 10 years ago, does the local government now pay more, about the same,
or less attention to what people like you think when it decides what to do?” N = 412 communities.
FIGURE 6.3
Communities where governments became more responsive were more likely to
report an increase in levels of safety and peace
% increase in safety/peace levels
18
16
15.6
13.8
14
11.5
12
10
10.3
10.1
8
6.4
6
4
2
0
Peace in community
Safety from crime
when at home
More responsive
Safety in streets
after dark
Less responsive
Source: Authors’ analysis using data from the community questionnaire with key informants and responses
to the question: “Compared to 10 years ago, does the local government now pay more, about the same, or
less attention to what people like you think when it decides what to do? N = 420 communities.
238
Success from the Bottom Up
When we first started discussing the study with political scientists, some
wondered why we expected any relationship between local democracy and
moving out of poverty. Fortunately, the data collection had already started.
The presence of basic infrastructure—water, roads, electricity, health facilities,
and schools—clearly facilitates livelihoods and often prevents disease, a major
drain on incomes. But as Prem’s life story shows, a responsive local government
can do much more beyond provision of infrastructure to assist livelihoods.
In the hundreds of life stories we studied, local government plays positive roles in poor people’s lives in many small and big ways: by providing
farming inputs, loans, training, land, and housing and by providing disaster
relief. In Kabtito, Uganda, besides constructing a road, the local government
distributes improved varieties of seeds that have helped farmers increase their
income. In Delapong, Philippines, people spoke about a well-administered
scholarship program for poor children and about loans to start small businesses. In Thailand, local self-government bodies called Tambon Administrative Organizations (TAOs) provide support in building feeder canals for
irrigation, enabling farmers to produce two rice crops a year. The TAOs also
help communities manage the Baht Village Fund, which provides credit to
buy agricultural machines such as seed planters and crop harvesters.
Local governments played a particularly valuable role in supporting livelihoods in conflict-affected areas. Lupotogo, a community in North Maluku,
Indonesia, was hit by conflict between Christians and Muslims in 1999. Residents credit the local government’s help in large part for their recovery. “After
the conflict, there was government assistance in the form of katinting [motorboat], handicraft tools, cooking tools, and so forth,” said Umi. “If it wasn’t for
that assistance, what work would we do? Because everything was destroyed
during the conflict.” In a katinting, fishermen can go farther out to sea and
bring back a bigger catch, increasing their profits.
As a check on our qualitative data, we once again performed multilinear
regression analyses to see whether there is a statistical association between the
probability of moving out of poverty and local government responsiveness.
At the household level, we combined four questions into one. Our measure
includes indicators of the level of trust people have in their local government
officials, whether they are satisfied with democracy in their local government,
whether their local government takes into account citizen concerns, and their
ability to contact local government and influence its actions.12 We control for
the effect of other factors such as economic prosperity, collective action, corruption, individual empowerment, social stratification, and the usual individual factors such as assets and education.
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
239
FIGURE 6.4
Responsiveness of local democracy has a significant association with moving
out of poverty, particularly in South Asian study regions
Coefficient and Standard Errors: MOP and Responsiveness of Local Democracy
0.2
Propensity to move out of poverty
PHI
BAN
0.1
UP WB
MAL
UGA
AP
SEN TAN
PHIC
ASSAM
AFG INDO
MEX
THAI
COL
0
–0.1
–0.2
Study region
Source: Multivariate linear regression analysis using data from household survey and community questionnaire (see appendix 6).
Figure 6.4 reports the association between our measure of “responsiveness of local democracy” and household movement out of poverty. As in
other box plots, the single dots represent the coefficients: the greater their
height, the higher the value of the coefficient. The bars around the coefficient
represent the one and two standard error bounds. The more tightly clustered
the bounds, the smaller the standard error and the more significant the association between responsiveness and moving out of poverty (MOP).
As figure 6.4 illustrates, the evidence is mixed. There is a positive association between a responsive local democracy and moving out of poverty in
some regions, the association being strongest in the Indian states (with the
exception of Andhra Pradesh) and in Bangladesh.
For illustrative purposes only, let us take the case of Uttar Pradesh, where
responsiveness of the local panchayats has a significant influence on poor
households’ ability to improve their well-being. A change in the local government’s ability to pay attention to citizen concerns from a minimum score
of “less attention” to a maximum score of “more attention” increases the
240
Success from the Bottom Up
likelihood of moving out of poverty by 6.6 percent. Compare this to the
influence of a unit change in the household head’s education level, from illiteracy to primary schooling or from primary schooling to secondary schooling. This change affects MOP by 3.4 percent.13 An increase of 1 hectare in
the amount of land owned by the household at the start of the study period
only pushes up the household’s likelihood of moving out of poverty by 1.3
percent. Similarly, each of the other component variables—satisfaction with
local democracy, trust in local government, and ability to influence government actions—has a greater influence on MOP than land or education.
In the African and some conflict study regions, however, responsiveness
of local democracy is insignificant for MOP. In the conflict regions, in fact,
there is usually a negative association between responsiveness and MOP. The
exceptions are the conflict-affected communities in Assam and the Philippines,
where increased responsiveness of the local democratic structure is associated
with an increase in MOP (positive sign). In the Philippines, this phenomenon
may be because of a generally positive perception of local democracy and the
many government-financed programs at the local level. In India, it may reflect
the important role that local panchayats play, at least in service delivery and in
implementing centrally sponsored programs for poor families.
There are two ways of looking at these results. On the positive side, one
can marvel at this evidence of strong and significant positive association
between local democracy—despite all its real-life messiness—and moving
out of poverty. These results remain after controlling for other factors. All this in
general bears out poor people’s faith in local democracy.
On the negative side, one can point out the variations and the negative
associations in some countries. And finally, the results do not tell us anything
about the cost of moving out of poverty or whether one person’s success may
hurt the efforts of others.
Benefits to some, costs to others
There are people who get jealous of you and wish you to fail. [A person]
might pay somebody to steal your working animals or your crops.
—Men’s discussion group, Paitatu, Philippines
In communities where resources are limited, if I gain access to some
resources, you may have even less. In other words, if I win, you lose. We do
find evidence of poor people fighting over limited resources. Thus, the question of whether a responsive local democracy benefits some people at the
expense of others is a serious one for our study.
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
241
We approach this question using a technique called the leave-out mean
(LOM), which averages the response of all households in the village excluding
a given household (let us call it household X). It could well be that household
X’s perceptions of government responsiveness are influenced by the benefits
it derives from the local public works program, but that its participation in
the program serves to exclude others. In that case, the overall social impact of
the program could be negative. The leave-out mean for X is the average of all
responses on responsiveness of local government less X’s own response. This
helps differentiate private effects from purely social effects.
In earlier research in Tanzania, we applied the leave-out mean technique
to measure the impact of social capital (group membership) on an individual’s well-being and on the well-being of the rest of the community where
the individual lives (Narayan and Pritchett 1997). We found that even if an
individual does not belong to any groups, he or she gains by living in a village
where many people belong to groups—a pure social benefit. Later, a study in
Indonesia used the technique to disentangle the private and social effects of
household participation in local government. It found that one household’s
participation has a strong crowding-out or chilling effect on the voice and
participation of other households in the same village (Alatas, Pritchett, and
Wetterberg 2007).
In the present study, we constructed a similar leave-out mean variable
for our measure of responsiveness of local democracy. Figure 6.5 captures
the association between this variable and household MOP using multivariate
linear regressions, as reported in appendix 6.
In many of the South Asian study contexts where this variable was significant, we observe negative spillover effects.14 This finding is reflected in the
negative coefficient on the leave-out mean variable in Uttar Pradesh and significantly so in West Bengal, Assam, Bangladesh, Malawi, and Senegal. This
observation suggests that there is considerable crowding out among poor
households in their fight over the very limited goods—fertilizer packets, water,
scholarships, houses, and so on—distributed by their local governments. In
Indonesia, the Philippines, and Andhra Pradesh, however, the association is
positive and significant, which seems to be related to three factors. First, in
middle-income contexts, governments have focused much more on improving community-wide facilities used by everyone, primarily infrastructure such
as roads, bridges, electricity, and schools. Second, it is possible that when
limited goods are distributed, this is done in a way that is widely perceived to
be fair. Finally, it may be that in wealthier contexts, targeted programs are so
well endowed so that all who qualify benefit equally.
242
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 6.5
Responsiveness of local democracy to some has negative spillovers on others
Propensity to move out of poverty
Coefficient and Standard Errors: MOP and LOM of Responsiveness of Local Democracy
1.5
PHI
TAN
1.0
UGA
0.5
THAI
AP
0
UP WB
BAN
MAL
INDO PHIC
MEX
ASSAM
SEN
–0.5
Study region
Source: Multivariate linear regression analysis using data from household survey and community questionnaire (see appendix 6).
Why Isn’t Local Democracy More Effective?
Although poor people in poor environments turn to their local governments
with hope, their hopes are often dashed. Across communities, we found three
factors that block democratic structures from being more responsive and playing positive roles. They are rules and regulations, especially those governing
micro and small businesses; corruption; and elite capture of resources and
power by particular groups. The extent of elite capture appears to be closely
linked to the extent to which the community is divided by caste, ethnicity,
and religion—that is, the level of social stratification.
Restrictive rules and regulations
When you are looking for a license to do business, sometimes you are told
to come tomorrow. If you go back to the office the following day, you are
told again to come tomorrow. Hence, you have to put your hands in your
pocket to ensure that fast service is delivered to you.
—Discussion with women, Kaludoma, Ruvuma, Tanzania
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
243
You see this young man, this executive officer? He is tiny. If I push him,
he would fall. He cannot even carry a jerry can of water. But touch [him]
and see what he will do. They have powers hidden in the rules they design.
Their powers are hidden in papers.
—Discussion groups with men and women
in a village in Kagera, Tanzania
Over and over again, in the communities we visited, we found that rules
and regulations discriminate against poor women and men. Discretion and
lack of accountability at the local level lead to pervasive informal levies that
are a net drain on any poor person who ventures to be entrepreneurial.15
Poor people might find their livelihoods shut down or strictly curtailed by
regulations supposedly intended to protect the environment or the common
good, with no provision made for alternative livelihoods. And in some cases,
the rules imposed by higher levels were just plain silly.
Despite economic liberalization at the national level, poor people at the
local level remain subject to complex rules around licensing, ownership of
assets, and livelihoods. Across contexts, local government officials have devised
informal regulations that sometimes appear to have no purpose other than to
create a hidden or not-so-hidden flow of private revenue. Women in Surjana,
Bahraich, Uttar Pradesh, reported, “The hawkers or vegetable vendors in the
market have to pay a tax of 3–4 rupees [about 10 cents] per day. If they want to
open a regular shop in the market, then a license is necessary. For the license, the
expenditure is around 4,000–5,000 rupees [US$100–US$125].” A fisherman
in Chakboeng, Cambodia, found himself paying huge fines. “One day I put a
broul [bamboo trap] to catch fish in the open fishing area of the river. But then
a number of fishery inspectors approached and forced me to take the broul out
of the river unless I paid them US$600. On behalf of the village fishery community, I spent almost a morning bargaining for a reasonable fee of US$400, or
1,600,000 riels. Finally, the inspectors agreed to this amount. I then had to borrow money from a Vietnamese fisherman I knew to pay them. Although I was
fishing in the open area, I could not claim my rights because they had guns.”
Authorities frequently impose a flat tax on all businesses irrespective of
their size, which penalizes small businesses and favors large ones. In Chiwolo,
Ruvuma, Tanzania, the village government imposed levies on households
with micro businesses such as shops, fishmonger stalls, and mini-restaurants
known as migahawa. Kevin, a small businessman, complained, “The local
government has been very active in collection of levies from petty businesses.
Unfortunately, there are no clear rules and regulations when it comes to
244
Success from the Bottom Up
imposing levies.” People said the rules are designed to favor certain local
government officials who themselves own businesses in the community.
In many communities by lakes or coastal waters, fishing in shallow waters
has been banned to protect dwindling fisheries. Poor fishermen do not have
the necessary equipment to fish safely in deeper waters, with their currents and
storms. In Maguli, Ruvuma, Tanzania, such a change in the law led to the death
of four poor fishermen who ventured into deep waters in their small canoes.
In Afghanistan, the ban against growing poppy has imposed great hardships in the absence of other viable livelihood choices. Many people told us
that when they returned to their lands with nothing and started rebuilding
their houses and farms, the only way to survive was to cultivate poppy. In one
community, people said, “There was no hope for us in Pakistan, and we were
only waiting to see our country achieve independence and to return. We were
finally able to come back in 2002. We were very happy but also afraid to see
what had become of our village. Once we were back, poppy cultivation was
the only way we had to improve our damaged economy.” In another village,
the groups said, “People have lost everything—their tools, their houses, their
properties, and even their families. Poppy was the only income for us, first,
because poppy does not need a lot of water to grow, and second because the
income we get when we sell it is five times higher than for other common
crops, wheat or barley.” Although few would argue that poppy growing should
be legal, it is indisputable that laws against it have penalized poor people. It is
imperative to give poor people other attractive livelihood alternatives, for the
sake of the antidrug policy’s success as well as for sheer fairness.
Corruption
Money, money, money! There is no responsibility or accountability from
authorities and government officials.
—Discussion with men and women, Somrampi, Cambodia
They say first keep money in our hands. Then you will see magic.
—Discussion with men, Appilepalle, Andhra Pradesh
Corruption appears to be widespread across the study regions. Overall, 70
percent of the communities reported dealing with corrupt government officials,
and 50 percent reported that all or almost all local officials are corrupt. The numbers from our household survey are not very different: 60 percent of respondents
on average said that bribe taking is omnipresent (figure 6.6). By and large, the
never poor report more extensive corruption, which probably reflects their more
frequent contacts with local governments as they run their businesses.
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
245
100
90
80
71
70
68
62
60
62
58
49
50
61 59
55 54
46
39
40
32
30
25
20
22
15
10
G
m
(E
M
te
H
as
(C
(S
BA
N
AP
P
U
)
po
w
AL
)
U (In
G
A fra)
(P
M ane
EX
l)
(
SE Ethn
N
)
(
PH Infr
I ( a)
Pa
TA ne
W N l)
(R
B
(L uv
an )
TH ddi
A st)
IN (In
D
O eq)
(
AF Con
G
f)
(C
PH on
I ( f)
CO Co
n
AS L ( f)
SA Co
M nf)
(C
on
f)
0
)
% households reporting most or almost all
officials engage in corruption
FIGURE 6.6
More than half of households across study contexts believe that most or almost
all government officials in the country engage in corruption
Nonconflict study region
Conflict study region
Source: Authors’ analysis using household survey; N = 8,215.
Note:
AFG (Conf) = Afghanistan, Conflict
AP (SHG) = Andhra Pradesh, Self-help groups
ASSAM (Conf )= Assam, Conflict
BAN (Empow) = Bangladesh, Women’s
empowerment
COL (Conf) = Colombia, Conflict
INDO (Conf) = Indonesia, Conflict
MAL (Infra) = Malawi, Infrastructure
MEX (Ethn) = Mexico, Ethnicity
PHI (Conf) = Philippines, Conflict
PHI (Panel) = Philippines, Panel study
SEN (Infra) = Senegal, Infrastructure
TAN (Ruv) = Tanzania, Ruvuma
THAI (Ineq) = Thailand, Inequality
UGA (Panel) = Uganda, Panel study
UP (Caste) = Uttar Pradesh, Caste
WB (Landdist) = West Bengal, Land distribution
reforms
In Uttar Pradesh, where over 70 percent of households mentioned corruption, discussion group after discussion group complained that bribes are
needed to launch any new livelihood. Bribes are demanded for getting a land
record signed or obtaining a license to start a business. In the village of Rahamat, women said, “For farming, the big officers close the deals. They don’t do
any work without taking money. How will we pay money when we can’t even
fill our stomachs?” Men concurred, “You need a license to start a business. It
may be anything—opening a meat shop, rearing hens—all need a license. The
licenses are distributed at the district level, and the middlemen make money
246
Success from the Bottom Up
for giving them. People usually pay up to save themselves from trouble.” In
Piprawan, Lakhimpur, young women agreed, “You have to first place money
in their hands and then they sign.” The stories were similar in Andhra Pradesh,
where bribes were needed for everything, from participation in food-for-work
programs to obtaining caste, income, old age, and even death certificates.
Some likened corruption to “water spreading under a mat.”
In Bangladesh, young people reported bribe taking as among the most
serious constraints to their ability to fulfill their aspirations. Nasima, a young
woman, said, “Previously, a word of mouth was enough to get a job. Now it is
impossible to get a job without paying a bribe.” Young women in Konchala,
Bangladesh, commented, “The local leaders take bribes for giving jobs at Eco
Cotton Mill. They take 5 taka every day from the girls who are given jobs.”
Youth, particularly in the South Asian context, often express a desire to find
government jobs, which, once obtained, are held for life. Giving bribes to obtain
these jobs is considered part of the process that will later lead to receiving. In
Barbakara, Assam, young men said, “Who does not think about giving money
these days? If they get a job, it takes only a short time to get back the money.”
Across contexts, most people seem more or less resigned to corruption as
a way of life. Bribery is seen as a necessary evil if one wants access to government services.16 In Kaludoma, Ruvuma, Tanzania, bribes are the only way
to “ensure fast service being delivered.” In a community in Uganda, a man
explained, “The leaders in this place are so free that they can even enjoy corruption. We are so enslaved that they can ask us for bribes, and we give them
because if we do not do so, they will imprison us. Who wants to go to prison?
Why can’t I give him 2,000 [shillings] and be free?”
Overall, with the exception of Malawi, bribery appears to be less prevalent in the African communities than in the South Asian or conflict-affected
communities. The lowest bribery numbers were in Thailand; these were confirmed by qualitative data in which Thai communities praised their local
governments. In West Bengal, relatively low levels of bribe taking may be
related to a culture of equality promoted by the socialist government; more
likely, distribution of benefits in the state is determined by party affiliation
rather than by direct bribes.
Corruption, of course, goes beyond bribe taking to include any misuse
of public office and resources for private gain. In some senses, the practice
becomes a two-way street: people ask for favors with the expectation that
they will have to give something in return. Often this something is money;
sometimes it is political support or merely respect. Thus, the lines of callers
outside the offices or homes of elected officials are long as people pay their
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
247
dues. This veneration of politicians is limited strictly to their term in office.
People in the village of Chedulla, Andhra Pradesh, noted, “If the wife or
some relative of the powerful person dies, everyone will weep. If the powerful
person himself dies, no one will visit the family and console them.” Once a
politician departs, naturally or via the ballot box, allegiance shifts to the next
person who “sits in the chair.”
In our household survey, we asked respondents whether at any time in
the past 10 years they had met, called, or written a letter to a local politician. If the answer was yes, the interviewer asked whether the respondent
had done so for a personal matter or a public issue. Across our sample, more
than 75 percent of the households surveyed had contacted a local politician
for private matters. There were no major differences between those who had
moved out of poverty and others on this score. In South Asia (the Indian
states, Bangladesh, and Afghanistan), this percentage was as high as 90 percent. Only in some of the African contexts did we see a reverse trend. For
instance, in Ruvuma, Tanzania, equal numbers had approached local politicians for public and private matters.
These findings may help explain the variation in the crowding-out effects
of local democracy. When people approach politicians only for their selfinterest, having their individual problem resolved may lead to others being
left out. These effects are more likely to emerge in places with low levels of
economic development, where even basic service delivery requires political
connections and where the government and politicians have some resources
to distribute, as they do in South Asia.
A final excerpt from an animated discussion group with young men in
Bangladesh on democracy and corruption:
Noor: One has to pay for a job.
Ibrahim: Not everyone accepts bribes. There are some good people too.
Noor: Your brother, Ibrahim, now that he has a government job, will also accept
bribes. He got the job by paying 100,000 taka. Doesn’t he have to recover the
money?
The group erupted into laughter. The cycle of corruption continues.
Does corruption help or hurt mobility?
Like dogs at burial grounds, they [government officials] look for money
for every work.
—Discussion group, Vellamaddi, Andhra Pradesh
248
Success from the Bottom Up
Although corruption is clearly a bad thing, we wondered whether the
pervasive corruption we encountered might nonetheless have helped some
poor people move out of poverty. We therefore tested the association between
MOP and corruption using multivariate linear regression analysis (for detailed
results, see appendix 6). Our measure captures corruption levels 10 years ago
on a four-point scale, ranging from a few to almost all local government officials engaging in bribery and corruption.17
We found that corruption mostly has a negative association with MOP,
significantly so in Uttar Pradesh, Bangladesh, Senegal, and Mexico (figure
6.7). In other words, the greater the corruption, the harder it is for people
in these contexts to move out of poverty. The impact of corruption in Uttar
Pradesh is striking. An increase in the incidence of corruption among local
government officials from “almost none” to “almost all” is associated with
a 10.2 percent decrease in MOP. In other words, it is sufficient to offset the
influence that land and education, together, have on a household’s chances
of escaping poverty.
In several study regions, however, there is a positive association between
corruption and moving out of poverty. In Tanzania (Ruvuma), and Indonesia, the relationship is strong and statistically significant. In these contexts,
even after controlling for other factors including responsiveness, corruption
FIGURE 6.7
Corruption has a mostly negative association with moving out of poverty
Coefficient and Standard Errors: MOP and Corruption
MAL
Propensity to move out of poverty
0.4
THAI
0.2
TAN
PHI
INDO
ASSAM
0
UP
WB
AP
UGA
BAN
MEX
SEN
–0.2
Study region
Source: Multivariate linear regression analysis using data from household survey and community questionnaire (see appendix 6).
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
249
facilitates movement out of poverty. This finding suggests that poor people
who can afford it can bribe their way out of poverty. In Ruvuma, for instance,
a change in corruption levels from the minimum (almost no local government officials are corrupt) to the maximum (almost all are corrupt) increases
the likelihood of moving out of poverty by 18 percent. Owning assets at the
beginning of the study period helps: a unit change in assets is associated with
a 7.6 percent increase in MOP. But clearly, assets do not help as much as being
able to bribe corrupt local officials.
The widespread practice of bribe taking, although annoying to those
forced to pay up, does not appear to detract from the legitimacy of the state.
In fact, despite the negative association between corruption in local government and their mobility, respondents in study contexts like South Asia
seemed to want more government intervention rather than less. This mirrors
the finding of Di Tella and MacCulloch (2007) that people who perceive
corruption to be high in their contexts tend to support more government
intrusion into economic matters. When corruption is high, left-leaning politicians’ rhetoric against corruption finds support and results (paradoxically)
in public support for more government intervention. It is also possible that
when poor people find markets rigged and impenetrable, they place their
faith in government delivery.
Elite capture
After being elected, the chairman and members become blind; they eat up
all the aid received from the government.
—Piara, female farmer and mover, Digbari, Bangladesh
Elite capture is pervasive at the local level. Theory predicts it.18 Empirics
support it.19 Not surprisingly, we found ample evidence of elite capture in
our study villages, where it further diminishes the resources flowing to poor
people.
For poor women and men, power and privilege are big obstacles to
accessing the programs supposedly targeted to them. In 1997, the farming
village of Matdombo in Malawi suffered a prolonged drought that led to
great hunger. The government announced that each household in the village
would receive 10 kilograms of free fertilizer and 1 kilogram of free maize in
what were called “starter packs,” handed out under the government’s targeted
input program. The distribution of these packs, however, was not neutral. A
discussion group of men explained, “We registered our names with the village chief, but our names didn’t come out each and every time we did so. We
250
Success from the Bottom Up
didn’t get anything while some households got more than three packs. The
rule was one pack for each household!” The women added, “The leaders [the
village headman and his councilors] made a list of all households. But when
they went aside, they removed the names of some people, and in place of
them they wrote down the names of their children who do not even stay in
the village. Their children then sold fertilizer and maize at a higher rate and
made money.” Young boys in the village scoffed, “He [the leader] even wrote
down the names of his former wives, whom he divorced a long time ago,
while many people well qualified for the program received no packs.”
“The poorest have nowhere to complain,” lamented men and women in
another discussion group in Matdombo. “Sometimes they are given things
as handouts, but these things do not reach them because those who give out
the things deal with the well-to-do, and the things end up in the hands of the
well-to-do. Power is desirable because it comes with fringe benefits.”
Elite capture affects everything—seeds and fertilizers, jobs and scholarships, credit, land, public services such as health clinics, even cemeteries.
Absurdly, the elite have even figured out how to capture pure public goods
such as roads. People in Namdenye, a village in Ruvuma, Tanzania, described
how a local investor had virtually captured the feeder road linking the village
to the main highway. The investor reportedly purchased land that started at
the road junction and covered the whole feeder road up to the village, so that
the feeder road now passes through his private property. After buying it, he
fenced his property and demolished the signage at the road junction. With
the feeder road inaccessible, the villagers have to traverse bushy and steep
slopes to reach the main road. Mohamedi, a village resident, spoke of the
incident bitterly. “We have been cut off from the government. Even if the district education officer wants to visit our school, he will never find it, as there
is no sign showing where the school is located.” The villagers also fear that
crop buyers will be unable to reach the village.
How to acquire power and become an elite
Without money, everything is empty. If you have money, you can even get
tiger’s milk.
—A young man, Dhamalia, Assam
The upper castes are the dominating people with power. When they speak,
they speak with guns in their hands.
—Discussion with women, Jugsana, Uttar Pradesh
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
251
Money comes from the party. When a bridge is constructed, money is
demanded. Money is extorted at gunpoint. One feels strong when he does
politics.
—A man, Hasanbagh, Bangladesh
Elites clearly have many powers and privileges. So we asked our respondents: How do people become elites?
Acquire wealth. Across study regions, everyone was clear that the surest
way to acquire power was to acquire money, through legal or illegal means.
Money opens the way to education, jobs, and connections; it conveys the
power to do good deeds or bad deeds. In the village of Nasher Khan, Afghanistan, people quoted a proverb: “If the hand is full, it does not matter if it is
full of bees.” In Bangladesh and India, where tigers have become rare, “the
milk of the tigress is available if one has money.”
In a Bangladeshi village, young Masum said, “Money is everything. If you
spend money, you can buy the police and the administration, and people will
be afraid of you.” In Digbari, young men told us, “Being rich is the easiest
route to acquiring power. Many things can be done if one has money. You can
roam around with followers and speak in a loud voice.”
One can gradually acquire a measure of power by getting out of poverty.
A youth in Hathina, Uttar Pradesh, described the process, “It is akin to drops
of water collecting gradually to fill in a pot. As a person slowly moves up
and out of poverty, he starts gaining power. Then there is everything at your
disposal.”
Be born into the right family. In many places, people spoke about the continuity of elite status across generations and about the importance of having
“ancestral property” or other inherited wealth. In Mechiri, Andhra Pradesh,
men explained, “Yes, there are economically well-off people in the community who are very powerful. But none of these people have become powerful
recently. We have only those who have been powerful from generations, as
they own ancestral properties.” In Kodola, Uganda, men and women defined
inherited power as power obtained “when one is born in a rich and powerful
family. That person will always have power over others.”
Belong to the right social group. The genesis of economic and political
power often lies in social power, and those with the good fortune to be born
into the privileged caste, ethnicity, or religion have a huge head start. In many
of our study communities, “horizontal inequalities” (Stewart 2001) between
socially constructed groups are important in determining the distribution of
power and privilege.
252
Success from the Bottom Up
In India, caste continues to be a great divider, even as changes are reported
in many places. A woman from the village of Ibrahimpur, Uttar Pradesh, spoke
of how the lower-caste villagers live in constant fear of their Thakur (uppercaste) landlords. “We live here as if a tongue between the teeth. The Thakurs are
the teeth and the lower castes are the tongue. If they [the lower castes] commit
a mistake, then the tongue will be cut off.” In the village of Jugsana in Agra district, the upper castes are doubly powerful because of their money and weapons. Our findings from Uttar Pradesh suggest that scheduled caste households
are significantly less likely to move out of poverty than other social groups.
In communities affected by conflict in eastern Sri Lanka, ethnicity is an
important criterion influencing access to government programs. Young girls
in the community of Thambulla in Ampara asserted that local government
programs reach only the dominant social group in each locality. “If there is
a program in the village with a majority of Muslims, they benefit more compared to other ethnic groups. In a village with a majority of Tamil families,
the Tamils get more benefits than other groups. There is no equal distribution
among the village.”
In communities in Afghanistan, people belonging to different tribes
within the same ethnic group have different levels of power. A discussion
group in Shazimir said, “The Hazaras coming from Turkmen are not as free
and powerful because they are strict. This comes from their low education
level. They do not allow their daughters to get education and never let their
women go out for work. The people from Ghazni are more broad minded.
Although they are Hazara, they are educated, have awareness and money, and
also have more freedom.”
Over time, social definitions of which group is elite may change through
migration (Gupta and Sharma 1991), conflict, or electoral success. In Uttar
Pradesh, government policies on land distribution and the reservation of
some panchayat seats for lower castes have combined with electoral trends to
shift some power from the upper-caste Thakurs to the other backward castes
(OBC) and even the Dalits.20 In the village of Nagara, where the village head
comes from the Lodhi caste, only households belonging to the Yadav and
Lodhi (OBC) community have access to Kisan credit cards for buying agricultural equipment. The electoral sweep by the Bahujan Samaj Party, a political party of traditionally excluded caste groups, in state elections in Uttar
Pradesh in 2007 suggests that they may now have a greater chance of catching
up with other caste groups.
Join a political party. Acquiring wealth can take years, and birth into the
right family and social group is under no one’s control. Joining a politi-
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
253
cal party and becoming associated with political leaders—the bigger the
better—is another, perhaps faster way to power and elite status.
It is in South Asia, especially West Bengal and Bangladesh, that acquiring
power via politics was mentioned most frequently. In part this may reflect
the existence of large government transfer programs in the region, many of
them targeted to the poor. In West Bengal villages, people reported that government benefits and jobs are distributed only to party members, including
poor members. A women’s discussion group in Anakha said, “If common
men want to acquire power, the easiest way is to join politics. After joining
politics, government money helps to start a business. Through the party, one
can easily acquire power. Here there are some people who do not work much,
but they work for the panchayat leader and other party leaders. Thus, from
the party they get financial benefit. They get loans and below-poverty-line
cards [entitling them to targeted benefits], and they do not have to think
much about their income.”
Across the border in Bangladesh, discussion groups described how one
could rise by starting as a party worker, moving up to the thana and then the
district level, and finally becoming connected with ministers in the central
government. Manikjan explained, “After finishing studies, many learn politics through close association with the leaders of the Awami League or the
Bangladesh Nationalist Party. After becoming chairmen or members, they
rise to prominence through good comportment with people, distribution of
cards, old age pension, widows’ allowance, relief goods, etc. They earn the
heart of the people and slowly move up.” Not everyone was so sanguine. As
in West Bengal, many people in Bangladesh also reported that government
programs targeted to poor households were distributed instead to “boot lickers and party cadres.”
How to become a politician
You need money to engage in politics. If you do not have money, how can
you hold campaigns? How will you buy people something to drink?
—A man, Bugokela, Kagera, Tanzania
A local politician must engage personally: be honest, be polite, be correct,
and show love and concern for the village good.
—Discussion with women, Koldiaye, Senegal
Only those who have money and goons with them are in politics. They eat
other people’s money and don’t even belch.
—Discussion with young women, Pittupur, Uttar Pradesh
254
Success from the Bottom Up
Someone who climbs steadily through the party ranks may in time
become a politician. People identified three attributes that could help a person rise to elite status this way: money, personal character and good deeds,
and finally muscle and guns.
Money. Not all politicians start out rich, but all successful politicians have
to tap into financial resources from somewhere. It is easiest when they start
with their own wealth. In Kagera, Tanzania, and elsewhere, some of the local
government officials also own large businesses. The necessity to spend money
on campaigns in democratic systems and the culture of favor mongering it
generates have led to a worldwide clamoring for campaign finance reform,
with relatively little success.21 In Andhra Pradesh, people described traffic
jams caused by politicians visiting villages at election time. In the village of
Kotham, groups said, “At the time of elections, it is like a small festival, as
everyone is bribing people with alcohol and money. Contestants pay money
to the voters for getting votes.” Men in the village of Dhampur noted, “On the
day of the festival of votes [election], the politicians make many promises like
giving us wages, and they take us in autos and make us vote for them. They
give us money, as if only the rich should rule.”
In Afghanistan, candidates distributed free mobile handsets to poor
people. In the village of Mpusola, Malawi, rich political aspirants provided
free coffins whenever someone died. They attended different church services
and donated substantial amounts of money during the offerings. Men and
women in the community acknowledged that such practices do not always
lead to wise voting. “Before we vote, we assess the candidates’ homes to see
what they own. This is the reason we are having problems—we are choosing
people based on their wealth and not because they can help us. We look at
their car and we think that they are going to give us a ride in it, not knowing
that all we are ever going to get is dust after they pass us on the road.”
Personal characteristics and good deeds. Despite the shenanigans at election
time, people want their local politicians to have desirable human qualities
and to help their communities prosper. The qualities mentioned most frequently were being friendly and approachable, being concerned about the
welfare of the community, and bringing in government projects to the community. Trust, honesty, and integrity were high on the agenda. Some people
also called for education and knowledge and the ability to lead.
In Indonesia, women’s groups in Tattantok said that politicians should
be honest, wise, friendly, and united with the people. In Delapong, Philippines, the politician “must show a pleasant personality. He should know how
to get along with people. He should be easily approached, especially in times
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
255
of emergency.” Women in Barumangga, Indonesia, suggested that politicians
“win people’s hearts by doing positive things—by giving food to people, and
so on.” Respondents in Thailand were the most demanding, perhaps reflecting the Buddhist value of being self-effacing. In Nong Tong, a youth group
said that a local politician “should not be conceited or arrogant, should be
personable, should not defame others, and should not use his power to bully
the villagers. When the local politician gets elected, he should seek funds for
village development activities.”
In most regions, people acknowledged that it is possible to be elected
without being rich. In Kamlondo, Uganda, a men’s discussion group expected
the local politician to “be sincere, come from a good family, and deliver what
he promises.” They added, “Our chairman was elected by us. He never gave us
sugar or soap. We elected him on merit.” In several communities in Andhra
Pradesh, people reported that poor men from the lowest caste had been
elected because of their reputation, without spending much money on elections, although they were probably aided by the system of reserved seats.22
However, the ability to win elections without wealth is rare. People in Baroygor, Philippines, went so far as to say that candidates without money have
“zero chance of winning.”
Muscle and guns. With disheartening frequency, people in many South
Asian communities report that the way to political power is through threats
and guns. In Tihuliya, Uttar Pradesh, young men described a powerful person as one “who has tons of money, the size of their family is large, there is
unity in the family. He has criminal habits, keeps a dagger and a gun, and
two to four followers are always with him.” In another village, Kursi, young
men stated, “If one wants to become a leader, he must have four to six criminal cases against him.” Across at least half of the villages visited in the state,
getting into politics required goondagardi (hooliganism) and guns. In some
villages, people reported that the goons wait with crossed arms at polling
booths and openly say, “If you don’t vote for the pradhan [village head], we
will make life difficult for you.” Our respondents added, “We want to stay
alive. Who wants to be beaten up? We want to live in peace, so we vote as they
say.” A popular local proverb, jiski lathi uski bhains, which roughly translates
as “whoever has the stick owns the buffalo,” has been modified to “whoever has the gun owns the buffalo.”23 In Alampur, another village in Uttar
Pradesh, a women’s group affirmed, “Power means to create chaos and thrash
people. Power means to beat someone till the blood flows.”
Reminiscent of Chicago in the 1920s, people spoke about the importance of “muscle power,” the enforcers surrounding a politician. In Anakha,
256
Success from the Bottom Up
West Bengal, a men’s discussion group said, “Those who are sitting on the top
post of the party, they have bodyguards for their safety. And these people save
politicians when they face danger. Here people cannot speak against these
politicians because of their muscle power.” In Gangua, also in West Bengal, a
young women’s group said, “A gun is the source of all power. With a gun, one
can scare others, and rob the power from others’ clutches. The politicians in
this community do have such power.”
In Bangladesh, politicians were described as dacoits or bandits. For aspiring politicians, committing crimes and even going to prison can be a good
career move. “Someone can become a leader out of anger, murder, and imprisonment. While [he is] in prison, there are posters all around with political
writings about [him]. This way a politician captures the eyes of all.”
When power is absolute and misused, people sometimes respond with
the “weapons of the weak,” notably humor and sarcasm. Irshad related the
following during a men’s discussion group in Chanpasha, Bangladesh:
My mother had died on Sunday, 10 September. Five months later, when I
went to the polling booth to cast my vote, I learned that my mother had
already voted. I kept on weeping. My mother had descended from heaven,
voted and had left without even meeting me! The army people threw me
out after giving me a good bashing. I had a good education about the definition of power on election day.
Is There Any Hope: Can Local Democracy Be Uncaptured?
Rich people are buying politicians to enjoy opportunity.
—Discussion with women, Baintala, West Bengal
They do not call the poor for opinions. Only the wealthy ones are invited.
—A woman, Digbari, Bangladesh
Now people in the community are being consulted. We are more aware
of what is happening during the meetings. Promises are being kept. Local
leaders have become more modest and more easily accessible than before.
—Discussion group, Lamraab, Morocco
It may seem naïve to be optimistic about the power of local democracy
to do any good for poor people, but despite guns and goons, it is already
doing good in some places. Indeed, in some places, ratings of government
responsiveness have changed for the better over the last 10 years, sometimes
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
257
quite dramatically. Even deeply corrupt local democracies are not immutable.
Chicago changed. There is hope.
Overall, nearly half of the communities across the study regions experienced no changes in their local democracies or in the way they functioned.
But there was some improvement. One-third of the communities visited
reported that their local government now pays more attention to their concerns, suggesting that change is possible. Moreover, the communities where
such a positive shift took place outnumbered by nearly two to one the communities where local democracies’ attention to citizen concerns had declined
over time (32 percent compared to 17 percent).
In this section, we examine the question of what makes local governments more responsive. We have already described some of the positive
associations between responsiveness, improved infrastructure for communities, and improved livelihoods for poor people. Our data reveal one other
important finding about responsiveness: communities that rated their local
government as highly responsive also had remarkably lower corruption.
Sixty-eight percent of communities where people rated local government as
highly responsive had no or almost no corruption. By contrast, 68 percent
of communities where government was unresponsive reported that most or
almost all local government officials were corrupt and took bribes.
In The Burden of Democracy, political scientist Pratap Bhanu Mehta (2003)
writes that chronic poverty coupled with a lack of accountability has kept
Indian democracy from fulfilling its main function, which is to increase the
self-respect of all individuals. The “burden of democracy,” then, is to find a
way to recover a sense of morality and responsibility.
Although guided by theory, we remain empiricists about what makes
local democracy work in practice. Given low levels of literacy, high levels
of poverty, and many forms of “illiberal electoral democracy” in contexts
of deeply embedded social inequality, we do not take for granted that local
elections or people’s participation necessarily create responsive democracies. Once again, we gave primacy to people’s own narratives as we combed
through hundreds of pages of notes from communities and combined this
qualitative data with some quantitative data.24 We came up with five factors that appear to be important in unlocking local democracy so that it
works more effectively for poor women and men. These are good leaders;
local elections; information, particularly about local government; participation; and people’s organizations. The mechanisms that make these factors
effective are context-specific and difficult to unravel in our cross-country
sweep.
258
Success from the Bottom Up
Give me a great local leader
What interests us about our leaders is not wealth but humility, integrity,
and putting forward the public benefit.
—Discussion with men, Djatick, Senegal
It is difficult to talk to those high, literate officials. Probably some of them
have no knowledge of our lives and are afraid to come near us because we
smell.
—Discussion group, Salvia Prey, Cambodia
The farming village of Tattantok in East Java, Indonesia, is one of the communities in which responsiveness ratings of local democracy changed from
negative to positive during the decade. A relatively prosperous Muslim community, it has an active and educated youth population, but there have been
problems with internal conflict, gambling, and theft of animals and crops.
The turning point in the community’s prosperity was identified as a change
in local leadership in 2003. Discussion groups explained, “Before 2003, theft
and gambling happened all over the place. Since 2003, gambling has been
eradicated. . . . Because of the village head’s initiative, there was a meeting that
asked the village representatives to help stop gambling.” A discussion group of
women reported, “The 2003 election of the current klebun [village head] was
the turning point. We were not happy with the former klebun because he could
not fight for people. He only helped those who were close to him. The current
klebun fights for us.” Participation levels and service delivery in the community
improved with the arrival of the new village head. The men continued, “Before,
the green cards [for health insurance] existed, but they didn’t reach the people. The cards were distributed to those who were closest to the former village
head.” The women were pleased that they were now encouraged to participate
in village meetings. One said, “The building of the current primary school is
an example. I made the suggestion that it should be made in an L-shape. They
agreed with the idea, and now it is being built in an L-shape.”
A majority of communities where democracy ratings improved over the
study period identified good leadership as the most important reason for the
change. A selfless leader who has “a heart for the community”—as the people
of Bukwaime, Uganda, put it—can set a community on a path of development. In Kabtito, Uganda, good local leadership has brought some community development programs into the village and has led to improvement in
peace and security. A group of men and women in the village said they can
now approach the local village council directly on any matter.
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
259
For study communities in Afghanistan, the malek plays a crucial role in
bringing improvements to his people. Bibi, a 60-year-old woman in Riah Khillaw, Herat province, praised the leader of the newly elected provincial council
in her village, “Mohammed Nasir is a member of the Welayati shura. He is
from our community and is now living in Kabul, but he helped the community get electricity and water.” In Ramili Qali, Parwan, the malek, who is also
head of the local agricultural cooperative, took the initiative to seek out help
for his community. During our field team’s interview with him, he asked if
we could mention the community to a particular person working for a French
agricultural cooperative in the area in order to secure the cooperative’s help.
By the same token, a corrupt head who works with his coterie of supporters, ignoring the voice of the majority, can prove disastrous for a community.
We heard many reports of corrupt, venal leaders who mostly used the local
democracy and its programs for their own good or as a vehicle for political
patronage—what Bardhan (2002) calls “jobs for the boys.”
Free and fair elections increase accountability and responsiveness
The leaders know that if they do not give us attention, especially about
problems we face in our area, we will not reelect them. As a result, they
make sure that they take keen interest in community affairs.
—Mukyala, a farmer, Lulyunka, Uganda
We do not know who our representatives are or how to get them. We know
only that they come in a vehicle that belongs to the government.
—Women’s discussion group, Mpusola, Malawi
In their research on the success of gram panchayats in implementing land
reforms in West Bengal, Bardhan and Mookherjee (2004, 2006) found that
greater effort went into land reform in places where local elections were strongly
contested by the two rival political parties in the state, the Left Front and the
Congress Party. Reform efforts were less intense in areas that were leftist voting strongholds. Bardhan and Mookherjee conclude that the level of political
contestation and vote share has a critical effect on responsiveness, a perspective
shared by other political scientists. A guaranteed constituency and slack political
competition means that ruling parties have less need to satisfy voter demands.
Across our study contexts, people referred to elections as a powerful tool for
holding their local politicians accountable. This was reaffirmed by the positive
and significant association between voting and the measure of responsiveness
of local democracy in virtually all study regions in our model (see annex 6.2).
260
Success from the Bottom Up
Afghanistan is a case in point. In the Afghan study communities, people
said that the election of community development councils under the auspices of the National Solidarity Program (NSP) has brought local leadership closer to the people.25 Each council includes 15 male members and 15
female members who deliberate separately and share their decisions. Once
elected, the council organizes village consultations on projects to be financed
by an NSP grant. Communities are involved in decision making about project
design and implementation.
The council in Ramili Qali, a community close to Kabul, was a typically
well-functioning one. Elections to the council had reportedly been open and
fair. “All the people voted on their own choices,” said a group of youths.
“They voted with a special zeal and without fear for their favorite candidates.”
The council heard from women and youth and was open to fresh ideas and
opinions from them. A women’s discussion group said the district officer
could no longer “do everything by his own wish. He is now consulting with
the general public and accepts their ideas.” The women’s council voted to
equip the village with two 40-kilowatt generators that provide about four
hours of electricity at night to all the houses in the village. The men’s council
voted for the rehabilitation of culverts and small irrigation structures that
help farmers regrow the grapevines burned during the conflict.
While elections in Afghanistan are a means to establish a democratic structure after the anarchy of war, in other contexts they are seen as a way to motivate local politicians to deliver on their promises. In Rahamat, Uttar Pradesh, a
discussion group of men explained, “The focus in democracy is on the people.
Work is done at a fast pace, and now with election time, the politicians get work
done soon to woo the public. Last year, a school was built in our village. A road
was made as well, and this has left a good impact on the people.”
But the mere ability to vote is not sufficient. Elections are not always
free and fair. While elections in some contexts tend to be transparent—particularly in the East Asian study regions, in Morocco, and in Afghanistan—in
other places, respondents complained about the conduct of elections. A discussion group of women in Mpusola, Malawi, asserted, “We do not choose
politicians. We are asked only to vote. The district officials just come here
and say that we have chosen this person to be your councilor or member
of parliament, so you should vote for him during elections. So we vote for
a person whom we do not know because we don’t have a choice.” Men and
women in Chakboeng, Cambodia, told a similar story. “We did go to vote,
but we do not know or even care about whether the electoral process was free
and fair. We just think and care about how to make a living. We got nothing
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
261
from the election except the black paint on our finger” (the ink used to show
that someone has voted).
Even fairly elected leaders, of course, can disappoint. In almost all the
study regions, there were reports of elected officials and politicians reneging
on their mandates. In Yasapira, North Maluku, Indonesia, women spoke of the
“rubber promises” of politicians. Politics is all about “telling lies” for one of the
villages in Kagera, Tanzania. A discussion group said, “You just have to know
how to speak a lot, make people laugh and forget what you said, so that when
you come back, they do not ask you what you had promised.” In Troula Trav,
Cambodia, a discussion group put it this way, “Before the elections we are like
small babies who are taken care of. But after . . . when they win . . . they are like
stars in the sky. They do not care about us anymore.” In Nasher Khan, Nangarhar, Afghanistan, a young girl reported that the local politician had quite
literally taken back what he had promised, “We remember one candidate. He
came here before the elections and gave us several sewing machines. But when
he lost, he came and took all of them back.” Universal suffrage is clearly not
enough to ensure good leadership and policies that benefit poor people.
Information is power
Newspapers nowadays differ greatly from newspapers in the 1970s and
even the 1990s. TV has changed as well. They have unraveled many hidden truths. Nowadays, nothing can be veiled. Every day, we read things in
the newspaper we couldn’t even imagine reading before.
—Men’s discussion group, Tindyata, Morocco
Two-way information flows between citizens and their representatives are
critical for responsible citizenship and a responsive and accountable democracy. Informed citizens are better equipped to take advantage of opportunities, access services, exercise their rights, negotiate effectively, and hold state
actors accountable. Without timely information that is presented in forms
that can be understood, it is impossible for poor people to take effective
action (Narayan 2002b).
Several studies of decentralized governance have underscored the role
that easily accessible information can play in ensuring responsiveness. In the
city of Bangalore, India, for instance, citizen report cards are revolutionizing
the manner in which city residents relate to service providers (Paul 2007).26
In a panel study of major Indian states, Besley and Burgess (2002) document
the role local newspapers have played in increasing the responsiveness of state
governments to natural disasters. Reinikka and Svensson (2005) describe the
262
Success from the Bottom Up
impact of a media campaign informing local communities of their entitlement to school funds from the central government in Uganda. The campaign,
along with an increase in central government monitoring, reduced diversion
of funds for the project by provincial governments from 80 to 20 percent.
Our quantitative and qualitative evidence affirms the importance of
information. Our two measures, newspaper readership and access to information about local government programs, show a significant, positive association with our government responsiveness measure in several study contexts.
In fact, access to information about the local government is the single most
important factor out of 11 explanatory variables we hypothesized to be associated with responsiveness (annex 6.2).
Improved access to information is helping people monitor their local
governments in our study sites in Morocco. In Abzif, for example, a discussion group said, “Before, people didn’t feel protected against injustice. People
could not protest about what they had to put up with. Before, we couldn’t
bring up the wrongs committed by governmental representatives in front of a
court. But today we can. We are supported by lawyers, newspapers.”
In Senegal, the study communities have witnessed a considerable shift in
information sources. Independent small private radio stations provide news
about government and development projects, allowing the population to
monitor their government’s performance. Discussions with men in the village of Djatick revealed the changes. “Thanks to private radios, we can now
express our dissatisfaction if an elected official doesn’t do his job properly,
and we can sanction him/her in the next election. Our community now really
believes that it’s possible to remove a leader who doesn’t fulfill our demand.”
Women in Dapi Toube, Senegal, agreed, “We can denounce certain unfairness
thanks to the proliferation of media [private radio stations, mobile phones,
etc.]. Formerly, food that was intended for people used to be embezzled and
no one talked about it, but that is impossible now because of the media.”
Democracy is participation
In the past, we did not dare to get in touch with the civil servants. When
we talked to them, we were already shaking. But today we do not have to
be afraid at all.
—Men’s discussion group, Nong Tong, Thailand
The strong link between democracy and participation, underscored
decades ago by the liberation theologian Paulo Freire (1974), was reaffirmed
both in group discussions and in our quantitative data. Communities where
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
263
local government had become more responsive over time also had much
higher participation rates than those where responsiveness had decreased (62
percent versus 39 percent). In our regression analysis as well, we find positive
association between people’s participation in community decision making
and our measure of responsiveness of local democracy in most of the study
contexts, significantly so in some of them (annex 6.2). When participation
in decision making is real and translates into local government decisions,
democracies function for the benefit of all, as seen in the positive spillover in
our leave-out mean exercise reported earlier (figure 6.5). We found this to be
true in three contexts: Mexico, Thailand, and Andhra Pradesh.
In the state of Oaxaca, Mexico, where all the study communities are
indigenous, people’s participation is rooted in a traditional form of self-governance called usos y costumbres (literally, practices and customs). Under this
system, citizens have the right and obligation to vote in public assemblies on
governance issues. In the community of Guapa del Mar, a woman described
how the system works, “Any decision or problem is communicated to the
citizens, and it is not just the president who decides but the entire village.” A
young man praised the system as free from the danger of elite capture. “There
is no relation between political and economic power because the decisions
are taken by the community and are not taken by the persons who have economic or political power here in the community.” A 60-year-old man in the
community proclaimed with much pride, “There is no corruption or bribery
here; never has been.”
Study communities in Thailand reported a rise in what are called “village
civil society gatherings.” Eighty-four percent of all household survey respondents said that they participate more in consultation meetings now than in
the past. More than 60 percent reported that the Tambon Administrative
Organizations take into account their concerns and listen to their needs. The
village of Nong Tong is typical. A small hamlet of 52 households engaged in
paddy and vegetable farming, it has a village headman and a village committee that also elect a representative to the next-higher administrative level of
the tambon. The TAO and its members were generally reported to be responsive. It has built roads, formed different types of groups, and encouraged
people to participate in community affairs. Access to information through a
recently installed public broadcast tower has helped people demand accountability from their local government and “more distribution of authority to
the villagers.” Homjun, a paddy farmer in the village, said, “Satisfaction is
to see the people participating in activities.” Another man added, “There is
freedom and no abuse.”
264
Success from the Bottom Up
Not all communities are as fortunate in having meaningful participation. In
Upper Deuri, Assam, the village leaders are said to exclude ordinary people. “The
villagers cannot affect the decisions of the panchayat. Actually, the panchayat
does not give us a chance to speak about any decision. Every decision is taken by
a meeting in the gaon bura’s [village head’s] house or in the drawing room of the
president. We have nothing to do there,” reported a discussion group of men.
Discussion groups in Salvia Prey, Cambodia, spoke of exclusion based on wealth:
“The officials are too high and costly for us to contact, too far to reach and not
always available to talk to. We are down-to-earth, illiterate, and dirty.”
People’s organizations and self-help groups
Before I was just one person; now I am 10. And so I feel I would dare to go
up to any government official.
—Venkatlakshmi, member of a women’s self-help group,
Chedulla, Andhra Pradesh
As with the findings on participation, we find mostly a positive association between the numbers of groups in communities and responsiveness
levels in almost all study contexts (annex 6.2). The strongest findings emerge
from Bangladesh, known for large numbers of women’s groups formed
through well-established NGOs such as Grameen Bank, BRAC, ASHA, and
Proshika. Over time, the presence of the collective—just the fact that women
get together to undertake some activity—eventually spills over into local government performance.27
In Andhra Pradesh, there has been an explosion of women’s self-help
groups (SHGs) across the state. Ironically, these groups, formed under a statewide government-run program, are now challenging corrupt and inept government and elected officials. Illiterate women are getting organized, running
groups, managing savings and credit, and launching new income-generating
activities. In many communities, they have become a political force through
their sheer numbers.
In one incident, SHG members brought to account a corrupt teacher
working at the government school in the village. The teacher had demanded
Rs 200 (approximately US$5) extra from each student, causing one SHG
member to stop sending her child to school. The other women went to the
school to make inquiries. This situation rapidly turned into a confrontation,
at which point the SHG set a date for a formal meeting and informed the
teacher that she would be required to submit details of her expenditures on
that date to the groups. “She, the teacher, then got nervous and returned all
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
265
the money, and soon after that had herself transferred to another district,”
recounted our respondents with glee. They added, “Now we’re being called
for school functions and are invited to attend functions even by officials!”
As women’s self-help groups have become a social force in some areas,
local leaders have started to pay attention to women’s needs and women’s
votes. This attention, in turn, may have helped reduce levels of domestic violence in these communities. We found some evidence that communities with
low levels of domestic violence also have more responsive local democracies.
The association was significant in Uttar Pradesh, Senegal, Ruvuma (Tanzania), and Mexico (annex 6.2). To remove problems of endogeneity, violence
levels 10 years ago were considered; lower domestic violence then seems to be
associated with higher current responsiveness of local governments in some
study contexts. The mediating variable was civil society activism that over
time changed the norms around domestic violence, drinking, and respect
for women. This change, in turn, encouraged government to show greater
responsiveness toward women, treating them with respect and including
them in local decision making. In Andhra Pradesh, for instance, several of
the study communities with well-organized women’s self-help groups had
been successful in reducing the consumption of arak (locally brewed alcohol)
among men and the domestic abuse that often followed.
A Tale of Two Communities
De landlord is landlord, de politician is landlord, de judge is landlord, de
shurf [sheriff] is landlord, ever’body is landlord, en we ain’ got nothing.
—A Mississippi sharecropper’s testimony in 1936,
cited by Schulman (1994: 16)
As long as poor people are competing with richer groups who control
their livelihoods—and who also happen to be the political leaders and
magistrates in their community—poor people are likely to lose. Whether in
Mississippi or in Kagera, Tanzania, economic and political forms of power
inevitably converge to defy all policy attempts at change. Redistribution
schemes must be carefully designed if they are to overcome the self-interest of
powerful intermediaries and reach poor people. Interventions that improve
the functioning of local democracy, discussed above, improve poor people’s
chances of benefiting from targeted government programs.
However, there is another, less-explored way to achieve the same end,
which is to expand the economic pie at the local level rather than focusing
266
Success from the Bottom Up
only on redistribution.28 Benjamin Friedman, in The Moral Consequences of
Economic Growth (2005: 4), argues that across the Western world, a period
of economic growth, with rising incomes for the clear majority of citizens,
“more often than not fosters greater opportunity, tolerance of diversity, social
mobility, commitment to fairness and dedication to democracy.” When living standards stagnate or decline, most societies make little progress on these
goals and may indeed go backward.29
There are strong parallels in our community-level study. But we also find
that the extent of social stratification affects who benefits from economic
growth or opportunities at the local level. Let us look at two case studies of
village development from West Bengal.
Baral: Expanded opportunities for all
When our teams arrived in Baral, in the district of Purulia, West Bengal, the
village had been facing drought conditions for several years. Conditions were
so dire that the government of West Bengal had declared Purulia to be a “dry
district.” Most households in Baral depend on cultivation of rice, a crop that
is water intensive. With the failure of the rains, one would expect a substantial
proportion of people in Baral to have slipped into destitution.
In 1995, at the start of the study period, 72 percent of households sampled for the ladder of life exercise in the village were classified poor. Basic
infrastructure in Baral was primitive. The road connecting the village to the
district center was nonmetaled and muddy, making for a long, treacherous
commute to the local market. Though situated on the banks of a river, the village had no proper system of canals to bring river water to the fields. Dependent on the rains, people could harvest only one rice crop a year. Migration
out of the village was common. “Earlier, people of our village went to other
places to do daily labor,” recounted Padmalochan, a man participating in a
discussion group. “We cultivated our land only once and people went outside
and worked, even for a low wage.”
But a series of infrastructural and livelihood initiatives undertaken
by the state, district government, and local panchayat in Baral changed
all that. In 1995, the state government, working in coordination with the
local panchayat, implemented a Comprehensive Area Development Program that focused on agriculture. The centerpiece was efforts to improve
productivity of rice by creating seed banks of new high-yielding varieties and training local farmers to grow them. The difference in productivity when compared to native rice was substantial. “Earlier, we produced
10–12 mon of paddy from 1 bigha [of land]. But now we are getting 22–26
mon paddy,” explained women in a discussion group.30 The program also
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
267
helped households diversify their livelihood portfolios by training them in
activities such as dairy farming, fish farming, and cultivation of new crops.
It made available seeds and saplings of vegetables and flowers and particularly encouraged women to grow them.
In addition to providing agricultural training, the local panchayat in
Baral, with funds from the zilla parishad (the district council), was instrumental in the construction of a dam on the river and a network of canals.
Canal irrigation had brought multiple benefits to the farmers. About a third
of them had shifted to cultivating wheat. “They cultivate wheat in the winters
and sell it in the summer. They can get wheat seeds from the panchayat.” In
addition, the dam enabled people to take up fish farming, bringing in extra
income of at least Rs 35–45 per day.
Finally, the local panchayat had built a new metaled road connecting the
village to the local market and to the highway leading to the district center.
“There is a big market in Balrampur,” explained a discussion group of men.
“Businessmen come there from Jamshedpur [a prosperous industrial center
in West Bengal]. People who are cultivating fish sell it at 1–2 rupees profit
per kilogram. Those who cultivate wheat sell it at 1–2 rupees profit per kilogram.” This price was more than what producers had earned for their produce in the village market. The additional income rippled through the village
economy. Some households had opened small kiosks selling food and other
items along the road. Women reported, “The purchasing power of people has
increased. They are now buying things from the market for their family. For
instance, there are more grocery and sweet shops.”
Even villagers who survived on daily wage labor had benefited from the
building of the road and dam. They were employed by the panchayat on the
construction projects and were paid in both rice and money.
The result of all these initiatives was a substantial increase in income. By
2005, 50 percent of the households sampled for the ladder of life discussion
had moved out of poverty over the preceding decade. “We now have goddess
Lakshmi in our house,” exclaimed one of our key informants, referring to the
Hindu goddess of wealth.
Even more remarkable was the reported decrease in social and political
inequalities in the village. The opening up of markets reduced the stranglehold of the upper-caste elite. Bihari, an upper-caste man our team met, spoke
of the change. “We are Brahmins. Earlier our predecessors felt unsociable
toward the lower castes, so all the work in the village was done by lower-caste
people. But now even we are working and cultivating along with them.” Badal
added, “People of higher castes are now going to the houses of the lower
castes. They do not insult lower-caste people now.”
268
Success from the Bottom Up
The improvements also transformed the villagers’ relationship with the
panchayat. With expanded opportunities, daily wage laborers and small cultivators gained the courage to question their local officials on the workings
of local government. Most respondents agreed that there was no corruption
or bribe taking in the village, and elections were free and fair. Each time the
panchayat received an order to do any public work, it discussed the work in
a village assembly where everyone, including women, could give their opinions. If labor contractors refused to pay laborers after work was completed,
the laborers could go to the panchayat, which heard their grievances and took
action. Jagannath described the shift: “Earlier, the panchayat took one-sided
decisions. They did not consult with everyone. Now the opinion of the village people is taken into consideration. They can tell their discomfort and
problems. Because of the increase of work and wages, common people have
improved their position.” Over and over again, people said with great confidence, “We vote for a candidate who will work for us.”
Khalsi: Stagnation and discrimination
Life in Khalsi, another village in Purulia, presents a stark contrast. This village
also suffered from lack of proper roads and irrigation facilities in 1995—and
still does today. Lack of water has made it impossible for farmers to shift to
hybrid and higher-yielding varieties of rice. Aloka, a woman in the village,
described their plight: “Hybrid crops need sufficient water. Otherwise they
need manure. We cannot provide manure due to want of money, and the irrigation system of our village is pathetic. We are dependent on rain.” Without
a passable road, villagers cannot take their produce in vehicles to markets
and the district center. Women said, “If anybody wants to come to our village
or go from here, he has to walk on foot through a muddy road because no
vehicles want to enter through this road. But we have no other alternative.
The road is an obstacle in the path of improvement of our village. If we had
a metaled road leading from the main road to our village, then everyone in
the village would have benefited in every sphere.”
Ten years ago, just as in Baral, 71 percent of the population in Khalsi was
in poverty. But by 2005, only 15 percent of Khalsi households had moved out
of poverty. With limited options, many poor people migrated to nearby cities
for work—a tradition that had stopped in Baral.
The lack of opportunities in the village has left the social and political
dynamics unchanged. Young people described the many deeply embedded
discriminatory practices. “When a higher-caste person visits a lower-caste person, he has to bathe afterward [to wash off the pollution]. If a lower-caste
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
269
person drinks water or tea, you have to wash the utensils. The people of the
lower caste do not sit in the same row as the higher caste.”
Unlike the panchayat members in Baral, local officials in Khalsi were consistently described as corrupt, full of tricks, and uninterested in working for the
good of the community. Benefits were channeled along party lines. A men’s discussion group said, “Only those involved in the party are recipients of goats,
cows, and bullock carts for plowing. We get nothing. The panchayat members
and party leaders attend the meeting, and they take decisions about what kind
of work, where, when, and how they will do it. They also decide whom they will
pay. More than half the government aid is misappropriated by the party leaders
and members of the panchayat. The money is divided as booty among the party
members and the party bosses. There are no statements of accounts. Whatever
the panchayat says is right. It doesn’t matter if it is good or bad. Whatever they
say, we have to agree with them. Everything they pay is to the party members who
are engaged with the party. For others, they always ring the bell ‘not available.’”
A sense of frustration was evident across Khalsi. Men said, “We used
to visit the panchayat office earlier. But we visit the office only occasionally
now because they do nothing for us. They are busy looking after their own
benefits and the people close to them.” Young girls in the community had
the final word. “We don’t blame the CPM [ruling leftist party]. [But] we shall
have to bring new faces, leaving the old ones; only then improvement will be
possible. As they have been ruling for a long time, there is more corruption.
There will be no change in the coming days.”
Looking beyond the two cases
The contrasting stories of Baral and Khalsi show how the expansion of economic opportunity sets can help open up closed social systems and change
political dynamics in a community. To test whether this was true for other
communities as well, we return to our leave-out means on local democracy.
When the sign is positive, it means that all in the community gain. When the
sign is negative, it means that democracy is still functioning to benefit a few
at the expense of others.
We wanted to know whether an expansion in economic opportunities
in any way lessens the crowding-out effects of local democracy (the negative
sign). We constructed leave-out means for responsiveness of local democracy
(our indicator for crowding out) separately for communities that experienced
rising prosperity over the study period. We then compared them to the leaveout means for villages where prosperity declined.31 The results, reported in
table 6.2, reflect the variation in the depth of social stratification by caste in
270
Success from the Bottom Up
TABLE 6.2
Economic opportunities can create positive spillovers
LOM for responsiveness of local democracy
State
Bottom 33% of villages
ranked on net prosperity
Top 33% of villages ranked on
net prosperity
Uttar Pradesh
Significantly negative
Significantly more negative
West Bengal
Significantly negative
Positive
Assam
Significantly negative
Significantly more negative
Andhra Pradesh
Positive
Significantly more positive
the communities in our sample in the four Indian states. We note the pattern
of results but do not impute causality.
In West Bengal, in confirmation of our case study findings, the leave-out
mean indicator moved from negative to positive with increasing economic
prosperity, suggesting a process of “crowding in” rather than crowding out.
That is, all gain from local democracy as communities move from less prosperity to more prosperity. Three decades of communist rule in West Bengal
has broken the hold of caste; the most important social differentiator is now
political party affiliation, something that can be manipulated more easily
than the ascribed category of caste.
In Uttar Pradesh and Assam, on the other hand, increases in economic
opportunities aggravated exclusion as local democracy concentrated resources
in the hands of even fewer people. Uttar Pradesh is deeply stratified along
caste lines and has few people’s organizations that are not caste affiliated.
Assam, affected by protracted conflict and a large influx of people from Bangladesh, is in flux, with ethnic and religious divisions.
Andhra Pradesh has positive signs in communities with low economic
opportunity, and the sign even more strikingly becomes more positive in the
villages with high economic opportunity. All benefit from responsive local
democracies. As mentioned, women’s self-help groups have had a strong
positive effect on the responsiveness of local democracies.
In conclusion, we believe that an expansion of the economy can have
positive “moral consequences” (Friedman 2005), even at the micro level,
provided that there is some moderating influence on deep social inequalities.
These results suggest that democracy and participation of people in governance through poor people’s organizations can moderate the effect of deeply
embedded social inequalities on access to economic opportunities. Growth
alone will not automatically increase everyone’s access to expanding economic opportunities in an unequal social environment.
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
271
The expansion of economic opportunity is important but not sufficient.
Inequalities in access can be moderated either by building organizations of
poor people, by encouraging civil society activism, or by promoting government ideologies that support equity and dignity for all.
Conclusion: New Roles for Local Democracy—beyond
the Zero-Sum Game
Democracy is about something permanent, while politics is something that
changes every day.
—Discussion group, Gabunazi, Kagera, Tanzania
Our micro-level evidence demonstrates that poor people value the ideals
of democracy: freedom, rights, equality, participation, and justice. What is striking is that they also see an association between the responsiveness of their local
democratic structure—be it the shura in Afghanistan or the village executive
committee in Tanzania or the panchayat in India—and their attempts to move
out of poverty. While the broad characterizations of democracy as liberal or
illiberal may be helpful at the national level, to understand how the functioning
of democracy affects poor people’s lives, it is critical to focus on the disaggregated level of communities, districts, or provinces within countries. Ninety-three
percent of the variation in democratic functioning is within country.
Poverty discourses over the past 60 years have largely ignored political factors and political institutions, despite the recent focus on decentralization of
government functions, funds, and functionaries. Our study points to the critical
importance of improving local democracy to help people move out of poverty.
Given the existence of “coalitions of power” (Acemoglu and Robinson
2008), local democracy often functions as a zero-sum game. If some poor
people gain, others lose. In addition, our evidence suggests that local democracies often become corrupt and co-opted by the elite. The probability of
corruption, exclusion, and elite capture is higher in societies that are socially
stratified, where lines around social, economic, and political power converge.
We put some numbers on the negative effects of corruption to illustrate orders
of magnitude. In Uttar Pradesh, a unit increase in corruption decreases the
probability of moving out of poverty by 10 percent. It offsets the combined
positive effects of increasing ownership of land by 1 hectare and increasing
education from illiterate to primary-literate levels. In other places, when they
can afford it, poor people are buying their way out of poverty.
Fortunately, there are ways in which local democracy can be uncaptured
and kept accountable. They include promoting good leaders, ensuring the
272
Success from the Bottom Up
right to vote in free and fair elections, providing increased access to information about the local government, and supporting associational life and poor
people’s participation in community decisions. People’s organizations that
have legitimacy can play an important role in keeping governments accountable, especially when they achieve scale across localities. A political culture
that enshrines values of fairness and equity can also play an equalizing role
when economic opportunities expand.
It is important for policy makers to stop treating local government bodies mainly as channels for the distribution of goods and services that come
from the central and state governments—as players in a zero-sum game. Wellfunctioning local governments can be dynamic entities that help liberalize
the economy from below. They can do so by bringing in infrastructure, promoting agricultural improvements, encouraging households to diversify their
livelihoods, and demystifying rules and regulations that constrain entrepreneurship. As the economic pie expands, there is greater hope of diminishing
the importance of social differences in determining economic and political
allocations by local democracies.
Local leaders can play a critical role in expanding the economic pie. Our
accounts suggest that with the right incentives, local leaders can bring programs
to their communities and advance the interests of their constituents at higher
levels of government. In South Asia, and to some extent in other regions, a
new generation of younger, educated leaders is emerging (Krishna 2002; Powis
2007). In China, local leaders have played a key role in the economic transformation (Qian 2003; Putterman 1995). Mechanisms will need to be developed
to track the accountability of such leaders: fair elections and regular state/central government audits (Olken 2004) can prove useful in this regard.
In the end, we conclude that democracy is not a simple concept. Local
democracy on the ground has its problems, yet it holds out great hope. In
a speech in New York, Adam Michnik, a veteran of the Polish struggle for
democracy, captured the ambiguities:
Democracy is neither black nor red. Democracy is gray. . . . It chooses banality over excellence, shrewdness over nobility, empty promise over true competence. . . . It is eternal imperfection, a mixture of sinfulness, saintliness
and monkey business. This is why the seekers of a moral state and of a perfectly just society do not like democracy. Yet only democracy—having the
capacity to question itself—also has the capacity to correct its own mistakes.
Michnik is reported to have ended his speech with “Gray is beautiful!”32
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
273
Annex 6.1 Factors Associated with Responsiveness
of Local Democracy
PCA index of voting/elections
• Voting in state/national elections (currently, rh508)
Distance to main center
• Distance to main center (c202bi)
Access to information about local government
• Trend in access to information about local government (over 10 years, rh515b)
Household newspaper readership
• Number of times anyone in household read a newspaper (in past 1 month, h518)
Participation in community decision making
• Participation in community affairs: focus group discussion (over 10 years, rc916)
Collective action (PCA index with current weights)
• Coming together to solve water problems (10 years ago, rc412b)
• Coming together to assist each other (10 years ago, rc413b)
Social capital
• Number of groups household belonged to (10 years ago, h406Tb)
Individual empowerment (PCA index)
• Control over everyday decisions (over 10 years, rh501b)
• Position on ladder of power and rights (10 years ago, h708)
Violence against women in community
• Leave-out mean of violence against girls and women within households (10 years
ago, h609b)
Education of household head
• Education of household head (currently, h106)
Extent of social divisions
• Extent of social divisions in community (10 years ago, c414b)
LOCAL DEMOCRACY INDEX
PCA index of current responsiveness of local democracy using household-level data
• Trust in local government officials (rh415a)
• Satisfaction with democracy in local government (rh511)
• Extent to which local government takes into account concerns (rh502a)
• Ability to influence actions of local government (rh504)
Note: For explanation of codes, see appendix 4.
274
Success from the Bottom Up
Annex 6.2 Full OLS Regression Results with Responsiveness
of Local Democracy as Dependent Variable
Voting in elections
(rh508)
Distance to main
center (c202bi)
Household
newspaper
readership (h518)
Access to
information about
local government
(rh515b)
Participation
in community
decision making
(rc916)
Collective action
(PCA rc412b,
rc413b, with
current weights)
Social capital
(h406Tb)
Individual
empowerment (PCA
rh501b, h708)
Violence against
women in
community (LOM
h609b)
Education of
household head
(h106)
Extent of social
divisions (c414b)
UP
Caste
WB
Landdist
ASSAM
Conf
AP
SHG
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
0.094
0.174
0.043
0.019
0.008
0.131
[3.56]***
[1.42]
[0.33]
[0.22]
0.001
−0.004
0.005
−0.001
0.007
[0.16]
[0.56]
[1.01]
[0.28]
[0.60]
0.012
[3.45]***
1.08
[20.47]***
[3.16]***
0.009
0.009
0.008
0.003
[2.06]**
[2.42]**
[0.87]
[0.32]
1.098
0.823
0.567
0.469
[7.62]*** [12.85]***
[5.08]***
[2.98]***
−0.012
[2.40]**
[4.67]***
0.057
0.046
0.106
0.006
0.247
0.033
[0.90]
[0.45]
[1.75]*
[0.04]
[1.38]
[0.40]
0.009
0.007
0.108
0.011
−0.054
−0.094
[0.18]
[0.11]
[0.11]
[0.42]
[1.18]
0.025
0.081
0.01
0.001
0.201
−0.127
[0.44]
[1.52]
[0.24]
[0.03]
0.156
−0.234
0.294
0.18
[2.91]***
[4.81]***
[5.75]***
[5.98]***
[2.87]***
−0.407
−0.084
−0.184
−0.303
[3.30]***
[0.35]
[1.45]
[0.96]
[1.98]**
[2.54]**
−0.09
[1.22]
0.002
0.022
−0.006
−0.015
0.095
[0.45]
[1.18]
[1.30]
[0.54]
[2.26]**
0.007
−0.004
0.01
0.15
0.227
0.042
[0.17]
[0.04]
[0.17]
[1.44]
[2.33]**
[0.78]
−2.286
−2.496
−1.689
−1.268
−2.445
[7.26]***
[5.40]***
[5.99]***
[3.28]***
[4.98]***
Observations
1,635
1,192
746
839
850
714
R2
0.32
0.34
0.37
0.15
0.11
0.06
Constant
Note: Cluster-robust t-statistics in brackets.
*p < .10 **p < .05 ***p < .01 (White heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors)
For key on codes and abbreviations, see appendixes 2 and 4.
0.17
[0.90]
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
275
MAL
Infra
SEN Infra
TAN
Ruv
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
conf
COL
Conf
MEX Ethn
PHI
Panel
0.15
0.102
0.005
0.442
0.318
0.15
0.146
0.228
0.462
[1.36]
[1.38]
[0.09]
[2.71]***
[5.40]***
[2.46]**
[1.92]*
0.001
−0.009
0.001
−0.007
−0.027
[0.30]
[1.28]
[0.20]
[1.45]
[0.46]
0.095
−0.013
0.043
−0.002
0.007
−0.028
−0.007
0.179
[0.13]
[0.50]
[1.46]
[0.55]
[2.23]**
0.279
−0.473
0.556
0.023
[3.04]***
0.321
[3.45]***
[4.54]***
0.449
0.655
[2.09]**
[2.42]**
[1.43]
0.294
[2.61]***
[2.82]***
0.34
0.042
[2.34]**
[2.54]**
[1.71]*
0
[0.68]
0.011
[1.76]*
[0.98]
[4.96]***
0.775
−0.146
−0.129
0.154
[1.19]
[1.67]*
[0.55]
[0.50]
[1.66]*
−0.757
−0.434
−0.272
−0.441
−0.083
0.133
0.352
[0.72]
[2.16]**
[1.61]
[3.94]***
[0.53]
[0.88]
0.012
0.013
−0.027
0.005
0.037
0.105
0.074
0.211
[0.21]
[0.26]
[0.30]
[0.08]
[0.49]
[1.26]
[0.77]
[1.21]
0.02
0.118
0.058
0.017
−0.016
0.112
0.051
0.172
[0.13]
[1.24]
[0.70]
[0.29]
[0.21]
[1.42]
[0.48]
[0.87]
1.728
−0.714
−1.96
1.275
1.158
0.718
−0.285
−0.55
[2.44]**
[1.74]*
[5.21]***
[0.68]
[1.31]
[2.49]**
[1.97]**
[0.68]
0.232
−0.077
−0.005
−0.132
0.086
0.058
[1.27]
[1.19]
[0.06]
[0.68]
[1.15]
[0.50]
[2.57]**
−0.199
[2.33]**
0.86
[2.62]***
[4.97]***
−0.44
[3.31]***
0.597
[3.94]***
−0.203
0.709
[3.39]***
0.306
[7.60]***
0.172
[1.88]*
−0.073
[0.87]
−0.92
−0.207
0.012
−0.184
0.161
0.093
[3.27]***
[0.67]
[0.31]
[0.63]
[1.11]
[2.09]**
[3.06]***
−3.131
−0.886
−0.726
−3.072
−1.349
0.239
[3.31]***
[0.33]
[0.61]
[3.75]***
[1.82]*
[0.34]
−1.606
1.075
1.698
[0.67]
[0.86]
[0.94]
122
287
301
0.26
0.22
0.1
0.483
[1.37]
0.07
[0.33]
72
368
300
227
294
220
0.35
0.11
0.12
0.17
0.26
0.48
276
Success from the Bottom Up
Notes
1. In Political Liberalism, John Rawls writes, “The first principle covering the equal
basic rights and liberties may easily be preceded by a lexically prior principle
requiring that citizens’ basic needs be met, at least insofar as their being met is
necessary for citizens to understand and to be able fruitfully to exercise those
rights and liberties” (1993: 7).
2. It is difficult to sustain the argument that democracy has put a drag on India.
Despite contentious coalition politics, India has sustained a growth rate of 8
percent and is expected to grow at 5–7 percent despite the financial crisis.
3. This alternative interpretation of high voter turnout as a sign of voter desperation
was suggested by Pratap Bhanu Mehta (personal communication, April 2008).
4. There is a growing literature on accountability, including social and downward
accountability. See Bovens (2006); Goetz and Jenkins (2005); Lankina, Hudalla,
and Wollmann (2007); Narayan (2002b); Sisk (2001); and Yilmaz, Beris, and
Berthet (2008).
5. Country-specific results are available in the country reports, and some will be
discussed in detail in forthcoming publications in this series.
6. Decentralization of government is a vastly important and complex subject, but
it is not our focus. For an insightful review of some of the issues, see Bardhan
(2002), Shah and Thompson (2004), and Crook and Manor (1998).
7. This view emerged in focus group discussions on livelihoods, freedom, power,
and democracy that were conducted separately with women, men, and youth in
each community. The participants in each group were asked three open-ended
questions: “What does democracy mean to you? What are its features or dimensions? Which three features are most important to making democracy work?
Why?” In each case, the local-language word used to mean “democracy” was predetermined in training workshops before the investigators went into the field.
8. In his writings on the country-town nexus in India, sociologist Dipankar Gupta
contends that the rural political landscape is changing with circular migration.
Although lower-caste laborers used to depend on their landed upper-caste benefactors, especially during lean agricultural seasons, they now migrate to cities
for work. When they return to their villages, often flush with cash, they seek a
new place in the village social and political hierarchy. This trend, together with
affirmative action policies such as reserving certain government jobs for lowercaste applicants, has brought more combative politics to rural India (Gupta and
Sharma 1991).
9. Focusing on the Indonesian tradition of gotong royong, or voluntary communal
work, Rao (2008) argues that even though the system initiated by Suharto was
coercive, it created over time a collective understanding of what it means to be a
good citizen. It helped create a normative desire for citizenship and expectation
of democracy, which, in turn, has provided a foundation for community-driven
development and decentralized local governance. Looking at the management
of common property resources in Tamil Nadu, India, Mosse (1997) argues that
water tanks and village temples could serve as public institutions that symbolize
social relations, status, prestige, and honor. Turner (1982) suggests that when a
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
277
social group celebrates a particular event such as a festival, it “celebrates itself”
by “manifesting in symbolic form what it conceives to be its essential life.”
Fung and Wright (2003, 33–34) focus on how unequal power in society creates
problems for the practice of deliberative democracy. Such practice “may pay insufficient attention to the fact that participants in these processes usually face each
other from unequal positions of power. Citizens who are advantaged in terms of
their wealth, education, income, or membership in dominant racial and ethnic
groups participate more frequently and effectively than those who are less well
off. If both strong and weak are well represented, the strong may nevertheless use
tools at their disposal—material resources, information asymmetries, rhetorical
capacities—to advance collective decisions that unreasonably favor their interests.”
Kaufman (1968) calls this the “paradox of participatory democracy.”
So we could tease out the variation, responses for communities that experienced
no change in responsiveness have not been reported.
We used the technique of principal components analysis to aggregate all the
variables into a composite index of responsiveness. We test the association
quantitatively between our measure of responsiveness of local democracy and
an individual household’s ability to move out of poverty. Using the multivariate
linear regression model reported in appendix 6, we use household MOP as the
dependent variable, testing its association with several other independent variables
(including responsiveness) that we believe can have an association with mobility.
For purposes of our analysis, we have given equal weights to a unit change in
education at either level—from illiterate to primary literate or from primary
literate to secondary literate. In the real world, this weighting may not hold true.
The household head’s transition from illiteracy to primary literacy may be more
significant in influencing his or her family’s chances of escaping poverty than the
achievement of a higher level of education.
In certain study contexts, the variable had to be dropped because of problems of
multicollinearity.
According to Prud’homme (1995), decentralization may be accompanied by
corruption as it creates more layers of taxes. In his study of Zaire, Prud’homme
(1992) estimated that informal taxes at the local level, including payoffs to local
authorities, gifts, and donations, were at least eight times more important than
formal taxes. Paucity of resources at lower levels of democracies can also open up
avenues for rules that conceal corrupt practices. In his study of regional governments in Russia, Zhuravskaya (2000) found that less allocation of resources to
local governments weakens their incentive to foster local business development.
Using data on bribery of public officials in Uganda and Peru, Hunt (2007) estimates that bribery rates and bribe amounts are higher where clients are frustrated
with slow service. Bribery allows clients to avoid the poor service delivered to
those who refuse to bribe.
It could be that movers out of poverty report lower corruption levels in their
community because they have close ties with their local political leader, who has
assisted their mobility. Using initial corruption levels and community-assessed
mobility as the dependent variable in the regression model reduces room for
such halo effects.
278
Success from the Bottom Up
18. Schattscheiner (1963) described how multiple interlocking social and economic
relationships between local elites act as formidable barriers to progress for others. He famously remarked, “The flaw in the pluralist heaven is that the heavenly
chorus sings with a strong upper-class accent.” Some theorists consider elite capture as a malaise that is bound to afflict local democracies and/or governments.
While political agents at appropriately decentralized levels may have greater
incentive to serve voters at large because of their physical and social proximity to
them (Seabright 1996; Khemani 2001; Tomassi and Weinschelbaum 1999), this
same closeness may facilitate the making and fulfillment of clientelist promises
to a few of those voters. This change may be especially true for newly instituted
local democracies that try to first serve their political patrons (Keefer 2002).
Varshney (2007) calls this the mass-politics constraint.
19. Studies in several countries have attempted to describe the phenomenon of
elite capture empirically. Wright (1974) provided some of the first evidence that
political factors influence allocation of federal funds across states in the United
States. More recent studies that find evidence of elite capture include Bardhan
and Mookherjee (2004, 2006) on use of public fiscal grants in 89 panchayats
in West Bengal; Olken (2004) on road projects in Indonesia; Lieten (1996),
Mathew and Nayak (1996), and Besley, Pande, and Rao (2007) on panchayats in
India; and Galasso and Ravallion (2005) on a decentralized food-for-education
program in Bangladesh.
20. The caste system in Uttar Pradesh and India as a whole divides the Hindu population into different tiers according to their caste or varna (traditional occupation).
Castes from the “general category” are engaged in respectable professions such as
teaching (Brahmins). At the bottom of the ladder are the untouchables or outcastes. Known today as the Dalits, this category consists of the scheduled castes
(SC). After India gained independence, the newly drafted national constitution
provided for a separate category of “other backward classes” (OBC). This category
consisted of peasant cultivators like the Yadavs and Lodhis, who were not SCs but
were as disadvantaged as them in most respects. Although the OBCs did not face
historical discrimination, the first Backward Classes Commission in India used
caste as an explicit criterion for judging their backwardness. Thus, the OBCs came
to be known also as “other backward castes.”
21. According to Keefer and Vlaicu (2008), electoral candidates in younger democracies may engage in clientelist practices and corruption to gain credibility
and votes. Such patron–client networks often run deep, especially in smaller
electorates where “vote buying [is] a cost-effective electoral strategy.” However,
as democracies age, political reforms that expand the size of the electorate, introduce secret ballots, and impose limits on electoral spending can make elections
more issue based.
22. The Indian Constitution (articles 330 and 332) mandates reservations for scheduled castes and scheduled tribes in federal and state legislatures. Scheduled
castes have for centuries occupied the bottom of the Hindu caste system, while
scheduled tribes are marked by their geographic and cultural isolation.
23. A lathi, a long baton, is a traditional weapon that is also used to control domestic
animals.
All Politics Is Local: How Better Governance Helps the Poor
279
24. We again used multivariate regression techniques. Our measure of responsiveness of local democracy became the dependent variable, and we used independent variables that we believed could explain higher or lower responsiveness. The
framework and variables used for the exercise are listed in annex 6.1, with results
in annex 6.2.
25. The NSP is a rural development program funded by the World Bank and managed by the Ministry of Rural Rehabilitation and Development. The program
provides grants of up to US$60,000 to villages for rehabilitation, reconstruction,
and income generation projects.
26. Citizen report cards grade a service provider based on feedback from users. Documenting the success of this innovation in Bangalore, India, Paul (2007) shows
that by the third round of report cards, satisfaction with most public services in
the city had registered dramatic improvement.
27. This result reaffirms findings in the literature about the positive impact of community participation on service delivery and other governance issues (Isham,
Narayan, and Pritchett 1994; Santos 1998; Baiochhi 2005; Foster and Rosenzweig
2001). In a study of 500 villages in South India, Besley, Pande, and Rao (2007)
find that gram sabha meetings provide a platform for participation by some of
the most disadvantaged groups in the village—the landless and scheduled castes
and tribes. Their results show that illiterate households in villages that have held
gram sabhas in the past year are more likely to have a below-poverty-line card
entitling them to benefits.
28. Knack (2005) presents a similar argument for empowerment policies for poor
people. Using the concept of Pareto efficiency, he argues that if the total amount
of power available is assumed to be fixed, efforts focused on increasing the power
of the poor are likely to face substantial resistance from the nonpoor, who stand
to lose. The only politically feasible way to empower the poor, therefore, is to
focus on “identifying options for economic and political change that can benefit
the poor without necessitating a comparable decline in benefits to the nonpoor,”
that is, by shifting from what he calls a “zero sum approach” to a “positive sum
game.”
29. While we are in general agreement with Friedman’s main argument, we do not
agree with his idea that presumed Western values of hard work and diligence
predispose Western societies to economic productivity and growth. The author
seems to perpetuate the myth that people in developing countries are morally
less advanced than those in the developed world.
30. A mon is a traditional measure of weight used in West Bengal and Bangladesh.
One mon is roughly the amount of rice that would be harvested from 20 kathas
(approximately 1,338 square meters) of land.
31. We used the net prosperity index (NPI) as a measure of prosperity. The index
measures the net movement on the ladder of life in a village, that is, all those
who moved up less all those who moved down.
32. Reported in the New Yorker, December 9, 1996, and quoted by Bardhan (1999).
The Unfulfilled Potential
of Collective Action
The most important thing is the family
union and the desire to keep on living,
moving on. Without that, there is
nothing.
—A DRIANA ,
A
29- YEAR - OLD WOMAN ,
El Mirador, Colombia
We have to organize ourselves for
the journey to the farms. Although
everybody has his own plot, you cannot
go alone.
—F ARMERS
IN
N AMDENYE , R UVUMA , T ANZANIA ,
a village menaced by lions
These people tell us that we have to
contribute for the school, for the police,
and for offices. But we are the ones who
bring stones. We make the bricks and offer
our labor. So where does the money go?
—M EN ’ S DISCUSSION GROUP ,
Bugokela, Kagera, Tanzania, complaining about
a community-driven development project
7
C HAPTER
A
round the world, fables transmit the deepest values of a culture. We
start this chapter with a favorite fable from India, “The Talkative Tortoise,” probably first recorded sometime in the third to fifth century AD.1
Once upon a time, a tortoise lived in a village pond. Two young geese
used to visit the pond, and the three became good friends. One year, a severe
drought afflicted the region, and all the rivers, lakes, and ponds started drying up. With no water to drink, the birds and animals in the village began
to die.
The geese thought of migrating to another lake, but they didn’t want to
leave their friend, the tortoise, behind. The tortoise came up with an idea.
He told the geese, “Why don’t you bring a strong stick? You can hold the two
ends of the stick in your beaks, and I will grasp the stick in the middle with
my mouth. In this way, I can fly with you.” The geese agreed, but knowing
their friend’s talkative nature, they imposed one condition. “You must promise not to open your mouth while we fly.”
The tortoise agreed, and the three started on their journey. At one point,
they flew over a village. The people in the village were surprised to see the
spectacle and started laughing and clapping. Unable to control his anxiety,
the tortoise opened his mouth to ask the geese, “Friends—what is this all
about?” He fell to his death.
The beauty of fables is that there many lessons and morals that can be
drawn. One clear lesson of this fable is to know when to keep your mouth
shut! A more central one for us is about collective action, circles of trust,
friendship, and the importance of connecting with people unlike oneself to
survive and flourish in life.
There is a very extensive literature on collective action, from Mancur
Olson (1965) to Elinor Ostrom (1990) to Robert Putnam (1993). Much is
already known about collective action in different contexts, but a debate has
281
282
Success from the Bottom Up
emerged between those who sing the virtues of collective action and those
who see drawbacks. Our findings confirm the importance and potential of
grassroots collective action. We suggest strategies to scale up such activities,
building on the circles of trust established by groups to increase equitable
access to markets and to local democracies.
In this chapter, we highlight four findings and draw out implications for
policy. First, across the communities in our sample, the family is the most
important context within which collective action takes place. Observing the
features of successful families can give us insights that are potentially applicable to other forms of collective action. Second, poor people have a propensity to come together in spontaneous bonding groups, which helps them
survive but does not often help them move out of poverty. Third, although
there are ways of building on indigenous forms of collective action, outsiders, whether from NGOs or government, often get it wrong. Poor people
and formerly poor people our teams spoke with rarely mentioned NGOs as
sources of support. Achieving scale in collective economic activities is possible, but it demands radical new thinking, with a strong market orientation
and investment in poor people’s organizations. Fourth, the most important
contributions of collective action may be political, in improving the quality
of local democracy and the provision of local public goods. While collective
action often substitutes for the failures of governments and markets, there
is a need to move from substitution to complementarity between people’s
organizations and local government performance.
First Site of Collective Action: The Family
What I feel has helped me most is the union of our family. This union is
our strength. With unity and agreement, you can do anything.
—Tomás, a man in chronic poverty, Chakax, Mexico
Across study sites, families stand out as the most important institution
in people’s lives. Family love and unity provide the moral and psychological support that enables people to survive hard times. Families pool their
resources and work together to move out of poverty. People also turn first to
their families to cope with shocks, whether financial setbacks, sickness, or
displacement by disaster or conflict. But families can also hold people back
through demands for sharing (with the risk of free riding), oppressive family
traditions (including gender discrimination), and risk aversion.
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
283
The centrality of the family emerges in both our quantitative and qualitative data. We used an inductive approach to code 2,700 life stories from India
to understand the role of institutions in asset accumulation. People spoke
about four sets of institutions that had helped them accumulate assets: public
institutions, the private sector, civil society, and the family. Across all mobility
groups in India, more than 80 percent of such institutional references were
to families. Among the fallers, it was 88 percent; among the chronic poor,
85 percent; among the movers, 82 percent; and among the never poor, 81
percent.2 This salience of the family was evident in life stories and discussion
groups in other country contexts as well.
Trust, loyalty, love, and sacrifice
Since I was a child, my parents loved me so much because I am the fourth
and a cute girl. . . . I got married in 1992 and until now I have lived
with them. In 1997, my mum got sick and died. All of our relatives came
and paid respect and spent money on the funeral. We were all sad and in
mourning. Now I live with my old, ill dad. . . . Although we are very poor,
there are no arguments or quarrels in the family.
—Chuon, a 40-year-old woman, Kdadaum, Cambodia
Trust, unity, and solidarity provide the foundation on which collective
action is built. In discussion after discussion, people reiterated the importance of having these qualities within the family. Often, they see family
cohesiveness as a precondition for upward mobility or for maintaining the
household’s present status.
Families, especially large families, can give people a sense of power.
In the village of Nurpur in Bangladesh, Kashem, a woman in a discussion
group, said, “To marry into a big house with many brothers and sisters-in-law
is power.” Tahera added, “The numerical strength of relatives is power. If a
man has many children, he has extra power. Other people are afraid of going
against him.” The young men in the village added, “If the brothers in a family
are united, they have power because five brothers are like five sticks [which
together cannot be broken]. Other people in the village are afraid of them.”
Nasiruddin, a 31-year-old fisherman in Kramrrak, Indonesia, attributed
his successful move out of poverty to the love and practical assistance provided by his wife. While he works hard each day to catch and sell fish, his
wife sells snacks at a kiosk in the village. He was quick to note that his wife’s
financial contribution is valuable to the household. “Back then [10 years
284
Success from the Bottom Up
ago], 10,000 rupiah per day was enough because I had only one child. But
today, it is not enough. That’s why my wife’s kiosk is very helpful to me.”
Nasiruddin’s wife also helps him manage his wealth. “So far I talk only to
my wife for management of my assets. Besides her, there’s nobody else I turn
to for managing my funds. My self-confidence is increasing because my wife
understands me. She helps me a lot, like with her kiosk, so I don’t feel alone
in facing my problems.”
Our data reveal the presence of a strong, almost atavistic instinct to sacrifice for the family, especially for one’s children and spouse. Parents often
struggle throughout their lives to give their children an education (box 7.1).
Self-sacrifice may even include leaving one’s country and everything one
BOX 7.1
Giving up everything to send children to school
Racman, a 44-year-old woman from Bakimati, Philippines, was rated as
chronic poor by her peers in the village. Her husband works on their small
farm and on the farms of others. Racman has worked as a waitress, a maid,
and a laundry woman, striving to provide two meals a day for her children
and to educate them well.
Racman moved to Bakimati with her family in 1998 so that the children
could receive an education, as her native village had no school. But the
family was forced to leave Bakimati in 2000 because of civil conflict in the
Mindanao region. They went to Parang to stay at an evacuation center. Racman served food in a cafeteria in the morning and took in washing at night.
“It seemed as if all my energy was drained. There were times that I would ask
only for rice instead of money so that I would be assured that my children
would have something to eat when I got home. It was so hard, but I had to
make some sacrifices so that we would survive. It was better than having
nothing for my children.”
Racman and her family returned to Bakimati in 2001, after the conflict
had subsided. She now sells vegetables and cooked food in the village. It has
been hard for the family to acquire property and other fixed assets because
they have put everything they have into their children’s education. Racman
keeps some savings at home in a piggybank, but she says, “I would break my
piggybank whenever there are some expenses for my children’s schooling.”
She concludes, smiling, “If my children could finish their studies, then maybe
that would be the time that we would experience a better life. That’s why I
really want all my children to finish college—something I was not able to
attain in my life.”
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
285
knows in order to earn money to send back to the family. Said, a 62-year-old
man from the village of Almichi in Morocco, migrated to France to work in a
coal mine. His main aim was to earn a pension that would provide financial
security to his wife once he was gone. Widows in Morocco lead deplorable
lives and were consistently ranked at the very bottom of the ladder of life
in our study communities. Said explained, “When I first got my pension,
that was a big relief because it will be a security for my wife. If I die before
her . . . God knows . . . I don’t have any guarantee that my children are going
to treat their mother well. Now I can die quietly; my wife is not going to beg
to provide for her needs.”
Joint portfolios: Farming, business, and migration
Each and every person has to work hard if a family is to reach a higher step.
If we simply sit idle and eat, even hills would melt.
—Discussion with women, Govindapalle, Andhra Pradesh
I pray to God that I will never have to return to the United States. Not for
fear of work, but for fear of leaving the family. Migration splits the family,
and it is not with money that you can cure the effect of separation.
—Adolfo, a 29-year-old man, Guadalamoros, Mexico
Beyond providing psychological support, the family unit plays an
extremely important role in the movement out of poverty through its joint
and pooled economic activities. Family support for income generation has
two important, closely related dimensions. One consists of putting many
hands to work, including managing businesses together. The other consists
of migrating for employment and sending back remittances. Often these
are combined, as when households use remittances from a family member
abroad to invest in new livelihood opportunities at home.
Across our study sites, it is common for all members of a household,
including women and children, to work. Often, this contribution yields
barely enough to meet daily consumption needs. In some cases, though, it
enables households to save and move up.
Lal in Kandulimari, Assam, worked as a daily wage laborer and farmed
potatoes and chilies on his small plot of land. “The money was enough to
fund our expenses for oil and salt,” he recalls. With great difficulty, Lal managed to finance the education of his four sons. Rated poor in 1995, Lal’s family
has since moved out of poverty. His peers attribute his success to the fact that
his educated sons have come of age and now contribute to the family pot.
286
Success from the Bottom Up
The eldest son has a job in Guwahati. The second one set up a shop that sells
electrical equipment in the village. The third works as a decorator for marriage
ceremonies, while the youngest sells cigarettes and paan (a chewing mixture) at
a kiosk in Kandulimari. “No one sits bekar [idle] at home,” said Lal when asked
the secret of his success. “My sons cooperate with each other. In 2003, all of
them made this house together. Previously, the house was made of straw and
bamboo. Now we have GC sheets [galvanized metal] on the roof, brick walls,
and concrete floors.” The sons have equipped the house with an electricity
connection and furnished it with a sofa, beds, and a television. They have even
bought an insurance policy for their father, as well as a pair of cows. “I dream
about more progress for my sons in the future,” Lal says happily. “That they can
progress more is my only wish. If God blesses us, certainly they will prosper.”
In putting all hands to work, it is very common for families to send one
member to seek employment outside the community, typically in a nearby
city or abroad. Remittances sent back by family members who have migrated
play pivotal roles in upward mobility. In Morocco and Mexico, migration to
Europe and the United States, respectively, are important escape routes out of
poverty. Migration is particularly important in conflict-affected communities.
The remittances that migrants send back allow their families to cope with the
economic shock of conflict and in some cases to save and build assets.
Fasmin, a 25-year-old woman in Kumputhiri, Sri Lanka, is described as
a mover by her community. She lives with her child in Kumputhiri while her
husband lives and works in Kuwait. Both were born into poor families and
initially worked as coolies in the village to earn their daily bread. Fortunately,
the husband’s mother lived in Kuwait and sent remittances to help the couple
cope. In 2003, with the mother’s help, Fasmin and her husband migrated
to Kuwait as well. While her husband worked as a driver, Fasmin became a
housemaid. “After going abroad, both my husband and I earned a lot,” said
Fasmin. “Earlier, it was difficult to carry on our lives because there were no
permanent jobs in this area. We did not have a house to live in. But now my
husband earns about 15,000 Sri Lankan rupees per month. We have our own
house, and we can do anything we want. So I feel we have a better life now.”
Although she misses her husband, she thinks it is better that he stay in Kuwait
for the time being. “If my husband comes to Sri Lanka, he cannot work here.
He has to go back. If the war starts, we would have to move from this place as
well.” But she adds, “We would eventually want to start our own work here.
Being abroad for long is not useful.”
Indeed, migration is in some ways a mixed blessing for families. The stress
of separation affects both those who migrate and those who stay behind. In
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
287
our opening story Adolfo from Mexico, recalled the time he spent across the
border, in the United States. “It is difficult on the other side. There is a lot of
pressure, and I would not like to live this way.” Yet Adolfo feels he had no
choice but to migrate. “I was helping the family. I was the son. . . .” he shrugged.
“There is no money, no work here in Guadalamoros. . . . I pray to God that I
will never have to return to the United States. Not for fear of work, but for fear
of leaving the family. Migration splits the family.”
Investing remittances in new livelihood activities emerges as a clear path
to mobility for many households. Shahana, a mover from Dayabhara, Bangladesh, is recognized as one of the empowered women in her village. In 1995,
her husband, Haque, was a small farmer in Dayabhara. The family could barely
get by. Borrowing money from his relatives to finance the trip, Haque left the
village in 1996 to work in Saudi Arabia. The first year was very difficult, as
Haque could not send much money home. By 1998, however, he found a
secure job in Saudi Arabia and began sending more. The couple soon repaid all
their loans and started saving and investing. Shahana used her husband’s hardearned income wisely. She first invested in rearing poultry and cattle. With the
profits and additional remittances, she built a brick house with a latrine. She
also bought agricultural land and farmed it. She took care that her children
never missed school. When our team met her, Shahana was an active member
of a saving group and a respected member of her community.
In the study communities in Oaxaca and Yucatán, Mexico, the migration
of a family member is a key factor distinguishing those on the higher steps of
the ladder of life. The other distinction is diversified family livelihood portfolios, with women earning income and all members working to jointly manage
family businesses (table 7.1). In fact, across our study sites in Mexico, a family
member finding employment outside the community is a nearly guaranteed
route to climbing the ladder. In Yucatán, this endeavor takes the form of commuting to nearby towns to find off-farm employment. In Oaxaca, family members typically migrate to other parts of Mexico or the United States.
Although remittances benefit the receiving families most directly, they
can also drive community-wide mobility. In the village of Nurpur, Bangladesh, most residents have at least one family member who has migrated to
countries such as Dubai, Pakistan, or Saudi Arabia. People in Nurpur have
invested their remittances in local businesses like cell phone sales and furniture. An increase in local supply has enabled people to spend their money
within the village rather than in nearby towns. This spending has galvanized
the creation of a vibrant market, and the profits, in turn, are leading to more
spending in the community.
288
Success from the Bottom Up
TABLE 7.1
Migration and multiple hands at work trigger upward movement in Mexico
Bottom 2 steps
Migration
Multiple
hands at
work
No migration.
If family
members are
employed,
it is usually
as temporary
casual labor.
Household may
grow some food.
Wives sell petty
handicrafts.
Step where households
are no longer considered
poor
Top 1–2 steps
Oaxaca: Household
members have migrated
to Mexico City, northern
Mexico, or the United
States.
Oaxaca: Households
members have migrated
and are often legal U.S.
residents with steady
jobs.
Yucatán: Head of
household works outside
the community in
agriculture or construction.
Yucatán: Family
members have off-farm
employment outside the
community.
Oaxaca: Family grows
own food and sells surplus
produce. Women make
handicrafts, wash clothes,
or sell cooked food.
Families often own a
grocery store, bakery,
or tortilla shop in the
community. Many still
farm on the side or raise
and sell animals. More
than one member of
the household works
and wife contributes by
selling other produce or
services.
Yucatán: Women may
have salaried work. Many
households own small
grocery stores and/or raise
animals.
Source: Ladder of life focus group discussions, Mexico.
Coping with adversity
In 1986, my house was destroyed, my brother died, and two of my sons
were wounded. Airplanes were bombing our village. . . . I was also thinking about killing myself. I didn’t have any hope. . . . Now my children are
adults and take care of me. I feel more relaxed and confident.
—Naim, a 60-year-old man, Nasher Khan, Afghanistan
An important function of families is to face risks and adversity together.
Families pool their resources, both financial and psychological, to confront
health shocks, injury, and death. This function of families is especially important in conflict areas. In Afghanistan, we found people using their filial networks to protect their families and to migrate out of the most dangerous
zones together (box 7.2).
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
289
Across contexts, families use their assets—livestock, land, jewelry—to
pay for the expenses of a sick family member. In Tinkata, a coffee-cultivating
community in Ruvuma, Tanzania, 44-year-old Analis suffered several miscarriages. After the delivery of her fourth child, who was born with disabilities
in 1993, she lost all strength and will to live. Soon thereafter, she became
pregnant again and suffered yet another miscarriage. Among the people who
BOX 7.2
Solidarity in time of war
Once a beautiful village surrounded by grape vineyards in the Shamali plains
of Afghanistan, Ramili Qali now has a haunted look. In 1999, the people of
the village lost everything to the intense fighting between the Taliban and
the U.S.-supported Northern Alliance. Our team met Abdul, a farmer who
recalled the horror of seeing his village burn. “They set fire to our gardens
and our grapevines. They blew up the irrigation canal. Of course, the Taliban
and the Northern Alliance looted our houses. The Taliban once totally burned
some of them. The Northern Alliance soldiers one winter took all the wood,
logs, from our houses to make firewood. And both put a lot of landmines in
the village.” At the time our field team visited Ramili Qali, it was estimated to
have 2,000 landmines.
With the village turned into a battleground, families were forced to evacuate to nearby cities like Jalalabad. One man recalled, “The Taliban deported
the families: women and children on one side, and men on another side.
They were deported to Kabul, then quickly to camps in Jalalabad.” The Taliban also put 100 men from the village in a prison in Pul-e-Charkhi. Twenty
of the weakest ones died there. The fate of the deported was no better. “The
authorities of Jalalabad did not want them. There was news that the Taliban
would bring them back to Kabul. It was then that these families decided
to leave the country.” Pir Mohammad, a farmer in a discussion group,
recounted, “Around 500 families migrated together to Kashmir, where some
of our villagers were living already. Around 50 families migrated to Panjsher,
and another 50 families went together to Iran.”
All 500 families that left for Kashmir stuck together. People described
with much pride how these families survived until the end of the conflict by
taking care of each other in the absence of the men. Even more remarkable
was how Pashtuns (the tribe to which the Taliban belong) and Tajiks (of the
Northern Alliance) coexisted peacefully upon the villagers’ return. “There is
no social inequality where we live,” men in a discussion group exclaimed
proudly. “All people live in the same condition. Since people stopped fighting, they feel unity among each other.”
290
Success from the Bottom Up
helped her was her father-in-law. During her pregnancies, he gave her money
so she could go to a hospital that was distant from Tinkata. Other relatives
donated blood for transfusion at the time of the miscarriages. “These were
my brother, my sister, and my aunt. My husband could not donate because
we have different blood groups,” she said.
Especially in India, Bangladesh, and Sri Lanka, outlays for dowries and
wedding ceremonies often constitute a serious financial shock for a household. Again, families help cushion the blow. Suman, a woman in Kursi, Uttar
Pradesh, knew from the time of her daughter’s birth that she would eventually
need money for a dowry. “I was happy on her birth because she was my first
child. But I was also sad because the birth of a girl in a poor family is equivalent
to death.” Suman’s husband fell ill soon after, and the family barely scraped
by. “There was no food in the house, and my children and I had to consume
roti [bread] with salt and vinegar.” Suman’s mother then sent her some money
to run the house. With the money, Suman bought three packets of biscuits,
10 candies, and five packs of cigarettes and set them out for sale. Slowly but
steadily, her sales picked up, and eventually she had enough to invest in a small
shop. At the time of the interview, Suman had managed to save Rs 2,000 (about
US$50) for her daughter’s dowry. “I saved every rupee that I had and put it in
the bank,” Suman told our field team. She cannot think what their fate would
have been had her mother not stepped in to help.
Division, desertion, and death: How family breakups can lead to falls
In 1998, my father separated me from the family. It brought me great pain.
The power that exists in unity does not exist when you stay separately.
—Badloo, a 30-year-old man in chronic poverty,
Hathina, Uttar Pradesh
Given the importance of families, losing one’s spouse or children through
death or desertion or becoming estranged from one’s family can trigger a
decline into poverty. In a community in the conflict region in the Philippines,
men asked, “What if your spouse, whom you depend on, dies? You know that
she is good in business and deals well with the customers. [Her death] can be
one factor that will push you down. But we cannot really avoid death because
that is where all people go.”
The problem is particularly acute for women in male-dominated societies. Across study contexts, widows and women abandoned by their husbands occupy the very bottom step of the ladder of life. In Afghanistan and
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
291
Morocco, women who are both widowed and fatherless are described as helpless. With little or no income or savings, no insurance, and no social security,
many are reduced to begging. A discussion group of women in Tindyata,
Morocco, described one such woman in their community. “There is a widow
who doesn’t have income. She walks around to her neighbors to get what she
needs: a little flour, a cup of oil, a little tea, and sugar.” Women who lost their
husbands during the war in Afghanistan also live in appalling conditions. A
group of men in Nasher Khan noted, “Men are like a mountain. Families who
have more mountains are more powerful.”
A division among siblings that fragments the family inheritance can
lead to falling, as can being abandoned by one’s adult children. This is particularly striking in the Indian rural context, where it is still common to live
in extended or “joint” families. In the village of Khetoosa in Uttar Pradesh,
47-year-old Chander had separated from his brothers and received a meager
inheritance. “I only got 8 bighas of land on which it was possible to farm
only once a year. Furthermore, because my plot was on the banks of a river,
I constantly faced problems of waterlogging. The floods washed away my
crops each year.” But he didn’t lose hope, as he had three sons to rely on.
Three years after separating from his brothers, Chander married off his eldest
son, taking a loan to pay for the marriage ceremony. “I had little worry about
the loan, because I thought that my son would help me in cultivation and
we would pay off the loan together. However, this did not happen. My son
separated from the family.” Chander now feels he is doomed. “Coming out
from debt is now difficult. I feel distressed because I have yet to arrange the
marriages of two sons and one daughter. It will be difficult for me to come
out of poverty. Nobody will come to my help. The rest of the children are
small and are unable to do any work. My son’s separation has been the greatest cause of our downward mobility. He does not even talk to us, so how can
I ask him to repay the loan amount?”
Family as a burden
We can have as many children as we want, like 10 to 15. But then we’ll
die. How are we going to feed them all? Are we going to feed them maize
husks?
—Discussion with men and women, Bamlozi, Malawi
While large families are a sign of power to many, they can also pose an
obstacle to moving up. More people in a family means more hands at work,
292
Success from the Bottom Up
but it also means more mouths to feed, more bodies to clothe, and more
people with conflicting needs and aspirations becoming involved in decisions and plans. It means more sharing and less saving.
Across study regions, families with many children and few working
members are placed at the bottom steps of the community ladders. A male
discussion group in Riah Khillaw, Afghanistan, described such households in
their village. “The poorest usually have big families—on average eight people
in the house. They do not own the house they live in, nor any land. This category includes widows, who have a small income and no children of working
age, or families where the male head of household is too old to earn a good
income.” Similarly, a group of men in the fishing village of Mirjakhathi, Bangladesh, thought that smaller families with fewer children are better able to
save and invest in livelihood activities. “If they have fewer members in the
family, they could even save some money. With that saving, they could buy
more fishing nets.”
In Malawi, some young people see their large families as an obstacle to
achieving their aspirations. “Parents continue having children, but hunger
does not go away,” said a youth discussion group in Mzaponda. “Being their
children, youth fail to speak up to parents to stop this tendency of having
more children. There are homes with as many as 15 people. All of them need
clothes and other things. So if their parents can get a 500 kwacha note by
doing piecework on other people’s farms, it ends up on purchase of food. This
results in most boys doing farm piecework so they can support themselves.”
Especially in African contexts, where norms of sharing are especially
strong, kinship networks extend far beyond the immediate nuclear family. Anyone who manages to move up the ladder is expected to extend help
to wide circles of kith and kin and even unrelated community members.
Deference to this societal norm of sharing can become a net drain on family resources, but failure to provide help is frowned upon and can result in
estrangement from the community. Men and women in a discussion group
in Mzaponda, Malawi, gave an example: “When they [people in the community] see steam at other houses, that’s when they decide to go there and ask
for a light, when in actual fact they want to be invited to share the porridge
that’s being cooked. If you don’t invite them, they start saying that you are
greedy.”
Finally, large families are also seen to be prone to conflicts over sharing
of resources and labor. “If several pots are banged together, there will be some
noise,” argued Ramesh in Kursi, Uttar Pradesh. “When there are more members in a family, the chances of infighting increase. After marriages, divisions
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
293
are bound to occur as wives influence their husbands. Usually as expenses
start rising, it leads to trouble and there is a division in the family.”
For some, separation from family can even spell liberation, bringing the
freedom to work hard for oneself and not for others. Tarawati, a 45-year-old
woman in Bhairo Khurd, Uttar Pradesh, rated separation from her husband’s
family as the most important positive event in their life. Married at 16 to a
poor, illiterate man, Tarawati lived at first with her husband and in-laws, and
the entire family worked together on the family farm. Tarawati described her
father-in-law as a generous man and the thread that tied everyone together.
But after his death, the atmosphere deteriorated. As Tarawati’s brothers-inlaw married and the family grew, the disputes increased. In 1990, when Tarawati was 31, her husband split from his extended family.
With their own land and a house to live in, Tarawati and her husband
could invest in their farm. Working and saving over nearly eight years, they
bought a tractor and more land. With these improvements, their farm’s productivity increased and their social status rose. Tarawati now lives comfortably
in her own house with her husband, sons, daughters-in-law, and grandchildren. “The split was the turning point, because my husband prospered then
in his individual capacity,” she concluded.
Gender discrimination and violence within families
The only wrong thing I did was to be born as a girl in this society.
—A young girl, Mechiri, Andhra Pradesh
It is the fanaticism of people. They don’t like when girls are going to school,
and sometimes our families show reaction against schooling, and they say
school isn’t good for girls.
—Najila, an 18-year-old female student, Ramili Qali, Afghanistan
Not all families are happy collectives, with unity and equity between
members. The most potent conflict, although sometimes unexpressed, is
between men and women within households. The issues revolve around
inequalities and unfairness in decision making, division of labor, distribution of resources, freedom of movement, and respect.
Ndyamuhaki, in Bufkaro, Uganda, said that men in her community
hardly consult their wives. “The man will just sell the land without the woman
knowing and drink all the money,” she said. In Butmuli, another village in
Uganda, women indicated that some men in their village had even made
294
Success from the Bottom Up
decisions to sell off their daughters, typically when they were in an inebriated
state at drinking joints. Their wives had no say in the matter.
Like hundreds of researchers before us, we found that members of a family do not necessarily function as a harmonious whole, with similar preferences and spending patterns.3 Men tend to spend their income on themselves,
while women are more likely to purchase goods for children and for general
household consumption.
Unequal allocation of resources based on gender is also reflected in the
lack of investment in education and health care for girls.4 When asked what
she wanted to do in the future, a young girl in Mechiri, Andhra Pradesh, said,
“My parents stopped my education after grade 9. They thought that women
shouldn’t get more education so they stopped me from going to school. The
only wrong thing I did was to be born as a girl in this society. Now I don’t
have any desires. My parents will take every decision for me.” Many girls our
research teams met in other contexts remain illiterate and confined to their
homes, and can only hope to find good husbands.
Women and girls particularly chafe against restrictions on their physical freedoms—freedom to dress as they wish and go where they please. To
women in Uttar Pradesh, freedom means freedom from the veil; in Afghanistan, it means freedom from the chador. In Bangladesh, women long to go to
the market without permission from their husbands. According to women in
Tecamín, Mexico, while women are hobbled, men freely “come and go and
tell their daughters and wives what to do and where to go.”
Intra-household inequality frequently gives rise to domestic violence.
Across contexts, women report being beaten by their husbands, parents,
brothers, and other relatives. In Abzif, Morocco, girls described how their
brothers beat them if they stopped on the streets to watch a funeral ceremony
pass by. “Even if a man looks at her, to her brother it means they have had
illicit relations, and she is assaulted automatically.” At other times, women
become targets of violence because of small, daily disputes. From villages in
Bangladesh to Cambodia, focus groups described how failure to prepare the
evening meal on time can invite the wrath of husbands. In Koh Phong, Cambodia, young men said, “Domestic violence results from the fact that the wife
does not prepare food in time for the husband who has come back from work
in the forest. And sometimes it is because the men are drunk.”
A general lack of respect for women is pervasive across study contexts.
Demanding dowry (in South Asia) and keeping multiple wives (in Africa) are
accepted traditions. The norms of gender inequity are so deeply imbedded in
some contexts that men cite religious texts to defend their legitimacy. A man
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
295
in Kaludoma, Ruvuma, Tanzania, argued, “This is biblical, that men will have
power over women. A man is the first one to come in this world. The bride
price paid to her parents allows a man to overpower her.” In Shantakalia,
Bangladesh, men scoffed, “Women’s power? What is that? Whatever we say
to our mothers, wives, and sisters, they do it.” Women who try to oppose
such social norms are usually considered aggressive and evaluated negatively,
while adherence invites respect (see also box 4.1 in chapter 4).5
Melise, a 35-year-old woman in Chiksisi, Malawi, is among those who
spoke of earning respect from her husband—but not without initial resistance. Her husband initially refused to let her take a loan for brewing and
selling beer. “He said that if I take the loan, I will become promiscuous.
He beat me over this issue. What made me determined more than ever was
the fact that I was not his only wife. I had discovered that he had another
wife from Mozambique whom he married before me.” Melise went ahead
and took the loan over her husband’s objections, using the money to buy
a bale of clothes to sell in the local market. The business earned her good
money and, eventually, respect from her husband. “He started being nice
to me and started telling me that we should sit down and strategize on the
way forward.”
Amartya Sen (1990) uses the phrase “cooperative conflict” to describe
gender tensions within families. He argues that women and men have both
congruent and conflicting interests that affect family life. Because of the
extensive areas where interests converge, decision making in the family tends
to feature the pursuit of cooperation, with some agreed resolution, usually
implicit, of the conflicting aspects. Our data mostly support this interpretation. Conflicts are present within families, yet the family still offers the best
recourse in the absence of other options available to women.
Markers of successful family collective action
In thinking about what kinds of collective action and entities can help people
move out of poverty, it is useful to understand the main characteristics that
make families successful settings for collective action. In our data, five such
features stand out: underlying norms of trust, loyalty, and solidarity; repeated
interactions and relationships over long periods of time; authority and control over decisions and resources; pooling of production and/or joint production; and sharing of both upside gains and downside risks.
These characteristics of successful family collective action are present to
a more limited degree in several other types of collective entities, including
spontaneous groups of poor people, externally supported community-based
296
Success from the Bottom Up
organizations, large-scale microcredit schemes, community-driven development programs, and microequity corporations (table 7.2).
The economic literature supports the importance of these features of the
family, especially trust. Trust is the foundation of family life: it both derives
from and reinforces interactions and relationships built over long periods
of time. Such high levels of trust seldom extend to those outside the family.
Indeed, some scholars have cited the inability to trust anyone beyond the
family as an explanation for why some cultures seem to enjoy greater prosperity than others. Banfield (1958), in his Moral Basis of a Backward Society,
was one of the first to propose a cultural explanation for underdevelopment.
He attributed the backwardness of a village in southern Italy to the inability
of villagers to transcend their immediate family interests and come together
for the common good. Putnam (1993), also using Italy as an example, discussed the positive impact of a more altruistic, “civic” culture on the quality of political institutions. In Trust, Fukuyama (1995) shows how successful
family businesses in China are built on high levels of family trust. But this
trust does not extend to nonfamily members; hence the difficulties in scaling
up family businesses to large corporations.
Our data, too, support the importance of trust outside the family as a
basis for cooperative endeavors. On average, nearly 60 percent of respondents
across study regions who said they were “very likely” to cooperate to solve
common problems—to solve water problems or deal with a crisis—also said
that people can be trusted. In contrast, only 40 percent of these likely cooperators said “you can’t be too careful” when it comes to trusting others.
In nonfamily settings, especially where parties are unknown to each
other, collective economic action may suffer from problems of moral hazard, lack of information, and lack of ability to monitor performance. Arrow
(1971) uses the insurance market as a model. Once a client receives a life
insurance policy, he has the incentive to engage in discretionary behavior like
smoking because he knows that the insurance agent cannot keep an eye on
him or that the costs of tracking behavior are too high. Similarly, in the case
of joint production, it is difficult to observe everyone’s behavior, which gives
individuals the incentive to shirk and free ride.
This is seldom the case within families, where repeated interactions and
long-term relationships among members reduce the incentive and ability to
free ride or cheat.6 Family members expect to be together for a long time; thus
how they treat each other today will matter in the future. People rely on their
relatives in running businesses because loyalty to the family fosters a shared
commitment to the family firm and its prosperity (Ward 1987; Van den Ber-
TABLE 7.2
Collective entities replicate some but not all characteristics of successful families
Community-based organizations
Family
Friends
Spontaneous
groups
Trust, loyalty,
solidarity
High
High
High
Low to none
Repeated
interactions/longterm relationships
High
Authority and
control over
decisions and
resources
High
Low
Medium
Pooling/joint
production
Both
Pooling
Sharing both
downside risks and
upside gains
Both
Downside
High
Large-scale
microcredit
schemes
Communitydriven
development
programs
Microequity
corporations
High
Low/
Medium/
medium
low
Low/
Medium/
medium
low
Low
Low
Low/high
High
Pooling
Mostly pooling
Pooling
Pooling
Both
Downside and
limited reciprocal
upside
Primarily downside; Downside
some upside
Both
Upside
High
Medium
High
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
Characteristics
Organized groups
linked to external
organizations
297
298
Success from the Bottom Up
ghe and Carchon 2003). The intimate relations between family members
facilitate communication and shared decision making, reduce information
asymmetries, and encourage risk taking for the benefit of the firm. Everyone’s
interests align more easily to growth opportunities, and the costs of reaching,
monitoring, and enforcing more formal contracts are practically negligible.
The strong social bonds within families withstand many pressures that can
tear apart other forms of collective economic action.7
Given the difficulty in replicating all the features of families in nonfamily collective action, joint ownership and production in these settings
remains rare. It is more common to find collective action that involves some
pooling of activities in the production or marketing chain—for example, a
dairy cooperative with individual ownership of cattle but joint marketing
of milk.
As noted, families usually face negative shocks together. They also work
collectively to get ahead and, most of the time, share the gains. Outside the
family, by contrast, it appears that there are more successes in collectively
confronting downside shocks than in sharing upside gains. In part, this is
because it is easy to verify shocks such as illness, accidents, fires, and death,
and there is usually nothing to be gained from hiding the information. Windfall profits are another matter. In this case, the incentive to hide gains is high,
because if they are fully disclosed, they will have to be shared.
In the remainder of this chapter, we briefly analyze the successes and
failures of the main nonfamily forms of collective action, from the many
informal groups of poor people all the way to the few instances of shared
equity. We evaluate the extent to which these organizations have been able to
reproduce the features of successful family-based collective action. We focus
on functional equivalence rather than on form; for example, we consider
the extent to which monitoring of behavior has been achieved and do not
assume it will always involve face-to-face interaction as in the family.
Friendships Matter
I tried to be a bad boy in school. I liked using drugs. But I had a friend in
high school who really affected my life. We treated each other like brothers. I was hooked on drugs; he was not. He became my counselor, and he
pointed out the ill effects of my vices. He really influenced me and helped
me change. He opened my eyes for me to see all the wrongdoings I had
done.
—Noel, a 25-year-old man, never poor, Kilaluna, Philippines
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
299
It is not so much our friends’ help that helps us as the confident knowledge
that they will help us.
—Epicurus
Poor men and women in our study regions universally spoke of the value
of having good friends. Friends come to the rescue in times of urgent need with
money to buy food or medicine for a sick child. Friends also teach valuable
skills—farming, fishing, driving, carpentry, weaving—and provide information
on market prices. They may inculcate good habits and encourage quitting bad
ones. And in conflict areas, friends guard homes fiercely as if they were their
own. When asked whether he felt endangered, Mohtar, a man in Lupotogo,
Indonesia, a village affected by Christian–Muslim conflict, said, “When the riot
occurred, my house was very sheltered. After all, it was guarded by friendship,
wasn’t it?” The multiple ways in which friends help each other are illustrated
by the story of Richard, a poor man in Tanzania (box 7.3).
Our quantitative data confirm the extent to which people in our communities depend on friends for help. Friends are an important source of borrowing for everyday consumption, second only to relatives. This finding is
true for all groups except the fallers, for whom moneylenders are second and
friends are third. In the African study contexts, all groups rated friends to be
more important than even relatives as a source of credit for consumption.
However, when it comes to bigger loans to finance major household
events such as a marriage, an illness, or a funeral, friends fall to third place,
after relatives and moneylenders, among all four mobility groups. Poor people’s friends are usually poor themselves. Although they can assist in meeting shortfalls in everyday consumption, they often do not have the capacity
to help meet major expenses. This is why so many poor people turn to
moneylenders for big expenses, and it is also why they attempt to cultivate
and connect with richer patrons.
In setting up business activities, the chronic poor and the fallers depend
primarily on relatives and moneylenders. In contrast, movers from poverty
and the never poor more frequently have access to government banks. Nearly
23 percent of movers and 30 percent of never poor said that they had taken
loans from a government bank over the study period to finance their farms
and stores. In contrast, only 5 percent of the chronic poor and 18 percent of
the fallers were able to access bank loans. While friends may not have helped
the poorest finance major events or businesses, all groups considered their
friends, along with their relatives, as their most important source of information on government programs.
300
Success from the Bottom Up
BOX 7.3
Richard’s story: Friends to the rescue
In the remote region of Kagera, Tanzania, our team met Richard, age 43, who
had fallen into poverty over the study period. Yet he had retained his faith in
life and said that “cooperation with relatives and friends” had helped him
pull through.
Richard once earned his living by fishing in Lake Victoria, and he attributed his fishing skills to fishermen he had befriended when he was 18 years
old. In 1993, at the age of 31, Richard migrated to a small island in Uganda,
also situated on the lake. He stayed there until 1998, catching sardines, a
risky and low-paying job. His wife remained at home, taking care of their
small family farm. Toward the end of his stay in Uganda, he developed a
tumor. His friends there paid his medical expenses. Next, he received the
message that one of his children had died. He came home to Tanzania and
started mourning.
At the time the field team met him, Richard was cultivating bananas, a
skill he had learned from his parents when young. His friends had been an
invaluable support for the trade. Whenever he failed to sell his bananas at
the local market, he would store them at a friend’s house instead of carrying
them back to the village. A friend also lent him a bicycle that he still depends
on to transport the bananas.
In addition to providing support for his livelihoods, his friends in the village helped him cope with the adversities he faced on returning home. His
wife had to be hospitalized, and his child was bitten by a dog. To make matters worse, he was accused of theft. “In 2002, I bought bananas from somebody else and was arrested. I was informed that those three bananas I bought
from that guy were stolen one day before.” His friends stood by him through
all this, and one of them even paid T Sh 10,000 for his bail. “I was about to
smell the jail when my friend helped me.”
Though he still lives in abject poverty, Richard feels much gratitude. He
is saving to cope with emergencies and to buy his own bicycle, and he is an
adviser to the village football team. “I still thank God that everything went
well. I am on good terms with my community. I feel more confident now
than in the past, because my family is more stable, and the society and my
friends respect me.”
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
301
Bonding: Spontaneous Community Organizations
If you do not belong to any group in this village, you cannot survive.
—Discussion with men, Bufkaro, Uganda
The most frequent type of collective action our field teams encountered, beyond the family, consists of spontaneous groups of people coming together to pursue common ends. Most people instinctively prefer to
associate with those like themselves, and most such groups bring together
friends and neighbors who are all poor. In communities with a high degree
of social stratification, this tendency to stick with one’s own can be problematic. First, it helps keep poor people poor, as they associate with others who
also have limited resources, information, and contacts. Second, the elite also
bond among themselves, blocking poor people’s access to opportunities and
sometimes fighting dirty if they feel threatened by poor people in any way.8
Bonding groups thus reflect and perpetuate these inequalities.9
Limitations of poor people’s bonding groups:
Coping but not prospering
There are no formal credit organizations here. One can borrow from
friends and relatives if one wants to take a child back to school. You can
also borrow from community groups such as Bika Oyeguze and Okusuka
[revolving credit groups]. But we don’t have sureties, and we are unable to
access credit and loans from banks and credit organizations.
—Men’s discussion group, Bufkaro, Uganda
In general, our qualitative data show that poor people’s groups help them
meet important immediate household needs, but seldom more than that.10
The groups operate on too small a scale and have too little capital to provide
the finance, livelihood training, or markets that could help their members
move out of poverty. Sustaining small and underfunded bonding groups, in
isolation from each other, is often difficult. Without an influx of new ideas,
skills, markets, or capital, many such groups dissolve once immediate needs
are met—or when they come up against the formidable obstacles posed by
the rich, who come together to defend their own interests.
Most often, poor people come together to save. In such groups, sometimes called rotating savings and credit associations, the members meet (usually weekly) to chip in small amounts of money, then take turns drawing
the entire pool of savings. A principal purpose of saving groups is to finance
302
Success from the Bottom Up
immediate household needs.11 Such groups may be relatively stable, or they
may be formed on an ad hoc basis to deal with emerging problems.
On average, we encountered more finance, credit, and saving groups in
the study communities than groups formed around livelihood, health, education, politics, religion, or ethnicity, though the presence of political groups
is also striking (figure 7.1). On average, more than 2.5 credit groups exist in
each community visited.
There are some regional differences. The sampled communities in Bangladesh, Andhra Pradesh, Uganda, and Thailand have more than three credit
groups per village (figure 7.2). Conversely, very few credit groups exist in
the communities we visited in Colombia, which are home to large numbers
of internally displaced people; in these sites, the church and other religious
associations play a more important role.
Besides saving groups, funeral and burial groups exist in almost all our
study communities in Africa.12 As in revolving credit groups, members make
regular (usually monthly) payments into a common pool, which members
can then draw on to meet expenses for burial ceremonies and wakes. A poor
man in Ntogo in Kagera, Tanzania, said, “I am a member of the Bushunguru
funeral group, and I pay 500 shillings monthly. The group is involved in digging graves, fetching firewood, and contributing 10,000 for buying a shroud.
FIGURE 7.1
Finance/credit/saving groups are more common than livelihood, health,
education, religious, or ethnic groups across all study regions
Average number of groups
per community
3.1
2.8
2.5
2.3
2.5
2.0
2.0
1.5
1.3
1.1
1.0
0.5
0
Finance/
credit/
saving
groups
Farming/
trading
groups
Source: Community questionnaire.
Health/
education
groups
Political
groups
Religious
groups
Ethnic
groups
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
303
It has never helped me, and I wish it will never help me. Because the group is
for funerals, and a funeral is not a good thing.”
In the village of Bufkaro, Uganda, women recalled that before the burial
groups existed, people sometimes had to sell part of their land to finance
funeral ceremonies. “Now, when a member loses someone, the group uses
the money that has been raised to buy food for mourners, the coffin, and
other requirements for the funeral. Funerals take a lot of money when you
have to spend from your own savings.” The burial groups in Bufkaro also
help when people fall ill. Women in the village recalled how one of them
had fallen sick while working in the garden. The chairperson of the group
FIGURE 7.2
Saving and credit groups are more common in Andhra Pradesh, Uganda,
Bangladesh, the Philippines, and Thailand
Average number of saving/credit
groups per community
4.0
3.5
3.0
3.7
3.3 3.2
3.1
2.9
2.7
2.5
2.5
2.0
1.5
2.0
1.8
1.9
1.6 1.5
1.2
1.0
1.3 1.3
1.0
0.5
AP
U (SH
G
A G
BA (P )
N an
(E el)
m
TH pow
A
)
(
PH Ine
q
I(
)
P
SE ane
W N ( l)
In
B
(L fra
an )
d
U dis
P
t
(C )
TA aste
)
N
M (Ru
AL v)
(
M Infr
E
a
AS X ( )
SA Eth
M n)
IN (C
D on
O
f)
(
AF Con
G
f)
(C
PH on
I ( f)
CO Co
nf
L
)
(C
on
f)
0
Study region
Source: Community questionnaire.
Note:
AFG (Conf) = Afghanistan, Conflict
AP (SHG) = Andhra Pradesh, Self-help groups
ASSAM (Conf )= Assam, Conflict
BAN (Empow) = Bangladesh, Women’s
empowerment
COL (Conf) = Colombia, Conflict
INDO (Conf) = Indonesia, Conflict
MAL (Infra) = Malawi, Infrastructure
MEX (Ethn) = Mexico, Ethnicity
PHI (Conf) = Philippines, Conflict
PHI (Panel) = Philippines, Panel study
SEN (Infra) = Senegal, Infrastructure
TAN (Ruv) = Tanzania, Ruvuma
THAI (Ineq) = Thailand, Inequality
UGA (Panel) = Uganda, Panel study
UP (Caste) = Uttar Pradesh, Caste
WB (Landdist) = West Bengal, Land distribution
reforms
304
Success from the Bottom Up
organized members to carry her to the hospital on an engozi, a stretcher made
of local materials. The women added with amusement, “We have nicknamed
them [engozis] our personal helicopters because they help carry people above
someone else’s shoulders.”
Yet another type of poor people’s collective action is the digging society.
These groups were reported to involve only women, because “men do not dig.”
At the start of each agricultural season, the women prepare the land on the
farms of relatively well-off households in the community. They use the money
to buy household items like saucepans, clothes, mattresses, plates, and cups, as
well as books and uniforms for their children in school. However, payment is
not always guaranteed, especially when harvests are bad. And because of petty
theft in communities, members may need to take extreme measures to protect
their money. The treasurer of one digging group resorted to keeping the money
“hidden under her bed or in sacks of sorghum or even in a bottle.”
Our regression analysis further confirms the finding that collective
action rarely help poor people move out of poverty. We use two indicators
to measure spontaneous collective action in our data. The first is an index of
propensity of collective action constructed through principal components
analysis, which includes two questions: (a) the likelihood of cooperation
between people in the village in the event of a fire or other calamity, and
(b) cooperation in solving common problems like water supply issues in
the village.13 Responses for both were ranked on a four-point scale ranging
from very likely to very unlikely. To avoid problems of endogeneity, initial
conditions were used for both questions. The second indicator focuses on the
extent to which access to networks and associations within the community
had increased, remained about the same, or decreased over 10 years (for the
detailed specification and results, see appendixes 4 and 6).
Figures 7.3 and 7.4 report the association between the index of collective
action and access to networks and household movement out of poverty after
controlling for other variables. Study regions where these measures were not
consistently available in all communities have been dropped from the graphs.
As before, the single dots represent the coefficients: the greater their height,
the higher the magnitude of the estimated association. The bars around the
coefficient represent the one and two standard error bounds. The more tightly
clustered the bounds, the lower the standard error (or error one can expect in
the estimation) and the more significant the association between collective
action/access to networks and moving out of poverty.
Collective action or change in access to networks is mostly negatively
associated with household mobility, except in some regions in Africa
305
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
FIGURE 7.3
Community’s propensity for collective action has mostly negative association
with movement out of poverty
Coefficient and Standard Errors: MOP and Collective Action
Propensity to move out of poverty
0.4
SEN
UGA
0.2
INDO
AFG
0
UP
WB
COL
AP
ASSAM
PHI MEX
BAN
TAN
–0.2
–0.4
Study region
Source: Multivariate linear regression analysis using data from household survey and community questionnaire (see appendix 6).
(Uganda, Senegal) and in Afghanistan and Indonesia. In fact, the association
is negatively significant in the study communities in Uttar Pradesh, Andhra
Pradesh, Bangladesh, Tanzania (Ruvuma), and Mexico. In purely statistical
terms, the negative association implies that propensity for collective action
is less among the movers and higher among those stuck in chronic poverty.
This is because the chronic poor gravitate to their own bonding groups as a
means of coping in the absence of other alternatives. The chronic poor are
more likely to engage in collective action precisely because they are poor.
In Uganda, the propensity to come together for the collective good has
a positive but insignificant association with moving out of poverty. That is,
households are more likely to move out of poverty in villages where people
are more likely to engage in collective action, but not significantly so. Our
qualitative data on groups in Ugandan communities support this finding.
In sum, then, poor people’s propensity to come together and cooperate
among themselves does not seem to be directly associated with lifting them out
of poverty. Poor people’s small, spontaneous groups find it difficult to link to
306
Success from the Bottom Up
FIGURE 7.4
Change in access to networks has mostly negative association with movement
out of poverty
Propensity to move out of poverty
1.0
Coefficient and Standard Errors: MOP and Change in Access to Networks
PHI
0.5
MAL
0
UP
MEX
PHIC ASSAM
WB
COL
BAN
INDO
TAN
–0.5
–1.0
Study region
Source: Multivariate linear regression analysis using data from household survey and community questionnaire (see appendix 6).
external funds, organizations, and resources, and they mostly remain excluded
from groups of the more prosperous. However, the propensity to cooperate
does play a critical role in sheer survival and eases the pain of poverty. Such
cooperation also nurtures the trust and self-confidence that can provide a foundation for scaling up collective action and forging external ties so that poor
people’s groups grow in size and influence. Finally, as we discuss in the last
part of this chapter, actions by groups of poor people can improve government
performance and the quality of public goods provided by government.
Collective action by those who have the least, then, paradoxically helps
society even though it may not lift poor people themselves out of poverty.
Organizing by the rich: Garrisoning against poor people
If anybody catches fish in any private-owned land of the village, he or she
needs to share the fish with the ijaradars [private leaseholders]. Catching
fish openly in the marshland has been banned for the villagers. The ijaradars arrange to guard the marshland with their own people. They guard
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
307
the water. They have 15 or 20 dogs and hire people who possess weapons,
pistols, shields, cutlass, etc.
—Discussion with women, Shantakalia, Bangladesh
Poor people’s collective action is deeply affected by social inequality. Deep social divisions result in parallel worlds—and separate bonding
groups—for the rich and poor. While poor people’s groups lack resources
and connections, rich people’s groups are powerful precisely because they
have these advantages.
Although social divisions appear to be universal in our study communities, caste, ethnicity, and wealth are particularly strong markers of division in
the South Asian villages. In Shantakalia, Bangladesh, many poor people live
by fishing in the village ponds. But the landlords guard the ponds fiercely,
using pistols and packs of guard dogs to keep poor fishermen away. Those
who are caught fishing either are punished and sent to prison or are forced
to share their catch. Marshlands are guarded as well. According to both women’s and men’s discussion groups, a local administrative officer ordered the
landowners to stop such practices. He also formed a cooperative of the local
fisherfolk and leased land to the group. Not surprisingly, the official was soon
“transferred.” A key informant reported that since the transfer, the problems
have started again. He said, “The landowners have now infected the ponds
with poison. . . . Many poor people could not tolerate this shock and wanted
to commit suicide.”
Such extreme behavior seems to be more common during periods of
economic stagnation. Growing inequalities may also increase the incidence
of crime and cause social networks to deteriorate even further. An elderly
woman our team met in Malawi does all her farming herself because she
does not trust anyone in her village and fears her crops will be stolen. “I was
once a victim of such act. My whole pen of goats was stolen,” she said. Her
case is an extreme form of what Putnam (2007) calls “hunkering down,” that
is, people withdrawing into their shells like turtles in economically divided
communities.
Organized Groups Linked to External Organizations:
Coffee, Dairy, and Pigs
To become a member of cooperatives, one needs to have the means. These
organizations may be a help in moving out of poverty. But in the beginning, it is necessary to have a certain standard of living and a capacity
308
Success from the Bottom Up
of financing to pay the “admission fee,” to have the cows to be a member
of the cooperative, and to have the guarantees and the money to enter a
system of savings and credit.
—Discussion group on livelihoods with men and women,
Ferjama, Morocco
Poor people’s groups are weak in part because all their members are
similarly constrained and bring meager resources to the collective. But it is
also because these groups are not linked to any outside sources of capital
and know-how, such as banks, government agencies, or NGOs. Private sector
partnerships are almost totally missing. The absence of such linking organizations in rural areas is striking.
We did find cases of community organizations that bridged social groups
and were supported either by NGOs or by the government, unlike the spontaneous bonding groups discussed earlier. But they were few and far between in
our data, and they experienced considerable problems in scaling up.
We present three examples of externally supported livelihood groups
from our data: from Tanzania, Morocco, and Malawi. All three have been
successful in a limited sense. Each, however, is limited to a single community,
and scaling up has proved difficult. Using these case studies and others, we
identified four types of problems that can hinder the efforts of livelihood
groups to be successful and extend their benefits to a wider set of people.
First, even when groups are linked to external resources, there often is no
attempt to make them self-sustaining in the long run. Second, while external
support helps, it also increases the likelihood of corruption, cheating, and
elite capture of new resources. Third, groups may experience lack of trust and
solidarity among their members. Finally, businesses started by such groups
often turn out to be unprofitable because of poor advice or because they
quickly saturate local markets.
In Ngimyoni, a village in Ruvuma, Tanzania, 74 of 700 local coffee farmers switched to growing organic coffee in 2002 with the help of TechnoServe,
an international NGO. TechnoServe started working with coffee farmers after
the government dismantled the state-run coffee cooperatives that had provided farmers with subsidized inputs, credit, savings instruments, markets,
and advice. Two years after liberalization, as a new set of middlemen captured the coffee market and international coffee prices fell, the prosperity of
coffee farmers dropped dramatically. The only exception was the farmers who
had switched to specialty coffee with TechnoServe. These groups boasted,
“Mwe nakulengana na nenga; ne mi mukikundi sa kahawa,” meaning “You can-
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
309
not be as well off as I am; I am a member of Specialty Coffee Growers.” The
normal reply to such boastful words was “Na ne lasima nyingila mukikundi
omo,” meaning “I will also join the Specialty Coffee Growers Group.”
Some specialty coffee farmers in Ngimyoni became part of a new branch
of the Association of Kilimanjaro Specialty Coffee Growers. The association
consists of groups of 25 farmers, mobilized by TechnoServe, who receive
training in best practices for growing specialty coffee. The NGO supplies them
with inputs, buys their coffee in cash at good prices, and pays them additional
amounts if the coffee fetches better-than-expected prices in the international
market. As members of the association supported by TechnoServe, the groups
have access to credit to purchase agricultural inputs, and agricultural extension officers from the NGO visit their farms to ensure good practices. TechnoServe has not achieved the scale of the government-run cooperatives, and
it has experienced problems including lack of trust, cohesion, and capital
among members. Still, the Ngimyoni coffee farmer groups are among the
few cases of successful cooperatives we encountered. Not all cooperatives in
Ruvuma or other study regions have done as well.
In Morocco, several kinds of formal associations are an important part
of community life. These groups range from dairy cooperatives to water user
associations to goat breeding associations, some of which are supported by
the local government. Membership does entail economic benefits, usually
through pooled marketing of products like goat milk. But over time, poor
members have complained of losing control over resources to the more powerful, elite members.
The community of Ferjama has the highest level of mobility among both
poor and well-off households in our Morocco sample. It has benefited from
a range of associations, including a dairy cooperative, a village development
and cultural association, and a water users association to manage irrigation.
The dairy cooperative in particular has contributed to the mobility of many
households in Ferjama. Initiated by the local office of the Ministry of Agriculture, it uses premises provided by a local ruling tribe. The cooperative
purchased dairy cattle for its members, deducting payments from their subsequent sale of milk. The cows are individually owned. In addition to collecting the milk and selling it to the central dairy in Casablanca, the association
provides fodder for livestock and organizes the breeding process.
The cooperative has expanded over the years as members have invested
in more cattle. Women praised the cooperative, noting that the profits have
helped people cope with crises in their households. The men were more skeptical. They noted incidents of conflict between members, although, they said,
310
Success from the Bottom Up
“We manage to resolve them between us on the basis of our traditions and
customs.” But fissures were evident. At the time of our study, the members
were discussing ways of taking their products themselves to other local and
regional markets, bypassing the cooperative. Most important, the cooperative had become less accessible to poorer households in Ferjama. The richer
members had raised the membership fee steeply over the years, leaving the
poor behind.
A livelihood club of 10 women in the village of Bamlozi, Malawi, was
one of the few cases of successful joint production we found, but it also illustrates the serious problems such groups can face. The club was established in
1997 through the efforts of a community development assistant (CDA) who
worked for the Ministry of Community Development and Social Welfare. The
CDA had approached the village headman to sell him the idea of women’s
clubs, but people were not interested, having been disappointed in the past
by such groups. They said, “We are tired of giving our deposits to the government. The government just wants to steal money from us.” After a lot of convincing, finally 10 women who were neighbors came forward to try again.
The first business the women undertook was cooking and selling fritters.
They shared the costs of cooking oil and flour and made the fritters at home.
By the time our field team visited, the women had expanded their operations
into white pig breeding. An initial investment of MK500 was raised collectively by the members and deposited in the government-owned Savings and
Credit Cooperatives (SACCO), and the group received a loan of MK34,000
to buy pigs and feed. They also received training in pig rearing and in how to
construct a kraal (pigsty). The pigs multiplied and the women prospered.
Things started going wrong in 2001, a drought year, when the women
had to feed the pigs grass because maize husks had become too expensive.
Many piglets died. At the same time, SACCO loan officers started demanding
repayment, and the women gave the CDA money to deposit in their account.
The CDA told the women that SACCO was misappropriating their money
and advised them not to give SACCO any more payments directly. Unfortunately, the CDA—the only man they trusted—then died, and the women
were visited by a new CDA. “That new CDA took our SACCO account book
to his office. He said they will sort out any differences between them and
SACCO.” Meanwhile, an outbreak of African swine fever killed many local
pigs. Although the pigs reared in the group’s kraal were not affected, the new
CDA advised the women to sell them and get new pigs.
To this day, the club members don’t know what happened to their deposit
book or to the savings they used to make payments on the loan. At the time of
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
311
the field visit, the women were determined to pool their resources and buy two
piglets to start over. The 10 women have now worked together for more than 10
years (one new member joined three years ago). All of them are illiterate, but
they have joined adult literacy classes so that they can read their deposit books.
Despite their problems, the women have prospered somewhat, and they are
proud to have contributed to other people’s prosperity by selling them piglets.
They said, “If you see big white pigs in this village or neighboring villages, they
are breeds from our kraal. We sell a four-month piglet at 2,000 kwacha; they
sell a full-grown pig for 6,000 kwacha. We really regret that we listened to the
CDA boss and sold our pigs for 11,000 kwacha.”
Scaling Up Collective Action
Scaling up activities that help improve poor people’s livelihoods can yield
benefits, but it is difficult to get it right. In this section, we first discuss the
surprisingly low profile of NGOs in supporting collective activities in our
study sites. We then look more closely at three ways of scaling up collective
action: savings and credit, community-driven development, and microequity
corporations.
Absence of NGOs
I open my thoughts. I can say what I want to say. Right after the conflict,
I learned that if I will not air my thoughts, I will continue to struggle.
Nobody can say what I can or cannot do [laughs].
—Mina, a 20-year-old woman talking about how NGOs helped her
in Glikati, a conflict area of the Philippines
Nongovernmental organizations are strikingly absent in people’s
accounts of the most important factors that helped them move out of poverty in our study sites across countries. Indeed, when movers were asked to
name the three main reasons for their escape from poverty, NGO support was
hardly mentioned, accounting for just 0.3 percent of the reasons given. It was
mentioned just slightly more often than illegal activities (0.1 percent).
This finding does not mean that NGOs are not present or not helping.
They are helping in ways that our participants do not directly link to their
movement out of poverty. One reason is that direct NGO assistance to households is often small and spread out over time, as is the case with microloans.
Often, support for livelihoods is provided without a clear market analysis,
leading to quick market saturation or to problems of price and quality.
312
Success from the Bottom Up
Second, NGO activity may be linked to provision of infrastructure such as
water, schools, and health clinics. Such assistance is critical for survival, but
it may or may not be seen as leading to poverty escapes. Third, many NGOs
are involved in providing critical humanitarian assistance, assisting orphans
or the disabled, or providing relief after humanmade and natural disasters.
Finally, some NGOs are involved in activities to “empower” poor women and
men, activities that are extremely important but that in themselves may not
necessarily translate into economic capital. These qualifications apply to the
activities of both national and international NGOs.
In conflict-affected Glikati, Philippines, for example, discussion groups
mentioned the local women’s association and the international NGO Oxfam.
The women’s association was a new credit association consisting of 30
women. Perhaps because it was new and small, it was difficult to get much
information, even from members, about how the organization operates and
which NGO started it. But this is also symptomatic of the problems that
affect groups created by outsiders: it is easy to create groups, but difficult to
make them function effectively. Oxfam was praised for its many activities,
particularly in installing water pumps, which had helped prevent illness in
young children. Group participants said, “We didn’t realize how dangerous
our water here is until Oxfam told us the effect of just dumping human waste
into the river.” Oxfam also provided relief goods right after the conflict.
In Guluteza and Matdombo, Malawi, several different types of NGOs
were mentioned and sometimes praised. The Malawi Council for the Handicapped reaches out to the disabled. Discussion groups reported, “The good
part with this organization is that it gives monetary support and also business
loans on easy terms to its members once a year in order to do some incomegenerating activities.” Another NGO takes care of orphans. People also mentioned NASFAM, the National Smallholder Farmers’ Association of Malawi,
which demonstrates modern methods to farmers and buys their produce.
People appreciate the support offered by NASFAM, but the success of farmers
still depends on exogenous factors, mainly the rains. Malawi suffered from
drought in the early 2000s; participants said, “Now the only thing remaining
to have is good rain.” Marketing remains a problem for some crops. Soyabean
farmers said that even when they can produce crops, they have bags sitting
in their backyards, unable to find markets. People criticized several credit
organizations, saying that they “at times trap people into cycles of loan taking
and repayment.” Sometimes NGO help is clearly too little. Save the Children
distributed 20 blankets once and 11 blankets another time, but “these were
not sufficient for the needy.”
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
313
Despite these problems, civil society has a critical role to play, particularly in helping poor people scale up their economic activities through linked
and federated organizations. We encountered a few examples of scaled-up
activities, three of which are described below.14 Two of them are supported
by government: the women’s self-help group movement in southern India,
which reaches millions of poor and often illiterate women, and the Kecamatan Development Program in Indonesia. Grameen Bank is an independent
people’s organization that includes a bank and several activity-specific companies such as Grameen Telecom.
Microcredit groups
Installment is given weekly, and this is a great problem. If one gets one taka
one Tuesday, the next Tuesday they will come and sit for that taka [waiting
for repayment]. They will remain seated even at night. They will remain
seated for money even if one dies.
—Ziaul, a man in Digbari, Bangladesh
Poor people need more credit, not less (see chapter 5). They are also
willing to pay high interest rates, because the alternative of borrowing from a
moneylender is usually even more expensive. The Grameen Bank experience
and its replication around the world has proven poor people to be bankable,
yet we do not see a flow of loans to small entrepreneurs. Banks still hesitate to
give poor people loans because of the high costs of monitoring, which raises
the probability of default, a classic moral hazard problem (Stiglitz and Weiss
1981; Bester 1985, 1994). Poor people lack collateral with which to signal
their willingness to repay.15 Poor people also borrow small amounts and
often live in remote locations, making the transaction costs of serving them
high. Recent innovations using “smart cards” are overcoming these constraints
and combining microcredit with a broader range of financial services.
According to our data, we report two examples of large-scale programs that
deliver microcredit to poor women and a range of services to support poor people’s livelihoods. In both cases, despite impressive achievements, it is unclear
whether most of their members have moved out of poverty—although it is
clear that most are better off than before they participated in these programs.
The first example is that of women’s self-help groups in Andhra Pradesh, which
are sponsored by the state government and now reach millions of poor women.
The second is Grameen Bank, a microcredit bank owned by poor women in
Bangladesh. Grameen is one of several large-scale microcredit NGOs working
in Bangladesh; the others include BRAC, ASA, and Proshika.
314
Success from the Bottom Up
Although the SHGs are government-sponsored and Grameen Bank selffinanced, the two programs share features in common. Both create solidarity
groups of poor women who meet weekly and generally live close to each
other. Both start with activities to build self-confidence and trust. Both focus
on savings and credit activities. While bringing women together in groups
builds solidarity for peer monitoring and ease of transaction with facilitators,
loans are given to individuals and are used for individual activities. If one
member defaults, all are denied subsequent loans; if all pay promptly, they
are entitled to larger loans. This gives incentives for group members to monitor each other and pay promptly. Repayment is made easy with doorstep collection and by splitting the loan amount into small weekly installments, and
repayment rates are 90–98 percent. Both programs have started programs to
finance and insure against illness and death. Both give loans for children’s
education and undertake other social protection activities.
Both programs have initiated livelihood activities among members.
Grameen’s borrowers usually start small businesses, anything from basket
weaving to rice cleaning to rickshaw companies. SHG members in Andhra
Pradesh have made individual improvements in their livelihoods, from rearing livestock to running shops. Working in groups, they also produce grains,
including maize and groundnuts, for the government. The groups have also
initiated a rice credit line that has achieved scale quickly and improves food
security of all members, who can buy rice in small quantities at lower prices
than from the shops.
The Andhra Pradesh SHGs have achieved vertical scale over the past
decade by federating across villages into federations at the level of the mandal (second tier of local government) and district. These provide services and
loans to members. By March 2007, the state government had helped organize 8.6 million poor women into 688,253 SHGs. These had federated into
just over 30,000 village organizations, which, in turn, had federated into 910
organizations at the mandal level, feeding into a smaller number of districtlevel federations. By 2005, the groups were able to mobilize $250 million in
savings every year, receiving $475 million from banks (Aiyar, Narayan, and
Raju 2007). Grameen Bank currently extends loans with no collateral to more
than 7 million poor people, 97 percent of whom are women. As of October
2007, Grameen had extended loans totaling $6.55 billion, according to the
organization’s Web site.
It is difficult to obtain precise statistics on the extent to which SHG members or Grameen Bank members have moved out of poverty. From our own
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
315
study in Andhra Pradesh, we find that belonging to SHGs is associated with
moving out of poverty. Grameen Bank estimates that 64 percent of its members have moved out of poverty, though other studies have offered more conservative estimates.16
The microcredit model works because the risks are exogenous and noncovariant, which gives people incentives to pool. Social relations become
effective substitutes for a failure of the market or the government to provide
credit. However, while microcredit through group lending generally helps in
sharing the downsides, as people use the small loans to cope with shocks, it
has been far less successful in creating upsides by expanding livelihoods.17
The very practices that microcredit institutions use to enforce repayment
discipline may hinder members’ ability to use the loans for businesses.
For instance, most microfinance institutions (MFIs) give small loans, with
repayment beginning immediately. This limits the usefulness of the loans
for financing activities like a business, from which returns may only accrue
in the medium term. As Roodman and Qureshi (2006) observe, “If a woman
takes out a loan to buy and raise a calf, for example, the calf will not start
generating income for her a week later, when the first payment is due.” Poor
borrowers consequently are hesitant to take risks, as they are afraid of business failure.
Some of our study participants from Bangladesh complained that the
strict repayment regimen poses obstacles to moving up. In Mirabari, poor
people spoke of having to sell their rickshaws to repay their loans. Jibon,
a chronic poor woman in Digbari, had to sell off her poultry to repay the
installments. She lamented, “I borrowed about 13,000 taka from BRAC and
Grameen Bank. Out of that, I have repaid 5,000 taka and I spent the remaining 8,000 idly as my fields at that time were flooded and I could not work.
This year, I bought nine chickens. When I could not return the installment
amount, I had to repay it by selling the nine chickens.” Asiya, a woman in
Hasanbagh, wondered, “How good are these loans? We have to repay them in
installments each week. The amount they give finishes off quickly.”
Community-driven development
People appreciated the fact that even the building of the school is
participatory.
—Discussion group talking about the Kecamatan Development
Program, Patobako, East Java, Indonesia
316
Success from the Bottom Up
I was asleep. A local guard came in my home and commanded me to go
and transport bricks on my head in order to build a school. Am I free? Am
I not a slave in my own country and village?
—A poor man in a discussion group about a CDD program,
Bugokela, Kagera, Tanzania
The term community-driven development (CDD) was coined by Hans
Binswanger and Deepa Narayan in 1996 at the World Bank to describe programs
that give community groups authority and control over development decisions
and resources, including finances. Special attempts are made to involve poor
people, women, and other marginal groups. Funds generally flow through local
governments to community bank accounts. The hallmark of such programs,
when they are well done, is transparency: information about rules, budgets,
wages, contractors, and bid amounts is widely disseminated in an attempt to
reduce the corruption and collusion that have plagued many traditional programs. CDD programs start with solidarity and information meetings among
people living in the same village or neighborhood. Community members set
priorities, develop proposals, and implement and monitor the programs. Grants
are given for communal infrastructure and loans for individual livelihoods. The
more successful CDD programs also address downside risks, particularly health
risks, either directly or through linkages with existing health care systems.
One of the world’s largest and most successful CDD programs is the
$1.3 billion Kecamatan Development Program in Indonesia. It reaches about
35,000 villages, half of all villages in Indonesia, with block grants for community infrastructure development. It also supports a variety of entrepreneurial activities through groups. In several of the communities our study teams
visited, this program was mentioned as among the top factors contributing
to community prosperity. The program taps into local traditions of gotong
royong (working together to solve problems) and musyawarah (public discussion of issues). In conflict-affected communities in North Maluku, both
Christians and Muslims credited the program with rebuilding trust across
religious groups as they undertook rehabilitation of houses together.18 The
Indonesian experience illustrates the importance of trust, unity, participation, transparency, accountability, and pooling of risks—the features associated with successful families—in making collective action work.
In contrast, the experience with CDD in some villages in Tanzania shows
how difficult it is to change existing practices of elite capture and build trust
and solidarity. In environments of low trust and elite control over resources,
it is likely that external resources will get captured as well. The Tanzania
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
317
Social Action Fund is working well in several communities, but in the villages
of Gabunazi and Bugokela in Biharamulo district in Kagera, the program is
dysfunctional. Both are semi-arid border villages where a constant influx of
migrants has resulted in poor social cohesion and low levels of trust. The
recent discovery of gold was followed by a surge of gold seekers; this has
strained the traditional social fabric and is blamed for a rise in crime. In this
context, CDD initiatives are seen as a “development tax,” a tool given to leaders and powerful groups in the community to exploit the weak even further.
Most decision making about projects is concentrated in the hands of these
elites, and poor people see demands to participate and contribute as infringing on their freedom. One poor man in Bugokela said, “Freedom is when you
can sleep and nobody comes to disturb you at night, telling you to go and
fetch water for building a school.”
In both villages in Tanzania, an aura of nepotism and corruption surrounds “development contributions.” People try to hide from local officials
and policemen so that they will not be forced to hand over what little savings they have. One man commented, “These people tell us that we have to
contribute for the school, for the police, and for offices. But we are the ones
who bring stones. We make the bricks and offer our labor. So where does
the money go? They do not even tell us what they use it for. Of course we
understand where it goes. This is the money they use for drinking; this is the
money they use to buy more goats; and this is the money they use to pay us
when we do casual labor for them.”
Poor people’s corporations
While there are some efforts to scale up livelihood groups horizontally, across
districts, states, and countries, there are hardly any examples of scaling up vertically to create corporations owned and managed by poor people or on their
behalf. In our responses from 60,000 people, we found not one example of
such corporations. Although hundreds of women were frying fritters, rolling
out tortillas, or making cookies, there was no “Mrs. Fields” in our data.
In the United States, Debbie Fields started her business of making cookies for home parties with sales of $50 and $75 on the first and second days.
Today, Mrs. Fields Cookies is a vertically integrated company with franchise
outlets in malls across America and annual sales of about $70 million. The
Indian equivalent of Mrs. Fields is Lijjat Papad, a women’s organization manufacturing various products such as baked snacks that are exported around
the world. Started by seven women, it is now run like a cooperative, with
40,000 female member-owners who are referred to as “sisters.” One of the
318
Success from the Bottom Up
core values of the corporation is the concept of “mutual family affection,
concern, and trust.”19
The most advanced form of capitalism, shared equity, embodies the
norms that are embedded in successful families, notably that of trust. In
most cases, corporations accomplish this trust not through face-to-face relationships, but through institutional norms and practices, including financial
disclosure and shareholder voting on major decisions. When rules and transparency are violated, trust declines, and even large corporations can sink.
Poor people have the skills, initiative, and trust within their families that
can provide a foundation for successful business ventures. What they need
to become the next Mrs. Fields or Lijjat Papad are innovative instruments to
improve their access to finance, supported by technical guidance. Indeed,
what they need are the same financial instruments that are available to the
well-off, including equity, and the means to scale up their livelihoods vertically (see box 7.4 for some innovations). The ideal is microequity, where
poor people own their businesses. Equity financing reduces risk by sharing it
between the microentrepreneur and the financier who gives the grant. It also
lowers transaction costs and, most important, gives poor people a stake in
their own business (Pretes 2002).
Getting Together for Local Public Goods
Now democracy is working in its full spirit. Compared to the past 10 years,
the local government is showing more interest and concern for the public
good, as the people’s political awareness and comprehension has increased.
They are questioning the government on every issue. Meetings are held,
public consensus is taken into consideration, and all people are involved
in the deliberations. The government’s activities and its policies are now
people-oriented.
—Discussion with men, Lingatla, Andhra Pradesh
In her now-classic Governing the Commons (1990), Elinor Ostrom shows
the ability of local groups to cooperate to manage common property resources
and avoid overexploitation. Our data are replete with instances of cooperation around local public goods. This cooperation takes two main forms:
improving the social environment and improving the physical environment.
Unlike group activity around livelihoods, collective action to improve the
social and physical environment is generally undertaken by the rich and poor
working together to solve problems that affect them all. This is perhaps one
of the key reasons for its success.
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
319
BOX 7.4
Transforming collective action into corporations of the poor
Corporations “for profit” and “of the poor” are rare and just starting. It is not
a surprise, therefore, that we hardly saw any evidence of such corporations in
our own data.
Grameen has created a yogurt company as a joint venture with the
French Danone company. Sweet yogurt is a traditional food in Bangladesh,
hence there is local demand for the product. The factory will produce 3,000
tons of yogurt, employ 1,700 Grameen Bank members, and source milk from
300 microfarms each owning less than four cows. The yogurt will be sold at
the affordable price of about 7 cents a cup. Once the French company is paid
off, this “social business” will be totally owned by Grameen Bank members,
so poor women will have a stake in its success.
Fabindia, a large Indian ethnic wear company, created a number of
small producer-owned companies as part of its Artisanal Company Network.
Aided by a grant from a private investor, the network has set up communityowned joint ventures in rural areas with artisans and craftspeople as shareholders. Currently sourcing textile and nontextile products from 15,000
artisans across 21 states in India, the network is expected to create 100,000
sustainable jobs for artisan shareholders by 2012. Although the network will
ease Fabindia’s sourcing supply chain, which is currently overstretched at one
location in Delhi, artisans will benefit from inputs, training, access to funding, and sustained demand.
Besides corporations, there are new models of MFIs that are raising
finance by investing in public equity markets. Their potential is reflected in
the response to the initial public offering of shares in Financiera Compartamos, Latin America’s largest microlender. Shares of the Mexico-based microfinance institution (MFI) were oversubscribed 13 times, with prices rising by
22 percent on the first day of trading (CGAP 2007). The pent-up demand for
shares is largely a reflection of the high interest rates charged by the MFI,
which were at one time in the range of 110 percent per year. Compartamos
defends its high-interest, high-earnings strategy as a means to expand the
number of people it serves; basically it overcharges existing clients in order to
reach out to potential future clients. Despite high interest rates, Compartamos
has not at any point lacked clients; poor people are willing to pay very high
rates of interest, and the interest rate charged by Compartamos is still lower
than the rates charged by moneylenders and other sources (CGAP 2007).20
320
Success from the Bottom Up
Most collective action around public goods in our sample appears to be a
substitute for state and market failure. In the absence of basic services such as
schools, clinics, or security, or when these services are of poor quality, people
come together to provide or improve them. We do find some examples of
collective action that complement the state. These include people’s efforts to
share costs and participate in providing public goods and solving community
problems in tandem with state efforts. Even when the state is functioning
well, groups perform important functions in claiming people’s rights and
monitoring the performance of the state and markets.21 In a well-functioning
modern state, an informed citizenry, a well-organized civil society, and the
threat of losing elections keep governments motivated to perform well.
Improving the social environment
Chiefs became tired of thieves, murderers, and those who swear when
drunk. They got together and came up with a group that would not be
scared to enforce security. People offered themselves, those who were ready
to die or kill. They put together weapons such as a bow and arrow, a club,
thick rubber bands, a maize flywheel, and a catapult.
—Discussion group, Bamlozi, Malawi
Almost everyone wants to live in a community and household free from
fear, crime, violence, social discrimination, and social tensions. One of the more
common forms of cooperation we found is people getting together for selfdefense. We also found innumerable cases, particularly in the African contexts,
in which community residents have come together to guard themselves.
Village defense parties are common in many African villages we studied,
particularly in Malawi and Tanzania. In some villages in Ruvuma, Tanzania,
they provide protection against wild animals. In Namdenye, a village located
near the Selous Game Reserve, the fear of wildlife is pervasive. Elephants, wild
pigs, and baboons destroy crops such as paddy, maize, and bananas that are
major sources of income to the community. People are angry that the government seems intent on preserving wildlife at the cost of human life. Several
cases of lions hurting and killing people and livestock have been reported to
the district authorities, but nothing has been done. The villagers now move
together in defense groups. “We have to organize ourselves for the journey to
the farms. Although everybody has his own plot, you cannot go alone. If you
want to go to the farm while your neighbor has planned another economic
activity like brewing, you have to cancel the trip—even if that means staying
home idle for the whole day.” Although the village defense groups are generally credited with improving security, over time some of these organizations
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
321
have evolved into local militia, thus threatening the very cause of security for
which they were formed (box 7.5).
People’s self-defense groups are also common in conflict-affected settings.
In several communities in Assam, respondents spoke of how village defense
parties had become involved in dispute resolution and had helped young men
who had strayed into antisocial activities, sometimes by giving them loans.
BOX 7.5
Community policing in Malawi: From protection to abuse
In the poor farming community of Mzaponda, Malawi, discussion groups
spoke of getting together for self-preservation and safety. In 2001, a spell of
dry weather caused an epidemic of severe hunger, which in turn led to widespread stealing and violence. “People’s maize was being stolen, but the worst
affected were the goats. A lot of people lost their livestock,” reported a discussion group. A 50-year-old woman continued, “The thieves used to challenge
us. They could even take off your clothes if you were found sleeping outside
your home. We used to wake up in the morning, see our property, and say
‘thank God you really exist!’ People were being killed at night while tourists
were being robbed. Some were also being murdered.”
Despite repeated requests to the authorities, security did not improve.
According to discussion groups, the police worked in cahoots with the
thieves and released them as soon as they were caught. The villagers then
formed what they called Inkatha, a community policing group. The group
now provides security in the village. But a discussion group with youths
revealed how Inkatha really works. “Inkatha are people who are chosen by
people in the village. When they are chosen, they are given powers. When
you are caught stealing by the village headman, you can argue, but when
you are caught stealing by the Inkatha, you cannot do anything.” As our team
found out later, Inkatha simply takes the thieves away and beats them. Only
then do they hand the thieves over to the police.
Inkatha has helped curb crime and is mostly respected in the community. But there are whispers that the group is becoming yet another evil to
contend with. In a discussion on livelihoods, the women in the village had
this to say: “Inkatha is causing our businesses to decline. As soon as it is six in
the evening, they declare that time is up for business. They come to the place
where we sell beer and say that they are going to break the clay pots we are
using unless we give them a little bit of something. The money we have been
able to generate is already very little. They stop us from making more sales;
then they demand money from us for them not to break up our clay pots. Can
a person improve [and get ahead] with such acts?”
322
Success from the Bottom Up
Such groups are also common in the conflict sites in Indonesia and the Philippines, where at times they are recognized and assisted by the army.
Women in some contexts have organized to improve their own security
against violence in their homes. In some villages in Andhra Pradesh, participation in self-help groups gave women the courage to collectively protest the
sale of locally brewed alcohol called arrack, which they considered a cause of
domestic violence. In the village of Malkapur, women came together to close
down all liquor shops in the village. “We threw out the storage cans and other
vessels filled with liquor,” they informed our field team. “This was possible only
with the women groups, which gave us collective power.” In Dhampur, women
revealed how their SHGs fought abuse. “If any injustice is done to our women,
we do not keep quiet. Recently, one husband thrashed his wife while he was
in a drunken state. Our group came to know about this incident, and we all
went to him and abused and threatened him, saying that if it happens again,
we will take serious action against him. The power of women’s groups is up to
that extent.”
More broadly, women’s voice and organization is challenging deep
norms of gender inequality. As they gain confidence, women run up against
resistance and sometimes violence. In most cases this gives way to reluctant
acceptance, which later turns to admiration as women start bringing new
money home. A poor scheduled tribe woman in Pulagampalle, Anantapur,
Andhra Pradesh, said that her husband objected to her joining a SHG because
the meetings, held outside the village, would cut into her working hours. He
beat her, but she joined anyway. She took a loan of Rs 10,000 (about $250)
and started a petty shop. Slowly, her husband changed his mind, and he now
encourages her to go to group meetings. She is illiterate, but her two daughters are studying medicine. In Dayabhara, Bangladesh, Shehnaz met similar
resistance when she joined a group. Her husband beat her, and her motherin-law called her names. “But now that our family is benefiting from my savings, they don’t do this,” Shehnaz said. Women in both study sites said they
now insist on their names being included on documents like land titles. And
they are fearless enough to go to court if abandoned by their husbands.
Overcoming deeply entrenched caste inequalities is another challenge
that women’s groups in Andhra Pradesh have confronted. Through rituals,
songs, and prayers, groups are helping women of different castes break down
old barriers. Pedakka, a member of a SHG in the village of Atmakur, said,
“When we come together in groups, we realize that the blood in you and me
is the same. In the meetings, now everyone sits together. There is no discrimination.” In Malkapur, people spoke of how access of the lower-caste groups
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
323
to temples and schools has improved thanks to women coming together in
groups. “Ten years ago, inequalities of caste and religion were predominant
in our society. Because of these differences, people belonging to the scheduled caste and tribe communities were not allowed to enter the temple. Now
there are no such differences, and even SC and ST people are coming to the
temple along with us. They are coming to our houses and sitting beside us.”
Although caste was specific to the study regions in India, in other sites, too,
cooperation in groups is seen as leading to an increased sense of equality.
“Torang—all of us in the village are equal,” said one of our participants in
Tattantok, Indonesia. “Tarada—there is no difference. The groups taught us
that we are together in better or worse.”
Improving the physical environment
The community did all this. The school was built with the help of everybody
in the community. The families with kids in school had to cooperate, give
money.
—Discussion with women, Guadalamoros, Mexico
People come together to repair or build infrastructure, usually minor. They
improve mud roads and paths, clear bush, build schools and places of worship,
reclaim ponds and wells. The success of such collective action depends on good
leadership and social solidarity, both of which build trust that people’s contributions will not be misused. In Guadalamoros, Mexico, where the women were
determined to obtain secondary school education for their children, the community built a secondary school, along with a community center and a health clinic.
All were financed in part by remittances, and the school eventually received government help as well. In Chiksisi, Malawi, the community started a preschool
for young children, coming together to mold bricks for the building. A churchsupported relief organization contributed cement and food for the children.
The very act of working together reinforces unity and cooperation. In
Senialpara, Assam, people attributed improved social harmony to the coming together of the entire community to build a namghar (prayer hall). “We
the villagers together dug large ponds and started a fishery last year. By selling
fish, we earned about one lakh of rupees, and with this money we constructed
a big namghar in our village. This namghar has united the villagers more, and
now even people who earlier did not take part in social activities, do; redress
of disputes is held in this namghar. Earlier it was very small and could not
include all the persons inside, but now it is a lot bigger. This namghar has
increased the unity and religious feelings of the people.”
324
Success from the Bottom Up
Pressing claims and demanding accountability
I have done things I did not know I was going to do. I did not know I was
going to develop, coming to an office, explaining to someone my rights as
a displaced person and fighting for them.
—Alejandra, a 35-year-old displaced woman, Villa Rosa, Colombia
In addition to improving the physical and social environment, collective community action offers poor people a powerful tool to advance their
claims to resources and enhance accountability of government (Heyer, Stewart, and Thorp 2002). We find countless examples of people cooperating to
demand better roads, water supply, schools, health clinics, and community
halls. Often, they are first denied and succeed only after repeated tries. Our
evidence on collective action enforcing accountability is supported by studies
that highlight the role of people’s collective efforts in working for the benefit
of the community at large.22
The residents of Shivanoor, Andhra Pradesh, faced a drinking water crisis. Women were compelled to walk 5 kilometers each day to fetch one can
of water, which was often insufficient for the entire household. They recalled,
“Our bodies pained. Our necks were strained because of holding these heavy
water cans. The children who accompanied us had wounds on their feet due
to lack of footwear. We used the water only for drinking purposes and bathed
only once in 20 days.” In 1998, the women together with the rest of the village collectively approached the local leader and sought redress. Their voices
were heard, and the community was equipped with a borewell and a water
pipeline the following year.
Residents of Barumangga village in Indonesia together decided to request
replacement of a civil servant because of his poor performance and corrupt
practices. The community was affected by conflict between Christians and
Muslims and had received government assistance for evacuees. The civil servant had misappropriated these funds. “In addition, there was a lack of cooperation among his staff, and service to the community was not very good,”
recalled one of our key informants. Under pressure from the community, the
local government finally replaced the bureaucrat.
Most of the examples we found involved people demanding resources
or accountability from government. There were very few examples of people
demanding accountability or redress from rigged markets, perhaps because
cases of joint production and ownership of assets are rare or suffer from
free-rider issues, making it difficult for small producers to come together and
demand fair prices.
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
325
Complementarity and substitution: Interaction between states
and social ties
North (1990) and Knack and Keefer (1997) capture in their work this two-way
directionality between civic cooperation and the functioning of states. Woolcock (1998) and Narayan (1999) further explore this dynamic interaction
between the state and society and argue that different combinations of bridging
ties and state functioning can result in different outcomes (figure 7.5).
In the ideal scenario (quadrant I, labeled social and economic wellbeing), good governance complemented by high levels of cross-cutting ties
among social groups leads to positive economic and social outcomes. Informal social groups complement the functioning of the state. While people
crowd local sports matches, choral groups sing in every church and hall, and
neighbors get together to picnic, business clusters produce export-quality
goods and government-provided services hum along.
We did see evidence of virtuous circles between local governments and
collective action. The village of Mintang in Bukidnon, Philippines, shifted in its
democracy ratings from being nonresponsive 10 years ago to being responsive
at the end of the study period. This was due to a combination of two factors:
election of a village leader who listens and presence of community associations
FIGURE 7.5
Different combinations of bridging ties and state functioning result in different
outcomes
WELL-FUNCTIONING STATES
LOW
CROSS-CUTTING
TIES
(insular social groups)
II. Exclusion
(latent
conflict)
I. Social and
economic
well-being
III. Conflict
IV. Coping
DYSFUNCTIONAL STATES
Source: Adapted from Narayan 1999.
HIGH
CROSS-CUTTING
TIES
(civic engagement)
326
Success from the Bottom Up
that started working with the elected leader. The leader was known to be fair
and approachable, and the associations were driven by mutual understanding
and respect among community members. The outcome, within a fairly short
time, was total transparency in local government budgets.
But all communities are not blessed with the virtues of good leadership or
social unity. In such contexts, our evidence suggests that external interventions
by government programs such as the National Solidarity Program in Afghanistan and Janmabhoomi in Andhra Pradesh can play a role in engaging communities in development. NSP is a rural development program initiated by the
World Bank and managed by the Ministry of Rural Rehabilitation and Development in Afghanistan. The program provides grants to villages for rehabilitation,
reconstruction, and income generation projects. In order to benefit from these
grants, the communities have to first hold democratic elections of a community development council, which is then engaged in all stages of the project.
Similarly, the Janmabhoomi program was initiated by the state government of
Andhra Pradesh to engage communities in their own development.
In quadrant II, labeled exclusion, communities have reasonably well-functioning governments but these have been taken over or unduly influenced by
the dominant social groups. Exclusion leads to latent conflict. This is visible in
many of the villages our teams visited in the South Asian context. The cases of
rich landlords poisoning communal ponds to exclude poor fishermen in Shantakalia, Bangladesh, or the upper-caste Lambadis restricting opportunities for
the lower castes in Dhampur, Uttar Pradesh, fall into this category.
When such communities degenerate, they land in quadrant III, where
conflict, violence, and anarchy prevail, and the state dissolves or collapses.
As the state ceases to fulfill its functions, the primary social groups become
informal substitutes for the state. Warlords, mafias, guerrilla movements,
and other armed groups seize control. We see examples of this in Colombia,
where many urban communities have been taken over by different guerilla
factions, and community leaders have “disappeared.” Some communities in
Assam and in the southern Philippines also fall in this category.
However, when societies have cross-cutting ties to a reasonable extent,
they can overcome social divisions and cope with poorly functioning governments. This is the situation in quadrant IV, labeled coping. Groups and associations of the poor, such as savings groups and village defense parties, become
substitutes for failed or dysfunctional states and provide coping strategies.
In Bangladesh, for example, poor men and women wanted to access government loans, but red tape and corruption kept government credit schemes out
of reach. People found it much easier to obtain credit from their own groups
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
327
that were linked to NGOs. Similarly, the Inkatha self-defense groups, which
often lead to vigilante justice, start as a system to provide security in communities facing a collapse of law and order.
When formal institutional arrangements fail, whether in providing policing or schooling or credit, people often try to solve their problems themselves,
collectively. However, these efforts are substitutes for failed modernization and
failed formal institutions. Collective action has a cost in time and money, as
people must come together for meetings, organize, raise funds, implement
plans, manage and repair resources, and solve conflicts. The idea should not
be to make citizens fend for themselves in providing basic services, but to
guarantee that poor people have access to the basic minimum so they can get
on with improving their lives.
When governments and markets do their job, networks and groups of
poor people can play a key role in enforcing accountability among the providers of goods and services. They can also enable people to exercise their
citizenship rights in the effort to create just societies.23
Conclusion
Across our study communities, the most common unit of collective action
is the family. It is not indigenous organizations working in isolation, nor is
it collective action supported by NGOs, the government, or the private sector. We highlight the features of the family that seem to underlie the success
of family collective action: social solidarity, unity, and loyalty; repeat interactions and relationships over time; authority and control over decisions;
pooling of resources and/or joint production; and the ability to share both
downside risks and upside gains.
All other forms of collective action fall short when they are measured
against these criteria. There are some successes, but all have limitations. We
draw several important conclusions.
First, in most instances, poor people’s collective action in isolated small
groups helps them cope and survive but not get ahead. Indeed, in socially
stratified societies, poor people’s bonding groups reflect and perpetuate
social inequality. Poor people bond with other poor people precisely because
they are poor and find themselves mostly excluded from groups of the rich.
This is not to suggest that collective action by poor women and men is unimportant. Spontaneous bonding among poor people provides the essential
foundation for scaling up and for creating social movements. Poor people’s
organizations also have important spillover effects in improving the overall
social and political environment.
328
Success from the Bottom Up
Second, collective action may not help poor people move out of poverty
unless there are outside interventions that help them break the constraints of
resources, knowledge, skills, capital, and markets. Interventions like Grameen
microcredit and the Andhra Pradesh self-help groups have allowed poor people’s groups to link up horizontally and vertically so they can gain sufficient
scale to access resources and gradually gain social and political voice in their
communities.
Third, creating economic organizations of poor people is very time- and
resource-intensive and does not yield immediate results. As a result, there is
massive underinvestment by NGOs, the private sector, and governments in
organizations of poor people. Without such investment, it will be impossible to scale up poor people’s organizations so that they become players
with bargaining power in markets. Nor will it be possible for poor people to
capture the greater profits higher up the production value chain. Investment
in organizations and associations that represent poor people’s interests and
are not captured by the elite is perhaps the single most important action that
NGOs, private corporations, foundations, and the government can take to
ensure fairer returns to poor people in market economies.
Fourth, collective action that substitutes for the failure of the state and
markets to provide basic services should be viewed as a transitional measure.
Collective action traditions are important in all societies and lay the foundations for the emergence of a strong civil society. Their ultimate goals should
not be to build schools or fend off lions, but to press demands for equity and
to hold governments and markets accountable.
Finally, while there are a few remarkable examples of successful microcredit and community-driven development programs, the challenge ahead
is to have many more such large-scale successes. There is a need to create
networked organizations of poor people in which they become the owners, hiring managers as needed. Ironically, the only organization that fits
this description is the equity corporation. We believe that a big challenge is
the creation of corporations and microequity organizations owned by poor
people that can help large numbers of poor people move permanently out of
poverty and live the lives they choose.
Notes
1. The fable comes from the Panchatantra, a series of five ancient Hindu texts that
use analogies from the animal kingdom to teach about life. The books stress five
principles pertaining to the value of friendship: mitra bhedha (loss of friends);
mitra laabha (gaining friends); suhrudbheda (dissension between friends); vigraha
(separation); and sandhi (union).
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
329
2. The fact that family help is most important to fallers and chronic poor may suggest that these groups are less able than others to access other resources (government, NGO, private). This is both a cause and a consequence of their difficult
situation.
3. Alderman et al. (1995) recognize conflict within the family as a central element
in poverty outcomes. They emphasize that individual household members are
likely to have different preferences and that this may affect the impact of transfers made to households to reduce poverty.
4. Using data from Indian hospitals on admissions of girls and boys, Kynch and
Sen (1983) showed that girls were typically much more ill before they were
taken to a hospital. The families themselves perceived little discrimination in
treatment, but there was clearly an earlier recognition of serious ailments among
boys.
5. For discussions of gender inequality in the literature, see, among others, Agarwal, Humphries, and Robeyns (2006) and Robeyns (2007). Robeyns argues that
social norms are usually gendered, that is, they apply to men and women in different ways. They impose notions of appropriate and normal behavior for men
and women, placing clear limits on how assertive a woman can be before she is
considered aggressive.
6. Axelrod’s Evolution of Cooperation (1984) is an important work that led to the
recognition of social relationships in economic thinking. In repeated trials of the
prisoner’s dilemma game, the author found that even when individuals followed
tit-for-tat strategies, stable outcomes that were more cooperative could emerge.
When they did, these outcomes were usually due to some norms that produced
cooperation between individuals.
7. Family-owned enterprises are not completely free from governance issues. Analyzing data from 883 family-owned firms in the United States, Schulze, Lubatkin, and Dino (2003) find problems like free riding and high consumption
of perks. Family firms may also be forced to provide employment for family
members, which may result in decisions that are suboptimal from a business
point of view. See also Gersick et al. (1997) and Daily and Dollinger (1992).
8. For the rich and powerful, bonding social capital enhances opportunities. Bebbington et al. (2006) found that local elites in rural Indonesia were able to consolidate their power through connections to the government and local private
companies. O’Brien, Phillips, and Patsiorkovsky (2005) also found evidence of
the “restrictive nature” of bonding social capital in communities in the United
States and Russia. In extreme cases, social bonding can facilitate violence (the
Ku Klux Klan, the Mafia, and Al Qaeda all come to mind). Rubio (1997) shows
how high levels of bonding within criminal organizations in Colombia supports
illegal activities, with returns exclusively for those involved in the group.
9. The same ties that bind can also exclude entire groups of people. The literature
on collective action clearly establishes that bonding only within one’s own social
group reduces opportunity sets for groups lacking power and wealth. In a famous
study, Loury (1977) showed that African American youth are disadvantaged in
the labor market in part because their parents lack social connections that would
give them information about jobs. Portes (1998) describes how the caste system
330
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
Success from the Bottom Up
in India, with its rigid boundaries, can restrict the lower castes’ access to opportunities. Moreover, a history of prejudicial treatment may spill into expectations of
poor outcomes. Using controlled experiments, Hoff and Pandey (2006) showed
that lower castes in India tend to start believing that as hard as they try, they will
get unfair rewards for their efforts. This expectation or belief can further reinforce
bonding.
Our study’s findings are in line with those of previous research by the authors
on this topic. In a poverty assessment in Kenya, Narayan and Nyamwaya (1996)
found more than 200,000 community groups in rural areas. But these groups
rarely helped the poor escape poverty, as they remained disconnected from
outside resources. Narayan (2002a) found that members of many indigenous
groups in Latin America, while exhibiting high levels of internal social solidarity, remained in poverty. Again, this was because they lacked the resources and
power to tilt the rules of the game in their favor.
In a study of 70 rotating savings and credit associations in rural Kenya, Gugerty
(2007) found that members mostly used group funds to finance immediate
expenses such as household items, school fees, food, medical care, and clothes,
as well as to pay down debts.
Dercon et al. (2006) find funeral groups to be highly prevalent in rural Tanzania
and Ethiopia. Such groups, they report, are usually “based on well-defined rules
and regulations, often offering premium-based insurance for funeral expenses.”
Question (a) was “Suppose something unfortunate happened to someone in
this village/neighborhood, such as a serious illness, or his house burning down.
How likely is it, in your view, that people in the community would get together
to help this person? Please rate your answer on a scale of 1 to 4, where 1 is very
likely and 4 is very unlikely. Has this changed from 10 years ago? Please rate your
assessment of the situation 10 years ago on the same scale.” Question (b) was
“If there was a problem with getting enough water in this village/neighborhood,
how likely is it, in your view, that people would cooperate to try to solve the
problem? Please rate your answer on a scale of 1 to 4, where 1 is very likely and 4
is very unlikely. Has this changed from 10 years ago? Please rate your assessment
of the situation 10 years ago on the same scale.”
There are many well-known examples of extremely successful NGOs that have
achieved large scale in Asia and Latin America. NGOs also play a critical role
in campaigning and lobbying at the national and international levels on such
issues as landmine removal, debt cancellation, and increased development support for Africa.
Lack of collateral, however, need not be the constraint. In a survey of 1,438
households across six provinces in Indonesia by Johnston and Morduch (2007),
only about 10 percent of the households that were creditworthy and not borrowing from banks reported lack of collateral as a deterrent. About half the poor
households that were creditworthy reported a strong aversion to taking debt—
they simply did not want to borrow and hence did not seek credit. This finding
challenges traditional thinking about the potential impacts that giving legal titles
to assets like land can have on the poor (de Soto 2000).
The Unfulfilled Potential of Collective Action
331
16. In a 1998 study, Khandker found that poverty among Grameen Bank members
could be reduced by 5 percentage points per year as a result of participation in
the program. This participant-level result can be translated into poverty reduction of 2.7 percentage points per year at the village level. However, in a 2005
study using panel data from 1991/92 and 1993/98, Khandker suggests that
long-term impacts of microcredit programs are smaller than those obtained from
cross-sectional study. That is, a woman’s participation in a microcredit program
reduces poverty by 1.6 percentage points at the participant level and 1 percentage
point at the village level.
17. In a study of 1,438 households in Indonesia, Johnston and Morduch (2007)
found that loans taken from microcredit institutions by low-income households
served immediate households needs about 30 percent of the time.
18. In a review of the impact of the Kecamatan Development Project, Barron,
Diprose, and Woolcock (2007) found that even though the project had little
direct impact on mitigating local-level conflict, it indirectly helped change
norms, attitudes, and expectations regarding how disputes could be resolved.
19. Information about Mrs. Fields and Lijjat Papad is available on their Web sites,
http://www.mrsfields.com/ and http://www.lijjat.com/index1.asp.
20. There are a number of small venture capital funds for micro and small enterprises including Root Capital and Lok Capital, among many others. For descriptions
of recent innovations, see the Web sites of the Clinton Global Initiative (www.
clintonglobalinitiative.org) and CGAP (Consultative Group to Assist the Poor,
www.cgap.org).
21. Heyer, Stewart, and Thorp (2002) distinguish three types of functions that
groups perform: overcoming market and state failures (efficiency), improving
the position of their members (claim), and distributing resources to the less
well-off (equity). They conclude that groups that better regulate within-group
relationships (based on rules, intragroup distribution, or other local institutions) are more likely to survive and function effectively.
22. A study of 121 rural water supply projects by Isham, Narayan, and Pritchett
(1994) revealed the significant role of participation in keeping the systems
functioning. Hammer and Pritchett (2006) find that when water supply projects
are redesigned to engage with communities, places with stronger social ties and
more cooperation do a better job of creating and maintaining water supply
than those with weaker ties. Knack (2000), using data from the United States,
finds that in states with more social capital, government performance is rated
higher. Our findings also tie in well with Putnam’s (1993) work on Italy, which
suggested that the density and quality of civic associations was the main factor
explaining the quality of regional government performance.
23. One of the main conclusions of the World Bank’s World Development Report
2004: Making Services Work for Poor People (2003) was that empowering the poor
through measures such as increased access to information can allow them to
hold politicians more accountable for service delivery.
Concluding Reflections
8
C HAPTER
H
ow do you conclude a study that has taken four years; spanned 21
regions in 15 countries, each with its own country team; used 10 different research instruments, both qualitative and quantitative; and analyzed
the responses of over 60,000 individuals? Besides, that is, with relief?
The literature on poverty is old, broad, and deep, and has lately become
technically sophisticated as well. Our study adds three new twists. One is that
we seek to understand poverty not by finding people who are currently poor
and studying them—the usual approach—but by finding those who have
moved out of poverty and asking them how they did it. After all, if we are interested in reducing poverty, why not ask those who escaped, if only to complement the hundreds of studies that examine those who are still poor? The
second twist was that we asked people to tell their own stories. We did this
both in individual settings and in a variety of focus group exercises. Rather
than conjecturing a theoretical narrative and looking to fill in the details
quantitatively, we let people create their own narratives, which we tried to
capture. These narratives are not the reality or even their reality, but they are
at least their own public framing of their realities. The third twist is that our
study focused on the local realities. While national policies get a great deal
of attention in poverty studies, the local conditions in which people live and
interact on a daily basis are often overlooked. These local conditions, we
would argue, are at the heart of the poverty narrative.
Oscar Lewis’s classic Five Families (1959) traces the day-to-day experiences and life stories of five poor families in Mexico. With just five narrative
arcs, his book, nonetheless, presents a picture of enormous complexity. Imagine, then, our concern about our own study, which uses open-ended research
methods to capture tens of thousands of voices and trace thousands of lives.
Would anything emerge beyond cacophony and chaos? Perhaps after 60,000
stories, there are no common themes, just 60,000 stories. Or perhaps, faced
333
334
Success from the Bottom Up
with the onslaught of data, we would superimpose our own narrative, wittingly or not—after all, “deconstructing” other people’s narratives is a popular academic sport.
We tried as best we could to distill from these data a set of common narratives or themes. We do not presume to have identified all the relevant issues,
and we are careful not to make specific attributions of causality. Rather, we
have tried to construct a set of coherent metanarratives that capture common
elements but allow for locally specific variations. Throughout, we have tried
to weave together the particular and the general, providing examples from
specific regions that illustrate the general themes.
Framing “Poverty”
Two historically persistent metanarratives exist about “the poor”: one associated with the political right and the other with the political left. They
have played important roles in framing the issue of poverty and poverty
reduction.
One metanarrative might be called the Victorian notion of poverty,
though it extends further back in time and has had a broader geographic
reach than even the empire on which the sun never set. It is that the problem
of poverty is the pathology of poor people. If, after all, life is a fair contest,
then the problem of losing is the losers themselves. This approach tends to
isolate “the poor” as a small, relatively stable group of people whose poverty
is the result of either their behavior (drinking, drugs, laziness), their attitudes
(fatalism, lack of initiative), their lack of skills (illiterates who cannot learn),
or bad luck (mental or physical disability, widowhood). Although few development professionals who work in poor countries share this view, this notion
of poverty remains popular among the better-off, in poor and rich countries
alike.
Like many persistent ideas, this one has both a small grain of truth and
a large dose of self-interest. The grain of truth, on which our study respondents often agree, is that people with serious substance abuse problems or
those who do not take initiative are more likely to remain stuck in poverty.
However, such individuals account for a minuscule fraction of the millions
of people in poverty around the world. This framing of poverty is based on
a fundamental fallacy. (All bears have hair, but this doesn’t mean that all, or
even most, creatures with hair are bears.)
The large dose of self-interest is that if the problem of poverty is a problem of poor people, then it is poor people’s problem. This belief justifies
Concluding Reflections
335
either of two unhelpful responses. One is the hard-line approach sanctioning few if any actions to benefit the poor, who are pictured as undeserving.
Some even argue that assistance to the poor encourages the bad behaviors
that are the cause of poverty (e.g., Murray 1984). The other response consists
of charity—identifying the poorest of the poor and giving them just enough
to allow them to survive, but not enough to move out of poverty.
The other metanarrative, also from the Victorian era but from a different
point on the political spectrum, is that poverty is a systematic and unavoidable result of the operation of market forces and that solving poverty requires
mass-based political action. This would have the government in a vanguard
role, acting to “save” the poor from the vagaries of an indifferent, if not hostile, market. Again, this view survives on a grain of truth and a generous helping of self-interest.
The grain of truth is that the poor do face an uphill struggle as they grapple with markets that are at best indifferent and at worst deliberately rigged
against them. Lacking assets, connections, access, and sometimes business
expertise, poor people often have great difficulty riding market forces out of
poverty, as chapter 5 explains.
The self-interest is that if the poor cannot save themselves, then someone
else must save them, and by grabbing power in the name of the many, the few
have often done very well. U.S. academic James Scott (1998) points out that
in order to make human beings manageable by the state, the complex realities
of their lives have to be reduced to a simple picture that the state can “see.”
This simplification makes problems amenable to solutions of what he calls
“bureaucratic high modernism”—programs that classify, quantify, and follow
rules. The vision of a top-down effort to eliminate poverty—by reducing it to
technical problems of program and policy design, finding the solution that can
be implemented by a modern Weberian bureaucracy, and funding that solution adequately—has great seductive power. In limited spheres, such top-down
programs have often had laudable results, leading, for example, to the massive
expansions of education and public health. But the attempt to eradicate poverty
by eradicating messiness and complexity, and in the process limiting choice and
the use of markets, has often led to disappointing, if not tragic, results.
Nearly everyone who works on development issues recognizes the inadequacy of these two metanarratives of poverty. While some think they are
straw men, and we hope that they are, nevertheless some straw men are, like
the Hindu demon Ravana, worth burning each year.1
If our findings do not support these metanarratives, can we suggest a
more useful way of thinking about poverty? An alternative framing of pov-
336
Success from the Bottom Up
erty, however simplified, does emerge from the narratives of the poor and the
formerly poor that we gathered.
In our study of communities around the world, poverty is not a problem
of “the poor” but is much broader. It is a problem of the many, not the few.
Poverty is fluid: it is a situation or a condition people find themselves in,
not a permanent characteristic. Most people living in poverty do not suffer
from fatalism or low aspirations; rather, they take initiative to change their
conditions, and most are confident that with hard work they will prevail.
Poor people value freedom and their social relationships, and they want to
use them to improve their well-being in a variety of ways. But their initiatives,
whether individual or collective, often come up against blocked opportunities, whether in the context of rigged markets or local democracies captured
by the elite. The key to poverty reduction lies in the intersection of initiative
and opportunity.
Practical Implications
We offer in conclusion some ideas about how the results of this study could
inform development practice. We do so with some trepidation, as the study
was not designed to isolate and examine the impact of popularly debated
programs, like microcredit, or controversial policies, like free trade. Nor could
we, with our data, evaluate the relative returns to specific projects—whether
a road would be better here or there, or whether input subsidies are more or
less useful than technical training for increasing productivity.
What we can do is relate the findings to four current approaches to poverty and then to three principles that we believe should inform poverty reduction efforts. We outline these principles in the full knowledge that no study
sees the whole picture and that there are no simple answers.
In the continuously roiling debates among actors concerned in one
way or another with poverty reduction—development practitioners, human
rights activists, NGO workers, entrepreneurs, philanthropists, economists,
and finance ministers, almost all of them nonpoor, the authors of this book
included—one can distinguish four major approaches.
National growth is all, and policy is the key to growth. One view is that the
primary determinant of how many people move out of poverty is how rapidly economic output in the country they live in is growing. Although there
might be churning of individuals and there might be local variations, in the
end most people are pulled up by rising wages and expanding employment.
These are the result not of individual actions but of market forces. Poverty
Concluding Reflections
337
reduction thus depends on policies that allow and encourage free-market
forces to do their work.
Although there is some substance to this viewpoint, as we showed in
chapter 5, it does not capture the whole picture. As Joseph Stiglitz (2005) puts
it, “Growth may be everything, but it’s not the only thing.” Our study brings
two caveats to the fore.
First, a growing economy does create opportunities, but access to those
opportunities is far from equitable. Poor people do not enjoy equal access to
free markets, where an invisible hand works in everyone’s interest. Rather, a
visible hand often works to hold poor people back. Sometimes this visible
hand is that of government, imposing restrictions that have the effect (if not
the intent) of thwarting poor people’s initiatives. Sometimes the visible hand
is of powerful private actors who collude to rig markets in their own favor.
Second, the national economy is important, but there are wide differences among localities. Seventy-three percent of the variation in net prosperity between our communities is within study regions. Where one lives can
make a great difference in how much one benefits from national economic
growth. Bringing the lagging localities up to speed can both help sustain
growth and create local opportunity where it matters most.
Poverty policy is about safety nets and programs. Another view, one focusing on the instruments directly under the control of governments, considers
poverty reduction a matter of creating the right set of redistributive transfers, income generation programs, and expenditures on social services (such
as health and education) used by the poor. Again, this approach has some
merit, as we show in chapters 6 and 7. Certainly programs that support poor
people and address their vulnerabilities are important dimensions of public
policy. But our study suggests three considerations.
First, our community mobility matrixes reinforce what has been emerging from various data sets that have tracked households over time: poverty
transitions are very fluid, and “the poor” are not in fact a stable, identifiable
group of people. There is much rising and falling. No static formula for targeting programs—by region, age, education, even current poverty status—is
going to predict accurately who will be poor, even in the near future. And
transfers (grants, loans) have to be fairly large to stabilize families, reduce
vulnerability, and end the cycling in and out of poverty.
Second, even accounting for people’s natural tendency to overstate their
own role in their achievements, it was striking how few people credited
external programs of any type as instrumental in their move out of poverty.
Although it is exciting to find programmatic initiatives that seem to be mak-
338
Success from the Bottom Up
ing a difference in particular contexts, it is nonetheless sobering to note that
NGOs were mentioned as a cause of moving out of poverty by only 0.3 percent
of our respondents—barely more than those who mentioned “illegal activities.” People most often cite new jobs, new agricultural initiatives, and new
businesses as routes out of poverty. Externally assisted programs need to play
a part, however small, in enabling people to scale up their livelihood activities into self-sustaining and market-worthy initiatives. Unless they can do so,
they offer only mitigation, not sustained reduction, of poverty.
Third, social services are important, but their impact on poverty reduction varies. In the case of education, while it obviously plays a large role, most
people have received by early adulthood all the formal education they are
ever going to have. Poverty reduction has to reduce poverty for those people,
not simply ask them to wait until their more educated children can escape
poverty.
Health plays a large role, but generally in a negative sense. Good health
by itself is almost never sufficient to move people up and out of poverty. Bad
health, on the other hand, bleeds resources and can wipe a family out financially. Bad health keeps poor people from moving out of poverty, and among
those who are not poor, a serious health shock can trigger a fall into poverty.
This finding is of key importance, because reducing falling can dramatically
increase the numbers moving out of poverty.
Abject poverty is a challenge for philanthropy. A third approach, less common in development agencies but looming large in the public mind in rich
and poor countries, is the view that “the poor” are beyond any help but direct
charity. This view defines poverty downward to include only the poorest of
the poor, the chronically destitute. In this case, it is easy to characterize poor
people as needing and deserving the charity of the well-to-do.
Our study really did not speak to this view of poverty. We allowed our
respondents to define poverty, and this view is not how they see poverty or
how most of the poor people in the study see themselves. Across study sites,
the chronically destitute are at most a very small fraction of those who are in
poverty, so our participants had little to say on this score.
There is certainly nothing wrong with wanting to help those who cannot help themselves. The danger of this view is that it redirects attention
from poverty as a global and mass-based phenomenon, affecting more than
half the world’s population, and redefines it as a narrow problem that can
be solved with individual acts of charity or corporate largesse. Instead of
demanding that markets and governments create fair and equitable access to
opportunity, it lets them off the hook for a public relations pittance.
Concluding Reflections
339
Poverty reduction will be driven by external actors. As noted above, some
view poverty as the result of a system that is biased against the poor, a system so powerful that it strips poor people both collectively and individually
of any agency in bringing about change. This view lends itself to solutions
featuring either large-scale redistribution of income or replacement of the
market as an economic system.
When the poor are viewed as a powerless mass, this denies the power
of their individual initiative and downplays the importance of freedom. An
unspecified “we” must help “them,” as they are incapable of overcoming the
powerful systemic forces holding them down. Again, there is something to
be said for this view. Those in poverty do often face an uphill battle against
powerful economic and political forces and formal systems seemingly biased
against them.
But overwhelmingly, poor people in their narratives do not see themselves as trapped. Again and again our respondents told stories of overcoming
obstacles by using their freedom to seize opportunities. They see maintaining
their own freedom and power as essential to finding their way out of poverty.
We come away from this study with the conviction that any initiative that
does not start at the root, by looking at the initiative and opportunities of
those in poverty, is bound to be misguided.
Given the flaws in these four approaches, what are the principles that
should inform poverty reduction?
The first principle is that all actions should seek to expand the scope for people
in poverty to use their agency. The view of the poor as people with “needs” to be
filled pervades development thinking. While there is no question that people
have needs, reducing people to their needs undermines their ability to help
themselves. People have needs but they also have dreams, ambitions, plans,
skills, ideas, and preferences—and people experiencing poverty are no exception. Despite the obstacles they face, the overwhelming majority of people in
poverty believe that the future will be better for themselves and for their children, and they see hard work and initiative as the means to achieve that future.
This expansion of agency applies equally to the public and private
spheres. Just as human beings cannot be reduced to their animal needs, neither are human beings reducible to the private sphere of homo economicus
and all else is intrusion. Rather, this expansion of agency takes into account
that people are embedded—in a family, in a location, in overlapping communities and identities, and as citizens in local and national governments.
Expanding agency is not code for laissez faire; it applies to expanding agency
in social and political spheres of life as well.
340
Success from the Bottom Up
Poor women, men, and youths exercise their agency as individuals as
well as collectively through groups and organizations that sometimes achieve
scale. External actors often find it difficult to invest in organizations of the
poor without trying to control these organizations. Moreover, investment in
organizing, whether for political or economic reasons, rarely yields immediate returns; hence the tremendous underinvestment. However, such investment is critical. When poor people are aggregated into linked groups and
organizations, their sheer numbers increase their bargaining power in markets and local democracies and bring them fairer returns.
The second principle is that actions should seek to transform markets into
ones that poor people can access and participate in fairly. A very large number
of poor people see market-based initiative as a means to advancement. But
poor people do not enjoy equal opportunities in free markets. The solution
is not to eliminate markets but to expand access to them in equitable ways.
Among many NGOs, there is deep skepticism about markets, although some
business interests lack respect for NGOs and for poor people as able business
partners. More equitable markets, particularly in rural areas, are more likely
to emerge when these unlikely partners work together to innovate and create
new business models and move poor people’s production activities higher
up the value chain.
The very small scale of most poor people’s enterprises creates great disadvantages in the marketplace. To the extent that their tiny livelihood activities can be linked and scaled up through organizations of poor people, the
playing field will become more level. Moreover, many poor people struggle
with a lack of connectedness—roads to reach markets, electrical connections,
channels to bring water for irrigating farms. Improving connectedness, especially for communities in rural areas, can greatly increase people’s ability to
take advantage of economic opportunities. Another piece of the puzzle is
credit and financial services. The microloans typically available to the poor
are often too small and too immediate in repayment terms to be used for
productive purposes that help amass wealth. Finally, connections to market
information and market know-how are vital.
The third principle is that well-functioning local democracies can help people
move out of poverty. People in poverty seek freedom and power over their lives.
But governance at the local level all too often turns into a zero-sum contest
for spoils. Corruption is pervasive, creating opportunities for some and barriers for others. The combination of fair elections, improved access to information, and collective action can enable poor people to demand accountability
Concluding Reflections
341
from local leaders. Fair, accountable local democracies and local leaders can
do much to liberalize economies from below.
Poor people are already working to change their world. They hope, they
work, they risk, they challenge, they take initiative, they fail, and they try over
and over again to make the world better—for themselves, their children, their
families, their communities, and their countries. Despite their experiences,
poor people still believe in markets and governments that are equitable and
just. What can we do to make this a reality?
Notes
1. In Hinduism, Ravana is seen as the principal antagonist to Lord Rama in the
Hindu epic Ramayana. Head of the Rakshasas or demons, he was defeated in a
battle of good over evil by Rama. The occasion is celebrated in India by burning
him in effigy during a yearly festival.
Appendix 1: Researchers and
Institutions Involved in
Country Studies
343
Other researchers
Research institutes
Philibert de Mercey,
Alejandra Val Cubero,
Najibullah Ziar
ACNielsen India, Masooma Essa, Aliya Wahdat, Mohammad Zarif
Sediqqi, Shingul Kaliwal, Abdul Wahdood, Besmellah Alokozay,
Sayed Awlia
Altai Consulting
Bangladesh
Shahana Rahman, Fatima
Habiba Lavoni Suvra, Mostafizur Rahman, Hummayan Kabir,
Jahan Seema, Nishat Sharmin, Mahamudur Rahman, Sabera Tabassum, Toufiqul Islam, Shamima
Gautam Shuvra Biswas
Sultana, Mahamud Kollol, Mujib Ul Hasan, Shakhawat Hossain,
Khadiza Begum, Anis Uj Zaman, Nahida Hasan, Sabera
Tabsumm, Shamima Nasrin, Sanker Kumer Roy, Md. AbdullahAl-Mamun, A. M. Anisuzzaman, Sabera Tabassum, Mohammad
Delwar Hossain, Debashis Fani, Wahid Sarker, Habiba Lavoni
Suvra, Nazma Yeasmin, Saleh Akram, Pritylata Biswas
PROSHIKA
Cambodia
So Sovannarith, Ingrid
FitzGerald
Chan Sophal, Kem Sithen, Tuot Sokphally, Pon Dorina, Kem
Sithen, Ann Sophapim, Chea Sovann, Chen Soportea, Chey
Nath, Chheang Vuntha, Choun Chanthoura, Chim Charya, Hang
Vannara, Heng Daravuthy, Hov Idh, Keo Ouly, Kim Sithy, Khun
Chandavy, Long Kolab, Men Sam On, Ouk Leakhana, Pean
Pancy, Ros Channak, Sek Vuthy, Sok Saroeun, Tang Kruy, Thun
Sean Heng, Yous Samrith, K. A. S. Murshid, Pon Dorina, Chhay
Pidor, Brett Ballard, Neak Samsen
Cambodia Development
Resource Institute (CDRI)
Colombia
Ana María Ibáñez, María
Teresa Matijasevic, Sergio
Iván Prada, Carlos Ariel
García
Liliana Velásquez, Mónica Ramírez, Carolina Villada, Miguel
Ángel Rivera, Adriana Quiceno, Lina Isabel Trujillo, Alejandra
Velásquez
Centro de Estudios Regionales,
Cafeteros y Empresariales
(CRECE)
India
Deepa Narayan, Binayak Sen
ACNielsen India, Sandeep Ghosh, Bharat M. Shah, Devendra
Tyagi, Mukund Chandran, Sarfaraz Nasir, Ruchika Kapoor, Vishnu
Shankar Tiwari, Saveena Khan, Arjit Mukhopadhyay, Kamath
Gopalkrishnan
World Bank; ACNielsen India
Success from the Bottom Up
Lead researchers
Afghanistan
344
Country
Other researchers
Research institutes
Deepa Narayan, Soumya
Kapoor, Giovanna Prennushi
Devendra Tyagi, Gopalakrishnan Kamath, Mukund Kumar
Chandan, Ghouse, Rajender, Santhosh, Niranjan
World Bank; ACNielsen India
India:
Assam
Deepa Narayan, Binayak Sen,
Ashutosh Varshney
Arijit Mukhopadhyay, Debnath Bhadra, Arijit Mukherjee, Pankaj
Deka, Tilak Kalita, Chandan Das, Rupjyoti Borah, Prasanna
Hazarika, Rahul Barman, Shankar Thakuria, Deuti Hazarika,
Hiren Bhattacharjee, Chandan Sarma, Kamal Lodh, Bidya Sinha,
Sanjay Das, Utpal Saibia, Rama Kanta Barman, Rapjuyoti Ratna,
Maqbul Ali
World Bank; ACNielsen India
India: Uttar
Pradesh
Soumya Kapoor, Deepa
Narayan, Saumik Paul, Nina
Badgaiyan
Saveena Khan, Vishnu Shankar Tiwari, Devendra Pratap Singh,
Arvind Kumar Singh, Rajesh Singh, Bhawana Nainwal, Sher
Bahadur Prajapati, Narendra Pandey, Ram Singh Mourya,
Jaiprakash Bajpai, Pankaj Srivastav, Anand Kumar Mourya, Minoti
Mitra, Ruby Nainwal, Pankaj Kumar Verma, Raj Kumar Yadav
World Bank; ACNielsen India
India: West
Bengal
Binayak Sen, Deepa Narayan,
Klaus Deininger
Saptarshi Guha, Mukund Kr Chandan, Debashish Basu, Arijit
Mukhopadhyay, Atanu Dey, Jaya Mandal, Sujay Majumder,
Bismita Das, Bratin Banerjee, Ujjala Biswas, Paramita Sasmal,
Amit Chowdhury, Pranab Das, Arnab Bose
World Bank; ACNielsen India
Indonesia
Sri Kusumastuti Rahayu, Vita
Febriany
Ruly Marianti, Wawan Munawar, Didit Wicaksana, Mutmainah,
Khoirul Rosyadi, Suroso, Akhmadi, Mutmainah, Ari Ratna,
Ivanovich Agusta, Heri Rubianto, Widy Taurus Sandi, Erfan
Agus Munif, Sulton Mawardi, Syahidussyahar, Ervan Abdul
Kadir, Nurdewa Safar, Muhlis A. Adam, Musriyadi Nabiu,
Salha Marasaoly, Abdulgani Fabanjo, Edy Nasriyanto Hatari,
Muhammad Noor, Nurdewa Safar, Abdul Kadir Kamaluddin
SMERU Research Institute
345
Lead researchers
India:
Andhra
Pradesh
Researchers and Institutions Involved in Country Studies
Country
346
Lead researchers
Other researchers
Research institutes
Malawi
Maxton Grant Tsoka, John
Kadzandira, Manohar Sharma
James Mwera, Nozgechi Phiri, Veronica Mbulaje, Augustine
Harawa, Macdonald Chitekwe, Andrew Zulu, James Mwera,
Mapopa Nyirongo, Massy Chiocha
University of Malawi
Centre for Social Research;
International Food Policy
Research Institute (IFPRI)
Mexico
Trine Lunde, Vicente García
Moreno, Alejandro Ramírez
Abraham Jahir Ortiz Nahón, Vicente García, Marianne Isazkun
Bernat Aznar, Larissa Bosh Paullada, Israel Morales de la Peña,
Abraham Ortiz, Etoile Garcia, David Gallardo, José Guillermo
Hernández, Miguel Venegas, Rodolfo García, Rafael Pech
Morocco
Abdesselam Fazouane, Aziz
Chaker, Miria Pigato, Jose
Lopez-Calix, Nora Dudwick,
Deepa Narayan
Mohamed Ahlibou, Naima Hajji Rachid Harimi, Az-Eddine El
Abbassi, Achour Boulal
Social and Economic
Development Group, Middle
East and North Africa Region,
World Bank
Philippines:
Bukidnon
Agnes R. Quisumbing, Chona
R. Echavez, Erlinda MontilloBurton, Scott McNiven
Research Institute for Mindanao Culture, Xavier University;
CGIAR Systemwide Program on Collective Action and Property
Rights (CAPRi), University of Wisconsin–Madison
IFPRI
Philippines:
conflict
(Mindanao)
Erlinda Montillo-Burton,
Chona R. Echavez, Imelda G.
Pagtulon-an
Jennefer Lyn Bagaporo, Vergil Boac, Donna Sanchez, Conralin
Yap, Adonis Gonazales, Carla Vergara, Marie Clarisse Gomos,
Michael Lou Montejo, Lourdes Wong, Prospercora Vega, Vicky
Regidor, Betty Aposakas, Lucia Sabanal, Carol Pagtulon-an,
Roxendo Ucat, Marlo Reyes, Esther Briones, Rowena Abilja
Research Institute for
Mindanao Culture, Xavier
University
Senegal
Mamadou Daffe, Souleymane
Guèye, Soukèye Thiongane,
Aissatou Ba
Chimère Diaw, Aminata Diop, Moustapha Ly, Sidy Bouya Bâ,
Aïssatou Sakho Diop, Jean Pierre Yvon Fall, Daba Ndiaye,
Alioune Sarr, Awa Ndao, Henriette Baldé, Moustapha Ka, Demba
Ndong, Abdoul Gnimana Diallo, Waly Clément
Senagrosol Consult
Success from the Bottom Up
Country
Other researchers
Research institutes
Prashan Thalayasingam
Gayathri, Sujatha, Gayan, Chathura, Siriwardane, Dayal, Indira,
Munas, Vigitha, Sivadeepan, Sivaharan, Rathan, Leo, Azam,
Shehan, Suchith, Baanu, Shahim, Rahuman, Kosalai, Sudarshan,
Braveena, Niroshan, Kannan
Centre for Poverty Analysis
(CEPA), AC Nielsen Lanka Pvt.
Ltd.
Sri Lanka:
tea estates
Neranjana Gunetilleke,
Sanjana Kuruppu, Susrutha
Goonesekera
Sanjana, Dulani, Suranjith, Nishantha, Sandika, Sujatha, Shahim,
Munas, Sandika, Sanjitha, Susrutha, Gayathri, Nishantha, Mansi
Centre for Poverty Analysis
(CEPA)
Tanzania:
Kagera
Joachim De Weerdt
Adalbertus Kamanzi, Respichius Mitti, Khamaldin Mutabazi,
Hanneke Honer, Adela Katunzi, Josien de Klerk, Leonard Kyaruzi,
James Mitchener, George Musikula, Thaddeus Rweyemamu
Economic Development
Initiatives (EDI)
Tanzania:
Ruvuma
Flora Kessy, Oswald
Mashindano, Dennis
Rweyemamu, Prosper Charle
Kim Kayunze, Justin Urassa, Dennis Rweyemanu, Monica
Kimaro, Rosemary Kamugisha, Esther Michael, Timothy Lucas,
Swide Mashina, Salvastory Mkama
Economic and Social Research
Foundation (ESRF)
Thailand
Priyanut Piboolsravut,
Somsakdi Arjprachan,
Prasopsee Sookmark, Rajana
Netsaengtip
Niwes Laechart, Kesinee Banjong, Morakot Supalak
National Economic and Social
Development Board; Local
Development Foundation
(LDF); Local Knowledge
Management Institute (LMI);
National Statistical Office of
Thailand
Uganda
Richard Ssewakiryanga
Akim Okuni, Frank Muhereza, Nsubuga Charles, Simon
Rutabajuuka, Frank Muhereza, Joseph Enyimu, Rossetti
Nabbumba, Diego Angemi, David Lawson, Kristen Himelein,
Paul Mpuga, James Muwonge, Byron Twesigye, Anthony Matovu,
Hassan Wasswa, Joseph Robert Bugembe
Ministry of Finance, Planning
and Economic Development;
Uganda Participatory Poverty
Assessment Project (UPPAP);
Centre for Basic Research
347
Lead researchers
Sri Lanka:
conflict
Researchers and Institutions Involved in Country Studies
Country
Appendix 2: Technical Note
on Household Regressions
349
350
Success from the Bottom Up
T
his note addresses technical issues pertaining to the use of data from the
household survey carried out as part of the Moving Out of Poverty study.
In particular, it discusses the use of the household responses in a multivariate regression to examine the correlates at the individual and village levels of
moving out of poverty. It looks at the sampling frame, the construction of the
dependent and independent variables, and the multivariate regression functional form and weights. The full regressions are reported in appendix 6, and
the results are discussed in the text of the book in the appropriate sections.
Description of the Study
The Moving Out of Poverty (MOP) study is a large, complex research program
carried out in 21 diverse study regions in 15 countries around the world.
The study combines both qualitative and quantitative work in an attempt to
unpack from below the processes, interactions, and sequencings associated
with household transitions out of poverty. The focus is on learning from men
and women who have managed to move out of poverty over the past decade
about the factors and processes that came together for their asset accumulation and the role of broader community institutions, if any, in supporting or
obstructing their mobility.
Choosing the study regions
In selecting countries and regions within countries to participate in the study, an
effort was made to ensure that a variety of contexts would be covered. As shown
in table A.1, the 15 countries differ in terms of their income levels, national
growth rates, and governance environments. Not surprisingly, while there is
considerable variation along the dimensions, some cells of the table are empty:
for example, there are no low-income/high-governance countries in the study.
Selection of regions also took into account the availability of local
research institutes with the interest and capacity to carry out the multidisciplinary study, as well as interest on the part of national governments
and World Bank country teams.
Sampling for communities (villages, neighborhoods)
In addition to a broad set of hypotheses, the study addressed specific policy
questions that are of current concern in each study region. The focus was on
one or two variables that are central to understanding growth and poverty
reduction in the local context. These variables were identified through an iter-
Technical Note on Household Regressions
351
TABLE A.1
Countries in the MOP study stratified by income, growth, and governance
Economy
High
governance
Low
governance
Very low
governance
India, Malawi,
Senegal
Bangladesh,
Cambodia,
Tanzania,
Uganda
Low income (US$825 or less)
High growth
Low growth
Afghanistan
Lower middle income (US$826–US$3,255)
High growth
Philippines,
Thailand
Low growth
Indonesia,
Morocco, Sri
Lanka
Colombia
Upper middle income (US$3,256–US$10,065)
High growth
Mexico
Low growth
Note: Income figures are per capita gross national income. Growth and governance classifications reflect
the growth rate in 2004 and the average governance rating for 1996–2004. A growth rate <= 3 indicates
a low-growth country. High governance rating refers to a governance average > 0 and < 2.5; low governance rating, a governance average < 0 and > −0.5; very low governance rating, a governance average
< −0.5 and > −2.5. Governance average is the simple average of six components (voice and accountability, political stability, rule of law, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, and control of corruption)
of the governance dataset in “Governance Matters IV: Governance Indicators for 1996–2004.”
ative process that was based on data availability and discussion with different
actors familiar with the growth and poverty debate in the region, including
national and state-level policy actors and poverty and growth experts within
government, research institutes, civil society, and donor agencies. The Malawi
study, for instance, explores the impact on mobility of access to social and
economic infrastructure. In the state of Uttar Pradesh, India, the study examines the role of caste in facilitating or hindering people’s movements out of
poverty. The Indonesia study focuses on local-level conflicts to understand
how conflict in different growth contexts affects people’s ability to move out
of poverty. The focus in Thailand is on growth and inequality.
Three different sampling strategies were employed for districts/blocks/
villages to identify study sites within the 21 regions, which were grouped in
three categories (table A.2):
• Study regions with a preexisting panel data set. In regions where panel data
were available, the communities that had been in the previous panel
352
Selection criteria
Blocks
Communities
No. of
communities
No. of household
surveys
Study region
Provinces/districts
India: Andhra
Pradesh
Panel study
60
839
Cambodia
Panel study
9
—
Philippines:
Bukidnon
Panel study
10
259
Uganda
Panel study
18
724
Tanzania: Kagera
Panel study
8
—
India: Uttar
Pradesh
Growth
Irrigation and caste
Random
110
1,635
India: West Bengal
Purposive using
government survey
% of land reform
beneficiaries
Random
80
1,200
Bangladesh
Poverty headcount
Average landholding
and literacy rates
Women’s empowerment,
food security, and growth in
agricultural wages
16
862
Sri Lanka: tea and
rubber estates
Crop type, geographic
spread, poverty
headcount
Ownership of estate (private/state), population size,
remoteness, labor supply (resident/nonresident)
20
—
Thailand
Growth and income
inequality
Growth and income inequality
40
600
Success from the Bottom Up
TABLE A.2
Choosing locations within study regions
Selection criteria
Study region
Provinces/districts
Blocks
Communities
Mexico
Yucatán and Oaxaca
Communities with high % of indigenous population,
varying in growth
Morocco
Growth and migration
Tanzania: Ruvuma
Growth
Malawi
No. of
communities
No. of household
surveys
346
3 communities (2 rural, 1 urban) selected in each of 3
provinces
9
—
Distance to district headquarters, population size
8
332
Access to infrastructure and markets
15
139
Senegal
Access to infrastructure
15
301
India: Assam
Growth and conflict
Conflict
50
746
Sri Lanka: conflict
Growth and conflict
Conflict
9
—
Afghanistan:
conflict
Conflict, proximity to city or borders, cultivation and trade of poppy, degree of
exposure to international aid
6
91
Indonesia: conflict
Type of conflict (ethnic,
religious, local)
10
372
Colombia: conflict
Growth, conflict, and whether communities were either receiving displaced
populations or were themselves displaced
8
252
Philippines:
conflict
Study conducted only in
the Mindanao region
10
300
523
8,998
Total
Growth
Growth
Conflict
Conflict and ethnic/religious
composition
Conflict
Note: In all conflict regions, districts with a very high level of active conflict at the time of the survey were not chosen for reasons of safety of the field team.
Technical Note on Household Regressions
12
353
354
Success from the Bottom Up
were revisited. This was the method used in five regions: Cambodia;
the Bukidnon region of the Philippines; the Kagera region of Tanzania;
Uganda; and the state of Andhra Pradesh, India.
• Study regions with a particular focus. Where the focus was on a specific
theme, this theme informed sampling. The desire was to select provinces/
districts, blocks, and communities that differed substantially in the
thematically relevant dimensions. This was the method used in 10
regions.
• Study regions with conflict. The MOP study included a separate substudy
with an emphasis on conflict. It was carried out in six regions: Afghanistan, Colombia (with an emphasis on the displaced population), Indonesia, Sri Lanka, the Philippines, and the state of Assam in India. In these
regions, the spatial sampling was devoted to finding communities within
the broader region with higher and lower levels of conflict.
All local-level communities in the study (villages, barrios, etc.) are identified by pseudonyms in this book. Higher-level entities (blocks, provinces,
districts, regions, states, and countries) are identified by their real names.
Sampling for household questionnaires:
The community mobility matrix
The MOP study consists of several different instruments, one of which is the
household quantitative questionnaire (see appendix 3 for a list of data collection methods). For studies that used panel data, the questionnaires were
conducted by revisiting panel households and interviewing the same person
who was interviewed for the panel before. Where panel data were unavailable, the selection of informants for the household questionnaire was based
on a household sorting exercise undertaken during a focus group discussion
called the “ladder of life.” The discussion, conducted in each study community, proceeded in four steps:
1. The focus group first discussed events and factors that had affected their
community’s prosperity over the past 10 years.
2. The group then constructed a figurative ladder of life for their community.
Each step of the ladder corresponded to a category of household
well-being that the group defined in terms of specific household characteristics (land ownership, assets, occupation, living conditions, and
social prestige, among others). The process did not force a set number
of ladder steps, and the focus groups varied in the number of steps they
defined for their communities.
Technical Note on Household Regressions
355
3. As part of this discussion, each group developed its own definition of a
poverty line, called the community poverty line (CPL). The CPL marked
the step on the ladder above which people were considered no longer
poor in their community.
4. Once it had created the ladder in the abstract, the focus group did
a household sorting activity. Every household on a list of up to 150
households residing in the community (developed prior to the discussion)
was mapped onto the ladder to denote its status both 10 years ago (1995)
and today (at the time of the survey, 2005). Based on these rankings, a
community mobility matrix was developed (see chapter 3 for examples).
The matrix showed which households had moved up or down the ladder
or stayed at the same step over the 10-year study period. The MOP study’s
community mobility matrixes are similar in many ways to standard transition matrixes that are based on measured income or consumption, except
that they are based on community-defined categories (not constructed
categories like quintiles of income) and on community recall.
Because the matrix was based on the sorting of 100–150 individual
households in a community, it provided a useful source for selecting respondents for the household survey. Four mobility groups were considered:
• Movers: households that were poor in 1995 but had moved out of poverty
by 2005
• Chronic poor: households that were poor in 1995 and remained poor in
2005
• Never poor: households that were not poor in 1995 and remained not
poor in 2005
• Fallers: households that were not poor in 1995 but fell into poverty by
2005
In each case, “poor” means below the locally defined community poverty line
and “not poor” means above it.
Once households in the matrix were stratified into these groups, a minimum of 15 households in each community were selected for the survey. We
deliberately oversampled movers and the never poor because of the study’s
interest in learning from those who had moved out of poverty and those
who had been able to maintain their wealth. Table A.3 shows the approximate desired distribution for sampling the household questionnaires in each
community.
Adherence to this distribution depended on availability of sufficient
numbers of households in each of the four mobility groups. Sometimes it
356
Success from the Bottom Up
TABLE A.3
Desired distribution of households across mobility groups
Now
10 years ago
Poor or worse off
Nonpoor or better off
Poor or worse off
Chronic poor: 20%
Movers: 40%
Nonpoor or better off
Fallers: 10%
Never poor: 30%
was not possible to match the target percentages: in very poor communities,
for instance, the number of movers was limited; therefore, fewer movers were
interviewed. Panel studies were an exception to the distribution rule. The
questionnaires were conducted by revisiting panel households and interviewing the same person that was interviewed for the panel before.
The questionnaires were conducted mainly with adults between 30 and
60 years of age. The aim was to identify and understand the range of factors that helped or hindered the mobility of individuals within the larger
context of their households and communities. The multimodule questionnaires were innovative in that they collected information on the individual
respondent’s social capital, personal aspirations, and perceptions of local
governance, freedom, crime, insecurity, and violence, in addition to the usual
demographic and economic information on assets, expenditure, health, and
education. While many of the questions on expenditure and assets related
to the household, the subjective questions were about the individual. The
far-right column in table A.2 summarizes the number of household surveys
collected in the different study regions. These households varied from only 91
in Afghanistan to over 1,600 in Uttar Pradesh, for a total of 8,998 household
surveys in the entire study.
Two points are worth noting. First, the study made no attempt to create
a nationally representative sample. In the discussion, country names are used
merely as a shorthand way of identifying data from the study regions within
those countries. Thus, by “Indonesia,” it should be clear that we mean “the
communities/households sampled for our study within the selected regions
of Indonesia.” As noted on page xxiv, we try to provide in our abbreviations
and acronyms both a country and a study focus in order to remind the reader
that the unit is the study region, not the country.
Second, the household surveys were not used to estimate numbers of
poor or nonpoor or movers. Those numbers are estimated in the community
Technical Note on Household Regressions
357
mobility matrix. The household surveys had two main uses. One was to reveal
difference in reported characteristics, attitudes, behaviors, and outcomes
between the movers out of poverty and other groups. The second was to run
multivariate regressions using the household’s mobility status, as ascribed by
the focus group, to establish associations between household mobility and
characteristics of the household and locality. We made no attempt to establish causality or make causal claims based on these regressions, though that
is one possible way to interpret the associations.
Background to the Regressions: Dependent
and Independent Variables
To construct the regressions, we first specify (a) a measure for the dependent
variable (i.e., “movement out of poverty” or “mobility of the poor”), (b)
measures for each of the conceptual variables, (c) the way we propose to distinguish between private and community impacts of some of the conceptual
variables (particularly the local democracy and agency measures), and (d) the
control variables included in the regressions.
Examining measures for movement out of poverty
and mobility of the poor (MPI)
Because the study is about the mobility of poor people, only those households that were poor 10 years ago, at the beginning of the study period, were
included for purposes of regression analysis. Within this “initial poor set,”
the objective was to differentiate between those who moved up from poverty
over the 10 years and those who did not. Two dependent variables were used
for the regression analysis:
• MOP: households that were initially poor and moved up and out of
poverty over 10 years, crossing the community poverty line
• MPI: households that were initially poor and moved up any distance over
10 years, irrespective of whether they crossed the community poverty
line
The data offered two measures that could be used to calculate the dependent variables. The first was status of and change in the household’s rank on
the ladder of life, now compared to 10 years ago, as identified by the ladder
of life focus group discussion. The second was status of and change in the
household’s self-assessed rank on the ladder of life, now compared to 10
358
Success from the Bottom Up
years ago, as identified by the respondent himself or herself in the household
questionnaire.
Both dependent variables were constructed using the first measure—
community perceptions of the household’s mobility on the ladder of life. It
is important to note that the mobility ratings were not self-assessed. This was
to avoid endogeneity biases or “halo effects” that might arise in regressing
a household’s own perception of movement against its perception of variables measuring the conceptual categories. For instance, it may well be that
people who subjectively feel they have more control over decision making
also subjectively feel they are moving up—even if others perceive them as
economically stagnant. By using the community’s perception of mobility as
the dependent variable and the individual’s responses about the household as
measures of the right-hand-side variables, this particular problem is attenuated, if not eliminated.
Construction of MOP score. The ladder of life discussion group developed
mobility rankings of each household that received the survey. Focus group
members recalled the household’s placement on the well-being ladder 10
years ago and then determined its current step on the ladder. Based on these
mobility ranks and the community poverty line, the MOP score was constructed as a binary variable (yes/no) using the following formula:
where step is the step on the ladder of life constructed by the focus group and
CPL is the community poverty line set by the group and n is the (roughly
10-year) recall period.
Construction of MPI score. Any score constructed for movement out of
poverty is subject to the placement of a threshold line that can vary across
communities and contexts. Given problems that relative lines like the CPL
pose, a broader score of upward MPI was also used as the dependent variable
using the following formula:
MPI h,j =
h,j
1 if stepth,j > stept−n
0 otherwise
Using measures for conceptual categories of independent variables
The MOP and MPI dependent variables were regressed against various independent variables to produce the partial associations (no attribution of cau-
Technical Note on Household Regressions
359
sality is expressed or implied). These variables included both household
variables and community variables. A list of all of the variables, their sources,
and coding is presented in appendix 4.
Household-level standard control variables. In estimating the regressions,
we control for variables that may influence household mobility but that
are not a major focus of the study. These are mainly well-known correlates of mobility and are included mainly to distinguish the influence of
various other variables that may be correlated. For instance, more educated
households may feel more empowered or may have more influence over
their local governments. In each multivariate regression, the household
demographic and economic characteristics included a proxy for the household’s initial wealth. Ownership at the beginning of the study period was
included for (a) house, (b) collection of household assets, (c) livestock, and
(d) farmland. The education level of the respondent and reported health
shocks experienced by the household over 10 years were also included as
variables in each regression.
Household variables unique to the study. In addition to the usual covariates,
there are several variables from the household questionnaire that are of special interest to this study (see appendix 4):
• Aspirations. Respondents were asked two questions, one about aspirations for the respondent and one about aspirations for future generations. These answers were combined into a single index using PCA.
• Personal agency. Respondents were asked two questions about their
level of agency, one about control over everyday decisions and one
about their position on a ladder of power and rights. Again, the two
questions were combined into a single index with principal components
analysis.
• Responsiveness of the local government. Respondents were asked four
questions about (a) their trust in local government officials, (b) their
satisfaction with local democracy, (c) the extent to which local government
takes into account people’s concerns, and (d) their ability to influence
the actions of the local government. These answers were combined into
an index using principal components analysis (see below for more detail
on PCA).
• Fairness of the economy. Respondents were asked four questions about
(a) farmers getting fair prices, (b) fairness in treatment by the law,
(c) whether the respondent had been denied credit, and (d) whether he
or she expected to be denied credit. Again, these answers were combined
360
Success from the Bottom Up
into a single index of fairness for each respondent based on weights from
PCA.
• Violence against women. Respondents were asked about their perception
of the prevalence of violence against women in their community.
We also included a policy focus variable for each of the study regions.
In Uttar Pradesh, for example, proxies are included for the caste of each
household.
For the household-level variables, we used the respondent’s recollection of conditions 10 years ago rather than current levels. This is an
attempt to mitigate the endogeneity bias of using current perceptions, as
current conditions are certainly affected by changes over the past 10 years.
One can easily imagine that households that moved out of poverty would
be likely to report, for example, higher empowerment scores because of
that move. Of course, given that our only option was to use recall data,
there is no guarantee that currently reported perceptions of the past are
not also affected by events.
In addition to the household variables, there are community-level variables of two types. One set comes from the community instruments, such as
the focus group. The other comes from using the household responses and
computing leave-out means.
Community variables from community instruments. Seven community-level
variables were used in the regressions that were drawn either from the community-level information provided by key informants or from the focus
group discussions. These were (mostly) created by combining questions into
indices using PCA.
• Corruption. The key informant questionnaire included two questions
about corruption, one about officials at the national level and one about
officials at the local or community level. In addition, the focus group
discussion produced an estimate of corruption among government
officials in the community.
• Initial strength of the economy. Key informants were asked about the
strength of the local economy, the presence of private employers, and
the difficulty of finding a job 10 years ago.
• Change in economic prosperity over 10 years. The focus group discussions
were asked about trends in community prosperity, trends in available
economic opportunities, trends in access to such opportunities, and
whether it was easier or harder to make a living.
Technical Note on Household Regressions
361
• Collective action. Key informants were asked two questions, one about the
likelihood of the community coming together to solve water problems
and one about community members coming together to assist each
other.
• Social stratification. Key informants were asked one question about the
divisions among people based on locally relevant social categories (e.g.,
ethnicity, caste).
• School inequality. Key informants were asked about trends over 10 years in
the extent of discrimination in schools based on (a) ethnic or religious
factors and (b) gender.
• Access to networks or associations. Focus groups were asked to estimate
whether access to networks and associations within the village had
increased or decreased (or had remained the same) over 10 years.
Community variables constructed from household survey instrument. The
household questionnaire contains several questions about household perceptions, including perceptions of the responsiveness of the local democratic
structure and perceptions of the household’s own empowerment and aspirations. An average of household responses for these questions cannot be
treated as an indicator of a responsive local democracy or of an empowered community. At best, the responses are indicators of the “perception of
democracy” or “perception of empowerment” based on the sample surveyed
within a community.
Furthermore, it could well be that some households answered that their
local democracy is responsive because they have had an opportunity to participate in it or derive benefits from it. However, one household’s participation can have a strong “chilling” or “crowding out” effect on other households
in the same community. The association of the average or net perception
therefore may not necessarily be the sum of individual perceptions (Alatas,
Pritchett, and Wetterberg 2007).
To distinguish between private effects (association of the own household’s
perceptions with outcomes) and social effects (impact of one household on
other households), we use the fact that our sampling is by communities. We
can, therefore, calculate for each community both the perception of each
household (private effect) and perceptions of all other households in the
community (social effect). Consider as an example the response to the following question: “Compared to 10 years ago, does the local government now
pay more, less, or about the same attention to what people like you think
when it decides what to do?” The leave-out mean for a given individual is
362
Success from the Bottom Up
simply the perception of local government responsiveness of all other individuals in their community, leaving out that one person.
The use of leave-out means is an attempt to disentangle social effects
from private effects or pure household perceptions by aggregating all individual responses in community j, except for household i. Suppose there were
a linear, causal relationship between the mobility of poor household i in
village j and whether it reports higher local government responsiveness and
the perceptions of government responsiveness of all other households in the
community.
MPIi,j = α + βHH(LGi,j)+ βLOM(LG–i,j)
The private impact of the ith household’s perceptions of the local government
on the likelihood that it moves up is the coefficient βHH.
The impact of the ith household’s perceptions of the local government
on all other households in the community is to raise the “community less
household” average by 1/Nj for each household. The social impact of the ith
household’s perceptions of the local government is then βLOM/N j on each
other household in the community. This could be zero if there is no interaction at all. However, if the ith household’s positive perceptions of responsiveness are influenced by the benefits it derives from a zero-sum public good,
say a local public works program from which the ith household benefits by
excluding others, the social impact on others could be negative (in fact, it
would have to be negative). In this case, the net impact on mobility of the
poor associated with the ith household’s perceptions of local government
responsiveness is just the sum of the private and social impacts—but it cannot be assumed to be the sum of the individual coefficients alone.
Using principal components to combine
conceptually related variables
For many of the phenomena that the analyst might wish to elicit and
examine, it is impossible to know with any precision which question will
produce the most reliable responses. Hence, questionnaires often include
questions on closely related concepts. When data are to be used in multivariate regressions, this leaves the analyst with four options. We chose to
combine conceptually similar questions into a single index using principal
components.
A word about the three options rejected. One is “profligacy,” simply
including in the regressions all of the possible variables. This has the advan-
Technical Note on Household Regressions
363
tage of “letting the data decide,” but it has the disadvantages of creating
regressions with 50 or more individual variables and of producing massive
multicollinearity if the variables are in fact closely related conceptually. A
second option is to choose the “best” indicator for each conceptual category. This can be done a priori, which runs the risk of choosing the empirically least successful (e.g., most subject to measurement error), or it can
be done based on “horse races” of available candidates, which is the very
definition of data mining. The third option is to use some index based on
a weighted average of the questions. This has the advantage of reducing the
numbers of variables and avoids data mining, but the weights are arbitrary.
A common practice of using “equal” weights has nothing in particular to
recommend it.
The technique of principal components is a commonly used data reduction technique that reduces a set of variables to a single variable. Principal
components analyzes the correlations between a set of variables and produces a set of weighted averages of the underlying variables such that (a) each
captures the maximum common variation among the set of variables, and
(b) each additional factor after the first is orthogonal to the previous factor.
So the first factor is a linear weighted average of the set of N variables with
weights chosen so as to maximize the overall common variance of all the
variables.
While in many ways the index produced is arbitrary, this does have
three advantages. First, it is not data mining, as it does not use any information about the dependent variable in choosing the specification. Second, it chooses weights that, if the set of N variables are truly conceptually
related, statistically best capture the common variation. Third, because it is
a linear index, it is relatively easy to map back from the underlying variable
through the regression coefficient to the association with the dependent
variable.
We did the principal components analysis study region by study region,
rather than imposing common weights across all study regions. The results
for each study region for each PCA-constructed variable are presented in
appendix 5. First, whenever there are only two variables, PCA just produced
equal weights. Second, the results are mostly in accord with expectations. All
variables are recoded so that movements in the same direction numerically
represent movement in the same conceptual direction (this is not necessarily
true in the raw questions). We see that most of the PCA, therefore, produces,
as expected, indexes with all positive weights, often nearly equal. But third,
there is considerable variation across countries in the weights, including
364
Success from the Bottom Up
some negative values. Rather than attempt to choose the “best” fit for each
study region, we just implemented the data reduction technique for each and
used the weights produced.
The only way in which this process differed from the perfectly gardenvariety PCA was that we wanted an index of conditions 10 years ago. But
rather than using the PCA weights from 10 years ago, we did PCA on the current variables and then used those weights to construct an index for 10 years
ago, while using the values of the underlying variables from that time.
Once we had the PCA scores, we could infer the estimate associated with
each individual component variable in that index with the dependent variable (MOP or MPI). To do so, we proceeded in two steps. First, we used the
PCA weights to calculate how much a change in an individual component
of the index would change the index (which involved the variance of the
component because PCA norms the raw variables) would produce in the PCA
score. Next, we multiplied this value with the ordinary least squares regression coefficient for the PCA score to estimate the concomitant associated
change in MOP or MPI.
Here is an example of going from raw component to estimated association when PCA has been used. Take the case of the study region in Afghanistan, where aspirations had a significant positive association with an initially
poor household’s ability to move out of poverty over 10 years. Considering
the individual components of the aspirations index, we find that a 2-unit
increase in beliefs about one’s own future (1 = worse off, 3 = better off) is
associated with a change of nearly 2 units in the aspirations index using the
following formula:
Change in PCA index = (loading on individual component × range
of individual component)/standard error of
individual component
(for aspirations in Afghanistan) = (0.7071 × 2)/0.708
The subsequent change of 2 units in the PCA index for aspirations when
multiplied with the OLS regression coefficient for household aspirations in
Afghanistan (0.11) is associated with an increase of nearly 21 percent in the
likelihood of escaping poverty. A 2-unit increase in aspirations for one’s children nearly doubles the probability of exit from poverty to 42 percent (range
= 2, standard error = 0.36).
Technical Note on Household Regressions
365
Functional Form and Weights
Functional form
An OLS model was used for running regressions. Because the dependent variable is a binary outcome (0/1), this is sometimes referred to as the linear
probability model (LPM). It is well known that with a limited dependent
variable, there are estimation techniques (such as probit and logit) that are
more statistically efficient. This is because by imposing in estimation the constraint (which must be true) that the predictions of outcomes by the regression techniques have to be strictly between zero and one, these techniques
produce lower standard errors than OLS.
We did not do this, however, for three reasons. First, the loss from not
using a logit or probit estimator is only efficiency (a second-order property
of estimators), not consistency, and we suspect that, in this case, the gains to
precision are not particularly meaningful. Second, the LPM has ease of interpretation, particularly when moving from the underlying PCA-constructed
indexes to the reporting of outcome associations. Third, with nonlinear functional forms like logit and probit, the use of the leave-out means is much
more complicated.
All of the standard errors used the standard adjustment to be consistent
with cluster-based sampling using the cluster techniques available in Stata
data analysis software.
While a complete specification was run for the study regions in India,
a relatively parsimonious model was used for the non-India study regions,
where sample sizes were much smaller. The sparse specification excluded the
PCA index on fairness, the PCA index for social inequality in schools, and
ownership of land. Leave-out means were only included for the responsiveness of local democracy and personal agency PCAs.
Weighted versus unweighted regressions
The structure of the sampling of those who were interviewed for the household instrument produces four issues about weights, even though in this
appendix, we are focused on the regressions.
Let us use a simple example to illustrate these issues. Suppose in a given
country 25 percent of the population consists of red people and 75 percent
of blue people. Red people are taller on average than blue people. Suppose
an instrument contains observations on height and weight. Finally, assume
366
Success from the Bottom Up
the sample was chosen to have equal numbers of red and blue people (so red
people were oversampled).
First, since sampling was not random, the overall averages from the
household surveys of any characteristic are not consistent estimates of the
sampled population. The unweighted average height would be wrong about
the average height of the population, as red people are taller and are oversampled. In the MOP study, this example shows that because the movers were
oversampled, if they are different, the overall averages of characteristics from
household surveys are not estimates of the overall average of the population
characteristics.
Second, as long as the individuals within the groups are chosen randomly,
then summary statistics of the differences across the groups on an unweighted
basis are consistent. In the example, comparing red people’s average height
to blue people’s average height is a consistent estimate of the subpopulation
heights.
Third, all of the regression results reported are unweighted. For the regressions themselves, because we assume a linear functional form, the issue of
weighted versus unweighted regressions is an issue of estimator efficiency (in
that the weighted estimates might produce lower standard errors), but not
one of consistency.
Returning to the example, suppose that there is a linear relationship
between height and weight and that this linear relationship is the same for
red and blue people. In this case, an unweighted regression would produce
a consistent estimate of the relationship between height and weight, even
though red people are oversampled.
It is possible that using sampling weights would produce a more efficient
(lower standard errors) estimator, but our view is that these gains are likely
to be small. We don’t want to give ourselves over to t-statistic fetishism in any
case. That is, if the difference between “statistical significance” (usually taken
as rejecting the null hypothesis at some standard significance level such as
5 percent or 1 percent) is whether estimates are weighted or unweighted, it
would be questionable to make much of the relationship in any case. This is
a general point about reported empirical work, not about our report, because
in most instances, there are large deviations of the actually applied statistical
procedures and the conditions under which the classic theory of hypothesis
testing are valid.
Moreover, if the weighted and unweighted partial association estimates
were to differ—which they do not, for the most part, in the cases where this
has been explored—this would not be an indication that the weighted results
Technical Note on Household Regressions
367
are to be preferred. In fact, heuristically, the differences between unweighted
and weighted results can be thought of as a Hausman-like (1978) test for
model specification. Because under the maintained null used in estimating an OLS regression the unweighted and weighted are both consistent for
the “true” coefficient, this implies that they should also converge (in large
samples) to be “near” one another. Hence, a large difference (where “large”
would be normed for statistical tests by the appropriate variance-covariance
matrix of the difference between the two estimators) between weighted and
unweighted results suggests model misspecification. But as this type of test
is an omnibus specification test (that is, it has power against many forms
of misspecification), a difference between weighted and unweighted to first
order is difficult to interpret and cannot be taken to mean the weighted result
is “better.”
Fourth, there is a tricky final issue, not about the weighting of the regressions in general but about leave-out means. These are used, in some sense,
as “community characteristics,” and thus although they are not reported,
they might seem to fall under the first category of not using the unweighted
results to estimate summary statistics of characteristics. But there are two
points. One, this does maintain the assumption of the linearity of the effect,
so we assume that in the leave-out mean the impact on a mover of having a
higher value of the variable of a faller or never poor person is the same, so
in that case, the same issue of linearity discussed above applies. Second, as
long as the sampling was done consistently across villages, the bias as community variables of the sample should be (roughly, on average) constant
across villages.
Results
The regression results for each of the study regions are reported in appendix
6, with MOP and then MPI as the dependent variable. As expected, the results
vary considerably across study regions in terms of both the magnitude of the
coefficients and their associated standard errors.
In the body of the text, these results are usually presented using a graph
that displays the OLS-LPM coefficient and one and two standard error bounds
around the point estimate. This allows the reader to assess both the magnitude and the associated precision across countries.
Appendix 3: Data Collection
Methods
369
370
Data collection method
Purpose
Sources of information
1
Selective literature review
• Provide background to the key growth
and poverty puzzles in the country.
Secondary sources
2
Key informant interview or
workshop: national timeline
• Identify policy questions to be addressed
by the study.
• Help design the study.
Policy experts from government, civil society, and
private sector
• Develop a national timeline of key events
and policies that have helped or hindered
people’s movements out of poverty.
3
4
Community profile
Key informant interview:
community timeline
• Identify community-level factors that have
helped or hindered movement out of
poverty and the overall prosperity of the
community over the past 10 years.
Key informants
• Quantify and code data emerging from
focus discussions on the basis of their
ratings of issues ranging from community
prosperity to freedom and inequality.
Focus group discussion
• Understand community-level events or
factors that have helped or hindered
movement out of poverty and the overall
prosperity of the community.
2–4 key informants in a group or individually
• Gain an understanding of the local
context.
Success from the Bottom Up
Activity
Activity
Data collection method
Purpose
Sources of information
5
Focus group discussion: ladder
of life
• Identify the range of factors that help
or hinder movement out of poverty or
prosperity over time at the community
level.
1 focus group of adult men
1 focus group of adult women
• Identify the range of factors that help
or hinder movement out of poverty or
prosperity over time at the household
level, and the reasons for movement at
the different levels.
• Identify the sequencing and interaction
among factors at the household level that
enable movement between different steps
of the ladder of life.
• Identify the mobility status of specific
households in the community.
Focus group discussion:
livelihoods, freedom, power,
democracy, and local
governance
• Understand trends in economic
opportunities for the community.
1 focus group of adult men
• Understand the impact of government
rules and regulations and other factors on
access to economic opportunities.
Depending on the local context, this activity can
be conducted as one discussion, or there can be
2 sections discussing (a) sources of economic
opportunities and the role of governance, and
(b) freedom, power, inequality, and democracy.
If there are 2 sections, a total of 4 focus group
discussions per community will be needed for this
activity.
• Explore people’s understanding of
the concepts of freedom, power, and
inequality, and how these concepts relate
to economic mobility and well-being.
371
• Explore people’s understanding of
democracy and how democracy is
working at the local level.
1 focus group of adult women
Data Collection Methods
6
372
Data collection method
Purpose
Sources of information
7
Focus group discussion:
aspirations of youth
• Explore youths’ aspirations for earning a
living and steps they are taking to prepare
for their future.
1 focus group of male youths
1 focus group of female youths
• Explore youths’ understanding of the
concepts of freedom, power, inequality,
and democracy, and how these concepts
relate to economic mobility and wellbeing.
8
Two mini–case studies:
community-wide events and
factors affecting mobility
• Provide in-depth analysis from a range
of perspectives on two important events
or factors affecting the overall economic
prosperity of the community over the past
10 years.
Key informants and focus group discussions
9
Household questionnaire
• Identify the range of factors that help or
hinder mobility of households.
For countries with panel data: Depending on
panel sample size and sampling strategy chosen,
the team should revisit panel households and
interview an adult member of the household
(30–60 years of age). If it is not possible to identify
a large enough sample from the panel, individuals
may be randomly selected from households
identified by the ladder of life focus group
discussion as belonging to a particular mobility
category. For countries without panel data:
Select informants based on the household sorting
exercise undertaken during the ladder of life focus
group discussion.
Success from the Bottom Up
Activity
Activity
Data collection method
Purpose
Sources of information
10
Open-ended interviews:
individual life stories
• Understand how and why some
individuals escaped poverty, and the
factors and processes that led to their
escape.
Adults (men or women) 30–60 years of age. It
is important that a household questionnaire be
completed with each informant who provides an
individual life story. Identification of informants
follows a process similar to selection of informants
for the questionnaire.
• Understand how and why some
individuals managed to stay out of
poverty, and the factors and processes that
helped them maintain their wealth.
• Understand how and why some
individuals remained trapped in chronic
poverty, and the factors and processes that
kept them in poverty.
• Understand how and why some
individuals fell into poverty, and the
factors and processes that led to their
decline.
Data Collection Methods
• Understand the factors and processes
that come together for accumulation or
depletion of assets and savings.
373
Appendix 4: List of Variables
for Household Regressions
375
376
Success from the Bottom Up
Explanatory variable
Source
Coding/directionality
Strength of local economy 10 years ago
(rc205b)
KI
very weak=1, very strong=5
Presence of private employers 10 years
ago (rc208b)
KI
yes=1, no=0
Difficulty of finding a job 10 years ago
(rc209b)
KI
very difficult=1, very easy=6
Whether easier or harder to make a living
(rc904)
FGD
harder=1, easier=2
Trend in community prosperity (rc903)
FGD
less prosperous=1,
more prosperous=3
Economic opportunity
Initial strength of economy (PCA index a)
Changes in economic prosperity
(PCA index)
Trend in available economic opportunities FGD
(rc912)
fewer=1, more=3
Trend in access to economic
opportunities (rc917)
FGD
fewer have access=1,
more have access=3
Trust in local government officials
(rh415bi)
HH
not at all=1,
to a very great extent=5
Satisfaction with democracy in local
government (rh511)
HH
very dissatisfied=1,
very satisfied=4
Extent to which local government takes
into account concerns (rh502b)
HH
less=1, more=3
Ability to influence actions of local
government (rh504)
HH
decreased=1, increased=3
Corruption in government officials at the
country level (c505b)
KI
almost none=1, almost all=4
Corruption in government officials in
village (c506b)
KI
almost none=1, almost all=4
Corruption in government officials in
community (c924)
FGD
almost none=1, almost all=4
Local democracy
Responsiveness of local democracy
(PCA index)
Corruption (PCA index)
List of Variables for Household Regressions
Explanatory variable
377
Source
Coding/directionality
Farmers getting fair prices (rh240b)
HH
deteriorated=1, improved=3
Fairness in treatment by law in
community (rh606b)
HH
yes=1, no=0
Denied credit (h234)
HH
yes=1, no=2
Expectation of denial of credit (h236)
HH
yes=1, no=2
HH
none at all=1, very much=4
Initial position on 10-step ladder of
power and rights (h708)
HH
scale from 1 to 10
Control over everyday decisions (trend)
(rh501b)
HH
less=1, more=3
Aspirations for self (rh716)
HH
worse off=1, better off=3
Aspirations for future generation (rh717)
HH
worse off=1, better off=3
Coming together to solve water problems
10 years ago (rc412b)
KI
very unlikely=1,
very likely=4
Coming together to assist each other 10
years ago (rc413b)
KI
very unlikely=1,
very likely=4
FGD
less access=1,
more access=3
KI
no division=1,
to a very great extent=5
Ethnic/religious discrimination in schools
(c305b)
KI
improved=1, deteriorated=3
Gender discrimination in schools (c304b)
KI
improved=1, deteriorated=3
Fairness
Fairness (PCA index)
Violence against women
Violence against women in households
10 years ago (h609b)
Individual agency
Personal agency (PCA index)
Household aspirations (PCA index)
Collective agency
Index of collective action (PCA index a)
Access to networks and associations
Change in access to networks and
associations within the community
(rc919)
Social stratification
Extent of social divisions in the village
10 years ago
Differences between people based on
ethnicity, caste, etc., 10 years ago (c414b)
School inequality measure (trend)
378
Success from the Bottom Up
Explanatory variable
Source
Coding/directionality
Present education status of household
headb (h106)
HH
no schooling=1,
university=8
Health shocks over 10 years (rh305)
HH
yes=1, no=0
Initial landholding (h204 i+ii+iii+iv)bc
HH
number of hectares owned
Ownership of house 10 years ago (rh206b)
HH
whether owned (yes=1,
no=0)
Initial assets index (PCA indexa of assets
owned 10 years ago) (rh201 i–xiii)b
HH
whether owned (yes=1,
no=0)
Initial livestock index (PCA indexa of assets
owned 10 years ago) (rh203 i–x)b
HH
whether owned (yes=1,
no=0)
Control variables
Note: Reference questions in the community questionnaire are indicated by c and in the household
questionnaire by h. Prefix r means variable was recoded. Suffix a means current (at time of the study);
b means initial (approximately 10 years ago). KI = key informant; FGD = focus group discussion;
HH = household.
a. A PCA was first done on current conditions, and weights were applied to initial conditions 10 years
ago. A weighted average of initial conditions (with current weights) was then used as an explanatory
variable.
b. In the survey, the education level of the household head is measured in 2005, but it is unlikely to have
changed significantly over the previous 10 years for an adult head of household.
c. The symbols i, ii, iii, and iv signify irrigated land, unirrigated temporary crop land, unirrigated permanent crop land, and grazing land/wasteland, respectively.
Appendix 5: Weights for the
PCA-Constructed Indexes,
by Study Region
379
380
UP
Caste
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
MAL
Infra
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
MEX
Ethn
COL
Conf
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
ASSAM
Conf
Initial strength of local economy
Strength
of local
economy,
10 years ago
(rc205b)
0.47
0.72
0.57
0.52
0.55
0.49
0.71
0.59
0.68
0.24
0.54
0.44 used
directly
0.70
0.41
−0.05
Presence
of private
employers,
10 years ago
(rc208b)
0.60
0.17
0.54
−0.42
0.46
0.56
0.71
0.60
0.31
0.68
0.61
0.69
—
0.42
0.72
0.71
Difficulty in
finding a job,
10 years ago
(rc209b)
0.65
0.68
0.62
0.75
0.69
0.67
—
−0.54
0.66
0.70
0.57
−0.58
—
0.58
−0.56
0.70
1.72
1.56
1.73
0.84
1.71
1.72
1.41
0.66
1.65
1.61
1.73
0.55
0.00
1.70
0.57
1.36
Changes in economic prosperity
Trend in
community
prosperity
(rc903)
0.58
0.55
0.15
0.53
0.45
0.57
0.55
−0.07
0.16
0.64
0.50
0.44
0.35
−0.03
0.37
0.50
Whether
easier or
harder to
make a living
(rc904)
0.42
0.66
0.69
0.38
0.14
0.50
0.63
0.54
−0.51
0.55
0.50
0.46
0.45
0.51
0.39
0.44
UP
Caste
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
MAL
Infra
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
MEX
Ethn
COL
Conf
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
ASSAM
Conf
Trend in
available
economic
opportunities
(rc912)
0.54
0.41
0.70
0.52
0.64
0.40
0.46
0.62
0.59
0.36
0.49
0.46
0.67
0.62
0.55
0.49
Trend in
access to
economic
opportunities
(rc917)
0.45
0.30
0.10
0.55
0.61
0.52
−0.31
0.56
0.61
0.39
0.50
0.62
0.47
0.59
0.64
0.56
1.98
1.92
1.65
1.98
1.84
1.99
1.33
1.66
0.85
1.95
2.00
1.98
1.94
1.69
1.95
1.99
−0.29
0.49
0.19
0.44
0.10
−0.22
0.60
0.37
0.36
0.45
0.64
0.54
0.51
0.41
0.61
0.63
0.58
0.57
Responsiveness of local democracy
Trust in local
government
officials
(rh415bi)
0.39
0.51
0.47
0.24
—
0.04
—
Satisfaction
with
democracy
in local
government
(rh511)
0.53
0.57
0.47
0.50
0.51
0.53
0.56
381
382
UP
Caste
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
MAL
Infra
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
MEX
Ethn
COL
Conf
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
ASSAM
Conf
Extent to
which local
government
takes into
account
concerns
(rh502b)
0.58
0.22
0.56
0.59
0.55
0.60
0.59
0.61
0.59
0.57
0.49
0.56
0.59
0.39
0.55
0.51
Ability to
influence
actions
of local
government
(rh504)
0.49
0.61
0.49
0.59
0.66
0.60
0.58
0.58
0.06
0.59
0.55
0.71
0.48
0.29
0.48
0.54
1.98
1.90
1.99
1.91
1.72
1.77
1.73
1.35
1.78
1.89
1.99
1.78
1.47
1.92
1.97
1.98
Corruption in
government
officials at the
country level
(c505b)
0.67
0.70
0.65
0.71
0.71
—
0.71
0.65
−0.71
−0.71
0.58
0.61
0.70
0.71
0.68
Corruption in
government
officials
in village
(c506b)
0.69
0.71
0.68
0.71
0.71
—
0.71
0.63
0.64
0.57
0.71
0.70
0.73
Corruption
—
0.71 used
used
directly directly
Corruption in
government
officials in
community
(c924)
UP
Caste
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
MAL
Infra
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
0.28
0.09
0.35
—
—
used
directly
—
−0.43
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
MEX
Ethn
COL
Conf
—
0.71
0.51
LOM: HH:
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
ASSAM
Conf
0.08
−0.09
0.06
1.49
1.31
1.47
0.55
1.64
1.50
1.67
1.41
1.41
0.00
1.41
0.84
0.00
0.00
0.00
1.73
1.73
383
384
UP
Caste
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
MAL
Infra
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
Farmers getting
fair prices
(rh240b)
0.13
0.32
−0.18
0.52
—
—
0.71
−0.16
Fairness in
treatment by
law within
community
(rh606b)
0.23
0.50
0.43
0.66
−0.03
0.29
0.71
−0.08
Denied credit
(h234)
0.67
0.69
0.65
—
0.71
0.67
—
Expectation
of denial of
credit (h236)
0.70
0.41
0.60
0.54
0.71
0.68
1.72
1.92
1.50
1.72
1.38
Step on ladder 0.71
of power and
rights, 10 years
ago (h708)
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
1.41
1.41
1.41
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
MEX
Ethn
COL
Conf
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
ASSAM
Conf
0.71
0.25
−0.15
0.02
0.42
0.13
0.23
0.41
0.71
0.21
−0.19
0.24
0.01
−0.29
0.08
0.70
0.64
—
0.66
0.68
0.70
0.64
0.67
0.70
—
0.69
0.65
—
0.68
0.69
0.68
0.64
0.67
0.68
1.65
1.41
1.16
1.70
1.41
1.79
1.02
1.63
1.72
1.18
1.68
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
Fairness
Personal agency
Control over
everyday
decisions
(rh501b)
UP
Caste
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
MAL
Infra
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
MEX
Ethn
COL
Conf
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
ASSAM
Conf
Household aspirations
Aspirations for
self (rh716)
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
—
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
Aspirations
for future
generation
(rh717)
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
—
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
0.00
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
Coming
together to
solve water
problems,
10 years ago
(rc412b)
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71 used
directly
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
−0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
Coming
together to
assist each
other 10 years
ago (rc413b)
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
—
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
0.00
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
0.00
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
Collective action
385
386
UP
Caste
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
MAL
Infra
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
MEX
Ethn
COL
Conf
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
ASSAM
Conf
School inequality
Ethnic/
religious
discrimination
in schools
(c305b)
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.69
−0.71
0.66
0.71
0.71
−0.71
0.71
—
0.71
Gender
discrimination
in schools
(c304b)
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.71
0.69
0.71
0.66
0.71
0.71
—
0.71
—
0.71
1.41
0.00
1.41
0.20
LOM: Change
in equality
in schools
(h303b,
3=improved,
1=deteriorated)
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.41
1.59
0.35
0.00
1.67
0.71
1.41
1.41
0.00
Appendix 6: Regression Results
Tables for MOP and MPI
387
388
Full OLS Regression Results with MOP as Dependent Variable
Independent
variables
associated with
MOP
UP
Caste
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
MAL
Infra
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
MEX
Ethn
COL
Conf
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
ASSAM
Conf
−0.19*** −0.18*** 0.08
0.05*
0.02* −0.10*** −0.04***
0.18**
0.04
(0.03)
(0.01)
(0.06)
(0.03)
Initial strength of
economy (PCA
rc205b, rc208b,
rc209b)
−0.02
0.01
−0.02
0.03*
0.11
−0.12**
0.04
(0.02)
(0.01)
(0.05)
(0.01)
(0.11)
(0.04)
(0.03)
Change in
economic
prosperity (PCA
rc904m, rc903m,
rc912m, rc917m)
−0.01
−0.01
0.00
0.07***
0.13**
0.01
−0.00
0.32***
0.03
0.04
0.04
0.02
0.08***
0.07***
0.06
0.01
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.04)
(0.02)
(0.05)
(0.03)
(0.01)
(0.05)
(0.12)
(0.05)
(0.03)
(0.02)
(0.03)
(0.01)
(0.05)
(0.02)
0.04**
0.03*
−0.02
0.06**
0.01
−0.05
−0.02
0.01
0.08*
−0.04
−0.01
−0.00
−0.04
−0.01
0.04
0.04*
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.07)
(0.04)
(0.03)
(0.04)
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.01)
(0.04)
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.02)
−0.03
LOM of
responsiveness of
(0.02)
local democracy
(locdemocracylom)
−0.04
0.13* −0.17***
0.37* −0.10*
(0.02)
(0.05)
(0.18)
(0.06)
−0.03
0.01
−0.04
−0.07*** −0.09*
0.21*
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.04)
Fairness index (PCA 0.03*
rh240b, rh606b,
(0.01)
h234, h236)
0.04*
0.05
0.04
(0.02)
(0.05)
(0.02)
Responsiveness of
local democracy
(PCA rh504,
rrh415bi, rh511,
rh502b)
Corruption (PCA
c505b, c506b,
c924m)
(0.06)
(0.01)
(0.05)
(0.10)
(0.03)
−0.17*** 0.77***
(0.05)
(0.06)
(0.02)
(0.01)
0.85**
0.04
0.06
0.27***
0.16* −0.11*
(0.27)
(0.12)
(0.08)
(0.05)
(0.08)
−0.08*** 0.09*** −0.02
−0.01
(0.03)
(0.01)
(0.17)
(0.01)
(0.08)
(0.10)
−0.03***
(0.01)
(0.04)
0.09***
0.03
(0.03)
(0.03)
Independent
variables
associated with
MOP
UP
Caste
−0.02
LOM of fairness
index (fairindexlom)
(0.03)
WB
Landdist
Household
aspirations (PCA
rh716, rh717)
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
MAL
Infra
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
MEX
Ethn
COL
Conf
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
ASSAM
Conf
−0.03
0.00
(0.03)
(0.05)
0.04* −0.01
Personal agency
index (PCA rh501b,
(0.02) (0.03)
h708)
LOM of personal
agency index
AP
SHG
0.01
0.07**
0.04* −0.07
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.02)
−0.01
0.06
0.03
−0.03
0.05
0.03
0.05*
−0.06
(0.06)
(0.03)
(0.07)
(0.03)
(0.05)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.03)
(0.05)
0.08**
(0.03)
−0.08
0.03
−0.23*
0.00
0.14
0.01
−0.10*
0.48
0.13
0.14
0.97***
0.06
(0.06)
(0.04)
(0.09)
(0.08)
(0.36)
(0.15)
(0.05)
(1.00)
(0.18)
(0.16)
(0.21)
(0.09)
0.14**
0.25**
−0.04*
0.01
0.03* −0.02
0.00
0.03
−0.01
n.a.
0.01
−0.02
0.11*
0.01
0.03
0.09**
(0.01)
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.04)
(0.03)
(0.02)
(0.06)
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.02)
LOM of household −0.18** −0.19**
aspirations
(0.03) (0.03)
(hhsasplom)
Index of collective
action, 10 years
ago (PCA rc412b,
rc413b)
−0.03* −0.01
Change in access
to networks and
associations
(rc919m, 1=less,
3=more)
(0.01)
(0.05)
0.05
−0.10
(0.05)
(0.06)
−0.11* −0.04***
(0.02)
(0.05)
−0.01
0.00
n.a.
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.01)
−0.28***
(0.06)
0.05
n.a.
(0.07)
n.a.
0.15** −0.25*** −0.21*
(0.05)
0.10
(0.07)
n.a.
(0.05)
−0.56***
(0.10)
n.a.
(0.09)
0.06
(0.48)
n.a.
−0.07*
0.00
0.06**
0.11***
(0.03)
(0.02)
0.03
(0.03)
−0.05
(0.10)
−0.15*** n.a.
(0.02)
n.a.
−0.34*** −0.08
(0.06)
0.01
(0.02)
(0.06)
−0.04
(0.05)
389
390
Independent
variables
associated with
MOP
Extent of social
divisions in the
village, 10 years
ago (c414b, 1=no
division, 5=to a
great extent)
Violence against
women in
households, 10
years ago (h609b,
1=none, 4=much)
LOM of violence
against women
in households,
10 years ago
(h609blom)
School inequality
measure, trend
(PCA c304b,
c305b)
Present education
status of household
head (educ2005)
Health shocks,
over 10 years
(healthshock,
1=yes, 0=no)
UP
Caste
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
MAL
Infra
SEN
Infra
−0.01
0.00
0.03
0.06**
0.01
−0.10
−0.09
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.04)
(0.02)
(0.07)
(0.09)
(0.06)
0.04
−0.08*
(0.02)
(0.04)
−0.08** n.a.
n.a.
(0.03)
−0.02
n.a.
(0.11)
TAN
Ruv
n.a.
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
0.02
−0.07
(0.29)
(0.08)
MEX
Ethn
COL
Conf
AFG
Conf
0.31** 0.10***
(0.13)
INDO
Conf
−0.38***
(0.01)
(0.05)
PHI
Conf
ASSAM
Conf
0.17*
0.02
(0.09)
(0.02)
0.03
−0.08
0.01
0.02
0.03
−0.02
0.06
0.02
0.09**
(0.03)
(0.08)
(0.08)
(0.04)
(0.02)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.07)
(0.03)
−0.07
0.08
−0.15**
(0.05)
(0.05)
(0.05)
0.00
0.00
0.05
0.00
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.04)
(0.02)
0.04**
−0.01
(0.01)
0.03**
(0.01)
(0.01)
−0.02
−0.04
0.00
−0.09**
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.03)
n.a.
n.a.
−0.04
0.06
(0.08)
(0.20)
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
0.07**
0.01
(0.03)
(0.03)
n.a.
0.06*
n.a.
(0.03)
0.04**
(0.01)
(−0.00)
0.03
−0.07
0.06
0.05
−0.12
−0.05
−0.05
−0.09*
(0.07)
(0.06)
(0.08)
(0.06)
(0.06)
(0.17)
(0.07)
(0.07)
(0.05)
Independent
variables
associated with
MOP
Initial landholding
(land1995)
UP
Caste
Initial livestock
index (PCA
rh203ib–rh203xib)
Policy variable
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
MAL
Infra
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
MEX
Ethn
COL
Conf
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
ASSAM
Conf
0.02**
0.00
−0.01
(0.00)
(0.01)
−0.01
(0.04)
0.07
0.12**
(0.04)
(0.05)
n.a.
−0.16
(0.03)
n.a.
0.05**
0.00
0.12**
0.07
0.13*
(0.02)
(0.05)
(0.06)
(0.06)
n.a.
0.00
0.03
0.01
0.01***
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.00)
−0.09* −0.03
(0.03)
0.15*** −0.13
(0.23)
(0.02)
(0.01)
(0.04)
Constant
AP
SHG
(0.01)
0.16
Ownership of
house, 10 years ago
(0.12)
(ownhouse1995,
1=yes, 0=no)
Initial assets index
(PCA rh201ib–
rh201xiiib)
WB
Landdist
0.03
n.a.
(0.07)
0.02
−0.06
(0.02)
(0.05)
(0.09)
−0.03
0.04
−0.05
−0.01
0.15
0.04
(−0.21)*
0.16
(0.06)
(0.08)
(0.07)
(0.04)
(0.12)
(0.12)
(0.10)
(0.15)
0.08*
0.08
−0.09*
0.05*
−0.01
0.01
0.23***
0.10**
0.03
(0.04)
(0.09)
(0.04)
(0.03)
(0.02)
(0.08)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(−0.03)
−0.04
(0.04)
(0.04)
n.a.
−0.02
0.03
0.09
0.00**
0.01
0.00
(0.03)
(0.02)
(0.11)
(0.00)
(0.06)
(0.02)
−0.05** (−0.07)**
(0.02)
0.20*** −0.05
(0.02)
(0.01)
(0.03)
−0.08**
(0.04)
−0.15*** 0.04
(0.02)
(0.02)
0.44**
0.54**
0.72** 1.11***
0.44**
0.34*
0.07
1.90***
0.28
0.62*
0.24
−0.10
0.70*
1.40***
0.89*** 0.35
(0.15)
(0.06)
(0.25)
(0.18)
(0.19)
(0.27)
(0.13)
(0.20)
(0.31)
(0.24)
(0.15)
(0.27)
(0.25)
(0.18)
(0.17)
(0.32)
Observations
969
620
531
501
217
75
200
233
100
217
261
211
67
238
167
452
R2
0.32
0.41
0.17
0.18
0.17
0.09
0.20
0.16
0.44
0.09
0.12
0.51
0.20
0.19
0.36
0.30
Note: Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. n.a. = not available.
*p < .10 **p < .05 ***p < .01 (White heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors)
391
392
Full OLS Regression Results with MPI as Dependent Variable
Independent
variables
associated with
MPI
Initial strength of
economy (PCA
rc205b, rc208b,
rc209b)
UP
Caste
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.08
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.05)
(0.02)
(0.06)
0.00
−0.01
−0.01
(0.01)
(0.05)
0.04**
0.03*
−0.03
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.02)
−0.03
LOM of
responsiveness of
(0.02)
local democracy
(locdemocracylom)
−0.02
Responsiveness of
local democracy
(PCA rh504,
rh415bi, rh511,
rh502b)
Corruption (PCA
c505b, c506b,
c924m)
UGA
Panel
−0.01
(0.01)
Change in
economic
prosperity (PCA
rc904m, rc903m,
rc912m, rc917m)
BAN
Empow
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
AFG
Conf
−0.05** −0.15*** −0.03*
(0.02)
(0.01)
−0.05** −0.33***
INDO
Conf
−0.09***
(0.02)
0.01
PHI
Conf
MEX
Ethn
PHI
Panel
0.15*** −0.07*** −0.00
(0.03)
COL
Conf
(0.01)
THAI
Ineq
ASSAM
Conf
−0.00
0.04
0.07**
(0.06)
(0.04)
(0.07)
(0.02)
0.06***
0.07
0.02
0.03***
0.01
0.03**
0.02
−0.12
0.05
0.01
(0.02)
(0.04)
(0.02)
(0.06)
(0.02)
0.01
(0.03)
(0.01)
(0.02)
(0.10)
(0.05)
(0.02)
0.05**
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.02
0.03
0.08*** −0.00
−0.02
0.04
−0.04
0.04*
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.03)
(0.02)
(0.02)
0.03
(0.02)
(0.03)
(0.07)
(0.03)
(0.02)
0.20** −0.27***
0.11
(0.02)
(0.05)
(0.07)
(0.13)
(0.05)
−0.01
0.01
−0.01
−0.06**
−0.03
−0.02
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.03)
(0.02)
−0.16** −0.55***
(0.14)
0.21***
(0.01)
(0.03)
0.29***
0.16***
0.09
0.90** −0.06
0.04
(0.04)
(0.08)
(0.30)
−0.03
(0.02)
(0.10)
−0.09**
(0.03)
−0.04**
0.07
0.02
0.01
(0.02)
(0.05)
(0.15)
(0.02)
Independent
variables
associated with
MPI
UP
Caste
Fairness index (PCA 0.02
rh240b, rh606b,
(0.02)
h234, h236)
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
0.04*
−0.01
(0.02)
(0.05)
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
COL
Conf
THAI
Ineq
−0.08
0.04*
Personal agency
index (PCA rh501b, (0.02)
h708)
−0.01
0.02
0.05*
0.02
−0.01
0.01
0.02
−0.09
(0.03)
(0.04)
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.03)
(0.05)
0.04
(0.05)
−0.08
0.04
−0.12
0.14*
−0.44*
0.04
(0.05)
(0.05)
(0.11)
(0.08)
(0.24)
(0.05)
0.13**
0.24** −0.04
−0.01
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.10**
0.00
0.03
0.02
(0.01)
(0.02)
(0.01)
(0.03)
(0.02)
(0.04)
(0.04)
0.05
(0.03)
(0.02)
(0.03)
LOM of household
aspirations
(hhsasplom)
−0.17** −0.17**
(0.03)
Index of collective
action, 10 years
ago (PCA rc412b,
rc413b)
ASSAM
Conf
0.05**
−0.02
Household
aspirations (PCA
rh716, rh717)
PHI
Panel
(0.02)
LOM of fairness
0.02
index (fairindexlom) (0.03)
LOM of personal
agency index
MEX
Ethn
(0.06)
(0.02)
0.03**
(0.01)
0.36*
0.21
−0.04
0.12*
0.03
0.07*
(0.04)
(0.06)
(0.03)
(0.03)
0.16
1.46
−0.13
−0.03
(0.14)
(0.98)
(0.17)
(0.08)
0.00
−0.02
(0.03)
(0.04)
n.a.
0.11**
(0.02)
0.04
−0.09
(0.04)
(0.07)
(0.06)
−0.01
−0.02
−0.11
−0.00
0.06
0.17*** (−0.02)
0.06***
0.19***
0.04
−0.01
−0.18*
(0.01)
(0.02)
(0.06)
(0.01)
(0.05)
(0.05)
(0.02)
0.01
(0.03)
(0.05)
(0.09)
(0.04)
n.a.
−0.03
(0.02)
393
394
Independent
variables
associated with
MPI
Change in access
to networks and
associations
(rc919m, 1=less,
3=more)
Extent of social
divisions in the
village, 10 years
ago (c414b, 1=no
division, 5=to a
great extent)
UP
Caste
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
BAN
Empow
0.01
−0.01
n.a.
−0.11
(0.01)
(0.01)
UGA
Panel
SEN
Infra
n.a.
n.a.
(0.08)
−0.01
0.02
−0.01
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.03)
TAN
Ruv
(−0.02)
AFG
Conf
n.a.
(0.11)
0.10**
0.07
0.07
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.08)
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
INDO
Conf
–0.27***
0.06
n.a.
−0.18***
0.05
PHI
Conf
COL
Conf
MEX
Ethn
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
n.a.
0.00
−0.04
−0.05
0.40
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.08)
(0.37)
0.10** −0.10*** −0.07
(0.03)
ASSAM
Conf
−0.05
(0.04)
−0.16
−0.09
−0.001
(0.02)
(0.16)
(0.22)
(0.07)
(0.02)
0.04
−0.07
−0.05
(0.02)
(0.04)
(0.04)
−0.05
0.02
−0.15**
(0.04)
(0.05)
(0.05)
0.01
School inequality
measure, trend
(0.01)
(PCA c304b, c305b)
0.00
0.06*
0.01
(0.01)
(0.03)
(0.02)
Violence against
women in
households, 10
years ago (h609b,
1=none, 4=much)
LOM of violence
against women
in households,
10 years ago
(h609blom)
0.00
0.02
−0.02
0.01
0.03*
−0.02
−0.10
−0.01
(0.04)
(0.05)
0.05
(0.07)
(0.01)
(0.03)
(0.09)
(0.05)
0.07**
(0.03)
Independent
variables
associated with
MPI
Present education
status of household
head (educ2005)
Health shocks,
over 10 years
(healthshock,
1=yes, 0=no)
Initial landholding
(land1995)
UP
Caste
0.03**
Initial livestock
index (PCA
rh203ib–
rh203xib)
AP
SHG
−0.01
(0.01)
BAN
Empow
0.03***
(0.01)
(0.01)
UGA
Panel
SEN
Infra
n.a.
n.a.
TAN
Ruv
n.a.
AFG
Conf
n.a.
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
MEX
Ethn
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
−0.03*
0.05
n.a.
n.a.
(0.02)
(0.03)
(−0.13)*
0.03
−0.03
0.11
−0.07
−0.08
(0.06)
(0.02)
(0.05)
(0.08)
(0.08)
(0.04)
0.06***
0.01
−0.04
−0.02
−0.04
−0.06*
0.04
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.03)
(0.08)
n.a.
(0.01)
−0.27
−0.07
(0.07)
(0.20)
0.07
COL
Conf
ASSAM
Conf
0.03*
(0.02)
0.01*
0.00*
−0.01
(0.01)
(0.00)
(0.01)
0.09
Ownership of
house, 10 years ago (0.11)
(ownhouse1995,
1=yes, 0=no)
Initial assets index
(PCA rh201ib–
rh201xiiib, with
current weights)
WB
Landdist
0.04
0.14**
(0.05)
(0.06)
n.a.
−0.01
0.04*
0.02
0.02
0.04
(0.04)
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.04)
(0.05)
n.a.
0.00
0.03*
0.04
0.01
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.02)
(0.00)
0.10*** −0.02
0.10
0.03
−0.19
0.08
−0.01
−0.01
0.04
0.19
(0.03)
(0.11)
0.12
(0.13)
(0.07)
(0.06)
(0.17)
(0.06)
(0.17)
0.10**
0.02
0.15***
0.07
0.04
0.02
0.01
−0.08
0.03
(0.04)
(0.07)
0.05
(0.05)
(0.04)
(0.03)
(0.07)
(0.05)
(0.04)
0.18***
0.00
0.06
−0.01
−0.03
0.02
n.a.
(0.03)
0.00
(0.05)
(0.01)
(0.03)
(0.05)
n.a.
n.a.
(0.09)
(−0.03)
(0.02)
−0.02
(0.02)
395
396
Independent
variables
associated with
MPI
UP
Caste
Policy variable
−0.08*
−0.03
0.02
−0.03
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.01)
(0.04)
Constant
WB
Landdist
AP
SHG
BAN
Empow
UGA
Panel
SEN
Infra
TAN
Ruv
AFG
Conf
INDO
Conf
PHI
Conf
COL
Conf
MEX
Ethn
PHI
Panel
THAI
Ineq
ASSAM
Conf
1.01*** −0.07*** −0.15*** −0.08***
0.07**
0.03
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.02)
−3.06***
(0.01)
0.02
(0.01)
0.33*
0.63**
0.80*
0.68*** 0.50*** −0.01
0.99***
0.82***
0.84***
1.06*** 0.96*** 0.41** 0.83**
0.54
(0.13)
(0.08)
(0.32)
(0.22)
(0.11)
(0.28)
(0.19)
(0.26)
0.24
(0.18)
(0.13)
(0.23)
(0.16)
(0.32)
(0.30)
Observations
969
620
531
501
217
200
233
67
238
167
211
261
100
217
452
R2
0.28
0.38
0.15
0.14
0.11
0.13
0.15
0.22
0.14
0.22
0.41
0.14
0.27
0.091
0.32
Note: Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. n.a. = not available.
*p < .10 **p < .05 ***p < .01 (White heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors)
Regression Results Tables for MOP and MPI
397
Notes
1. The basic specification includes variables on economic opportunity, local democracy, collective action, agency, aspirations, violence against women, and extent of
social divisions in the village.
2. Also included are household characteristics (assets, livestock, house ownership,
education level, health shocks).
3. The standard errors reported for all regressions are corrected for cluster-based
sampling. Seed set at 123 for imputations.
4. Non-India regressions: Because of small sample sizes, the basic model has been
reduced to include a limited set of variables under each block or concept. Fairness, school inequality, and ownership of land have been dropped.
5. Regressions combine the variables on power and rights and control over decision
making into a personal agency index.
6. Leave-out means (LOM) are included only for the democracy and personal
agency indexes. LOMs for violence against women, fairness, and aspirations have
been dropped except for India.
7. Conflict countries include a variable for conflict.
8. In some conflict countries, corruption, social divisiveness, and the LOM variables
had to be dropped because of high multicollinearity with the conflict variable.
9. In Malawi, the absolute ranks for each household on the mobility matrix were
not consistently entered. It was not possible, therefore, to calculate upward
mobility (MPI) for each household. However, the status of each household as
ranked by the mobility matrix (i.e., whether mover, faller, chronic poor, or never
poor) was available and was used for the MOP household regressions.
Country notes
UP (Caste): Policy variable is whether household belongs to scheduled caste (1=yes,
0=no).
WB (Landdist): Policy variable is whether village had a land reform program in the
past 10 years (1=yes, 0=no).
AP (SHG): Policy variable is number of groups household belonged to 10 years ago.
BAN (Empow): Violence against women: n.a. Corruption index includes only c505b
and c506b. Initial assets index (PCA h201ib, iib, ivb, vib, viiib, with current
weights). Initial livestock index (h203iib, h203vb, h203viiib, with current
weights). No policy variable is included.
UGA (Panel): Change in access to networks, violence against women, education status
of household head, ownership of house, initial livestock index: n.a. Responsiveness of local democracy does not include rh415bi. Corruption index includes
only c505b and c506b. Initial assets index = mean of assets 10 years ago. No
policy variable is included.
MAL (Infra): Index of collective action, education status of household head: n.a.
Change in economic prosperity includes only rc912 and rc917. For corruption,
c924 used directly. Policy variable is access to growth facilities.
398
Success from the Bottom Up
SEN (Infra): Change in access to networks, violence against women, initial livestock
index, initial asset index, education status of household head, health shocks: n.a.
Initial strength of economy includes only rc205b and rc208b. Responsiveness of
local democracy does not include rh415bi. Corruption index does not include
c924. For ownership of house, housing conditions used as proxy (PCA rh207).
For collective action, rc412 used directly. Policy variable is access to social infrastructure (1=less, 3=more).
TAN (Ruv): Education status of household head, extent of social divisions in the village: n.a. Personal agency index and its LOM dropped as a result of low variance.
Initial strength of economy includes only rc205b and rc208b. Corruption index
does not include c924. Imputed variables: household aspirations, responsiveness of local democracy, violence against women, ownership of house, health
shocks. Policy variable is log (distance to main centers).
PHI (Panel): Education status of household head: n.a. Corruption index does not
include c924. No policy variable is included.
THAI (Ineq): Household aspirations, index of collective action, change in access
to networks, education status of household head, initial livestock index: n.a.
Imputed variables: responsiveness of local democracy, personal agency index,
violence against women, initial assets, ownership of house, health shocks. No
policy variable is included.
MEX (Ethn): All variables except for the initial asset index, initial livestock index, and
education status of household head were imputed. Corruption index does not
include c506b. No policy variable is included.
COL (Conf): Policy variable is impact of conflict (0=no conflict, 4=large harmful effect).
Corruption, LOM of responsiveness of local democracy, and LOM of personal
agency index dropped because of high multicollinearity with the conflict variable.
Imputed variables: initial strength of economy, responsiveness of local democracy,
household aspirations, violence against women, ownership of house.
AFG (Conf): Policy variable is impact of conflict on functioning of markets (1=no
effect, 4=large harmful effect). Education status of household head: n.a. Change
in access to networks is not included because of lack of variation. Corruption,
social divisions, and both LOMs are dropped because of high multicollinearity with the conflict variable. Initial strength of economy: rc205b used directly.
Imputed variables: responsiveness of local democracy, personal agency index,
household aspirations, ownership of house.
INDO (Conf): Policy variable is impact of conflict on functioning of markets (1=no
effect, 4=large harmful effect). Imputed variables: household aspirations.
PHI (Conf): Index of collective action and education status of household head: n.a.
Policy variable is impact of conflict on functioning of local markets (1=no effect,
4=large harmful effect). LOM of personal agency index and corruption dropped
due to high multicollinearity with the conflict variable.
ASSAM (Conf): Policy variable is conflict trajectory (1=peace to peace; 2=conflict to
peace; 3=peace to conflict; 4=conflict to conflict).
References
Acemoglu, D., and J. A. Robinson. 2008. “Persistence of Power, Elites, and Institutions.” American Economic Review 98 (1): 267–93.
Agarwal, B., J. Humphries, and I. Robeyns, eds. 2006. Capabilities, Freedom, and Equality: Amartya Sen’s Work from a Gender Perspective. New Delhi: Oxford University
Press.
Aiyar, S., D. Narayan, and K. Raju. 2007. “Empowerment through Self-Help Groups:
Andhra Pradesh Shows the Way in India.” In Ending Poverty in South Asia: Ideas That
Work, ed. D. Narayan and E. Glinskaya, 104–35. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Alatas, V., L. Pritchett, and A. Wetterberg. 2007. “Voice Lessons: Evidence on Social Organizations, Government Mandated Organizations, and Governance from Indonesia’s
Local Level Institutions Study.” In Membership-Based Organizations of the Poor, ed. M.
Chen, R. Jhabvala, R. Kanbur, and C. Richards, 313–51. New York: Routledge.
Alderman, H., P. Chiappori, L. Haddad, J. Hoddinott, and R. Kanbur. 1995. “Unitary
Versus Collective Models of the Household: Is It Time to Shift the Burden of
Proof?” World Bank Research Observer 10 (1): 1–19.
Alesina, A., and G. Angeletos. 2005. “Fairness and Redistribution.” American Economic
Review 95 (4): 960–80.
Alesina, A., and E. Glaeser. 2004. Fighting Poverty in the U.S. and Europe: A World of
Difference. New York: Oxford University Press.
Alesina, A., E. Glaeser, and B. Sacerdote. 2001. “Why Doesn’t the United States
Have a European-Style Welfare State?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 32
(2001–02): 187–278.
Alkire, S. 2002. Valuing Freedoms: Sen’s Capability Approach and Poverty Reduction. New
York: Oxford University Press.
———. 2008. “Concepts and Measures of Agency.” Working Paper 9, Oxford Poverty
and Human Development Initiative, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK.
Alsop, R., and N. Heinsohn. 2005. “Measuring Empowerment in Practice: Structuring
Analysis and Framing Indicators.” Policy Research Working Paper 3510, World
Bank, Washington, DC.
Appadurai, A. 2004. “The Capacity to Aspire: Culture and the Terms of Recognition.”
In Culture and Public Action, ed. V. Rao and M. Walton, 59–84. Stanford, CA:
Stanford University Press.
Arrow, K. J. 1971. Essays in the Theory of Risk-Bearing. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
399
400
Success from the Bottom Up
Ashforth, A. 2005. Witchcraft, Violence, and Democracy in South Africa. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Axelrod, R. 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books.
Baiochhi, G. 2005. “Inequality and Innovation: Decentralization as an Opportunity
Structure in Brazil.” In Decentralization and Local Governments in Developing Countries: A Comparative Perspective, ed. P. Bardhan and D. Mookherjee. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Bandura, A. 1995. “Comments on the Crusade against the Causal Efficacy of Human
Thought.” Journal of Behavior Therapy and Experimental Psychiatry 26 (3): 179–90.
———. 1998. “Personal and Collective Efficacy in Human Adaptation and Change.”
In Advances in Psychological Science, vol. 1, Social, Personal, and Cultural Aspects, ed.
J. G. Adair, D. Belanger, and K. L. Dion, 51–71. Hove, UK: Psychology Press.
Banerjee, A., and E. Duflo. 2006. “The Economic Lives of the Poor.” Discussion Paper
5968, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.
Banfield, E. 1958. The Moral Basis of a Backward Society. New York: Free Press.
Bardhan, P. 1999. “Democracy and Development: A Complex Relationship.” In
Democracy’s Value, ed. I. Shapiro and C. Hacker-Cordón, 93–111. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
———. 2002. “Decentralization of Governance and Development.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 16 (4): 85–205.
Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 2004. “Poverty Alleviation Efforts of West Bengal
Panchayats.” Economic and Political Weekly, February 28, 965–74.
———. 2006. “Pro-poor Targeting and Accountability of Local Governments in West
Bengal.” Journal of Development Economics 79 (2): 303–27.
Barro, R. 1994. “Democracy and Growth.” Working Paper 4909, National Bureau of
Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Barron, P., R. Diprose, and M. Woolcock. 2007. “Local Conflict and Development
Projects in Indonesia: Part of the Problem or Part of a Solution?” Policy Research
Working Paper 4212, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Baulch, B., and N. McCulloch. 2002. “Being Poor and Becoming Poor: Poverty Status
and Poverty Transitions in Rural Pakistan.” Journal of Asian and African Studies
37 (2): 168–85.
Bebbington, A., L. Dharmawan, E. Fahmi, and S. Guggenheim. 2006. “Local Capacity,
Village Governance, and the Political Economy of Rural Development in Indonesia.” World Development 34 (11): 1958–76.
Beegle, K., J. De Weerdt, and S. Dercon. 2006. “Orphanhood and the Long-Term
Impact on Children.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 88 (5): 1266–
77.
Bénabou, R., and J. Tirole. 2006. “Belief in a Just World and Redistributive Politics.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 121 (2): 699–746.
Bertrand, M., and S. Mullainathan. 2001. “Do People Mean What They Say? Implications for Subjective Survey Data.” American Economic Review 91 (2): 67–72.
Besley, T., and R. Burgess. 2002. “The Political Economy of Government Responsiveness: Theory and Evidence from India.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4):
1415–51.
Besley, T., R. Pande, and V. Rao. 2007. “Just Rewards? Local Politics and Public
Resource Allocation in South India.” Development Economics Paper 49, Sun-
References
401
tory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related Disciplines,
London School of Economics and Political Science.
Bester, H. 1985. “Screening vs. Rationing in Credit Markets with Imperfect Information.” American Economic Review 75 (4): 850–55.
———. 1994. “The Role of Collateral in a Model of Debt Renegotiation.” Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking 26 (1): 72–86.
Bhide, S., and A. K. Mehta. 2004. “Chronic Poverty in Rural India: Issues and Findings
from Panel Data.” Journal of Human Development 5 (2): 195–209.
Booth, C. 1889. Life and Labour of the People in London. London: Macmillan.
Boudon, R. 1973. L’inégalité des chances: La mobilité sociale dans les sociétés industrielles.
Paris: Colin.
Bourdieu, P., and J. C. Passeron. 1970. La Reproduction. Paris: Editions de Minuit.
Bovens, M. 2006. “Analysing and Assessing Public Accountability: A Conceptual
Framework.” European Governance Papers (EUROGOV), no. C-06-01. http://
www.connex-network.org/eurogov/.
Carter, M. R., and M. Ikegami. 2007. “Looking Forward: Theory-Based Measures
of Chronic Poverty and Vulnerability.” Working Paper 485, Chronic Poverty
Research Centre, Manchester, UK.
Carter, M. R., and J. May. “One Kind of Freedom: Poverty Dynamics in Post-apartheid
South Africa.” World Development 29 (12): 1987–2006.
CGAP (Consultative Group to Assist the Poor) 2007. “CGAP Reflections on the Compartamos Initial Public Offering: A Case Study on Microfinance Interest Rates
and Profits.” Focus Note 42, CGAP, Washington, DC.
Chambers, R. 2002. “Power, Knowledge, and Policy Influence: Reflections on an Experience.” In Knowing Poverty: Critical Reflections on Participatory Research and Policy,
ed. K. Brock and R. McGee, 135–65. London: Earthscan.
———. 2003. “Deliberative Democratic Theory.” Annual Review of Political Science 6:
307–26.
Chen, S., and M. Ravallion. 2000. “How Did the World’s Poorest Fare in the 1990s?”
Policy Research Working Paper 2409, World Bank, Washington, DC.
———. 2007. “Absolute Poverty Measures for the Developing World, 1981–2004.”
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 104
(43): 16757–62.
Chronic Poverty Research Centre. 2008. Chronic Poverty Report, 2008–09: Escaping
Poverty Traps. Manchester, UK: CPRC.
CIFOR (Center for International Forest Research). 2005. Contributing to African Development through Forests: CIFOR’s Strategy for Engagement in Sub-Saharan Africa.
Bogor, Indonesia: CIFOR.
Cohen, J., and C. Sabel. 1997. “Directly Deliberative Polyarchy.” European Law Journal
3 (4): 313–42.
Cord, L. 2005. Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and Insights from 14 Countries.
World Bank: Washington, DC.
Crook, R., and J. Manor. 1998. Democracy and Decentralization in South Asia and West
Africa: Participation, Accountability, and Performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Dahl, R. 1989. Democracy and Its Critics. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
402
Success from the Bottom Up
Daily, C. M., and M. J. Dollinger. 1992. “An Empirical Examination of Ownership
Structure in Family and Professionally Managed Firms.” Family Business Review
5 (2): 117–36.
Deaton, A. 2004. “Measuring Poverty.” Working Paper 170, Woodrow Wilson School
of Public and International Affairs, Research Program in Development Studies,
Princeton University, Princeton, NJ.
Deininger, K., and J. Okidi. 2003. “Growth and Poverty Reduction in Uganda, 1992–
2000: Panel Data Evidence.” Development Policy Review 21 (4): 481–509.
Deininger, K., and L. Squire. 1996. “A New Data Set Measuring Income Inequality.”
World Bank Economic Review 10 (3): 565–91.
Dercon, S. 2004. “Growth and Shocks: Evidence from Rural Ethiopia.” Journal of
Development Economics 74: 309–29.
Dercon, S., with J. De Weerdt, T. Bold, and A. Pankhurst. 2006. “Group-Based Funeral
Insurance in Ethiopia and Tanzania.” World Development 34 (4): 685–703.
Dercon, S., and P. Krishnan. 2000. “Vulnerability, Seasonality, and Poverty in Ethiopia.” In Economic Mobility and Poverty Dynamics in Developing Countries, ed. B.
Baulch and J. Hoddinott. London: Frank Cass.
de Soto, H. 2000. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails
Everywhere Else. New York: Basic Books.
Diamond, L. 2002. “Elections Without Democracy: Thinking about Hybrid Regimes.”
Journal of Democracy 13 (2): 21–35.
———. 2005. “Empowering the Poor: What Does Democracy Have to Do with It?” In
Measuring Empowerment: Cross-Disciplinary Perspectives, ed. D. Narayan, 403–25.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
Diener, E., and R. Biswas-Diener. 2005. “Psychological Empowerment and Subjective
Well-Being.” In Measuring Empowerment: Cross-Disciplinary Perspectives, ed. D.
Narayan, 125–40. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Di Tella, R., and R. MacCulloch. 2007. “Why Doesn’t Capitalism Flow to Poor
Countries?” Working Paper 13164, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Cambridge, MA.
Dyrberg, T. B. 1997. The Circular Structure of Power: Politics, Identity, Community. New
York: Verso.
Ferguson, J. 1999. Expectations of Modernity: Myths and Meanings of Urban Life on the
Zambian Copperbelt. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Fields, G. S. 2001. Distribution and Development: A New Look at the Developing World.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press; New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Foster, A., and M. Rosenzweig. 2001. “Democratization, Decentralization and the
Distribution of Local Public Goods in a Poor Rural Economy.” Department of
Economics, Brown University, Providence, RI.
Freire, P. 1974. Education for Critical Consciousness. Trans. M. Marshall, M. B. Ramos,
and L. Bigwood. London: Sheed and Ward.
Friedman, B. 2005. The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth. New York: Knopf.
Fukuyama, F. 1995. Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. New York:
Free Press.
Fung, A., and E. O. Wright. 2003. “Thinking about Empowered Participatory Governance.” In Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance, ed. A. Fung and E. O. Wright, 3–42. New York: Verso.
References
403
Galasso, E., and M. Ravallion. 2005. “Decentralized Targeting of an Anti-Poverty Program.” Journal of Public Economics 85 (April): 705–27.
Galbraith, J. K. 1983. The Anatomy of Power. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Gersick, K. E., J. A. Davis, M. M. Hampton, and I. Lansberg. 1997. Generation to
Generation: Life Cycles of the Family Business. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business
School Press.
Gibbs, M., R. Lindner, and A. Fischer. 1986. “Reliability of Two Survey Techniques: A
Study of Innovation Discovery by Farmers.” Statistician 35 (4): 429–39.
Gladwell, M. 2000. The Tipping Point: How Little Things Can Make a Big Difference. New
York: Backbay Books.
Glewwe, P., and G. Hall. 1998. “Are Some Groups More Vulnerable to Macroeconomic Shocks than Others? Hypothesis Tests Based on Panel Data from Peru.”
Journal of Development Economics 56: 181–206.
Grootaert, C., and R. Kanbur. 1995. “The Lucky Few Amidst Economic Decline: Distributional Change in Côte d’Ivoire as Seen through Panel Data Sets, 1985–1988.”
Journal of Development Studies, 31 (4): 603–19.
Gugerty, M. K. 2007. “You Can’t Save Alone: Commitment in Rotating Savings and Credit
Associations in Kenya.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 55 (2): 251–82.
Gupta, D., and K. L. Sharma, eds. 1991. Country-Town Nexus: Studies in Social Transformation in Contemporary India. Jaipur: Rawat.
Hammer, J., and L. Pritchett. 2006. “Scenes from a Marriage: World Bank Economists
and Social Capital.” In The Search for Empowerment: Social Capital as Idea and
Practice at the World Bank, ed. A. Bebbington, M. Woolcock, S. Guggenheim, and
E. Olson, 63–90. Bloomfield, CT: Kumarian Press.
Harrison, L. E., and S. P. Huntington, eds. 2000. Culture Matters: How Values Shape
Human Progress. New York: Basic Books.
Hausman, J. A. 1978. “Specification Tests in Econometrics.” Econometrica 46 (6):
1251–71.
Heyer, J., F. Stewart, and R. Thorp, eds. 2002. Group Behavior and Development: Is the
Market Destroying Cooperation? New York: Oxford University Press.
Himmelfarb, G. 1992. Poverty and Compassion: The Moral Imagination of the Late Victorians. New York: Vintage.
Hirschman, A. O., and M. Rothschild. 1973. “The Changing Tolerance for Income
Inequality in the Course of Economic Development.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 87 (4): 544–66.
Hoff, K., and P. Pandey. 2004. “Belief Systems and Durable Inequalities: An Experimental Investigation of Indian Caste.” Policy Research Working Paper 3351,
World Bank, Washington, DC.
———. 2006. “Discrimination, Social Identity, and Durable Inequalities.” American
Economic Review 96 (2): 206–11.
Hunt, J. 2007. “Bribery in Health Care in Peru and Uganda.” Working Paper 13034,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Huntington, S., and J. Nelson. 1976. No Easy Choice: Political Participation in Developing Countries. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
404
Success from the Bottom Up
Ibrahim, S., and S. Alkire. 2007. “Agency and Empowerment: A Proposal for Internationally Comparable Indicators.” Oxford Development Studies 35 (4): 379–403.
Isham, J., D. Narayan, and L. Pritchett. 1994. “Does Participation Improve Performance? Establishing Causality with Subjective Data.” World Bank Economic
Review 9 (2): 175–200.
Jalan, J., and M. Ravallion. 2000. “Is Transient Poverty Different? Evidence for Rural
China.” Journal of Development Studies 36 (6): 82–99.
———. 2002. “Geographic Poverty Traps? A Micro Model of Consumption Growth in
Rural China.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 17: 329–46.
Johnston, D., and J. Morduch. 2007. “Microcredit vs. Microsaving: Evidence from
Indonesia.” Paper presented at World Bank conference on Access to Finance,
Washington, DC, March 15–16.
Kabeer, N. 1999. “Resources, Agency, Achievement: Reflections on the Measurement
of Women’s Empowerment.” Development as Change 30 (3): 435–64.
———. 2001. “Reflections on the Measurement of Women’s Empowerment: Theory
and Practice.” In Discussing Women’s Empowerment: Theory and Practice. Sida Studies 3. Stockholm: Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency.
Kahneman, D., and A. Krueger. 2006. “Developments in the Measurement of Subjective Well-Being.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 20 (1): 3–24.
Kanbur, R. 2008. “Globalization, Growth and Distribution: Framing the Questions.”
Working Paper 2008-3, Department of Applied Economics and Management,
Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.
Karelis, C. H. 2007. The Persistence of Poverty: Why the Economics of the Well-Off Can’t
Help the Poor. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Kaufman, A. 1968. “Participatory Democracy: Ten Years Later.” La Table Ronde, no.
251–252: 216–28. Reprinted in The Bias of Pluralism, ed. W. E. Connolly. New
York: Atherton Press, 1971.
Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and M. Mastruzzi. 2005. “Governance Matters IV: Governance Indicators for 1996–2004.” Policy Research Working Paper 3630, World
Bank, Washington, DC.
Keefer, P. 2002. “Clientelism, Credibility, and Democracy.” Development Research
Group, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Keefer, P., and R. Vlaicu. 2008. “Democracy, Credibility, and Clientelism.” Journal of
Law, Economics, and Organization 24 (2): 371–406.
Khandker, S. R. 1998. Fighting with Microcredit: Experience in Bangladesh. New York:
Oxford University Press.
———. 2005. “Microfinance and Poverty: Evidence Using Panel Data from Bangladesh.” World Bank Economic Review 19 (2): 263–86.
Khemani, S. 2001. “Decentralization and Accountability: Are Voters More Vigilant in
Local than in National Elections?” Policy Research Working Paper 2557, World
Bank, Washington, DC.
Knack, S. 2000. “Social Capital and the Quality of Government: Evidence from the
U.S. States.” Policy Research Working Paper 2504, World Bank, Washington,
DC.
References
405
———. 2005. “Empowerment as a Positive-Sum Game.” In Measuring Empowerment:
Cross-Disciplinary Perspectives, ed. D. Narayan, 365–81. Washington, DC: World
Bank.
Knack, S., and P. Keefer. 1997. “Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff? A
Cross-Country Investigation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4): 1251–88.
Kraay, A. 2006. “When Is Growth Pro-poor? Evidence from a Panel of Countries.”
Journal of Development Economics 80: 198–227.
Krishna A. 2002. Active Social Capital: Tracing the Roots of Development and Democracy.
New York: Columbia University Press.
———. 2004. “Escaping Poverty and Becoming Poor: Who Gains, Who Loses, and
Why?” World Development 32 (1): 121–36.
———. 2006. “Pathways Out of and Into Poverty in 36 Villages of Andhra Pradesh,
India.” World Development 34 (2): 271–88.
Krishna, A., M. Kapila, M. Porwal, and V. Singh. 2005. “Why Growth Is Not Enough:
Household Poverty Dynamics in Northeast Gujarat, India.” Journal of Development Studies 41 (7): 1163–92.
Krueger, A., and D. Schkade. 2007. “The Reliability of Subjective Well-Being Measures.” Working Paper 13027, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Kynch, J., and A. Sen. 1983. “Indian Women: Well-Being and Survival.” Cambridge
Journal of Economics 7 (3/4): 363–80.
Lane, R. 1959. “The Fear of Equality.” American Political Science Review 53 (1): 35–51.
Lanjouw, P., O. Jean, C. Elbers, and G. Demombynes. 2007. “How Good a Map? Putting Small Area Estimation to the Test.” Policy Research Working Paper 4155,
World Bank, Washington, DC.
Lankina, T., A. Hudalla, and H. Wollmann. 2007. Local Governance in Central and
Eastern Europe: Comparing Performance in the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, and
Russia. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Lerner, M. 1982. The Belief in a Just World: A Fundamental Delusion. New York: Plenum
Press.
Lewis, O. 1959. Five Families: Mexican Case Studies in the Culture of Poverty. New York:
Basic Books.
———. 1966. La Vida: A Puerto Rican Family in the Culture of Poverty—San Juan and New
York. New York: Random House.
Lieten, G. 1996. “Panchayats in Western Uttar Pradesh.“ Economic and Political Weekly,
September 28, 2700–5.
Loury, G. 1977. “A Dynamic Theory of Racial and Income Differences.” In Women,
Minorities, and Employment Discrimination, ed. P. Wallace and A. LaMond, 153–
88. Lexington, MA: Heath.
Lukes, S. 1974. Power: A Radical View. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan.
Mathew, G., and R. Nayak. 1996. “Panchayats at Work: What It Means for the
Oppressed?” Economic and Political Weekly, July 6, 1765–71.
Mayhew, H. 1851. London Labor and the London Poor. London: G. Woodfall.
Mayoux, L. 2003. “Women’s Empowerment, Participation, and Micro Finance: Issues,
Evidence, and Ways Forward.” In Sustainable Learning for Women’s Empowerment:
Ways Forward in Micro-Finance, ed. L. Mayoux. New Delhi: Samskriti.
406
Success from the Bottom Up
Mehta, P. B. 2003. The Burden of Democracy. New Delhi: Penguin India.
Molnar, A., A. White, and A. Khare. 2008. “Forest Rights and Asset-Based Livelihoods:
Catalyzing Rural Economies and Forest Conservation through Policy Reform
and Collective Action.” In Assets, Livelihoods, and Social Policy, ed. A. Dani and C.
Moser, 257–78. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Moser, C., and A. Norton. 2001. “To Claim Our Rights: Livelihood Security, Human
Rights, and Sustainable Development.” Overseas Development Institute, London.
Mosse, D. 1997. “The Symbolic Making of a Common Property Resource: History,
Ecology, and Locality in a Tank-Irrigated Landscape in South India.” Development
and Change 28: 467–504.
Munshi, K., and M. R. Rosenzweig. 2005. “Why Is Mobility in India So Low? Social
Insurance, Inequality, and Growth.” CID Working Paper 121, Center for International Development, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.
Murray, C. 1984. Losing Ground: American Social Policy, 1950–1980. New York: Basic
Books.
Narayan, D. 1999. “Social Capital and the State: Complementarity and Substitution.”
Policy Research Working Paper 2167, World Bank, Washington, DC.
———. 2002a. “Bonds and Bridges: Social Capital and Poverty.” In Social Capital and
Economic Development: Well-being in Developing Countries, ed. J. Isham, T. Kelly,
and S. Ramaswamy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
———, ed. 2002b. Empowerment and Poverty Reduction: A Sourcebook. Washington, DC:
World Bank.
———, ed. 2005. Measuring Empowerment: Cross-Disciplinary Perspectives. Washington,
DC: World Bank.
Narayan, D., R. Chambers, M. Shah, and P. Petesch. 2001. Voices of the Poor: Crying Out
for Change. New York: Oxford University Press and the World Bank.
Narayan, D., D. Nikitin, and B. Richard. 2009. “Assets Gained and Lost: Understanding Mobility through Life Stories.” In Moving Out of Poverty: The Promise of
Empowerment and Democracy in India, ed. D. Narayan. New York: Palgrave Macmillan; Washington, DC: World Bank.
Narayan, D., and D. Nyamwaya. 1996. “Learning from the Poor: A Participatory Poverty Assessment in Kenya.” Environment Department Paper 34, Social Policy and
Resettlement Division, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Narayan, D., R. Patel, K. Schafft, A. Rademacher, and S. Koch-Schulte. 2000. Voices of
the Poor: Can Anyone Hear Us? New York: Oxford University Press and the World
Bank.
Narayan, D., and P. Petesch. 2002. Voices of the Poor: From Many Lands. New York:
Oxford University Press and the World Bank.
Narayan, D., and P. Petesch, eds. 2007. Moving Out of Poverty: Cross-Disciplinary Perspectives on Mobility. New York: Palgrave Macmillan; Washington, DC: World Bank.
Narayan, D., P. Petesch, and S. Paul. 2009. “Communities Where Poor People Prosper.” In Moving Out of Poverty: The Promise of Empowerment and Democracy in
India, ed. D. Narayan. New York: Palgrave Macmillan; Washington, DC: World
Bank.
References
407
Narayan, D., and L. Pritchett. 1997. “Cents and Sociability: Household Income and
Social Capital in Rural Tanzania.” Policy Research Working Paper 1796, World
Bank, Washington, DC.
North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
Nussbaum, M. 2000. Women and Human Development: The Capabilities Approach. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
O’Brien, D. J., J. L. Phillips, and V. V. Patsiorkovsky. 2005. “Linking Indigenous Bonding and Bridging Social Capital.” Regional Studies: Journal of the Regional Studies
Association 39 (8): 1041–51.
Olken, B. 2004. “Monitoring Corruption: Evidence from a Field Experiment in
Indonesia.” Working Paper 11753, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Cambridge, MA.
Olson, M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective
Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Ottaway, M., and M. Riley. 2006. “Morocco: From Top-down Reform to Democratic
Transition?” Carnegie Paper 71, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace,
Washington, DC.
Paul, S. 2007. “Citizen Report Cards in Bangalore, India: A Case Study in Accountability.” In Ending Poverty in South Asia: Ideas that Work, ed. D. Narayan and E.
Glinskaya, 347–77. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Petesch, P., C. Smulovitz, and M. Walton. 2005. “Evaluating Empowerment: A
Framework with Cases from Latin America.” In Measuring Empowerment: CrossDisciplinary Perspectives, ed. D. Narayan, 39–67. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Pew Global Attitudes Project. 2007. Global Opinion Trends, 2002–2007: A Rising Tide
Lifts Mood in the Developing World. Washington, DC: Pew Research Center.
Portes, A. 1998. “Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology.”
Annual Review of Sociology 24: 1–24.
Pottier, J. 1988. Migrants No More: Settlement and Survival in Mambwe Villages, Zambia.
Bloomington: Indiana University Press; London: International African Institute.
Powis, B. 2007. “Systems of Capture: Reassessing the Threat of Local Elites.” Social
Development Paper 109, South Asia Series, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Pretes, M. 2002. “Microequity and Microfinance.” World Development 30 (8): 1341–
53.
Pritchett, L., A. Suryahadi, and S. Sumarto. 2000. “Quantifying Vulnerability to
Poverty—A Proposed Measure, with Application to Indonesia.” Development
Economics Working Paper 83, East Asian Bureau of Economic Research, World
Bank, Washington, DC.
Prud’homme, R. 1992. “Informal Local Taxation in Developing Countries.” Government and Policy 10: 1–17.
———. 1995. “The Dangers of Decentralization.” World Bank Research Observer 10 (2):
201–20.
408
Success from the Bottom Up
Przeworski, A., M. Alvarez, J. Cheibub, and F. Limongi. 2000. Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 1950–90. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Putnam, R. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. With Robert
Leonardi and Raffaella Nannetti. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
———. 2007. “E Pluribus Unum: Diversity and Community in the Twenty-first Century.” Scandinavian Political Studies 30 (2): 137–74.
Putterman, L. 1995. “The Role of Ownership and Property Rights in China’s Economic Transition.” China Quarterly 144: 1047–64.
Qian, Y. 2003. “How Reform Worked in China.” In In Search of Prosperity: Analytical
Narratives on Economic Growth, ed. D. Rodrik, 297–333. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Rao, V. 2008. “Symbolic Public Goods and the Coordination of Collective Action: A
Comparison of Local Development in India and Indonesia.” In The Contested
Commons: Conversations between Economists and Anthropologists, ed. P. Bardhan and
I. Ray. Malden, MA: Blackwell.
Rao, V., and M. Walton, eds. 2004a. Culture and Public Action. Stanford, CA: Stanford
University Press.
———. 2004b. “Culture and Public Action: Relationality, Equality of Agency, and
Development.” In Rao and Walton 2004a, 3–36.
Ravallion, M. 1995. “Growth and Poverty: Evidence for Developing Countries in the
1980s.” Economic Letters 48 (July): 411–17.
———. 2001. “Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: Looking Beyond Averages.” World
Development 29 (11): 1803–15.
———. 2004. “Competing Concepts of Inequality in the Globalization Debate.”
Policy Research Working Paper 3243, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Ravallion, M., and S. Chen. 1997. “What Can New Survey Data Tell Us about Recent
Changes in Distribution and Poverty?” World Bank Economic Review 11 (2):
135–52.
———. 2004. “How Have the World’s Poorest Fared Since the Early 1980s?” World
Bank Research Observer 19 (2): 141–70.
Ravallion, M., S. Chen, and P. Sangraula. 2008. “Dollar a Day Revisited.” Policy
Research Working Paper 4620, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Ravallion, M., G. Datt, and D. van de Walle. 1991. “Quantifying Absolute Poverty in
the Developing World.” Review of Income and Wealth 37 (December): 345–61.
Rawls, J. 1993. Political Liberalism. John Dewey Essays in Philosophy, no. 4. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Ray, D. 2006. “Aspirations, Poverty, and Economic Change.” In Understanding Poverty,
ed. A. Banerjee, R. Bénabou, and D. Mookherjee, 409–22. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Reinikka, R., and J. Svensson. 2005. “Fighting Corruption to Improve Schooling: Evidence from a Newspaper Campaign in Uganda.” Journal of the European Economic
Association 3 (2/3): 259–67.
Robeyns, I. 2007. “When Will Society Be Gender Just?” In The Future of Gender, ed.
Jude Browne. New York: Cambridge University Press.
References
409
Roodman, D., and U. Qureshi. 2006. “Microfinance as Business.” Working Paper 101,
Center for Global Development, Washington, DC.
Rowntree, B. S. 1901. Poverty: A Study of Town Life. London.
Rubio, M. 1997. “Perverse Social Capital: Some Evidence from Colombia.” Journal of
Economic Issues 31 (3): 805–16.
Santos, B. D. 1998. “Participative Budgeting in Porto Alegre: Towards a Redistributive
Democracy.” Politics and Society 26 (4): 461–510.
Schattscheiner, E. 1963. Politics, Pressures, and the Tariff. Hamden, CT: Archon Books.
Schulman, B. 1994. From Cotton Belt to Sunbelt: Federal Policy, Economic Development,
and the Transformation of the South, 1938–1980. Durham, NC: Duke University
Press.
Schulze, W., M. Lubatkin, and R. Dino. 2003. “Toward a Theory of Agency and Altruism in Family Firms.” Journal of Business Venturing 18: 473–90.
Scott, J. 1985. Weapons of the Weak: Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance. New Haven,
CT: Yale University Press.
———. 1998. Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition
Have Failed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Seabright, P. 1996. “Accountability and Decentralization in Government: An Incomplete Contracts Model.” European Economic Review 40: 61–89.
Sen, A. 1985. “Well-Being, Agency, and Freedom: The Dewey Lectures.” Journal of
Philosophy 82 (4): 169–221.
———. 1990. “Gender and Cooperative Conflict.” In Persistent Inequalities: Women
and World Development, ed. Irene Tinker, 123–49. New York: Oxford University
Press.
———. 1992. Inequality Re-examined. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press
———. 1993. “Capability and Well Being.” In The Quality of Life, ed. M. Nussbaum
and A. Sen, 30–53. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.
———. 1999. Development as Freedom. New York: Knopf
Sen, B. 2003. “Drivers of Escape and Descent: Changing Household Fortunes in Bangladesh.” World Development 31 (3): 513–34.
Shah, A., and T. Thompson. 2004. “Fiscal Decentralization in Developing and Transition Economies: Progress, Problems, and the Promise.” Policy Research Working
Paper 3282, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Sisk, T., ed. 2001. Democracy at the Local Level: The International IDEA Handbook on
Participation, Representation, Conflict Management, and Governance. Stockholm:
International IDEA.
Smith, A. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London:
Methuen.
Stewart, F. 2001. “Horizontal Inequalities: A Neglected Dimension of Development.”
CRISE Working Paper 1, Center for Research on Inequality, Human Security, and
Ethnicity, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK.
Stiglitz, J. E. 2005. “The Ethical Economist.” Foreign Affairs, November/December,
129.
Stiglitz, J. E., and A. Weiss. 1981. “Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information.” American Economic Review 71 (3): 393–410.
Tilly, C. 1999. Durable Inequality. Berkeley: University of California Press.
410
Success from the Bottom Up
———. 2006. Why? Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Tommasi, M., and F. Weinschelbaum. 1999. “A Principal-Agent Building Block for the
Study of Decentralization and Integration.” Working Paper, Universidad de San
Andres, Buenos Aires.
Turner, V. 1982. Introduction to Celebration: Studies in Festivity and Ritual, ed. V.
Turner. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution Press.
Van den Berghe, L. A. A., and S. Carchon. 2003. “Agency Relations within the Family
Business System: An Exploratory Approach.” Corporate Governance: An International Review 11 (3): 171–79.
Varshney, A. 2005. “Democracy and Poverty.” In Measuring Empowerment: CrossDisciplinary Perspectives, ed. D. Narayan, 383–401. Washington, DC: World
Bank.
———. 2007. “India’s Democratic Challenge.” Foreign Affairs, March/April.
Vollmann, W. T. 2007. Poor People. New York: Ecco.
Ward, J. L. 1987. Keeping the Family Business Healthy: How to Plan for Continuous
Growth, Profitability, and Family Leadership. San Francisco: Jossey Bass.
Weber, M. 1947. The Theory of Social and Economic Organization. Trans. A. M. Henderson and T. Parsons. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
———. 1968. Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology. New York: Bedminster Press.
Winters, A., and S. Yusuf. 2007. Dancing with Giants: China, India, and the Global
Economy. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Withey, S. B. 1954. “Reliability of Recall Income.” Public Opinion Quarterly 18 (2):
197–204.
Woolcock, M. 1998. “Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward a Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework.” Theory and Society 27 (2): 151–208.
World Bank. 1990. World Development Report 1990: Poverty. New York: Oxford University Press.
———. 2003. World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for Poor People. New
York: Oxford University Press.
———. 2006. World Development Report 2006: Equity and Development. New York:
Oxford University Press.
———. 2007. Doing Business 2008. Washington, DC: World Bank.
———. 2008. India: Self-Help Groups, Savings Mobilization, and Access to Finance. New
Delhi: World Bank.
Wright, G. 1974. “The Political Economy of New Deal Spending: An Econometric
Analysis.” Review of Economics and Statistics 56 (1): 30–38.
Yilmaz, S., Y. Beris, and R. Berthet. 2008. “Local Government Discretion and Accountability: A Diagnostic Framework for Local Governance.” Social Development
Paper 113, Local Governance and Accountability Series, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Zhuravskaya, E. 2000. “Incentives to Provide Local Public Goods: Fiscal Federalism,
Russian Style.” Journal of Public Economics 76 (3): 337–68.
Index
Boxes, figures, notes, and tables are denoted by b, f, n, and t, following the page numbers.
A
absolute poverty, estimates of, 98
access to markets. See market access
accountability, 276n4, 324, 331n23.
See also elections and electoral
accountability
Afghanistan
aspirations in, 22, 54, 55, 154, 155
community engagement in, 82
democracy
local democratic structure in, 233
views on, 229–30, 231
destiny or luck in, 68
elections in, 260
ethnicity in, 252
gender discrimination in, 293
gender equality in, 232
government rules and regulations in,
244
hard work as way out of poverty in,
58, 60–61, 60–61t
health shocks in, 166, 170
market access in, 196, 203
migration of families in, 288, 289b
mobility and power in, 144, 159
overpopulation, effect on families in,
292
politicians in, 254, 259
site of study, 9
sources of power in, 139, 251, 254
water resources in, 206
women in
freedom of movement of, 81, 294
widowhood, 291
Africa. See also individual countries
aspirations in, 54, 55
collective action in, 84
community forests in, 199
corruption in, 246
fallers in, 99, 107
freedoms valued in, 81
friendships and collective action in,
299
government and donor aid in, 141
hard work valued in, 58
kinship in, 292
less hierarchical structures in, effect
of, 178n5
morality in, 138, 144
quantifying personal agency in,
145–46, 146f
responsive local democracies in, 240
study sites in, 9
agency
on collective level, 115–16
factors facilitating or hindering, 145,
159–70, 173b, 174–77t
assets and education, 159–62
death and illness, 164–70
political connections, 162–64
importance of, 41, 130, 339
on individual level, 115
for moving out of poverty, 46, 46f,
129–30, 178n1
power and mobility linked to, 26–30,
144–52, 151f, 339–40
quantifying personal agency,
145–49
agriculture
as choice of occupation by children,
157–58
credit availability and, 213
digging societies, 304
as family enterprise, 285–87
Internet access to market prices for,
220
market access and, 196
moving out of poverty through,
59–60, 59f, 68, 188
technical support and inputs for,
208–9
AIDS. See HIV/AIDS
411
412
Index
alcohol abuse. See drug and alcohol
abuse
Alderman, H., 329n3
Alesina, A., 58
Andhra Pradesh (India)
aspirations in, 22, 55, 158–59
bad character as cause of poverty in,
75
collective action in, effectiveness of,
305
community engagement in, 83, 326
comparison of communities in,
119–21
corruption in, 244, 247
credit availability in, 211–12, 213,
302
democracy, views on, 231–32
destiny or luck in, 68
economic opportunities in, 270
education’s importance in, 162
family-related opportunities in, 285
family wealth in, 251
festivals in, 83–84
gender discrimination in, 293, 294,
322
government distribution of goods in,
241
ladder of life sample from, 12,
14–15t, 17
microcredit organizations in,
313–14
politicians in, 255
poverty dynamics in, 99
“power with” in, 134
sources of power in, 254
study site, 9
women’s self-help movement in,
39–40, 171, 264, 265, 322
anxiety of the poor, 57
Appadurai, A., 155
Arrow, K. J., 296
aspirations, 54–57
capacity to aspire, 46, 46f, 131,
153–59, 155f
for children’s future, 22, 54–56, 55f,
56f, 154–55
health shocks and households with
lower aspirations for their
children, 168, 170, 170f
of youth, 131, 156–59, 156t
Assam (India)
aspirations in, 157
bad character as cause of poverty in, 75
“bad power” in, 139
collective action to improve physical
infrastructure in, 323
crowding out among poor in fight
over limited goods in, 241
disabled persons in, 69, 72
economic opportunities in, 270
family’s importance in, 82–83, 285
freedom as value in, 77
guerrilla factions in, 326
hard work as way out of poverty in,
58–59
health shocks in, 166
land ownership in, 214–15
location as factor in economic
opportunities in, 221n4
mobility in, 144, 152
participation in democracy in, 264
“power to” in, 133
responsive local democracies in, 240
roads in, 202, 236
self-confidence and mobility in, 28
sources of power in, 140, 250
study site, 9
assets and savings
families’ role in asset accumulation,
39, 40f, 291
inheritance, 65, 66f, 68, 212, 251, 291
initiative taking and, 65–66
on ladder of life, 17
moving out of poverty and, 152,
159–62, 161f
savings and credit associations, 301–2,
302f, 303f, 330n11
success and redistribution of, 144
Association of Kilimanjaro Specialty
Coffee Growers, 309
Axelrod, R., 329n6
B
Backward Classes Commission (India),
278n20
bad behavior as cause of poverty, 52–54,
72–76
Baht Village Fund (Thailand), 238
Bahujan Samaj Party (India), 252
Bandura, Albert, 145
Index
Banfield, E., 296
Bangladesh
agricultural improvements in, 209
aspirations in, 22, 54, 55, 153, 158
changes in women, effect on men in,
134, 135–36b
collective action in, effectiveness of,
305
community engagement in, 85
corruption in, 246, 248
credit availability in, 209, 210,
213–14, 302
crowding out among poor in fight
over limited goods in, 241
democracy, views on, 229, 247
elite capture in, 249, 256
equal opportunity in, 32–33
families in, 283
festivals in, 84
freedom as value in, 77
“good power” in, 138
inequalities in power in, 140, 141
initiative and opportunity in, 64–65
joining political party in, 253
microfinance organizations in, 134,
313, 315. See also Grameen Bank
migration and remittances, effect of,
287
mobility in, 152
overpopulation, effect on families in,
292
personal agency’s effectiveness in, 130
political connections in, 162
politicians in, 256
poverty reduction in, 102
“power with” in, 133, 134
responsive local democracies in, 239
rich keeping poor down in, 144,
306–7
roads in, 201, 202
self-confidence and mobility in,
28–29
site of study, 9
sources of power in, 139, 251
telephone access in, 207–8
women in, 134, 135–36b, 158, 171,
178n5, 294, 322
Bardhan, P., 259, 278n19
Barron, P., 331n18
Bebbington, A., 329n8
413
behavioral characteristics of households,
18
Besley, T., 261, 279n27
Bhatt, Ela, 221n6
Binswanger, Hans, 316
Booth, Charles, 72–73, 103b
border location. See location as factor in
economic opportunities
Boudon, R., 178n7
bribes. See corruption
The Burden of Democracy (Mehta), 257
bureaucratic high modernism, 335
Burgess, R., 261
burial societies, 45, 84, 302–4, 330n12
business know-how, importance of, 33
business licensing, 199, 216–18
C
Cambodia
aspirations in, 57
assets’ importance in, 160
“bad power” in, 138
corruption in, 244
domestic violence in, 294
drug addiction in, 75
education’s importance in, 162
elections in, 260–61
families in, 283
forest lands, access to, 199
government rules and regulations in,
243
hard work as way out of poverty in,
61–62
participation in democracy in, 264
politicians in, 258
power of rich in, 189–92
“power to” in, 132–33
roads in, 202
site of study, 9
sources of power in, 139
widowhood in, 69
capitalism, 318
Carter, M. R., 98
castes. See socially stratified
communities
causes of poverty, 51–85, 334
bad behavior on part of poor, 52–54,
72–76
destiny, 62, 68–72, 70–71f
inequality, 52
414
Index
CDD (community-driven development),
315–17, 328
cell phones and economic
opportunities, 207–8
Chambers, Robert, 43
change over time, 8. See also mobility
Chen, S., 183
children’s future, aspirations for, 22,
54–56, 55f, 56f, 154–55
China
cultural values of, 54
family businesses in, 296
leaders’ role in economic
transformation in, 272
poverty line in, 103b
poverty reduction in, 183–84, 219–20
choice, freedom of, 77–78, 78b
chronic poor
aspirations of, 54, 55, 56, 56f, 153,
154f
asset ownership and, 160
children’s aspirations, 157
collective action and, 305
defined, 12
democracy and, 257
estimates of, 98
factors creating trap of chronic
poverty, 98
families and, 283, 329n2
happiness rating of, 63, 63f
hard work as way out of poverty for,
59–60, 59f
health shocks and, 164, 165f, 169f
initiative taking by, 20, 65, 66t
quantifying personal agency of, 145,
146f, 148f
self-confidence and, 27–28, 27f
Chronic Poverty Research Centre, 98
Circular Structure of Power (Dyberg),
145
citizenship level and chronic poverty, 98
civil conflicts, 192, 284b, 324, 326
displacement due to. See displaced
households in Colombia
responsive local democracies and,
238, 240
civil liberties. See freedom
civil society organizations. See
nongovernmental organizations
(NGOs)
Clinton Global Initiative, 49n5
coffee market and growers, 38–39,
195–96, 308–9
Cohen, J., 230–31
collective action, 33, 281–331
collective agency, 115–16
community activities and assistance,
43–45, 44f, 301–7
community-driven development
(CDD), 315–17, 328
limitations of poor people’s groups,
301–6
purposes of community groups,
301–2, 302f
rich organizing against poor,
306–7, 329n8
spontaneous groups, 301
cooperation around local public
goods, 318–27, 331nn21–22
accountability, 324
interaction with states, 325–27,
325f
physical environment
improvements, 323
security improvements, 320–23
corporations of poor people, 317–18,
319b
democracy and, 231–32
effectiveness of, 38–41, 44f
for moving out of poverty, 46–47,
46f, 304–6, 305f, 306f, 328
engagement in community, 82–85,
326
external groups, links to, 307–11, 337
family unit. See families
friendships and, 298–99, 300b
literature on, 281–82
low profile of NGOs in, 311–13, 338
microcredit groups, 313–15
scaling up, 311–18, 338
Colombia
aspirations in, 54, 153
“bad power” in, 139
business licensing in, 199
community engagement in, 84, 329n8
corruption in, 164
credit availability in, 212, 302
guerrilla factions in, 140, 326
hard work as way out of poverty in, 60
health shocks in, 170
Index
initiative and opportunity in, 64
location as factor in opportunities in,
188
mobility and power in, 145
“power over” in, 137
“power to” in, 132, 133
“power with” in, 133
problems of scale in, 193, 196–97
quantifying personal agency in,
146–47
self-confidence and mobility in, 29,
63–64
site of study, 9
common resources
cooperation centered around, 318–27,
331nn21–22
management of, 276n9
problems in access to, 199–200
community, engagement in, 82–85, 326.
See also collective action
community analysis, 43–45, 44f
prosperity, 106–9, 108–9f
community mobility matrix (CMM),
12, 13, 24, 89, 90–91f, 100, 106,
149, 337
community organizations, 301–7. See
also collective action
community poverty line (CPL), 12, 17
co-movement of poor and nonpoor,
111–15, 112f, 114f, 122, 123t
conceptual framework of research,
42–48
confidence. See self-confidence
conflict. See civil conflicts
consumption on ladder of life, 17
cooperatives, 307–11
coping with adversity
collective action’s effect, 38–41, 44f,
326–27
families’ role in, 288–90
shocks, effect of, 290–91
Cord, L., 183, 184–85
corporations of poor people, 317–18,
319b
corruption, 34, 36, 42, 164, 191, 201,
245f
business opportunities and, 217–18,
218f, 220
decentralization and, 277n15
in local governance, 244–47
415
mobility and, 247–49, 248f
movers and, 277n17
rate of services and, 277n16
credit. See also microcredit groups
community groups formed for
purpose of providing, 301–2,
302f, 303f
economic opportunities and, 209–14,
210f, 211f, 220
land ownership and, 215
needs of poor people and, 33, 301,
313, 330n15
cultural values and poverty, 53–54
Culture Matters (Harrison & Huntingon,
eds.), 53
culture of poverty, 18–23, 52, 53–54
D
Dalits, 252, 278n20
data analyses, 42–48, 334
household mobility and, 149–52,
151f
leave-out mean in, 241
local responsive democracies and,
238–40, 239f
regression results tables for MOP and
MPI, 388–98
weight for PCA-constructed indexes,
by region, 380–86
data collection methods, 10–11, 42, 333,
370–73. See also community
mobility matrix (CMM); ladder
of life; sites of study
Datt, G., 103b
death. See health shocks, effect of
decision making
at community level, 226, 260, 263,
265
participation in, 47, 119, 140, 223,
224. See also democracy
personal agency and daily decision
making, 145, 147, 151, 152
health shocks and, 168
women excluded from. See
discrimination
Deininger, K., 183
democracy
deliberative vs. representative,
230–32, 277n10
effectiveness of, 226–29, 242–56
416
Index
democracy (continued)
elections. See elections and electoral
accountability
freedom as intrinsic value, 77–81,
78–79b, 224, 226–27
hunger for freedom, 76–81
leadership, importance of, 258–59
meaning of democracy to the poor,
229–32, 230t, 256–65
participation in, 262–64
responsive local democracies, 33–38,
35f, 42, 115, 232–41, 340
change from elite capture, 256–65
community outcomes and, 234–36,
235f, 237f
factors associated with, 273b,
274–75t
individual outcomes and, 236–40,
239f
negative spillovers from, 241, 242f
new roles for, 271–72
policy makers and, 272
positive spillovers from, 269–71, 270t
tradeoffs of, 240–41, 242f
types of, 228
Dercon, S., 100, 330n12
destiny, 62, 68–72, 70–71f
destruction of property due to jealousy,
143
Development as Freedom (Sen), 227
digging societies, 304
dignity and respect, freedom to live
with, 78b, 80, 226–27
Dino, R., 329n7
Diprose, R., 331n18
disabled persons, 69, 312
disaster recovery, 84–85. See also shocks,
effect of
discrimination
chronic poverty and, 98
ethnicity and, 252
lack of opportunities and, 268–69
rules and regulations discriminating
against poor, 243
against women, 47, 293–95, 322,
329nn4–5
displaced households in Colombia, 60,
63, 84, 128–29, 133, 146–47,
153, 188, 212
displacement of workers, 60
Di Tella, R., 249
divorce and separation, effect of, 69,
290–91, 293
Doing Business report (World Bank), 199
$1 a day standard for poverty line, 13,
102, 103b, 104–5, 104f
domestic violence, 74, 81, 265, 294–95,
322–23
donor aid, inequal access to, 141
drug and alcohol abuse
domestic violence and alcohol, 265,
322
as reason for fall, 21, 21f, 74
as reason for poverty, 72, 73–75
Durable Inequality (Tilly), 178n4
Dyrberg, T. B., 145
E
East Asia. See also individual countries
elections in, 260
electricity in, 207
investment in assets in, 160
miracle growth in, 227
study sites in, 9
East India Company, 76
e-choupals (India), 220
economic growth on national level
correlation with poverty reduction,
47, 182–86, 184f, 227, 336–37
suppression of human freedoms and,
227
economic opportunities
credit availability and, 209–14, 210f,
211f, 220
expansion of
effect of, 266–68, 269–71, 270t
ways to promote, 201–18
family and, 285–87
government rules and regulations,
effect of, 198–201, 220, 242–44
influence, effect of lack of, 194–95
infrastructure, creation to enhance,
205–9
local context and, 115, 186–89
policy recommendations for, 218–20
poor economic opportunity and
chronic poverty, 99
power of rich and, 189–92
problems of scale and, 193–98, 219
roads and, 201–3, 219, 236
Index
economic remoteness, effect of, 186–89
education
community groups formed to provide,
302, 302f
democracy and, 229
family sacrifice to educate children,
284b
of household head and children, 17
importance of, 57
improvements in due to more
responsive local governance, 235,
235t
personal agency and, 159–62
women and, 294
youth aspirations and, 158
elections and electoral accountability,
47, 223, 228, 259–61, 278n21
electricity and economic opportunities,
207, 234
elite capture, 37, 249–53, 278nn18–19,
329n8
empowerment, 26–30, 62–64, 127–79,
279n28. See also agency;
aspirations; power
moving out of poverty and, 46, 46f,
152
England. See Victorian view of the poor
equal opportunity, 30–33, 181–221. See
also economic opportunities
business licensing and, 214–18
infrastructure creation for, 205–9
land titling and, 214–18
location as factor, 186–89, 219, 221n4
market access and, 189–201, 203–4,
219–20, 340
national economic growth and,
182–86
policy recommendations for, 218–20
roads, building of, 201–3, 219
equity financing, 318, 319b
ethnicity, 252, 329nn8–9. See also
socially stratified communities
Europe, mobility out of poverty in, 58
Evolution of Cooperation (Axelrod), 329n6
exclusion and social bonding, 329nn8–9
F
Fabindia (Indian company), 319b
failed institutions, trying to cope with,
327, 328
417
fallers
aspirations of, 56, 56f
asset ownership and, 160
defined, 13
families and, 283, 329n2
happiness rating of, 63, 63f
health shocks and, 164, 165f, 169f
initiative taking by, 65, 66t
power of rich and, 190
quantifying personal agency of, 147,
147f
reasons for falling, 3, 21, 21f, 48n4,
57, 74, 76
self-confidence of, 27, 27f, 63
sense of power and, 152
families, 282–98, 327
asset accumulation and, 39, 40f, 251,
290
inherited wealth and power, 65,
66f, 68, 212, 251, 291
breakups of, effect of, 290–91, 329n3
as burden, 291–93
collective action and, 282–98
coping with adversity and, 288–90
elite capture and, 251
engagement in, 82–85
gender discrimination in, 293–95,
329nn4–5
hierarchies of power in, 134, 137
markers of successful family collective
action, 295–98, 297t, 329nn8–9
pooled economic activities of,
285–87, 329n7
“power with” of, 133
trust, loyalty, love, and sacrifice of,
283–85
violence in, 293–95
fear, freedom from, 78–79b, 80
festivals, importance of, 83–84
Fields, Debbie, 317
Fields, G. S., 183
Financiera Compartamos (Latin
American microlender), 319b
findings, 18–42
collective action’s effect, 38–41, 44f
culture of poverty, 18–23
equal opportunity, 30–33
lessons from poor people, 41–42, 333
“poverty is a condition, not a
characteristic,” 22, 23–26, 87–121
418
Index
findings (continued)
power, 26–30
responsive local democracies, 33–38,
35f, 42
Five Families (Lewis), 333
focus group discussion
data collection methods, 10, 88
definition of poverty used by, 16–17
ladder of life constructed by. See
ladder of life
forest lands, access to, 199–200
freedom, 77–81. See also democracy
of choice, 77–78, 78b
for economic opportunity, 81
of expression and worship, 229, 231
from fear and oppression, 78–79b,
80, 229
to live with dignity and respect, 78b,
80, 226–27
of mind, 77, 78b
of movement, 79b, 80
Freire, Paulo, 262
friendships and collective action,
298–99, 300b
Fukuyama, F., 296
funeral groups. See burial societies
Fung, A., 277n10
G
Galbraith, J. K., 131
gambling as reason for fall, 21, 21f, 74
gangs, 140
gender differences. See women
gender discrimination. See
discrimination
Ghana’s values contrasted with South
Korea’s, 53
Gladwell, Malcolm, 202
Glaeser, E., 58
globalization, 101
governance, 223–79. See also democracy
community organizations and selfhelp groups, 264–65
corruption. See corruption
elections. See elections and electoral
accountability
information and, 261–62
participation in, 241, 262–64
rules and regulations, effect on
economic opportunities, 198–
201, 220, 242–44
supporting programs to provide safety
nets to the poor, 337
Governing the Commons (Ostrom), 318
government aid, inequal access to, 141
Grameen Bank (Bangladesh), 39, 65,
264, 313, 314–15, 319b, 331n16
Gugerty, M. K., 330n11
Gupta, Dipankar, 276n8
H
Hammer, J., 331n22
happiness, 63, 63f
hard work as way out of poverty, 20,
57–62, 59f, 60–61t, 279n29
Harrison, Lawrence, 53
Hassan II, King of Morocco, 225
health services
community groups formed to provide,
302, 302f
improvements due to more responsive
local governance, 235, 235t
health shocks, effect of, 29, 57, 172,
179n10
bad luck and, 68–69
households with lower aspirations
for their children and, 168, 170,
170f
personal agency and, 164–70
Heyer, J., 331n21
hierarchy of needs for the poor, 227
Hirschman, A. O., 144
HIV/AIDS, 75, 166, 167, 168
Hoff, K., 145, 330n9
home ownership, 160, 161f
household dynamics, 89–92, 90–91f
implications of poverty dynamics,
100–102
on ladder of life, 92–95, 93t, 94f,
96f
power and personal agency linked to,
149–52, 151f
household surveys
household regressions and, 349–67,
376–78
interviews as data collection methods,
10
limitations of, 87–88, 106, 124nn1–2
poverty mapping linking survey data
to census data, 125n11
Hunt, J., 277n16
Huntington, Samuel P., 53
Index
I
Ikegami, M., 98
illness. See health shocks, effect of
India. See also Andhra Pradesh; Assam;
Uttar Pradesh; West Bengal
British rule in, 76
business licensing in, 199, 217
castes in, 25–26, 119–20, 252, 276n8,
278n20, 278n22, 322–23,
329–30n9
co-movement of poor and nonpoor
in, 113
Constitution of, 278n22
crowding out among poor in fight
over limited goods in, 241
cultural values of, 54
democracy in, 226–27, 233, 257,
276n2, 279n27
economic growth of, 227
hard work as way out of poverty in,
58–59
health shocks in, 179n10
identity labels in, 145
information access in, 261
initiative taking by poor in, 20, 65,
66f
Internet access to market prices for
crops in, 220
location as factor in opportunities in,
188
management of common property in,
276n9
mass poverty in, 22
measures of well-being dynamics
associated with local factors in,
116–18, 117t
mobility in, assets associated with,
160
poverty line in, 103b
responsive local democracies in, 239,
240, 258
roads in, 203
site of study, 9
Indira Vikas Yojna (India), 236
individual voices and data collection
methods, 10, 48n1, 333
Indonesia
aspirations in, 56
attitudes of the poor in, 19
community-driven development
program in, 40, 315, 316
419
corruption in, 248–49
credit availability in, 209, 331n17
democracy, views on, 229, 230, 231
economic growth of, 227
education’s importance in, 162
elections in, 261
elite capture in, 329n8
families in, 283–84
freedom for economic opportunity
in, 81
friendships and collective action in,
299
government distribution of goods in,
241
government jobs in, 200
government participation in, 241
hard work as way out of poverty in,
57, 59
household dynamics in, 92
jealousy in, 142, 143
mobility in, 152
politicians in, 254
poverty dynamics in, 100
“power with” in, 133
responsive local democracies in, 238
security and defense groups in, 322
self-confidence and mobility in, 28,
62
site of study, 9
voluntary communal work in, 276n9
Industrial Revolution, 19, 227
inequality. See also discrimination
acceptance of, 29
access to economic opportunities and,
115, 270–71
categorical inequalities, 178n4
“durable inequality” and social
stratification, 47, 120
national growth rate and, 183–85
in power, 140–42
influence, effect of lack of, 194–95
information, power of, 261–62, 331n23
infrastructure and economic
opportunities, 205–9, 235–36,
323
inheritance. See assets and savings
initiative and opportunity for moving
out of poverty, 19–20, 20f,
45–48, 46f, 64–68, 66f, 66t,
67f, 336. See also economic
opportunities
420
Index
insecurity and chronic poverty, 98
“invisible hand” theory and market
access, 192–201
Isham, J., 331n22
Italy, family interests in, 296
ITC, 220
J
Jalan, J., 101
Janmabhoomi program (India), 119,
125n15, 326
jealousy of other’s gains, 130, 142–44,
240
Johnston, D., 330n15, 331n17
justice, 230, 232
K
Kaiser Family Foundation survey on
causes of poverty, 73
Kanbur, R., 101
Karelis, Charles, 19
Kashmir, migration to, 289b
Kaufman, A., 277n10
Kecamatan Development Program
(Indonesia), 209, 313, 316,
331n18
Keefer, P., 278n21, 325
Kennedy School of Government
survey on causes of poverty,
73
Kenya, savings and credit associations
in, 330n11
Khandker, S. R., 331n16
Kipling, Rudyard, 76–77
Knack, S., 279n28, 325, 331n22
Kraay, A., 183
Krishna, P., 100
Kynch, J., 329n4
L
ladder of life
community mobility matrix. See
community mobility matrix
(CMM)
data collection methods, 10, 12–13,
48n3, 88, 124n3
household dynamics on, 92–95, 93t,
94f, 96f, 124n4
samples from Andhra Pradesh and
Uganda, 14–15t
land
government program giving land to
the poor, 236
importance of in moving out of
poverty, 160
reform and titling of, 214–18, 215f
Latin America. See also individual
countries
aspirations in, 54
NGOs in, 330n14
social solidarity and mobility in,
330n10
study sites in, 9
law and order, 236, 237f
community policing, 321b
leadership
in democracy, 258–59
moral leadership, 138, 254–55
lessons from poor people, 41–42, 333
Lewis, Oscar, 19, 53, 333
liberalization, need for, 33, 37, 219
licensing. See business licensing
Lijjat Papad (Indian company),
317–18
local context
agency and, 115–16
democracy and, 33–38, 35f, 42, 115.
See also democracy
differences among communities, 25,
116, 118–21
economic opportunities and, 115,
186–89
importance of, 8, 42, 47, 88, 105–15,
333
pseudonyms used to protect
identities, 48n1
public works projects and local
prosperity, 216, 216f
location as factor in economic
opportunities, 186–89, 219,
221n4
Lok Capital, 331n20
Loury, G., 329n9
Lubatkin, M., 329n7
luck’s role in moving up, 67f, 68–72
Lukes, S., 130, 131–32
M
Macaulay, Lord, 76
MacCulloch, R., 249
Index
Malawi
attitudes of the poor in, 19
“bad power” in, 138
community engagement in, 84
credit availability in, 213
crowding out among poor in fight
over limited goods in, 241
democracy, views on, 229, 230t
distrust in, 307
elections in, 259, 260
elite capture in, 249–50
equal opportunity in, 32
forest lands, access to, 200
freedom for economic opportunity
in, 81
gender discrimination in, 295
government distribution schemes in,
200
hard work as way out of poverty in, 58
health shocks in, 164, 165–66, 167
HIV/AIDS in, 75
household dynamics in, 92
infrastructure improvements in, 323
initiative and opportunity in, 64
jealousy in, 143
livelihood clubs in, 310–11
location as factor in opportunities in,
186
market access in, 197–98
mass poverty in, 22
movers in, 25
NGOs in, 312
overpopulation, effect on families in,
291
politicians in, 254
poverty dynamics in, 99
“power over” in, 134
responsive democracy in, 36
security and defense in, 234, 321b
site of study, 9
sources of power in, 254
women in, 81, 310–11
Malawi Council for the Handicapped,
312
Malkapur. See Andhra Pradesh (India)
Manifest Destiny, 77
market access
as engine of change, 203–4
equal opportunity and, 141, 189–92,
219–20
421
“invisible hand” theory and, 192–201
roads, need for, 33, 201–3, 219, 236
transformation to allow poor people
access, 42, 340
Marshall, Alfred, 1, 73, 204
Marxism and the poor, 19, 52
Mayhew, Henry, 62, 72
Mehta, Pratap Bhanu, 257, 276n3
metaphors to describe lives of poor, 142
methods of study, 7–11. See also
community mobility matrix
(CMM); ladder of life
conceptual framework of research,
42–48
data collection methods, 10–11, 42,
333, 370–73
sites, 9
study participants, 48n1
Mexico
collective action in, effectiveness of,
305, 323
corruption in, 248
education’s importance in, 162
electricity in, 207
family-related opportunities in, 285
family’s importance in, 82, 282, 333
freedom as value in, 80
hard work as way out of poverty in,
58, 62
health shocks in, 164
location as factor in opportunities in,
186
migration from, 287, 288t
participation in democracy in, 263
prosperity in, 107, 125n13
site of study, 9
women in
abuse of, 81
local democracies and, 265
restrictions on, 294
widowhood, 69
Michnik, Adam, 272
microcredit groups, 33, 134, 171,
313–15, 328, 331n16, 331n20,
340
microequity, 318, 319b
middle-income countries and poverty
line, 103b
migration and remittances, 83, 286–87,
288t, 289b
422
Index
military service as desirable occupation,
158
mind, freedom of, 77, 78b
mobile banking, 208
mobility
across communities within regions,
109–11, 110f. See also community
mobility matrix (CMM)
aspirations correlated with. See
aspirations
categories, 12–13, 337. See also
chronic poor; fallers; movers;
never poor
collective action’s effect on, 46–47,
46f, 304–6, 305f, 306f, 328
co-movement of poor and nonpoor,
111–15, 112f, 114f, 122, 123t
corruption and, 247–49, 248f
in European countries vs. in U.S., 58
freedom of geographic movement,
79b, 80
household dynamics, 89–92, 90–91f
implications of poverty dynamics,
100–102
on ladder of life, 92–95, 93t, 94f,
96f
power and personal agency linked
to, 149–52, 151f
measures of well-being dynamics
associated with local factors in,
116–18, 117t
poverty dynamics, 95–100, 97t
power and personal agency linked to,
26–30, 144–52, 151f, 339–40
Mohammed VI (Morocco), 225
money as source of power, 139–40,
189–92, 251, 254
Mookherjee, D., 259, 278n19
Moral Basis of a Backward Society
(Banfield), 296
moral character, 59
“good power” and, 137–38, 254–55
moral codes, 138
Morduch, J., 330n15, 331n17
Morocco
aspirations in, 57
bad behavior as cause of poverty in, 72
business licensing in, 216–17
cooperatives in, 307–8, 309–10
credit availability in, 212
democracy, views on, 232, 256
domestic violence in, 294
drug abuse in, 75
elections in, 260
families in, 285
festivals in, 84
hard work as way out of poverty in, 60
information access in, 261, 262
infrastructure and economic
opportunities in, 205
politics and governance in, 225–26
“power over” in, 134
site of study, 9
women in, 291
Mosse, D., 276n9
movers
aspirations of, 56, 56f, 153, 154f
asset ownership and, 160
collective action and, 305
corruption and, 277n17
defined, 12
families and, 283
happiness rating of, 63, 63f
health shocks and, 164, 165f, 168,
169f
initiative taking by, 3, 19–20, 20f, 65,
66t
luck and, 68
poverty as characteristic disproven
by, 26
predicted number of, 48n4
quantifying personal agency of, 145,
146f, 147, 148f
self-confidence and, 27, 27f
self-eulogies of, 148–49
Mrs. Fields Cookies, 317
mutual aid societies, 84
mutual help, success of efforts, 39
N
Narayan, Deepa, 316, 325, 330n10,
331n22
NASFAM (National Smallholder
Farmers’ Association of Malawi),
312
national economic growth’s influence
on poverty reduction, 47,
182–86, 184f, 336–37
National Public Radio survey on causes
of poverty, 73
National Solidarity Program
(Afghanistan), 260, 279n25, 326
Index
never poor
aspirations of, 56, 56f
asset ownership and, 160
corruption and, 244
defined, 13
destiny or luck of, 68
families and, 283
happiness rating of, 63, 63f
health shocks and, 169f
initiative taking by, 65, 66t
quantifying personal agency of, 147f
self-confidence and, 27, 27f
nonagricultural initiatives and moving
out of poverty, 68
nongovernmental organizations (NGOs)
coffee growers and, 308–9
critical roles played by, 330n14
loans from, 213
low profile in supporting collective
activities, 311–13, 338
partnerships with, 49n5, 264
poor people’s view of, 40, 311–13
North, D. C., 325
nursing career choice, 158
Nyamwaya, D., 330n10
O
O’Brien, D. J., 329n8
occupations
aspired to by youth, 156–59, 156t
land ownership and, 17
opportunity. See economic
opportunities; initiative and
opportunity for moving out of
poverty
optimism. See aspirations
Ostrom, Elinor, 318
overpopulation, effect on families,
291–93
Oxfam, 312
P
Pande, R., 279n27
Pandey, P., 145, 330n9
Patsiorkovsky, V. V., 329n8
Paul, S., 279n26
The Persistence of Poverty (Karelis), 73
Peru, corruption in, 277n16
Pew Global Attitudes Project, 55
philanthropy and poorest of the poor,
338
423
Philippines
aspirations in, 54, 153
attitudes of the poor in, 19
“bad power” in, 138–39
business licensing in, 199
credit availability in, 214
democracy, views on, 231
education’s importance in, 162, 284b
electricity in, 207
freedom as value in, 77–78, 79
friendships and collective action in, 298
government distribution of goods in,
241
guerrilla factions in, 326
health shocks in, 168
inequality in power in, 141
infrastructure and economic
opportunities in, 205
NGOs, role in, 311, 312
political connections in, 163, 164
politicians in, 254–55
poverty dynamics in, 99
resilience in, 193
responsive local democracies in, 35,
238, 240, 325
security and defense groups in, 322
site of study, 9
sources of power in, 139, 140
U.S. rule over, 77
Phillips, J. L., 329n8
physical coercion, 140, 255–56
police, 191
Political Liberalism (Rawls), 276n1
politics, 37, 223–79. See also governance
becoming a politician, 253–56
community groups formed around,
302, 302f
corruption. See corruption
economic opportunity and, 48
elections. See elections and electoral
accountability
good deeds and reputation and,
254–55
importance of political connections,
162–64, 163f, 224–25, 246–47
joining political party, 252–53
ladder of power and, 30
local level. See local context
muscle power and, 255–56
resistance to political participation by
poor, 142
424
Index
politics (continued)
veneration of politicians, 247
wealth and, 254
Poor People (Vollmann), 62
poppy cultivation in Afghanistan, 244
Portes, A., 329n9
poverty, definition and scope of, 11–18,
334–36
causes of poverty. See causes of
poverty
culture of poverty, 18–23, 52, 53–54
households classified in 2005 as poor,
16f
lessons from poor people, 41–42, 333
mobility and. See mobility
as moral and physical condition, 73,
76, 334
political and market forces framing,
335
poverty gap, 124n5
“poverty is a condition, not a
characteristic,” 22, 23–26,
87–121, 334, 336
poverty lines and people’s perception
of, 102–5, 103b, 104f
“problem of the many, not the few,”
13–18, 85, 102–3, 336
realities of, 3, 7, 76, 334–36
as social construct, 51, 334
subjective vs. objective definitions, 105
poverty assessments, 22
power, 131–44
“bad power,” 138
defined, 131
“good power,” 137–38, 254–55
inequalities in, 140–42
information as, 261–62
personal agency and mobility linked
to, 26–30, 144–52, 151f, 339–40
“power over,” 130, 131–32, 132t,
134–37
“power to,” 130, 131, 132–33, 132t
“power with,” 130, 131, 132t, 133–34
resistance to, 142
social science literature on, 178n3
sources of, 139–40, 250–53
types of, 131–32, 132t
Principles of Economics (Marshall), 73,
204
principles of study, 7–8
Pritchett, L., 100, 331n22
prosperity, 106–9, 108–9f
Prud’homme, R., 277n15
public goods. See common resources
public works projects and local
prosperity, 216, 216f
Puerto Ricans, Lewis’ study of, 53
purchasing power parities (PPPs), 103b,
125n10
Putnam, R., 296, 307, 331n22
Q
Qureshi, U., 315
R
Rao, V., 276n9, 279n27
Ravallion, M., 101, 103b, 183
Rawls, John, 276n1
redistributive programs, 22–23
Reinikka, R., 261–62
remittances sent home by migrants, 83,
286–87
repression, 138
resistance to power, 142
respect
freedom to live with, 78b, 80
mobility creating, 148
responsive local democracies. See
democracy
rich people. See also elite capture
in collective action with poor people,
47
money as source of power, 139–40,
189–92, 251, 254
organizing and working against poor,
144, 306–7, 329n8
power over poor, 141
roads, building of, 33, 201–3, 219, 236,
237f
Robeyns, I., 329n5
Roodman, D., 315
Root Capital, 331n20
Rothschild, M., 144
Rowntree, Benjamin Seebohm, 103b
Rubio, M., 329n8
Russia
allocation of resources in, 277n15
elite capture in, 329n8
S
Sabel, C., 230–31
sabotage of public property, 143
Index
Sacerdote, B., 58
sarcasm as form of resistance, 142
Sarkozy, Nicolas, 50
Save the Children, 312
savings. See assets and savings
Schattscheiner, E., 278n18
Schulze, W., 329n7
Scott, J., 142, 335
security and defense, 234, 320. See also
law and order
self-confidence, 22, 26–30, 27f, 46, 62–64,
129–33, 160, 306. See also agency
self-defense groups, 320–23, 321b
self-efficacy, beliefs about, 145
Self Employed Women’s Association
(India), 221n6
self-help groups, 134, 264–65, 313–15.
See also women
Sen, Amartya, 51, 77, 129–30, 227, 295,
329n4
Senegal
aspirations in, 22, 54, 55, 157
community engagement in, 84
community improvements in, 234–35
corruption in, 164, 248
crowding out among poor in fight
over limited goods in, 241
democracy, views on, 232
destiny’s role in, 68, 70–71f
hard work as way out of poverty in, 58
health shocks in, 164
information access in, 262
politicians in, 258
poverty dynamics in, 99
“power over” in, 134, 137
site of study, 9
women in, 265
sex discrimination. See discrimination
shocks, effect of
community coping with, 330n13
co-movement of poor and nonpoor
and, 113
families coping with, 290–91
health shocks, 29, 57, 68–69
social shocks, 57
sites of study, 9
researchers and institutions involved
(by country), 343–46
Smith, Adam, 51, 75, 192–93
social environment improvements,
320–23
425
socially stratified communities, 25–26,
47, 119–20
collective action reflecting structure
of, 327
distribution of jobs and government
schemes and, 200–201
elite capture and, 251–52, 329n8
equality as part of democracy for, 232
festivals and, 83–84
government taken over by dominant
social groups, 326
Hindu system of castes, 278n20
identity labels, effect of, 145
inability to move out of poverty in,
330n10
participation in elections, 228
power of rich and, 192
women in, 322–23
social shocks, effect of, 57
social status, 18
soil fertility, 39
SOSOTEC (Self-Organizing System on
the Edge of Chaos), 43, 49n6
South Asia. See also individual countries
aspirations in, 54
corruption in, 34, 213, 246
emerging leaders in, 272
family power in, 133
government jobs, desirability in, 246
joining political party in, 253
muscle power in, 255
political connections in, 162, 247, 253
responsive local democracy in, 239f,
241, 249
study sites in, 9
South Korea’s values contrasted with
Ghana’s, 53
spatial disadvantage and chronic
poverty, 98
spontaneous community organizations,
301–7
Squire, L., 183
Sri Lanka
alcoholism in, 74
democracy, views on, 231
ethnicity in, 252
killings of people better off in, 143
migration from, 286
“power to” in, 132, 133
site of study, 9
war, the poor’s anxiety about, 57
426
Index
states and civic cooperation, 325–27,
325f
Stewart, F., 331n21
Stiglitz, Joseph, 182, 337
Sumarto, S., 100
Suryahadi, A., 100
Svensson, J., 261–62
T
Taliban, 229, 289b
Tambon Administrative Organizations
(Thailand), 238, 263
Tanzania
agricultural improvements in, 208
aspirations in, 54
bad behavior as cause of poverty in,
73–74
collective action in, effectiveness of,
305
community-driven development
program in, 316–17
cooperatives in, 308
corruption in, 246, 248
credit availability in, 212
democracy, views on, 233, 271
disabled persons in, 69
divorce and separation, effect of, 69
elections in, 261
elite capture in, 250
equal opportunity in, 32
family’s importance in, 82
forest lands, access to, 200
freedom as value in, 77, 79, 80, 81
friendships and collective action in,
300b
funeral groups in, 302–3
gender discrimination in, 295
“good power” in, 138
government rules and regulations in,
198, 242–44
group membership’s impact on
individual well-being in, 241
hard work as way out of poverty in, 58
health shocks in, 164
HIV/AIDS in, 75
location as factor in opportunities in,
186, 187–88
market access in, 219
nsango groups in, 38–39
poverty dynamics in, 99
“power to” in, 132, 133
prediction of falling in, 26
resistance to political participation
in, 142
roads in, 202, 203
security and defense in, 320
site of study, 9
sources of power in, 254
views on poverty in, 142
water resources in, 206–7
witchcraft in, 143
women in, 141, 265
Tanzania Social Action Fund, 316–17
TechnoServe (Tanzania), 308, 309
telephone access and economic
opportunities, 207–8
Thailand
corruption in, 246
credit availability in, 302
education’s importance in, 162
“good power” in, 138
participation in democracy in, 262,
263
politicians in, 255
responsive local democracies in, 238
site of study, 9
Thorp, R., 331n21
Tilly, Charles, 148–49, 178n4
The Tipping Point (Gladwell), 202
trust
aspirations and, 168
collective action and, 282, 283–85
corporations and, 318
in family, 296
as foundation for participation,
231–32
lack of trust in community, 307, 308,
309, 316
in local governance, 254
mobility and, 188
in officials, 34
rebuilding after civil conflict, 316
workers and, 59
Trust (Fukuyama), 296
tunnel effect, 144
Turner, V., 276n9
U
Uganda
alcoholism of the poor in, 74
aspirations in, 54, 154
burial groups in, 303–4
Index
collective action in, 301, 305
community analysis for Bufkaro,
43–45, 44f
corruption in, 164, 277n16
credit availability in, 213, 301, 302
democracy, views on, 233
elections in, 259
elite capture in, 251
freedom for economic opportunity
in, 81
gender discrimination in, 293–94
“good power” in, 138
hard work as way out of poverty in,
57, 58
health shocks in, 164, 165, 166,
167–68
jealousy in, 143
ladder of life sample from, 12,
14–15t, 16, 17
mobility in, 152
politicians in, 255, 258
“power over” in, 134
resistance to political participation
in, 142
responsive local democracies in, 238
roads in, 236
sabotage of public property in, 143
self-confidence and mobility in, 28
site of study, 9
United States
elite capture in, 278n19
family-owned enterprises in, 329n7
Manifest Destiny doctrine in, 77
mobility in European countries vs.,
58
Philippines, rule over, 77
social bonding and exclusion in,
329n9
tax rates and social spending in, 58
women-owned corporations in, 317
Universal Declaration of Human Rights,
77
Uttar Pradesh (India)
agricultural improvements in, 209
aspirations in, 54
“bad power” in, 138
business licensing in, 217
castes in, 252, 278n20
collective action in, effectiveness of,
305
community improvements in, 236
427
community mobility matrix from, 89,
90–91f
corruption in, 245–46, 248
crowding out among poor in fight
over limited goods in, 241
democracy, views on, 230
destiny or luck in, 68
divorce and separation, effect of, 293
economic opportunities in, 270
elections in, 260
elite capture in, 252
family’s importance in, 83, 290
freedom as value in, 80
government rules and regulations in,
243
hard work as way out of poverty in, 57
health shocks in, 167, 168
market access in, 204
mobility in, 152
muscle power in, 255
overpopulation, effect on families in,
292–93
power of rich in, 192
responsive local democracies in,
239–40
rich keeping poor down in, 144
roads in, 203
self-confidence and mobility in, 28
sources of power in, 139, 140, 250,
251
study site, 9
women in
local democracies and, 265
restrictions on, 80–81, 142
V
Van de Walle, D., 103b
Varshney, A., 278n18
Victorian view of the poor, 19, 72–73,
103b, 334
violence. See also domestic violence
as source of power, 140, 255–56
Vlaicu, R., 278n21
Voices of the Poor study, 7, 43
Vollmann, William, 62
W
war, anxiety about, 57
water resources, 205–7, 331n22
The Wealth of Nations (Smith), 51,
192–93
428
Index
Weber, M., 137
West Bengal (India)
agricultural improvements in, 209,
221n5
aspirations in, 154, 155, 156, 157
bad character as cause of poverty in,
72, 76
crowding out among poor in fight
over limited goods in, 241
economic equality in, 232
electricity in, 234
elite capture in, 256
expanded opportunities in, 266–68,
270
“good power” in, 137
health, importance of, 69
joining political party in, 253
metaphors to describe lives of poor
in, 142
muscle power in, 256
political connections in, 162
politics and governance in, 226
poverty dynamics in, 99
self-confidence and mobility in, 29,
62
stagnation and discrimination in,
268–69
study site, 9
water resources in, 205–6
The White’s Man Burden (Kipling), 76–77
Why? (Tilly), 149
widows, 68–69, 290–91
witchcraft, 143
women
alcoholism of men, views on, 74
changes in, effect on men, 134, 135–
36b, 322
corporations run by, 317–18
digging societies formed by, 304
discrimination against, 47, 293–95
divorce and separation, effect of, 69,
290–91, 293
education of, 294
electricity and, 207
empowerment of, 178n5
equality of, 232
inequalities in power and, 141–42
inheritance laws and, 68
movement of, restrictions on, 80–81
nsango groups and, 38–39
nursing career choice of girls, 158
occupational choices of, 158
“power to” and, 133
“power with” of, 131, 134
roads, effect on lives of, 203
self-help movement, 39–40, 171,
264–65, 310–11, 313–15
violence against. See domestic
violence
widowhood, 68–69, 290–91
Woolcock, M., 325, 331n18
work ethic. See hard work as way out of
poverty
World Bank
Doing Business report (2008), 199
National Solidarity Program (NSP),
260, 279n25, 326
on poverty line, 103b
World Development Report 1990 (World
Bank), 103b
World Development Report 2004 (World
Bank), 331n23
World Values Survey, 58
Wright, E. O., 277n10
Wright, G., 278n19
Y
yogurt business in Bangladesh, 319b
youth
aspirations of, 131, 156–59, 156t
bribing officials to get jobs for life,
246
power defined by, 134
Z
Zaire, corruption in, 277n15
Zambia, mass poverty in, 22
ECO-AUDIT
Environmental Benefits Statement
The World Bank is committed to preserving
endangered forests and natural resources. We
have chosen to print Moving Out of Poverty (vol.
2): Success from the Bottom Up on 60-pound
Roland Opaque, a recycled paper with 30%
post-consumer waste. The Office of the Publisher has agreed to follow the recommended
standards for paper usage set by the Green Press
Initiative, a nonprofit program supporting publishers in using fiber that is not sourced from
endangered forests. For more information, visit
www.greenpressinitiative.org.
Saved:
• 16 trees
• 11 million BTUs of total energy
• 1,439 pounds of net greenhouse
gases
• 5,972 gallons of waste water
• 767 pounds of solid waste
“No matter if I fall, I get up again. If I fall 5,000 times, I will stand up another
5,000 times.”
— William, a 37-year-old from El Gorrión, Colombia
W
hy and how do some people move out of poverty—and stay out—while others remain
trapped? Most books on growth and poverty reduction are dominated by the perspectives of policy makers and academic experts. In contrast, Moving Out of Poverty: Success
from the Bottom Up presents the experiences of poor people who have made it out of poverty.
The book’s findings draw from the Moving Out of Poverty research conducted in communities
in 15 countries in Africa, East Asia, Latin America, and South Asia. The authors synthesize the
results of qualitative and quantitative research based on discussions with over 60,000 people
in rural areas. They offer bottom-up perspectives on the processes and local institutions that
play key roles in escapes from poverty.
The study finds that there are no differences in the initiatives taken by the poor, the rich, and the upwardly mobile. What, then, explains the difference in outcomes? The authors demonstrate how—in
the face of deep social inequalities that block access to economic opportunities and local democracies—individual initiative and empowerment by themselves are often not enough to escape poverty.
This book will be of interest to all concerned with equity in an increasingly unequal world.
“Today, too few people around the world have enough opportunity to connect their dreams
and their talents with the outcomes of their efforts to lift themselves out of poverty. As we
work to expand these opportunities, we can learn a lot from the voices of the poor themselves,
especially those who have lifted themselves up successfully. This book, based on conversations
with thousands of people around the world, is an important resource for everyone who’s working to alleviate poverty.”
— BILL CLINTON
Former President, the United States
“Here is a treasure trove of stories, data, and creative analysis that no one who cares about
ending poverty should miss…. From thousands of interviews in 15 poor countries, the authors
extract some surprising conclusions: Most poor people do not feel trapped; local markets
and politics and community leadership and institutions matter more than average national
income in who escapes poverty. An important complement to the World Bank–sponsored
Spence Commission Report on growth.”
— NANCY BIRDSALL
President, Center for Global Development
SKU 17215
Printed in the
United States
ISBN 978-0-8213-7215-9