Macroeconomic Shocks and Corporate R&D
John Burger∗
Norman Sedgley†
Kerry Tan‡
December 2016
Abstract
This paper investigates the impact of output and credit market shocks on R&D spending in
advanced economies and builds on the commonly accepted view that credit constraints lead to
procyclical R&D spending. A theoretical model is developed where output and credit shocks
are treated separately, though these shocks may be highly correlated. The estimation procedure utilizes a panel vector autoregression (VAR) in order to empirically identify the role of
credit market shocks separately from the output shocks more commonly studied in the existing
literature. The primary empirical findings can be summarized as follows: (1) R&D responds
pro-cyclically to output shocks at the macroeconomic level, and (2) R&D co-moves positively
with credit. More concretely, the results indicate that negative output shocks induce a simultaneous and subsequent contraction in credit and R&D consistent with a model where credit
constraints drive cyclical adjustments to R&D. The impact of output and credit shocks on R&D
are economically significant and a simulation exercise suggests the shocks associated with the
global financial crisis have reduced US R&D by 10% relative to the pre-crisis path.
JEL classification codes: C32, E32, E44
Keywords: R&D Spending, Credit Constraints, Business Cycle, Panel VAR
∗
Department of Economics, Loyola University Maryland,
[email protected]
Corresponding author: Department of Economics, Loyola University Maryland,
[email protected]
‡
Department of Economics, Loyola University Maryland,
[email protected]
†
1
1 Introduction
In the aftermath of the global financial crisis, economists and policymakers are concerned not
only with the slow pace of recovery but also with the possibility that the severity of the recession
has damaged long-run growth prospects. For example, the severe recession may have impacted
the willingness and ability of firms to engage in R&D, which in turn would reduce the likelihood
of future innovation and damage growth prospects. If R&D was significantly impacted on an
economy-wide level, it would likely lead to a reduction in the potential long-run growth path for
the entire economy.
Theoretical discussions of the relationship between R&D and the business cycle date back at
least as far as Schumpeter (1939), who argued that innovative activity is likely concentrated in
downturns when the opportunity cost in terms of forgone output and profits is low. This opportunity cost theory suggests a countercyclical pattern of R&D spending (R&D should rise during
recessions and fall during expansions), but economists generally find the opposite result. Explanations for the common finding of procyclical R&D have generally focused on a role for credit
conditions which make it more likely that firms will engage in R&D during expansions rather than
during recessions when firms might be credit constrained.1
The existing literature on R&D and credit constraints can be parsed along several dimensions
including (1) the empirical methodology (panel data analysis versus single equation time series
models), (2) the level of aggregation in the data (firm, industry, or macro level analysis), and (3)
the treatment of credit conditions (ranging from financial development proxies to firm-level credit
measures). The review here focuses on several recent and prominent contributions that are most
closely related to this paper.
Saint-Paul (1993), Walde and Woitek (2004) and Ouyang (2011) each establish the general
1 Barlevy
(2007) provides an alternative explanation. He suggests that innovators weight near-term profits highly
because profits will become diffused by competitors over time. The implication is that innovative activity (R&D) will
be procyclical because expected short term profits are higher during boom times.
2
result of procyclical R&D using time series analysis.
Saint-Paul (1993) analyzes macro level
productivity, R&D, and the business cycle using a semi-structural VAR for OECD economies
and finds some evidence in support of the view that business cycles have significant effects on
R&D/productivity. Walde and Woitek (2004) use OECD countries as the unit of analysis and look
at annual data from 1973-2000. Correlations are calculated after filtering the log per capita data
with a number of different methodologies (including HP filter, simple difference, etc). Generally
positive contemporaneous correlations with varying degrees of statistical significance are reported.
The only significant exception is Italy, where R&D appears to be countercyclical. On the other
hand, Ouyang (2011) analyzes industry level data for 20 US manufacturing industries over the
1958-1998 time period. He finds evidence supporting Walde and Woitek (2004), but reports that
reductions in R&D during recessions is the primary force behind procyclical R&D.
Aghion, Angeletos, Banerjee, and Manova (2010) (hereafter, AABM) provide a macro level
study of the role of credit constraints on the composition of investment in OECD countries. Although they do not explicitly focus on R&D, their theoretical model suggests that the long-term
share of investment will be procyclical in the face of credit constraints. Empirically, AABM (2010)
find that the impact of commodity price shocks on long-term investment is mitigated by financial
development (or exacerbated by financial constraints). They interpret this result as evidence that
credit constraints are associated with more procyclical long term investment.
Aghion, Askenazy, Berman, Cette, and Eymard (2012) (hereafter, AABCE) extend the analysis of the previous literature to address the cyclicality of R&D using data at the firm level in
France from 1994-2004. Using firm level data on "payment incidents" to construct a proxy for
credit constraints, they demonstrate that current bank credit is significantly impacted by previous
payment incidents and that credit impacts firms’ ability to fund R&D. The cyclicality of R&D is
demonstrated in relation to firm level sales. R&D appears to be countercyclical for firms that are
not credit constrained, but it is procyclical for firms that are credit constrained (i.e. have had past
payment incidents). It is unclear if these firm level results imply overall countercyclical or pro3
cyclical R&D at the macro level. The authors note that their findings do not necessarily translate to
the macroeconomy, especially if the bulk of R&D is concentrated in a small number of large (less
credit constrained) firms. They explore the aggregate implications by presenting results weighted
by firm size. The similarity between weighted and unweighted results suggests procyclical R&D
at the macro level. However, the authors close the paper by suggesting that further work on the
role of credit constraints at the macro level is needed.
Finally, Campello, Graham, and Harvey (2010) survey 1,050 CFOs about credit constraints and
planned investment during the global financial crisis of 2008. A majority of surveyed firms selfreport as being credit constrained during the crisis and most constrained firms report that attractive
investment opportunities were curtailed by the credit crisis.
This paper makes a number of significant contributions to the existing literature. First, it focuses on the cyclical behavior of R&D at the macro level, while most existing studies use firm
or industry level data. The firm/industry evidence suggests that the finding of procyclical R&D is
likely related to credit conditions, but this result has not been confirmed on a macroeconomic level.
Second, this paper jointly models the time series behavior of output, credit, and R&D, while most
previous studies have either calculated simple correlations or attempted to identify output shocks
while treating credit conditions as exogenous.
This paper extends the existing literature by providing a simple model of R&D investment that
is directly motivated by previous work on R&D and credit constraints. The theoretical model incorporates both output and credit market shocks and motivates the empirical analysis. The empirical
investigation employs a panel vector autoregression (VAR), which not only models the time series
properties of output, credit, and R&D for 19 advanced economies but also identifies the endogenous response of credit and R&D to macroeconomic shocks. The key findings suggest that shocks
to output and credit are significant drivers of R&D and the identified impulse response functions
are consistent with credit constraints as an explanation for procyclical R&D at the macro level in
advanced economies.
4
The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 presents the model, Section 3 describes the data,
Section 4 presents the empirical results, and Section 5 provides some concluding comments.
2 Model
The level of financial development is a key determinant of R&D funding, productivity growth,
and volatility/stability (Levine and Zervos (1989); Levine, Loayza, and Beck, (2000); Beck, DemirgucKunt, Laeven, and Levine (2008)). The following model of R&D spending and credit constraints
is directly motivated by Aghion and Saint-Paul (1998) and Aghion, Banerjee, and Piketty (1999)
and includes separate shocks for output and credit markets. The model is intended to provide an
exposition of a firm’s R&D decisions and the role of credit constraints in these decisions. Therefore, the model abstracts from the determination of GDP and long run productivity trends, treating
these aspects of the model as exogenous and outside of the control of the firm.
2.1 Credit market financing without credit constraints
Using notation that is standard in the R&D and credit constraint literature, the relationship
between productivity adjusted resources devoted to R&D, n, and the probability of successfully
innovating, µ , is specified as
n=
R ψ µ2
.
=
2
Â
In this equation R is the firm’s level of resources devoted to R&D projects and  is a target
level of technological advance equivalent to a technological frontier. The equation simply implies
that more resources are needed to achieve a higher chance of success, there are diminishing returns
to resources devoted to R&D, and a higher target level of technology requires a larger investment.
A successful innovation supplies the firm with a discounted stream of profits from the R&D
5
project, π . In the following analysis, π is taken to be profits associated with a successful research
endeavor and depends, in part, on current macroeconomic conditions. The R&D funding problem
is expressed as a simple optimization problem:
π ψ µ2
max(µπ − R) = µ −
Â.
µ
2
Â
This optimization problem leads directly to an equilibrium probability of innovation, µ ∗ =
The firm’s optimal and desired R&D spending is R∗ =
π
.
Âψ
π2
.
2Âψ
Next the firm’s R&D decisions are linked to exogenous macroeconomic conditions. Define
X as a firm’s retained earnings, higher retained earnings give the firm more resources for use in
conducting research. Retained earning are a function of macroeconomic conditions. Define the
GDP gap as Ye and allow retained earnings to be a function of the GDP gap, X = X(Ye ), X ′ (Ye ) > 0.
When Ye = 0 retained earning are at an equilibrium level X. Offsetting the effect of Ye on available
resources is the impact of the GDP gap on the opportunity cost of conducting R&D (Schumpeter
1939). This is captured by allowing the economic profits associated with R&D, π , to be a function
of Ye , π (Ye ). Procyclical opportunity cost is specified with the sign of the derivative, π ′ (Ye ) < 0, and
drives desired R&D to be countercyclical. When Ye = 0 R&D profits are at an equilibrium level π .
The amount of credit market financing, CMF, is
CMF =
π (Ye )2
2Âψ
0
− X(Ye ) R∗ > X
otherwise
Note that in the absence of credit constraints R&D decisions are driven by changes desired
R&D and are clearly countercyclical. The cyclicality of credit market financing depends on the
trade-off between the output gap’s impact on desired R&D
6
π (Ye )2
2Âψ
relative to the impact on X(Ye ).
2.2 Credit market financing with a credit constraint
The relationship between productivity adjusted resources devoted to R&D, ne, and the proba-
e , for the credit constrained firm is
bility of successfully innovating, µ
ne =
e2
Re ψ µ
=
.
2
Â
The credit multiplier, ν > 1, is introduced in the specification of resources spent on R&D as
follows: Re∗ = ne = ν X(Ye ). The value of ν − 1 determines the amount of borrowing possible, as a
percentage of internal resources, for a firm with retained earnings X(Ye ). Combining these insights
produces the probability of a successful innovation under credit constraints:
e∗ =
µ
s
2ν X(Ye )
.
Âψ
] are:
The amount of realized R&D, Re∗ and credit market financing for a constrained firm, CMF,
Re∗ = vX(Ye )
] = (ν − 1) X(Ye ).
CMF
Note that the definition of desired R&D has not changed, R∗ =
π (Ye )2
.
2Âψ
Of course the level of
R&D for the credit constrained firm is now determined by Re∗ < R∗ . Realized R&D and credit
market financing under a credit constraint are procyclical because X ′ (Ye ) > 0.
2.3 Output and Credit Shocks
Allow GDP to be subject to shocks, Ye = δY . Additionally allow for shocks to credit markets
by extending the definition of ν , ν = v(δν ), v(0) = v. The shocks follow unspecified distributions
7
and are potentially correlated:
σY2
δY 0
∼ ,
δν
σY2ν
0
σY2ν
σν2
.
e ∗ < µ ∗ . Substituting expressions for µ
e ∗ and µ ∗ defines a critical
The credit constraint binds if µ
value of the credit multiplier, ν ∗ , below which credit constraints become binding:
v∗ =
π (Ye )2
.
2ψ ÂX(Ye )
] < CMF.
e ∗ < µ ∗ it is straight forward to demonstrate that CMF
If µ
Figure 1 shows equilibrium in the model for two representative firms A and B. The critical
value of the credit multiplier, ν ∗ , is identified on the horizontal axis. Note that v∗ is a function
of δY , but it is not a function of δν . To the left of this value, firms are credit constrained; thus,
firm A in the figure is credit constrained, whereas firm B is not. The upper schedule, labeled R,
determines the level of R&D spending. When the firm is credit constrained, relaxing the constraint
(i.e. an increase in ν ) increases R&D spending. When the firm is not credit constrained, relaxing
the constraint has no impact on the level of R&D spending and the schedule has a slope of zero.
The lower schedule shows the amount of equilibrium credit market funding of R&D, which is
found by subtracting X from R∗ .
[Insert Figures 1 and 2 Here]
Figure 2 shows the impact of a negative output shock, δY , on R&D spending. First consider
firm A, the credit constrained firm. The output shock lowers retained earnings and therefore the
resources the firm has available for funding R&D. This is depicted by the downward shift in the
R schedule. Note that the output shock also changes the critical value of the credit multiplier,
ν ∗ , increasing the likelihood that firms will face constraints in financing. As expected R&D is
procyclical for this firm and R&D falls. Next, consider the case of a firm that does not face credit
8
constraints, such as firm B. Here, any shortfall of internal financing due to the output shock is
offset by more credit market funding of projects. Desired R&D is countercyclical, and therefore
realized R&D spending is countercyclical as well. In the figure the impact of the output shock
causes credit market finance to increase,
2π (Ye )π ′ (Ye )
2Âψ
< X ′ (Ye ).
[Insert Figure 3 Here]
Figure 3 shows the impact of a credit shock, δv , on R&D spending. The credit constrained firm
A sees a drop in R&D because the ability to borrow has decreased even though retained earnings
are unchanged. On the other hand, nothing of consequence changes for the unconstrained firm.
Their level of R&D remains at the desired level and financing through credit markets remains
constant.
The model highlights the potential role of output shocks on R&D through an impact on internal
resources for a credit constrained firm, the role of output shocks in determining the critical value of
the credit multiplier, ν ∗ , at which firms become credit constrained, and the direct impact of credit
shocks via the parameter δν . An empirical investigation of the relationship between R&D and the
business cycle should account for the role of credit shocks and output shocks to avoid confounding
the role of these shocks at the estimation stage. In the remainder of the paper, an empirical model
is estimated that identifies the role of each type of shock using a panel VAR estimation strategy
to uncover the dynamic relationship between R&D, output shocks, and credit market shocks, as
well as assess the importance of these shocks in explaining the variation of R&D spending across
advanced economies.
3 Data
The data used for this paper are combined from four sources. First, the OECD provides data
on business enterprise R&D spending from 1982-2011, which dictates the time period used in
9
this study.2 The OECD reports significant gaps in R&D spending for some countries, resulting
in an unbalanced panel. A proxy for the risk premium in credit markets, measured as the spread
between bank lending rates and short term treasury bills from 1982-2011, is collected from the
World Bank’s World Developent Indicators3 . Next, GDP data from 1982-2011 is available from
the IMF.4 Finally, credit data is retrieved from an extensive new international database created
by the Bank for International Settlements (BIS).5 The burgeoning literature on the financial cycle
has typically used growth in real total non-financial private sector credit along with a proxy for
housing prices (see Borio et al. (2014)). The new BIS data set splits the credit data into household
and corporate sectors. Since this paper focuses on credit available to corporations engaging in
R&D rather than credit extended to households (e.g. mortgages), the series on credit to the nonfinancial corporate sector from 1982-2011 is used. All data are transformed into real terms and are
denominated in local currency.
[Insert Table 1 Here]
Table 1 reports the results of panel unit root tests on the levels of our variables. The tests suggest
that the levels of R&D, credit, and GDP are nonstationary variables. Therefore, our baseline panel
vector autoregression model in Section 4 uses log differences of these variables. RGDPi,t , Crediti,t ,
and R&Di,t are defined as the log first differenced value of country i’s GDP, credit extended to the
non-financial corporate sector, and business enterprise R&D spending, respectively. The interest
rate spread/risk premium, denoted ispreadi,t is stationary. This variable is used, without differencing, with RGDPi,t and Crediti,t in constructing alternative measures of credit conditions. The final
data set consists of 392 observations on 19 countries. Although the IMF classifies more than 19
countries as advanced economies, the availability of data on R&D spending limits the sample to
2 http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=GERD_FUNDS
3 http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/FR.INR.LNDP?page=6.
4 http://www.imf.org/external/ns/cs.aspx?id=28
5 http://www.bis.org/statistics/credtopriv.htm.
10
See Dembiermont et al. (2013) for details.
these countries. Summary statistics for these variables and a list of countries included in the final
data set are provided in Table 2.
[Insert Table 2 Here]
Growth in credit provided to the private sector, Crediti,t , is the main measure of credit market
conditions in this paper. Clearly, observations of credit flows represent an equilibrium outcome in
credit markets and therefore represent an imperfect measure of the role of credit constraints highlighted in the model of Section 2.6 To complement the credit growth variable, we also incorporate
information from the interest rate spread and construct the following financial conditions index:
f in_indexi,t =
Crediti,t − min(Crediti,t )
ispreadi,t − min(ispreadi )
−
,
max(Crediti ) − min(Crediti ) max(ispreadi ) − min(ispreadi )
where ispread is the World Bank’s risk spread (defined above), and Credit is the growth rate in
credit extended to the non-financial corporate sector. Our financial conditions index combines a
country-specific percentile ranking of the credit growth and interest spread variables. The index
has a maximum value of 100 (which would indicate the most rapid credit growth and most narrow
interest spread) to -100 (slowest credit growth and widest interest spread).
4 Empirical Analysis
This section analyzes the cyclical behavior of annual R&D in a panel of 19 advanced economies.
Although R&D data is available for a slightly wider set of countries, the sample is restricted to advanced economies (based on the IMF definition) in order to achieve a more homogeneous panel.7
6 See
Khan and Thomas (2013) for the importance of isolating credit shocks.
existing studies use a sample of OECD countries. The results using the OECD sample are very similar to
those reported in the paper. The IMF advanced economy sample is preferred since it provides a group of countries
with similar levels of financial development.
7 Many
11
4.1 Estimation Strategy and Results
A panel VAR is employed to evaluate the response of R&D to output and credit shocks at the
macroeconomic level. A major advantage of this framework is that each variable in a VAR model
is treated as potentially endogenous. The estimated model is a pth order panel VAR where p is
order of the autoregressive lag. The panel VAR is specified as follows:
Yi,t = A1Yi,t−1 + A2Yi,t−2 + ... + A pYi,t−p + fi + ut
(1)
i ∈ {1, 2, ..., N} ,t ∈ {1, 2, ..., Ti }
The panel is defined by N = 19 countries (i) and a maximum of 28 years (t) per country. The vector
Yi,t includes k = 3 three variables: (1) RGDP, (2) credit conditions ∈ {Credit, f in_index} , and (3)
R&D. Note that RGDP and R&D are transformed into real growth rates and denominated in local
currency. Measures of credit conditions, described above, are stationary. These variables are used
to identify shocks to output and credit as suggested by the theoretical model in Section 2. The
country fixed effect, fi , absorbs cross-country variation in the mean of each macroeconomic series.
In a dynamic setting, the commonly employed mean-differencing procedure would create biased
coefficients on the lagged dependent variables (see Arellano and Bover (1995)). Following Love
and Zicchino (2006), Helmert forward mean-differencing is implemented to estimate the dynamic
fixed effects model.
The individual equations are stacked and simultaneously estimated using
GMM. In this process L ≥ kp instruments are constructed from lagged values of the Yi,t.
Specifying a lag structure with an over identifying number of instruments allows for the determination of the optimal lag structure using a Consistent Model Moment Selection Criteria
(CMMSC) based on Hansen’s J statistic for over identifying restrictions (Andrews and Lu, 2001).
Table 3 reports three CMMSC criteria based on the Bayesian, Akiake, and Hannan-Quinn information criteria. Using q = 5 lags per variable the three CMMSC statistics are calculated for lags
1 through 4. The first four rows are for the baseline panel VAR using log differences in Crediti,t .
12
The next four rows test the optimal lag length for the model using f in_indexi,t . In each case the
optimal lag length is unambiguously equal to one lag.8
[Insert Table 3 Here]
The most common means of identifying structural shocks is to employ a Choleski decomposition of the variance-covariance matrix of residuals and investigate impulse response functions. The
Choleski decomposition is a recursive decomposition requiring an ordering of the variables such
that contemporaneous correlation for any pair of variables is assigned to shocks in the variable ordered first. For example, the baseline ordering is: (1) output, (2) credit, (3) R&D, which assumes
that output shocks have a contemporaneous impact on credit and R&D and that credit shocks have
a contemporaneous impact on R&D but not output. Clearly, output and credit are highly endogenous at the macroeconomic level with feedback running in both directions. Ordering output first is
appropriate because firms do not necessarily spend on capital projects immediately after obtaining
credit and the full (multiplied) macroeconomic impact of credit on GDP comes with a lag. The
annual frequency of the data does require a lag that is potentially problematic (a one quarter lag
would be more easily defended). As it turns out, the contemporaneous correlation of the residuals
from the output and credit equations in the baseline panel VAR is only 0.13, therefore the results
are quite similar if credit is ordered before output.9
[Insert Figures 4 and 5 Here]
Figures 4 and 5 refer to panel VAR Specifications 1 and 2, respectively, and display the impulse
response functions and 90% confidence intervals generated with Monte Carlo simulations.10 The
first column of each figure displays the responses of each variable to a shock in output. An output
8 As a robustness check a lag of two was also fully analyzed. The results are not significantly different from those
reported in the paper.
9 The results of this alternative ordering can be obtained from the authors upon request.
10 We use 500 Monte Carlo draws to estimate the 90% confidence interval for the impulse responses. See Love and
Zicchino (2006) for more information.
13
shock has a highly statistically significant impact on credit market conditions and R&D spending in
each specification. A shock to output generates a long lived positive response of credit (consistent
with findings in the credit cycle literature) and a contemporaneous impact on R&D in the same
direction of the shock.
In both specifications, one observes a positive and statistically significant comovement between output and R&D induced by an output shock, which is consistent with the common finding
of procyclical R&D. In a Schumpeterian world, if firms were not credit constrained, lower opportunity costs during a downturn and higher opportunity costs during expansions would induce
countercyclical R& D. Our finding of procyclical responses of R&D and credit conditions to output shocks are potentially consistent with a role for credit constraints in explaining the cyclical
behavior of R&D as suggested by the theoretical model in Section 2. In the theoretical model,
output shocks are represented by δY , which impacts the firm’s retained earnings (see the shift in
the R schedule in Figure 2) as well as desired R&D. For credit constrained firms, a positive output
shock will relax the credit constraint by providing more internal resources to fund R&D (while
negative output shocks induce a decline in internal funds and R&D). Additionally, the model tells
us that a positive output shock simultaneously lowers ν ∗ , the threshold at which credit constraints
bind, and leads to both an increase in credit extended to constrained firms and an increase in R&D
spending for credit constrained firms. The impulse responses in the first columns of Figures 4 and
5 provide empirical support for these mechanisms.11
One of the novelties of the theoretical model in Section 2 is the separate role for credit shocks
in influencing R&D, and the VAR methodology allows an empirical investigation of these shocks.
The empirically identified credit shock is a proxy to the δv shock in the theoretical model. Ceteris
paribus, this represents a pure stochastic innovation in credit market conditions. The lower credit
multiplier reduces the availability of credit market financing for credit constrained firms, and thus
11 Alternatively, observed R&D may be procyclical because desired R&D is in fact procyclical as suggested by
Barlevy (2007).
14
causes a decrease in R&D. Empirical support for the role of credit market shocks is found in the
second column of Figures 4 and 5. In each specification, the credit shock has a highly statistically
significant impact on R&D spending, providing further evidence that credit constraints play an
important role in determining R&D on a macroeconomic level even in advanced economies where
financial markets are well developed. Our finding of procyclical R&D that is sensitive to credit
market conditions provides macro level support for the firm level evidence found in AABCE(2012).
It is useful to decompose the forecast error variance into the proportions due to each type of
shock. The variance decompositions are reported in Table 4, which shows the percentage of longrun variation in each variable that is explained by each shock in the estimated VAR.12 Again,
results are highly consistent across specifications of the panel VAR and alternative measures of
credit shocks. Here we focus on the variance decomposition for the baseline specification, Specification 1. It is common to find that a large degree of variation in a variable is due to its own
innovations, but we find a considerable amount of the variation in credit market conditions is explained by output shocks. Of particular interest for this study is the third row of Table 4, where it
is noted that 4.1% of the variation in R&D over a 10-year horizon is explained by output shocks
and 4.3% is explained by credit shocks. In sum, roughly 8.4% of the variation in R&D is therefore
attributable to cyclical conditions stemming from shocks to output and credit. Although this historical decomposition reveals a limited role for short run fluctuations in explaining R&D spending, in
the next section we demonstrate that cyclical shocks are economically significant when analyzing
the behavior of R&D in the aftermath of the Great Recession.
[Insert Table 4 Here]
12 Variance decompositions at various forecast horizons and under the alternative ordering of the variables are similar
to those reported in Table 4.
15
4.2 Application to the Great Recession
The role of credit and output shocks in explaining the cyclicality of R&D is potentially important in assessing the costs associated with the global financial crisis, a period in which the global
economy was hit by a series of output and credit shocks. In order to quantify the economic significance of the R&D response in our model, consider some back of the envelope calculations which
attempt to match actual US GDP and credit growth during the Great Recession with the estimated
shocks from our model. For example, US real GDP growth averaged 2.7% in our sample, but
dropped to essentially zero in 2008 and -2.8% in 2009. The panel VAR estimates an orthogonalized one standard deviation shock to output at 1.6% (see top left corner of Figure 4), which suggests
the US experienced roughly a one standard deviation negative output shock in 2008 (which is a
conservative estimate given that output growth dropped close to zero) followed by a two standard
deviation negative output shock in 2009. Similar calculations suggest the US also experienced a
one standard deviation negative credit shock during 2009.13
[Insert Figure 6 Here]
Of particular interest for this study is the impact of these output and credit shocks on R&D.
Simulating the US experience by feeding the series of negative output and credit shocks detailed
above into the R&D impulse response functions yields the results (dotted blue line) displayed in
Figure 6. The solid red line plots US R&D spending using the actual 2007 value and projecting
a long-run average growth rate of 3.9%. Finally, the dashed green line plots actual US R&D
spending for years 2007-2011. Actual US R&D spending roughly follows the pattern predicted by
the impulse response functions during 2008-2010 but suffers an additional dip in 2011 (perhaps
due to yet another shock). The conservative estimates produced by the model suggest that by 2011
R&D falls $26 billion below its pre-crisis path and that a permanent R&D gap of 10% has opened
13 US credit growth averaged 4.2% in our sample, but dropped to approximately zero in 2009 and -2.5% in 2010.
The
estimated impact of the output shocks in 2008 and 2009 on subsequent credit growth combined with a one standard
deviation shock to credit itself in 2009 would roughly generate the observed pattern in credit.
16
up between pre- and post-crisis R&D.14 This economically significant drop in the level of R&D
suggests a channel through which the Great Recession could significantly damage long-run growth
prospects. Estimating the impact on long-run potential supply is beyond the scope of this paper,
but the results provide support for the estimates provided by Reifschneider et al. (2013) and the
concerns about stagnation registered by Summers (2014).
5 Conclusion
This paper makes a number of significant contributions to the existing literature. First, it focuses on the cyclical behavior of R&D at the macro level using data that includes the recent financial crisis, while most existing studies use firm or industry level data. Second, this paper jointly
models the time series behavior of output, credit, and R&D using a panel VAR. The primary empirical findings can be summarized as follows: (1) R&D responds pro-cyclically to output shocks
at the macroeconomic level, and (2) R&D co-moves positively with credit. More concretely, the
results indicate that negative output shocks induce a simultaneous and subsequent contraction in
credit and R&D consistent with a model where credit constraints drive cyclical adjustments to
R&D. In addition the results indicate an independent impact of credit shocks directly on R&D.
The impact of output and credit shocks on R&D are economically significant and a simple simulation exercise conservatively estimates that the shocks associated with the global financial crisis
have reduced US R&D spending by 10% relative to the pre-crisis path. In sum, the empirical
evidence is strongly consistent with an important role for credit conditions in explaining the cyclical behavior of R&D, perhaps surprisingly strong evidence given that the sample is restricted to
advanced economies with the world’s most sophisticated financial systems.
14 The
R&D gap is permanent because R&D exhibits a unit root as described in Section 3.
17
References
Andrews, D. and B. Lu (2001), "Consistent Model and Moment Selection Procedures for GMM
Estimation with Application to Dynamic Panel Data Models," Journal of Econometrics 101(1),
123-164.
Aghion, P., G.M. Angeletos, A. Banerjee, and K. Manova (2010), "Volatility and Growth: Credit
Constraints and the Composition of Investment," Journal of Monetary Economics 57(3), 246265.
Aghion, P., P. Askenazy, N. Berman, G. Cette, and L. Eymard (2012), "Credit Constraints and the
Cyclicality of R&D Investment: Evidence from France," Journal of the European Economic
Association 10(5), 1001-1024.
Aghion, P., A. Banerjee, and T. Piketty (1999), "Dualism and Macroeconomic Volatility,"
Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 1359-1397.
Aghion, P. and G. Saint-Paul (1998), “Virtues of Bad Times: Interaction Between Productivity
Growth and Economic Fluctuations,” Macroeconomic Dynamics 2, 322-344.
Arellano, M. and O. Bover (1995), "Another Look at the Instrumental Variable Estimation of
Error-Components Models," Journal of Econometrics 68(1), 29-51.
Barlevy, G. (2007), "On the Cyclicality of Research and Development," The American Economic
Review 97(4), 1131-1164.
Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, L. Laeven, and R. Levine (2008), "Finance, Firm Size and Growth,"
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40(7), 1379-1405
Borio, C. (2014), "The Financial Cycle and Macroeconomics: What Have We Learnt?" Journal of
Banking & Finance 45, 182-198.
Campello, M., J. Graham, and C. Harvey (2010), "The Real Effects of Financial Constraints:
Evidence from a Financial Crisis," Journal of Financial Economics 97, 470-487.
Dembiermont, C., M. Drehmann, and S. Muksakunratana (2013), "How Much Does the Private
Sector Really Borrow? A New Database for Total Credit to the Private Non-Financial Sector,"
18
BIS Quarterly Review March 2013, 65-81.
Ha, J. and P. Howitt (2006), "Accounting for Trends in Productivity and R&D: A Schumpeterian
Critique of Semi-Endogenous Growth Theory," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39, 733774.
Khan, A. and J. Thomas (2013), "Credit Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations in an Economy with
Production Heterogeneity," Journal of Political Economy 121(6), 1055-1107.
Levine, R. and S. Zervos (1998), "Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth," American
Economic Review 88, 537-558.
Levine, R., N. Loayza, and T. Beck (2000), "Financial Intermediation and Growth: Causality and
Causes," Journal of Monetary Economics 46, 31-77.
Love, I. and L. Zicchino (2006), "Financial Development and Dynamic Investment Behavior:
Evidence from Panel VAR," The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 46(2), 190-210.
Ouyang, M. (2011), Ön the Cyclicality of R&D," Review of Economics and Statistics 93(2), 542553.
Reifschneider, D., W. Wascher, and D. Wilcox (2013), "Aggregate Supply in the United States:
Recent Developments and Implications for the Conduct of Monetary Policy," Working Paper.
Saint-Paul, G. (1993), "Productivity Growth and the Structure of the Business Cycle," European
Economic Review 37(4), 861-883.
Schumpeter, J. (1939), Business Cycles, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Summers, L. (2014), "US Economic Prospects: Secular Stagnation, Hysteresis, and the Zero
Lower Bound," Business Economics 49(2), 65-73.
Walde, K. and U. Woitek (2004), "R&D Spending in G7 Countries and the Implications for
Endogenous Fluctuations and Growth," Economics Letters 82, 91-97.
19
Figure 1: Equilibrium and Credit Constraints
Figure 2: Output Shock
20
Figure 3: Credit Shock
Figure 4: Impulse Response Functions (Specification 1)
21
Figure 5: Impulse Response Functions (Specification 2)
Figure 6: Great Recession R&D Gap
22
Table 1: Unit Root Tests
Real GDP
R&D
Credit
Interest Rate Spread
Financial Conditions Index
Statistic P-Value
1.011
(0.844)
1.330
(0.908)
3.224
(0.999)
-4.272 (0.000)
-4.225 (0.000)
Phillips-Perron unit root test with inverse normal test statistic reported. Null hypothesis is all panels contain unit roots. Alternative hypothesis is at
least one panel is stationary. Time trends included for GDP, R&D and Credit. Panel means and two lags are included for all variables.
Table 2: Summary Statistics
N
All 19 Countries 392
Australia
26
Belgium
26
Canada
30
Czech Republic
15
Denmark
8
Finland
14
France
29
Germany
16
Ireland
9
Italy
29
Japan
29
Korea
15
Netherlands
8
Norway
9
Portugal
28
Singapore
16
Spain
29
United Kingdom 26
United States
30
RGDPi,t
Mean (Std. Dev.)
0.025 (0.026)
0.033 (0.014)
0.019 (0.016)
0.025 (0.022)
0.027 (0.030)
0.008 (0.030)
0.024 (0.036)
0.018 (0.015)
0.014 (0.022)
0.018 (0.042)
0.015 (0.019)
0.021 (0.026)
0.044 (0.038)
0.031 (0.012)
0.021 (0.025)
0.024 (0.025)
0.056 (0.043)
0.027 (0.021)
0.026 (0.023)
0.027 (0.020)
Crediti,t
Mean (Std. Dev.)
0.041
(0.054)
0.048
(0.065)
0.053
(0.048)
0.032
(0.038)
0.006
(0.066)
0.012
(0.029)
0.045
(0.035)
0.038
(0.032)
0.023
(0.037)
0.106
(0.080)
0.032
(0.040)
0.024
(0.050)
0.055
(0.066)
0.042
(0.028)
0.065
(0.058)
0.032
(0.060)
0.050
(0.085)
0.050
(0.058)
0.059
(0.065)
0.042
(0.039)
R&Di,t
Mean (Std. Dev.)
0.052 (0.081)
0.091 (0.088)
0.027 (0.048)
0.039 (0.074)
0.062 (0.110)
0.085 (0.075)
0.054 (0.068)
0.033 (0.034)
0.033 (0.036)
0.034 (0.067)
0.025 (0.069)
0.041 (0.057)
0.075 (0.075)
0.032 (0.061)
0.076 (0.086)
0.101 (0.132)
0.091 (0.150)
0.067 (0.086)
0.017 (0.049)
0.039 (0.046)
Notes: RGDPi,t is the log first differenced value of country i’s GDP.
Crediti,t is the log first differenced value of credit extended to non-financial corporate sector in country i.
R&Di,t is the log first differenced value of business enterprise R&D spending in country i.
23
ispreadi,t
Mean (Std. Dev.)
2.720 (1.869)
3.329 (0.629)
3.879 (1.418)
1.645 (0.371)
2.934 (1.609)
1.733
6.063
(1.563)
(0.550)
3.116
2.122
(1.422)
(0.669)
6.787
4.282
1.373
0.303
3.044
(2.153)
(0.858)
(1.871)
(0.262)
(0.448)
Table 3: Optimal Lag Selection
# of lags
1
2
3
4
1
2
3
4
MBIC
MAIC
Specification 1
-171.712 -40.097
-128.562 -29.850
-83.432 -17.624
-42.688 -9.784
Specification 2
-149.139 -28.987
-114.831 -24.717
-78.305 -18.229
-38.712 -8.674
MQIC
-92.852
-69.417
-44.002
-22.973
-77.570
-61.154
-42.520
-20.820
Note: MBIC = J − (|q| − |p|)k2 ln(n), MAIC = J − 2(|q| − |p|)k2 , and MQIC = J − R(|q| − |p|)k2 ln(n). In each case, J is Hansen’s J for over
identification.
Table 4: Variance Decomposition (10 Year Horizon)
Specification 1
Variation in:
Shocks to:
RGDPi,t
Crediti,t
R&Di,t
RGDPi,t
Crediti,t
0.987
0.010
0.115
0.884
0.041
0.043
Specification 2
R&Di,t
0.003
0.000
0.915
Variation in:
Shocks to:
RGDPi,t
f in_indexi,t
R&Di,t
RGDPi,t
0.972
0.097
0.044
24
f in_indexi,t
0.023
0.896
0.035
R&Di,t
0.006
0.007
0.921