Accepted Manuscript
The Skewness of Commodity Futures Returns
Adrian Fernandez-Perez , Bart Frijns , Ana-Maria Fuertes ,
Joelle Miffre
PII:
DOI:
Reference:
S0378-4266(17)30150-4
10.1016/j.jbankfin.2017.06.015
JBF 5167
To appear in:
Journal of Banking and Finance
Received date:
Revised date:
Accepted date:
10 November 2016
21 June 2017
30 June 2017
Please cite this article as: Adrian Fernandez-Perez , Bart Frijns , Ana-Maria Fuertes , Joelle Miffre ,
The Skewness of Commodity Futures Returns, Journal of Banking and Finance (2017), doi:
10.1016/j.jbankfin.2017.06.015
This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service
to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo
copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final form. Please
note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and
all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
The Skewness of Commodity Futures Returns
Adrian Fernandez-Perez*, Bart Frijns**, Ana-Maria Fuertes***, Joelle Miffre****
Research Fellow, Auckland University of Technology, Private Bag 92006, 1142 Auckland, New
Zealand. Phone: +64 9 921 9999; Fax: +64 9 921 9940; Email:
[email protected]
**
Professor of Finance, Auckland University of Technology; Email:
[email protected]
***
Professor of Financial Econometrics, Cass Business School, City University London, ECIY
8TZ, England; Tel: +44 (0)20 7040 0186 E-mail:
[email protected].
IP
T
*
Abstract
US
CR
**** Professor of Finance, Audencia Business School, 8 Route de la Jonelière, 44312 Nantes, France;
Tel: +33 (0)2 40 37 34 34. Corresponding author.
This article studies the relation between the skewness of commodity futures returns and
AN
expected returns. A trading strategy that takes long positions in commodity futures with the
most negative skew and shorts those with the most positive skew generates significant excess
M
returns that remain after controlling for exposure to well-known risk factors. A tradeable
skewness factor explains the cross-section of commodity futures returns beyond exposures to
PT
ED
standard risk premia. The impact that skewness has on future returns is explained by
investors’ preferences for skewness under cumulative prospect theory and selective hedging
CE
practices.
Keywords: Skewness; Commodities; Futures pricing; Selective hedging
AC
JEL classifications: G13, G14
This version: June 21, 2017
1
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
US
CR
IP
T
§ We are thankful to two anonymous referees for their valuable comments and suggestions. We also
acknowledge the comments of Guiseppe Bertola, Maik Dierkes, Fabian Hollstein, Florian Ielpo,
Abraham Lioui, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Rafael Molinero, Marcel Prokopczuk, Sofia Ramos,
Andrea Roncoroni, Andy Vivian, Robert Webb, and conference participants at the 2015 EDHEC-Risk
Institute Conference, London, the 2015 Derivative Markets Conference, Auckland, the 2015 CFE
Conference, London, the 2016 New Zealand Finance Colloquium, the 2016 Commodity Markets
Conference, Hannover, the 2016 Energy and Commodity Finance Conference, Cergy, the 2016
INFINITI Conference on International Finance, Dublin, the 2016 FMA, Las Vegas, and the 2016
Word Finance Conference, New York; and seminars participants at Audencia Business School,
EDHEC Business School, ESSEC Business School and Leibniz University Hannover. We also
acknowledge excellent technical assistance of Olaf Draeger in processing the data.
1. Introduction
Recent research on equities has studied the relationship between skewness and expected
returns. While theory predicts a negative relation between skewness and expected returns
AN
(Mitton and Vorkink, 2007; and Barberis and Huang, 2008), empirical results are mixed (e.g.,
M
Kumar (2009), Bali et al. (2011), Amaya et al. (2015) find evidence in support of this
negative relation, whereas Xiang et al. (2010), Cremers and Weinbaum (2010), and Rehman
PT
ED
and Vilkov (2012) document a positive relation). Given these mixed results, a study that
focuses on a different asset class can shed light on the relation between skewness and
expected returns. In this paper, we fill this gap by focusing on commodity futures and
CE
examining whether the skewness of daily commodity futures returns tells us anything about
expected returns on these futures. The answer to this question is of great importance to
AC
academics interested in developing commodity pricing models and more generally getting a
better understanding about the role of skewness in the pricing of assets. It is also relevant to
long-short market participants concerned with the design of practical investment solutions in
commodity futures markets.
Using a time-series approach, we examine the performance of a long-short portfolio
sorted on skewness where the latter is estimated over the past 12 months of daily futures
returns. Taking fully-collateralized long positions in the 20% of commodities with the most
2
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
negative skewness and short positions in those with the most positive skewness at each
month-end generates an average excess return of 8.01% per annum that is statistically
significant (t-statistic of 3.83). The average alpha of the long-short skewness-sorted portfolio
stands at 6.21% per annum across pricing models1 and thus the excess return cannot be
explained by standard pricing models documented in the literature. The time-series evidence
IP
T
is robust to transaction costs and liquidity considerations.
Cross-sectional tests show that the long-short skewness portfolio explains the pricing of
US
CR
commodity futures. The price of skewness is statistically significant and positive with an
average of 5.04% per annum across models. In comparison to other factors, the skewness
factor commands the most significant and largest premium. Including the skewness factor
AN
increases the average explanatory power of commodity pricing models marginally (from
31.77% to 35.26% or by 3.5%) but systematically. 2 These results corroborate the time-series
M
evidence in showing that skewness matters to the pricing of commodity futures and that
of skewness.
PT
ED
investors demand higher compensation for exposure to commodity futures with lower levels
Taken altogether, these results lend support to the theories on skewness preferences
1
CE
(Mitton and Vorkink, 2007; Barberis and Huang, 2008). In these frameworks, skewness
AC
The literature on commodity futures pricing has established that a suitable benchmark should include
a long-only commodity portfolio as well as long-short portfolios deemed to capture the phases of
backwardation and contango (see Bakshi et al., 2017 or Fernandez-Perez et al., 2017 for recent
references). Acknowledging that backwardation (contango) signals a likely rise (fall) in futures prices,
such long-short portfolios buy backwardated commodities described by lower standardized inventories
(Fama and French, 1987; Symeonidis et al., 2012; Gorton et al., 2013), downward sloping forward
curves (Erb and Harvey, 2006; Gorton and Rouwenhorst, 2006; Szymanowska et al., 2014; Koijen et
al., 2017), good past performance (Erb and Harvey, 2006; Miffre and Rallis, 2007; Asness et al.,
2013; Gorton et al., 2013), net short hedging and net long speculation (Bessembinder, 1992; Basu and
Miffre, 2013; Dewally et al., 2013); they also short contangoed commodities with opposite
characteristics. Aside from these now-standard signals, the literature also documents significant
spreading returns earned on portfolios sorted on liquidity, change in open interests, inflation beta,
dollar beta, value or volatility (Hong and Yogo, 2012; Asness et al., 2013; Szymanowska et al., 2014).
2
The rise in explanatory power obtained when moving from a given model to the same model
augmented with a skewness factor, albeit small, is similar to that obtained in the equity literature
(Chang et al., 2013).
3
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
matters because of investors’ preference for positive skewness (lottery-type payoffs), which
causes positively skewed equities to become overpriced and earn lower expected returns than
equities with negative skews. This overpricing is not arbitraged away either because of shortselling restrictions (Mitton and Vorkink, 2007) or because positive skewness has a valuable
impact on the utility investors derive from their investments (Barberis and Huang, 2008).3
IP
T
Since commodity futures markets are not subject to short-sale constraints and are dominated
by speculators and hedgers, with retail investors rarely participating, our findings are more in
US
CR
line with the cumulative prospect theory framework of Barberis and Huang (2008).
An additional mechanism through which skewness could affect commodity prices relates
to selective hedging, or more specifically, to hedging under skewness preferences (Stulz,
AN
1996; Gilbert et al., 2006 and Lien and Wang, 2015). Selective hedging is a practice in which
hedgers’ view of future price movements influences their optimal hedge ratio. In this sense,
M
hedgers with preferences either described by cumulative prospect theory (Barberis and
Huang, 2008) or influenced by skewness (Gilbert et al., 2006) may not only want to minimize
PT
ED
risk but also maximize skewness. Consistent with our empirical findings, these skewness
preferences could increase net long hedging, and accordingly, overprice positively skewed
commodities; and vice versa for negatively-skewed ones. Aligned with the selective hedging
CE
hypothesis, we show that commercial traders have a propensity to take relatively longer
(shorter) hedges in positively (negatively) skewed commodities.
AC
Neither the theory of storage of Kaldor (1939), nor the hedging pressure hypothesis of
Cootner (1960) explicitly state that skewness matters to commodity futures pricing. It is
important to note however that in an extension of the theory of storage, Deaton and Laroque
(1992) argue that scarce inventories induce positive skewness, backwardation and thus an
3
Barberis and Huang (2008) use the cumulative prospect theory framework of Tversky and Kahneman
(1992) to show that overweighting the probabilities of the occurrence of tail events leads to a
preference for positively skewed assets. As this preference for positive skewness is part of the utility
functions of investors this is not arbitraged away by short positions.
4
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
expectation of rising futures prices. Stated differently, their model allows for the possibility of
a positive link between skewness and expected returns. Our results highlight the presence of a
strong negative relation between skewness and expected returns and thus do not support the
predictions of Deaton and Laroque (1992).
The rest of the article unfolds as follows. Section 2 presents the theoretical motivation of
IP
T
why skewness matters in commodity futures markets. Section 3 presents the commodity
futures data and benchmarks. Section 4 examines the performance of the skewness trading
US
CR
strategy. Section 5 investigates the ability of a tradeable skewness factor to explain the crosssection of individual commodity returns. Finally Section 6 concludes.
AN
2. Theoretical background
In this section, we discuss the theoretical background for why skewness can affect the
M
expected returns of commodities. We focus specifically on the skewness preference literature,
which argues that investor preferences affect demand for assets with certain distributional
PT
ED
properties. In addition, we discuss the literature on selective hedging where hedgers’ view of
future price movements influences the exposure that is hedged.
There are two theoretical frameworks that motivate a negative relation between skewness
CE
and expected returns. The first framework by Mitton and Vorkink (2007) relies on the notion
of two types of traders, one being the traditional mean-variance optimizer, while the other
AC
being a trader with an inherent preference for assets with positively skewed distributions (i.e.,
lottery-like assets). This framework largely builds on a behavioral bias, where investors have
an intrinsic preference for positive skewness (lottery-like equities); hence, positive-skewness
equities are overpriced and have lower expected returns than equities with negative skewness.
Equivalently, we could say that there is a negative relationship between skewness and
expected returns. The overpricing is not arbitraged away because of short-selling restrictions.
5
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Empirically, Kumar (2009) shows that those investors with preferences for lottery-type
equities are typically retail investors.
The second framework (based on the work of Barberis and Huang, 2008) is different, in
the sense that all investors have homogenous preferences, but have utility functions based on
cumulative prospect theory preferences (Tversky and Kahneman, 1992). Under cumulative
IP
T
prospect theory preferences, investors have value functions that are concave over gains, but
convex over losses (this makes investors risk averse over moderate gains, but risk seeking
US
CR
over moderate losses). In addition, investors overweigh the likelihood of events with low
probabilities of occurring, and underweigh the likelihood of events with high probabilities of
occurring. Barberis and Huang (2008) demonstrate that in an economy with skewed assets
AN
and short-selling constraints, investors overweigh the likelihood of extreme events occurring,
and thus are willing to pay more for an asset with a small probability of a large positive
M
outcome; positively skewed assets will then become overpriced and will have low expected
expected returns.
PT
ED
returns. Stated differently, this setting predicts a negative relationship between skewness and
However, as Barberis and Huang (2008) point out, even in the case where investors can
short-sell, under cumulative prospect theory preferences skewed assets will be mispriced. In
CE
the case of a positively skewed asset, investors would not be willing to short much of that
asset, as it would expose them to the possibility of a large negative return, and since these
AC
investors overweigh the probability of these negative events occurring, they would find short
position in positively skewed asset very unattractive unless they receive a premium for
exposing themselves to this risk. Likewise, investors with cumulative prospect theory
preferences would not prefer to hold negatively skewed assets, but actually prefer to short
those assets (as that would essentially expose them to positive skewness). This suggests that
even in the case where short-selling is allowed (as in commodity futures markets), we would
6
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
observe that negatively skewed assets end up being underpriced, while positively skewed
assets become overpriced. In our context, commodity investors may have preferences for
positive skewed commodities or utility functions with cumulative prospect theory preferences
that make them overprice (underprice) contracts with positive (negative) skewness. Therefore,
we expect to see a negative relationship between skewness and commodity expected returns.
IP
T
A potential mechanism through which skewness preferences could affect commodity
prices is selective hedging (see Stulz, 1996). Selective hedging is a practice in which the risk
US
CR
manager’s view of future price movements influences the percentage of the exposure that is
hedged. In this case, commercial traders do not fully hedge their positions; rather their
hedging strategies incorporate a speculative component that depends on their anticipation of
AN
forthcoming price changes.
In this sense, if hedgers form preferences based on cumulative prospect theory (Barberis
M
and Huang, 2008) or in general have skewness-based preferences (Gilbert et al., 2006), they
will favor an overall position (underlying plus hedge) that minimizes risk and at the same
PT
ED
time maximizes skewness. For a short hedger (or producer), a positively skewed position in
the commodity will result in a short futures position that falls short of her minimum variance
hedge ratio (as taking a full short hedge would remove the positive skewness that the hedger
CE
seeks). Likewise, a long hedger (or consumer) in a positively skewed commodity will have a
hedging demand that exceeds her minimum variance hedge ratio (as she then reverts the
AC
negative skewness she is exposed to in the underlying into a positive skewness). This implies
that from a hedging demand side, we expect to see more net long hedging demand in
positively skewed assets which makes them overpriced. Reversing the argument, we expect to
see more net short hedging demand in negatively skewed assets which makes them
underpriced.
7
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Recent hedging literature highlights this potential mechanism. For instance, Gilbert et al.
(2006) develop an optimal hedging model where hedgers care about mean, variance and
skewness of the expected profit distribution (which include the positions in the spot and
futures contracts) through a negative exponential utility function, and compare this with the
optimal hedging positions under a mean-variance utility framework. Under the assumption
IP
T
that the futures price is a biased estimate of the expected future spot price, they demonstrate
that positive skewness reduces the short hedging, and likewise, a negative skewness of the
US
CR
spot prices increases the short hedging. Lien and Wang (2015) show that under the
assumption of a skewed Student t-distribution for the spot price and negative exponential
utility for the producer, the producers will hedge more (less) when negative (positive)
AN
skewness prevails compared with a mean-variance hedger. In both papers, skewness of the
PT
ED
3. Data and Pricing Models
M
underlying has an effect on the hedgers’ hedging positions and thus the demand for futures.
3.1. Description of Commodity Futures Data
Our main data for the analysis are daily settlement prices from Datastream on front-end and
second-nearest futures contracts for 27 commodities from distinct sectors: agriculture (cocoa,
CE
coffee C, corn, cotton n°2, frozen concentrated orange juice, oats, rough rice, soybean meal,
AC
soybean oil, soybeans, sugar n°11, wheat), energy (electricity, gasoline, heating oil n°2, light
sweet crude oil, natural gas), livestock (feeder cattle, frozen pork bellies, lean hogs, live
cattle), metal (copper, gold, palladium, platinum, silver), and random length lumber. Returns
are changes in log prices of the front-end contract up to one month before maturity; we then
roll to the second-nearest contract. The sample period is January 1987 to November 2014.
We compute the Pearson’s moment coefficient of skewness of each commodity at monthend t using the daily return history in the preceding 12-month window
8
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
̂
where
[ ∑
(
̂ ) ] ̂
are the daily returns of the ith commodity,
observations within the [t-11, t] window, and the parameters ̂
=[
∑
(
(1)
is the number of daily
∑
and ̂
̂ ) ] are the mean and variance estimates of the daily return
IP
T
distribution, respectively. The higher the absolute value of the skewness measure, the more
asymmetric the distribution.
US
CR
Figure 1 plots for illustrative commodities from each sector (corn, crude oil, gold and
feeder cattle) the evolution of ̂
alongside the 95% confidence bands; the legend of the
significant ̂
. Table I summarizes the distribution of skewness of
and ̂
AN
graph summarizes for each commodity i the percentage of sample months t=1,…,T with
individual commodity futures returns by providing the mean, 25th quantile, median (50th
where T are the sample months.
M
quantile), 75th quantile and standard deviation of ̂
[Insert Figure 1 and Table I around here]
PT
ED
The graphs in Figure 1, along with the standard deviation and 25th versus 75th percentile
statistics in Table I, show that, despite the overlapping nature of the 12-month observation
windows of daily data used to compute ̂
(at a monthly rolling frequency), the
CE
skewness of commodity futures returns varies considerably over time, changing sign too. The
percentage of months when the skewness coefficient attains a positive (negative) value ranges
AC
between 20% and 71% (29% and 80%) across the 27 commodities and averages 43% (57%).4
3.2. Commodity Risk Factors
4
Commodity futures prices are observationally equivalent to non-stationary process and therefore the
moments may not be constant. Effectively, this means that the skewness of the price distribution is
potentially problematic as it may not converge to any meaningful value as D increases.
9
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
To properly address the question of whether skewness matters, we place our forthcoming
time-series and cross-sectional analyses in the context of a baseline and augmented
commodity pricing models as outlined next in Sections 3.2.1 and 3.2.2, respectively. Section
3.2.3 discusses various summary statistics for the set of commodity risk factors employed.
IP
T
3.2.1. Baseline Commodity Pricing Model
Bakshi et al. (2017) construct three systematic risk factors as the excess returns of an equally-
US
CR
weighted long-only portfolio of all commodity futures (EW factor, hereafter) that they refer to
as the average commodity factor, a term structure portfolio (TS) and a momentum portfolio
(Mom). Basu and Miffre (2013) advocate a hedging pressure (HP) factor. Whereas the EW
factor is meant to capture overall commodity market risk, the TS, Mom and HP factors proxy
AN
for the risks associated with the backwardation/contango cycle of commodity futures markets.
The beta-expected return representation of the baseline four-factor model can be written as
)
PT
ED
where i is a commodity futures,
(2)
M
(
are the risk factors,
collects the vector of factor risk premia, which is common to all
commodities, and
are the commodity-specific factor
CE
betas or loadings which represent scaled conditional covariances.
The EW portfolio is a long-only, equally-weighted and monthly-rebalanced portfolio of
AC
all commodity futures. The factors, referred to as TS, Mom and HP, are the excess returns of
long-short fully-collateralized portfolios of commodity futures that long (short) the most
backwardated (contangoed) quintile. The TS and HP risk factors are directly motivated by the
theories of storage and hedging pressure, respectively. The Mom factor can also be motivated,
albeit indirectly, by the theory of storage. For most commodities, the replenishing of scarce
inventories through production in backwardated markets or the depletion of abundant
inventories through consumption in contangoed markets is a lengthy process during which
10
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
price continuation will occur. To put it differently, scarce (backwardated) commodities are
likely to be momentum winners and abundant (contangoed) commodities are likely to be
momentum losers (Miffre and Rallis, 2007; Gorton et al., 2013).
To construct the TS, Mom and HP risk factors, we average the following signals over a
prior 12-month ranking period and hold the long-short portfolios on a fully-collateralized
IP
T
basis for a month. The signal employed in the construction of the long-short TS portfolio is
the roll yield measured for each commodity as the daily difference in the logarithmic prices of
US
CR
the front-end and second-nearest contracts; the portfolio buys (and simultaneously sells) the
quintile with highest (lowest) average roll-yield over the previous 12 months. The long-short
Mom portfolio is based on past performance over the past 12 months; the portfolio buys
AN
(sells) the quintile with highest (lowest) average return over the previous 12 months. Finally,
the pertinent signal for the construction of the long-short HP portfolio is the hedgers’ and
M
speculators’ hedging pressure measured for each commodity as
PT
ED
, respectively; where
(
) and
and
(
) denote the
open interests of long and short hedgers (speculators), respectively;5 the long-short HP
portfolio buys (sells) the quintile with the lowest (highest)
and highest (lowest)
. The
CE
time span of our sample together with the choice of ranking period imply that we obtain
monthly observations for the risk factors from January 1987 to November 2014. The choice
AC
of a “long” ranking period of 12 months is motivated by the slow evolution of the
backwardation/contango cycle as suggested by the theory of storage and hedging pressure
hypothesis (e.g., Gorton et al., 2013).
5
The Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) classifies traders based on the size of their
positions as large (reportable) or small (non-reportable). The reportable category accounts for 76% of
long open interest and 80% of short open interest on average across commodities in our sample period.
Non-reportable traders are not required to specify the motives of their positions but reportable traders
have to inform the CFTC as to whether they are commercial (hedgers) or non-commercial
(speculators) participants. These declarations are checked, summarized in the Aggregated
Commitment of Traders Report and published on the CFTC website going back to January 1986.
11
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
3.2.2. Augmented Commodity Pricing Models
We augment the baseline commodity pricing model (featuring the
,
,
and
factors) with a set of factors that is deemed to explain the pricing of commodity futures (Hong
and Yogo, 2012; Asness et al., 2013; Szymanowska et al., 2014). This set of additional
systematic factors that may price commodity futures includes i) a liquidity risk factor based
IP
T
on (as sorting signal) the daily Amihud et al.’s (1997) dollar volume to absolute return ratio
averaged over the two most recent months, ii) an open interest (∆OI) factor deemed to capture
US
CR
future price inflation and based on the changes in the open interest of individual commodities
at the time of portfolio formation, iii) an inflation factor constructed according to the slope
coefficient β of prior 60-month regressions of monthly commodity futures returns on
AN
unexpected inflation measured as the change in one-month U.S. CPI inflation rate, iv) a
currency risk factor constructed according to the slope coefficient β of prior 60-month
M
regressions of monthly commodity futures returns on the changes in the U.S. dollar versus a
basket of foreign currencies, iv) a value factor that picks up long-run mean reversion by
PT
ED
sorting commodities on the log of the average daily front-end futures prices from 4.5 to 5.5
years ago divided by the log of the front-end futures price at time t, and vi) a volatility factor,
net of the momentum effect, constructed as the coefficient of variation (CV) of daily futures
CE
returns over the prior 36 months. The literature has shown that contracts with low liquidity,
rising OI, high inflation betas, low dollar betas, high value and high CV outperform those at
AC
the other extreme (Erb and Harvey, 2006; Hong and Yogo, 2012; Asness et al., 2013;
Szymanowska et al., 2014).
Similar to our definition of TS, Mom and HP factors, these additional systematic factors
are defined as the excess returns of long-short quintiles with the long and short positions held
for one month on a fully-collateralized basis. Appendix A provides further details.
3.2.3. Descriptive Statistics for the Risk Factors
12
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Table II presents descriptive statistics for the risk factors employed in the paper. Beginning
with the commodity risk factors, the results confirm the importance of capturing the phases of
backwardation and contango when modelling the risk premium of commodity futures. Over
the period January 1987 to November 2014, the TS, Mom and HP portfolios outperform all
other commodity portfolios. For example, the mean excess returns of the TS, Mom and HP-
IP
T
sorted portfolios range from 4.63% to 8.95% p.a., all of which are significant at the 5% level
or better. In sharp contrast, the other commodity portfolios earn at best 3.52% p.a. and none
US
CR
of the mean excess returns is significant at the 10% level. The risk-adjusted performance
metrics reported in Table II, Sharpe and Omega ratios, unanimously confirm the
outperformance of the TS, Mom and HP portfolios among all commodity portfolios.6 Panel C
AN
of Table II reports summary statistics for the S&P-GSCI, the well-known equity (market
portfolio, SMB, HML and UMD) risk factors and bond (Barclays) risk factor, which we
M
eventually employ in various robustness checks. Appendix B shows that the pairwise
correlations amongst the other long-short factors are small. This motivates their joint
PT
ED
inclusion into the various pricing models employed.
[Insert Table II around here]
CE
4. Time-Series Portfolio Setting
4.1. Characteristics of Skewness-Sorted Portfolios
AC
We conduct time-series tests of the relationship between commodity futures skewness and
expected returns using a long-short portfolio approach. To do so, at the end of each month, t,
6
Additional summary statistics computed separately for the long and short portfolios confirm the
stylized fact that backwardated (contangoed) contracts appreciate (depreciate) in value. For
concreteness, the long TS, Mom and HP portfolios earn positive mean excess returns of 4.24% (tstatistic of 1.05), 7.41% (t-statistic of 1.61) and 2.29% (t-statistic of 0.58) p.a., respectively; while the
short TS, Mom and HP portfolios earn negative mean excess returns of -5.03% (t-statistic of -1.36), 10.49% (t-statistic of -2.54) and -9.28% (t-statistic of -2.53) p.a., respectively. Since the long-short
portfolios are fully collateralized their return is half that of the longs minus half that of the shorts.
13
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
we estimate the Pearson’s moment coefficient of skewness ( ̂ ) of the daily return
distribution of commodity
using the data available within the most recent month
t-11 to month t window.7 Then at each month-end t, we rank the i = 1,…,N commodities in
the cross-section (N = 27) according to their ̂
values and group them into five portfolios
or quintiles; quintile Q1 contains the 20% of commodities with the lowest ̂ , and so forth,
IP
T
up to quintile Q5 that contains the 20% of commodities with the highest ̂ .
US
CR
We start by examining some of the properties of the skewness portfolios by looking at the
characteristics of the different quintiles. Table III summarizes the results with Panel A
focusing on the pre-ranking skewness of the quintiles. Since this is precisely the signal used to
group the commodities into quintiles, it is not surprising to see that ̅̅̅ is negative for Q1 at -
AN
0.73 and positive for Q5 at 0.54, and the differential ̅̅̅
̅̅̅
is strongly significant at the
column of the table.
M
1% level as suggested by the Newey-West (1987) h.a.c. robust t-statistic reported in the last
PT
ED
[Insert Table III around here]
Then we turn attention to four signals – roll-yield, past performance, hedgers’ hedging
pressure and speculators’ hedging pressure – that are well-known to capture the
backwardation and contango cycle. The signals are measured at each month-end t over the
CE
same 12-month rolling observation windows as the ̂
signal, and the statistics reported are
AC
again averages. The main conclusion that can be gleaned from Panel B of Table III is that the
constituents of Q1 present backwardated characteristics such as higher roll-yield, better
performance, higher speculators’ hedging pressure and lower hedgers’ hedging pressure. Vice
versa, the constituents of Q5 present contangoed characteristics such as lower roll-yield, worst
7
For expositional clarity, throughout the paper our skewness signal is obtained employing a ranking
period R=12 months and a holding period H=1 month. Nevertheless, in additional unreported results,
we considered different ranking and holding periods R={6, 36, 60, 96} and H={3, 6, 12}. The main
empirical findings remain unchallenged. Detailed results are available upon request.
14
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
past performance, lower speculators’ hedging pressure and higher hedgers’ hedging pressure.
The difference in roll-yield between Q1 and Q5 is highly significant at the 1% level; likewise
for hedgers’ hedging pressure and speculators’ hedging pressure. For these three signals, there
are clear monotonic patterns across quintiles; e.g., the speculators’ hedging pressure decreases
without exception from 0.6570 for the most negative-skew commodities (Q1) to 0.5848 for
IP
T
the most positive-skew commodities (Q5). The difference in past performance (excess return
p.a.) across Q1 and Q5 is also significant albeit only at the 10% level. Hence, in assessing
US
CR
whether skewness contains information about expected returns, we need to control for these
traditional risk factors.
AN
4.2. Summary Statistics for the Performance of the Skewness-Sorted Portfolios
Figure 2 illustrates the cumulative logarithmic returns (
∑
) of each
M
skewness-sorted quintile. Monotonically, the end-of-period cumulative returns of the
skewness quintiles are inversely related to the degree of skewness; that is,
PT
ED
. For concreteness, the end-of-period cumulative return of the most negativelyskewed portfolio Q1 amounts to a gain of about 150% (or 5.12% p.a.) whereas that of the
CE
most positively-skewed portfolio Q5 amounts to a loss of about 300% (or 10.89% p.a.).
[Insert Figure 2 around here]
A potential concern that one could raise is that the returns of the different quintile
AC
portfolios could be driven by a few commodities that persistently end up in the high or low
skewness portfolios. To address this concern, Figure 3 shows the frequency of portfolio
formation months t = 1,…,T that each commodity enters the long (Q1) and short (Q5)
portfolio per sector. None of the frequencies comes near 100% (most below 50%) which
confirms that none of the commodities is perpetually part of the Q1 or Q5 portfolios; in other
15
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
words, different commodities enter the extreme (most positive or negative) skewness
portfolios over time.
[Insert Figure 3 around here]
The observation that commodities in Q5 outperform those in Q1 as observed in Figure 2
motivates us to examine a commodity skewness trading strategy: a monthly-rebalanced “low-
IP
T
minus-high skewness” portfolio (or long-short skewness portfolio, hereafter) that buys Q1 and
shorts Q5. Table IV summarizes the 1-month returns accrued by the individual long-only
US
CR
(quintiles) portfolios and by the long-short skewness portfolio. All portfolios are fullycollateralized and returns are in excess of the risk-free rate.
[Insert Table IV around here]
AN
Panel A of Table IV shows that mean excess returns decrease monotonically from the
most negatively (Q1) to the most positively skewed portfolio (Q5). The mean excess return of
M
Q1 is positive at 5.12% a year (Newey-West t-statistic of 1.42), and that of Q5 is negative at 10.89% a year (Newey-West t-statistic of -3.35). With regards to risk, the standard deviation
PT
ED
of Q1 is larger than that of Q5. In terms of risk-adjusted performance, and as consistently
suggested by the Sharpe, Sortino and Omega ratios, portfolio Q1 outperforms portfolio Q2,
portfolio Q2 outperforms portfolio Q3, and so forth in a monotonic fashion. As the
CE
penultimate column of Table IV reveals, taking simultaneous fully-collateralized long
positions in the most negative-skew commodities (Q1) and short positions in the most
AC
positive-skew commodities (Q5) at each month-end t of the sample period yields a mean
excess return of 8.01% a year (Newey-West t-statistic of 3.83), a Sharpe ratio of 0.7848 and
an Omega ratio of 1.8136. We should note that these performance measures are better than
16
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
those of the long-short TS, Mom and HP portfolios typically used as risk factors in the
literature on commodity futures pricing (c.f., Table II).8
The performance of the long-short portfolios appears to be more driven by the relatively
large negative return and low volatility of the shorts (Q5) than by the lesser positive return
and higher volatility of the longs (Q1). The performance of the fully-collateralized long-short
IP
T
skewness portfolio is quite alluring both relatively-speaking (i.e., compared to each of the
individual, long-only Q1 to Q5 portfolios) and absolutely due to its high 8.01% excess return
US
CR
p.a., low risk (e.g., low volatility, 99% VaR, and maximum drawdown), and high Sharpe,
Sortino and Omega ratios. These results show that the skew of the distribution of daily
commodity futures returns conveys information about subsequent returns; namely, there is a
AN
significantly negative relation between skewness and expected returns.9
Panel A of Table IV also reports the average post-ranking skewness of the quintile
M
returns, where the latter is measured by first calculating the skewness of each constituent
using daily returns in the holding period and then averaging these skewness measures for a
PT
ED
given quintile across constituents and over time. Relative to the pre-ranking skewness
reported in Panel A of Table III, the post-ranking skewness measures do not rise
monotonically from Q1 to Q5 and show little variation across quintiles (range of [-0.10, -
CE
0.01] for the post-ranking skewness versus [-0.73, 0.54] for the pre-ranking skewness). Panel
AC
A of Table IV also reports the skewness of portfolio returns per quintile and again we do not
8
Inspired by Harvey and Siddique (2000) and other studies in the equity market literature, we sort
commodities into quintiles based on their co-skewness with a market proxy M made of 90% of stocks
and 10% of commodities (the co-skewness signal is the slope coefficient on the M² returns in a
regression of daily commodity futures returns onto M and M² returns). The long-short systematic coskewness portfolio yields a Sharpe ratio of 0.1132, which is much lower than that reported in Table IV
(0.7848). The skewness signal, Equation (1), therefore conveys more information about expected
commodity futures returns than co-skewness.
We filter out from Q1 (Q5) those commodities with non-negative (non-positive) ̂ . The
performance measures for the resulting long-short portfolio are nearly identical to those reported in
Table IV, e.g. a mean excess return of 7.93%, Sharpe ratio of 0.78 and Omega ratio of 1.80.
9
17
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
observe any monotonic increase in skewness going from Q1 to Q5. These results are in line
with the observations in Figures 1 and 3 and show that commodity skewness is time-varying,
which leads to different commodities making up the extreme quintiles over time.
Overall, Table IV demonstrates that positively (negatively) skewed commodities
underperform (outperform), which is in line with the skewness preference theories discussed
IP
T
in Section 2. These results are also consistent with the notion that commercial participants
engage in selective hedging and, for example, take longer hedging positions in positively
US
CR
skewed commodities to reflect upon their preference for positive skewness. As a result these
positively-skewed commodities become overpriced and subsequently underperform.
AN
4.3. Alpha and Factor Decomposition
Seeking to ascertain whether the profitability of the skewness portfolios is merely a
M
compensation for exposure to commodity risk factors, we measure the alpha of the skewness
PT
ED
trading strategy relative to the baseline four-factor commodity pricing model
where
(3)
denotes the month t return of either the long-short skewness portfolio or the
individual long-only Q1 to Q5 portfolios. The parameter vector (
is
CE
estimated by Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) and inferences are based on Newey-West robust
t-statistics. Table IV, Panel B, presents the results. Q1 (Q5) has positive (negative) loadings
AC
on the TS and HP risk factors, albeit they are only significant for the Q1 regression. The sign
of these loadings suggests that the negative-skew quintile Q1 tends to display more
backwardated characteristics than the positive-skew quintile Q5. Accordingly, the TS and HP
risk loadings in the long-short skewness portfolio are positive but only the beta of the TS risk
factor is significant as suggested by a robust t-statistic of 2.74.
18
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
The most important finding is that the baseline four-factor model cannot fully explain the
outperformance of Q1 and the underperformance of Q5. The alphas of the five skewness
quintiles decrease monotonically from 4.28% a year (t-statistic of 1.79) for Q1 to -8.89% a
year (t-statistic of -3.96) for Q5. The risk-adjusted excess return of the fully-collateralized
long-short skewness portfolio is a non-negligible 6.58% a year (t-statistic of 3.58). This
account for the possibility of non-normality in the alpha distribution.10
IP
T
inference is not challenged when we employ bootstrap p-values (reported in curly brackets) to
US
CR
The alpha of 6.58% p.a. accrued by the long-short skewness portfolio is not much smaller
than its mean excess return of 8.01% p.a. (Panel A of Table IV). This suggests that the
outperformance of the long-short skewness portfolio is not merely compensation for exposure
AN
to the backwardation and contango risk factors. This result is confirmed by the low adjustedR² of the four-factor benchmark fitted to the long-short skewness portfolio returns (5.66%)
M
and by the low correlations between the skewness excess returns and the TS, Mom and HP
PT
ED
factors (in the last row of Appendix B).
4.4. Robustness Tests
We now assess the robustness of the performance of the long-short skewness portfolio to
CE
various considerations. We begin by addressing the time-dependence issue by carrying out
conditional tests in the same spirit of Lewellen and Nagel (2006). To visualize the time-
AC
variation in the alpha, we deploy the long-short portfolio strategy based on the ̂
signal
We construct B=10,000 sequences of bootstrap residuals, { ̂
,
, by concatenating
random blocks (length M) drawn from the residuals of regression (3). Using these artificial residuals
and the original regression parameter estimates we simulate B time-series of portfolio returns under
the null hypothesis (
and then re-estimate regression (3) with each of them. The bootstrap p∑ ̂
value is
̂
̂
̂
̂ where
̂
with ̂ and ̂
the original
estimate and the estimates of alpha over bootstrap replications, respectively. We empirically verify
that M=10 suffices to obtain B sequences of bootstrap residuals with similar autocorrelation properties
(average 1st order autocorrelation 0.25) as the sequence of original residuals (1 st order autocorrelation
0.28).
10
19
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
over seven-year subsamples that are rolled forward monthly. Figure 4 plots the alphas
together with 95% confidence bands based on Newey-West standard errors. The magnitude of
the alpha changes over time as one would expect but the significance of the alpha is quite
pervasive. Consistent with the preceding unconditional results, the average conditional alpha
is positive and significant at 8.53% a year (Newey-West t-statistic of 21.74).
IP
T
[Insert Figure 4 around here]
Table V shows the annualized alphas of long-short skewness-sorted portfolios for various
US
CR
additional tests, their corresponding Newey-West significance t-statistics in parentheses and
bootstrap p-values in curly brackets. We begin by measuring the commodity skewness,
Equation (1), at the end of each month t using filtered-returns instead of observed returns as
AN
until now. These filtered returns are residuals of regressions of the daily commodity futures
excess returns spanned in [t-11, t] windows on an intercept and i) the baseline four systematic
M
risk factors, ii) business cycle indicators11 and/or iii) calendar-month dummies (deemed to
capture seasonality in supply and demand). We then proceed as before and form long-short
PT
ED
portfolios by sorting commodities according to the thus-obtained skewness ̂ . The results
in Panel A of Table V indicate that the alphas of the long-short
-sorted portfolios remain
economically sizeable and statistically significant. Altogether, this first batch of robustness
CE
checks suggest that the negative skewness-expected return relation uncovered is not driven by
exposure to backwardation and contango, the ups and downs of the business cycle and the
AC
phases of production and consumption.
[Insert Table V around here]
11
Following the literature, the business cycle indicators are the default spread (yield differential
between BAA and AAA bonds), TED spread (3-month LIBOR minus 3-month T-bill rate), term
spread (10-year T-bond minus 3-month T-bill yield), daily change in VXO index and, given our
commodity focus, the change in the Baltic Dry index (Bakshi et al., 2012). Interest rates and VXO
data are obtained from the FED and CBOE websites, respectively, and Baltic Dry Index from
Bloomberg.
20
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
In Panel B, we measure the alpha of the long-short skewness strategy with reference to i)
a four-factor model that employs the long-only S&P-GSCI returns (instead of the EW
portfolio returns) as proxy for the overall commodity market portfolio, and ii) augmented
versions of the baseline pricing model that includes additional systematic risk factors. We add
the additional factors described in Section 3.2.2, in turn, and also estimate “kitchen sink”
IP
T
pricing models that features all systematic factors. The sign and significance of the resulting
alphas are not challenged by these benchmark re-specifications. For completeness, the bottom
US
CR
part of Panel B reports the alpha of the long-short skewness portfolio relative to traditional
pricing models employed in the equity market and bond market literatures which remain
sizable.
AN
Our next batch of robustness tests, reported in Panel C of Table V, addresses liquidity
and transaction costs issues. To address concerns relating to illiquidity, we systematically
M
exclude at each formation point the 20% of commodities with the lowest liquidity according
to the Amihud et al. (1997) measure and reconstruct the long-short skewness portfolios on the
PT
ED
remaining cross-section. The alpha of the resulting long-short portfolio relative to the baseline
four-factor model remains positive and significant. To address matters pertaining to
transaction costs, we calculate the alpha of the long-short skewness portfolio after subtracting
CE
from traded returns twice the transaction cost estimate of Locke and Venkatesh (1997) or
twice 0.033%. We also calculate the break-even transaction cost (or cost per trade that would
AC
be needed to wipe out all excess returns) of the skewness strategy and find it equal to 0.933%.
Both of these tests show that transaction costs have a negligible effect on skewness profits.
Taken altogether, the robustness tests presented in this section suggest that the effect of
skewness on expected returns is robust to how skewness is measured, alternative asset pricing
model and illiquidity and transaction costs.
21
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
5. Cross-sectional Asset Pricing Tests
The time-series evidence presented in the previous section motivates us to ask whether a
tradeable skewness factor can explain the cross-section of commodity futures over and above
well-known commodity risk factors.
IP
T
5.1. Tradeable Skewness Factor
In this section we test whether the tradeable skewness factor calculated as the difference in
US
CR
returns between Q1 and Q5 explains the cross-section of excess returns for individual
commodity futures. For expositional clarity, we use the notation
for the tradeable skewness
factor to distinguish it from the commodity-specific skewness signal denoted
. Let the
AN
baseline representation of the pricing model be formalized as in Equation (2). We re-specify it
by adding the tradeable skewness factor as follows
)
(4)
M
(
PT
ED
and estimate both models (baseline and augmented) by OLS using the Fama and MacBeth
(1973) approach. Accordingly, we estimate pass-one time-series regressions month-by-month
(daily data) to obtain the commodity sensitivities or monthly betas to the risk factors
the number of days in month t. Then we estimate the pass-two cross-sectional
CE
with
(5)
AC
regression
̂
̂
(6)
on each month (t=1,…,T) of the sample period. We report the average lambdas of the pass-
two cross-sectional regression (6) which includes the skewness factor, and of the counterpart
regression without the skewness factor,
̂
. We also compare the
explanatory power of both pass-two regressions and test the statistical significance of the
22
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
price of skewness,
̅
, using Shanken’s (1992) t-statistics. We repeat these cross-
sectional pricing tests by augmenting Equation (2) with the factors discussed in Section 3.2.2.
Table VI presents the pass-two cross-sectional estimation results. Model A focuses on the
baseline four-factor model, Models B to H consider additional systematic risk. The most
striking and novel result of Table VI is the pervasive rejection of the hypothesis that the
of skewness priced factor
IP
T
tradable skewness factor is not priced at the 5% significance level or better. The average price
equals 0.0042 a month or 5.02% p.a. Thus, investors demand a
US
CR
higher compensation or premium for exposure to commodity futures with lower levels of
skewness. Albeit small, we notice a systematic increase in explanatory power when switching
from a given pricing model to an extended version thereof that includes the tradeable
AN
skewness factor. On average, explanatory power in Table VI rises from 31.77% to 35.26% or
by 3.5%. This increase in adjusted R-square is similar to that obtained in equity markets
M
(Chang et al., 2013).
[Insert Table VI around here]
PT
ED
The conclusion that skewness is priced cross-sectionally holds within the baseline pricing
model that captures the phases of backwardation and contango (Model A) and shows that
skewness is not merely another proxy for the phases of backwardation and contango. The
CE
Mom and HP risk factors relating to the fundamentals of backwardation and contango are
found to pervasively price the cross-section of commodity returns. On average
and
AC
equal 0.0040 and 0.0035 per month which amount to annualized risk premia of 4.76% and
4.17%, respectively. This result, alongside the insignificance of the price of risk associated
with the long-only EW risk factor, stresses the wisdom that the risk premia of commodity
futures markets can only be captured in a long-short portfolio setting. These results align well
with the summary statistics reported in Table II and with the literature (e.g., Basu and Miffre,
2013). The “kitchen sink” model (Model H) explains close to 50% of the cross-sectional
23
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
variation in the excess returns of individual commodities. Altogether four risk factors are
found to have significant pricing power at the 10% level or better; these are based on
skewness, momentum, hedging pressure, and value. In comparison to other factors, the
skewness factor is found to command the most significant and largest premium.12
5.2. Robustness Checks
IP
T
We first deploy the Fama-McBeth two-step regressions conditionally using seven-year rolling
windows. The focus is on Equation (6), referred to as Model A in Table VI, and the parameter
together with 95%
US
CR
of interest is the price of the skewness factor. Figure 5 plots the ̂
confidence bands based on the Shanken (1992) standard errors. The price of skewness ̂
is
not constant over time, as one would expect, but it is generally positive.
AN
[Insert Figure 5 around here]
Table VII shows additional analyses conducted to assess the robustness of the previous
M
cross-sectional results. For this purpose, first we alter the signal used to construct the
tradeable skewness factor in Panel A constraining the analysis to the baseline pricing model
PT
ED
(Model A of Table VI). Second, we use the same skewness signal, Equation (1), but alter the
pricing model in Panel B. The table reports the average cross-sectional price of skewness
factor ̅ and the significance Shanken’s (1992) robust t-statistic. The last two columns in
CE
each panel are the explanatory power of the pricing model and its simpler version without the
AC
tradable skewness factor.
[Insert Table VII around here]
As shown in Panel A, when the tradeable skewness factor is constructed using the daily
commodity futures returns stripped of i) the systematic
and
risks; ii)
12
We also consider the 29 commodity portfolios formed by sorting the commodities into quintiles
using skewness, roll-yield, past performance, hedgers’ hedging pressure or speculators’ hedging
pressure signals, and 4 additional sector portfolios – agriculture, energy, livestock and metal – that
monthly-rebalance and equally-weight constituent commodities. The skewness factor is significantly
positively priced with an average price of 0.0063 a month or 7.52% p.a..
24
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
business cycle; or iii) monthly seasonality, reassuringly, the significantly positive price of
skewness factor is not challenged. These cross-sectional results reinforce the evidence from
the time-series portfolio analysis in Section 4 leading us to more firmly assert that the
skewness signal is not simply a manifestation of (and thus it conveys information beyond) the
phases of backwardation and contango. The information content of skewness is not an artifact
IP
T
either of the ups-and-downs of the business cycle nor of seasonality in supply and demand.
Panel B of Table VII shows that replacing the EW portfolio with the S&P-GSCI portfolio
US
CR
as alternative proxy for the average commodity factor or using traditional pricing models
emanating from the equity and bond literature does not qualitatively alter the findings on the
skewness factor pricing. Overall, Table VII confirms the previous results (c.f., Table VI) that
AN
the tradable skewness factor is significantly positively priced at 0.0044 or 5.23% p.a. on
average. Adding the skewness factor to a given pricing model increases explanatory power by
M
4.05% on average.
Finally, we run additional cross-sectional regressions that include the original
PT
ED
characteristics instead of the factor loadings in the second step of the Fama-McBeth
regressions. Taking, for example, the baseline model, this amounts to replacing the slope
in (4) by lagged characteristics such as roll-yield, futures returns, hedgers’ and
vector
CE
speculators’ hedging pressure as averaged over the previous 12 months. Table VII, Panel C
reports ̅ , the average slope coefficient obtained in the second stage on the skewness signal,
AC
its associated Newey-West t-statistic, as well as the adjusted-R² of models that include and
exclude the skewness signal. Irrespective of the specification considered, the skewness signal
is negatively priced corroborating once again the presence of a negative relationship between
skewness and expected returns. Its inclusion in the pricing equation raises explanatory power
systematically throughout models but only slightly (by an average of 1.41%).
25
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
6. Conclusions
This article studies the relationship between past skewness and expected returns in
commodity futures markets, providing an important out-of-sample test on this relation
observed in equities. Using a time-series portfolio analysis and cross-sectional pricing tests,
we demonstrate that the skewness of commodity futures returns contains information about
IP
T
subsequent returns and, in particular, the direction suggests a negative skewness-expected
returns relation. A tradeable skewness factor that buys the most negatively-skewed
US
CR
commodities and shorts the most positively-skewed commodities commands a premium that
is economically and statistically larger than the risk premiums previously identified. The
long-short skewness portfolio earns a sizeable alpha relative to a battery of benchmarks
AN
deemed to capture commodity risk factors. Through cross-sectional pricing tests, the paper
further establishes that the tradable skewness factor commands a positive premium that is
M
more sizeable and more significant than any of the risk factors thus far considered in the
literature.
PT
ED
We document that traditional commodity risk factors cannot explain the excess returns
generated by the skewness strategy, suggesting that skewness is not another proxy for the
fundamentals of backwardation and contango in commodity futures. Our findings are thus in
CE
line with the literature on skewness preferences, and specifically provide evidence for
investors with cumulative prospect theory preferences and selective hedging practices in
AC
commodity markets.
To gain better understanding of the reasons behind the pricing of skewness, we see it as
interesting to study, in the spirit of Moskowitz et al. (2012), Asness et al. (2013) or Koijen et
al. (2017), skewness profits and drawdowns across asset classes.
26
IP
T
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
This table provides definitions and data sources for the risk factors utilized in the paper.
Name
Definition
US
CR
Appendix A. Description of the risk factors.
AN
Panel A: Baseline four-factor model
EW
Excess return of equally-weighted long-only monthly-rebalanced portfolio of commodity futures
TS
Excess return of long-short portfolio sorted by prior 12-month roll yield
Mom
Excess return of long-short portfolio sorted by prior 12-month excess returns
HP
Excess return of long-short portfolio double-sorted by prior 12-month speculators' and hedgers' hedging pressure
PT
ED
M
Panel B: Other systematic risk factors
Liquidity
Excess return of long-short portfolio sorted by prior 2-month dollar volume over absolute return
∆OI
Excess return of long-short portfolio sorted by changes in current total open interest along entire term structure
Inflation b
Excess return of long-short porfolio sorted by β of 60-month regression of commodity futures returns on unexpected inflation
Dollar b
Excess return of long-short porfolio sorted by β of 60-month regression of commodity futures returns on effective US dollar
changes versus a basket of foreign currencies
Value
Excess return of long-short portfolio sorted on value, defined as the ratio of the log of the average daily front-end futures prices
from 4.5 to 5.5 years ago divided by the front-end log futures price at time t
CV
Excess return of long-short portfolio sorted by variance-over-mean of daily futures returns over prior 36 months
AC
CE
Panel C: Traditional risk factors motivated by the equity, fixed income and commodity literature
S&P-GSCI
S&P-GSCI excess return index
EqMkt
Excess value-weighted return of all CRSP US firms listed on the NYSE, AMEX, or NASDAQ
SMB
Small-minus-large or size factor (difference in returns between small and large capitalization stocks)
HML
High-minus-low or value factor (difference in returns between high and low book-to-market stocks)
UMD
Up-minus-down or equity momentum factor (difference in returns between winner and loser stocks)
Bond
Excess returns on the Barclays US Aggregate Bond Index
Data source
Datastream
Datastream
Datastream
CTFC
Datastream
Datastream
FED
FED
Datastream
Datastream
Datastream
K.R. French's website
K.R. French's website
K.R. French's website
K.R. French's website
Bloomberg
27
IP
T
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
US
CR
Appendix B. Pairwise correlations among monthly factors.
The table reports Pearson correlation coefficients for the factors described in Table II and Table IV (Q1-Q5). Appendix A provides a detailed
description of all the risk factors. Bold signifies significance at the 10% level or better. The sample observations for the estimation are monthly returns
from January 1987 to November 2014.
0.05
0.00
0.19
0.16
-0.23
0.11
0.15
-0.08
0.24
0.15
-0.30
0.16
-0.02
-0.17
0.14
0.01
-0.42
0.20
-0.26
0.06
-0.08
0.13
-0.31
0.18
-0.05
0.33
0.05
-0.01
-0.01
-0.06
-0.08
0.08
0.06
S&P-GSCI
EqMkt
SMB
HML
UMD
Bond
Skewness
0.74
0.26
0.09
0.01
-0.05
0.01
0.07
0.23
0.08
0.14
-0.09
0.07
-0.01
0.21
0.21
0.02
0.11
0.02
0.20
0.05
0.10
-0.07
0.04
0.15
-0.06
-0.05
0.03
0.15
0.34
0.02
-0.02
-0.01
0.08
-0.10
0.09
-0.03
0.02
-0.02
-0.14
0.02
-0.06
-0.14
PT
ED
CE
AC
Augmented commodity pricing model
∆OI Inflation b Dollar β Value
0.16
-0.33
0.00
0.47
-0.02
0.04
0.09
0.15
-0.13
0.28
CV
S&P-GSCI
0.09
0.02
0.02
0.02
0.03
0.07
0.06
0.17
0.11
0.06
0.07
-0.03
0.16
Traditional risk factors
EqMkt SMB
HML
UMD
Bond
0.26
-0.29
-0.25
0.11
-0.10
0.00
AN
Liquidity
∆OI
Inflation b
Dollar b
Value
CV
Liquidity
M
TS
Mom
HP
Baseline commodity pricing model
EW
TS
Mom
HP
0.10
0.14
0.30
0.11
0.02
0.29
-0.23
-0.08
-0.20
0.29
0.15
0.15
-0.05
0.02
0.02
0.16
-0.37
-0.09
-0.15
-0.06
-0.07
-0.11
-0.16
-0.30
0.04
-0.14
0.09
-0.09
0.03
-0.01
0.05
0.12
28
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
References
Adrian, T., and Rosenberg, J., 2008. Stock returns and volatility: pricing the short-run and
long-run components of volatility risk. Journal of Finance 63, 2997-3030.
Amaya, D., Christoffersen, P., Jacobs, K., and Vasquez, A., 2015. Does realized skewness
predict the cross-section of equity returns? Journal of Financial Economics 118, 135-167.
Amihud, Y., Mendelson, H., and Lauterbach, B., 1997. Market microstructure and securities
values: evidence from the Tel Aviv stock exchange. Journal of Financial Economics 45,
365–390.
IP
T
Asness, C., Moskowitz, T., and Pedersen, L., 2013. Value and momentum everywhere.
Journal of Finance 68, 929-985.
US
CR
Bakshi, G., Gao, X., and Rossi, A., 2017. Understanding the sources of risk underlying the
cross-section of commodity returns. Management Science, Forthcoming.
Bakshi, G., Panayotov, G., and Skoulakis, G., 2012. The Baltic Dry index as a predictor of
global stock returns, commodity returns, and global economic activity. Unpublished
working paper, University of Maryland, Hong Kong University of Science &
Technology, University of British Columbia.
AN
Bali, T. G., Caciki, N., and Whitelaw, R. F., 2011. Maxing out: stocks as lotteries and the
cross-section of expected returns. Journal of Financial Economics 99, 427–446.
M
Bali, T. G., and Murray, S., 2013. Does risk-neutral skewness predict the cross section of
equity option portfolio returns?. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 48, 11451171.
PT
ED
Barberis, N., and Huang, M., 2008. Stocks as lotteries: the implications of probability
weighting for security prices. American Economic Review 98, 2066–2100.
Basu, D., and Miffre, J., 2013. Capturing the risk premium of commodity futures: the role of
hedging pressure. Journal of Banking and Finance 37, 2652-2664.
CE
Bessembinder, H., 1992. Systematic risk, hedging pressure, and risk premiums in futures
markets. Review of Financial Studies 5, 637-667.
Boyer, B., Mitton, T., and Vorkink, K., 2010. Expected Idiosyncratic Skewness. Review of
Financial Studies 23, 169-202.
AC
Boyer, B., and Vorkink, K., 2014. Stock options as lotteries. Journal of Finance 64, 14851527.
Chang, B. Y., Christoffersen, P., and Jacobs, K., 2013. Market skewness risk and the cross
section of stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics 107, 46–68.
Conrad, J., Dittmar, R., and Ghysels, E., 2012. Ex-ante Skewness and Expected Stock
Returns. Journal of Finance 68, 85-124.
Cootner, P., 1960. Returns to speculators: Telser vs. Keynes. Journal of Political Economy 68,
396–404.
29
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Cremers, M., and Weinbaum, D., 2010. Deviations from put-call parity and stock return
predictability. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 45, 335-367.
Deaton, A., and Laroque, G., 1992. On the behaviour of commodity prices. Review of
Economic Studies 59, 1-23.
Dewally, M., Ederington, L., and Fernando, C., 2013. Determinants of trader profits in
commodity futures markets. Review of Financial Studies 26, 2648-2683.
Erb, C., and Harvey, C., 2006. The strategic and tactical value of commodity futures.
Financial Analysts Journal 62, 69-97.
IP
T
Fama, E. F., and MacBeth, J. D., 1973. Risk, returns, and equilibrium: empirical tests. Journal
of Political Economy 81, 607-636.
US
CR
Fama, E., and French, K., 1987. Commodity futures prices: some evidence on forecast power,
premiums, and the theory of storage. Journal of Business 60, 55-73.
Fernandez-Perez, A., Fuertes, A.-M., and Miffre, J., 2017. Commodity markets, long-horizon
predictability and intertemporal pricing. Review of Finance 21, 1159-1188.
Gilbert, S., Jones, S. K, Morris, G. H. 2006. The impact of skewness in the hedging decision.
Journal of Futures Markets 26, 503-520.
AN
Gorton, G., Hayashi, F., and Rouwenhorst, G., 2013. The fundamentals of commodity futures
returns. Review of Finance 17, 35-105.
M
Gorton, G., and Rouwenhorst, G., 2006. Facts and fantasies about commodity futures.
Financial Analysts Journal 62, 47-68.
PT
ED
Harvey, C. R., and Siddique, A., 2000. Conditional skewness in asset pricing tests. Journal of
Finance 55, 1263-95.
Hong, J., and Yogo, M., 2012. What does futures market interest tell us about the
macroeconomy and asset prices? Journal of Financial Economics 150, 473-490.
Kaldor, N., 1939. Speculation and economic stability. Review of Economic Studies 7, 1-27.
CE
Koijen, R., Moskowitz, T., Pedersen, L., Vrugt, E. 2017. Carry. Journal of Financial
Economics, Forthcoming.
Kumar, A., 2009. Who gambles in the stock market? Journal of Finance 64, 1889-1933.
AC
Lewellen, J., and Nagel, S., 2006. The conditional CAPM does not explain asset-pricing
anomalies. Journal of Financial Economics 82, 289-314.
Lien, D., Wang, Y., 2015. Effects of skewness and kurtosis on production and hedging
decisions: A skewed t distribution approach. European Journal of Finance 21, 1132-1143.
Locke, P., and Venkatesh, P., 1997. Futures market transaction costs. Journal of Futures
Markets 17, 229-245.
Miffre, J., and Rallis, G., 2007. Momentum strategies in commodity futures markets. Journal
of Banking and Finance 31, 1863-1886.
Mitton, T., and Vorkink, K., 2007. Equilibrium underdiversification and the preference for
skewness. Review of Financial Studies 20, 1255-1288.
30
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Moskowitz, T., Ooi, Y. H., Pedersen, J. 2012 Time Series Momentum. Journal of Financial
Economics 104, 228-250.
Newey, W. K., and West, K.D., 1987. Hypothesis testing with efficient method of moments
estimation. International Economic Review 28, 777-787.
Rehman, Z., and Vilkov, G., 2012. Risk-neutral skewness: Return predictability and its
sources. Goethe University Working Paper.
Shanken, J., 1992. On the estimation of beta-pricing models. Review of Financial Studies 5,
1–33.
IP
T
Symeonidis, L., Prokopczuk, M., Brooks, C., and Lazar, E., 2012. Futures basis, inventory
and commodity price volatility: an empirical analysis. Economic Modelling 29, 26512663.
US
CR
Stulz, R., 1996, Rethinking risk management. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 9, 3, 824.
Szymanowska, M., De Roon, F., Nijman, T., and Van Den Goorbergh, R., 2014. An anatomy
of commodity futures risk premia. Journal of Finance 69, 453-482.
AN
Tversky, A., Kahneman, D. 1992. Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of
uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5, 297–323.
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
Xiang, Y., Zhang, X., and Zhao, R., 2010, What does the individual option volatility smirk
tell us about future equity returns? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 45,
641-662.
31
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Table I. Summary statistics for individual commodity time-series of skewness
This table summarizes per commodity the sequence of Pearson coefficients of skewness,
Equation (1), obtained at each month-end t using daily data over the preceding t-11 to t
window. It provides the mean, 25th quintile, median (50th quantile), 75th quintile and standard
deviation. The sampling period is January 1987 to November 2014.
T
Mean
StDev
25%
Median
75%
0.5245
0.673
0.3587
0.3231
0.3057
1.3526
0.3684
0.263
0.3428
0.2817
0.4004
0.279
-0.3079
-0.3098
-0.2583
-0.2489
-0.2919
-0.3171
-0.1372
-0.3605
-0.2281
-0.0406
-0.3954
-0.1064
0.1248
-0.0256
-0.0413
-0.0911
-0.1269
-0.0414
0.0290
-0.1473
-0.0058
0.1441
-0.1061
0.0941
0.3355
0.3314
0.2527
0.0502
0.1111
0.4672
0.1986
0.0112
0.2086
0.3433
0.0435
0.2606
0.8284
0.3473
0.6951
0.8497
0.4151
-0.3697
-0.1216
-0.385
-0.2984
-0.2346
-0.1297
0.1472
-0.2202
-0.1017
-0.0038
0.0828
0.299
0.0025
0.077
0.2693
0.0138
-0.0093
-0.0190
-0.0938
-0.0931
0.3687
0.0117
-0.1705
0.0011
0.1510
-0.1596
0.0677
Panel B: Energy commodities
Crude oil
335
Electricity
128
Gasoline
335
Heating oil
335
Natural gas
295
-0.2461
0.0880
-0.2716
-0.2272
0.0250
Panel C: Livestock commodities
Feeder cattle
335
Frozen pork bellies
303
Lean hogs
335
Live cattle
335
-0.1269
0.0915
-0.0746
-0.0500
0.2751
0.5039
0.1788
0.265
-0.2134
-0.0587
-0.2025
-0.1574
-0.1062
-0.0038
-0.0922
-0.0152
0.0295
0.1053
0.0372
0.0984
-0.1144
-0.3056
-0.1998
-0.2762
-0.4321
0.5333
1.0287
0.4487
0.4287
0.5833
-0.3018
-0.7974
-0.4991
-0.5504
-0.8362
-0.0059
-0.4286
-0.2702
-0.3338
-0.3501
0.2157
0.0532
0.0987
-0.0933
0.0115
0.0616
0.1554
-0.0337
0.0654
0.1320
Panel E: Lumber
Lumber
335
US
CR
AN
M
PT
ED
CE
AC
Panel D: Metal commodities
Copper
316
Gold
335
Palladium
335
Platinum
335
Silver
335
IP
T
Panel A: Agricultural commodities
Cocoa
335
Coffee
335
Corn
335
Cotton
335
Oats
335
Orange juice
335
Rough rice
178
Soybeans
335
Soybean meal
335
Soybean oil
335
Sugar
335
Wheat
335
32
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Table II. Summary statistics for the risk factors
StDev
Sharpe
ratio
Omega
ratio
US
CR
Mean
IP
T
The table presents summary statistics for monthly risk factors over the sample January 1987
to November 2014. Panel A focuses on a baseline pricing model that includes a long-only
equally-weighted portfolio of all commodities, as well as long-short portfolios based on
signals that capture the backwardation and contango cycle. Panel B contains other long-short
commodity-specific benchmarks that mimic systematic factors. Panel C presents traditional
risk factors that emanate from the equity, bond and commodity pricing literature. Appendix A
provides a detailed description of all the factors. Significance t-ratios for the annualized mean
excess returns are shown in parentheses. Sharpe ratios are annualized mean excess returns
(Mean) over annualized standard deviations (StDev). Omega ratios are the probability of
gains divided by the probability of losses using 0% as threshold.
0.9861
1.3355
1.5979
1.4460
Panel B: Augmented commodity pricing model
Liquidity
0.0114
∆Open interest (∆OI)
0.0032
Inflation b
0.0296
Dollar b
0.0127
Value
0.0334
Coefficient of variation (CV)
0.0318
(0.52)
(0.18)
(1.16)
(0.57)
(1.44)
(1.56)
0.1003
0.0946
0.1340
0.1162
0.1201
0.0993
0.1133
0.0338
0.2208
0.1093
0.2783
0.3207
1.0900
1.0255
1.1848
1.0872
1.2320
1.2944
Panel C: Traditional risk factors
S&P-GSCI
Equity index (EqMkt)
Size (SMB)
Value (HML)
Equity momentum (UMD)
Bond index
(0.77)
(2.70)
(0.14)
(1.23)
(2.15)
(4.51)
0.1989
0.1542
0.1055
0.1010
0.1621
0.0367
0.1768
0.5275
0.0236
0.2742
0.4313
0.9156
1.1481
1.4823
1.0192
1.2482
1.4667
1.9465
Panel A: Baseline pricing model
Equal-weighted portfolio (EW)
Term structure (TS)
Momentum (Mom)
Hedging pressure (HP)
(-0.08)
(2.07)
(3.40)
(2.37)
0.0352
0.0814
0.0025
0.0277
0.0699
0.0336
0.1207
0.1196
0.1455
0.1206
-0.0175
0.3873
0.6153
0.4796
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
-0.0021
0.0463
0.0895
0.0578
33
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Table III. Relationship between skewness signal and other characteristics
Q2
Q3
Q4
-0.7294
-0.2596
-0.0707
0.0978
Panel B: Backwardation versus contango characteristics
Roll-yield
-0.0008 -0.0034
Excess return
2.91%
0.57%
Hedgers' hedging pressure
0.3969
0.4295
Speculators' hedging pressure
0.6570
0.6387
-0.0060
0.78%
0.4389
0.6198
Q1-Q5
0.5407
-1.27
(-17.73)
0.01
4.77%
-0.06
0.07
(5.29)
(1.75)
(-6.10)
(5.97)
-0.0094
-1.90%
0.4417
0.5974
-0.0105
-1.86%
0.4531
0.5848
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
Panel A: Pre-ranking skewness
Q5
US
CR
Q1
IP
T
The table summarizes the properties of skewness-based commodity quintiles from January
1987 to November 2014. Q1 is the quintile with the 20% lowest
commodities and Q5 the
quintile with the 20% highest
commodities. The characteristics are measured over 12month windows that are sequentially rolled forward one month at a time. The last column
shows Newey-West h.a.c. t-statistics for the null hypothesis that there is no difference in a
given characteristic across the Q1 and Q5 quintiles. Panel B shows the characteristics related
with backwardation and contango phases such as the roll-yield, excess return, hedgers’
hedging pressure and speculators’ hedging pressure signals. Bold font denotes significant at
the 10% level or better. The sampling period is January 1987 to November 2014.
34
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Table IV. Performance of skewness quintiles and long-short portfolios
Excess kurtosis
0.0512
(1.42)
0.1748
-0.1006
0.0090
(0.07)
1.3891
(5.10)
0.1291
55.25%
-0.4244
0.2932
0.1266
1.2547
0.0401
(0.99)
0.1755
-0.0774
-0.7888
(-5.80)
3.1699
(11.65)
0.1696
55.56%
-0.6006
0.2287
0.0910
1.1985
-0.0020
(-0.06)
0.1715
-0.0102
-0.2246
(-1.65)
0.9979
(3.67)
0.1341
48.46%
-0.7300
-0.0114
-0.0045
0.9915
0.0428
(1.79)
{0.08}
0.9571
(13.12)
0.1951
(2.27)
0.0334
(0.47)
0.0786
(0.93)
0.0410
(1.93)
{0.02}
1.0502
(15.05)
0.2375
(3.69)
-0.0894
(-1.78)
0.0806
(1.65)
49.12%
56.57%
PT
ED
99% VaR (Cornish-Fisher)
% of positive months
Maximum drawdown
Sharpe ratio
Sortino ratio (0%)
Omega ratio (0%)
Q3
Q4
Q5
Q1-Q5
-0.0277
(-0.80)
0.1647
-0.0165
-0.5818
(-4.28)
2.7427
(10.08)
0.1577
50.62%
-0.8205
-0.1683
-0.0632
0.8792
-0.1089
(-3.35)
0.1596
-0.0247
-0.1563
(-1.15)
1.0168
(3.74)
0.1321
41.05%
-0.9731
-0.6820
-0.2375
0.5969
0.0801
(3.83)
0.1020
-0.0760
0.2874
(2.11)
1.1646
(4.28)
0.0627
59.26%
-0.2973
0.7848
0.4017
1.8136
0.0134
(0.67)
{0.31}
1.0427
(19.31)
-0.0933
(-1.45)
0.0037
(0.07)
-0.0606
(-0.98)
-0.0174
(-0.80)
{0.19}
1.0283
(13.80)
-0.1096
(-1.66)
0.0048
(0.09)
0.0341
(0.54)
-0.0889
(-3.96)
{0.00}
0.8949
(14.55)
-0.1645
(-2.31)
0.0293
(0.48)
-0.1439
(-1.75)
0.0658
(3.58)
{0.00}
0.0311
(0.66)
0.1798
(2.74)
0.0021
(0.04)
0.1113
(1.46)
52.79%
56.87%
45.21%
5.66%
AN
StDev
Post-ranking skewness
Skewness
Q2
M
Panel A: Summary statistics
Mean
Q1
US
CR
IP
T
This table summarizes the performance of the long-only portfolios containing the 20% most
negative-skew commodities (Q1) to the 20% most positive-skew (Q5) commodities, and the
low-minus-high fully-collateralized skewness portfolio that longs Q1 and shorts Q5. The
underlying signal is the Pearson’s moment of skewness of the daily returns measured over a
ranking period of 12 months. Panel A summarizes the portfolio monthly return distribution.
Mean denotes annualized average excess return, StDev annualized standard deviation, Sharpe
ratio is Mean divided by StDev, Sortino ratio is Mean divided by annualized downside
volatility and Omega ratio measures the probability of gains over probability of losses. Panel
B presents annualized alphas and beta coefficients with Newey-West t-statistics in
parentheses (bootstrap p-values for alphas in brackets) from regressions of the excess returns
of skewness portfolios on the average commodity factor (EW), term structure factor (TS),
momentum factor (Mom) and hedging pressure factor (HP); details on the construction of the
factors are provided in Section 3.2.1. Bold font denotes significant at the 10% level or better.
The sample period is January 1987 to November 2014.
Panel B: Regression analysis
β (EW)
AC
β (TS)
CE
α
β (Mom)
β (HP)
Adjusted R 2
35
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Table V. Robustness checks for performance of long-short skewness portfolios
US
CR
IP
T
The table studies the abnormal performance of various long-short skewness (Q1-Q5)
portfolios. Panel A uses as signal the skewness of the residuals from time-series regressions of
daily commodity futures returns on daily observations for the EW, TS, Mom and HP factors,
business cycle indicators and/or calendar-month dummies. Panel B uses as alternative pricing
models i) a four-factor equation comprising the excess returns of the S&P-GSCI, TS, Mom
and HP portfolios, ii) the baseline four-factor equation augmented with systematic risk
factors, and iii) equations motivated from the equity/bond pricing literature. Panel C excludes
from the cross-section the 80% of futures contracts with lowest liquidity according to the
Amihud et al. (1997) measure, and deducts transaction costs of 0.066% per trade. The
abnormal performance is measured as the annualized alpha (α) modeled in reference to the
baseline four-factor model, except in Panel B where alternative pricing models are used in
place. Newey-West t-statistics for the alphas are reported in parentheses and bootstrap pvalues are in curly brackets. Appendix A provides a detailed description of all the factors.
Bold denotes significance at the 10% level or better. The sampling period is January 1987 to
November 2014.
α
Panel A: Signal used to construct the skewness risk factor
EW, TS, HP, Mom-filtered returns
0.0673
0.0386
Business cycle-filtered returns
Calendar month dummy-filtered returns
0.0518
Risk factor, business cycle and dummy-filtered
0.0383
t -stat
p -value
{0.00}
{0.03}
{0.01}
{0.02}
0.0647
(3.53)
{0.00}
Baseline pricing model augmented with systematic risk factors
Liquidity
0.0637
∆OI
0.0681
Inflation β
0.0602
Dollar β
0.0652
Value
0.0702
CV
0.0658
All risk factors
0.0581
(3.51)
(3.67)
(3.36)
(3.54)
(3.71)
(3.61)
(3.20)
{0.00}
{0.00}
{0.00}
{0.00}
{0.00}
{0.00}
{0.00}
Traditional commodity, equity and fixed income pricing models
Carhart (1997), Bond index
0.0873
Carhart (1997), Bond, Commodity risk factors
0.0765
(3.59)
(3.52)
{0.00}
{0.00}
Panel C: Iliquidity and transaction costs
80% most liquid contracts
T-costs = 0.066%
(2.80)
(3.40)
{0.01}
{0.00}
Panel B: Choice of asset pricing model
AC
CE
PT
ED
S&P-GSCI, TS, Mom, HP
M
AN
(3.92)
(1.94)
(2.51)
(2.07)
0.0512
0.0624
36
IP
T
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Table VI. Cross-sectional pricing ability of skewness factor
EW
TS
Mom
HP
Liquidity
∆OI
Model E
Model F
Model G
Model H
-0.0015 -0.0016
(-0.84) (-0.89)
0.0040
(2.48)
0.0024 0.0027
(1.20) (1.35)
-0.0006 0.0000
(-0.35) (-0.02)
0.0031 0.0034
(1.47) (1.54)
0.0031 0.0031
(1.76) (1.72)
0.0012 0.0014
(0.76) (0.86)
-0.0020 -0.0016
(-1.14) (-0.90)
0.0034
(2.10)
0.0029 0.0026
(1.46) (1.31)
0.0002 0.0006
(0.09) (0.35)
0.0042 0.0042
(1.97) (1.95)
0.0031 0.0031
(1.75) (1.72)
-0.0028 -0.0030
(-1.57) (-1.67)
0.0043
(2.62)
0.0037 0.0041
(1.87) (2.01)
0.0001 0.0006
(0.08) (0.32)
0.0035 0.0039
(1.60) (1.72)
0.0036 0.0035
(1.96) (1.88)
-0.0024 -0.0020
(-1.32) (-1.09)
0.0042
(2.57)
0.0033 0.0030
(1.64) (1.51)
0.0007 0.0008
(0.42) (0.46)
0.0044 0.0042
(2.03) (1.93)
0.0034 0.0038
(1.90) (2.06)
-0.0019 -0.0020
(-0.98) (-1.04)
0.0044
(2.49)
0.0028 0.0031
(1.32) (1.49)
0.0003 0.0004
(0.16) (0.22)
0.0036 0.0034
(1.57) (1.45)
0.0034 0.0033
(1.80) (1.68)
-0.0022 -0.0019
(-1.21) (-1.08)
0.0045
(2.70)
0.0031 0.0030
(1.55) (1.51)
0.0002 0.0005
(0.09) (0.26)
0.0038 0.0038
(1.75) (1.73)
0.0039 0.0040
(2.18) (2.15)
0.0023 0.0022
(1.46) (1.37)
-0.0008 -0.0012
(-0.40) (-0.59)
0.0046
(2.62)
0.0024 0.0029
(1.07) (1.27)
0.0008 0.0013
(0.43) (0.67)
0.0051 0.0052
(2.16) (2.19)
0.0037 0.0037
(1.88) (1.82)
0.0017 0.0019
(0.97) (1.06)
0.0011 0.0009
(0.72) (0.57)
0.0033 0.0033
(1.57) (1.52)
0.0001 0.0004
(0.06) (0.19)
0.0038 0.0038
(1.90) (1.90)
0.0022 0.0024
(1.31) (1.38)
30.39% 33.71%
47.17% 49.80%
0.0004 0.0010
(0.31) (0.70)
Inflation b
Dollar b
Value
CV
29.82% 33.54%
CE
25.82% 29.68%
AC
Adjusted R 2
Model D
AN
Skewness
-0.0020 -0.0016
(-1.12) (-0.92)
0.0040
(2.42)
0.0027 0.0025
(1.34) (1.26)
-0.0002 0.0003
(-0.11) (0.16)
0.0039 0.0038
(1.82) (1.76)
0.0033 0.0035
(1.86) (1.93)
Model C
PT
ED
Intercept
Model B
M
Model A
US
CR
The table reports average coefficients from pass-two Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions of excess commodity futures returns on factor
loadings or betas, where we augment the baseline four-factor model, Model A, with systematic risk factors. The test assets are the 27 individual
commodities. Shanken (1992) t-statistics are reported in parentheses. Appendix A provides a detailed description of all the factors. Bold means
significant at the 10% level or better. The sample period is January 1987 to November 2014.
30.32% 33.65%
0.0031 0.0028
(1.51) (1.37)
0.0005 0.0004
(0.26) (0.24)
0.0041 0.0040
(2.05) (1.98)
30.99% 34.25%
29.70% 33.26%
29.94% 34.18%
37
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Table VII. Cross-sectional robustness tests
Adjusted R²
without
with
skewness
skewness
US
CR
Panel A: Signal used to construct the skewness factor
EW, TS, HP, Mom-filtered returns
Business cycle-filtered returns
Calendar month dummy-filtered returns
̂
IP
T
The table tests the robustness of the cross-sectional Fama-MacBeth estimation results to the
signal used for the construction of the tradeable skewness factor (Panel A), to the choice of
pricing models (Panel B) and to the use of commodity characteristics in place of sensitivities
to the risk factors in the cross-sectional regression (Panel C). The table reports the average
skewness premium, ̂ ; t-statistic for its significance using a Shanken-adjustment in Panels A
and B and Newey and West-adjustment in Panel C; the explanatory power of the pricing
model at hand and of the same model without the skewness factor. The pricing model in Panel
A is the baseline four-factor (EW, TS, Mom and HP) model. Appendix A provides a detailed
description of all the factors. Bold font indicates significance at the 10% level or better. The
sample covers the period from January 1987 to November 2014.
t -statistic
(2.80)
(2.02)
(2.04)
28.78%
29.66%
30.19%
25.82%
25.82%
25.82%
0.0039
0.0048
0.0057
(2.40)
(2.64)
(3.20)
29.59%
29.43%
42.21%
25.93%
23.54%
38.63%
-0.0088
(-3.59)
10.19%
9.04%
Baseline characteristic model augmented with systematic signals
-0.0083
Liquidity
∆OI
-0.0093
Inflation β
-0.0085
Dollar β
-0.0089
-0.0083
Value
-0.0078
CV
-0.0076
All systematic signals
(-3.37)
(-3.67)
(-2.90)
(-3.28)
(-3.41)
(-2.95)
(-2.38)
8.98%
10.30%
15.26%
14.24%
15.04%
11.40%
22.05%
7.72%
9.19%
14.09%
12.48%
13.64%
10.13%
20.16%
AN
M
Panel B: Other pricing models
S&P-GSCI, TS, Mom, HP
Carhart (1997), Bond index
Carhart (1997), Bond, Baseline commodity factors
AC
CE
PT
ED
Panel C: Pricing model based on characteristics
Baseline characteristic model
0.0042
0.0035
0.0033
38
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Figure 1. Skewness of daily commodity futures returns over 12-month rolling windows
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
US
CR
IP
T
This figure plots the Pearson moment of skewness of the distribution of daily commodity
futures returns on each month end t using data over the preceding t-11 to t window. The two
horizontal lines are the 95% confidence bands to test the hypothesis that skewness is zero.
The plotted lines pertain to four representative commodities pertaining to different sectors.
The legend reports the percentage of months for each commodity when the skewness is
significantly positive or negative. The sampling period is January 1987 to November 2014.
39
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
US
CR
IP
T
Figure 2. Cumulative log returns of skewness-based commodity portfolios
The figure plots the cumulative log return of five portfolios: quintiles Q1 to Q5 formed
according to the Pearson’s moment of skewness
signal measured at the end of each month
with the daily returns in the most recent 12-month window. Q1 contains the 20% of
commodities with the lowest ̂ values and Q5 contains the 20% of commodities with the
highest ̂ values. The sampling period is January 1987 to November 2014.
40
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Figure 3. Frequency of commodities in long Q1 and short Q5 commodity portfolios
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
US
CR
IP
T
The graph shows the percentage of months over the entire sample period from January 1987
to November 2014 (T=324 months in total) that each commodity enters the long (mostnegatively-skew Q1) portfolio and short (most-positively-skew Q5) portfolio. For instance,
cocoa is a constituent of Q1 during 66 months (20.37%), Q5 during 124 months (38.27%),
and does not enter any portfolio, long or short, during the remaining 134 months (41.36%).
41
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Figure 4. Conditional alpha of commodity skewness strategy
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
US
CR
IP
T
The graph shows the sequential annualized alpha of the long-short skewness strategy based on
seven-year rolling regressions. The strategy buys the most negative-skew quintile Q1 and
shorts the most positive-skew quintile Q5 at the end of each month each seven-year window.
The discontinuous lines are the upper limit and lower limit of the 95% confidence band based
on Newey-West standard errors.
42
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Figure 5. Conditional price of skewness factor
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
US
CR
IP
T
The figure shows the conditional lambda of the skewness factor in Equation (6) based on
seven-year rolling estimation windows for 27 individual commodities (Model A in Table VI).
The discontinuous lines are the upper limit and lower limit of the 95% confidence band based
on Shanken standard errors.
43