CENTER FOR INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS
Working Paper Series
Working Paper No. 2011-06
Trade Openness and Economic Growth: A Panel
Causality Analysis
Thomas Gries, Margarete Redlin
June 2012
Trade Openness and Economic Growth: A
Panel Causality Analysis
T. Griesa) , M. Redlinb)F
University of Paderborn, Germany
Abstract
This paper examines the short-term and long-run dynamics between per
capita GDP growth and openness for 158 countries over the period 1970-2009.
We use panel cointegration tests and panel error-correction models (ECM) in
combination with GMM estimation to explore the causal relationship between
these two variables. We approach the problem of a potential endogeneity between openness and growth by including only growth rates and lagged values of
the independent variable. Additionally, we apply Di¤erence GMM and System
GMM estimation. These estimators also address the issue of a possible correlation between the lagged endogenous variable and the error term. The results
suggest a long-run relationship between openness and economic growth with a
short-run adjustment to the deviation from the equilibrium for both directions
of dependency. The long-run coe¢cients indicate a positive signi…cant causality
from openness to growth and vice versa, indicating that international integration
is a bene…cial strategy for growth in the long term. By contrast the short-run
coe¢cient shows a negative short-run adjustment, suggesting that openness can
be painful for an economy undergoing short-term adjustments. In addition to
the entire panel we subdivide the data into income-related subpanels. While
the long-run e¤ect remains predominantly positive and signi…cant, the shortrun adjustment becomes positive when the income level increases. This result
suggests that di¤erent trade structures in low-income and high-income countries
have di¤erent e¤ects on economic growth.
Keywords:
JEL Classi…cation:
openness, trade, growth, development,
panel cointegration,
F10, F15, F43, 05
1
a)
Corresponding author:
b)
F
Co-author:
Thomas Gries
[email protected]
Economics Department, University of Paderborn
Center for International Economics (C-I-E), www.C-I-E.org
Warburger Strasse 100
33098 Paderborn, Germany
Margarete Redlin
[email protected]
Economics Department, University of Paderborn
Warburger Strasse 100
33098 Paderborn, Germany
The autors would like to thank René Fahr and Wendelin Schnedler for theire
valuable comments.
1
Introduction
The relationship between openness and economic growth has long been a subject
of much interest and controversy in international trade literature. With regard
to a theoretical relationship between openness and growth most of the studies provide support for the proposition that openness e¤ects growth positively.
Romer (1993), Grossman and Helpman (1991) and Barro and Sala-i-Martin
(1995) among others, argue that countries that are more open have a greater
ability to catch up to leading technologies of the rest of the world. Chang,
Kaltani, Loayza (2005) point out that openness promotes the e¢cient allocation of resources through comparative advantage, allows the dissemination of
knowledge and technological progress, and encourages competition in domestic
and international markets. However there exists also the opposed position. For
example Krugman (1994) and Rodrik and Rodríguez (2001) argue that the effect of openness on growth is doubtful. Furthermore, if we include the gains
from trade debate we look at a long lasting debate discussing conditions and
circumstances when openness and trade may be favourable and may improve
the economic performance or not. These controversial theoretical …ndings also
appear in the empirical literature. Numerous econometric studies have tried
to identify the relationship and the causal direction between openness and economic growth. These studies can be divided into three groups. First, conventional regression analyses trying to capture the e¤ect of openness by regressing
it on per capita growth. There are several studies in this vein, with the vast
majority concluding that openness to trade is a signi…cant explanatory variable
for economic growth (see e.g. some more recent contributions like Dollar (1992),
Edwards (1998), Harrison (1996), Barro and Lee (1994), Easterly and Levine
(2001), Dollar and Kraay (2002), Irwin and Tervio (2000), Islam (1995), Salai-Martin (1997)). However, conventional regression methods analyse only one
direction of a possible bidirectional relationship and are unable to uncover the
causation of trade openness and GDP growth. The second group of studies uses
Granger causality based tests on the openness and economic growth variables.
Here the results show a more mixed picture. Jung and Marshall (1985) employ the Granger causality test and …nd unidirectional causality from exports
to growth for four out of 37 countries for the period 1951-1981. Chow (1987)
analyses eight industrialized countries and …nds bidirectional causality in six
cases and one case with unidirectional causality from exports to growth. Hsiao
(1987) uses Granger causality tests for Asian countries. The results show only
unidirectional causality from growth to exports for the case of Hong Kong. Ahmad and Kwan (1991) investigate 47 African countries and …nd no causality between exports and growth. However, Bahmani-Oskooee (1991) applies Granger
causality tests for 20 countries and …nds both positive and negative causality
e¤ects for both directions. Although these kinds of studies try to capture a
bidirectional relationship, Engle and Granger (1987) have shown that when the
series are cointegrated a standard Granger-causality test is misspeci…ed. The
third group of studies picks up the problem of biased results in the event of
cointegrated series and uses the concept of cointegration and error-correction
1
to explore the short-run and long-run dynamics between openness and growth.
These analyses are based on time series data and investigate the causalities at
country level. Islam (1998) uses an error-correction model for each of 15 Asian
countries1 for the period 1967-1991 and …nds export to growth causality for
10 out of 15 countries. Liu et al. (2002) investigate China over the period
1981-1997 and …nd bidirectional causality between FDI, exports and growth.
Bouoiyour (2003) applies the concept of cointegration and error correction to
the relationship between trade and economic growth in Morocco over the period 1960-2000. The results show a lack of long-run causality. In the short run
higher imports and exports cause higher GDP. Awokuse (2007) examines the
impact of export and import expansion on growth in three transition economies
on country level. The results show bidirectional causality between exports and
growth for Bulgaria, the Czech Republic exhibits unidirectional causality from
exports and imports on growth, and for Poland only the import-led growth hypothesis can be supported. A weak point of these studies is the absence of a
general examination of the causality between openness and economic growth on
cross-country level. All these studies investigate the relationship on a certain
country level for time series data. A general panel error correction model has
not been applied yet.
Therefore, this study aims to address this problem and to re-examine the issue of causal links between trade openness and growth using an error correction
model for a panel of 158 countries over the period 1970-2009. This methodological framework allows us to test for bidirectional causality relations from
openness to GDP and vice versa. Furthermore, this method enables us to distinguish between short-run and long-term e¤ects between trade and growth. In
particular we shed light on the question of whether bene…ts of trade or fears
of negative e¤ects of trade address di¤erent time horizons. That is, …nding a
long-term positive causality from trade to growth would provide evidence on
long-term bene…ts of international integration. Ba contrast, the presence of
negative causal e¤ects in the short term would be an indicator of the pain of
adjustment an economy has to sustain if long-term bene…t is the target. We also
break down our data set into …ve subpanels following the World Bank income
classi…cation to allow us to investigate income-related e¤ect di¤erences. The
paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the empirical investigation including the data, the methodology and the results of the panel unit root tests, the
panel cointegration tests, and the error-correction model. Section 3 concludes.
2
Empirical evidence
This section investigates the causal relationship between trade openness and
economic growth. In a …rst step we use recently developed panel unit root
and cointegration tests. Then we apply panel-based error-correction models to
1 The countries included in the analysis are Bangladesh, Fiji, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia,
Japan, Malaysia, Nepal, Pakistan, Papua New Guinea, Philippines, Singapore, South Korea,
Sri Lanka, and Thailand.
2
explore the bidirectional short-run and long-run dynamics between these two
variables. In our analysis we try to capture the problem of possible endogeneity
of the openness variable. Our starting point is to test for causality of openness
on growth and vice versa. However, a loop of causality between the independent
and dependent variables of a model leads to endogeneity problems in a simple
regression model. Previous studies of causality between openness and growth
ignore this potentially interdependence which leads to a correlation between
the endogenous variable and the error term. These kinds of studies disregard
a potential endogeneity of openness and growth and so produce biased and
inconsistent parameter estimates. Current literature identi…es this problem and
provides two common suggestions to deal with it. The …rst is the use of lagged
values of the exogenous variables. Second, the endogeneity problem can also be
addressed appropriately by using instrumental variables (IV) techniques. So if a
dependent variable is potentially endogenous, it is intuitively appealing to look
for a proxy that does not su¤er from the same problem. For example Frankel and
Romer (1999) use geographic attributes as instruments to identify the e¤ects of
trade on income. This approach is also adopted by Irvin and Terviö (2002) and
Noguera and Siscart 2005). We abstract from these geographical determinants
of trade by focusing on changes in openness. Our model includes only growth
rates and lagged values of the independent variable. Additionally, we approach
this problem by using GMM estimation. It also addresses the issue of a possible
correlation between the lagged endogenous variable and the error term. We use
the Di¤erence GMM and System GMM estimators developed by Arellano and
Bond (1991) and Blundell and Bond (1998). These estimators deal e¤ectively
with the endogeneity problem by using a set of instruments for the endogenous
variables. The former uses lagged levels as instruments for the equation in
di¤erences; in addition to that the latter uses lagged di¤erences as instruments
for the additional equations in levels. Furthermore, concerning the substance we
explore both directions of action between trade and growth using a simultaneous
bivariate model.
2.1
Data
Regarding openness there are several variables that can be used to measure the
degree of openness. They can be broadly divided into two categories: measures
of trade volumes and measures of trade restrictions. The most common measure
in the …rst group is trade share, which is the sum of exports plus imports divided
by GDP. The second category includes measures of trade barriers that include
average tari¤ rates, export taxes, total taxes on international trade, and indices
of non-tari¤ barriers. To perform a broad panel analysis of a large number of
countries and over a long period we select a measure that is widely available,
namely trade share. We use a balanced panel data set containing 158 countries
over the period 1970-2009. Our analysis is based on two variables from the Penn
World Table 7.0. provided by Heston et al. (2011):
3
Openness: opennessi;t Trade measured by the sum of exports and imports as a percentage of GDP at 2005 constant prices. The variable corresponds
to the openk variable from the Penn World Table.
GDP per capita: GDPi;t GDP per capita is PPP converted GDP per
capita (Laspeyres) at 2005 constant prices in international dollar per person.
The variable corresponds to the rgdpl variable from the Penn World Table.
In addition to the entire panel, we segment the data set into …ve subpanels
according to per capita income. We use the World Bank country classi…cation
that distinguishes between low-income economies ($1005 or less), lower-middleincome economies ($1006 to $3975), upper-middle-income economies ($3976 to
$12275), high-income economies ($12276 or more) and high-income OECD members. Table 1 provides the descriptive statistics of the panel data set and the
subpanels.2
Table 1: Descriptive Statistics
panel
1
2-LI
3-LMI
4-UMI
5-HI
6-OECD
observations
openness
mean
std. dev.
GDP per capita
mean
std. dev.
6320
1200
1800
1640
640
1040
75.52
50.23
50.38
29.46
80.88
39.34
76.13
44.76
133.08
74.25
58.85
44.91
8797.21
11083.70
793.34
349.01
2734.28
1721.35
6557.28
3451.02
21164.17
14772.27
24447.75
10193.08
2.2
Estimation
Methodology: To explore the short-run and long-run dynamics between
GDP growth and changes in openness we follow Yasar et al. (2006) and apply a
generalized one-step error-correction model (ECM) in combination with panel
data and GMM estimation. We prefer dynamic panel estimators for various reasons. GMM estimation circumvents the bias associated with including a lagged
dependent variable as a regressor and enables us to calculate consistent and ef…cient estimates. Additionally, by combining the time series dimension with the
cross-sectional dimension, the panel data provides a richer set of information
to exploit the relationship between the dependent and independent variables,
reduces collinearity among the explanatory variables, increases the degrees of
freedom, and gives more variability and e¢ciency. More speci…cally, our point
of departure is a bivariate autoregressive-distributed lag model
2 Appendix
1 provides a detailed list of all included countries and the income segmentation.
4
yi;t
=
0+
2
X
j yi;t
j
+
j=1
xi;t
=
0+
2
X
2
X
j xi;t j
+ fi + ui;t
(1)
j yi;t j
+
(2)
j=0
j xi;t
j
+
j=1
2
X
i
+
i;t
j=0
where index i=1...N refers to the country and t=1...T to the period. This
method allows us to include speci…c e¤ects for each country (fi and i ). This
individual e¤ect may correlate with the included explanatory variables, hence
omitting the individual e¤ect would become part of the error term, which would
lead to a bias in the estimates. The disturbances ui;t and i;t are assumed to be
independently distributed across countries with a zero mean. They may display
heteroskedasticity across time and countries, though. Following Granger (1969)
there is Granger causality from x to y if past values of x improve the prediction
of y given the past values of y. With respect to the model x Granger causes y
if not all j are zero. By the same token Granger causality from y to x occurs
if not all j are equal to zero. However, Engle and Granger (1987) have shown
that, if the series x and y are cointegrated, the standard Granger causality test
is misspeci…ed. In this case an ECM should be used instead. In a …rst step we
have to apply a unit root and a cointegration test. On the basis of the results we
determine whether to use the Granger causality framework or an ECM model
to test causality.
Panel unit root test: The Granger causality test requires the variables
to be stationary. We check their stationarity using two common panel unit root
tests, the IPS test by Im, et al. (2003) and the Fisher-type test by Maddala
and Wu (1999) and Choi (2001).
Formally, the test equation of both tests is
4yi;t =
i
+
i yi;t 1
+ "it ,
(3)
with the null hypothesis that each cross-section series in the panel has a unit
root and the alternative hypothesis that at least one cross-section in the panel is
stationary. Additionally, the formulation allows i to di¤er across cross-sections
so that both tests allow for heterogeneity.
H0
H1
:
:
i
i
= 0 f or all i
< 0; i = 1; 2; :::; N1 ;
i
Table 2: Panel unit root test
5
= 0;
(4)
i = N1 + 1; N2 + 1; :::N: (5)
variable
deterministic
IPS
Fisher-type
…rst di¤.
IPS
…rst di¤.
Fisher-type
openness
constant
const. + trend
constant
const. + trend
1.0752
-0.2000
5.1565
0.7044
319.487
329.420
250.553
334.263
-40.5784***
-34.8509***
-34.1635***
-30.0096***
2176.00***
1744.49***
1787.10***
1472.30***
GDP
Notes:
* Rejects the null of a unit root at the 10% level.
** Rejects the null of a unit root at the 5% level.
*** Rejects the null of a unit root at the 1% level.
The IPS test is a t-bar statistic based on the augmented Dickey-Fuller statistic (Dickey and Fuller 1979). The test statistic is computed by the sample
mean of the individual unit root tests for each of the N cross-section units. The
main idea of the Fisher-type unit root test is to combine p-values from the unit
root tests applied to each of the N cross-section units in the panel. While both
IPS and the Fisher-type test combine information based on individual unit root
tests, the crucial di¤erence between the two is that the IPS test combines the
test statistics while the Fisher-type test combines the signi…cance levels of the
individual tests. Table 2 presents the results of the tests for both variables
in levels and in …rst di¤erences. The results indicate that for both variables
the level data is non-stationary, however the test statistics of the di¤erenced
variables are highly signi…cant and show stationarity regardless of whether the
trend is included in the test or not.3 Hence, the following analysis is based on
the di¤erenced data, namely GDP growth and changes in openness.
Panel cointegration test: Since the panel unit root tests presented above
indicate that the variables are integrated of order one I(1), we test for cointegration using the panel cointegration test developed by Pedroni (1999, 2004).
This test allows for heterogeneity in the panel by permitting heterogenous slope
coe¢cients, …xed e¤ects and individual speci…c deterministic trends. The test
contains seven cointegration statistics, the …rst four based on pooling the residuals along the "within-dimension" which assume a common value for the unit
root coe¢cient, and the subsequent three based on polling the residuals along
the "between dimension" which allow for di¤erent values of the unit root coef…cient. The common idea of both classes is to …rst estimate the hypothesized
cointegration relationship separately for each group member of the panel and
then pool the resulting residuals when constructing the test for the null of no
3 Additionally, we test also the homogeneous alternative of the H hypothesis that assumes
1
that the autoregressive parameter is identical for all cross-section units. The Levin, Lin and
Chu (2002) and Breitung (2000) unit root tests also indicate that the variables are integrated
of order on I(1).
6
cointegration. Table 3 presents the results. In all cases the null of no cointegration is rejected at the 1% signi…cance level, indicating that the variables exhibit
a cointegration relationship.
Table 3: Panel cointegration test
openness - GDP
Panel -test
Panel -test
Panel pp-test
Panel adf -test
Group -test
Group pp-test
Group adf -test
4.3802***
-5.7259***
-6.3860***
-5.9561***
-3.2054***
-5.9503***
-6.4598***
Notes:
Based on individual intercept and automatic lag length selection based on AIC.
* Rejects the null of no cointegation at the 10% level.
** Rejects the null of no cointegation at the 5% level.
*** Rejects the null of no cointegation at the 1% level.
Error correction model: Engle and Granger (1987) have shown that
when the series x and y are cointegrated a standard Granger-causality test
as presented in the equations (1) and (2) is misspeci…ed, because it does not
allow for the distinction between the short-run and the long run-e¤ect. At
this point a error correction model (ECM) should be used instead. It is a linear
transformation of the ADL models above and provides a link between the shortrun and the long-run e¤ect (Banerjee et al. 1993, 1998).
yi;t
xi;t
= ( 1 1) yi;t 1 + 0 xi;t + ( 0 + 1 ) xi;t
+ (yi;t 2
xi;t 2 ) + fi + ui;t
= ( 1 1) xi;t 1 + 0 yi;t + ( 0 + 1 ) yi;t
+ (xi;t 2
yi;t 2 ) + i + i;t
1
(6)
1
(7)
While the coe¢cients ( 1 1), 0 and ( 0 + 1 ) as well as ( 1 1), 0
and ( 0 + 1 ) capture the short-run e¤ects, the coe¢cients
and
of the
error correction terms give the adjustment rates at which short-run dynamics
converge to the long-run equilibrium relationship. If and are negative and
signi…cant a relationship between x and y exist in the long run. The standard
error-correction procedure is a two-step method where in a …rst step the error
correction term is obtained by saving residuals of separate estimation of the
long-run equilibrium of x and y. In a second step the ECM with the included
error correction term can be estimated. However, the two-stage error correction
models have been criticized in the literature. Banerjee et al. (1998) argue that
there can be a substantial small-sample bias compared to a single-equation error
7
correction model where the long-run relation is restricted to being homogeneous.
Accordingly, in this study we use a one-step procedure to indicate the shortrun and long-run dynamics. The generalized one-step ECM is transformed as
follows:
yi;t
xi;t
= ( 1 1) yi;t 1 + 0
+ (yi;t 2 xi;t 2 ) +
= ( 1 1) xi;t 1 + 0
+ (xi;t 2 yi;t 2 ) +
xi;t + ( 0 + 1 ) xi;t
xi;t 2 + fi + ui;t
yi;t + ( 0 + 1 ) xi;t
xi;t 2 + i + i;t
1
(8)
1
(9)
where the long-run multiplier is restricted to being homogeneous
= 1.
Using this form of the error correction model allows us to calculate the true
^ ^
long-run relationship between x and y, which can be written as 1
( = ) and
^ ^
1 ( = ). Hence, the one step ECM permits us to directly calculate the shortrun and long-run elasticities between openness and growth. To avoid the problem of biased estimates through a possible correlation between the lagged endogenous variable and the error term we use the Di¤erence GMM and System
GMM estimators developed by Arellano and Bond (1991) and Blundell and
Bond (1998). The former uses all lagged observations to instrument the lagged
endogenous variable and circumvent a possible bias. The latter combines the
regression in di¤erences with the regression in levels in a system and uses additional instruments in levels. The moment conditions of the instruments of both
estimators can be veri…ed using the Sargan statistic that tests the validity of all
instruments.
2.3
Results
The results of the corresponding error-correction regressions are summarized in
table 4. They include the coe¢cients of the regressions, the summation of the
short-run and long-run e¤ects with the corresponding Wald test p-values, the
Sargan tests and the M1 and M2 tests for the regressions. The …rst two columns
explore the dynamics of openness on GDP growth and contain the results with
reference to equation (8), while the third and fourth column investigate the
other direction of causality and are consequently based on equation (9). The
results of the income subpanels are presented in tables 5 and 6.
To verify GMM consistency, we have to make sure that the instruments are
valid. We use the Sargan test of over-identifying restrictions to test the validity
of the instrumental variables. The null hypothesis assumes that the orthogonality conditions of the instrumental variables are satis…ed. In all cases the
p-values show satisfactory results, indicating that the instruments used for the
estimation are valid. We also consider the test of second-order serial correlation
of the error term suggested by Arellano and Bond (1991). If the null hypothesis
of no second-order serial correlation of the error term cannot be rejected, the
GMM estimator is valid.
8
The coe¢cients of the error-correction term give the adjustment rate at
which short-run dynamics converge to the long-run equilibrium relationship.
With cover to our speci…cations it is the adjustment rate at which the gap
between openness and growth is closed. Generally, all these coe¢cients are
negative and highly signi…cant as expected, so the results show that there exists a long-run relationship and provide evidence of a cointegration relationship
between the variables.
The short-run e¤ect can be divided into the e¤ect of the lagged dependent
variable and that of the independent variable. The short-time adjustment of
the independent variable is measured by the e¤ect of the contemporaneous and
lagged change of the independent variable. The signi…cance of the summarized
short-run e¤ects, which is simply the sum of the two coe¢cient values, is tested
via a Wald test. The long-run coe¢cients indicate the long-run elasticities of
the independent on the dependent variable. They are computed by subtracting
the ratio of the coe¢cient of the scale e¤ect (lag of independent variable) and
the coe¢cient of the error-correction term from one; again, a Wald test proves
the signi…cance of the e¤ect.
Table 4: Estimated error-correction model
9
model
Dependent Variables
ln GDP
ln openn
ln opennt
ln opennt
2
ln opennt
2
1
ln GDPt
ln openn
Di¤.GMM
Sys.GMM
Di¤.GMM
Sys.GMM
-0.0480***
(0.0009)
0.0084***
(0.0006)
-0.0044
(0.0036)
-0.0609***
(0.0009)
-0.0051***
(0.0006)
0.0053
(0.0010)
-0.1441***
(0.0029)
-0.1199***
(0.0020)
-0.1300***
(0.0031)
-0.1261***
(0.0015)
0.0917***
(0.0015)
-0.0968***
(0.0033)
-0.1082***
(0.0014)
-0.1355***
(0.0025)
0.0744***
(0.0015)
-0.0927***
(0.0014)
2
ln GDP
ln GDPt
0.0097**
(0.0042)
0.0357***
(0.0012)
-0.0616***
(0.0036)
-0.0345***
(0.0006)
Summation
Short-run coe¢cient
Wald test (P-value)
Long run coe¢cient
Wald test (P-value)
-0.0396
0.0000
0.9280
0.0000
-0.0660
0.0000
1.1550
0.0000
-0.0343
0.0000
0.2555
0.0000
-0.0612
0.0000
0.1434
0.0000
Sargan test (P-value)
AR1 (P-value)
AR2 (P-value)
Observations
1.0000
0.0000
0.1353
5846
1.0000
0.0000
0.1088
6004
1.0000
0.0000
0.2083
5846
1.0000
0.0000
0.2266
6004
ln GDPt
2
ln GDPt
2
1
ln opennt
2
Notes:
(1) Estimation based on the Di¤erence GMM and the System GMM estimator.
(2) Asymptotically robust standard errors reported in parentheses.
(3) Sargan test is based on the estimation with GMM standard errors.
(4) *, ** and *** denote signi…cance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level.
With regard to the …rst ECM presented in the …rst two columns of table 4 all coe¢cients except the lagged openness variable are signi…cant at
the 5% signi…cance level at least. As expected the error-correction term is
negative and signi…cant, indicating that there is a long-run relationship between growth and openness. Furthermore, the signi…cant error-correction
10
Table 5: Estimated error-correction model: long-run and short-run dynamics of changes in openness on growth for subpanels
Dependent Variables ln GDP
low-income
lower-middle-income
Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM
Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM
upper-middle-income
Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM
high-income
Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM
OECD
Di¤.GMM
Sys.GMM
0.0240
(0.1118)
-0.1348***
(0.124)
-0.0112
(0.0168)
-0.0246
((0.0993)
-0.0044
(0.1074)
0.0244
(0.0450)
-0.1338***
(0.0166)
-0.0022
(0.0106)
-0.0336
(0.0389)
-0.0197
(0.0437)
-0.1248***
(0.0331)
-0.0367***
(0.0096)
-0.0039
(0.0035)
-0.1442***
(0.0341)
-0.1048***
(0.0353)
-0.0673***
(0.0086)
-0.0728***
(0.0117)
-0.0164***
(0.0017)
-0.0840***
(0.0087)
-0.0384***
(0.0082)
0.0622
(0.0753)
-0.0056
(0.0094)
-0.0024
(0.0089)
-0.0214
(0.0599)
0.0026
(0.0502)
-0.0153
(0.0177)
0.0018
(0.0088)
-0.0230***
(0.0086)
-0.0671***
(0.0172)
-0.0356***
(0.0134)
-0.0631
(0.2162)
0.1745*
(0.0915)
0.1842
(0.1512)
-0.2155**
(0.0863)
0.0033
(0.2292)
0.2012***
(0.0522)
0.1378***
(0.0352)
0.1457***
(0.0169)
-0.0724*
(0.0392)
0.0392**
(0.0171)
0.2438***
(0.0486)
0.2168***
(0.0128)
0.0747***
(0.0159)
-0.0651***
(0.0246)
-0.0235**
(0.0119)
0.2785***
(0.0661)
0.2461***
(0.0154)
0.0709***
(0.0199)
-0.0590
(0.0395)
-0.0204
(0.0175)
Summation
Short-run coef.
Wald test (P-value)
Long run coe¢cient
Wald test (P-value)
-0.1461
0.000
0.8199
0.821
-0.1361
0.000
0.4133
0.493
-0.0407
0.000
0.2730
0.000
-0.0892
0.000
0.5432
0.000
-0.0080
0.643
1.1207
0.677
-0.0212
0.173
0.4688
0.000
0.3588
0.136
1.0155
0.340
0.2834
0.000
1.5418
0.001
0.2915
0.000
0.6384
0.000
0.3170
0.000
0.6546
0.000
Sargan test (P-value)
AR1 (P-value)
AR2 (P-value)
Observations
1.0000
0.0016
0.4845
1110
1.000
0.0015
0.4738
1140
1.000
0.0080
0.0392
1665
1.000
0.0081
0.0296
1710
1.000
0.0354
0.3381
1517
1.000
0.0513
0.2030
1558
1.000
0.1592
0.1875
592
1.000
0.0123
0.0774
608
1.000
0.0004
0.2217
962
1.000
0.0004
0.2961
988
model
ln GDPt
1
ln openn
ln opennt
ln GDPt
ln opennt
1
ln opennt
2
2
2
11
Notes:
(1) Estimation based on the Di¤erence GMM and the System GMM estimator.
(2) Asymptotically robust standard errors reported in parentheses.
(3) Sargan test is based on the estimation with GMM standard errors.
(4) *, ** and *** denote signi…cance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level.
Table 6: Estimated error-correction model: long-run and short-run dynamics of growth on changes in openness for subpanels
Dependent Variables ln openn
low-income
lower-middle-income
Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM
Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM
upper-middle-income
Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM
high-income
Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM
OECD
Di¤.GMM
Sys.GMM
-0.2181
(0.1867)
-0.5135***
(0.0458)
0.0126
(0.1098)
-0.1605
(0.1958)
-0.2912
(0.2717)
-0.3076***
(0.5808)
-0.5148***
(0.0425)
-0.0608
(0.0567)
-0.2704***
(0.0606)
-0.4410***
(0.1338)
-0.1576**
(0.0748)
-0.1964***
(0.0479)
-0.0667
(0.0738)
-0.1949***
(0.0720)
-0.3573***
(0.1574)
-0.1284***
(0.0225)
-0.1512***
(0.0225)
0.0321
(0.0222)
-0.1341***
(0.2155)
-0.2087***
(0.0429)
-0.3318***
(0.0834)
0.0939***
(0.0263)
0.1599***
(0.0144)
-0.3330***
(0.0873)
-0.2307***
(0.0710)
-0.1075***
(0.0087)
0.0847***
(0.0258)
0.1213***
(0.1497)
-0.1193***
(0.0082)
-0.0810***
(0.0107)
-0.1905
(0.1429)
0.2728***
(0.0735)
-0.0279
(0.0723)
-0.2082
(0.1471)
-0.1989
(0.1417)
-0.0334
(0.0600)
0.3005***
(0.0641)
-0.0631**
(0.0266)
-0.0805
(0.0617)
-0.0935
(0.0575)
-0.0801
(0.0762)
0.5686***
(0.0369)
-0.0252
(0.0454)
-0.1359**
(0.0661)
-0.0381*
(0.0218)
0.0721*
(0.0381)
0.5694***
(0.0283)
-0.1576***
(0.0354)
-0.0144
(0.0254)
-0.0132*
(0.0076)
Summation
Short-run coef.
Wald test (P-value)
Long run coe¢cient
Wald test (P-value)
-0.5009
0.000
-0.8143
0.448
-0.5756
0.000
-0.6307
0.085
-0.2631
0.029
-0.8334
0.141
-0.1291
0.003
-0.5559
0.069
0.2538
0.000
0.3070
0.000
0.2060
0.000
0.3209
0.000
0.2448
0.000
0.0443
0.616
0.2374
0.000
-0.1606
0.607
0.5434
0.000
0.7199
0.000
0.4119
0.000
0.0796
0.959
Sargan test (P-value)
AR1 (P-value)
AR2 (P-value)
Observations
1.0000
0.0013
0.4020
1110
1.000
0.0001
0.5130
1140
1.000
0.0000
0.2588
1665
1.000
0.0000
0.4941
1710
1.000
0.0165
0.2257
1517
1.000
0.0037
0.3471
1558
1.000
0.1409
0.2792
592
1.000
0.0990
0.2721
608
1.000
0.0004
0.9870
962
1.000
0.0000
0.9010
988
model
ln opennt
1
ln GDP
ln GDPt
ln opennt
2
ln GDPt
2
1
ln GDPt
2
12
Notes:
(1) Estimation based on the Di¤erence GMM and the System GMM estimator.
(2) Asymptotically robust standard errors reported in parentheses.
(3) Sargan test is based on the estimation with GMM standard errors.
(4) *, ** and *** denote signi…cance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level.
coe¢cient implies that when there are deviations from long-run equilibrium, short-run adjustments in openness will re-establish the long-run
equilibrium. The absolute value of the term provides the speed of the
short-run adjustment process, indicating that about six per cent (-0.0616)
of the discrepancy in the case of the Di¤erence GMM estimator and about
three per cent (-0.0345) in the case of the System GMM estimator are corrected in each period. Aside from speed of adjustment the results indicate
the magnitude of the short-run e¤ect. It is measured by the sum of the
contemporaneous and lagged dependent variable and indicates a negative
signi…cant causal e¤ect from changes in openness on growth. The longrun e¤ect is positive signi…cant, indicating that in the long run changes
in openness cause higher GDP growth. These short-term and long-run
results show that the debate of free trade versus protectionism in the international trade literature should not be considered as two contradictory
aspects. Rather, foreign competition seems to have a negative short-term
e¤ect on growth. At the …rm level, in particular import-competing …rms
are disadvantaged and seek protection against openness. However, the
results show that in the long run free trade policies prove bene…cial to
productivity and growth, which is consistent with recent literature that
suggests that openness promotes economic development through various
channels, such as technological progress, increasing key markets and rising
competition.
Concerning the other direction of the causal relationship presented in the
third and fourth column of table 4, all coe¢cients as well as the short- and
long-run e¤ects are signi…cant at the 1% level for both estimators. Again
the error correction term is negative and signi…cant. This intensi…es the
long-run relationship with a short-run adjustment to equilibrium that we
already found in the …rst model. At about 13 and 11 per cent (-0.1300 for
Di¤erence GMM and -0.1082 for System GMM), respectively, the speed
of adjustment is higher than in the reversed model. The short-run e¤ect
of GDP growth on openness is negative and at nearly the same level as
the e¤ect of the other direction, indicating that the short-run openness
response to a temporary growth shock is of the same magnitude as the
growth response of a temporary openness shock. The long-run e¤ect is
positive and signi…cant, indicating that higher GDP growth causes greater
changes in openness. The magnitude of this e¤ect is lower than that of
the e¤ect of openness on growth. This implies that the long-run growth
response to permanent shocks in openness tends to be greater than the
openness response to permanent changes in growth; hence growth is more
sensitive to openness than vice versa. Again, the results show that even
though in the long run openness seems to be bene…cial for growth, in the
short term negative growth shocks may hit the economy and invoke a call
for protectionism.
Tables 5 and 6 present the results for the income subpanels, which are lowincome economies, lower-middle-income economies, upper-middle-income
13
economies, high-income economies and high-income OECD members. The
former table shows the causality from openness to GDP, the latter the reverse direction. When GDP growth is the dependant variable the long-run
e¤ect remains positive when signi…cant. However, we are unable to reveal
a long-run causal e¤ect for the low-income economies as well as for the difference estimator of the upper-middle-income and high-income economies.
The short-run e¤ect is signi…cant except for the upper-middle-income
economies and the di¤erence estimator of the high-income economies. The
results change depending on income. While the coe¢cients of the poorer
subpanels are negative, the results of the high-income subpanels show
a positive short-run e¤ect. This suggests that not only the trade level
but also the structure of trade should be taken into consideration. For
example, Hausmann et al. (2007) and Rodrik (2006) suggest that the
structure of export products matters to growth, while Lederman and Maloney (2003) show that trade has a di¤erent e¤ect on growth depending
on its structure in terms of natural resource abundance, export concentration, and intra-industry trade. This is consistent with our results that
suggest that because of a di¤erent trade structure the e¤ect of trade in
developing countries is di¤erent from that of trade in the industrialized
countries. A proposal for further research could be to analyse the causality
of trade openness and growth as a function of trade structure. Concerning
the other direction of causality when changes in openness are the dependent variable, both the short-run and the long-run e¤ect exhibit a change
in sign from negative for lower-income countries to positive for higherincome countries. Furthermore, the higher the average income the greater
the e¤ect of growth on openness. The results show that economic growth
only e¤ects trade openness positively above a certain income level (uppermiddle-income), while in lower-income countries growth seems to impede
openness.
In summary the overall results of the estimated ECMs for the entire panel
suggest a bidirectional positive long-run causality between GDP growth and
openness, indicating that openness promotes economic development and vice
versa. The short-run results suggest negative e¤ects pointing towards required
painful adjustments which often elicit a call for protectionism. That said, deeper
income subpanel analyses indicate that this result has needs to be di¤erentiated
by income groups. Whereas higher-income countries exhibit positive causalities
for both directions for the short-run and long-run e¤ect, lower-income countries have a negative short-run adjustment and a positive long-run a¤ect from
openness to growth but a negative long-run e¤ect in the other direction.
3
Summary and conclusion
The present study examines the causal relationship between trade openness
and economic growth. After reviewing recent empirical research regarding the
14
link between openness and growth we use recent panel estimation methods to
explore the causal relationship between these variables. In a …rst step we check
for stationarity using two common panel unit root tests, the IPS test and the
Fisher-type test. After that we apply a panel cointegration test on openness
and growth. As the variables are cointegrated we use panel ECMs to explore
the bilateral short-run and long-run dynamics between these variables.
We approach the problem of a potential endogeneity between openness and
growth by including only growth rates and lagged values of the independent variable. Additionally, we use instrumental variables and the Di¤erence GMM and
System GMM estimators developed by Arellano and Bond (1991) and Blundell
and Bond (1998) These estimators also address the issue of a possible correlation
between the lagged endogenous variable and the error term. The results suggest
that the long-run causality between trade openness and growth runs in both directions. This is in line with Harrison (1996) who argues that although more
open trade policies do precede higher growth rates, it is also true that higher
growth rates lead to more open trade regimes. The short-run adjustment for
both directions is negative. However, additional analyses for income-grouped
subpanels show that apart from the long-run e¤ect of openness on growth which
is persistently positive for all subpanels the e¤ect changes in sign depending on
income. While the lower-income subpanel shows a negative causality, the highincome countries exhibit a positive relationship between growth and openness.
The desired growth-led openness and openness-led growth hypothesis can only
be supported for industrialized countries. In developing countries only the longrun openness-led growth hypothesis holds, while growth seems to slow down
openness in the long run.
References
[1] Ahmad, J.; Kwan, A.C.C. (1991), Causality between exports and economic
growth: Empirical evidence from Africa, Economics Letters, Vol. 37, No.
3, pp. 243-248.
[2] Arellano, M.; Bond, S. (1991), Some Tests of Speci…cation for Panel Data:
Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations, The
Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 58, No. 2, pp. 277-297.
[3] Awokuse, T.O. (2007), Causality between exports, imports, and economic
growth: Evidence from transition economies, Economics Letters, Vol. 94,
No. 3, pp. 389-395
[4] Bahmani-Oskooee, M.; Mohtadi, H.; Shabsigh, G. (1991), Exports, growth
and causality in LDCs: A re-examination, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 36, No.2, pp. 405-415.
15
[5] Banerjee, A.; Dolado, J.J.; Galbraith, J.; Hendry, D.F. (1993), Cointegration, Error Correction, and the Econometric Analysis of NonStationary Data, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
[6] Banerjee, A.; Dolado, J.J.; Mestre, R. (1998), Error-correction Mechanism
Tests for Cointegration in a Single-equation Framework, Journal of Time
Series Analysis, Vol. 19, No. 3, pp. 267 - 283.
[7] Barro, R.J.; Lee, J.W. (1994), Sources of economic growth, CarnegieRochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 40, pp.1-46.
[8] Barro, R.J.; Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995), Economic Growth, McGraw-Hill,
Cambridge, MA.
[9] Bouoiyour, J. (2003), Trade and GDP Growth in Morocco: Short-run or
Long-run Causality?, Brazilian Journal of Business and Economics , Vol 3.
No. 2, pp. 14-21.
[10] Breitung, J. (2000), The local power of some unit root tests for panel data.
Advances in Econometrics, Vol. 15: Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration, and Dynamic Panels, ed. B. H. Baltagi, pp.161–178.
[11] Chang, R.; Kaltani, L.; Loayza, N. (2009), Openness is Good for Growth:
The Role of Policy Complementarities, Journal of Development Economics,
Vol. 90, pp. 33-49.
[12] Choi, I. (2001), Unit root tests for panel data, Journal of International
Money and Finance, Vol. 20, No. 2, pp. 249-272.
[13] Chow, P. (1987), Causality between exports growth and industrial development. Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 26, pp. 55–63.
[14] Dickey, D.A.; Fuller, W.A. (1979), Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series With a Unit Root, Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 74, No. 366, pp. 427-431.
[15] Dollar, D. (1992), Outward-oriented Developing Economies Really Do
Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85, Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 40, No. 3, pp. 523-44.
[16] Dollar, D.; Kraay, A. (2002), Growth is good for the poor. Journal of
Economic Growth, Vol. 7, No. 3, pp. 195– 225.
[17] Douglas A.I.; Terviö, M.(2002), Does trade raise income?: Evidence from
the twentieth century, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 58, No. 1,
pp. 1-18.
[18] Easterly, W.; Levine, R. (2001), What have we learned from a decade
of empirical research on growth? It’s Not Factor Accumulation: Stylized
Facts and Growth Models, World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 15, No. 2,
pp 177-219.
16
[19] Edwards, S. (1998), Openness, Productivity, and Growth: What Do We
Really Know?, Economic Journal, Vol.108 (447), pp. 383-98.
[20] Engle, R.F.; Granger, C.W.J. (1987), Co-Integration and Error Correction:
Representation, Estimation, and Testing, Econometrica, Vol. 55, No. 2, pp.
251-276.
[21] Frankel, J.A.; Romer, D.H. (1999), Does Trade Cause Growth?, American
Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 3, pp. 379–399.
[22] Granger, C.W.J. (1969), Investigating Causal Relations by Econometric
Models and Cross-Spectral Methods, Econometrica Vol. 37, No. 3, pp. 424438.
[23] Grossman, G.M.; Helpman, E. (1991), Innovation and Growth in the Global
Economy, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
[24] Hausmann, R.; Hwang, J.; Rodrik, D. (2007), What You Export Matters,
Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 12, No. 1, pp. 1–25.
[25] Harrison, A. (1996), Openness and Growth: A Time-Series, Cross-Country
Analysis for Developing Countries, Journal of Development Economics, Vol
48, No. 2, pp. 419-47.
[26] Heston, A.; Summers, R.; Aten, B. (2011), Penn World Table Version 7.0,
Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at
the University of Pennsylvania.
[27] Hsiao, M.W. (1987), Tests of causality and exogeneity between export
growth and economic growth, Journal of Economic Development, Vol. 12,
pp. 143–159.
[28] Im, K.S.; Pesaran, M.H.; Shin, Y. (2003), Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 115, No. 1, pp. 53-74.
[29] Irwin, D.A.; Tervio, M. (2000), Does trade raise income? Evidence from
the twentieth century, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 58, No. 1,
pp.1-18.
[30] Islam, N. (1995), Growth Empirics: A Panel Data Approach, The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, No. 4, pp. 1127-1170.
[31] Islam M.N. (1998), Export expansion and economic growth: testing for
cointegration and causality, Applied Economics, Vol. 30, No. 3, pp. 415425.
[32] Jung, W.; Marshall, P. (1985), Exports, growth and causality in developing
countries. Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 18, pp. 1–12.
[33] Krugman, P. (1994), The Myth of Asia’s Miracle, Foreign A¤airs, Vol. 73,
No. 6, pp. 62-78.
17
[34] Lederman, D.; Maloney, W.F. (2003), Trade Structure and Growth, World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3025.
[35] Levin, A.; Lin, C.F.; Chu, C.S.J. (2002), Unit root tests in panel data:
asymptotic and …nite-sample properties, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 108,
No. 1, pp. 1-24.
[36] Liu, X.; Burridge, P.; Sinclair, P.J.N. (2002), Relationships between economic growth, foreign direct investment and trade: evidence from China,
Applied Economics, Vol. 34, No. 11, pp. 1433-1440.
[37] Maddala, G.S.; Wu, S. (1999), A Comparative Study of Unit Root Tests
with Panel Data and a New Simple Test, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics, Vol. 61, No. 1, pp. 631-652.
[38] Noguer, M.; Siscart, M. (2005), Trade raises income: a precise and robust
result, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 65, No. 2, pp. 447-460.
[39] Pedroni, P. (1999), Critical Values for Cointegration Tests in Heterogeneous Panels with Multiple Regressors, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics, Vol. 61, No. 0, pp. 653-70.
[40] Pedroni, P. (2004), Panel Cointegration: Asymptotic And Finite Sample
Properties Of Pooled Time Series Tests With An Application To The PPP
Hypothesis, Econometric Theory, Cambridge University Press, Vol. 20, No.
3, pp 597-625.
[41] Rodrik, D.; Rodríguez, F. (2001), Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A
Skeptics Guide to the Cross-National Evidence, in B. Bernanke and K.
Rogo¤ (editors), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, Vol. 15, MIT Press,
pp. 261-325.
[42] Rodrik, D. (2006), What’s So Special about China’s Exports? China and
the World Economy, Vol. 14, No. 5, pp. 1–19.
[43] Romer (1993), Two strategies for economic development: Using ideas and
producing ideas, proceedings of the World Bank annual conference on development economics, 1992, ed. Summers, L.H; Shah, S., pp. 63–91. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
[44] Sala-i-Martin, X. (1997), I Just Ran Two Million Regressions, The American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 2, pp. 178-183.
[45] Yasar, M.; Nelson, C.H.; Rejesus, R.M. (2006), The Dynamics of Exports
and Productivity at the Plant Level: A Panel Data Error Correction Model
(ECM) Approach, in B.H. Baltagi (ed.), Panel Data Econometrics: Theoretical Contributions and Empirical Applications, pp. 279-306, Amsterdam:
Elsevier.
18
4
Appendix
Appendix 1
The countries included in the analysis are
low-income economies ($1005 or less GDP per capita):
Afghanistan, Bangladesh, Benin, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cambodia, Central African Republic, Chad, Comoros, Dem. Rep Congo, Ethiopia, The Gambia, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Haiti, Kenya, Liberia, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali,
Mozambique, Nepal, Niger, Rwanda, Sierra Leone, Somalia, Tanzania, Togo,
Uganda, Zimbabwe
lower-middle-income economies ($1006 to $3975 GDP per capita):
Angola, Belize, Bhutan, Bolivia, Cameroon, Cape Verde, Republic of Congo,
Cote d‘Ivoire, Djibouti, Egypt, El Salvador, Fiji, Ghana, Guatemala, Guyana,
Honduras, India, Indonesia, Iraq, Kiribati, Laos, Lesotho, Marshall Islands,
Mauritania, Fed. Sts. Micronesia, Mongolia, Morocco, Nicaragua, Nigeria,
Pakistan, Papua New Guinea, Paraguay, Philippines, Samoa, Sao Tome and
Principe, Senegal, Solomon Islands, Sri Lanka, Sudan, Swaziland, Syria, Tonga,
Vanuatu, Vietnam, Zambia
upper-middle-income economies ($3976 to $12275 GDP per capita):
Albania, Algeria, Antigua and Barbuda, Argentina, Botswana, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China Version 1, China Version 2, Colombia, Costa Rica, Cuba,
Dominica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Gabon, Grenada, Iran, Jamaica, Jordan, Lebanon, Malaysia, Maldives, Mauritius, Mexico, Namibia, Panama, Peru,
Romania, Seychelles, South Africa, St. Kitts & Nevis, St. Lucia, St.Vincent &
Grenadines, Suriname, Thailand, Tunisia, Turkey, Uruguay, Venezuela
high-income economies ($12276 or more GDP per capita):
Bahamas, Bahrain, Barbados, Bermuda, Brunei, Cyprus, Equatorial Guinea,
Hong Kong, Israel, Macao, Malta, Oman, Puerto Rico, Singapore, Taiwan,
Trinidad & Tobago
high-income OECD members:
Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany,
Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Republic of Korea, Luxembourg, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Spain, Sweden,
Switzerland, United Kingdom, United States
19
Recent discussion papers
2012-06
Thomas Gries
Margarete Redlin
Trade Openness and Economic Growth: A Panel Causality
Analysis
2012-05
Mark Schopf
Hendrik Ritter
Reassessing the Green Paradox
2012-04
Yuanhua Feng
David Hand
Keming Yu
A Multivariate Random Walk Model with Slowly Changing
Drift and Cross-correlation Applied to Finance
2012-03
Sarah Brockhoff
Tim Krieger
Daniel Meierriecks
Looking Back on Anger: Explaining the Social Origins of
Left-Wing and Nationalist-Separatist Terrorism in Western
Europe, 1970-2007
2012-02
Sonja Brangewitz
Sarah Brockhoff
Stability of Coalitional Equilibria within Repeated Tax Competition
2012-01
Sarah Brockhoff
Tim Krieger
Daniel Meierriecks
Great Expectations and Hard Times The (Nontrivial) Impact of Education on Domestic Terrorism
2011-13
Tim Krieger
Jens Ruhose
“Honey, I shrunk the kids’ benefits!”—
Revisiting intergenerational conflict in OECD countries.
2011-12
Tim Krieger
9/11's Legacy: How Abstract Fear and Collective Memory
Lead to Real Economic Costs
2011-11
Yuanhua Feng
Data-driven estimation of diurnal duration patterns
2011-10
B. Michael Gilroy
Birke Thuy Duong Nguyen
Ist Fairer Handel Wirklich Fair?
2011-09
Yuanhua Feng
Zhichao Guo
Christian Peitz
Xiangyong Tan
A tree-form constant market share model for growth causes
in international trade based on multi-level classification
2011-08
Tim Krieger
Daniel Meierriecks
Ökonomische Aspekte des neuen globalen Terrorismus
2011-07
Tim Krieger
Daniel Meierrieks
Terrorist Financing and Money Laundering
2011-06
Thomas Gries
Stefan Jungblut
Wim Naudé
New Firm Creation and Failure: A Matching Approach
2011-05
Daniel Kaimann
"To infinity and beyond!" - A genre-specific film analysis
of movie success mechanisms
2011-04
Yuanhua Feng
Zhichao Guo
Christian Peitz
Xiangyong Tan
A tree-form constant market share analysis for modelling
growth causes in international trade
2011-03
Zhichao Guo
Yuanhua Feng
Xiangyong Tan
Impact of China’s accession to WTO and the financial crisis
on China’s exports to Germany
2011-02
Alexander Haupt
Tim Krieger
Thomas Lange
Competition for the International Pool of Talent: Education
Policy and Student Mobility
2011-01
B. Michael Gilroy
Daniel Kruse
Die Prinzipal-Agent-Theorie als Erklärungsinstrumentarium
von Korruption: Angewendet auf den Praxisfall „Siemens“
2010-09
Yuanhua Feng
An iterative plug-in algorithm for decomposing seasonal
time series using the Berlin Method
2010-08
Zhichao Guo
Yuanhua Feng
Xiangyong Tan
Short- and long-term impact of remarkable economic events
on the growth causes of China-Germany trade in agri-food
products
[published in: Economic Modelling 28 (2011), 2359-2368]
2010-07
B. Michael Gilroy
Elmar Lukas
Christian Heimann
Welchen Einfluss hat die Anwesenheit von
ausländischen und multinationalen Unternehmungen
auf die deutschen Exporte?
2010-06
Stefan Gravemeyer
Thomas Gries
Income and disparity in Germany and China
2010-05
Thomas Gries
Margarete Redlin
Short-run and Long-run Dynamics of Growth,
Inequality and Poverty in the Developing World
2010-04
Stefan Gravemeyer
Thomas Gries
Jinjun Xue
Poverty in Shenzen
2010-03
Alexander Haupt
Tim Krieger
Thomas Lange
A Note on Brain Gain and Brain Drain:
Permanent Migration and Education Policy
2010-02
Sarah Brockhoff
Tim Krieger
Daniel Meierrieks
Ties That Do Not Bind (Directly):
The Education Terrorism Nexus Revisited
2010-01
Claus-Jochen Haake,
Tim Krieger,
Steffen Minter
On the institutional design of burden sharing when financing
external border enforcement in the EU