Academia.eduAcademia.edu

Trade Openness and Economic Growth: A Panel Causality Analysis

2012

This paper examines the short-term and long-run dynamics between per capita GDP growth and openness for 158 countries over the period 1970-2009. We use panel cointegration tests and panel error-correction models (ECM) in combination with GMM estimation to explore the causal relationship between these two variables. We approach the problem of a potential endogeneity between openness and growth by including only growth rates and lagged values of the independent variable. Additionally, we apply Difference GMM and System GMM estimation. These estimators also address the issue of a possible correlation between the lagged endogenous variable and the error term. The results suggest a long-run relationship between openness and economic growth with a short-run adjustment to the deviation from the equilibrium for both directions of dependency. The long-run coefficients indicate a positive significant causality from openness to growth and vice versa, indicating that international integration i...

CENTER FOR INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Working Paper Series Working Paper No. 2011-06 Trade Openness and Economic Growth: A Panel Causality Analysis Thomas Gries, Margarete Redlin June 2012 Trade Openness and Economic Growth: A Panel Causality Analysis T. Griesa) , M. Redlinb)F University of Paderborn, Germany Abstract This paper examines the short-term and long-run dynamics between per capita GDP growth and openness for 158 countries over the period 1970-2009. We use panel cointegration tests and panel error-correction models (ECM) in combination with GMM estimation to explore the causal relationship between these two variables. We approach the problem of a potential endogeneity between openness and growth by including only growth rates and lagged values of the independent variable. Additionally, we apply Di¤erence GMM and System GMM estimation. These estimators also address the issue of a possible correlation between the lagged endogenous variable and the error term. The results suggest a long-run relationship between openness and economic growth with a short-run adjustment to the deviation from the equilibrium for both directions of dependency. The long-run coe¢cients indicate a positive signi…cant causality from openness to growth and vice versa, indicating that international integration is a bene…cial strategy for growth in the long term. By contrast the short-run coe¢cient shows a negative short-run adjustment, suggesting that openness can be painful for an economy undergoing short-term adjustments. In addition to the entire panel we subdivide the data into income-related subpanels. While the long-run e¤ect remains predominantly positive and signi…cant, the shortrun adjustment becomes positive when the income level increases. This result suggests that di¤erent trade structures in low-income and high-income countries have di¤erent e¤ects on economic growth. Keywords: JEL Classi…cation: openness, trade, growth, development, panel cointegration, F10, F15, F43, 05 1 a) Corresponding author: b) F Co-author: Thomas Gries [email protected] Economics Department, University of Paderborn Center for International Economics (C-I-E), www.C-I-E.org Warburger Strasse 100 33098 Paderborn, Germany Margarete Redlin [email protected] Economics Department, University of Paderborn Warburger Strasse 100 33098 Paderborn, Germany The autors would like to thank René Fahr and Wendelin Schnedler for theire valuable comments. 1 Introduction The relationship between openness and economic growth has long been a subject of much interest and controversy in international trade literature. With regard to a theoretical relationship between openness and growth most of the studies provide support for the proposition that openness e¤ects growth positively. Romer (1993), Grossman and Helpman (1991) and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995) among others, argue that countries that are more open have a greater ability to catch up to leading technologies of the rest of the world. Chang, Kaltani, Loayza (2005) point out that openness promotes the e¢cient allocation of resources through comparative advantage, allows the dissemination of knowledge and technological progress, and encourages competition in domestic and international markets. However there exists also the opposed position. For example Krugman (1994) and Rodrik and Rodríguez (2001) argue that the effect of openness on growth is doubtful. Furthermore, if we include the gains from trade debate we look at a long lasting debate discussing conditions and circumstances when openness and trade may be favourable and may improve the economic performance or not. These controversial theoretical …ndings also appear in the empirical literature. Numerous econometric studies have tried to identify the relationship and the causal direction between openness and economic growth. These studies can be divided into three groups. First, conventional regression analyses trying to capture the e¤ect of openness by regressing it on per capita growth. There are several studies in this vein, with the vast majority concluding that openness to trade is a signi…cant explanatory variable for economic growth (see e.g. some more recent contributions like Dollar (1992), Edwards (1998), Harrison (1996), Barro and Lee (1994), Easterly and Levine (2001), Dollar and Kraay (2002), Irwin and Tervio (2000), Islam (1995), Salai-Martin (1997)). However, conventional regression methods analyse only one direction of a possible bidirectional relationship and are unable to uncover the causation of trade openness and GDP growth. The second group of studies uses Granger causality based tests on the openness and economic growth variables. Here the results show a more mixed picture. Jung and Marshall (1985) employ the Granger causality test and …nd unidirectional causality from exports to growth for four out of 37 countries for the period 1951-1981. Chow (1987) analyses eight industrialized countries and …nds bidirectional causality in six cases and one case with unidirectional causality from exports to growth. Hsiao (1987) uses Granger causality tests for Asian countries. The results show only unidirectional causality from growth to exports for the case of Hong Kong. Ahmad and Kwan (1991) investigate 47 African countries and …nd no causality between exports and growth. However, Bahmani-Oskooee (1991) applies Granger causality tests for 20 countries and …nds both positive and negative causality e¤ects for both directions. Although these kinds of studies try to capture a bidirectional relationship, Engle and Granger (1987) have shown that when the series are cointegrated a standard Granger-causality test is misspeci…ed. The third group of studies picks up the problem of biased results in the event of cointegrated series and uses the concept of cointegration and error-correction 1 to explore the short-run and long-run dynamics between openness and growth. These analyses are based on time series data and investigate the causalities at country level. Islam (1998) uses an error-correction model for each of 15 Asian countries1 for the period 1967-1991 and …nds export to growth causality for 10 out of 15 countries. Liu et al. (2002) investigate China over the period 1981-1997 and …nd bidirectional causality between FDI, exports and growth. Bouoiyour (2003) applies the concept of cointegration and error correction to the relationship between trade and economic growth in Morocco over the period 1960-2000. The results show a lack of long-run causality. In the short run higher imports and exports cause higher GDP. Awokuse (2007) examines the impact of export and import expansion on growth in three transition economies on country level. The results show bidirectional causality between exports and growth for Bulgaria, the Czech Republic exhibits unidirectional causality from exports and imports on growth, and for Poland only the import-led growth hypothesis can be supported. A weak point of these studies is the absence of a general examination of the causality between openness and economic growth on cross-country level. All these studies investigate the relationship on a certain country level for time series data. A general panel error correction model has not been applied yet. Therefore, this study aims to address this problem and to re-examine the issue of causal links between trade openness and growth using an error correction model for a panel of 158 countries over the period 1970-2009. This methodological framework allows us to test for bidirectional causality relations from openness to GDP and vice versa. Furthermore, this method enables us to distinguish between short-run and long-term e¤ects between trade and growth. In particular we shed light on the question of whether bene…ts of trade or fears of negative e¤ects of trade address di¤erent time horizons. That is, …nding a long-term positive causality from trade to growth would provide evidence on long-term bene…ts of international integration. Ba contrast, the presence of negative causal e¤ects in the short term would be an indicator of the pain of adjustment an economy has to sustain if long-term bene…t is the target. We also break down our data set into …ve subpanels following the World Bank income classi…cation to allow us to investigate income-related e¤ect di¤erences. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the empirical investigation including the data, the methodology and the results of the panel unit root tests, the panel cointegration tests, and the error-correction model. Section 3 concludes. 2 Empirical evidence This section investigates the causal relationship between trade openness and economic growth. In a …rst step we use recently developed panel unit root and cointegration tests. Then we apply panel-based error-correction models to 1 The countries included in the analysis are Bangladesh, Fiji, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Nepal, Pakistan, Papua New Guinea, Philippines, Singapore, South Korea, Sri Lanka, and Thailand. 2 explore the bidirectional short-run and long-run dynamics between these two variables. In our analysis we try to capture the problem of possible endogeneity of the openness variable. Our starting point is to test for causality of openness on growth and vice versa. However, a loop of causality between the independent and dependent variables of a model leads to endogeneity problems in a simple regression model. Previous studies of causality between openness and growth ignore this potentially interdependence which leads to a correlation between the endogenous variable and the error term. These kinds of studies disregard a potential endogeneity of openness and growth and so produce biased and inconsistent parameter estimates. Current literature identi…es this problem and provides two common suggestions to deal with it. The …rst is the use of lagged values of the exogenous variables. Second, the endogeneity problem can also be addressed appropriately by using instrumental variables (IV) techniques. So if a dependent variable is potentially endogenous, it is intuitively appealing to look for a proxy that does not su¤er from the same problem. For example Frankel and Romer (1999) use geographic attributes as instruments to identify the e¤ects of trade on income. This approach is also adopted by Irvin and Terviö (2002) and Noguera and Siscart 2005). We abstract from these geographical determinants of trade by focusing on changes in openness. Our model includes only growth rates and lagged values of the independent variable. Additionally, we approach this problem by using GMM estimation. It also addresses the issue of a possible correlation between the lagged endogenous variable and the error term. We use the Di¤erence GMM and System GMM estimators developed by Arellano and Bond (1991) and Blundell and Bond (1998). These estimators deal e¤ectively with the endogeneity problem by using a set of instruments for the endogenous variables. The former uses lagged levels as instruments for the equation in di¤erences; in addition to that the latter uses lagged di¤erences as instruments for the additional equations in levels. Furthermore, concerning the substance we explore both directions of action between trade and growth using a simultaneous bivariate model. 2.1 Data Regarding openness there are several variables that can be used to measure the degree of openness. They can be broadly divided into two categories: measures of trade volumes and measures of trade restrictions. The most common measure in the …rst group is trade share, which is the sum of exports plus imports divided by GDP. The second category includes measures of trade barriers that include average tari¤ rates, export taxes, total taxes on international trade, and indices of non-tari¤ barriers. To perform a broad panel analysis of a large number of countries and over a long period we select a measure that is widely available, namely trade share. We use a balanced panel data set containing 158 countries over the period 1970-2009. Our analysis is based on two variables from the Penn World Table 7.0. provided by Heston et al. (2011): 3 Openness: opennessi;t Trade measured by the sum of exports and imports as a percentage of GDP at 2005 constant prices. The variable corresponds to the openk variable from the Penn World Table. GDP per capita: GDPi;t GDP per capita is PPP converted GDP per capita (Laspeyres) at 2005 constant prices in international dollar per person. The variable corresponds to the rgdpl variable from the Penn World Table. In addition to the entire panel, we segment the data set into …ve subpanels according to per capita income. We use the World Bank country classi…cation that distinguishes between low-income economies ($1005 or less), lower-middleincome economies ($1006 to $3975), upper-middle-income economies ($3976 to $12275), high-income economies ($12276 or more) and high-income OECD members. Table 1 provides the descriptive statistics of the panel data set and the subpanels.2 Table 1: Descriptive Statistics panel 1 2-LI 3-LMI 4-UMI 5-HI 6-OECD observations openness mean std. dev. GDP per capita mean std. dev. 6320 1200 1800 1640 640 1040 75.52 50.23 50.38 29.46 80.88 39.34 76.13 44.76 133.08 74.25 58.85 44.91 8797.21 11083.70 793.34 349.01 2734.28 1721.35 6557.28 3451.02 21164.17 14772.27 24447.75 10193.08 2.2 Estimation Methodology: To explore the short-run and long-run dynamics between GDP growth and changes in openness we follow Yasar et al. (2006) and apply a generalized one-step error-correction model (ECM) in combination with panel data and GMM estimation. We prefer dynamic panel estimators for various reasons. GMM estimation circumvents the bias associated with including a lagged dependent variable as a regressor and enables us to calculate consistent and ef…cient estimates. Additionally, by combining the time series dimension with the cross-sectional dimension, the panel data provides a richer set of information to exploit the relationship between the dependent and independent variables, reduces collinearity among the explanatory variables, increases the degrees of freedom, and gives more variability and e¢ciency. More speci…cally, our point of departure is a bivariate autoregressive-distributed lag model 2 Appendix 1 provides a detailed list of all included countries and the income segmentation. 4 yi;t = 0+ 2 X j yi;t j + j=1 xi;t = 0+ 2 X 2 X j xi;t j + fi + ui;t (1) j yi;t j + (2) j=0 j xi;t j + j=1 2 X i + i;t j=0 where index i=1...N refers to the country and t=1...T to the period. This method allows us to include speci…c e¤ects for each country (fi and i ). This individual e¤ect may correlate with the included explanatory variables, hence omitting the individual e¤ect would become part of the error term, which would lead to a bias in the estimates. The disturbances ui;t and i;t are assumed to be independently distributed across countries with a zero mean. They may display heteroskedasticity across time and countries, though. Following Granger (1969) there is Granger causality from x to y if past values of x improve the prediction of y given the past values of y. With respect to the model x Granger causes y if not all j are zero. By the same token Granger causality from y to x occurs if not all j are equal to zero. However, Engle and Granger (1987) have shown that, if the series x and y are cointegrated, the standard Granger causality test is misspeci…ed. In this case an ECM should be used instead. In a …rst step we have to apply a unit root and a cointegration test. On the basis of the results we determine whether to use the Granger causality framework or an ECM model to test causality. Panel unit root test: The Granger causality test requires the variables to be stationary. We check their stationarity using two common panel unit root tests, the IPS test by Im, et al. (2003) and the Fisher-type test by Maddala and Wu (1999) and Choi (2001). Formally, the test equation of both tests is 4yi;t = i + i yi;t 1 + "it , (3) with the null hypothesis that each cross-section series in the panel has a unit root and the alternative hypothesis that at least one cross-section in the panel is stationary. Additionally, the formulation allows i to di¤er across cross-sections so that both tests allow for heterogeneity. H0 H1 : : i i = 0 f or all i < 0; i = 1; 2; :::; N1 ; i Table 2: Panel unit root test 5 = 0; (4) i = N1 + 1; N2 + 1; :::N: (5) variable deterministic IPS Fisher-type …rst di¤. IPS …rst di¤. Fisher-type openness constant const. + trend constant const. + trend 1.0752 -0.2000 5.1565 0.7044 319.487 329.420 250.553 334.263 -40.5784*** -34.8509*** -34.1635*** -30.0096*** 2176.00*** 1744.49*** 1787.10*** 1472.30*** GDP Notes: * Rejects the null of a unit root at the 10% level. ** Rejects the null of a unit root at the 5% level. *** Rejects the null of a unit root at the 1% level. The IPS test is a t-bar statistic based on the augmented Dickey-Fuller statistic (Dickey and Fuller 1979). The test statistic is computed by the sample mean of the individual unit root tests for each of the N cross-section units. The main idea of the Fisher-type unit root test is to combine p-values from the unit root tests applied to each of the N cross-section units in the panel. While both IPS and the Fisher-type test combine information based on individual unit root tests, the crucial di¤erence between the two is that the IPS test combines the test statistics while the Fisher-type test combines the signi…cance levels of the individual tests. Table 2 presents the results of the tests for both variables in levels and in …rst di¤erences. The results indicate that for both variables the level data is non-stationary, however the test statistics of the di¤erenced variables are highly signi…cant and show stationarity regardless of whether the trend is included in the test or not.3 Hence, the following analysis is based on the di¤erenced data, namely GDP growth and changes in openness. Panel cointegration test: Since the panel unit root tests presented above indicate that the variables are integrated of order one I(1), we test for cointegration using the panel cointegration test developed by Pedroni (1999, 2004). This test allows for heterogeneity in the panel by permitting heterogenous slope coe¢cients, …xed e¤ects and individual speci…c deterministic trends. The test contains seven cointegration statistics, the …rst four based on pooling the residuals along the "within-dimension" which assume a common value for the unit root coe¢cient, and the subsequent three based on polling the residuals along the "between dimension" which allow for di¤erent values of the unit root coef…cient. The common idea of both classes is to …rst estimate the hypothesized cointegration relationship separately for each group member of the panel and then pool the resulting residuals when constructing the test for the null of no 3 Additionally, we test also the homogeneous alternative of the H hypothesis that assumes 1 that the autoregressive parameter is identical for all cross-section units. The Levin, Lin and Chu (2002) and Breitung (2000) unit root tests also indicate that the variables are integrated of order on I(1). 6 cointegration. Table 3 presents the results. In all cases the null of no cointegration is rejected at the 1% signi…cance level, indicating that the variables exhibit a cointegration relationship. Table 3: Panel cointegration test openness - GDP Panel -test Panel -test Panel pp-test Panel adf -test Group -test Group pp-test Group adf -test 4.3802*** -5.7259*** -6.3860*** -5.9561*** -3.2054*** -5.9503*** -6.4598*** Notes: Based on individual intercept and automatic lag length selection based on AIC. * Rejects the null of no cointegation at the 10% level. ** Rejects the null of no cointegation at the 5% level. *** Rejects the null of no cointegation at the 1% level. Error correction model: Engle and Granger (1987) have shown that when the series x and y are cointegrated a standard Granger-causality test as presented in the equations (1) and (2) is misspeci…ed, because it does not allow for the distinction between the short-run and the long run-e¤ect. At this point a error correction model (ECM) should be used instead. It is a linear transformation of the ADL models above and provides a link between the shortrun and the long-run e¤ect (Banerjee et al. 1993, 1998). yi;t xi;t = ( 1 1) yi;t 1 + 0 xi;t + ( 0 + 1 ) xi;t + (yi;t 2 xi;t 2 ) + fi + ui;t = ( 1 1) xi;t 1 + 0 yi;t + ( 0 + 1 ) yi;t + (xi;t 2 yi;t 2 ) + i + i;t 1 (6) 1 (7) While the coe¢cients ( 1 1), 0 and ( 0 + 1 ) as well as ( 1 1), 0 and ( 0 + 1 ) capture the short-run e¤ects, the coe¢cients and of the error correction terms give the adjustment rates at which short-run dynamics converge to the long-run equilibrium relationship. If and are negative and signi…cant a relationship between x and y exist in the long run. The standard error-correction procedure is a two-step method where in a …rst step the error correction term is obtained by saving residuals of separate estimation of the long-run equilibrium of x and y. In a second step the ECM with the included error correction term can be estimated. However, the two-stage error correction models have been criticized in the literature. Banerjee et al. (1998) argue that there can be a substantial small-sample bias compared to a single-equation error 7 correction model where the long-run relation is restricted to being homogeneous. Accordingly, in this study we use a one-step procedure to indicate the shortrun and long-run dynamics. The generalized one-step ECM is transformed as follows: yi;t xi;t = ( 1 1) yi;t 1 + 0 + (yi;t 2 xi;t 2 ) + = ( 1 1) xi;t 1 + 0 + (xi;t 2 yi;t 2 ) + xi;t + ( 0 + 1 ) xi;t xi;t 2 + fi + ui;t yi;t + ( 0 + 1 ) xi;t xi;t 2 + i + i;t 1 (8) 1 (9) where the long-run multiplier is restricted to being homogeneous = 1. Using this form of the error correction model allows us to calculate the true ^ ^ long-run relationship between x and y, which can be written as 1 ( = ) and ^ ^ 1 ( = ). Hence, the one step ECM permits us to directly calculate the shortrun and long-run elasticities between openness and growth. To avoid the problem of biased estimates through a possible correlation between the lagged endogenous variable and the error term we use the Di¤erence GMM and System GMM estimators developed by Arellano and Bond (1991) and Blundell and Bond (1998). The former uses all lagged observations to instrument the lagged endogenous variable and circumvent a possible bias. The latter combines the regression in di¤erences with the regression in levels in a system and uses additional instruments in levels. The moment conditions of the instruments of both estimators can be veri…ed using the Sargan statistic that tests the validity of all instruments. 2.3 Results The results of the corresponding error-correction regressions are summarized in table 4. They include the coe¢cients of the regressions, the summation of the short-run and long-run e¤ects with the corresponding Wald test p-values, the Sargan tests and the M1 and M2 tests for the regressions. The …rst two columns explore the dynamics of openness on GDP growth and contain the results with reference to equation (8), while the third and fourth column investigate the other direction of causality and are consequently based on equation (9). The results of the income subpanels are presented in tables 5 and 6. To verify GMM consistency, we have to make sure that the instruments are valid. We use the Sargan test of over-identifying restrictions to test the validity of the instrumental variables. The null hypothesis assumes that the orthogonality conditions of the instrumental variables are satis…ed. In all cases the p-values show satisfactory results, indicating that the instruments used for the estimation are valid. We also consider the test of second-order serial correlation of the error term suggested by Arellano and Bond (1991). If the null hypothesis of no second-order serial correlation of the error term cannot be rejected, the GMM estimator is valid. 8 The coe¢cients of the error-correction term give the adjustment rate at which short-run dynamics converge to the long-run equilibrium relationship. With cover to our speci…cations it is the adjustment rate at which the gap between openness and growth is closed. Generally, all these coe¢cients are negative and highly signi…cant as expected, so the results show that there exists a long-run relationship and provide evidence of a cointegration relationship between the variables. The short-run e¤ect can be divided into the e¤ect of the lagged dependent variable and that of the independent variable. The short-time adjustment of the independent variable is measured by the e¤ect of the contemporaneous and lagged change of the independent variable. The signi…cance of the summarized short-run e¤ects, which is simply the sum of the two coe¢cient values, is tested via a Wald test. The long-run coe¢cients indicate the long-run elasticities of the independent on the dependent variable. They are computed by subtracting the ratio of the coe¢cient of the scale e¤ect (lag of independent variable) and the coe¢cient of the error-correction term from one; again, a Wald test proves the signi…cance of the e¤ect. Table 4: Estimated error-correction model 9 model Dependent Variables ln GDP ln openn ln opennt ln opennt 2 ln opennt 2 1 ln GDPt ln openn Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM -0.0480*** (0.0009) 0.0084*** (0.0006) -0.0044 (0.0036) -0.0609*** (0.0009) -0.0051*** (0.0006) 0.0053 (0.0010) -0.1441*** (0.0029) -0.1199*** (0.0020) -0.1300*** (0.0031) -0.1261*** (0.0015) 0.0917*** (0.0015) -0.0968*** (0.0033) -0.1082*** (0.0014) -0.1355*** (0.0025) 0.0744*** (0.0015) -0.0927*** (0.0014) 2 ln GDP ln GDPt 0.0097** (0.0042) 0.0357*** (0.0012) -0.0616*** (0.0036) -0.0345*** (0.0006) Summation Short-run coe¢cient Wald test (P-value) Long run coe¢cient Wald test (P-value) -0.0396 0.0000 0.9280 0.0000 -0.0660 0.0000 1.1550 0.0000 -0.0343 0.0000 0.2555 0.0000 -0.0612 0.0000 0.1434 0.0000 Sargan test (P-value) AR1 (P-value) AR2 (P-value) Observations 1.0000 0.0000 0.1353 5846 1.0000 0.0000 0.1088 6004 1.0000 0.0000 0.2083 5846 1.0000 0.0000 0.2266 6004 ln GDPt 2 ln GDPt 2 1 ln opennt 2 Notes: (1) Estimation based on the Di¤erence GMM and the System GMM estimator. (2) Asymptotically robust standard errors reported in parentheses. (3) Sargan test is based on the estimation with GMM standard errors. (4) *, ** and *** denote signi…cance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level. With regard to the …rst ECM presented in the …rst two columns of table 4 all coe¢cients except the lagged openness variable are signi…cant at the 5% signi…cance level at least. As expected the error-correction term is negative and signi…cant, indicating that there is a long-run relationship between growth and openness. Furthermore, the signi…cant error-correction 10 Table 5: Estimated error-correction model: long-run and short-run dynamics of changes in openness on growth for subpanels Dependent Variables ln GDP low-income lower-middle-income Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM upper-middle-income Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM high-income Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM OECD Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM 0.0240 (0.1118) -0.1348*** (0.124) -0.0112 (0.0168) -0.0246 ((0.0993) -0.0044 (0.1074) 0.0244 (0.0450) -0.1338*** (0.0166) -0.0022 (0.0106) -0.0336 (0.0389) -0.0197 (0.0437) -0.1248*** (0.0331) -0.0367*** (0.0096) -0.0039 (0.0035) -0.1442*** (0.0341) -0.1048*** (0.0353) -0.0673*** (0.0086) -0.0728*** (0.0117) -0.0164*** (0.0017) -0.0840*** (0.0087) -0.0384*** (0.0082) 0.0622 (0.0753) -0.0056 (0.0094) -0.0024 (0.0089) -0.0214 (0.0599) 0.0026 (0.0502) -0.0153 (0.0177) 0.0018 (0.0088) -0.0230*** (0.0086) -0.0671*** (0.0172) -0.0356*** (0.0134) -0.0631 (0.2162) 0.1745* (0.0915) 0.1842 (0.1512) -0.2155** (0.0863) 0.0033 (0.2292) 0.2012*** (0.0522) 0.1378*** (0.0352) 0.1457*** (0.0169) -0.0724* (0.0392) 0.0392** (0.0171) 0.2438*** (0.0486) 0.2168*** (0.0128) 0.0747*** (0.0159) -0.0651*** (0.0246) -0.0235** (0.0119) 0.2785*** (0.0661) 0.2461*** (0.0154) 0.0709*** (0.0199) -0.0590 (0.0395) -0.0204 (0.0175) Summation Short-run coef. Wald test (P-value) Long run coe¢cient Wald test (P-value) -0.1461 0.000 0.8199 0.821 -0.1361 0.000 0.4133 0.493 -0.0407 0.000 0.2730 0.000 -0.0892 0.000 0.5432 0.000 -0.0080 0.643 1.1207 0.677 -0.0212 0.173 0.4688 0.000 0.3588 0.136 1.0155 0.340 0.2834 0.000 1.5418 0.001 0.2915 0.000 0.6384 0.000 0.3170 0.000 0.6546 0.000 Sargan test (P-value) AR1 (P-value) AR2 (P-value) Observations 1.0000 0.0016 0.4845 1110 1.000 0.0015 0.4738 1140 1.000 0.0080 0.0392 1665 1.000 0.0081 0.0296 1710 1.000 0.0354 0.3381 1517 1.000 0.0513 0.2030 1558 1.000 0.1592 0.1875 592 1.000 0.0123 0.0774 608 1.000 0.0004 0.2217 962 1.000 0.0004 0.2961 988 model ln GDPt 1 ln openn ln opennt ln GDPt ln opennt 1 ln opennt 2 2 2 11 Notes: (1) Estimation based on the Di¤erence GMM and the System GMM estimator. (2) Asymptotically robust standard errors reported in parentheses. (3) Sargan test is based on the estimation with GMM standard errors. (4) *, ** and *** denote signi…cance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level. Table 6: Estimated error-correction model: long-run and short-run dynamics of growth on changes in openness for subpanels Dependent Variables ln openn low-income lower-middle-income Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM upper-middle-income Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM high-income Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM OECD Di¤.GMM Sys.GMM -0.2181 (0.1867) -0.5135*** (0.0458) 0.0126 (0.1098) -0.1605 (0.1958) -0.2912 (0.2717) -0.3076*** (0.5808) -0.5148*** (0.0425) -0.0608 (0.0567) -0.2704*** (0.0606) -0.4410*** (0.1338) -0.1576** (0.0748) -0.1964*** (0.0479) -0.0667 (0.0738) -0.1949*** (0.0720) -0.3573*** (0.1574) -0.1284*** (0.0225) -0.1512*** (0.0225) 0.0321 (0.0222) -0.1341*** (0.2155) -0.2087*** (0.0429) -0.3318*** (0.0834) 0.0939*** (0.0263) 0.1599*** (0.0144) -0.3330*** (0.0873) -0.2307*** (0.0710) -0.1075*** (0.0087) 0.0847*** (0.0258) 0.1213*** (0.1497) -0.1193*** (0.0082) -0.0810*** (0.0107) -0.1905 (0.1429) 0.2728*** (0.0735) -0.0279 (0.0723) -0.2082 (0.1471) -0.1989 (0.1417) -0.0334 (0.0600) 0.3005*** (0.0641) -0.0631** (0.0266) -0.0805 (0.0617) -0.0935 (0.0575) -0.0801 (0.0762) 0.5686*** (0.0369) -0.0252 (0.0454) -0.1359** (0.0661) -0.0381* (0.0218) 0.0721* (0.0381) 0.5694*** (0.0283) -0.1576*** (0.0354) -0.0144 (0.0254) -0.0132* (0.0076) Summation Short-run coef. Wald test (P-value) Long run coe¢cient Wald test (P-value) -0.5009 0.000 -0.8143 0.448 -0.5756 0.000 -0.6307 0.085 -0.2631 0.029 -0.8334 0.141 -0.1291 0.003 -0.5559 0.069 0.2538 0.000 0.3070 0.000 0.2060 0.000 0.3209 0.000 0.2448 0.000 0.0443 0.616 0.2374 0.000 -0.1606 0.607 0.5434 0.000 0.7199 0.000 0.4119 0.000 0.0796 0.959 Sargan test (P-value) AR1 (P-value) AR2 (P-value) Observations 1.0000 0.0013 0.4020 1110 1.000 0.0001 0.5130 1140 1.000 0.0000 0.2588 1665 1.000 0.0000 0.4941 1710 1.000 0.0165 0.2257 1517 1.000 0.0037 0.3471 1558 1.000 0.1409 0.2792 592 1.000 0.0990 0.2721 608 1.000 0.0004 0.9870 962 1.000 0.0000 0.9010 988 model ln opennt 1 ln GDP ln GDPt ln opennt 2 ln GDPt 2 1 ln GDPt 2 12 Notes: (1) Estimation based on the Di¤erence GMM and the System GMM estimator. (2) Asymptotically robust standard errors reported in parentheses. (3) Sargan test is based on the estimation with GMM standard errors. (4) *, ** and *** denote signi…cance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level. coe¢cient implies that when there are deviations from long-run equilibrium, short-run adjustments in openness will re-establish the long-run equilibrium. The absolute value of the term provides the speed of the short-run adjustment process, indicating that about six per cent (-0.0616) of the discrepancy in the case of the Di¤erence GMM estimator and about three per cent (-0.0345) in the case of the System GMM estimator are corrected in each period. Aside from speed of adjustment the results indicate the magnitude of the short-run e¤ect. It is measured by the sum of the contemporaneous and lagged dependent variable and indicates a negative signi…cant causal e¤ect from changes in openness on growth. The longrun e¤ect is positive signi…cant, indicating that in the long run changes in openness cause higher GDP growth. These short-term and long-run results show that the debate of free trade versus protectionism in the international trade literature should not be considered as two contradictory aspects. Rather, foreign competition seems to have a negative short-term e¤ect on growth. At the …rm level, in particular import-competing …rms are disadvantaged and seek protection against openness. However, the results show that in the long run free trade policies prove bene…cial to productivity and growth, which is consistent with recent literature that suggests that openness promotes economic development through various channels, such as technological progress, increasing key markets and rising competition. Concerning the other direction of the causal relationship presented in the third and fourth column of table 4, all coe¢cients as well as the short- and long-run e¤ects are signi…cant at the 1% level for both estimators. Again the error correction term is negative and signi…cant. This intensi…es the long-run relationship with a short-run adjustment to equilibrium that we already found in the …rst model. At about 13 and 11 per cent (-0.1300 for Di¤erence GMM and -0.1082 for System GMM), respectively, the speed of adjustment is higher than in the reversed model. The short-run e¤ect of GDP growth on openness is negative and at nearly the same level as the e¤ect of the other direction, indicating that the short-run openness response to a temporary growth shock is of the same magnitude as the growth response of a temporary openness shock. The long-run e¤ect is positive and signi…cant, indicating that higher GDP growth causes greater changes in openness. The magnitude of this e¤ect is lower than that of the e¤ect of openness on growth. This implies that the long-run growth response to permanent shocks in openness tends to be greater than the openness response to permanent changes in growth; hence growth is more sensitive to openness than vice versa. Again, the results show that even though in the long run openness seems to be bene…cial for growth, in the short term negative growth shocks may hit the economy and invoke a call for protectionism. Tables 5 and 6 present the results for the income subpanels, which are lowincome economies, lower-middle-income economies, upper-middle-income 13 economies, high-income economies and high-income OECD members. The former table shows the causality from openness to GDP, the latter the reverse direction. When GDP growth is the dependant variable the long-run e¤ect remains positive when signi…cant. However, we are unable to reveal a long-run causal e¤ect for the low-income economies as well as for the difference estimator of the upper-middle-income and high-income economies. The short-run e¤ect is signi…cant except for the upper-middle-income economies and the di¤erence estimator of the high-income economies. The results change depending on income. While the coe¢cients of the poorer subpanels are negative, the results of the high-income subpanels show a positive short-run e¤ect. This suggests that not only the trade level but also the structure of trade should be taken into consideration. For example, Hausmann et al. (2007) and Rodrik (2006) suggest that the structure of export products matters to growth, while Lederman and Maloney (2003) show that trade has a di¤erent e¤ect on growth depending on its structure in terms of natural resource abundance, export concentration, and intra-industry trade. This is consistent with our results that suggest that because of a di¤erent trade structure the e¤ect of trade in developing countries is di¤erent from that of trade in the industrialized countries. A proposal for further research could be to analyse the causality of trade openness and growth as a function of trade structure. Concerning the other direction of causality when changes in openness are the dependent variable, both the short-run and the long-run e¤ect exhibit a change in sign from negative for lower-income countries to positive for higherincome countries. Furthermore, the higher the average income the greater the e¤ect of growth on openness. The results show that economic growth only e¤ects trade openness positively above a certain income level (uppermiddle-income), while in lower-income countries growth seems to impede openness. In summary the overall results of the estimated ECMs for the entire panel suggest a bidirectional positive long-run causality between GDP growth and openness, indicating that openness promotes economic development and vice versa. The short-run results suggest negative e¤ects pointing towards required painful adjustments which often elicit a call for protectionism. That said, deeper income subpanel analyses indicate that this result has needs to be di¤erentiated by income groups. Whereas higher-income countries exhibit positive causalities for both directions for the short-run and long-run e¤ect, lower-income countries have a negative short-run adjustment and a positive long-run a¤ect from openness to growth but a negative long-run e¤ect in the other direction. 3 Summary and conclusion The present study examines the causal relationship between trade openness and economic growth. After reviewing recent empirical research regarding the 14 link between openness and growth we use recent panel estimation methods to explore the causal relationship between these variables. In a …rst step we check for stationarity using two common panel unit root tests, the IPS test and the Fisher-type test. After that we apply a panel cointegration test on openness and growth. As the variables are cointegrated we use panel ECMs to explore the bilateral short-run and long-run dynamics between these variables. We approach the problem of a potential endogeneity between openness and growth by including only growth rates and lagged values of the independent variable. Additionally, we use instrumental variables and the Di¤erence GMM and System GMM estimators developed by Arellano and Bond (1991) and Blundell and Bond (1998) These estimators also address the issue of a possible correlation between the lagged endogenous variable and the error term. The results suggest that the long-run causality between trade openness and growth runs in both directions. This is in line with Harrison (1996) who argues that although more open trade policies do precede higher growth rates, it is also true that higher growth rates lead to more open trade regimes. The short-run adjustment for both directions is negative. However, additional analyses for income-grouped subpanels show that apart from the long-run e¤ect of openness on growth which is persistently positive for all subpanels the e¤ect changes in sign depending on income. While the lower-income subpanel shows a negative causality, the highincome countries exhibit a positive relationship between growth and openness. The desired growth-led openness and openness-led growth hypothesis can only be supported for industrialized countries. In developing countries only the longrun openness-led growth hypothesis holds, while growth seems to slow down openness in the long run. References [1] Ahmad, J.; Kwan, A.C.C. (1991), Causality between exports and economic growth: Empirical evidence from Africa, Economics Letters, Vol. 37, No. 3, pp. 243-248. [2] Arellano, M.; Bond, S. (1991), Some Tests of Speci…cation for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations, The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 58, No. 2, pp. 277-297. [3] Awokuse, T.O. (2007), Causality between exports, imports, and economic growth: Evidence from transition economies, Economics Letters, Vol. 94, No. 3, pp. 389-395 [4] Bahmani-Oskooee, M.; Mohtadi, H.; Shabsigh, G. (1991), Exports, growth and causality in LDCs: A re-examination, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 36, No.2, pp. 405-415. 15 [5] Banerjee, A.; Dolado, J.J.; Galbraith, J.; Hendry, D.F. (1993), Cointegration, Error Correction, and the Econometric Analysis of NonStationary Data, Oxford University Press, Oxford. [6] Banerjee, A.; Dolado, J.J.; Mestre, R. (1998), Error-correction Mechanism Tests for Cointegration in a Single-equation Framework, Journal of Time Series Analysis, Vol. 19, No. 3, pp. 267 - 283. [7] Barro, R.J.; Lee, J.W. (1994), Sources of economic growth, CarnegieRochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 40, pp.1-46. [8] Barro, R.J.; Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995), Economic Growth, McGraw-Hill, Cambridge, MA. [9] Bouoiyour, J. (2003), Trade and GDP Growth in Morocco: Short-run or Long-run Causality?, Brazilian Journal of Business and Economics , Vol 3. No. 2, pp. 14-21. [10] Breitung, J. (2000), The local power of some unit root tests for panel data. Advances in Econometrics, Vol. 15: Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration, and Dynamic Panels, ed. B. H. Baltagi, pp.161–178. [11] Chang, R.; Kaltani, L.; Loayza, N. (2009), Openness is Good for Growth: The Role of Policy Complementarities, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 90, pp. 33-49. [12] Choi, I. (2001), Unit root tests for panel data, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 20, No. 2, pp. 249-272. [13] Chow, P. (1987), Causality between exports growth and industrial development. Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 26, pp. 55–63. [14] Dickey, D.A.; Fuller, W.A. (1979), Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series With a Unit Root, Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 74, No. 366, pp. 427-431. [15] Dollar, D. (1992), Outward-oriented Developing Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85, Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 40, No. 3, pp. 523-44. [16] Dollar, D.; Kraay, A. (2002), Growth is good for the poor. Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 7, No. 3, pp. 195– 225. [17] Douglas A.I.; Terviö, M.(2002), Does trade raise income?: Evidence from the twentieth century, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 58, No. 1, pp. 1-18. [18] Easterly, W.; Levine, R. (2001), What have we learned from a decade of empirical research on growth? It’s Not Factor Accumulation: Stylized Facts and Growth Models, World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 15, No. 2, pp 177-219. 16 [19] Edwards, S. (1998), Openness, Productivity, and Growth: What Do We Really Know?, Economic Journal, Vol.108 (447), pp. 383-98. [20] Engle, R.F.; Granger, C.W.J. (1987), Co-Integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing, Econometrica, Vol. 55, No. 2, pp. 251-276. [21] Frankel, J.A.; Romer, D.H. (1999), Does Trade Cause Growth?, American Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 3, pp. 379–399. [22] Granger, C.W.J. (1969), Investigating Causal Relations by Econometric Models and Cross-Spectral Methods, Econometrica Vol. 37, No. 3, pp. 424438. [23] Grossman, G.M.; Helpman, E. (1991), Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [24] Hausmann, R.; Hwang, J.; Rodrik, D. (2007), What You Export Matters, Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 12, No. 1, pp. 1–25. [25] Harrison, A. (1996), Openness and Growth: A Time-Series, Cross-Country Analysis for Developing Countries, Journal of Development Economics, Vol 48, No. 2, pp. 419-47. [26] Heston, A.; Summers, R.; Aten, B. (2011), Penn World Table Version 7.0, Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania. [27] Hsiao, M.W. (1987), Tests of causality and exogeneity between export growth and economic growth, Journal of Economic Development, Vol. 12, pp. 143–159. [28] Im, K.S.; Pesaran, M.H.; Shin, Y. (2003), Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 115, No. 1, pp. 53-74. [29] Irwin, D.A.; Tervio, M. (2000), Does trade raise income? Evidence from the twentieth century, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 58, No. 1, pp.1-18. [30] Islam, N. (1995), Growth Empirics: A Panel Data Approach, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, No. 4, pp. 1127-1170. [31] Islam M.N. (1998), Export expansion and economic growth: testing for cointegration and causality, Applied Economics, Vol. 30, No. 3, pp. 415425. [32] Jung, W.; Marshall, P. (1985), Exports, growth and causality in developing countries. Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 18, pp. 1–12. [33] Krugman, P. (1994), The Myth of Asia’s Miracle, Foreign A¤airs, Vol. 73, No. 6, pp. 62-78. 17 [34] Lederman, D.; Maloney, W.F. (2003), Trade Structure and Growth, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3025. [35] Levin, A.; Lin, C.F.; Chu, C.S.J. (2002), Unit root tests in panel data: asymptotic and …nite-sample properties, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 108, No. 1, pp. 1-24. [36] Liu, X.; Burridge, P.; Sinclair, P.J.N. (2002), Relationships between economic growth, foreign direct investment and trade: evidence from China, Applied Economics, Vol. 34, No. 11, pp. 1433-1440. [37] Maddala, G.S.; Wu, S. (1999), A Comparative Study of Unit Root Tests with Panel Data and a New Simple Test, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 61, No. 1, pp. 631-652. [38] Noguer, M.; Siscart, M. (2005), Trade raises income: a precise and robust result, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 65, No. 2, pp. 447-460. [39] Pedroni, P. (1999), Critical Values for Cointegration Tests in Heterogeneous Panels with Multiple Regressors, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 61, No. 0, pp. 653-70. [40] Pedroni, P. (2004), Panel Cointegration: Asymptotic And Finite Sample Properties Of Pooled Time Series Tests With An Application To The PPP Hypothesis, Econometric Theory, Cambridge University Press, Vol. 20, No. 3, pp 597-625. [41] Rodrik, D.; Rodríguez, F. (2001), Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptics Guide to the Cross-National Evidence, in B. Bernanke and K. Rogo¤ (editors), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, Vol. 15, MIT Press, pp. 261-325. [42] Rodrik, D. (2006), What’s So Special about China’s Exports? China and the World Economy, Vol. 14, No. 5, pp. 1–19. [43] Romer (1993), Two strategies for economic development: Using ideas and producing ideas, proceedings of the World Bank annual conference on development economics, 1992, ed. Summers, L.H; Shah, S., pp. 63–91. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. [44] Sala-i-Martin, X. (1997), I Just Ran Two Million Regressions, The American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 2, pp. 178-183. [45] Yasar, M.; Nelson, C.H.; Rejesus, R.M. (2006), The Dynamics of Exports and Productivity at the Plant Level: A Panel Data Error Correction Model (ECM) Approach, in B.H. Baltagi (ed.), Panel Data Econometrics: Theoretical Contributions and Empirical Applications, pp. 279-306, Amsterdam: Elsevier. 18 4 Appendix Appendix 1 The countries included in the analysis are low-income economies ($1005 or less GDP per capita): Afghanistan, Bangladesh, Benin, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cambodia, Central African Republic, Chad, Comoros, Dem. Rep Congo, Ethiopia, The Gambia, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Haiti, Kenya, Liberia, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mozambique, Nepal, Niger, Rwanda, Sierra Leone, Somalia, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zimbabwe lower-middle-income economies ($1006 to $3975 GDP per capita): Angola, Belize, Bhutan, Bolivia, Cameroon, Cape Verde, Republic of Congo, Cote d‘Ivoire, Djibouti, Egypt, El Salvador, Fiji, Ghana, Guatemala, Guyana, Honduras, India, Indonesia, Iraq, Kiribati, Laos, Lesotho, Marshall Islands, Mauritania, Fed. Sts. Micronesia, Mongolia, Morocco, Nicaragua, Nigeria, Pakistan, Papua New Guinea, Paraguay, Philippines, Samoa, Sao Tome and Principe, Senegal, Solomon Islands, Sri Lanka, Sudan, Swaziland, Syria, Tonga, Vanuatu, Vietnam, Zambia upper-middle-income economies ($3976 to $12275 GDP per capita): Albania, Algeria, Antigua and Barbuda, Argentina, Botswana, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China Version 1, China Version 2, Colombia, Costa Rica, Cuba, Dominica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Gabon, Grenada, Iran, Jamaica, Jordan, Lebanon, Malaysia, Maldives, Mauritius, Mexico, Namibia, Panama, Peru, Romania, Seychelles, South Africa, St. Kitts & Nevis, St. Lucia, St.Vincent & Grenadines, Suriname, Thailand, Tunisia, Turkey, Uruguay, Venezuela high-income economies ($12276 or more GDP per capita): Bahamas, Bahrain, Barbados, Bermuda, Brunei, Cyprus, Equatorial Guinea, Hong Kong, Israel, Macao, Malta, Oman, Puerto Rico, Singapore, Taiwan, Trinidad & Tobago high-income OECD members: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Republic of Korea, Luxembourg, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, United States 19 Recent discussion papers 2012-06 Thomas Gries Margarete Redlin Trade Openness and Economic Growth: A Panel Causality Analysis 2012-05 Mark Schopf Hendrik Ritter Reassessing the Green Paradox 2012-04 Yuanhua Feng David Hand Keming Yu A Multivariate Random Walk Model with Slowly Changing Drift and Cross-correlation Applied to Finance 2012-03 Sarah Brockhoff Tim Krieger Daniel Meierriecks Looking Back on Anger: Explaining the Social Origins of Left-Wing and Nationalist-Separatist Terrorism in Western Europe, 1970-2007 2012-02 Sonja Brangewitz Sarah Brockhoff Stability of Coalitional Equilibria within Repeated Tax Competition 2012-01 Sarah Brockhoff Tim Krieger Daniel Meierriecks Great Expectations and Hard Times The (Nontrivial) Impact of Education on Domestic Terrorism 2011-13 Tim Krieger Jens Ruhose “Honey, I shrunk the kids’ benefits!”— Revisiting intergenerational conflict in OECD countries. 2011-12 Tim Krieger 9/11's Legacy: How Abstract Fear and Collective Memory Lead to Real Economic Costs 2011-11 Yuanhua Feng Data-driven estimation of diurnal duration patterns 2011-10 B. Michael Gilroy Birke Thuy Duong Nguyen Ist Fairer Handel Wirklich Fair? 2011-09 Yuanhua Feng Zhichao Guo Christian Peitz Xiangyong Tan A tree-form constant market share model for growth causes in international trade based on multi-level classification 2011-08 Tim Krieger Daniel Meierriecks Ökonomische Aspekte des neuen globalen Terrorismus 2011-07 Tim Krieger Daniel Meierrieks Terrorist Financing and Money Laundering 2011-06 Thomas Gries Stefan Jungblut Wim Naudé New Firm Creation and Failure: A Matching Approach 2011-05 Daniel Kaimann "To infinity and beyond!" - A genre-specific film analysis of movie success mechanisms 2011-04 Yuanhua Feng Zhichao Guo Christian Peitz Xiangyong Tan A tree-form constant market share analysis for modelling growth causes in international trade 2011-03 Zhichao Guo Yuanhua Feng Xiangyong Tan Impact of China’s accession to WTO and the financial crisis on China’s exports to Germany 2011-02 Alexander Haupt Tim Krieger Thomas Lange Competition for the International Pool of Talent: Education Policy and Student Mobility 2011-01 B. Michael Gilroy Daniel Kruse Die Prinzipal-Agent-Theorie als Erklärungsinstrumentarium von Korruption: Angewendet auf den Praxisfall „Siemens“ 2010-09 Yuanhua Feng An iterative plug-in algorithm for decomposing seasonal time series using the Berlin Method 2010-08 Zhichao Guo Yuanhua Feng Xiangyong Tan Short- and long-term impact of remarkable economic events on the growth causes of China-Germany trade in agri-food products [published in: Economic Modelling 28 (2011), 2359-2368] 2010-07 B. Michael Gilroy Elmar Lukas Christian Heimann Welchen Einfluss hat die Anwesenheit von ausländischen und multinationalen Unternehmungen auf die deutschen Exporte? 2010-06 Stefan Gravemeyer Thomas Gries Income and disparity in Germany and China 2010-05 Thomas Gries Margarete Redlin Short-run and Long-run Dynamics of Growth, Inequality and Poverty in the Developing World 2010-04 Stefan Gravemeyer Thomas Gries Jinjun Xue Poverty in Shenzen 2010-03 Alexander Haupt Tim Krieger Thomas Lange A Note on Brain Gain and Brain Drain: Permanent Migration and Education Policy 2010-02 Sarah Brockhoff Tim Krieger Daniel Meierrieks Ties That Do Not Bind (Directly): The Education Terrorism Nexus Revisited 2010-01 Claus-Jochen Haake, Tim Krieger, Steffen Minter On the institutional design of burden sharing when financing external border enforcement in the EU