Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.
To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to upgrade your browser.
2011, Theoretical Economics Letters
…
5 pages
1 file
In this paper, a new optimization-based approach to constructing a poverty index is considered. From a general perspective, first and second order conditions based on a general poverty intensity function are derived. Then using specific intensity functions defined by [1,3] respectively, we specify related necessary and sufficient conditions and the underlying poverty indices. An extension based on a large class of intensity function is also investigated.
2011
In this paper, a new optimization-based approach to constructing a poverty index is considered. From a gen-eral perspective, first and second order conditions based on a general poverty intensity function are derived. Then using specific intensity functions defined by [1,3] respectively, we specify related necessary and suffi-cient conditions and the underlying poverty indices. An extension based on a large class of intensity function is also investigated.
2009
A particular scale-invariant index of poverty is subjected to careful analysis. This leads to a new perspective, not seen before, on the family of subgroup-consistent and scaleinvariant poverty indices. Parametric families of new poverty indices are presented which offer the analyst a degree of flexibility in the choice of transfer sensitivity and distribution sensitivity which has not been available before now.
1991
We propose a poverty measure that satisfies *a number of properties that make it sensitive to the level of absolute deprivation of the poor. These properties are often violated by several poverty measures discussed in the literature. The measure corresponds to a Cobb-Douglas social welfare function which has a number of egalitarian features.
The Journal of Economic Inequality, 2011
The multitude of available poverty measures can confuse a policy maker who wants to evaluate a poverty-reduction policy. We proposes a rule for ranking poverty measures by use of the food-gap, calculated as the cost-difference between a household's normative food basket, derived from a healthy diet, and the actually chosen food basket. The rationale for this indicator is based on the fact, that (1) basic food needs reflect an ultimate necessity, (2) food expenditure is highly divisibility, thus allowing for efficient marginal substitution between competing necessities when the household's economic hardship increases. For these reasons we believe this to be an objective indicator for the sacrifice in the standard of living of a family under economic stress. A household is identified as 'truly' poor or non-poor by a given poverty measure if the diagnoses coincide and vice versa. The ranking is obtained by a gain-function, which adds up congruent and deducts contradicting outcomes for each poverty measure. We calculate four types of gainfunctions -of headcounts, food-gaps, FGT-like powered food-gaps and an augmented version of the latter. The poverty measures include expenditure-based, income-based, relative, absolute, mixed measures and a multidimensional measure of social deprivation. The most qualitative measure is found to be Ravallion's Food Energy Intake and Share measure, though it suffers from a possible bias, since it includes the food-norm in its design. The 60%-median income measure from all sources ranks highest among the unbiased measures. The absolute poverty measure yields the worst performance.
2007
This paper deals with the proposal of a synthetic indicator to measure intensity of poverty. So, whereas incidence of poverty can be clearly measured using the headcount ratio indicator, according to Sen (1976) dimensions of poverty, the choice of a better intensity poverty measure is still an open question to resolve. Thus, in this paper, a new procedure to obtain a synthetic indicator from a set of well-performed poverty intensity indices as a start is proposed, using an adaptation of Principal Component Analysis (PCA). Conditions needed to make longitudinal comparisons possible are studied and properties of these synthetic indicators will also be analyzed, connected to TIP curves as well. As an illustration, this paper analyzes the evolution of poverty in the 15 countries of E.U., whose household income data are available through the information contained in the European Community Household Panel (ECPH). This analysis allows static and dynamic comparisons, related to the period f...
2012
This paper presents a family of multidimensional poverty indices that measure poverty as a function of the extent and the intensity of poverty. I provide a unique axiomatics from which both extent and intensity of poverty can be derived, as well as the poor be endogenously identified. This axiomatics gives rise to a family of multidimensional indices whose extremal points are the geometric mean and the Maximin solution. I show that, in addition to all the standard features studied in the literature, these indices are continuous (a must for cardinal poverty measures) and ordinal, in the sense that they do not depend upon the units in which dimensions of achievements are computed. Moreover, they verify the decreasing rate marginal substitution property: the higher one's deprivation (or the extent of poverty) in one dimension, the smaller the increase of achievement in that dimension that suffices to compensate for a decrease of achievement in another dimension.
The Economic Journal, 1981
When discussing the state of research on poverty and social security in Britain Atkinson (I977) pointed out that, in measuring the prevalence of poverty, attention has been focused upon the proportion of the population with an income below the poverty line. It is well known that as an index of poverty this has serious shortcomings-in particular, it is insensitive to how far below the poverty line the incomes of the poor fall. Alternative indices have been proposed: the United States Social Security Administration introduced the notion of poverty gaps (see Batchelder (I97I)), that is, the aggregate value of the difference between the incomes of the poor and the poverty line, while Sen (I976) has suggested that income inequality among the poor is also an important dimension of poverty. Atkinson (I977) therefore proposed that researchers experiment with a range of indices which incorporate such aspects of poverty, given the possibility that the measurement of poverty may be sensitive to the precise index employed. Beckerman (I979) has shown that the information content of poverty gaps very usefully supplements that provided by the aggregate incidence approach. However, to our knowledge, there has been no attempt in Britain to compute indices which take account of inequality among the poor. In this paper we hope to correct this omission, and in doing so comments will be offered on some proposed methods of incorporating such a consideration. A close examination of these has prompted us to propose two further indices which, although relying on the setting up of an alternative structure for analysing this problem, are firmly based on the approaches favoured in the existing literature. THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL [JUNE
2011
The multitude of available poverty measures can confuse a policy maker who wants to evaluate a poverty-reduction policy. We proposes a rule for ranking poverty measures by use of the food-gap, calculated as the cost-difference between a household's normative food basket, derived from a healthy diet, and the actually chosen food basket. The rationale for this indicator is based on the fact, that (1) basic food needs reflect an ultimate necessity, (2) food expenditure is highly divisibility, thus allowing for efficient marginal substitution between competing necessities when the household's economic hardship increases. For these reasons we believe this to be an objective indicator for the sacrifice in the standard of living of a family under economic stress. A household is identified as 'truly' poor or non-poor by a given poverty measure if the diagnoses coincide and vice versa. The ranking is obtained by a gain-function, which adds up congruent and deducts contradicting outcomes for each poverty measure. We calculate four types of gainfunctions-of headcounts, food-gaps, FGT-like powered food-gaps and an augmented version of the latter. The poverty measures include expenditure-based, income-based, relative, absolute, mixed measures and a multidimensional measure of social deprivation. The most qualitative measure is found to be Ravallion's Food Energy Intake and Share measure, though it suffers from a possible bias, since it includes the food-norm in its design. The 60%-median income measure from all sources ranks highest among the unbiased measures. The absolute poverty measure yields the worst performance.
Archeologia Postmedievale, 2023
The Journal of Speculative Philosophy, 2018
RChD: creación y pensamiento, 2024
The Elementary School Journal, 2014
Imējigaku no Genzai: Warburg kara Shinkeikei Imējigaku he, ed. Yasuhiro Sakamoto / Jun Tanaka / Yoshikazu Takemine, Tokyo: Tokyo University Press, 2019
Ain Shams Journal of Forensic Medicine and Clinical Toxicology
Zenodo (CERN European Organization for Nuclear Research), 2023
Engenharia Agrícola, 2016
Transplant International, 1993
Journal of Alloys and Compounds, 2015
Cadernos Brasileiros De Saude Mental Brazilian Journal of Mental Health, 2013
Jornal Internacional de Estudos em Educação Matemática, 2018