Academia.eduAcademia.edu

The Doha Round, Poverty, And Regional Inequality In Brazil

2005, Policy Research Working Papers

This paper addresses the potential effects of the Doha round of trade negotiations upon poverty and income distribution in Brazil, using an applied general equilibrium (AGE) and micro-simulation model of Brazil tailored for income distribution and poverty analysis. Of particular importance is the fact that the Representative Household hypothesis is replaced by a very detailed representation of households. The model distinguishes 10 different labour types, and has 270 different household expenditure patterns. Income can originate from 41 different production activities (which produce 52 commodities), located in 27 different regions inside the country. The AGE model communicates to a micro-simulation model that has 112,055 Brazilian households and 263,938 adults. Economic activity in Brazil, a large country, is spread unevenly across the territory. Manufacturing industries are concentrated in the SouthEast region, while agriculture, although more evenly distributed geographically, is the main source of income of the Center-West states. Poverty, on the other hand, is a pervasive phenomenon in the country, which has one of the worse income distributions in the world. The poorest states in Brazil (defined based on the share of population below the poverty line) are concentrated in the NorthEastern states. Poverty and income distribution indices are computed over the entire sample of households and persons, before and after the policy shocks. Model results shows that even important trade policy shocks, such as those applied in this study, do not generate dramatic changes in the structure of poverty and income distribution in the Brazilian economy. The simulated effects on poverty and income distribution are positive, but rather small. The benefits are, however, concentrated in the poorest households. The study also suggests that the poverty reductions would arise from the income earning changes, and not from the fall in the consumption bundle prices. This outcome is highly correlated to the agriculture and related industries, which have their activity levels increased in all simulations. Finally, the bulk of the poverty impacts can be attributed to the liberalization by other countries, rather than to changes in Brazil's tariff structure. From a methodological point of view, the study emphasizes the need to approach poverty analysis by the household (rather than the personal) dimension, by tracking changes in the labor market from individual workers to households. In the PNAD 2001 data used here, the head-ofhousehold income accounts for only 65 percent of aggregated household income in Brazil. As a consequence, using head-of-household income as a proxy for household income may poorly predict the effect of policy changes.

August 5, 2005 The Doha Round, Poverty and Regional Inequality in Brazil by Joaquim Bento de Souza Ferreira Filho * and Mark Horridge ** Chapter 7 in Putting Development Back into the Doha Agenda: Poverty Impacts of a WTO Agreement, Thomas W. Hertel and L. Alan Winters (eds.) forthcoming from the World Bank, Washington, DC. * Escola Superior de Agricultura “Luiz de Queiroz”, Universidade de São Paulo. Departamento de Economia, Sociologia e Administração. Av. Pádua Dias, 11. Piracicaba, SP. CEP – 13.418-900. Tel: (019) 34178700. Email: [email protected] ** Centre of Policy Studies, Monash University. Melbourne, Australia. Email: [email protected]. Summary This paper addresses the potential effects of the Doha round of trade negotiations upon poverty and income distribution in Brazil, using an applied general equilibrium (AGE) and micro-simulation model of Brazil tailored for income distribution and poverty analysis. Of particular importance is the fact that the Representative Household hypothesis is replaced by a very detailed representation of households. The model distinguishes 10 different labour types, and has 270 different household expenditure patterns. Income can originate from 41 different production activities (which produce 52 commodities), located in 27 different regions inside the country. The AGE model communicates to a micro-simulation model that has 112,055 Brazilian households and 263,938 adults. Economic activity in Brazil, a large country, is spread unevenly across the territory. Manufacturing industries are concentrated in the South-East region, while agriculture, although more evenly distributed geographically, is the main source of income of the Center-West states. Poverty, on the other hand, is a pervasive phenomenon in the country, which has one of the worse income distributions in the world. The poorest states in Brazil (defined based on the share of population below the poverty line) are concentrated in the North-Eastern states. Poverty and income distribution indices are computed over the entire sample of households and persons, before and after the policy shocks. Model results shows that even important trade policy shocks, such as those applied in this study, do not generate dramatic changes in the structure of poverty and income distribution in the Brazilian economy. The simulated effects on poverty and income distribution are positive, but rather small. The benefits are, however, concentrated in the poorest households. The study also suggests that the poverty reductions would arise from the income earning changes, and not from the fall in the consumption bundle prices. This outcome is highly correlated to the agriculture and related industries, which have their activity levels increased in all simulations. Finally, the bulk of the poverty impacts can be attributed to the liberalization by other countries, rather than to changes in Brazil’s tariff structure. From a methodological point of view, the study emphasizes the need to approach poverty analysis by the household (rather than the personal) dimension, by tracking changes in the labor market from individual workers to households. In the PNAD 2001 data used here, the head-ofhousehold income accounts for only 65 percent of aggregated household income in Brazil. As a consequence, using head-of-household income as a proxy for household income may poorly predict the effect of policy changes. ii Introduction One of the most striking aspects of the Brazilian economy is its high degree of income concentration. Despite the changes the economy has faced in the last twenty years, ranging from the country’s re-democratization, trade liberalization, hyperinflation, many currency changes, and finally, to the macroeconomic stabilization in the mid-nineties, the country still shows one of the worst patterns of income distribution in the world. The resilience of this income distribution problem has attracted the attention of researchers worldwide, and is the central point of a lively debate in Brazil. The problem is, of course, extremely complex, related to a great number of socio-economic variables, which makes it a particularly difficult analytical issue, since the effect of many variables upon poverty is uncertain. At the same time, new changes in the external environment face the Brazilian economy. The Doha round of international trade negotiations may be one of the most important. A complex phenomenon in itself, the economic integration poses new questions relating to the prospects for the poor. This paper offers an attempt to address these questions with a systematic and quantitative approach. For this purpose, an applied general equilibrium model of Brazil tailored for income distribution and poverty analysis will be used. The model also has a regional breakdown, so we can examine the associated issue of regional inequality. The plan of the paper is as follows: the next section shows some figures about the problem of poverty and income distribution in Brazil, with a brief review of the recent literature on the topic. Then, we present the methodological approach to be pursued here, with a discussion of the relevant literature on the many different approaches. Then the model itself is presented, 3 with a discussion of its main aspects and of the database. Finally, results and conclusions are presented. 1. Poverty and income distribution evolution in Brazil: An overview Although Brazil is a country with a large number of poor people, its population is not among the poorest in the world. Drawing on the 1999 Report on Human Development, Barros et alii (2001) show that around 64 percent of the countries in the world have per capita income less than in Brazil, a figure that mounts to 77 percent if we consider the number of persons in the same condition. The same authors show that, while in Brazil 30 percent of the total population is poor, on average only 10 percent are poor in other countries with similar per capita income. Indeed, based on the same report the authors define an international norm that, based on per capita income, would impute only 8 percent of poor for Brazil. That is, if the inequality of income in Brazil were to correspond to the world average inequality for countries in the same per capita income range just 8 percent (rather than 30 percent) of the Brazilian population would be expected to be poor. Taking the concept of poverty in its particular dimension of income insufficiency, the same authors show that in 1999 about 14 percent of the Brazilian population lived in households with income below the line of extreme poverty (indigence line, about 22 million people), and 34 percent of the population lived in households with income below the poverty line (about 53 million people). Even though the percentage of poor in the population has declined from 40 percent in 1977 to 34 percent in 1999, this level is still very high and, it seems, stable. The size of poverty in Brazil, measured either as a percentage of the population or in terms of a poverty gap, stabilizes in the second half of the eighties, although at a lower level than was observed in the previous period. 4 Barros and Mendonça (1997) have analyzed the relations between economic growth and reductions in the level of inequality upon poverty in Brazil. Among their main conclusions, these authors point out that an improvement in the distribution of income would be more effective for poverty reduction than economic growth alone, if growth maintained the current pattern of inequality. According to these authors, due to the very high level of income inequality in Brazil it is possible to dramatically reduce poverty in the country even without economic growth, just by turning the level of inequality in Brazil close to what can be observed in a typical Latin American country. Brazilian poverty also has an important regional dimension. According to calculations by Rocha (1998) in a study for the 1981/95 period the richer South-East region of the country, while counting for 44 percent of total population in 1995 had only 33 percent of the poor. These figures were 15.4 percent for the South region (8.2 percent of poor), and 6.8 percent for the Center-West region (5.2 percent of poor). For the poorer regions, on the contrary, the share of population in each region is lower than the share of poor: 4.6 percent (9.3 percent of poor) for the North region, and 29.4 percent (44.3 percent of poor) for the North-East region, the poorest region in the country. In terms of evolution of regional inequality, Rocha (1998) concludes that no regular trend could be observed in the period. Moreover, the author also concludes that the yearly observed variations in concentration are mainly related to what happens in the state of São Paulo (SouthEast region) and in the North-East region. This reinforces the position of these two regions in the extremes of the regional income distribution in Brazil. The author also points out that once the effects of income increase that followed the end of the hyper-inflation period in 1995 run out, reduction of national and regional poverty will depend mainly on the macroeconomic 5 determinants related to investment. Also, the author concludes that even keeping unchanged the actual level of poverty, reductions in regional inequality will require reallocation of industrial activity to peripheral regions. And, finally, the same author also concludes that opening of the economy to the external market (mainly in relation to the formation of Mercosul) would help reduce regional inequality in Brazil. This would happen through reduced consumer prices in the poorest regions, which are fortunately lacking in the industries most threatened by new trade flows. The behavior of wages and the allocation of labor throughout the 1980-99 trade liberalization period in Brazil was analyzed by Green et al (2001). Among the main findings the authors point out that wage inequality remained fairly constant for the 1980s and 1990s, with a small peak in the mid 80s. The main conclusion of the study is that the egalitarian consequences of trade liberalization were not important in Brazil for the period under analysis. As caveats, the authors note the low trade exposure of the Brazilian economy (around 13 percent in 1997), as well as the low share of workers that have completed college studies in total (1 in 12 workers at that time). Gurgel, Harrison, Rutherford and Tarr (2003) present a CGE analysis of the effects on Brazil of trade liberalization. They use a GTAP-derived multi-country model with additional Brazilian detail. For Brazil, 10 urban and 10 rural household income types are recognized. The paper compares the effects of the FTAA, EU-MERCOSUL, and multilateral trade agreements on Brazil. Amongst variant scenarios are: the effects of FTAA or EU-MERCOSUL if the USA/EU did not offer free access to Brazilian farm products; and the interaction between trade deals, eg, whether FTAA makes EU-MERCOSUL less attractive. They conclude that the trade deals are in varying degrees good for Brazil, and especially good for Brazil's poor. The poor benefit more 6 because they tend to work in agriculture, which is export-oriented and currently suffers from both foreign trade barriers and indirect taxation through the protection of Brazilian manufacturing. 2. Methodology Computable general equilibrium (CGE) models have long been used for poverty analysis. Many CGE models use a single Representative Household to represent consumer behavior in the model. This formulation, although adequate for many purposes, limits the investigation of poverty and income distribution analysis. More recent approaches were developed to deal with these constraints. Savard (2003) provides a thorough discussion of the topic. He groups CGE models dealing with poverty and income distribution analysis into three main categories: models with a single representative household (RH), models with multiple-households (MH), and the microsimulation approach that links a CGE model to an econometric household micro-simulation model. The Representative Household model is the traditional method, and has been widely used in the literature. The main drawback of this model for income distribution and poverty analysis is that there are no intra-group income distribution changes, as the households are all aggregated into a single representative. The second approach, the multiple-household model (MH), consists of multiplying the number of households. For example, the afore-mentioned Gurgel et al. study distinguished 20 household types. Since they have varying expenditure and income source shares, the households are affected differently by economic changes. However, differences within a particular household group are ignored. 7 Increasing computation capacity allows us to have a large number of households in an MH model. To take an extreme case, the total number of households in a household survey could be used. This approach then allows the model to take into account the full detail in household data, and avoids pre-judgment about aggregating households into categories. The main disadvantages of this type of approach are that data reconciliation can be difficult, and that the size of the model can become a constraint. The third approach, which we call MS, draws on micro-simulation techniques. Here, a CGE model generates aggregate changes that are later communicated to a micro-simulation model based on a large unit record database. Savard (2003) points out that the drawbacks to the approach are coherence between models, since the causality usually runs from the CGE model to the micro-simulation model, with no feedback between them. The approach pursued in this paper takes advantage of the same general idea raised by Savard (2003) to overcome the difficulties posed by the three first options above-mentioned: the use of a CGE model linked to a micro-simulation model, but with a bi-directional linkage between them that would guarantee a convergence of solution for both models. Savard (2003) links the models by running them in a repeated sequence of CGE-MS model runs, first computing the CGE simulation, then the MS model simulation, in a looping way, until convergence occurs. The main advantages of this approach are that: we avoid scaling the microeconomic data to match the aggregated macro data; we can accommodate more households in the MS model; and the MS model may incorporate discrete-choice or integer behavior that might be difficult to incorporate in the CGE model. The CGE model used here is a static inter-regional model of Brazil based on the wellknown ORANI-G model of Australia (Horridge, 2000). The model’s structure is quite standard: 8 consumption is modeled through the Linear Expenditure System over composite commodities (domestic and imported); exporters of each commodity face constant-elasticity1 foreign demand schedules; production for exports or domestic markets are regulated by CET2 functions for each firm, production is a nested Leontief/CES structure for primary factors and composite inputs, labor is a CES function of 10 different types of labor. This non-linear model is solved with the GEMPACK software, and distinguishes between 42 sectors and 52 commodities3; 10 labor occupational categories. All quantity variables in the model are disaggregated according to 27 regions within Brazil, using an elaboration of the top-down regional modeling method described in Chapter 6 of Dixon et al. (1982). This methodology recognizes local multiplier effects: many service goods are little traded between regions, so that local service output must follow local demand for services. The CGE model is calibrated with data from the Brazilian economy for 1996, obtained from two main sources: the 1996 Brazilian Input-Output Matrix (IBGE. http://ibge.gov.br), and the Brazilian Agricultural Census (IBGE, 1996). On the income generation side of the model, workers are divided into 10 different categories (occupations), according to their wages. These wage classes are then assigned to each regional industry in the model. Together with the revenues from other endowments (capital and land rents) these wages will be used to generate household incomes. Each activity uses a particular mix of the 10 different labor occupations (skills). Changes in activity level change employment by sector and region. This drives changes in poverty and income distribution. Using 1 For the simulations reported here, we set the export demand elasticities to values derived from the GTAP model, so as to increase consistency between results for the world and Brazil models. 2 The domestic/exportable CET was set to infinity for the simulations reported below, to fit in with the assumptions of the GTAP model. 9 the POF data mentioned below, we extend the CGE model to cover 270 different expenditure patterns, composed of 10 different income classes in 27 regions. In this way, all the expenditure side detail of our micro-simulation dataset is incorporated within the main CGE model. There are two main sources of information for the household micro-simulation model: the Pesquisa Nacional por Amostragem de Domicílios –PNAD (National Household Survey – IBGE, 2001), and the Pesquisa de Orçamentos Familiares- POF (Household Expenditure Survey, IBGE, 1996). The PNAD contains information about households and persons, and shows a total of 331,263 records. The main information extracted from PNAD were wage by industry and region, as well as other personal characteristics such as years of schooling, sex, age, position in the family, and other socio-economic characteristics. The POF, on the other hand, is an expenditure survey that covers 11 metropolitan regions in Brazil. It was undertaken during 1996, and covered 16,014 households, with the purpose of updating the consumption bundle structure. The main information we drew from this survey was the expenditure patterns of 10 different income classes, for the 11 regions. We assigned one such pattern to each individual PNAD household, according to each income class. As for the regional dimension, the 11 POF regions were mapped to the larger set of 27 CGE regions. Here it must be stressed that the POF survey just brings information about urban areas (the metropolitan areas of the main state capitals). 2.1 Model running procedures and highlights As mentioned before, our model consists of two main parts: a Computable General Equilibrium model (CGE) and a Household Model (MS). The models are run sequentially. To ensure consistency between the two models we have two strategies. First of all, the CGE model 3 One of the activities (Agriculture) produces 11 commodities, A CET function determines output mix.. 10 is sufficiently detailed, and its categories and data are close enough to those of the MS model that the CGE model predicts MS behavior (that is also included in the CGE model, such as household demands or labor supplies) very closely. The role of the MS model is to provide extra information, for example about the variance of income within income groups, or about the incidence of price and wage changes upon groups not identified by the CGE model, such as groups identified by ethnic type, educational level, or family status. A second consistency strategy is that, if the MS model predicts household demands or labor supplies at variance with the CGE model we have the option of feeding back corrections into the CGE model, and running the two models iteratively until they agree. That option was not exercised in the simulations reported here4. We start with a set of trade shocks generated by a GTAP model simulation that excludes the effect of Brazil's own tariff reductions. These shocks consist of changes in import prices and in export demands. To these shocks we add the Brazilian tariff shocks (the trade liberalization in Brazil). Import prices and tariffs are naturally exogenous to the Brazil model. We apply the export demand changes via vertical shifts in the export demand curves facing Brazil (Table 7.6). The trade shocks are applied, and the results calculated for 52 commodities, 42 industries, 10 households and 10 labor occupations -- all of which vary by 27 regions. Next, the results from the CGE model are used to update the MS model. At first, this update consists basically in updating wages and hours worked for the 263,938 workers in the sample. These changes have a regional (27 regions) as well as sectoral (42 industries) dimension. 4 As in GTAP, labour supplies were fixed. Further, each household in our micro data set had one of the 270 expenditure patterns identified in the main CGE model. There is very little scope for the MS to disagree with the CGE model. 11 The model then relocates jobs according to changes in labor demand5. This is done by changing the PNAD weight of each worker in order to mimic the change in employment -- we call this the “quantum weights method”6. In this approach, then, there is a true job relocation process going on. Although the job relocation has very little effect on the distribution of wages between the 270 household groups identified by the CGE model, it may have considerable impact on the variance of income within a group. This is due to the fact that, while the jobs move, the workers do not. So regional adjustment is achieved by workers moving into or out of employment. One final point about the procedure used in this paper should be stressed. Although the changes in the labor market are simulated for each adult in the labor force, the changes in expenditures and in poverty are tracked back to the household dimension. This is possible since PNAD has a key that links persons to households. Each household contains one or more adults, either working in a particular sector and occupation, or unemployed, as well as dependents. In our model then it is possible to recompose changes in the household income from the changes in individual wages. This is a very important aspect of the model, since it is likely that family income variations are cushioned, in general, by this procedure. If, for example, one person in some household loses his job but another in the same household gets a new job, household income may change little. Since households are the expenditure units in the model, we would expect household spending variations to be smoothed by this income pooling effect. On the other hand, the loss of a job will increase poverty more if the displaced worker is the sole earner in a household. 5 The methodology is described in more detail in the annex, which is available in the World Bank Policy Research Working Paper version of this paper. Here we present only the main ideas 6 Mark Horridge developed this method for this project. 12 3. The base year picture In this section we extend the above description of poverty and income inequality in Brazil. The reference year for our analysis is 2001. Some general aggregated information about poverty and income inequality in Brazil can be seen in Table 7.1. The rows of Table 7.1 correspond to household income classes, grouped according to POF definitions7, such that POF[1] is the lowest income class, and POF[10] the highest. A fair picture of income inequality in Brazil emerges from the table. We see that the first 5 income classes, while accounting for 52.6 percent of total population in Brazil, get only 17 percent of total income. The highest income class, on the other hand, accounts for 11 percent of population, and about 45 percent of total income. The Gini index associated with the income distribution in Brazil in 2001, calculated using an equivalent household8 basis, is 0.58, placing Brazil's income distribution among the world's worst. The unemployment rate is also relatively higher among the poorer classes. This is a very important point to be noted, due to its relevance for modeling. The opportunity to get a new job is probably the most important element lifting people out of poverty: hence the importance for poverty modeling of allowing the model to capture the existence of a switching regime (from unemployment to employment), and not just changes in wages. As can be seen in Table 7.1 above, the unemployment rate reaches 36.5 percent among the lowest income group (persons above 15 years), and just 7.7 percent among the richest. The percentage of white people also increases considerably with household income, while the percentage of children decreases 7 POF[1] ranges from 0 to 2 minimum wages, POF[2] from 2+ to 3, POF[3] from 3+ to 5, POF[4] from 5+ to 6, POF[5] from 6-8, POF[6] from 8-10, POF[7] from 10-15, POF[8] from 15-20, POF[9] from 20-30, and POF[10] above 30 minimum wages. The minimum wage in Brazil in 2001 was around US$76. 8 The equivalent household concept measures the subsistence needs of a household by attributing weights to its members: 1 to the head, 0.75 to the other adults, and 0.5 to the children (eg, to feed 2 persons does not cost double). 13 markedly. Although the analysis does not specifically focus in gender and ethnical aspects, these are important indicators to take into account when analyzing results. For the purpose of further describing the state of income insufficiency in Brazil we set a poverty line defined as one third of the average household income9. According to that criterion 30.8 percent of the Brazilian households in 2001 would be poor10. This would comprise 96.2 percent, 76.6 percent and 53.5 percent respectively of households in the first three income groups11, or 34.5 million out of 112 million households in 2001. The first columns in Table 7.11 below report two overall measures of poverty following Foster-Greer-Thorbecke (1984) (FGT, for short): FGT0 – the proportion of poor households (i.e., below the poverty line), FGT1 – the average poverty gap ratio (proportion by which household income falls below the poverty line), for each POF group.12 These figures reveal a large average poverty gap for the two lowest income classes. Together these two income classes contribute to about half of the general average poverty gap index of the economy. The first income class, for example, falls below the poverty line by about 70%. Thus, large income increases for the poor are needed to significantly change the number in poverty. As stated before, this general poverty and inequality picture also has an important regional dimension in Brazil -- because economic activity is located mainly in the South-East region. This is particularly true of manufacturing; agriculture is more dispersed among regions. Figure 7.1 summarizes the regional variation of poverty and income inequality shading them Because poverty is defined here on an equivalent basis, a few (very large) families in middle incomes groups fall below the poverty line. 9 This poverty line is equivalent to US$ 48.00 in 2001. 10 Barros et all (2001), working with a poverty line that takes into account nutritional needs, find that 34 percent of the Brazilian households were poor in 1999. 11 The proportion of households below the poverty line in the other income groups are 0.284 percent for the 4th, 0.14 percent for the 5th, 0.04 percent for the 6th, 0.008 percent for the 7th, and 0.001 percent for the 8th. There are no households below the poverty line for the two highest income classes. 14 according to proportions of households in poverty. The states in the North-East region plus the states of Tocantins and Para in the N region show the highest poverty rates. If, however, regional population is taken into account, the populous regions of Ceará, Pernambuco, Bahia, Minas Gerais and São Paulo play a larger role in the overall poverty picture.13 Tables 7.2 and 7.3 report important information about the labor structure of the Brazilian economy. In these tables sectoral wage bills are split into the model's 10 occupational groups. The occupational groups are defined in terms of a unit wage ranking. More skilled workers, then, would be those in the highest income classes, and vice-versa. As can be seen in Table 7.2, Agriculture is the activity that uses more unskilled labor (40.5 percent of that sector’s labor bill), while Petroleum and Gas Extraction and Petroleum Refinery are the most intensive users of skilled labor (10th labor class) using activities, with Financial Institutions coming next. If labor inputs were measured in hours (rather than in values) the concentration of low-skill labor in Agriculture would be even more pronounced. Agriculture is also the sector that hires most unskilled labor in Brazil, around 41 percent of total workers in income class 1 (Table 7.3). The Trade sector is the second largest employer of this type of labor. As for the higher income classes, we see that the Financial Institutions and Public Administration sectors hire the largest numbers of well-paid workers. Table 7.4 shows the distribution of occupation wages (OCC) classes among the household income classes (POF classes). In this table, the rows show household income classes, while the columns show the wage earnings by occupation. It is evident from this table that the wage earnings of the higher wage occupations (OCC10, for example) are concentrated in the 12 13 The poverty gap and poverty line values are constructed with “adult equivalent” per capita household income. The reader is referred to the World Bank Policy Research Working Paper version of this paper for more details on the breakdown of poverty by region. 15 higher income households, and vice-versa. Most of the wages earned by workers in the first wage class (OCC1) accrue to the three poorest households, POF[1]-[3]. All the workers in the highest wage class, on the other hand, are located in households from the 8th income class and above. We see, then, that the household income classes are highly positively correlated with the occupational wage earning classes. 4. The simulations This section presents results for the central Doha scenario described in Chapter 2 and for the full-lib scenario. 4.1 Model closure In choosing a model closure we aimed to mimic the GTAP model that generated the foreign price scenario. On the supply side, we fixed total national employment by occupation, with jobs moving freely between sectors and regions14. The model allows substitution between occupations, driven by relative wages. Similarly capital is fixed nationally but is mobile between sectors and regions. The Land stock (used just in the Agriculture activity) is fixed15. Since agriculture is an activity that produces 11 products, land is allocated to these competing products through relative prices, allowing the crop mix to change.On the demand side government and 14 There is a tension between our GTAP-like closure and Brazilian reality. The microdata show substantial unemployment of less-skilled groups in all regions. For the microsimulation we assumed that jobs created (or lost) in a region were allotted to (or taken from) households in that region. An alternate scenario, where fixed real wages replaced national labour constraints, yielded results similar to those reported here. 15 The factor market closure causes the model to generate percent changes in prices for 10 labour types, capital and land, ie, price changes are uniform across regions. Percent changes in demand for each of the 12 factors vary in addition by sector and region. Each adult in the PNAD microdata is identified by region and labour type; those employed are also identified by sector. Changes in microdata poverty levels are driven by wage changes and by the redistribution of jobs between sectors and regions (and hence between households). 16 investment spending are fixed16, and a fixed trade balance enforces the national budget balance, which is accommodated by changes in real consumption. The trade balance, then, drives the level of absorption. The Consumer Price Index (CPI) is the model’s numeraire. Finally, tax revenue losses due to tariff cuts are replaced: real aggregate revenue from all indirect taxes is kept fixed, via a uniform endogenous change in the power of indirect taxes on sales to households. This mechanism is equivalent to a lump sum tax, of value proportional to each household's spending17. It also mimics the traditional method of raising tax revenues in Brazil, through indirect tax collection. 5. Results 5.1 The CGE model results The Brazilian economy has a limited exposure to external trade. The shares of exports and imports in total GDP were respectively 7.0 percent and 8.9 percent in the 1996 base year. These shares have increased recently, but not by enough to significantly change this picture18. Table 7.5 shows more information about the structure of Brazilian external trade as well as of related parameters and production structure, while Table 7.6 shows the nature and size of the shocks applied to the model. As stated before, the shocks applied to the model were generated by a previous run of the GTAP model, where the Doha scenarios were implemented. The GTAP effects on the Brazilian 16 In real terms, since the CPI is the model’s numeraire. That is, neither the distribution of spending nor relative prices facing households are altered. With fixed labour supplies, distortion of any labour-leisure choice does not arise. 18 The share of imports plus exports in Brazilian GDP in 2001 and 2002 were, respectively, 22.3 percent and 23.4 percent. 17 17 economy were then transmitted to the Brazil CGE model through tariffs and import prices changes, and shifts in the demand schedules for the Brazilian exports19. An inspection of Table 7.5 and Table 7.6 can give an idea of the importance of these shocks combined with the importance of each commodity in Brazilian external trade. As can be seen, Brazilian exports are spread among many different commodities, with no specialized trend. Raw agricultural products have very small share in total exports, composed almost entirely of soybeans. Processed food and agricultural-based exports (including Wood and Furniture, Rubber, Paper, Textiles and Apparel), however, account for a significant 0.369 share of total exports in the base year, highlighting the importance of Agriculture in the Brazilian economy. Imports as a share of each domestic production are concentrated in Wheat, Oil, Machinery, Electric Materials and Electronic Equipment, and Chemical Products. In terms of total import shares, however, Oil Products (Raw and Refined), Machinery, Electric Materials and Electronic Equipment, and Chemical Products are the most important products. Table 7.5 also shows some relevant parameters and other production characteristics of the model. The Armington elasticities are borrowed from the GTAP database. The same is true for the export demand elasticities (not shown in the table), made equal to the GTAP region-generic elasticity of substitution among imports in the Armington structure. The Agriculture sector is modeled as a multi-production sector, producing 11 commodities. Thus the capital/labor ratio (a ratio of values) in Table 7.5 is the same for every agricultural product. The value of land is not included in the value of capital here. If land was included, the value of the capital/labor ratio in agriculture would rise to 0.99. The value 19 The shifts in the demand schedules for Brazilian exports were calculated using export price and quantity results from GTAP, together with export demand elasticities drawn from GTAP data. 18 added/value of production column, on the other hand, includes the returns to land for Agriculture. In what follows, we present some macro results in order to establish a benchmark for the regional and poverty analysis. When interpreting these results one should bear in mind that the model has a “top-down” inter-regional specification, meaning that regional results depend on national results, but not vice-versa. National macro results can be seen in Table 7.7. Because the closure fixes total supply of all primary factors (land, the 10 categories of labor, and capital), GDP shows only a slight increase in the simulations. The real exchange rate rises (revaluation) as a result of the shocks, with corresponding gains in the external terms of trade. For factor market results, recall that land is used only by Agriculture, while capital and the 10 types of labor are fixed nationally, but mobile between sectors. As we can see, the average (aggregated) capital rental increases in all scenarios. With capital stocks and labor fixed in total, the expanding industries would attract capital and labor from the contracting ones. In these industries those with falling capital/labor ratios increase the marginal productivity of capital, and hence capital returns, determining an increase in aggregated results. The price of land also shows a strong increase, reflecting the increase in production of activities using this factor (Agriculture). National changes in industry output are shown in Table 7.8. As can be seen in Table 7.8, expanding industries in all scenarios are Agriculture and agricultural related industries (the food industry in general). The only exception is the Vegetable Oils industry that contracts under Full-lib. Model results show a general fall in activity in the Brazilian manufacturing sectors following the trade liberalization. This suggests that regions 19 specializing in manufacturing would fare worse. The Doha results are similar, just differing in size (but not sign), when compared with the Full-lib scenario, with a few exceptions. Table 7.9 shows regional results. In this table, states are grouped according to their macro-regions inside Brazil. For each of the 10 labour types, total employment is fixed, so labor demand (and unemployment) will be redistributed among regions according to changes in regional industry output.. Employment falls in Sao Paulo and Rio de Janeiro in the Southeast region (the most populous and industrialized states), and also in Amazonas, DF (Brasilia) and Amapa. The states of Sao Paulo and Rio de Janeiro are industrial states, hosting the bulk of Brazil's manufacturing. As seen before, manufacturing is contracting in general, in all three scenarios. The same effect drives the result for the Amazonas state, where there is a Free Exporting Zone, while reduced mining activity drives the results for Amapa state. Interestingly, the trade liberalization scenarios seem to redistribute economic activity towards poorer regions. However, this occurs because higher value-added sectors (manufacturing) shrink, and relatively lower value-added sectors (agriculture) grow. 5.2 Poverty and income distribution results We saw in the previous section that model results are differentiated among regions and industries. The outcome of these changes on income and income inequality measures as well as over income-group-specific Consumer Price Indices are presented in Table 7.10 and discussed below. In this table, the POF groups are groups of household income, being POF[1] the lowest one and POF[10] the highest. We see that the GINI index fell by 0.21 percent in the Doha scenario and 0.52 percent in the Full-lib case. 20 These results confirm the general understanding that the GINI index usually changes very little with policy measures in the short run, and accord with observed facts in Brazil in the last 15 years. Even though the country faced a strong trade liberalization process in the nineties, it was observed that the GINI index changed very little in the period. The CPI column in each scenario is the particular CPI change for each household income class, since the consumption bundle of each class is different. It is interesting to note that the bulk of the real income effect comes from the income generation side, and not from the fall in prices. Actually, there is a strong increase in some food products, like meats, in all scenarios, driven mainly by the liberalization in the rest of the world. This is in contrast with what was expected by Rocha (1998), mentioned before, who expected that opening the Brazilian economy to the external market would help reduce inequality in Brazil through reductions in prices in the poorest regions. Our results suggest that the CPI would actually go up more in the lowest income classes, but are more than compensated by the income elevation. An important point to note is that the highest positive changes in household income are concentrated on the lowest income households, decreasing monotonically as household income increases. Indeed, as can be seen in Table 7.11, the reduction in the number of poor households is concentrated in the poorest groups. High positive figures in POF groups 7 and 8 are percentage changes over very low numbers, since there are very few poor households in these income classes20. The headcount ratio index (FGT0 in Table 7.11) captures only the extension of poverty, but is insensitive to its intensity (Hoffmann, 1998). The change in the intensity of poverty can be 20 Some middle-income households have many family members. With low per-capita income, they fall below the poverty line. 21 seen through the FGT1 index, the insufficiency of income ratio. A reduction in FTG1 means a reduction in the severity of poverty inside each household income class. As seen from Table 7.11, the FGT1 index decreases more than the headcount ratio in all scenarios. This means that there was actually an income distribution improvement, but not enough to drive a large number of persons (or households) out of poverty. This is due to the high value of those indices in the base year, as noted before. We also computed separately (but do not tabulate here) the effects on Brazil of its own liberalization (assuming other countries did not liberalize). The Brazilian tariff reduction contributes very little to the Doha scenario and is dominated by the other countries’ actions even in the full liberalization scenario. Finally, Table 7.12 shows model results relating to the regional breakdown inside Brazil. These results summarize at regional level the outcome of the simulated scenarios, as a net effect of the regional industries. They reflect, then, the pattern of regional specialization in production. Table 7.12 shows that the states of Amazonas, Amapa, Sao Paulo and Rio de Janeiro would be the only ones where the number of households below the poverty line would increase in both simulations, although slightly. Amazonas and Amapa have small populations, while Sao Paulo and Rio de Janeiro are the most densely populated and industrialized states in Brazil. As noted before, the result is related to the high concentration of contracting (high value-added ) industries in the regions of Sao Paulo, Rio de Janeiro and Amazonas, mainly Automobiles, Machinery and Tractors, Electric Materials, Electronic Equipment, and Other Vehicles and Spare Parts, while the result for Amapa is driven by the mining industries. 22 6. Concluding Remarks One of the main objections raised by some opponents to multilateral trade reform in agriculture is that the bulk of the benefits will go to rich landowners in farm export-oriented economies such as Brazil, thereby worsening an already skewed income distribution. The findings in this chapter refute this hypothesis. In fact, multilateral trade reform under the Doha Development Agenda is found to reduce inequality as well as poverty in Brazil. While wealthy farmers may indeed gain – largely through higher returns to their land – the poor gain proportionately more. Their gains are derived through the labor market. Since 40% of the lowest skill group work in agriculture, an expansion of that sector benefits the poorest households, which rely heavily on earnings from low-skill work. More generally, the model results show that even important trade policy shocks do not generate dramatic changes in the structure of Brazilian poverty and income distribution. The simulated effects on poverty and income distribution are positive, but very small. This is partly due to the fact that the Brazilian economy is not very oriented towards external trade. The domestic market is far bigger and more important for the general economy than the external market, as researchers have long understood. This makes Brazil naturally less sensitive to tariff structure changes, as well as to changes in export demands. A second reason for the modest impacts of trade reform on poverty derives from the fact that we approach poverty through the household dimension, tracking the changes in the labor market from individual workers to households. This tends to blunt the impacts that trade may have on the employment of any single individual, on poverty at the household level. In the PNAD 2001 data we used, the head of the family income accounts for about 65 percent of aggregated household income in Brazil. Therefore, using head-of-household income as a proxy 23 for household income may poorly predict the effect of policy changes, as convincingly argued by Bourguignon et al (2003). If spending (and welfare) is in any sense a household phenomenon, this is the appropriate method. Even though there may be a somewhat higher computational cost associated with this procedure, it seems worthwhile. The role played by the Agriculture sector in the analysis should also be stressed. As seen before, agriculture still accounts for a large share of employment for the poorest in Brazil. Despite the steady decline over time of agricultural employment as a share of total employment we should not overlook the importance of agricultural policies for poverty alleviation in the country. Finally, it should be noted that this study assesses only the static impact of trade liberalization scenarios. The research methodology here used fails to capture many other effects generally associated with external trade liberalization, such as endogenous technology improvements and other dynamic effects. Indeed, our results suggest that if any strong impact over poverty is supposed to arise from trade liberalization it must be expected to arise from these other aspects. 24 References Barros, R.P; Mendonça, R.1997. O Impacto do Crescimento Econômico e de Reduções no Grau de Desigualdade sobre a Pobreza. IPEA. Texto para Discussão no. 528. 17p. Rio de Janeiro. Barros, R.P; Corseuil, C.H; Cury, S. 2001. Salário Mínimo e Pobreza no Brasil: Estimativas que Consideram Efeitos de Equilíbrio Geral. IPEA. Texto para Discussão no. 779. 24p. Rio de Janeiro. Barros, R.P; Henriques, R; Mendonça, R. 2001. A Estabilidade Inaceitável: Desigualdade e Pobreza no Brasil. IPEA. Texto para Discussão no. 800. 24p. Rio de Janeiro. Bourguignon, F; Robilliard, A.S; Robinson,S. Representative versus real households in the macro-economic modeling of inequality. Working Paper no. 2003-05. DELTA. Department et Laboratoire D’Economie Théorique et Apliquée. Centre National de la Recherce Scientifique. École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales. 41 p. 2003 Cury, S. 1998. Modelo de Equilíbrio Geral para Simulação de Políticas de Distribuição de Renda e Crescimento no Brasil. Doutorado. São Paulo, FGV. Foster, James, Joel Greer, and Erik Thorbecke 1984. A Class of Decomposable Poverty Measures, Econometrica 52: 761-765. Green, F; Dickerson, A; Arbache, J.S. 2001. A Picture of Wage Inequality and the Allocation of Labor Through a Period of Trade Liberalization: The Case of Brazil. World Development. Vol. 29, no.11, pp.1923-1939. Gurgel, A; Harrison, G.W.; Rutherford, T.F. and Tarr, D.G., 2003. Regional, Multilateral, and Unilateral Trade Policies of MERCOSUR for Growth and Poverty Reduction in Brazil, World Bank Research Working Paper No. 3051, May. Dixon, P., Parmenter, B., Sutton, J. and Vincent, D. (1982) ORANI: A Multisectoral Model of the Australian Economy, Amsterdam: North-Holland. Hoffmann, R. 1998. Distribuição de Renda: Medidas de Desigualdade e Pobreza. São Paulo. Editora da Universidade de São Paulo. 276 p. Horridge, J.M. 2000. ORANI-G: A General Equilibrium Model of the Australian Economy. Working Paper no. OP-93. Centre of Policy Studies. Monash University. Melbourne, Australia. IBGE - Instituto Brasileiro De Geografia E Estatística. 1996. Censo Agropecuário do Brasil. 366p.Rio de Janeiro. IBGE - Instituto Brasileiro De Geografia E Estatística. 2001. Pesquisa Nacional por Amostra de Domicílios. Brasil. IBGE - Instituto Brasileiro De Geografia E Estatística. 1996. Pesquisa de Orçamentos Familiares. Brasil. Rocha, S. 1998. Desigualdade Regional e Pobreza no Brasil: a Evolução – 1985/95. IPEA. Texto para Discussão no. 567. 21p. Rio de Janeiro. 25 Savard, L. 2003. Poverty and Income Distribution in a CGE-household sequential model. International Development Research Centre – IDRC. Processed. 32p. 26 Figure 7.1: Brazil states shaded according to proportion in poverty Amapa Roraima Para Amazonas Maranhao Ceara RGNorte Paraiba Piaui Pernambuco Alagoas Acre Tocantins Sergipe Rondonia Bahia MtGrosso DF Goias MinasG EspSanto MtGrSul SaoPaulo RioJaneiro Parana 0.14 (minimum) StaCatari 0.24 0.35 (median) 0.51 RGSul 0.58 (maximum) Proportion below poverty line 27 Table 7.1. Poverty and income inequality in Brazil, 2001. Income group PrPop Princ AveHouInc UnempRate PrWhite AveWage PrChild POF[1] 10.7 0.9 0.1 32.6 35.2 0.2 46.2 POF[2] 8.0 1.8 0.4 17.3 38.3 0.3 37.2 POF[3] 16.0 5.2 0.6 10.4 42.0 0.4 35.1 POF[4] 7.3 3.1 0.8 8.8 45.1 0.4 32.5 POF[5] 11.0 5.8 1.0 7.5 49.2 0.5 28.7 POF[6] 7.9 5.1 1.2 7.4 53.4 0.6 26.4 POF[7] 12.9 11.1 1.7 6.8 60.3 0.8 24.5 POF[8] 7.5 8.7 2.3 6.1 66.3 0.9 21.5 POF[9] 7.7 12.7 3.1 5.9 71.2 1.4 20.5 POF[10] 10.9 45.7 7.9 4.2 81.6 3.2 17.7 100.0 100.0 Total --- --- --- --- --- PrPop = % in total population; PrInc = % in country total income; AveHouInc = average household income; UnempRate = unemployment rate; PrWhite = % of white population in total; AveWage = average normalized wage; PrChild = share of population under 15 by income class. Source: PNAD, 2001. 28 Table 7.2. Share (%) of occupations in each activity’s labor bill. Sectors Agriculture MineralExtr PetrGasExtr MinNonMet IronProduc MetalNonFerr OtherMetal MachTractor EletricMat EletronEquip Automobiles OthVeicSpare WoodFurnit PaperGraph RubberInd ChemicElem PetrolRefin VariousChem PharmacPerf Plastics Textiles Apparel ShoesInd CoffeeInd VegetProcess Slaughter Dairy SugarInd VegetOils OthFood VariousInd PubUtilServ CivilConst Trade Transport Comunic FinancInst FamServic EnterpServ BuildRentals PublAdm NMercPriSer 1 40.5 12.0 0.0 7.1 1.9 1.9 1.9 0.5 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.3 8.2 2.3 0.8 2.1 0.5 0.0 1.7 1.6 14.7 3.2 4.1 8.6 8.6 8.6 8.6 8.6 8.6 8.6 16.8 1.7 6.3 10.0 4.6 1.4 0.9 16.4 2.9 2.0 1.7 7.6 2 30.2 19.4 0.0 18.8 6.8 6.8 6.8 4.6 3.8 3.8 2.5 2.5 11.7 7.8 4.7 7.8 1.5 6.8 5.7 6.3 9.0 17.3 16.2 14.3 14.3 14.3 14.3 14.3 14.3 14.3 13.4 17.5 13.4 14.2 7.0 4.6 3.5 20.3 8.1 4.3 13.1 16.6 3 5.8 6.8 0.0 7.4 4.0 4.0 4.0 1.9 2.6 2.6 1.0 1.0 6.6 3.7 3.2 3.0 2.7 9.6 3.1 2.3 4.9 7.5 6.5 6.1 6.1 6.1 6.1 6.1 6.1 6.1 6.6 5.3 8.6 6.6 4.4 2.4 1.3 7.4 4.3 2.7 3.6 6.0 OCCUPATIONS (WAGE CLASS) 4 5 6 7 6.0 5.2 3.3 3.7 6.9 8.4 6.1 12.8 0.9 0.9 6.1 16.1 8.9 11.5 11.8 14.1 6.3 10.2 9.7 22.7 6.3 10.2 9.7 22.7 6.3 10.2 9.7 22.7 4.8 6.8 9.0 19.6 3.3 10.3 11.6 20.4 3.3 10.3 11.6 20.4 2.4 7.7 8.6 19.6 2.4 7.7 8.6 19.6 8.8 12.4 11.9 16.6 6.2 8.4 8.1 18.7 4.6 14.4 5.5 24.0 4.2 9.1 11.8 14.2 0.3 9.0 5.7 13.1 13.4 25.3 0.0 14.5 6.8 4.1 7.5 13.5 8.5 12.8 12.1 24.6 7.2 12.5 11.0 17.6 15.1 16.1 9.7 15.7 13.5 18.2 13.0 14.4 9.6 13.2 11.3 15.1 9.6 13.2 11.3 15.1 9.6 13.2 11.3 15.1 9.6 13.2 11.3 15.1 9.6 13.2 11.3 15.1 9.6 13.2 11.3 15.1 9.6 13.2 11.3 15.1 6.2 11.4 7.4 13.1 8.6 7.1 6.0 12.9 10.1 12.5 9.0 20.2 8.2 10.7 8.2 15.1 4.7 7.5 7.1 19.0 5.1 7.9 9.4 18.6 3.5 6.6 4.2 10.0 8.4 9.6 6.8 12.1 5.7 8.1 6.4 13.0 4.8 9.9 6.3 17.1 7.2 7.6 6.8 13.0 9.2 9.3 10.9 13.7 29 8 1.8 9.9 12.1 7.6 14.0 14.0 14.0 17.2 15.5 15.5 15.7 15.7 9.3 13.0 13.6 15.6 7.2 2.8 11.3 10.3 11.3 5.4 5.7 8.3 8.3 8.3 8.3 8.3 8.3 8.3 7.8 12.2 9.6 8.3 16.1 13.9 11.8 6.5 8.6 8.8 12.1 8.2 9 1.9 10.8 22.8 7.4 15.4 15.4 15.4 16.8 17.0 17.0 22.4 22.4 9.6 16.7 16.6 16.4 10.5 7.9 18.7 9.0 6.2 4.5 4.8 7.4 7.4 7.4 7.4 7.4 7.4 7.4 10.7 14.2 6.9 10.0 18.1 17.2 23.3 7.2 15.7 18.4 19.3 11.6 10 Total 1.6 100 6.9 100 41.1 100 5.3 100 9.1 100 9.1 100 9.1 100 18.8 100 15.1 100 15.1 100 19.8 100 19.8 100 5.0 100 15.1 100 12.5 100 15.8 100 49.5 100 19.7 100 27.4 100 12.6 100 5.5 100 5.5 100 3.6 100 6.0 100 6.0 100 6.0 100 6.0 100 6.0 100 6.0 100 6.0 100 6.5 100 14.5 100 3.4 100 8.7 100 11.6 100 19.4 100 34.9 100 5.4 100 27.2 100 25.7 100 15.6 100 6.9 100 Table 7.3. Share of each activity in total labor bill, by occupation. Sectors Agriculture MineralExtr PetrGasExtr MinNonMet IronProduc MetalNonFerr OtherMetal MachTractor EletricMat EletronEquip Automobiles OthVeicSpare WoodFurnit PaperGraph RubberInd ChemicElem PetrolRefin VariousChem PharmacPerf Plastics Textiles Apparel ShoesInd CoffeeInd VegetProcess Slaughter Dairy SugarInd VegetOils OthFood VariousInd PubUtilServ CivilConst Trade Transport Comunic FinancInst FamServic EnterpServ BuildRentals PublAdm NMercPriSer Total 1 41.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 0.1 0.0 0.3 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.9 0.3 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.7 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.5 0.4 0.1 0.2 0.1 1.0 0.7 0.5 2.7 13.5 2.6 0.2 1.0 21.0 1.6 0.1 6.4 2.2 100.0 2 17.8 0.4 0.0 0.8 0.1 0.1 0.7 0.5 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.7 0.6 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.9 0.4 0.1 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.1 1.0 0.3 3.2 3.3 11.2 2.3 0.4 2.3 15.1 2.6 0.2 29.4 2.8 100.0 3 9.8 0.4 0.0 0.9 0.2 0.1 1.2 0.5 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.2 1.1 0.8 0.1 0.2 0.3 1.1 0.3 0.2 0.4 1.1 0.4 0.1 0.5 0.4 0.1 0.2 0.1 1.2 0.5 2.8 6.1 14.8 4.1 0.6 2.4 15.8 4.0 0.3 23.3 2.9 100.0 OCCUPATIONS (WAGE CLASS) 4 5 6 7 8 6.9 4.8 3.8 2.2 1.4 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.8 0.8 1.0 0.6 0.5 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 1.3 1.7 1.9 2.4 2.0 0.9 1.1 1.7 2.0 2.3 0.2 0.5 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.1 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.3 0.8 1.1 1.3 1.3 1.0 1.2 1.4 1.0 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.2 1.4 1.3 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.4 0.0 0.5 0.4 0.5 0.3 1.0 1.6 0.0 0.6 0.2 0.4 0.2 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.4 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.5 0.4 1.5 1.3 1.0 0.8 0.4 0.6 0.7 0.6 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 1.2 1.4 1.5 1.0 0.7 0.3 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.3 3.0 2.0 2.1 2.4 3.0 4.8 4.9 4.3 5.0 3.2 12.6 13.3 12.5 12.0 8.7 3.0 3.8 4.4 6.2 7.0 0.8 1.0 1.5 1.6 1.6 4.4 6.9 5.3 6.7 10.5 12.1 11.2 9.8 9.0 6.5 3.6 4.1 4.0 4.2 3.8 0.3 0.6 0.4 0.6 0.4 31.2 26.7 29.3 29.2 36.3 3.0 2.4 3.5 2.3 1.8 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 30 9 1.1 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.1 1.5 1.6 0.5 0.4 0.5 1.4 0.6 1.2 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.6 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.5 0.3 2.5 1.6 7.5 5.6 1.4 14.6 5.1 4.8 0.6 40.8 1.8 100.0 10 0.9 0.1 0.5 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.9 1.8 0.5 0.4 0.5 1.2 0.3 1.1 0.1 0.3 1.7 0.8 0.9 0.4 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.4 0.2 2.6 0.8 6.6 3.6 1.6 22.3 3.9 8.5 0.9 33.7 1.1 100.0 Table 7.4. Wage bill distribution according to occupational wages and household income classes. 1996 million Reais. Household Income Classes OCCUPATIONAL WAGES CLASSES (personal) OCC1 OCC2 OCC3 OCC4 OCC5 OCC6 OCC7 OCC8 OCC9 OCC10 Total POF[1] 1531 1637 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 3168 POF[2] 538 2409 1632 783 0 0 0 0 0 0 5362 POF[3] 1804 3996 1201 2460 4327 3728 342 0 0 0 17859 POF[4] 766 1513 861 1380 1077 616 5020 0 0 0 11233 POF[5] 932 2787 1147 1649 2746 2254 5945 3526 0 0 20985 POF[6] 537 1811 795 1410 2133 2127 4305 5517 405 0 19039 POF[7] 576 2315 1178 2012 3038 3102 8717 7654 12773 0 41365 POF[8] 201 1137 524 1045 1819 1969 4896 5585 13211 1427 31814 POF[9] 123 695 401 762 1312 1449 4571 5218 15864 16994 47388 POF[10] 83 527 301 576 1135 1185 3939 5086 18480 134499 165811 Total 7091 18827 8040 12077 17586 16430 37734 32586 60732 152920 364024 31 Table 7.5. Brazilian external trade structure. EXTERNAL TRADE Armington Elasticities Share in total Brazilian exports Exported share of total output PRODUCTION Import share in local markets Share in total imports Capital/ Labor ratio Value added/ value of production Coffee 2.38 0 0 0 0 0.64 0.61 SugarCane 2.2 0 0 0 0 0.64 0.61 PaddyRice 2.2 0 0 0.02 0.001 0.64 0.61 Wheat 2.2 0 0 0.68 0.020 0.64 0.61 Soybean 2.2 0.019 0.170 0.06 0.004 0.64 0.61 Cotton 2.2 0 0 0.02 0 0.64 0.61 Corn 2.2 0.001 0.015 0.01 0.001 0.64 0.61 Livestock 2.8 0 0 0.01 0.001 0.64 0.61 NaturMilk 2.2 0 0 0 0 0.64 0.61 Poultry 2.8 0 0.002 0.01 0 0.64 0.61 OtherAgric 2.38 0.022 0.019 0.02 0.015 0.64 0.61 MineralExtr 2.8 0.059 0.398 0.09 0.006 0.44 0.28 PetrGasExtr 2.8 0 0.002 0.41 0.063 4.19 0.51 MinNonMet 2.8 0.014 0.033 0.04 0.009 1.58 0.38 IronProduc 2.8 0.073 0.154 0.03 0.009 2.99 0.18 MetalNonFerr 2.8 0.041 0.196 0.1 0.014 2.99 0.23 OtherMetal 2.8 0.018 0.037 0.06 0.018 0.32 0.36 MachTractor 5.2 0.038 0.077 0.22 0.088 1.53 0.56 EletricMat 2.8 0.027 0.086 0.19 0.040 0.86 0.27 EletronEquip 2.8 0.018 0.047 0.36 0.123 3.04 0.38 Automobiles 5.2 0.029 0.057 0.1 0.034 2.60 0.25 OthVeicSpare 5.2 0.068 0.144 0.2 0.057 0.69 0.30 WoodFurnit 2.8 0.026 0.078 0.02 0.004 0.66 0.40 PaperGraph 1.8 0.032 0.067 0.06 0.018 0.45 0.28 RubberInd 1.9 0.012 0.071 0.1 0.010 2.41 0.32 ChemicElem 1.9 0.016 0.066 0.15 0.032 3.61 0.35 PetrolRefin 1.9 0.031 0.034 0.11 0.083 6.08 0.31 VariousChem 1.9 0.015 0.039 0.1 0.028 1.11 0.28 PharmacPerf 1.9 0.007 0.021 0.15 0.028 1.84 0.46 Plastics 1.9 0.004 0.021 0.07 0.010 1.46 0.43 Textiles 2.2 0.020 0.052 0.11 0.031 1.98 0.26 Apparel 4.4 0.003 0.011 0.03 0.005 0.37 0.38 0.006 0.71 0.35 0 2.64 0.21 ShoesInd 4.4 0.043 0.294 0.10 CoffeeInd 3.1 0.033 0.237 0 VegetProcess 2.2 0.058 0.105 0.04 0.012 1.69 0.22 Slaughter 2.2 0.025 0.055 0.02 0.004 1.45 0.19 Dairy 2.2 0.001 0.003 0.05 0.007 2.99 0.22 SugarInd 2.2 0.029 0.217 0 0 0.32 0.16 VegetOils 2.2 0.065 0.229 0.04 0.006 2.72 0.11 32 EXTERNAL TRADE PRODUCTION Armington Elasticities Share in total Brazilian exports Exported share of total output Import share in local markets Share in total imports Capital/ Labor ratio Value added/ value of production OthFood 2.2 0.022 0.029 0.05 0.020 1.03 0.27 VariousInd 2.8 0.010 0.049 0.22 0.028 1.22 0.43 PubUtilServ 1.9 0 0 0.03 0.014 0.91 0.59 CivilConst 1.9 0 0 0 0 4.06 0.66 Trade 1.9 0.009 0.016 0.01 0.011 0.18 0.53 Transport 1.9 0.053 0.084 0.04 0.022 0.19 0.49 Comunic 1.9 0.005 0.014 0.01 0.003 1.97 0.78 FinancInst 1.9 0.007 0.006 0.01 0.006 0.23 0.64 FamServic 1.9 0.016 0.010 0.05 0.067 0.36 0.67 EnterpServ 2.1 0.019 0.027 0.05 0.029 0.52 0.72 BuildRentals 1.9 0 0 0 0 51.56 0.95 PublAdm 1.9 0.010 0.003 0.01 0.012 0.00 0.73 NMercPriSer 2.1 0 0 0 0 0.01 0.93 33 Table 7.6. Shocks to the CGE model. Import Tariffs Doha Coffee -0.04 Import CIF Prices Implied Export Price Shift* Full-lib Doha Full-lib Doha Full-lib -6.43 0.74 1.92 -0.74 -0.73 SugarCane 0 -4.99 1.02 1.80 7.73 9.65 PaddyRice 0 -0.17 2.8 6.47 7.58 38.41 Wheat 0 -0.12 1.95 8.49 0.94 -1.80 Soybean 0 -0.09 2.54 5.92 3.90 15.49 Cotton 0 -5.55 2.45 4.26 5.37 18.13 Corn 0 -0.55 2.41 7.56 6.32 25.24 Livestock 0 -0.37 1.05 2.40 0.24 -4.50 NaturMilk 0 0.73 -0.26 -1.11 -9.08 Poultry 0 -4.53 0.45 1.9 0.47 0.39 -6.43 0.74 1.92 -0.74 -0.73 -2.95 0.16 0.12 0.48 1.40 0.14 0.6 0.20 1.70 OtherAgric -0.04 MineralExtr 0 PetrGasExtr 0 0 0 MinNonMet -0.01 -9.82 0.13 0.26 0.78 2.76 IronProduc -0.07 -10.72 0.04 0.19 0.25 0.88 MetalNonFerr -0.23 -7.57 0.03 -0.27 0.80 1.70 OtherMetal -0.04 -14.25 -0.01 0.13 0.45 1.76 MachTractor -0.02 -2.59 -0.17 -0.27 -0.09 -0.45 EletricMat -0.1 -10.92 -0.02 0.05 0.19 0.36 EletronEquip -0.01 -10.84 0 0.05 0.28 0.67 Automobiles -2.14 -16.91 0.24 -0.16 0.53 5.13 OthVeicSpare -0.02 -2.59 -0.17 -0.27 -0.09 -0.45 WoodFurnit -0.84 -11.81 0.06 0.24 0.49 1.54 PaperGraph 0 -8.54 0 -0.04 0.21 0.28 RubberInd -0.28 -7.98 0 -0.25 0.35 0.30 ChemicElem -0.28 -7.98 0 -0.25 0.35 0.30 -0.41 0.14 -0.31 0.45 2.65 PetrolRefin 0 VariousChem -0.28 -7.98 0 -0.25 0.35 0.30 PharmacPerf -0.28 -7.98 0 -0.25 0.35 0.30 Plastics -0.28 0 -0.25 0.35 0.30 Textiles 0 -13.6 -7.98 0.65 0.33 1.34 0.79 Apparel 0 -17.18 1.00 0.25 1.46 -0.67 ShoesInd -0.14 -11.64 0.43 0.21 0.26 -0.32 CoffeeInd -0.05 -16.54 0.25 0.2 1.50 1.66 VegetProcess -0.21 -7.66 0.74 0.46 2.20 10.32 -4.02 2.17 2.91 18.02 38.79 -6.39 4.43 6.74 7.56 15.41 Slaughter Dairy 0 -0.02 34 Import Tariffs Import CIF Prices Implied Export Price Shift* Doha Full-lib Doha Full-lib Doha Full-lib SugarInd 0 -13.18 5.22 5.93 4.30 14.73 VegetOils 0 -7.18 0.88 3.39 3.50 -0.70 OthFood -0.21 -7.66 0.74 0.46 2.20 10.32 VariousInd -0.05 -15.39 0.05 0.1 0.11 -0.15 PubUtilServ 0 0 -0.05 0.07 -0.08 -0.32 CivilConst 0 0 0.03 0.15 -0.03 0.02 Trade 0 0 0.05 0.89 0.01 0.52 Transport 0 0 -0.01 0.3 0.03 0.51 Comunic 0 0 -0.03 0.4 -0.06 0.03 FinancInst 0 0 -0.07 0.38 -0.10 -0.01 FamServic 0 0 -0.10 0.21 -0.11 -0.01 EnterpServ 0 0 -0.06 0.29 -0.04 0.16 BuildRentals 0 0 2.53 7.76 2.69 8.29 PublAdm 0 0 -0.05 0.07 -0.08 -0.32 NMercPriSer 0 0 -0.10 0.21 -0.11 -0.01 * Vertical shift in export demand schedule calculated from GTAP results. 35 Table 7.7. Selected macroeconomic results. Scenarios Macros (percentage changes) Doha Full-lib Real Household Consumption 0.22 0.61 Real Investment 0.00 0.00 Real Government Expenditure 0.00 0.00 Exports Volume 0.91 13.21 Imports Volume 1.98 12.39 Real GDP 0.04 0.26 Aggregated Employment 0.00 0.00 Real wage 0.02 -0.22 Aggregated Capital Stock 0.00 0.00 Average Rate of Return 0.24 1.36 Consumer Price Index - CPI - Numeraire 0 0 GDP Price Index 0.05 -0.33 Export Price Index 0.11 -0.38 Imports (CIF) Price Index -1.10 -1.65 Imports (Domestic Prices) Price Index -1.23 -7.63 Real Devaluation -1.15 -1.32 Terms of Trade 1.22 1.28 -1.26 -1.99 Balance of Trade as a GDP Share 0.00 0.00 Price of agricultural land 7.7 20.97 Nominal Exchange Rate 36 Table 7.8. Activity level variation by industry. Percentage changes. Activity Level Agriculture MineralExtr PetrGasExtr MinNonMet IronProduc MetalNonFerr OtherMetal MachTractor EletricMat EletronEquip Automobiles OthVeicSpare WoodFurnit PaperGraph RubberInd ChemicElem PetrolRefin VariousChem PharmacPerf Plastics Textiles Apparel ShoesInd CoffeeInd VegetProcess Slaughter Dairy SugarInd VegetOils OthFood VariousInd PubUtilServ CivilConst Trade Transport Comunic FinancInst FamServic EnterpServ BuildRentals PublAdm NMercPriSer Doha Full-lib 1.35 -1.00 -1.45 -0.36 -2.13 -1.55 -1.19 -2.25 -1.27 -0.60 -1.06 -3.32 -0.33 -0.58 -1.60 -0.86 -0.39 -0.23 -0.05 -0.49 0.27 0.20 -4.94 0.39 0.79 7.78 0.71 4.52 1.95 0.34 -1.08 -0.07 0.00 0.09 -0.10 -0.01 -0.07 -0.05 -0.30 0.14 -0.03 0.14 3.60 -1.21 -0.99 -1.13 -3.75 -0.50 -4.11 -4.95 -5.22 -3.36 -6.35 -6.55 0.01 -1.14 -4.76 -3.81 -0.48 -1.23 -0.01 -2.16 -3.06 -1.52 -10.86 0.72 4.52 18.81 0.86 19.08 -5.61 1.36 -7.75 -0.15 0.00 0.41 0.52 0.01 -0.28 -0.14 -0.35 0.23 -0.03 -0.01 37 Table 7.9. Regional results, 27 regions. Percentage changes, Brazil. Aggregate Employment Gross Regional Product STATE Doha Full-lib Doha Full-lib Rondonia 0.75 1.92 0.99 2.53 Acre 0.40 1.02 0.54 1.42 -0.14 -0.35 -0.19 -0.58 Roraima 0.48 1.33 0.74 2.09 Para 0.32 0.89 0.44 1.25 -0.03 0.00 -0.02 0.06 Tocantins 2.04 5.34 2.33 6.14 Maranhao 0.86 2.35 1.14 3.12 Piaui 0.86 2.15 1.24 3.16 Ceara 0.33 0.77 0.50 1.18 RGNorte 0.17 0.45 0.24 0.64 Amazonas Amapa Paraiba 0.23 0.56 0.35 0.85 Pernambuco 0.14 0.34 0.19 0.47 Alagoas 0.43 1.56 0.51 1.80 Sergipe 0.15 0.34 0.21 0.50 Bahia 0.24 0.62 0.22 0.64 MinasG 0.07 0.24 0.07 0.24 EspSanto 0.07 0.25 0.10 0.37 RioJaneiro -0.15 -0.26 -0.11 -0.13 SaoPaulo -0.21 -0.60 -0.25 -0.75 Parana 0.27 0.70 0.34 0.86 StaCatari 0.21 0.50 0.21 0.54 RGSul 0.01 0.09 0.02 0.21 MtGrSul 1.49 3.82 1.74 4.41 MtGrosso 1.06 2.76 1.24 3.11 Goias 0.71 1.80 0.85 2.14 -0.04 -0.09 0.01 0.05 DF 38 Table 7.20. Average household income, Consumer Price Index by household income class, and GINI index percentage change. Doha Full-lib Income CPI Income CPI 1 POF[1] 1.47 0.16 3.66 0.44 2 POF[2] 0.68 0.14 1.51 0.41 3 POF[3] 0.57 0.11 1.19 0.33 4 POF[4] 0.36 0.08 0.64 0.22 5 POF[5] 0.23 0.08 0.30 0.23 6 POF[6] 0.13 0.06 0.05 0.18 7 POF[7] -0.05 0.04 -0.40 0.12 8 POF[8] -0.13 0.00 -0.62 0.04 9 POF[9] -0.23 -0.01 -0.85 -0.03 10 POF[10] -0.27 -0.08 -0.96 -0.27 GINI -0.21 -0.52 Table 7.31. Percentage changes in the proportion of poor households (FGT0) and of the poverty gap ratio (FGT1) by household income groups. Different scenarios. Household income class Original Value Doha Full-lib FGT0 FGT1 FGT0 FGT1 FGT0 FGT1 1 POF[1] 0.9617 0.7334 -0.52 -1.45 -1.55 -3.74 2 POF[2] 0.7657 0.3047 -0.48 -1.31 -1.26 -2.91 3 POF[3] 0.5355 0.1496 0.00 -0.89 -0.91 -1.39 4 POF[4] 0.2837 0.0539 -1.72 0.39 -2.28 2.67 5 POF[5] 0.1143 0.0189 -1.03 2.71 1.55 9.85 6 POF[6] 0.0390 0.0054 1.78 11.22 9.44 33.32 7 POF[7] 0.0082 0.0009 10.96 57.55 32.24 156.86 8 POF[8] 0.0008 0.0001 92.35 417.68 247.52 1107.21 9 POF[9] 0.0000 0.0000 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 10 POF[10] 0.0000 0.0000 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Brazil 0.308 0.145 -0.37 -1.08 -0.78 -2.43 FGT0: Foster-Greer-Torbecke proportion of poor households index, or headcount ratio. FGT1: poverty gap ratio. 39 Table 7.42. Percentage changes in number of regional poor households by region, and total number change. SCENARIOS STATES Doha Full-lib 1 Rondonia -0.73 -1.58 2 Acre -0.36 -0.47 0.42 0.80 3 Amazonas 4 Roraima -0.60 -1.74 5 Para -0.24 -0.82 2.41 2.06 7 Tocantins -1.34 -3.94 8 Maranhao -0.87 -2.04 9 Piaui -0.34 -1.32 10 Ceara -0.32 -0.88 11 RGNorte -0.53 -0.83 6 Amapa 12 Paraiba -0.82 -1.56 13 Pernambuco -0.35 -1.09 14 Alagoas -0.38 -1.35 15 Sergipe -0.41 -0.61 16 Bahia -0.45 -1.04 17 MinasG -0.48 -1.08 18 EspSanto -0.71 -1.29 19 RioJaneiro 0.77 0.99 20 SaoPaulo 0.72 1.97 21 Parana -1.19 -2.47 22 StaCatari -1.79 -2.08 23 RGSul -0.54 -2.12 24 MtGrSul -2.77 -6.44 25 MtGrosso -2.32 -6.06 26 Goias -1.06 -2.80 0.11 0.18 -55,908 -139,874 -235,886 -481,989 27 DF Change in total number of households Change in total number of persons 40