International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND UNEMPLOYMENT: A LITERATURE REVIEW
Babangida Muhammad Musa
Department of Business Administration, Faculty of Arts and Social Sciences, Gombe State
University, Gombe – Nigeria
[email protected],
[email protected]
D.M. Semasinghe
Commerce and Financial Management Department, Faculty of Commerce and Management
Studies, University of Kelaniya, Sri Lanka
[email protected]
Abstract
A great deal of ambiguity exists in the literature over the relationship between entrepreneurship
and unemployment. The simple theory of income choice, which has been the basis for numerous
studies focusing on decision confronted by individuals to start-up venture and become
entrepreneur i.e. the increase in unemployment will lead to an increase in start-up activity (pusheffect) on the grounds that the opportunity cost of not starting a venture has decreased. This
study aims to contribute to the entrepreneurship literature by exploring the relationship between
the two conflicting concepts; entrepreneurship and unemployment. In this paper we reviewed the
relationship between entrepreneurship rate and unemployment rate using exploratory research.
Furthermore, using secondary data we attempt to address the ambiguity between the two
concepts empirically. However, we assumed that increase in entrepreneurship activities reduced
unemployment, at the same time, high rate of unemployment lead to slowdown or decrease in
entrepreneurial activity in an economy. Using available literature, we tried to justify this notion
and reconciled the two conflicting concepts, for policy-makers and researchers as well.
Keywords: entrepreneurship, unemployment, theory, relationship and literature review.
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
Introduction
The relationship between entrepreneurship and unemployment has been covered with ambiguity.
On the one hand, the simple theory of income choice, which has been the basis for numerous
studies focusing on the decision confronted by individuals to start a firm and become an
entrepreneur (Blau, 1987; Evans and Leighton, 1990; Evans and Jovanovic, 1989; and
Blanchflower and Meyer, 1994) suggests that increased unemployment will lead to an increase in
start-up or entrepreneurial activity on the grounds that the opportunity cost of not starting a firm
has decreased. On the other hand, the unemployed tend to possess lower endowments of human
capital and entrepreneurial talent required to start and sustain a new firm (Lucas, 1978;
Jovanovic, 1982), suggesting that high unemployment is associated with a low degree of
entrepreneurial activities. A low rate of entrepreneurship may also be a consequence of the low
economic growth levels, which also reflect higher levels of unemployment (Audretsch, 1995).
Entrepreneurial opportunities are not just the result of the push effect of (the threat of)
unemployment but also of the pull effect of produced by a thriving economy as well as by
entrepreneurial activities in the past. In addition to unemployment leading to more or less
entrepreneurial activity, the reverse is also the case to some extent. In this case a new-firm
startups hire employees, resulting in subsequent decrease in unemployment (Picot et al., 1998
and Pfeiffer and Reize, 2000a).
However, we postulated that unemployment slowdown entrepreneurship activity in one hand and
entrepreneurial activities reduced unemployment in another. This paper intends to review
analytically these assumptions in relation to the theories of entrepreneurship and unemployment.
We used secondary data mostly scholarly articles sourced from published and online journals
and conference proceedings. We also used the CIA World Bank Fact Book 2012 to drawn the
employment rates of the developed and undeveloped or developing countries for our comparism.
Theories of entrepreneurship
There is no universally accepted definition of entrepreneurship. Some scholars view
entrepreneurship as aggressive, ‘creative, and innovative business creation’ (Rogoff, 2008:5).
Others simply equate it with self-employment. In the academic literature, a dominant definition
views entrepreneurship as the process of pursuing opportunities and mobilizing resources needed
to bring new ventures to reality (Stevenson, 1990; Ireland, Hitt and Sirmon, 2003). Thus,
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
entrepreneurs are seen as individuals who create new or explore existing market opportunities
and pursue their goals while bearing personal, professional and financial risk. The willingness to
venture into unknown and ability to accept risk exposure are important and necessary ingredients
in entrepreneurship. This inspired the famous Austrian economist, Joseph Schumpeter to liken
entrepreneurs to ‘wild spirits’ who bring innovation and technological change in a nation.
At a practical level entrepreneurship has been defined as;
The process of using private initiative to transform a business concept into a new venture or to
grow and diversify an existing venture or enterprise with high growth potential. Entrepreneurs
identify an innovation to seize an opportunity, mobilize money and management skills, and take
calculated risks to open markets for new products, processes and services (UNDP, 1999:1).
More recently, however, particularly in empirical literature, there has been emerged an
increasing tendency to equate entrepreneurship to self-employment and small business
ownership. Research on entrepreneurship has always been a controversial topic in economic
theorizing. The significance of entrepreneurship is emphasized by almost all authors working on
innovation economics; nevertheless, most of the research work comes to an end at a purely
appreciative level. Still, a consistent theory of entrepreneurship is missing; a theory that is
adequate to combine the various strands of literature in order to come to an empirically testable
model, eventually. Besides the early theories that approach entrepreneurship from a rather
intuitive perspective, to be traced back to Schumpeter (1939), Kirzner (1973) and Kirzner
(1999), a modern evolutionary approach should also contain some specific theories such as the
theory of human capital (e.g. Schlutz (1975), social networks (e.g. Granovetter (1983)) and NeoSchumpeterian Economics (e.g. Loasby (1999)). They develop an eclectic approach by designing
an analytical model open to be applied to different industries and historical settings.
In static theories of competitive equilibrium, the size of the firm is determined by the efficient
allocation of given resources, including entrepreneurial resources, under given technologies.
Accordingly, the observed firm size is the efficient size, in the sense that long run costs are
minimized at that point. Growth follows from the assumption of profit-maximizing behavior and
from the shape of the cost functions. A firm will grow until it has reached the size where long
run marginal costs equal price, which is assessed as the “optimum” size of the firm. Thus, Lucas
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
(1978) equates the firm with the entrepreneur or manager and he assumes that a firm’s output is a
function of managerial ability as well as capital and labour. Lucas postulates therefore one
production technology subject to constant returns to scale, and a separate managerial technology
with diminishing returns to scale or “span of control.” Managers with higher abilities (i.e., higher
efficiency levels) will have lower marginal costs and therefore will produce larger outputs.
However, firm expansion will be limited due to decreasing effectiveness of the manager as the
scale of the firm increases. An implication of the Lucas model is that, for a small business to
grow, the small business owner must be willing and able to relinquish many day-to-day control
functions and delegate those tasks to an enlarged, specialized management team.
The theories discussed above are static. They say little about how an industry and the firms
within it evolve over time and they ignore the fact that individuals can learn their business
acumen by acquiring education and operating businesses over time.
Jovanovic (1982) addresses these deficiencies by developing a model of the firm life cycle
based on learning. According to Jovanovic’s life cycle model, individuals differ in their
entrepreneurial abilities (as in Lucas), but they are unsure of their abilities. In his model,
production technology is risky (as in Kihlstrom and Laffont), partly because individuals are
uncertain about their abilities and partly because production is inherently risky. His model also
assumes that individuals learn about their abilities over time by observing how well they perform
in a tough business world. Individuals who find out that they have underestimated their abilities
in one period will expand output in the next, while those that overestimated their abilities will
dissolve their business.
Jovanovic’s model has a rich set of empirical implications. Young firms have accumulated less
information than older firms about their managerial abilities (experience). Consequently,
younger firms have more variable growth rates than older firms because they have less precise
estimates of their true abilities. For the same reason it follows that there will be more exits
among younger firms, but also that among surviving firms, younger firms will grow faster than
older firms. As younger firms tend also to be smaller firms, Jovanovic argues that the same
observations hold for small firms as well. Surviving small firms are expected to grow faster than
larger firms and to have more variable growth rates.
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
According to the influential theory of Churchill and Lewis (1983), growth is part of the natural
evolution of a firm. The authors identify five stages of growth: existence, survival, success, takeoff and resource maturity. In each stage of development a different set of factors is critical to the
firm’s survival and success. Growth thresholds may exist as obstacles to the transition from one
stage to another. Accordingly, in the take-off stage – most relevant in a study of rapid growth –
there are two major concerns or obstacles to firm growth: the ability of the owner to a) hire new
people and b) delegate responsibility. The business will also need enough cash to satisfy the
greater demand for financial resources brought about by growth. The prevailing theories
recognize the attitudes and ability of the business owner (entrepreneur) have an important impact
on small firm success and will be reflected in strategic choices and the ways in which he/she
operates in business.
Entrepreneurship may influence economic performance in different ways. Entrepreneurs often
play a vital role in the early evolution of industries by way of introducing new products or
processes and, in the long term, enhancing productivity through increasing competition (Van Stel
& Thurik & Verheul & Baljeu, 2007). New entrants in the market may also create knowledge
about what is technically viable and what consumers prefer by introducing variations of existing
products and services in the market. The resulting learning process speeds up the discovery of
the dominant design for product -market combinations. The learning does not solely apply to the
experimenting entrepreneur (Baptista & Van Stel & Thurik, 2006). Knowledge spillovers play an
important role in this process (Audretsch & Aldridge & Oettl, 2006; Audretsch, 2007; Van Stel
& Thurik & Verheul & Baljeu, 2007).Finally, self -employed individuals tend to work longer
hours than wage-employed people and may be more productive as their income is more clearly
linked to working effort (Van Stel & Thurik & Verheul & Baljeu, 2007; Carree & Thurik, 2003;
Carree & Verheul & Thuri k, 2007).
Concept and theories of unemployment, its nature and magnitude in development
Unemployment is one of the most visible indicators of economic activity. The rate of
unemployment typically rises considerably during recessions then falls as the economic recovers.
People commonly view the typical unemployed worker as suffering long-lasting despair and
destitution, so the media publicize high unemployment as a great social problem. Some degree of
unemployment is socially and perhaps personally desirable. Much of unemployment consists of
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
new entrants to the labor market seeking their first job, individuals who are voluntarily changing
jobs or occupations, and people in jobs for which periodic or seasonal layoffs are normal,
expected, and compensated for by higher wages during periods of employment (Parker, 2010).
For these individuals, unemployment is not a problem at all. It is merely part of the natural
functioning of a flexible and efficient labor market.
Economists often view unemployment as one facet of an inevitable process of search in the labor
market. Jobs and workers are heterogeneous along many dimensions. Workers differ (among
other ways) by intelligence, creativity, education, training, experience, physical size and
strength, manual dexterity, ability to sustain repetitive tasks, and preferences about their work
environment. Jobs vary in the abilities, education, and experience that are required to perform
them, as well as in working conditions, location, opportunities for advancement, and many other
characteristics.
Rather than simply viewing unemployment as the counter-state to employment, we model it as a
process of search. The success that individuals seeking new jobs will have in finding them
depends on two broad kinds of circumstances: (1) the general balance of demand and supply in
the labor market, and (2) the match between the searchers’ characteristics and those of the
available jobs. There are two broad categories of approaches to explaining movements in
unemployment that correspond to these two kinds of circumstances.
One approach emphasizes the heterogeneity of workers and jobs. Because every worker and
every job has unique characteristics, matching them up through a search process is time
consuming. Search models examine the propensity of employers and job searchers to achieve
matches and how that propensity varies over time. This approach models the flows of workers
and jobs between states: a job match that results in a hire transforms an unemployed worker into
an employed worker and a vacant job into an occupied one. To complete the model, one must
examine the other labor-market flows: job creation and destruction, entry to and exit from the
labor force, and the flow of separations of existing workers from their jobs.
In the search approach, natural unemployment fluctuates when there are changes in the
efficiency of matching in the economy or in the other flows between labor-market states. For
example, if structural shifts in the economy make it more difficult to match the characteristics of
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
unemployed workers with those of vacant jobs, then matching will be less efficient and the
natural rate of unemployment will increase. It should be emphasized that the kind of
unemployment described by the search theories does not require a general excess supply of
labor. It stresses the fact that even when the number of unemployed is equal to the number of job
vacancies, neither number is likely to be zero.
Unemployment in the classical economic theory
Wicksell thinks that if wages are sufficiently flexible downward, then this decline can maintain
full employment (Jonung 1989). Cheaper credit to businessmen is the most effective measure to
fight unemployment. He even thought that the government should support private investment in
housing and soils. Government can support the introduction of various inventions as well.
Government support should be financed by taxation. Wicksell analyzes technical unemployment
due to technological change as well.
The introduction of machinery would cause unemployment but the unemployed will search for
new jobs, a search that will push wages downward. Hence, full employment is restored again.
For the normal (frictional) unemployment, Wicksell thinks that advertisements and employment
agencies can reduce the normal rate of unemployment. The cyclical unemployment, as another
type of unemployment, is due to the lack of effective demand. He though it would be a good idea
to raise wages in order for workers to buy more. But this action may cause workers to lose their
jobs as a result of higher wages.
Essentially, for Wicksell the cyclical unemployment was due to the wrong investment of capital.
Capital was invested in areas where rates of return were low. He concluded that public works is
the best measure to fight cyclical unemployment. After World War I, Wicksell thinks the boom
and the rise in prices induced by the war would come to an end. Thus, unemployment would rise.
Workers would have to accept lower wages. He also thought that government should provide
financial support to the unemployed who could not find jobs. After 1921, Wicksell turns to
Malthus. He thought that the causes of the unemployment are the surplus people, shortage of
capital brought about by the war, and the disorganized state of the monetary system. For the third
cause, after the war prices were falling and producers decided to produce lower amounts of
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
production because they knew they would receive lower prices for their products. Thus, they let
their money set idle in banks and workers became unemployed.
These causes suggest that emigration became one of the important policies for solving the
unemployment problem. Wage reduction is not a competent policy to increase employment. The
increase in wages is most likely due to increased labor productivity and wage reduction will
reduce work intensity and productivity. Wage reduction will not force some capital intensive
firms to switch to labor intensive techniques in the short run. Higher wages should stimulate the
substitution effect by employing more machines for labor.
And this substitution will increase labor productivity and employment in the long-run. Hayek
(Nishhiyama and Leube 1984) contends that unemployment is due “to a discrepancy between the
distribution of labor between industries and the distribution of demand among their producers.
This discrepancy is caused by a distortion of the system of relative prices and wages.” In other
words, the unemployment is caused by “a deviation from the equilibrium prices and wages
which would establish themselves with a free market and stable money.” This is actually a
mismatch between demand and supply of labor, which is usually caused by expansionary
monetary and fiscal policies and powerful trade unions. These policies create economic
dislocation and structural changes in an economy which misdirect labor and other economic
resources to other alternatives. Unions are also able to set higher wages compared to market
wages, which generate unemployment, particularly in industries that become less profitable. In
short, for Hayek the unemployment problem is caused by resources being in the wrong places at
the wrong time and can be corrected if wages and prices are determined by the equilibrium of
supply and demand.
In line with Hayek theory of unemployment, Trehan (2001) provides an important explanation of
the search theory of unemployment. Firms search for the productive workers and workers search
for high-paying jobs. So, both agents continue searching until matches are reached. At that point
a worker will leave the unemployment pool. But if a worker realizes later on that his/her
productivity is worth higher wages and firms are paying high wages on the average, then the
worker’s reservation wage will increase. Consequently, the unemployment rate will start rising
gradually, indicating a mismatch has occurred again.
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
Unemployment in the theory of innovations
Originally, this theory was developed by the German economist Von Mangoldt (Ekelund and
Hebert 2007) wrote a book about entrepreneurial profits in 1855 and connected profits to risk. He
provided several ways by which the entrepreneur can make profits. These ways are (1) finding
particular markets, (2) acquisition of productive agents, (3) skillful combination of factors of
production, (4) successful sales policy, and (5) innovations. And it is well understood proposition
that entrepreneurial profits will increase employment (Mouhammed 2010).
Schumpeter (1934) does not provide explicitly a theory of unemployment but his theory of the
business cycle does demonstrate clearly how unemployment can be reduced. Innovation (see also
Vecchi 1995) which creates more jobs relative to job destruction is the basic force beyond the
increases in employment and the decreases in unemployment. When entrepreneurs innovate
something new such as the production of a new product, the finding of a new market, introducing
a new method of production and the invention of new technologies and a new organization they
increase investments to materialize those innovations. Domestic investment expenditures will
increase demand on economic resources and will increase their prices. Other entrepreneurs will
imitate the leaders by adopting the new innovations. Labor and materials will be employed to
produce the new items. Consequently, wages will be increasing and unemployment will be
declining, assuming that employment creation will outweigh employment destruction due to the
new innovations (see also Mortensen and Pissarides 1998 and Manuelli 2000).
Theoretical nexus between entrepreneurship and unemployment
Really ambiguity exists in the literature over the link between entrepreneurship and
unemployment. The simple theory of income choice, which focuses on decision confronted by
individuals to start-up venture and become entrepreneur trigger many studies. (Blau, 1987; Evans
and Leighton, 1990; Evans and Jovanovic, 1989; and Blanchflower and Meyer, 1994) asserts that
increased unemployment will lead to an increase in start-up activity on the grounds that the
opportunity cost of not starting a venture has decreased. On the other hand, the unemployed tend
to possess lower endowments of human capital and entrepreneurial talent required to start and
sustain a new venture (Lucas, 1978; Jovanovic, 1982), assert that high unemployment is
associated with low degree of entrepreneurial activities. A low rate of entrepreneurship may also
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
be a consequence of the low economic growth levels, which also reflect higher levels of
unemployment (Audretsch, 1995).
Entrepreneurial opportunities are not just the result of the push effect of (the threat of)
unemployment but also of the pull effect of produced by a thriving economy as well as by
entrepreneurial activities (Parker, 1996). In addition to unemployment leading to more or less
entrepreneurial activity, the reverse has also been claimed to hold. On the one hand, new venture
start-ups hire employees, resulting in subsequent decreases in unemployment (Picot et, al. 1998
and Pfeiffer and Reize, 2000a). On the other hand, the low rates of survival combined with the
limited growth of the majority of small firms entail that the employment contribution of startups
is limited at best, which would argue against entrepreneurial activities reducing unemployment.
As Geroski (1995) has documented, the penetration rate, or employment share, of new startups is
remarkably low.
There is ambiguity in the empirical evidence between these two conflicting concepts. Some
studies have found that unemployment is associated with greater entrepreneurial activities, but
others have come with the opposite conclusion, that entrepreneurship and unemployment are
inversely related. For instance, Evans and Leighton (1990) found that unemployment is
positively associated with a greater propensity to start a new firm, but Garofoli (1994) and
Audretsch and Fritsch (1994) observe that unemployment is negatively related to new venture
start-ups, and Carree (2001) found that no statistically significant relationship exists between the
two concepts.
Audretsch and Thurik (2000) assert that an increase in the number of business owners reduces
the level of unemployment. They identify a ‘Schumpeter’ effect in terms of the positive impact
on employment resulting from the entry of new venture start-up activity. Storey (1991)
concludes that, the broad consensus is that time series analyses point to unemployment being,
ceteris paribus, positively associated with indices of new venture formation, whereas cross
sectional, or pooled cross sectional studies appear to indicate the reverse. Attempts to reconcile
these differences have not wholly successful.
Thus, while there are not just theoretical reasons, but also empirical support as well, that while
unemployment leads to increased entrepreneurial activity, entrepreneurship leads to reduced
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
unemployment. Unraveling the relationship between entrepreneurship and unemployment is
crucial, because policy is frequently on assumptions that do not reflect this ambiguity. For
example, in advocating a greater role for public policy to promote entrepreneurship in Europe,
the president of the European Commission, Romaro Prodi (2002), assert that ‘increases in
entrepreneurial activity tend to result in higher subsequent growth rates and a reduction of
unemployment’.
The relationship between entrepreneurship and unemployment
The unemployed people tend to possess lower endowments of human and social capital and
entrepreneurial talent required to start and sustain a new firm which may lead to early exit
(Thurik, 2007; Lucas, 1978; Jovanovic, 1982; Baptista & Van Stel & Thurik,2006) .High
unemployment may also imply lower levels of personal wealth reducing the likelihood of
becoming self-employed or the survival in the initial stages of business ownership (Hurst &
Lusardi, 2004; Van Stel & Thurik & Verheul & Baljeu, 2007). High level of unemployment may
correlate with low economic growth leading to a low number of entrepreneurial opportunities
(Audretsch & Thurik & Verheul & Wennekers, 2002; Baptista & Van Stel & Thurik, 2006). A
low rate of entrepreneurship may also be a consequence of the low economic growth levels,
which also reflect higher levels of unemployment (Audretsch, 1995; Audretsch & Carree &
Thurik, 2001).
While some studies find that greater unemployment serves as a catalyst for startup activity
(Reynolds & Miller & Makai, 1995; Reynolds & Storey & Westhead, 1994; Hamilton, 1989;
Highfield & Smiley, 1987; Yamawaki, 1990; Evans & Leighton, 1989 & 1990), but many
studies have found that unemployment reduces the amount of entrepreneurial activity (Audretsch
& Fritsch, 1994; Audretsch, 1995; Audretsch & Carree & Thurik, 2001). If a country prevails
high unemployment rate, entrepreneurs face reduced demand of products or services. This
reduces the revenue accruing from entrepreneurship, and capital availability, which leads to
increasing the risk of bankruptcy. In this way, individuals are "pulled out "of business because
the company's bankruptcy case becomes a higher risk than the gainful employment. According to
(Lucas, 1978; Javanovic, 1982) who observe that there is an inverse relationship between
entrepreneurship and unemployment (high level of unemployment is associated with a low level
of entrepreneurship), i.e. unemployed people do not have the necessary expertise to start-ups and
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
do not have intrinsic properties of the entrepreneur. This article authors hold, the prevailing
controversial opinions of the past about the relationship between entrepreneurship and
unemployment.
In addition to unemployment pushing to start-up new firm activity, it has been argued that
entrepreneurship influences (un)employment. There is also a lot of claiming that start-up activity
influences unemployment. The positive effect of entrepreneurship on economic performance has
been referred to as the Schumpeter effect (Van Stel & Thurik & Verheul & Baljeu, 2007). Newfirm startups hire employees, resulting in subsequent decreases in unemployment (Picot et al,
1998; Pfeiffer & Reize, 2000a; Audretsch & Carree & Thurik, 2001).
Thurik et al. (2007) examine the relationship between entrepreneurship and unemployment in
Japan .They find that, although Japan‘s unemployment rate has been influenced by specific
exogenous shocks, the effects of entrepreneurship on unemployment are not different when
compared to other OECD countries. They find that entrepreneurship significantly lowers
unemployment but that it takes a lag of four yearly data (VanStel & Thurik & Verheul & Baljeu,
2007). VanStel & Baptista & Thurik, (2006), examines the relationship between
entrepreneurship and unemployment, as measured by the variation in business ownership rates,
and unemployment in Portugal. They concludes that Portugal has been a relative outlier in regard
to the effects of entrepreneurship on unemployment when compared whit the OECD average.
They found that the industrial re-structuring effects brought about by increases in business
ownership rates probably do not have a significant impact on the reduction of unemployment.
Thurik (2003), the influence of industrial structure, more specifically of entrepreneurship, is
investigated on the level of unemployment in the UK. It will be concluded that the UK is a
relative outlier when using a simple model of the relationship between unemployment and the
rate of business ownership. The model is calibrated using recent data of some 23 OECD
countries. It underestimates the decrease in unemployment in the UK in the period 1982-1990.
Moreover, we observed that countries with higher entrepreneurial activity shows low rate of
unemployment, for instance, Japan rate of unemployment in 2012 is 4.6%, United Kingdom
8.1%, USA 7.7%, Finland 7.8%, Austria 4.8%, Germany 5.7%, Singapore 2.1%, and Malaysia
3.1%. In the other hand, the countries with lower entrepreneurial activity has high rate of
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
unemployment. Example of these countries are Kenya with 40% unemployment rate, Maldives
14.5%, Namibia 51.2%, Egypt 12.7%, Jamaica 13.0%, Iran 14.1%, Nepal 46%, Algeria 9.7%.
(CIA World Fact Book 2012).
Thus, while there are not just theoretical reasons, but also empirical support as well, that while
unemployment leads to increased entrepreneurial activity, entrepreneurship leads to reduced
unemployment. Unraveling the relationship between entrepreneurship and unemployment is
crucial, because policy is frequently on assumptions that do not reflect this ambiguity.
Findings
Our findings are in line with the individual observations of (Lucas, 1978; Javanovic, 1982) who
observe that there is an inverse relationship between entrepreneurship and unemployment. We
found that high level of unemployment is associated with a low level of entrepreneurship
activities, i.e. unemployed people do not have the necessary expertise to start-ups and do not
have intrinsic properties of the entrepreneur as well as the capital or collateral to start a business.
This can clearly be observed in the following evidences; we examined some countries in the
world in relation to the conflicting arguments between entrepreneurship and unemployment. We
discovered that countries with high rate of entrepreneurial activity have low rate of
unemployment (e.g. developed countries). While in the other hand countries with high rate of
unemployment have low rate of entrepreneurial activities (e.g. under-developed or developing
nations). Therefore, the interaction between entrepreneurship and unemployment is essentially
determined by the country’s position of the labour market.
Conclusion and recommendations
We finally conclude that entrepreneurship has a significant link with unemployment. This is
clearly shown in the findings of this study. Some countries with high rate of entrepreneurial
activity have low rate of unemployment (e.g. developed countries like USA, Japan, UK). While
in the other hand countries with high rate of unemployment have low rate of entrepreneurial
activities (e.g. developing nations like Namibia, Nepal, Kenya). The interaction between
entrepreneurship and unemployment is essentially determined by the country’s position of the
labour market. An examination of the communal relationship between entrepreneurship and
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
unemployment show that both in theory and practice, there is a "pull" (business reduces
unemployment) effects, while we opposed the "push" (unemployment encourages to take
business) effect notion.
We suggest the development of entrepreneurial skill and potentials and acting based on the
promotion of entrepreneurial thought. We also suggest policy makers should promote
entrepreneurial thought and skills of their people in order to establish entrepreneurial economies.
Small businesses, referring to entrepreneurs, are more able to quickly respond to markets
demands because they are not so rigorously rigid and are labour intensive. In modern economies
is entrepreneurship a legitimate if not a preferred choice for employment because it offers certain
benefits that one could not have when employed in a large corporation or in the public sector.
Reference
Audretsch, D. B. (2007). Entrepreneurship capital and economic growth. Oxford Review of
Economic policy, 23(1), 63-78.
Audretsch, D. B. (1995). Innovation and Industry Evolution. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Audretsch, D.B., Aldridge, T., & Oettl, A. (2006). The knowledge filter and economic growth:
The role of scientist entrepreneurship. Discussion paper on entrepreneurship, Growth
and public policy, 0611, Jena: Max Planck Institute of Economics.
Audretsch, D.B., Carree, M.A., & Thurik,A.R.(2001). Does entrepreneurship reduce
unemployment? Tinbergen Institute discussion paper T IOL-074/30.Erasmus University
Rotterdam. Available at <http://www.tinbergen.nl/discussionpapers/01074.pdf>
Audretsch, D. B., & Fritsch, M. ( 1994). The Geography of Firm Births in Germany. Regional
Studies, 28(4), July, 359-365.
Audretsch, D.B., & Thurik, A.R. (2000).Capitalism and democracy in the 21st century from the
managed to the entrepreneurial economy, Journal of Evolutionary Economics 10(1), 1734.
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
Baptista,R., Thurik, R., Van Stel, A.J.(2006). The relationship between entrepreneurship and
unemployment in Portugal. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74, 75–89.
Blanchflower, D., & Meyer, B. (1994).A Longitudinal Analysis of Young Entrepreneurs in
Australia and the United States. Small Business Economics, 6(1), 1-20.
Blau, D. M. (1987). A Time Series Analysis of Self Employment in the United States. Journal of
Political Economy, 95(3), 445 -467.
Caree, M.A., & Thurik, A.R. (2003). The impact of entrepreneurship on economic growth. In
Acs and Audretsch, eds. International Handbook of Entrepreneurial Research.
Churchill, N.C. and Lewis, V.L. (1983) The five stages of small business growth, Harvard
Business Review, 61(3): 30–41.
CIA – The World Factbook, URL: https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/,
15. 9. 2012.
Ekelund, Jr., Robert and Robert F. Hebert. ( 2007). A History of Economic Theory and Method.
Fifth edition, Long Grove, Illinois: The Waveland Press.
Evans, D. S., & Jovanovic,B. (1989). Estimates of a Model of Entrepreneurial Choice under
Liquidity Constraints. Journal of Political Economy, 97(3), 657-674.
Evans, D. S., & Leighton, L. (1990). Small Business Formation by Unemployed and Employed
Workers. Small Business Economics, 2(4), 319-330.
Evans, D. S., & Leighton, L.S.(1989). The Determinants of Changes in U.S. Self-Employment,
1968-1987. Small Business Economics, 1(2), 111-120.
Garofoloi, G. (1994).New Firm Formation and Regional Development: The Italian Case.
Regional Studies, 28(4), 381-394.
Geroski P. A. (1995) What do we know about entry? International Journal of Industrial
Organization, Vol. 13, No. 4, 421-440.
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
Granovetter, M. S.: 1983, The stength of weak ties. A network theory revisited, in R. Collins
(ed.), Sociological Theory, Jossey-Bass, San Francisco, pp. 201–233.
Hamilton, R.T. (1989).Unemployment and Business Formation Rates: Reconciling Time Series
and Cross Section Evidence. Environment and Planning, 21, 249-255.
Highfield, R., Smiley, R. (1987).New Business Starts and Economic Activity: An Empirical
Investigation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5, 51-66.
Hurst, E., lusardi, A .(2004).Liquidity Constraints,Household Wealth and Entrepreneurship.
Journal of Political Economy,112(2),319-347.
Ireland, R. D. (2003). A model of Strategic Entrepreneurship. Journal of Management 963-989.
Jovanovic, B. (1982). Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica, 50, 649-670.
Jonung, L. (1989). “Knut Wicksell on unemployment,” History of Political Economy, 21, 1,
27-42.
Kihlstrom, R.E. and Laffont, J.J. (1979). A general equilibrium entrepreneurial theory of firm
formation based on risk aversion. Journal of Political Economy, 87(4), 719-748.
Kirzner, I. M.: 1973,Competition and Entrepreneurship, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Kirzner, I. M.: 1999, Creativity and/or alertness: A reconsideration of the schumpeterian
entrepreneur, Review of Austrian Economics, Vol. 11, Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp.
5–17.
Loasby, B. J.: 1999,Knowledge, Institutions and Evolution in Economics, Routledge, New York.
Lucas, R. E. (1978). On the Size Distribution of Business Firms. Bell Journal of Economics, 9,
508 -523.
Manuelli, R. (2000). “Technological Change, the Labor Market, and the Stock Market,” NBER
Working Paper 8022 (November).
Mouhammed, Adil. (2010). “Unemployment and the Entrepreneur,” International Journal of
Economics and Research, 1, 1, 1-14.
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
Mortensen, D. and Pissarides, C. (1994). “Job Creation and Job Destruction in the Theory of
Unemployment,” The Review of Economic Studies, 61, 3, 397-415.
Nishiyama, C. and Leube, K. (1984). The Essence of Hayek. Hoover Institution: Stanford
University, Stanford, CA.
Parker, S.C. (1996). A time series model of self-employment under uncertainty. Economica,
63(251), 459-475.
Parker, S. C. (2010). The Economics of Self-employment and entrepreneurship. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Pfeiffer, F., & Reize, F. (2000). Business Start-ups by the Unemployed an Econometric
Analysis Based on Firm Data. Labour Economics, 7(5), 629-663.
Picot, G., Marilyn, E., Manser, & Zhengxi, Lin.( 1998).The Role of Self -Employment in Job
Creation In Canada and the U.S. OECD-CERF-CILN International Conference on SelfEmployment, Burlington, Ontario,
Canada.
Reynolds, P., Miller, B., & Makai, W.R. (1995).Explaining Regional Variation in Business
Births and Deaths: U.S. 1976 -1988. Small Business Economics, 7 (5), 389-707.
Reynolds, P., Storey, D. J., & Westhead, P.(1994).Cross-National Comparisons of the Variation
in New Firm Formation Rates. Regional Studies, 28(4), July 443-456.
Rogoff, E. G. (2008). The Issues and Opportunities of Entrepreneurship after age 50 New York:
Office of Academic Affairs, Occasional papers 5.
Schlutz, T. W.: (1975), The value of the ability to deal with disequilibria, Journal of Economic
Literature13, 827–846.
Schumpeter, J. A.: (1939), Business Cycles I, McGraw-Hill, New York.
Schumpeter, J.A. (1934). The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press.
International Conference on Business & Information 2013
ISBN 978-955-4563-17-9
Stevenson, H. H. (1990). A Paradigm for Entrepreneurship: Entrepreneurial Management.
Strategic Management Journal, 17-27.
Storey, D.J. (1991). 'The Birth of New Firms - Does Unemployment Matter? A Review of the
Evi-dence,' Small Business Economics, 3 (3), 167-178.
Thurik, A. R. (2003). Entrepreneurship and unemployment in the uk. Scottish Journal of political
Economy, 50(2), 264-290.
Thurik,R., Verheul, I., Baljeu, L.,Van Stel, A.J.(2007). The Relationship between
Entrepreneurship and Unemployment in Japan. Tinbergen Institute discussion paper TI080/3. Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam, universiteit uan Amsterdam, and vrije
universiteit Amsterdam.
Trehan, B. (2001). Unemployment and Productivity, Economic Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, Number 28, October 12, 1-3.
Vecchi, N. (1995). Entrepreneurs, Institutions and Economic Change: The economics thought of
J.A. Schumpeter (1905-1925).London: Edward Elgar.
Verheul,I., Stel, A.J.V., Thurik, A.R.,&Urbano,D.(2006).The relationship between business
ownership and unemployment in Spain: a matter of quantity or quality? Estudios de
Economia Aplicada, 24(2), 435-457.
Verheul,I., Wennekers, A.R.M., Audretsch, D.B., &Thurik, A.R.(2002). An eclectic theory of
entrepreneurship: policies, institutions and culture, in ‘Entrepreneurship: Determinants
and Policy in a European-US Comparison’, Boston/ Dordrecht. Kluwer Academic
Publishers, 11-81.
Yamawaki, H. (1990).The Effects of Business Conditions on Net Entry: Evidence from Japan. In
P.A. Geroski and J. Schwalbach