Reference: Acs, Z. J., Szerb, L., & Jackson, S. (2013). Entrepreneurship in Africa
Through the Eyes of GEDI. The International Journal of Entrepreneurship and
Innovation, 14(4) pp. 219-234,
Entrepreneurship in Africa through the Eyes of the GEDI
Zoltán J. Ács
School of Public Policy
George Mason University
Fairfax, VA, 22030, USA
E-mail:
[email protected]
László Szerb*
University of Pécs
Faculty of Business and Economics
Pécs, Rákóczi 80, H-7622, Hungary
E-mail:
[email protected]
Scott Jackson
United States Agency for International Development
Bureau of Energy, Education and the Environment (E3)
1300 Pennsylvania Avenue, Ronald Reagan Building
Washington, DC 20523
E-mail:
[email protected]
Abstract:
Since the 1990s, several new indices like the Index of Economic Freedom, Doing Business, Global
Competitiveness Index, have been created to achieving real progress in modernizing the business climates
of developed and developing countries alike. This enables the use of economic reform and a friendly
competition between governments in order to begin laying the foundations for meaningful poverty relief for
billions and by attracting commercial development. These indicators however are focused largely on
ameliorating burdens for current business, addressing issues with property rights, processes, etc. While
necessary conditions, in the public effort to improve the economic incentives and create employment, they
remain insufficient to foster the economic font of development: entrepreneurship. It has to be clear that
entrepreneurship, and entrepreneurship policy is not merely about small business, or even at times about
business at all, but about creating environments where people are able to perceive entrepreneurial
opportunities, opportunities to improve their lives and be empowered by the environment to act upon their
visions. While much has been written about the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor and increasingly about
the Global Entrepreneurship Development Index (GEDI), this paper represents the first attempt to examine
private enterprise development in Africa through the lens of the GEDI. It will explore the extant data for
African countries, postulate their meaning from a continental or trading block perspective, and suggest
how they might be used from the perspective of an individual country with brief examples.
*Acknowledgement: Financial support has been provided to László Szerb by OTKA
Research foundation, theme number K 81527.
The opinions expressed herein are those of the authors and do not represent those of the
United States Agency for International Development.
2 TYPE THE DOCUMENT TITLE
1. Intro
In 2002, the World Bank developed and launched the now famous Doing Business
indicators (World Bank 2012). While the technical merits of the indicators have been
debated for over a decade (Fauvarque-Cosson and Kerhuel (2009); Michaels (2009);
Kaufmann and Kraay (2008), the index has proven to be an invaluable tool in aiding
those attempting to achieving real progress in modernizing the business climates of
developed and developing countries alike.
When combined with other indices and
measurements such as the Heritage Foundation’s Index of Economic Freedom,
development professionals and policy makers have concrete goalposts to enable the
creation of tools aimed at improving the overall business climates in countries around the
globe. This enables the use of economic reform and a friendly competition between
governments in order to begin laying the foundations for meaningful poverty relief for
billions and by attracting commercial development.
These indicators however are
focused largely on ameliorating burdens for current business, addressing issues with
property rights, processes, etc.
While necessary conditions, in the public effort to
improve the economic incentives and create employment, they remain insufficient to
foster the economic font of development: entrepreneurship.
Entrepreneurship is a multifaceted phenomenon, which has been studied in disciplines
including psychology, sociology, anthropology, economic development, geography and
economics. Within economics it has a long history including the works of Richard
Cantillon, Jean-Baptiste Say, Adam Smith as well as a long lineage of Austrian
economists because of their focus on methodological individualism. It has in recent years
experienced a resurgence based in no small part on the awareness of the work of Joseph
Schumpeter (1934, 1942), but this does not equate with being a discipline whose roots
extend from the period following the second world war (Naudé 2010). It is, however,
curiously missing from the work of giants such as J.M. Keynes, whose work was the
parent of development economics, and for largely practical reasons “for many years, the
entrepreneur was largely an implied element in economic theory and empirical research
(Baumol, 1968, 1993, Minniti 2004; Jackson 2010). It is therefore not overly surprising
that the entrepreneur might be overlooked in development economics given its post3
WWII genesis and the prevailing thinking of that time which has been described as
following “the Newtonian paradigm of an ever-equilibrating economy” (Witt 2002, p.7)
instead of a more dynamic conceptualization of economies as complex, adaptive systems
with characteristics more akin to ecologies than machines. The function of
entrepreneurship has been described as that of converting innovation into economic
goods (Audretsch, et. als. 2002), and ranges in scale from a more process oriented
Kirznerian to the more transformative Schumpeterian, “creative destruction” forms.
Naudé (2010, 2011) has pointed out precisely that entrepreneurship as defined by the
rather atomistic types of small business ownership commonly found informal in
developing countries is not a binding constraint to growth. We would agree, and in fact,
this definition of entrepreneurship is both too narrow and empirically unimportant in part
because it does not differentiate conceptually between the entrepreneur and the small
business owner (Carland, et. al. 1984) and secondly because it does not provide room for
social entrepreneurship. A focus on both the management literature alone and regression
analysis betrays a poor grasp of the entrepreneurship literature over-emphasizing what
Shane (1996) calls "the rates school". It is important to note that whether something is
significant in a regression should not be confused with whether it is significant in
practice. As Minniti (2004, 2005) points out, entrepreneurship is a path dependent, nonergodic process whose significance is unknowable in the present period and whose
occurrence is plagued by simultaneity problems.
Thus, there are elements in
entrepreneurship that occur in the here and now such as the using/freeing up of resources
in the economic milieu, but the economic significance of an entrepreneurial act may not
be borne out until much later. An example of this was the march from obscurity to its
position of global leadership by Microsoft beginning in 1975 until the present. No one
save possibly Bill Gates and Paul Allen would have envisioned in 1975 that Microsoft
would one day employ 90,000 people in 105 countries, and no regression analysis would
have found the firm to be statistically significant prior to its alliance with IBM in 1978.
Idiosyncratic events like an entrepreneurial decision are neither random nor probabilistic
but are sandwiched in an economic environment or milieu. This does not diminish the
4 TYPE THE DOCUMENT TITLE
significance of the event or the milieu, it merely points out that nothing happens in a
vacuum and illustrates a very important point about both entrepreneurship and
development. The milieu does not create the event, but it can support, ignore or suppress
it. (Baumol 1990) No serious scholar of entrepreneurship doubts the importance of
institutions in everything from the availability of knowledge, the rule of law to the ability
of the entrepreneur to act upon their intuition in a productive and legal manner. Instead
entrepreneurship is about the actors, and actors are as important to development as are
institutions. (Eggertsson 2005) We simply offer here a tool to help focus the activities of
the developer with respect to fostering an environment for positive entrepreneurship
which will also benefit other areas within the economic environment.
While it is important not to romanticize “penniless entrepreneurs”, (Naude 2010;
Banergee and Duflo 2007), it is an equal risk of ignoring, marginalizing and dismissing
them as unimportant. You forget that “when you hold the world in your palm and inspect
it only from a bird’s eye view, you tend to become arrogant – you do not realize that
things get blurred when seen from an enormous distance.”(Yunis and Jolis 1999, p., ix)
Being so blinded you might ignore the conditions which lead someone like Mouhamed
Bouazizi, a poor penniless entrepreneur, to take the steps he did, because in the moment
he set himself ablaze he was an entrepreneur, marshalling the emotions of millions of his
kinsmen across the Arab world and simultaneously set that world on fire.
We therefore contend that entrepreneurship is not merely about commercial activities but
also includes social phenomenon (Austin, Stevenson and Wei-Skillern 2006). In one
sense, the development of Facebook illustrates both of these facets well (Mezrich 2009).
Facebook was a novel technological form representing a tremendous commercial
opportunity to its founders evolving from a small, localized college based program run by
a lone college student to a global social network phenomenon employing hundreds of
staff in a few short years. At the same time, the social networking that Facebook enabled
has resulted in at times tremendous political upheaval and meaningful social change as
evidenced by the events of the spring of 2011 (CFR 2011). From this it must be clear
that entrepreneurship, and entrepreneurship policy is not merely about small business, or
5
even at times about business at all, but about creating environments where people are
able to perceive entrepreneurial opportunities, opportunities to improve their lives and be
empowered by the environment to act upon their visions. While much has been written
about the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor and increasingly about the Global
Entrepreneurship Development Index (GEDI), this paper represents the first attempt to
examine private enterprise development in Africa through the lens of the GEDI. It will
explore the extant data for African countries, postulate their meaning from a continental
or trading block perspective, and suggest how they might be used from the perspective of
an individual country with brief examples.
2. Methodology
While a universally accepted definition of entrepreneurship does not exist, most scientists
agree that entrepreneurship is a multifaceted or complex phenomenon (Fortunato and
Adles 2011, Acs and Audretsh 2010). Guided by this consensus and drawn from the
arguments about the definition, the measurement, and the support of entrepreneurship,
Acs and Szerb (2011, 2012) and Acs et al (2013) developed the Global Entrepreneurship
and Development Index (GEDI). The GEDI methodology is predicated on
entrepreneurship as a complex, multifaceted phenomenon, and thus, holds that the proper
measure of entrepreneurship should be a complex, composite index incorporating the
quality aspects of entrepreneurship. The GEDI views country level entrepreneurship from
a system perspective involving both the individual and the institutional sides. Formally
we define country-level entrepreneurship as “…the dynamic, institutionally embedded
interaction between entrepreneurial attitudes, entrepreneurial abilities, and entrepreneurial
aspirations by individuals, which drives the allocation of resources through the creation
and operation of new ventures.” (Acs et al 2012 p. 11) It endeavors to capture the
complex social interaction between the entrepreneurial skills and aspirations of the
individual entrepreneur and the social milieu in which entrepreneurial activity transpires.
Like other composite indexes the GEDI has a multilevel structure consisting of (1)
variables, (2) pillars, (3) sub-indices, and, finally, (4) the super-index. All three subindices contain many pillars which can be interpreted as quasi-independent building
6 TYPE THE DOCUMENT TITLE
blocks of this entrepreneurship index. The three sub-indices of attitudes, abilities, and
aspiration constitute the entrepreneurship super-index, which we call the Global
Entrepreneurship and Development Index.
While the abilities and aspiration sub-indices (outlined below) capture actual
entrepreneurship abilities and aspiration as they relate to nascent and startup business
activities, the entrepreneurial attitude (ATT) sub-index aims to identify the attitudes of a
country’s population as they relate to entrepreneurship. For example, the pillar known as
opportunity perception potential is essential to recognizing and exploring novel business
opportunities. It is also critical to have the proper startup skills and personal networks to
exploit these opportunities. Moreover, fear of failure to start a business can have a
negative effect on entrepreneurial attitudes, even when opportunity recognition and
startup skills exist. Entrepreneurial attitudes are believed to be influenced by the crucial
institutional factors of market size, level of education, the level of risk in a country, the
population’s access to information as measured by the population’s rate of internet use,
and culture, all of which are interaction variables of the indicator.
The entrepreneurial abilities (ABT) sub-index is principally concerned with measuring
some important characteristics of the entrepreneur and the startup with high growth
potential. This high growth potential is approached by quality measures, including
opportunity motivation for startups that belong to a technology-intensive sector, the
entrepreneur’s level of education, and the level of competition. The country level
institutional variables include the freedom to do business, the technology adsorption
capability, the extent of staff training, and the dominance of powerful business groups.
7
GLOBAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND DEVELOPMENT INDEX
Entrepreneurial
Attitudes
Entrepreneurial
Abilities
Entrepreneurial
Aspirations
Sub-Index
Sub-Index
Sub-Index
Pillars
Risk Capital
Internationalization
High Growth
Process Innovation
Product Innovation
Competition
Informal Investment
Depth of capital market
Export
Globalization
Gazelle
Business Strategy
New Tech
GERD
New Product
Technology Transfer
Competitors
Market Dominance
Educational Level
Staff Training
Technology Level
Tech Absorption
Opportunity Motivation
Economic Freedom
Career Status
Corruption
Know Entrepreneurs
Internet Usage
Risk Acceptance
Business Risk
Skill Perception
Tertiary Education
Opportunity Recognition
Market Agglomeration
8 TYPE THE DOCUMENT TITLE
Quality of Human
Resources
Tech Sector
Opportunity Startup
Cultural Support
Networking
Non-fear of Failure
Start-up Skills
Opportunity
Perception
Variables
Source: Acs et al 2013 p.217
Figure I. The structure of the Global Entrepreneurship and Development Index
Table 1. The description of the GEDI index pillars
Pillar name
Opportunity
Perception
Start-up Skills
Non-fear of Failure
Networking
Cultural Support
Opportunity Startup
Tech Sector
Quality of Human
Resources
Competition
Product Innovation
Process Innovation
High Growth
9
Description
Opportunity Perception refers to the entrepreneurial opportunity
perception potential of the population weighted with the size and the level
of agglomeration of that country reflecting the potential size of the
market.
Start-up Skill captures the perception of start-up skills in the population
and weights this aspect with the quality of human resources available for
entrepreneurial processes in the country.
Non-fear of Failure captures the inhibiting effect of fear of failure of the
population on entrepreneurial action combined with a measure of the
country’s business risk.
This pillar combines two aspects of Networking: (1) a proxy of the
ability of potential and active entrepreneurs to access and mobilize
opportunities and resources and (2) the possible use of the internet.
The Cultural Support pillar combines how positively a given country’s
inhabitants view entrepreneurs in terms of status and career choice and
how the level of corruption in that country affects this view.
The Opportunity Startup pillar captures the prevalence of individuals who
pursue potentially better quality opportunity-driven start-ups (as opposed
to necessity-driven start-ups) and weights this against regulatory
constraints.
The Technology Sector pillar reflects the technology-intensity of a
country’s start-up activity combined with a country’s capacity for firmlevel technology absorption.
The Quality of Human Resources pillar captures the quality of
entrepreneurs as weighing the percentage of start-ups founded by
individuals with higher than secondary education with a qualitative
measure of the propensity of firms in a given country to train their staff.
The Competition pillar measures the level of the product or market
uniqueness of start-ups combined with the market power of existing
businesses and business groups.
The Product Innovation pillar captures the tendency of entrepreneurial
firms to create new products. This pillar was created by weighting the
percentage of firms that offer products that are new to at least some of
their customers with a complex measure of innovation.
The Process Innovation pillar captures the use of new technologies by
start-ups combined with the Gross Domestic Expenditure on Research
and Development (GERD). GERD serves as measurement of the
systematic research activity as opposed to easy to copy technological
improvements.
The High Growth pillar is a combined measure of (1) the percentage of
high-growth businesses that intend to employ at least ten people and plan
to grow more than 50 percent in five years and (2) business strategy
sophistication.
Internationalization
Risk Capital
The Internationalization pillar captures the degree to which a country’s
entrepreneurs are internationalized, as measured by businesses’ exporting
potential weighted by the level of economic globalization of the country.
The Risk Capital pillar combines two measures of finance: informal
investment in start-ups and a measure of the depth of capital market.
Availability of risk capital is to fulfill growth aspirations.
Source: Adopted from Autio et al (2012) pp. 29-30
The entrepreneurial aspiration (ASP) sub-index refers to the distinctive, qualitative, strategyrelated nature of entrepreneurial activity. Entrepreneurial businesses are different from regularly
managed businesses, thus it is particularly important to be able to identify the most relevant
institutional and other quality-related interaction variables. The newness of a product and of a
technology, internationalization, high growth ambitions, and informal finance variables are
included in this sub-index. The institutional variables measure the technology transfer and R&D
potential, the sophistication of a business strategy, the level of globalization, and the depth of
capital market.1
There are two methodological novelties in the calculation of the GEDI points. First, GEDI is
created for public policy use. Viewing the fourteen pillars of entrepreneurship it means that the
marginal improvement of the pillar values should be the same for all the pillars. However, the
pillar averages are quiet different ranging from 0.31 (Risk capital) to 0.67 (Opportunity
perception). It means that reaching the same value in Risk capital as compared to Opportunity
perception requires more than two times more effort and probably resources. For equating the
marginal effects we need a transformation to equate the average values of the fourteen pillars.
Equation 1 shows the calculation of the average value of a pillar
n
x
x
i 1
n
i
.
(1)
We want to transform the xi values such that the potential minimum value is 0 and the maximum
value is 1:
1
This description of the index structure is based on Acs et al 2013, Chapter 6.
10 TYPE THE DOCUMENT TITLE
0
yi
n k ny
1 1 xi
n k nx
if xi 0
otherwise
(2)
where k denotes the number of countries with the minimal original value. The yi transformed
values meet with the required assumptions, but they cannot exceed 1. It means that y 1
k
.
n
Another unique feature of the GEDI approach is the systemic view of entrepreneurship. The
Penalty for Bottleneck (PFB) methodology has been developed to quantify the interaction effect
of the 14 pillars of entrepreneurship. According to the PFB the entrepreneurial performance of a
particular country is more dependent on the harmonization of the pillars than it is of the strength
of any individual pillar. Consequently, the optimal entrepreneurial performance can be reached
by equalizing the normalized values of the 14 pillars. The most important feature of the PFB
methodology is the assumption that the performance of the system is determined by the lowest
performing or lowest-value pillar which constitutes a bottleneck and thereby limits the output of
the system by constraining the performance of the other pillars. The imbalance prevents the full
realization of the capacity of the better performing pillars and the magnitude of the penalty is a
function of the magnitude of the bottleneck: The larger the difference between a particular pillar
and the bottleneck pillar the larger the penalty. By assuming a exponential penalty function the
penalized pillar values can be calculated in the following way:
(3)
where
is the modified, post-penalty value of pillar j in country i
is the normalized value of index component j in country i
is the lowest value of
for country i.
i = 1, 2,……n = the number of countries
j= 1, 2,.……m= the number of pillars
The calculation of the index values is as follows
11
1. We start with the variables that come directly from the original data sources for each country
involved in the analysis. The variables can be at the individual level (personal or business) or
the institutional/environmental level (Appendix 1 and 2).
2. We calculate all pillars from the variables using the interaction variable method; that is, by
multiplying the individual variable with the proper institutional variable.
3. The 14 pillar values are normalized. to a range from 0 to 1:
(4)
for all j= 1 ... k, the number of pillars
where
is the normalized score value for country i and pillar j
is the original pillar value for country i and pillar j
is the maximum value for pillar j
4. All index building is based on a benchmarking principle. In our case we selected the 95
percentile score adjustment meaning that any observed values higher than the 95 percentile is
lowered to the 95 percentile. For this calculation we included all the 355 observation units over
the 2006-2012 time period.
5. We make the average pillar adjustment according to equations 1 and 2.
6. The PFB is applied to get the PFB adjusted values for all of the 14 pillars (equation 3).
7. The indicators are the basic building blocks of the sub-index: entrepreneurial attitudes,
entrepreneurial abilities, and entrepreneurial aspirations. The value of a sub-index for any country
is the arithmetic average of its PFB-adjusted pillars multiplied by 100. The maximum value of
the sub-indices is 100 and the potential minimum is 0, both of which reflect the relative position
of a country in a particular sub-index.
8. Finally, the super-index, the Global Entrepreneurship and Development Index, is simply the
average of the three sub-indices.
It is also possible to calculate a summary measure of the unbalance. The Average Bottleneck
Efficiency (ABE) is defined as how close a country’s pillars are to its best performing pillar
12 TYPE THE DOCUMENT TITLE
score, on average. ABE is expressed in terms of percentages. Higher ABE values imply more
balanced performance and therefore more efficient use of the available resources while lower
ABE values mean substantial imbalances over the fourteen pillars of the GEDI. 2 Equation 5
describes the calculation of ABE:
Equations 5a and 5b technically describe the general form of the calculation:
(5a)
(5b)
for all j, the number of pillars
where ABGi is the Average Bottleneck Gap for country i
where ABEi is the Average Bottleneck Efficiency for country i
There are some important policy related consequences of the PFB methodology. First, the
different pillars cannot be fully substituted with each other. In other words, the performance of
the better performing pillar may only partially compensate for the performance of the bottleneck
pillar. Second, the whole GEDI index score can be improved the most by increasing the score of
the bottleneck pillar. The magnitude of the enhancement depends on the relative size of the
bottleneck as compared to the other pillars. Third, for policy makers it means that the
enhancement of the worst performing bottleneck pillar is the most important priority for
entrepreneurship policy.3
3. Data and tables
Data description
As mentioned previously, individual variables are based on the GEM Adult Population Survey
dataset. Of the 120 countries, 87 participated in the survey in the 2006-2012 time period. Out of
2
Average Bottleneck Efficiency appears as Average Bottleneck Gap in the GEDI United Kingdom 2012 report
(Autio et al 2012). However, it is more appropriate to call it efficiency then gap measure because the higher ABE
value is associated with better performance not with higher lag.
3
For more information about the methodology see Acs et al (2013).
13
these 87 countries they were fourteen African countries. If data were available both in 2011 and
2012 we calculated the individual variable values by averaging these two years data. In Africa,
there was only three such countries, Algeria, Nigeria and South Africa. In all the other cases, we
used a single year individual data. For the details view Table 2. The distribution of the sample by
African countries and the calculation of the individual variables.4
In total 33 - out of these 19 African - countries’, individual variables are estimated by using
similar or nearby country data. Since the availability of the institutional data also limited the
selection of the countries, we could involve only those nations that participated in the World
Economic Forum 2011-2012 or 2012-2013 Global Competitiveness Report (GCR) survey. 24 of
these 142 GCR countries were left out because the lack of similar or nearby GEM countries. The
size of the sample in different years, the participating African countries and the calculation of the
individual variables, including the 19 non GEM countries, are also reported in Table 2. The
distribution of the sample by African countries and the calculation of the individual variables
Table 2. The distribution of the sample by African countries and the calculation of the
individual variables
Country/year
Algeria
Angola
Benin
Botswana
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cameroon
Chad
Côte d’Ivoire
Egypt
Ethiopia
Gabon
Gambia
Ghana
Kenya
Liberia
4
2009
2011
3373
2012
4984
2489
2003
2501
3003
2213
Individual variable way of calculation
Average of 2011-2012
2012 data
Average of Nigeria, Ghana and Malawi
2012 data
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
Average of Nigeria and Ghana and Malawi
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
2012 data
2012 data
Average of Namibia and Botswana
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
2012 data
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
For the description of the full dataset see Acs et al (2013).
14 TYPE THE DOCUMENT TITLE
Madagascar
Malawi
Mali
Mauritania
Morocco
Mozambique
Namibia
Nigeria
Rwanda
Senegal
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Swaziland
Tanzania
Tunisia
Uganda
Zambia
Sum
1847
1500
1500
2056
1959
2651
2724
2655
8153
2000
2343
2155
32803
Average of Ghana Uganda and Zambia
2012 data
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
2009 data
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
2012 data
Average of 2011-2012
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
Average of 2011-2012
Average of Namibia and Angola
Average of Ghana Uganda and Malawi
2012 data
2012 data
2012 data
42456
While it seems peculiar to investigate so many countries with estimated individual data, we
believe the validity of our approach and analysis because of three reasons. First, many African
countries are similar to one another in many respects that could imply similarities in individual
entrepreneurial performances. Second, we do have the institutional data for all the involved 33
African countries. As we know from previous analyses that institutional variables are the major
determinants of the pillar scores, the sub-index values and the GEDI points missing individual
data may seems to be less problematic than the lack of institutional data (Acs et al 2013). Since
data about the African continent countries are limited we think that a partially limited analysis
still can provide useful results as compared to a situation of completely missing analysis.
Table 3. The Global Entrepreneurship and Development Index Rank of the Countries, 2011
GEDI
ranking
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
15
Country
United States
Denmark
Australia
Sweden
Taiwan
France
United Kingdom
Switzerland
Netherlands
Per
capita
GEDI
GDP
GEDI
ranking Country
42486
79.4
61 Macedonia
32582
77.1
62 Mexico
34396
74.3
63 Jordan
35170
71.5
64 Serbia
68.4
65 Botswana
29819
68.2
66 Albania
32863
67.8
67 Namibia
39412
67.3
68 Panama
37112
66.1
69 Thailand
Per
capita
GDP
GEDI
9451
38.0
12814
37.9
5268
36.2
9830
35.6
13021
35.4
7861
35.3
5986
34.5
13766
34.4
7635
34.2
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
Iceland
Finland
Singapore
Norway
Belgium
Germany
Chile
Ireland
Austria
Puerto Rico
Israel
Estonia
Qatar
Slovenia
Korea
Oman
33516
32027
53591
46982
33127
34603
15251
36145
36139
17300
26720
18129
77987
24967
27541
25330
66.0
65.7
65.1
65.1
64.1
63.1
62.5
61.6
61.5
59.4
58.0
57.8
53.1
52.8
52.2
51.2
70
71
72
73
74
75
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
85
26
27
28
29
30
31
Saudi Arabia
Bahrain
Poland
Colombia
Lithuania
Turkey
United Arab
Emirates11
Latvia
Kuwait
Spain
Japan
Hong Kong
Czech Republic
Slovakia
Portugal
Bulgaria
Romania
Uruguay
Hungary
Malaysia
Lebanon
Peru
Croatia
Italy
Cyprus
Barbados
Montenegro
South Africa
Greece
China
Tunisia
Dominican
Republic09
21430
18087
8860
16877
13468
51.1
50.7
50.5
50.0
49.9
49.7
86
87
88
89
90
91
42293
13773
47935
26917
30660
44640
24011
20757
21304
11793
10905
13315
17295
14174
12900
9037
15954
27072
26046
16148
10469
9678
22301
7418
8258
48.7
48.7
48.5
47.8
47.7
47.0
46.9
46.8
46.4
46.1
45.7
45.1
44.8
43.3
42.6
42.4
41.5
41.3
41.2
40.7
40.7
39.6
39.5
39.5
39.2
92
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
100
101
102
103
104
105
106
107
108
109
110
111
112
113
114
115
116
8651
39.0
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
16 TYPE THE DOCUMENT TITLE
Russia
Indonesia
Nigeria
Kazakhstan
Moldova
India
Trinidad & Tobago
Morocco
Jamaica
El Salvador
Ukraine
Gabon
Bolivia
Algeria
Egypt
Paraguay
Bosnia and
Herzegovina
Ecuador
Philippines
Brazil
Zambia
Angola
14821
4094
2237
11568
2975
3203
22142
4373
7839
6032
6365
13998
4503
7643
5547
4858
33.6
33.3
33.3
33.0
32.8
32.6
32.6
32.4
32.3
31.9
31.8
31.8
31.6
31.3
30.8
30.7
7607
7655
3638
10279
1431
5227
30.4
29.7
29.6
29.6
28.9
28.0
Venezuela
Swaziland
Iran
Ghana
Cameroon
Benin
Honduras
Senegal
Liberia
Pakistan
Kenya
Nicaragua
Guatemala
Tanzania
Gambia
Rwanda
Mozambique
Côte d’Ivoire
Malawi
Ethiopia
Madagascar
Burkina Faso
Mali
Mauritania
Uganda
11258
5349
6360
1652
2083
1428
3574
1737
517
2424
1510
3366
4351
1336
1597
1132
861
1580
789
979
853
1149
964
2255
1188
28.0
27.7
27.3
26.7
26.5
25.8
25.8
25.2
24.6
24.2
24.1
23.9
22.9
22.5
22.4
22.1
21.6
21.5
21.3
21.1
21.0
20.9
20.5
20.3
20.1
117 Sierra Leone
769
19.0
58 Argentina
59 Brunei Darussalam
60 Costa Rica
15501
45707
10735
38.9
38.5
38.0
118 Bangladesh
119 Burundi
120 Chad
Legend: African countries are highlighted in blue cells.
Per capita GDP is in 2005 constant price international $ purchasing power parity
17
1569
533
1343
18.6
17.0
16.5
Table 4 The normalized score values of the 14 pillars of entrepreneurship in the African
countries (After equalizing the pillar averages)
Country
Algeria*
Angola*
Benin
Botswana*
Burkina
Faso
Burundi
Cameroon
Chad
Côte
d’Ivoire
Egypt*
Ethiopia*
Gabon
Gambia
Ghana*
Kenya
Liberia
Madagascar
Malawi*
Mali
Mauritania
Morocco*
Mozambique
Namibia*
Nigeria*
Rwanda
Senegal
Sierra Leone
South
Africa*
Swaziland
Tanzania
Tunisia*
Uganda*
Zambia*
1
0.68
0.63
0.38
0.52
2
0.39
0.06
0.24
0.11
3
0.45
0.23
0.41
0.51
4
0.23
0.29
0.09
0.12
5
0.40
0.24
0.44
0.70
6
0.36
0.31
0.28
0.42
7
0.32
0.22
0.22
0.30
8
0.15
0.25
0.11
0.35
9
0.26
0.23
0.45
0.50
10
0.31
0.38
0.35
0.35
11
0.28
0.46
0.28
0.32
12
0.23
0.23
0.21
0.66
13
0.21
0.63
0.15
0.45
14
0.50
0.39
0.31
0.31
0.27
0.10
0.58
0.21
0.07
0.06
0.23
0.04
0.29
0.14
0.28
0.14
0.08
0.05
0.12
0.06
0.47
0.23
0.31
0.23
0.36
0.34
0.29
0.15
0.20
0.19
0.22
0.19
0.04
0.04
0.14
0.04
0.37
0.39
0.49
0.34
0.28
0.21
0.36
0.27
0.29
0.31
0.28
0.27
0.11
0.10
0.22
0.11
0.13
0.10
0.15
0.12
0.31
0.31
0.31
0.31
0.51
0.50
0.20
0.68
0.30
0.63
0.31
0.21
0.32
0.15
0.33
0.28
0.52
0.31
0.32
0.81
0.18
0.41
0.25
0.15
0.41
0.11
0.12
0.08
0.22
0.07
0.81
0.08
0.01
0.11
0.08
0.21
0.09
0.14
0.19
0.12
0.15
0.04
0.29
0.22
0.22
0.36
0.14
0.42
0.29
0.14
0.29
0.15
0.14
0.29
0.51
0.29
0.56
0.13
0.14
0.43
0.29
0.07
0.34
0.05
0.15
0.22
0.23
0.52
0.08
0.06
0.09
0.06
0.11
0.66
0.10
0.24
0.63
0.15
0.33
0.05
0.36
0.39
0.40
0.38
0.42
0.57
0.33
0.50
0.39
0.45
0.42
0.38
0.46
0.38
0.52
0.31
0.65
0.44
0.38
0.25
0.24
0.40
0.34
0.35
0.42
0.34
0.33
0.37
0.23
0.29
0.25
0.55
0.37
0.40
0.35
0.38
0.33
0.30
0.20
0.28
0.20
0.29
0.20
0.21
0.20
0.20
0.19
0.20
0.20
0.20
0.18
0.20
0.29
0.26
0.20
0.21
0.20
0.05
0.19
0.19
0.24
0.06
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.04
0.04
0.04
0.04
0.07
0.04
0.17
0.34
0.05
0.04
0.04
0.36
0.28
0.39
0.39
0.50
0.40
0.44
0.49
0.39
0.47
0.43
0.36
0.36
0.46
0.42
0.44
0.44
0.43
0.35
0.27
0.28
0.21
0.34
0.33
0.14
0.33
0.33
0.28
0.64
0.29
0.26
0.15
0.26
0.61
0.37
0.33
0.32
0.22
0.27
0.31
0.38
0.44
0.26
0.27
0.33
0.35
0.28
0.81
0.30
0.35
0.40
0.29
0.42
0.32
0.27
0.34
0.27
0.12
0.61
0.21
0.39
0.14
0.28
0.14
0.14
0.12
0.03
0.11
0.12
0.31
0.11
0.31
0.42
0.14
0.14
0.11
0.14
0.20
0.02
0.48
0.15
0.17
0.14
0.09
0.12
0.10
0.13
0.14
0.71
0.14
0.61
0.31
0.11
0.15
0.11
0.31
0.34
0.31
0.34
0.31
0.31
0.31
0.31
0.31
0.31
0.31
0.31
0.31
0.31
0.36
0.32
0.31
0.31
0.31
0.51
0.14
0.34
0.36
0.21
0.36
0.13
0.07
0.04
0.45
0.17
0.08
0.59
0.11
0.43
0.56
0.28
0.28
0.20
0.35
0.24
0.38
0.26
0.26
0.46
0.41
0.43
0.54
0.35
0.39
0.47
0.43
0.28
0.48
0.25
0.39
0.27
0.25
0.20
0.45
0.18
0.20
0.25
0.21
0.05
0.41
0.05
0.33
0.68
0.39
0.39
0.43
0.31
0.38
0.71
0.42
0.31
0.61
0.16
0.35
0.58
0.34
0.33
0.43
0.31
0.33
0.57
0.29
0.12
0.41
0.07
0.15
0.64
0.51
0.11
0.17
0.16
0.72
0.34
0.42
0.31
0.32
0.31
0.31
Legend: 1. Opportunity Perception (ATT), 2. Start-up Skills (ATT), 3. Nonfear of Failure (ATT), 4.
Networking (ATT), 5. Cultural Support (ATT), 6. Opportunity Startup (ABT),7. Tech Sector (ABT),8.
Quality of Human Resources (ABT), 9. Competition (ABT), 10. Product Innovation (ASP), 11. Process
Innovation (ASP), 12. High Growth (ASP), 13. Internationalization (ASP), 14. Risk Capital (ASP)
The colors demonstrate the relative position of the particular country with respect to the
representative pillar from the disadvantageous red position to the favorable green one. Here we
18 TYPE THE DOCUMENT TITLE
are dealing only with the African countries. In the colors we can begin to see the relative position
of countries with respect to their level of optimization across pillars.
Table 5. The worst three pillars of the GEDI index in the African countries
Countries
1st worst pillar
2nd worst pillar
Algeria
Angola
Quality of Human Resources
Startup Skills
Benin
Botswana
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Networking
Startup Skills
Quality of Human Resources
Quality of Human Resources
Cameroon
Chad
Côte d’Ivoire
Egypt
Ethiopia
Gabon
Gambia
Ghana
Networking
Quality of Human Resources
Quality of Human Resources
Quality of Human Resources
Internationalisation
Startup Skills
Quality of Human Resources
Quality of Human Resources
Kenya
Liberia
Madagascar
Malawi
Mali
Mauritania
Morocco
Mozambique
Quality of Human Resources
Quality of Human Resources
Quality of Human Resources
Startup Skills
Quality of Human Resources
Quality of Human Resources
Quality of Human Resources
Quality of Human Resources
Namibia
Nigeria
Rwanda
Startup Skills
Startup Skills
Quality of Human Resources
Senegal
Quality of Human Resources
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Swaziland
Startup Skills
Startup Skills
Startup Skills
Tanzania
Tunisia
Startup Skills
Internationalisation
High Growth
Quality of Human
Resources
Networking
Nonfear of Failure
Quality of Human
Resources
Risk Capital
Uganda
Zambia
Quality of Human Resources
Startup Skills
High Growth
High Growth
19
Internationalisation
Tech Sector
Quality of Human
Resources
Networking
Startup Skills
Networking
Quality of Human
Resources
Startup Skills
Networking
Internationalisation
Networking
Networking
Startup Skills
Product Innovation
Startup Skills
Networking
Networking
High Growth
Networking
Startup Skills
Product Innovation
Startup Skills
Quality of Human
Resources
Nonfear of Failure
Startup Skills
3rd worst pillar
Networking
Competition/High Growth
Internationalisation
Tech Sector
Networking
Startup Skills
Internationalisation
Networking
High Growth
Nonfear of Failure
Startup Skills
Quality of Human Resources
High growth/Nonfear of Failure
Internationalisation
High
growth/Internationalisation
Internationalisation
Startup Skills
Quality of Human Resources
Startup Skills/High growth
Networking
Startup Skills
Networking
Networking
Cultural Support
Internationalisation
Startup
Skills/Internationalization
Networking
Quality of Human Resources
Opportunity Perception
Internationalisation
Opportunity Perception
Product
Innovation/Internationalisatio
n
Tech Sector
Table 6. The Average Bottleneck Efficiency values for the African countries (ABE values are in
percentages)
Country
Algeria
Angola
Benin
Botswana
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cameroon
Chad
Côte d’Ivoire
Egyipt
Ethiopia
ABE
46.2
47.7
58.9
54.0
45.9
43.3
45.5
48.7
42.6
50.1
55.3
Country
ABE
Gabon
48.3
Gambia
45.0
Ghana
45.4
Kenya
48.9
Liberia
30.5
Madagascar
55.6
Malawi
27.3
Mali
48.7
Mauritania
56.0
Morocco
50.9
Mozambique
48.8
Country
Namibia
Nigeria
Rwanda
Senegal
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Swaziland
Tanzania
Tunisia
Uganda
Zambia
ABE
59.9
41.6
33.4
62.4
51.3
62.2
58.2
56.1
67.5
59.7
40.6
As noted earlier, the average bottleneck efficiency speaks to the relative skew of the
entrepreneurship policies with the higher values corresponding to the more efficiently aligned
policy environments.
Table 7. GEDI Countries by Regional Trade Groupings
Country
WAMZ UEMOA
Algeria
Angola
X
Benin
Botswana
X
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cameroon
Chad
DR Congo
X
Côte d’Ivoire
Egypt
Ethiopia
X
Gambia
X
Ghana
Kenya
Madagascar
Malawi
X
Mali
Mauritania
Mauritius
Morocco
Mozambique
20 TYPE THE DOCUMENT TITLE
SADC
COMESA
X
X
EAC
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
Namibia
Nigeria
Rwanda
Senegal
South Africa
Swaziland
Tanzania
Tunisia
Uganda
Zambia
Zimbabwe
21
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
Table 8. Simulation of ’optimal’ policy allocation to increase the GEDI score by 5 in the African countries
Algeria
Angola
Benin
Botswana
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cameroon
Chad
Côte d’Ivoire
Egypt
Ethiopia
Gabon
Gambia
Ghana
Kenya
Liberia
Madagascar
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
1
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0.06
11%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
2
0
0%
0.19
61%
0.01
2%
0.16
52%
0.11
23%
0.1
18%
0.04
8%
0.13
23%
0.05
11%
0
0%
0.09
21%
0.18
47%
0.13
28%
0
0%
0.13
33%
0
0%
0.1
3
0
0%
0.02
6%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0.02
4%
0
0%
0.03
5%
0
0%
0.09
17%
0
0%
0
0%
0.06
13%
0
0%
0
0%
0.04
10%
0
4
0.07
15%
0
0%
0.15
33%
0.15
48%
0.1
21%
0.11
20%
0.14
27%
0.11
20%
0.13
28%
0
0%
0.15
35%
0.15
39%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0.1
24%
0.12
22 TYPE THE DOCUMENT TITLE
5
0
0%
0.01
3%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
6
7
8
0
0 0.15
0% 0% 33%
0 0.03
0
0% 10% 0%
0 0.03 0.13
0% 7% 28%
0
0
0
0% 0% 0%
0
0 0.14
0% 0% 30%
0
0 0.13
0% 0% 24%
0 0.05 0.13
0% 10% 25%
0.03
0 0.13
5% 0% 23%
0
0 0.15
0% 0% 32%
0.08 0.03 0.13
15% 6% 24%
0
0 0.01
0% 0% 2%
0
0 0.05
0% 0% 13%
0
0 0.15
0% 0% 33%
0 0.02 0.17
0% 6% 53%
0
0 0.15
0% 0% 38%
0
0 0.14
0% 0% 33%
0
0 0.14
9
10
0.05
0
11% 0%
0.03
0
10% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0.04 0.04
7% 7%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0 0.08
0% 25%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
11
0.03
7%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0.01
2%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
12
0.07
15%
0.03
10%
0.04
9%
0
0%
0.07
15%
0.07
13%
0.04
8%
0.07
13%
0.08
17%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0.06
13%
0
0%
0.06
15%
0.05
12%
0.06
13
0.09
20%
0
0%
0.1
22%
0
0%
0.05
11%
0.06
11%
0.11
22%
0.06
11%
0.06
13%
0.12
22%
0.18
42%
0
0%
0.06
13%
0.05
16%
0.06
15%
0.09
21%
0.06
14
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
Total
effort
0.46
9.64%
0.31
6.81%
0.46
11.70%
0.31
5.50%
0.47
14.44%
0.55
21.50%
0.51
12.82%
0.56
22.53%
0.47
14.09%
0.54
11.77%
0.43
13.08%
0.38
7.71%
0.46
13.34%
0.32
7.40%
0.4
10.53%
0.42
10.42%
0.48
Malawi
Mali
Mauritania
Morocco
Mozambique
Namibia
Nigeria
Rwanda
Senegal
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Swaziland
Tanzania
Tunisia
Uganda
Zambia
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0.01
2%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0.09
23%
0
0%
0.02
7%
0.01
2%
0
0%
21%
0.13
30%
0.07
14%
0.11
23%
0.01
4%
0.1
22%
0.16
43%
0.12
32%
0.07
15%
0.06
17%
0.14
27%
0.15
54%
0.16
41%
0.15
35%
0
0%
0.04
8%
0.18
51%
0%
0
0%
0.04
8%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0.19
51%
0.05
11%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0.12
31%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
25%
0.05
11%
0.12
24%
0.09
19%
0
0%
0.08
17%
0.07
19%
0
0%
0.04
9%
0
0%
0.12
24%
0.08
29%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0% 0% 29%
0
0 0.1
0% 0% 23%
0
0 0.14
0% 0% 29%
0
0 0.15
0% 0% 32%
0 0.05 0.15
0% 18% 54%
0
0 0.15
0% 0% 33%
0 0.01 0.13
0% 3% 35%
0 0.05
0
0% 14% 0%
0
0 0.15
0% 0% 33%
0
0 0.17
0% 0% 49%
0
0 0.13
0% 0% 25%
0 0.02 0.03
0% 7% 11%
0
0 0.02
0% 0% 5%
0
0 0.14
0% 0% 33%
0
0
0
0% 0% 0%
0 0.03 0.16
0% 6% 33%
0 0.06
0
0% 17% 0%
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0 0.07
0% 25%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0
0
0% 0%
0 0.06
0% 12%
0
0
0% 0%
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
13%
0.12
27%
0.07
14%
0.07
15%
0
0%
0.08
17%
0
0%
0
0%
0.06
13%
0.07
20%
0.06
12%
0
0%
0
0%
0.06
14%
0
0%
0.14
29%
0.11
31%
13% 0% 14.83%
0.04
0
0.44
9% 0% 12.01%
0.05
0
0.49
10% 0% 15.44%
0.05
0
0.47
11% 0% 14.89%
0
0
0.28
0% 0% 5.18%
0.05
0
0.46
11% 0% 13.74%
0
0
0.37
0% 0% 6.89%
0.01
0
0.37
3% 0% 7.12%
0.08
0
0.46
17% 0% 13.22%
0.05
0
0.35
14% 0% 8.68%
0.06
0
0.51
12% 0% 17.45%
0
0
0.28
0% 0% 4.37%
0
0
0.39
0% 0% 9.00%
0.08
0
0.43
19% 0% 12.04%
0.21 0.07
0.3
70% 23% 5.02%
0.05
0
0.49
10% 0% 15.94%
0
0
0.35
0% 0% 7.72%
Legend: A = required increase in pillar; B = percentage of total effort. 1. Opportunity Perception (ATT), 2. Start-up Skills (ATT), 3. Non-fear of Failure (ATT),
4. Networking (ATT), 5. Cultural Support (ATT), 6. Opportunity Startup (ABT),7. Tech Sector (ABT),8. Quality of Human Resources (ABT), 9. Competition
(ABT), 10. Product Innovation (ASP), 11. Process Innovation (ASP), 12. High Growth (ASP), 13. Internationalization (ASP), 14. Risk Capital (ASP)
23
4. What does this mean for Africa …
Before we launch into a discussion of the situation in Africa it is important to
remember that Africa is not a country. This may seem obvious, but sometimes in the
political dialogue of the day there is a tendency to over-aggregate and generalize
about a continent which houses no less than 2,110 (30.5%) of the world’s living
languages (ethnologue 2012) and ethnic groups and countries whose borders were
defined to varying degrees arbitrarily by foreign powers without consideration for
local institutions.
Nearly all of these countries achieved their independence to
varying degrees between the 1960s and 1980s. If complex problems are like peeling
an onion, with layers of subtleties, then discussing Africa is more like separating the
seeds in a pomegranate with hundreds of compartmentalized variations.
Probably the most enduring colonial legacy for Africa however is not the centuries of
war, forced deportation, subjugation, etc., but the legal regimes established by the
colonial powers, primarily with the purpose of extracting resources for a
diminishingly small group of elites. (Eggertson 2005) Regimes designed thusly are
easily captured by political parties, revolutionaries or by more enterprising groups of
armed men intent on extracting the wealth for a much more narrow set of benefits
than the greater public good (Marques 2011).
An example of this is how the influence of the second Portuguese republic’s policies
related to entrepreneurship, may have lead to the creation of systems of business
policy in the modern African states which were under Portuguese colonial rule.
Recognizing that entrepreneurship may in fact lead to alternate sources of wealth and
thus alternate sources of power, some southern Europe states have been particularly
suspicion of entrepreneurial activity, and thus, endeavored to limit it. (Malefakis
1995) An example of this was the industrial regulation law of the second Portuguese
republic which required any project designed to improve productivity or the transfer
of industrial license or sale of a business to a foreign entity be approved by the
government in advance. Redford (2012) The Portugal of the second republic is the
24
Portugal that these African states were most recently familiar with. Today, according
to the 2012 Doing Business Indicators, these four states have some of the worst
business rankings in the world with Cape Verde ranked the highest at (119), followed
by Mozambique (139), Angola (172) and Guinea-Bissau (176) out of 184 countries
reported.
In recent years, Africa has seemed to be on the mend. Several of Africa’s countries
have achieved substantial economic growth rates, and some, like Mozambique and
Angola have been identified as rising economic stars (Economist 2012). Given this
up and coming status, one could reasonably begin to ask, what can we say, continent
wide about Africa with respect to a culture of entrepreneurship? In a continent where
the vast majority of the economic activities of the countries are housed in the informal
sectors, where bone grinding poverty is the reality for the vast majority of the
continents population and where political stability seems more often a myth than a
reality, what can we say about entrepreneurship policy to the extent that it is entirely
different than business or even small enterprise policy, and what insights does the
GEDI provide?
One approach might be to explore what insights are there from the GEDI and PFB approach for factor driven
economies? These are economies where efficiency in basic factor production remains a challenge and where
process innovation is crucial to their intermediate and long term success. In addition, Africa in one manner of
speaking must compete with other developing regions in its efforts to assemble its talent and resources efficiently
to create the entrepreneurship necessary to pull it into the 21 st century.
Figure II. Relative Efficiency of Entrepreneurship Pillars in Factor Driven Economies (normalized
scores) helps to illustrate visually what the ABE metric is capturing: how far out of alignment the
entrepreneurship production process is in the factor driven economies. At present, most of the African
economies except Angola, Morocco, Namibia, South Africa, Swaziland and Tunisia are treated as factor driven
economies as they are thought to have entrepreneurial framework conditions where economic development is
driven primarily by basic requirements like institutional development, basic infrastructure, macroeconomic
stability, health and primary education. The approach of the PFB methodology is to suggest that the
appropriate approach to policy is to focus on “rounding the circle” in
Figure II. Relative Efficiency of Entrepreneurship Pillars in Factor Driven
Economies (normalized scores) in order to optimize the entrepreneurial ecology.
25
Figure II. Relative Efficiency of Entrepreneurship Pillars in Factor Driven Economies (normalized
scores)
There are some general observations about what seem to be the big problems in
Africa associated with the pillars of the model. Using the mode instead of the
average to minimize the effects of outliers for the data in Table 4 The normalized
score values of the 14 pillars of entrepreneurship in the African countries, the most
depressed pillars are (1) Quality of Human resources (0.11), (2) Startup Skills (0.16)
and (3) Networking (0.04), whereas the best pillars are (1) Cultural support (0.41), (2)
Competition (0.40) and (3) Opportunity perception.
If using the frequency of
occurrences in the individual three worst pillars (Table 5. The worst three pillars of
the GEDI index in the African countries), the most frequent three categories are the
26
same.
The quality of human resources seems inherently tied to education, and education in
Africa is complicated. In addition to general concerns about how to build effective
education systems that combine both access and quality, in recent years there has
been considerable public debate in particular in South Africa about the diminishing
quality of education and specifically poor primary and secondary schooling (Taylor
2008). While space does not permit a robust discussion of this subject, from the
perspective of an employer, finding qualified workers, educated locally at even a
basic level can be a substantial challenge for any potential employer in many of the
countries in the region and in particular the natural resource economies where
competition for labor from cash rich mineral companies is fierce. This is even more
complicated when the employer is a multinational located in a country with a less
widely used official language (e.g. Portuguese), in part, because the more restricted
the official language in terms of its global presence, the less access the country’s
educational system has to source materials, particularly in mathematics and the
physical sciences as the lingua franca of the sciences is English.
In the GEDI, the quality of human resources is measured by the percentage of new
firms started by individuals with education beyond the secondary level and within
firm training. This measure stems from a vast literature pointing out the strong
correlation with advanced education and successful entrepreneurial activity.
It
however points to a secondary consideration, the quality of tertiary education in
Africa and by extension primary and secondary education. One way to evaluate the
quality of secondary education is to ask to what extent are African countries seen as
destinations for foreign students seeking degrees. This measure is important because
exchange students are rarely talent limited, would perform well in nearly any
academic environment, and are not typically financially constrained. As a result,
their selection of school will be in some measure a function of the acceptability of the
program as a credential in their home country or the suitability of coursework done in
the exchange location as transfer credit at their home universities, and therefore, the
27
exchange locations perceived quality – equal to that of the home country or
university. While the US remains the country with the largest number of international
students (Choudaha and Chang 2012), according to the 2011 Open Doors report and
the Institute for International Education5, South Africa (#13) with 4,313 US exchange
students is the only African country which houses a substantial number of US
international students and thus whose educational quality is deemed by American
universities as adequate to accept for credit in their current accreditation scheme.
This suggests that other African countries tertiary systems may be less than adequate
with respect to quality and thus part of the reason for the poor performance of Africa
in this respect. The relatively low academic qualification of entrepreneurs in this
context may also explain the lack of within firm training provided by employers as
less educated employers may not value education and training as highly, and may also
be constrained in their business models to relatively low value added activities.
Given the importance of quality advanced education with respect to high value added
entrepreneurship, programs intended to diminish poverty through entrepreneurship
and micro-finance may in fact be ill conceived. A more successful approach might be
to focus development assistance to medium size enterprises which have already
addressed the basic start-up and labor force issues and have a business model that is
relatively successful within the relevant operating and institutional milieu. It is also
probable that the resources required to allow a firm of 100 people to add 10 additional
positions is less than that required to create five or ten, stable, growing one to two
person firms.
On the plus side, Africa scores well with respect to cultural support, competition and
opportunity perception. This may result from not only the market uniqueness but also
the propensity for African firms to be small and its industries unconsolidated, having
yet to achieve a critical mass or a dominant design, and despite some notable African
5
http://www.iie.org/Who-We-Are/News-and-Events/Press-Center/Press-Releases/2011/2011-11-14-OpenDoors-Study-Abroad
28
multinationals in agriculture, banking and basic materials with the potential to
improve overall sector organization. Cultural support for entrepreneurship may stem
from the ubiquity of the small firm by which we include the street vendor and a
general lack of hostility in Africa for business people.
Despite many African
countries being seen as highly corrupt, Africans themselves may not cite corruption
as an impediment to business as much as other entrepreneurs in other parts of the
world; however, the emergence of informality in the present era as the dominant
industrial design may be a reaction to corruption and reflect the relative ease of
extracting rents from larger commercial entities. Competition as a strength may not
be inherently obvious as many African markets may be more oligopolistic, controlled
by powerful elites; however, these markets often do not really serve the vast majority
of the population leaving open huge market segments for a new entrant aimed at the
underserved marketplace.
Opportunity perception in particular may result from the increasingly positive market
potential of Africa countries relative to the West (Economist 2012), and the cultural
support resulting from the fact that nearly everyone is involved in some sort of
business activity. Another factor influencing opportunity perception could be the
very rapid urbanization of most African countries over the decades since
independence. Many of Africa’s cities are among the largest urban agglomerations in
the world, such as, Lagos, Cairo, Kinshasa, and the higher scoring countries in this
category tend to have populations which are highly concentrated.
The role of the multilateral organization
There are numerous rationales for entering into bilateral and regional but multilateral
trade arrangements (Whalley 1998). While not an exhaustive list even within Africa,
the GEDI countries were differentiated by their regional trade agreements according
to Table 7. GEDI Countries by Regional Trade Group in an effort to ascertain whether
there existed any differences between countries based on their associations within
larger trading groups. The variations between these associations are dramatic ranging
from mere trade liberalization to customs and currency unions. So how did these
29
trade groups fair with respect to GEDI? Overall the average normalized GEDI scores
form two distinct groups with SADC (22.8) and WAMZ (27.5) separated from
COMESA (23.8), UEMOU (28,7) and EAC (21.1) following. While each of the
associations had some poor performing pillars, the countries of the EAC performed
consistently more poorly than the other trade blocks with respect to the GEDI pillar
indicators.
So what makes the difference? Since COMESA contains countries from all the legal
and language grouping in the continent, and since it faired as poorly as did EAC and
UEMOU, and because EAC and SADC are both English language affiliations with
polar opposite performances, it might be safe to conclude that language and legal
system, Roman versus Common Law, were not particularly good at explaining the
performance difference. It is interesting to note that while UEMOU and SADC to a
greater and lesser degree essentially share between their members a single currency,
the Central African Franc and South African RAND respectively; their performance
with respect to the GEDI in terms of having optimized policies is markedly different.
Similarly, while SADC and WAMZ are quite different in their composition, the one
thing they have in their favor is a single, large and wealthy economy, South Africa
and Nigeria respectively. Each group achieved the highest average normalized score
in an equal number of pillars, but SADC had a smaller range of normalized score
from 0.04 to 0.45 versus WAMZ which ranged from 0.16 to 0.58. This range could
suggest a more imbalance policy regime with respect to entrepreneurship in WAMZ
than in SAC. Despite fears that South Africa may be declining (Economist 2012a),
this may suggest that the effective incorporation of southern Africa’s fast growing
lusophone economies into SADC could result in it achieving economic dominance in
Africa if across the trading block they can optimize their pillar performance and
standardize their trading regulations. More generally, it may also suggest that while
individual countries pursue policies which reduce their own internal bottlenecks that
similar efforts need to be undertaken via the regional trade blocks in Africa.
30
5. So, what to make of the ABE efficiencies: Case examples
As can be observed from Table 6. The Average Bottleneck Efficiency values for the
African countries (ABE values are in percentages), the average bottleneck
efficiencies for the African countries range from 67.5% in Tunisia to 27.3% in
Malawi.
This is a measure of how efficiently aligned the various pillars of
entrepreneurship (Figure I. The structure of the Global Entrepreneurship and
Development Index) are to one another. We consult Table 8. Simulation of ’optimal’
policy allocation to increase the GEDI score by 5 in the African countries to
determine the ‘optimal’ allocation of and total effort required by pillar to achieve a 5
increase in the GEDI score. In Table 8. Simulation of ’optimal’ policy allocation to
increase the GEDI score by 5 in the African countries the row designated by the letter
A reflects the required increase in the specific pillar and the letter B reflects the
percentage of the total effort. In Egypt a total effort of 0.54 or 12% will be required
to increment the GEDI index by 5%. Focusing in nearly equal measure on improving
the Quality of Human Resources by 0.13 and Internationalization 0.12 pillars will
cover 46% of the required effort followed by nearly equal efforts in enhancing
Startup Skills by 0.09 and Opportunity Startup by 0.08. Minor increases in
Competition and Product Innovation and Tech Sector policies will complete the task.
In Gabon a total effort of 0.38 units is required to increment the index by 5, but unlike
in Egypt where the systems is less completely aligned, efforts in Burundi will require
a narrower effort covering 3 of the 14 pillars. Where should the authorities in Gabon
begin? As Table 7 suggests, the authorities in Gabon will get the biggest return on
their policy investment by focusing their efforts sequentially on improving startup
Skills followed by Networking. This will comprise 86% of the necessary effort to
raise the index by 5 units. The Quality of Human Resources requires the remaining
13% of the total effort.
A middle case: Angola
31
Angola is a land of contradictions. With approximately M18 inhabitants6 on 1.247
million square kilometers it is nearly twice the size of the USA state of Texas with
20% fewer people. The country has vast land, water and other natural resources.
Most of its population is concentrated within 100 miles of the coast in its six major
cities: Luanda, Benguela, Huambo, Lubango, Cabinda City and Namibe. It, along
with its cousin Mozambique, is one of Africa’s fastest growing economies, and like
Mozambique relatively recently emerged from a long, bloody civil war. Together
they may represent two of Africa’s rising economic powerhouses. To illustrate the
point, the Economist (2011) recently noted that Portuguese citizens, hard pressed to
find work in their native country, were heading to Angola to look for jobs, and
Mozambique has been growing at an annual rate of 8% for 15 years with no
indication of slowing (Economist 2012b).
Real GDP growth in the country has ranged from 3.1% in 2001 to 20.6% in 2005 and
its growth remained positive through the period of the global economic crisis;
however, there are wild swings in annual growth rates and some fears of currency
instability linger. At first glance one may be tempted to think this growth is driven
largely by the oil sector, and oil and diamonds do represent Angola’s export
economy, but Angola’s non-oil sectors have grown since 2001 at rates between
25.9% in 2006 and 7.8% in 2002. Inflation, while still high, has fallen to the low
teens. Despite this, Angola, which has recently improved its sovereign debt ratings to
within shot of investment grade and moved into the club of the middle income
countries, continues to have some of the worst social indicators in Africa.
From a policy perspective, the country’s government accounts for 40-50% of GDP
and its state oil monopoly, Sonangol, is often tasked with chores outside of its parent
industry – like the construction of houses. The government has a strong grasp on the
commercial environment, and yet, seems at times to lack the human capital to pursue
multiple policy objectives simultaneously. With respect to entrepreneurship policy,
Angola’s government has focused largely on the financial sector enhancements,
6
Angola has not had a census since before the start of the civil war in 1975.
32
recently authoring a new foreign investment law and beginning increasingly to put
efforts in greater financial transparency. These efforts may be why Risk Capital in
the GEDI methodology is not considered a constraint to entrepreneurship in the
country.
Because of this and its ABE score of 47.7%, Angola begins to represent what we
might call a middle case in the efficient production of positive entrepreneurial
activity. Angola requires a total effort of 0.31 in order to increment the index by 5
points. Examining Angola’s scaled scores in Table 4 The normalized score values of
the 14 pillars of entrepreneurship in the African countries it is easily observed that the
country’s scores range rather dramatically from 0.63 (Opportunity Perception and
Internationalization) to 0.06 (Startup Skills). Its best GEDI pillars are Opportunity
Perception (0.63), Internationalization (0.63) and Process Innovation (0.46), and its
areas of greatest needs are Start-up Skills (0.06) Tech Sector (0.22) and Competiton
and High growth (0.23). This does not mean that areas such as Risk Capital (0.39) are
not suitable for investment or that their distribution is not unequal, it is merely that
investment in these areas will not have as big a payback as investing in other more
neglected areas of the economy, and unlike a strategy that picks key sectors,
entrepreneurial firms are supra-sectoral as neither small firms nor entrepreneurial
firms constitute an economic sector in the production sense of the usage.
Of the 6.8% effort required to raise the GEDI by 5 and improve the balance in the
country’s entrepreneurship policy environment, Angola should focus most of its
effort (61%) on Startup Skills (0.06). This represents the lowest hanging fruit in terms
of return on effort in enhancing the entrepreneurship landscape. The country has a
nascent effort with USAID to create an entrepreneurship curriculum in the public
primary-secondary educational system, an international MBA-like curriculum at the
Catholic University of Angola and several, highly uncoordinated business incubator
projects around the country.
Improving such programs and coordinating their
capacity to build entrepreneurial skills within the population, including among its
better educated citizenry would provide the greatest payoff in terms of entrepreneurial
capacity. Examples of how this might be accomplished would be to build exchange
33
partnerships with US and European business schools, secondary entrepreneurial
education programs including those like the US junior achievement, 4-H and Future
Farmers of America and working with programs like the Global Small Business
Development Center at the University of Texas at San Antonio.7 In addition, placing
greater efforts on improving basic numeracy and literacy is a key component in being
able to address the Start-up Skill pillar to improve both job skill based instruction and
basic numeracy and literacy in the current adult population as well as in the country’s
youth. At present, Angola’s access to technology and its inter-regional trade is
severely constrained by a general lack of English literacy throughout the population.
This limits its ability to seek, find and exploit novel technologies for its own
advancement and limits the population’s capacity to engage more broadly in both
inter-regional and international trade, as well as, constrains the options available to its
young people to pursue advanced education in leading technology countries.
Subsequently, Angola could focus on improving the access of small firms and
business in general to novel technology thereby addressing the Tech Sector pillar
(0.22) of the GEDI. The Tech Sector pillar could for example be enhanced not only
by improving access to business technologies like IT but also by incorporating well
targeted basic agricultural research aimed at developing enhanced strains of
agriculturally important plants and livestock, improved dry farming techniques and
agricultural
product
processing.
Additionally,
the
development
of
an
entrepreneurship observatory aimed at improving the development and use of novel
technological resources by entrepreneurs such as mobile banking, marketing and
business services could round out a strategy for address Tech Sector weaknesses in
the entrepreneurial milieu.
After addressing Start-up Skills and Tech Sector, Angola could then move in turn to
the next group of pillars: Non-fear of Failure (0.23), Competition (0.23), High
Growth (0.23) and Cultural Support (0.24).
7
Global SBDC http://www.sbdcglobal.com/index.php/tn/
34
6. What does a development glide path look like with GEDI ….
As we think about how to use the insights gleaned from GEDI in a development
context, we are first struck by the ability of the index to help us begin to sort through
the myriad of possible approaches and make sense of a very complex environment.
While we have, at least initially, treated Africa as a whole, nothing could be farther
from the truth – Africa is no monoculture. This makes formulating coherent, crosscountry development policy and remediating skill gaps among entrepreneurs difficult
at best. This is especially true if development is to be broad based across the full
ethnic and social landscape. It is however important to remember that development is
an idiosyncratic phenomenon, unique to the particular country and its context. The
specific steps necessary will depend on the specific, evolving environment, but the
GEDI assists us in knowing where our focused efforts should yield their greatest
returns and avoid simply shopping around a particular development snake-oil for all
those who will buy it.
We are also struck with the recurrence of three primary analytical pillars: Quality of
Human Resources, Start-up skills, Networking. These three areas are primarily,
optimally remediated via different types of education and knowledge accumulation
measures such as the post secondary education enrollment, staff training and
development and internet penetration. It worth noting that two out of these three
pillars belong to the Entrepreneurial Attitudes sub-index and the Quality of Human
Resources belongs to the Entrepreneurial Ability sub-index. So Africa’s major
problem is not to improve the Entrepreneurial Aspirations related finance or
innovation but to develop education and basic infrastructure. Basic knowledge capital
accumulation can be translated into simple approaches like the incorporation of
mobile technology into basic business activities like finance, improving overall
business processing as well as improving the stock of basic knowledge necessary to
adapt advanced technology to the local natural and commercial environments.
Future policy work should involve fleshing out in greater detail potential policy
prescriptions consistent with our findings, testing the substitutability of the various
35
pillars, but also because we presently only have data for a fraction of Africa’s
countries further investment in the instruments and analytical techniques are
warranted.
36
Literature
1. Acs, Z. J. and Audretsch, D. B., 2010. “Introduction to the 2nd edition of the
Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research” in Acs & Audretsch (eds.), Handbook
of Entrepreneurship Research: An Interdisciplinary Survey and Introduction.
Second Edition International Handbook Series on Entrepreneurship Volume 5,
2010, pp 1-19.
2. Ács, Z. J., and L. Szerb (2012) Global Entrepreneurship and Development Index
2012. Edward Elgar Publishing, 2011.
3. Ács, Z. J., E. Autio and L. Szerb (2013) Global Entrepreneurship and
Development Index 2013. Edward Elgar Publishing, 2013.
4. Audretsch, David; Barry Bozeman, Kathryn L. Combs, Maryann Feldman, Albert
N. Link, Donald S. Siege, Paula Stephan, Gregory Tassey and Charles Wessner.
2002. The Economics of Science and Technology. Journal of Technology
Transfer. 27. 155–203.
5. Austin, James; Stevenson, Howard and Wei-Skillern, Jane (2006) “Social and
Commercial Entrepreneurship: Same, Different, or Both?”, Entrepreneurship
Theory and Practice, Vol. 30, Issue 1, pp. 1540-6520, DOI: 10.1111/j.15406520.2006.00107.x.
6. Autio, E., C. Matthew, M. Hart, J. Levie, Z.J. Acs, and L. Szerb 2012
Entrepreneurial Profile of the UK in the Light of the Global Entrepreneurship and
Development
Index
(April
24,
2012).
Available
at
SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2070320
7. Baumol, W. (1968). Entrepreneurship in economic theory. The American
Economic Review, 58(2), 64–71.
8. Baumol, W. (1990)
Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and
Destructive. The Journal of Political Economy. Vol. 98. No. 5. Part 1. Oct 1990.
893-921.
9. Baumol, W. (1993). Formal entrepreneurship theory in economics existence and
bounds. Journal of Business Venturing, 8, 197–210.
10. Bénédicte Fauvarque-Cosson and Anne-Julie Kerhuel (2009) “Is Law an
Economic Contest? French Reactions to the Doing Business World Bank Reports
and Economic Analysis of the Law”, Journal American Journal of Comparative
Law, Volume 57, Issue 4 / Fall 2009, Pages 811-829, DOI
10.5131/ajcl.2008.0024
37
11. Carland, James W., Frank Hoy, William Boulton and Jo Ann C. Carland. 1984.
Differentiating Entrepreneurs from Small Business Owners: A Conceptualization.
Academy of Management Review. Vol. 9. No. 2. 354-359.
12.
Choudaha and Chang (2012) Trends in International Student Mobility, World
Educational
Services,
downloaded
6/2/13,
http://www.uis.unesco.org/Library/Documents/research-trends-internationalstudent-mobility-education-2012-en.pdf.
13. Council on Foreign Relations (2011) The New Arab Revolt: What Happened,
What It Means, and What Comes Next, Goolge Books, downloaded 12/2/2012.
14. E.M. Goldratt and J. Cox (1992) The Goal: A Process of Ongoing Improvement,
2nd edition, North River Presss, Inc.: Great Barrington, MA.
15. The Economist (2011) “Angola and Portugal, Role reversal: An ex-colony may be
getting the better, in economic terms, of its old master”, Sep 3rd 2011,
http://www.economist.com/node/21528310, downloaded 12/1/2012.
16. The Economist (2012a) “Africa’s economy, Bulging in the middle: A boom in
sub-Saharan Africa is attracting business talent from the rich world”, Oct 20th
2012, http://www.economist.com/news/middle-east-and-africa/21564856-boomsub-saharan-africa-attracting-business-talent-rich-world, downloaded 12/1/2012
17. The Economist (2012b) “Baobab: The year ahead in southern Africa Parties,
politics
and
potential
collapse,
Jan
6th
2012,
http://www.economist.com/blogs/baobab/2012/01/year-ahead-southern-africa,
downloaded 12/1/2012.
18. Eggertsson, T. (2005), Imperfect Institutions: Possibilities and Limits of Reform,
University of Michigan Press: Ann Arbor, MI.
19. Ethnologue
(2012)
web
version,
http://www.ethnologue.com/ethno_docs/distribution.asp?by=area, downloaded 1Dec-12.
20. Fortunato, M. and Alter, T. R 2011 The Individual-Institutional-Opportunity
Nexus: An Integrated Framework for Analyzing Entrepreneurship Development
Entrepreneurship Research Journal. 1(1),
21. Jackson (2010) Mulling Over Massachusetts: Health Insurance Mandates and
Entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Sept 2010, DOI:
10.1111/j.1540-6520.2009.00351.x
22. Kaufman, Daniel and Kraay, Aart (2008) “Governance Indicators: Where are we,
where should we be going?”, World Bank Observer, Vol. 23, Issue 1. Pp. 1-30.
38
23. Malefakis, E. (1995) "The socioeconomic and historical context" in Gunther R.,
Diamandouros, P.N. & Puhle, H.J., Eds. The Politics of Democratic
consolidation: Southern Europe in Comparative Perspective. Baltimore: The
Johns Hopkins University Press as quoted in Costa Pinto, A. (1995). Salazar's
Dictatorship and European Fascism: Problems of Interpretation, New York:
Columbia University Press.
24. Marques, Rafael (2011) “Diamantes de Sangue: Corrupção e Tortura em Angola”,
Tinat-da-China: Lisbon, pp.230 [author’s translation “Blood Diamonds:
Corruption and Torture in Angola”]
25. Mezrich, Ben (2009) The Accidental Billionaires: The Founding of Facebook: A
Tale of Sex, Money, genius and betrayal. Doubleday:New York.
26. Michaels, Ralf (2009) “Traditional Comparative Law”, Journal American Journal
of Comparative Law , Volume 57, Issue 4 / Fall 2009, Pages 765-795, DOI
10.5131/ajcl.2008.0022
27. Minniti, M. (2004). Entrepreneurial alertness and asymmetric information in a
spin-glass model. Journal of Business Venturing, 19, 637–658.
28. Minniti, M. (2005). Entrepreneurship and network externalities. Journal of
Economic Behavior and Organi- zation, 57, 1–27.
29. Naudé, W. (2011) “Entrepreneurship is not a binding constraint on growth and
development in the poorest countries”, World Development. 39(1):33-44.
30. Naudé, W. A. (2010). “Entrepreneurship, developing countries and development
economics: New approaches and insights”. Small Business Economics, 34(1), 1–
12.
31. Redford, D.T. (2012) Entrepreneurship and Public Policy in Today and
Tomorrow’s Portuguese republic. Working Paper, Portuguese Studies Program,
University
of
California
at
Berkley,
p.
10,
http://escholarship.org/uc/item/2g79g3zf downloaded 12/1/2012.
32. Schumpeter, Joseph (1934) The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge.
Harvard University Press.
33. Schumpeter, Joseph (1942) Captialism, Socialism and Democracy. Harper &
Row: New York.
34. Shane, S. (1996). Explaining variation in rates of entrepreneurship in the Unites
States: 1899–1988. Journal of Management, 22(5), 747–781.
39
35. Taylor (2008) What’s Wrong with South African Schools?, Presentation to the
Conference What’s Working in School Development, JET Education Services,
28-29
February
2008
http://www.jet.org.za/events/conferences/What%20works%20in%20school%20de
velopment/Papers/Taylor%20Whats%20wrong%20with%20SA%20schools%20J
ET%20Schools%20Conf%20final.pdf
36. Whalley, John (1998) “Why Do Countries Seek Regional Trade Agreements?”, in
The Regionalization of the World Economy, Ed. Jeffrey A. Frankel, Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, http://www.nber.org/books/fran98-1, January 1998.
Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c7820, pp. 63 – 90.
37. Witt, Ulrich (2002) How Evolutionary is Schumpeter’s Theory of Economic
Development, Industry and Innovation, Volume 9, Numbers 1/2, 7–22,
April/August 2002.
38. World
Bank
(2012)
“About
the
Doing
Business
http://www.doingbusiness.org/about-us downloaded 12/2/2012.
Project”
39. Yunis, M. and Jolis, A. (1999) Banker to the Poor: Micro-Lending and the Battle
Against World Poverty, Public Affairs: New York, NY.
40
Appendix
Appendix 1: The description of the individual variables used in the GEDI
Individual
variable
Opportunity
Recognition
Skill
Perception
Risk
Acceptance
Know
Entrepreneurs
Carrier
Status
Career Status
Opportunity
Motivation
Technology
Level
Educational
Level
Competitors
New Product
New Tech
Gazelle
Export
Informal
Investment
Mean
Business
Angel
Informal
Investment
41
Description
The percentage of the 18-64 aged population recognizing good
conditions to start business next 6 months in area he/she lives,
The percentage of the 18-64 aged population claiming to posses
the required knowledge/skills to start business
The percentage of the 18-64 aged population stating that the fear
of failure would not prevent starting a business
The percentage of the 18-64 aged population knowing someone
who started a business in the past 2 years
The percentage of the 18-64 aged population saying that people
consider starting business as good carrier choice
The percentage of the 18-64 aged population thinking that people
attach high status to successful entrepreneurs
The status and respect of entrepreneurs calculated as the average
of Carrier and Status
Percentage of the TEA businesses initiated because of
opportunity start-up motive
Percentage of the TEA businesses that are active in technology
sectors (high or medium)
Percentage of the TEA businesses owner/managers having
participated over secondary education
Percentage of the TEA businesses started in those markets where
not many businesses offer the same product
Percentage of the TEA businesses offering products that are new
to at least some of the customers
Percentage of the TEA businesses using new technology that is
less than 5 years old average (including 1 year)
Percentage of the TEA businesses having high job expectation
average (over 10 more employees and 50% in 5 years)
Percentage of the TEA businesses where at least some customers
are outside country (over 1%)
The mean amount of 3 year informal investment
The percentage of the 18-64 aged population who provided funds
for new business in past 3 years excluding stocks & funds,
average
The amount of informal investment calculated as
INFINVMEAN* BUSANG
Appendix 2: The description and source of the institutional variables used in the GEDI
Institutional
variable
Description
Source
of data
World
Econom
ic
Forum
Data
availability
The Global
Competitiven
ess Report
2011-2012, p.
498
Domestic market size that is the sum
of gross domestic product plus value
of imports of goods and services,
Domestic Market minus value of exports of goods and
services, normalized on a 1–7 (best)
scale data are from the World
Economic Forum Competitiveness.
Urbanization that is the percentage United http://data.wo
of the population living in urban Nations rldbank.org/i
Urbanization
areas, data are from the Population
ndicator/SP.U
Division of the United Nations,
RB.TOTL.IN
2010 estimate
.ZS/countries
The size of the market: A combined
measure of the domestic market size
Own
Market
and the urbanization that later calculat
Agglomeration
measures
the
potential
ion
agglomeration effect. Calculated as
Domestic market*Urbanization
Gross enrolment ratio in tertiary UNESC http://stats.uis
education, 2009 or latest available
O
.unesco.org/u
Tertiary
data.
nesco/TableV
Education
iewer/tableVi
ew.aspx?Rep
ortId=167
The business climate rate “assesses Coface
the overall business environment
http://www.c
quality in a country… It reflects
oface.com/Co
whether
corporate
financial
facePortal/C
information is available and reliable,
OM_en_EN/
whether the legal system provides
pages/home/r
fair and efficient creditor protection,
isks_home/bu
and whether a country's institutional
siness_climat
Business Risk
framework
is
favorable
to
e/rating_table
intercompany
transactions”
?geoarea(http://www.trading-safely.com/). It
country=&cra
is a part of the Country Risk Rate.
ting=&bratin
The alphabetical rating is turned to a
g=
seven point Likert scale from 1 (“D”
rating) to 7 (A1 rating). 30
December 2010 data.
Internet Usage
The number Internet users in a Internat http://www.it
42
particular
country
inhabitants, 2010 data
Corruption
Economic
Freedom
Tech Absorption
Staff Training
Market
Dominance
43
per
100
ional
Teleco
mmunic
ation
Union
u.int/ITUD/ict/statistic
s/
IndividualsUs
ingInternet_0
0-10.xls
The Corruption Perceptions Index Transpa http://www.tr
(CPI) measures the perceived level
rency ansparency.or
of public-sector corruption in a Internat g/policy_rese
country. “The CPI is a "survey of
ional
arch/surveys_
surveys", based on 13 different
indices/cpi/20
expert and business surveys.”
10/results
(http://www.transparency.org/policy
_research/surveys_indices/cpi/2009
) Overall performance is measured
on a ten point Likert scale. Data are
from 2010.
“Business freedom is a quantitative
measure of the ability to start, Heritag http://www.h
operate, and close a business that
e
eritage.org/in
represents the overall burden of Foundat dex/explore.a
regulation, as well as the efficiency
ion/
spx
of government in the regulatory World
process. The business freedom score
Bank
for each country is a number
between 0 and 100, with 100
equaling the freest
business
environment. The score is based on
10 factors, all weighted equally,
using data from the World Bank’s
Doing
Business
study”.
(http://www.heritage.org/Index/pdf/I
ndex09_Methodology.pdf). Data are
from 2010.
Firm level technology absorption World The Global
capability: “Companies in your Econom Competitiven
country are (1 = not able to absorb
ic
ess Report
new technology, 7 = aggressive in Forum 2011 - 2012.
absorbing new technology)”.
p. 491
The extent of staff training: “To World The Global
what extent do companies in your Econom Competitiven
country invest in training and
ic
ess Report
employee development? (1 = hardly Forum 2011-2012, p.
at all; 7 = to a great extent)”.
449
Extent of market dominance: World The Global
“Corporate activity in your country Econom Competitiven
Technology
Transfer
GERD
Business
Strategy
Globalization
Venture Capital
44
is (1 = dominated by a few business
ic
ess Report
groups, 7 = spread among many Forum 2011-2012, p.
firms)”.
453
These are the innovation index World The Global
points from GCI: a complex Econom Competitiven
measure of innovation including
ic
ess Report
investment
in
research
and Forum 2011-2012, p.
development (R&D) by the private
22
sector, the presence of high-quality
scientific research institutions, the
collaboration in research between
universities and industry, and the
protection of intellectual property.
Gross domestic expenditure on UNESC http://stats.uis
Research & Development (GERD)
O
.unesco.org/u
as a percentage of GDP, year 2009
nesco/TableV
or latest available data Puerto Rico,
iewer/tableVi
Dominican Republic, and United
ew.aspx?Rep
Arab Emirates are estimated
ortId=2656
Refers to the ability of companies to World The Global
pursue distinctive strategies, which Econom Competitiven
involves differentiated positioning
ic
ess Report
and innovative means of production Forum 2011-2012, p.
and service delivery.
22
A part of the Globalization Index
KOF
Dreher, Axel
measuring the economic dimension Swiss (2006): Does
of globalization. The variable Econom Globalization
involves the actual flows of trade,
ic
Affect
Foreign Direct Investment, portfolio Institute Growth?
investment and income payments to
Evidence
foreign nationals as well as
from a new
restrictions of hidden import
Index of
barriers, mean tariff rate, taxes on
Globalization
international trade and capital
, Applied
account restrictions. Data are from
Economics
the 2010 report and based on the
38, 10: 10912007
survey.
1110.
http://globalization.kof.ethz.ch/
globalization_2011b_long.xls
A measure of the venture capital World The Global
availability on a 7-point Likert scale Econom Competitiven
generating from a statement:
ic
ess Report
Entrepreneurs with innovative but Forum 2011-2012, p.
risky projects can generally find
484
venture capital in your country (1 =
not true, 7 = true)”.
45
View publication stats