Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
Policy Research Working Paper
WPS7599
7599
Effect of Lengthening the School Day
on Mother’s Labor Supply
Dante Contreras
Paulina Sepúlveda
Development Economics Vice Presidency
Operations and Strategy Team
March 2016
Policy Research Working Paper 7599
Abstract
This article examines how a policy oriented toward a specific group within the population can have collateral effects
on the economic decisions of other groups. In 1996, the
Chilean government approved the extension of the school
day from half- to full-day school. This article exploits the
quasi-experimental nature of the reform’s implementation
by time, municipality, and age targeting of the program in
order to examine how the maternal labor supply is affected
by the childcare subsidy implicit in the lengthening of the
school day. Using data from the Chilean socioeconomic
household survey and administrative data from the Ministry of Education for 1990–2011, the authors estimate that,
on average, there is a 5 percent increase in labor participation and employment rates of single mothers with eligible
children (between 8 and 13 years old) with no younger
children, who are the group that would be mainly affected
by the policy. No significant labor supply responses are
detected among others mothers with eligible children.
This paper is a product of the Operations and Strategy Team, Development Economics Vice Presidency. It is part of a
larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy
discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org.
The authors may be contacted at
[email protected] and
[email protected].
The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development
issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the
names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those
of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and
its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent.
Produced by the Research Support Team
Effect of Lengthening the School Day on Mother’s Labor Supply
Dante Contreras and Paulina Sepúlveda
JEL Codes: H42, J13, J22, O12
Keywords: Childcare, Chile, female labor supply, fertility, labor supply
Dante Contreras (corresponding author) is a professor in the Department of Economics,
Universidad de Chile, Santiago, Chile; his e-mail address is
[email protected]. Paulina
Sepúlveda is a researcher at MINEDUC and Universidad de Chile; her e-mail address is
[email protected]. The authors acknowledge the funding provided by Center for Advanced
Research on Education and the grant by Centre for Social Conflict and Cohesion Studies
(CONICYT/FONDAP/15130009). They are also grateful for the comments made by Francisco
Gallegos, Norbert Shady, and the participants of the workshops at Universidad de Chile, IADB,
Chilean Economic Society, Universidad de Concepción, and Network Inequality and Poverty.
The authors also thank Soledad Cabrera for her excellent work in preliminary versions of the
paper. Any errors or omissions are the exclusive responsibility of the authors. Please cite the
article published in the World Bank Economic Review: Contreras, D and P. Sepúlveda “Effect of
Lengthening the School Day on Mother´s Labor Supply” (forthcoming),
http://wber.oxfordjournals.org/.
Despite progress in recent decades to bring gender equality in the labor market, women
continue to bear a heavier burden when it comes to balancing work and family. Affordable and
good-quality childcare services may improve the reconciliation of paid work and household
commitments and thus foster female labor market participation and gender fairness.
Unfortunately, the relationship between extra childcare and female labor opportunities in the
market is not well established. Indeed, although there is extensive literature that studies the
relationship between childcare and female labor participation, the evidence presents a mixed
picture of the net.
On the other hand, most of the literature that studies the effect of the expansion of
childcare availability on mothers’ labor supplies focuses on studying the effects on mothers with
preschool-aged children. However, there is a lack of evidence focusing on the effects of
increasing the length of the school day on mother labor supply. This article analyzes the effect of
the extension of the school day on mother’s labor participation in Chile.
In most developed countries, the school day of public education is highly compatible with
the workday of women.1 These countries show high levels of female labor participation and
employment rates (Adser 2005). In contrast, in developing countries the school day is, in most
1. See, e.g., France and Sweden.
2
cases, not compatible with the nine-to-six workdays. In fact, most of the school systems in
developing countries work on a half-day basis.2
Female labor participation has experienced significant growth in Chile. The rate of
female participation increased from 35 percent in 1990 to 49 percent in 2011 (in women from 15
to 65 years old). However, the situation of women in the Chilean labor market is still poor,
particularly for women with lower income levels. Women who belong to the poorest 20 percent
of the country’s population present a participation rate of 32 percent , while those from 20
percent of the wealthiest households achieve rates of 67 percent.3 Female labor participation in
Chile has been relatively late and is one of the lowest in Latin America in spite of the
comparatively high levels of education that Chilean women achieve.4
There are important reasons to study determinants of female labor supply in a developing
country. First, the access of women into the labor market should have positive effects for the
most vulnerable families as it represents a new source of income for these households and thus
could lead to a reduction in poverty (Ganuza et al. 2001). Second, despite the fact that greater
opportunities have emerged for women, there are still significant gaps between the participation
of men and women in all areas and discriminatory cultural patterns persist (Antecol 2003; Araújo
and Scalon 2005; Contreras and Plaza 2010).
2. However, there are various initiatives that promote the implementation of the full school day. In Latin America,
Chile, Argentina, Uruguay, and Venezuela has promoted different policies to expand the school day.
3. Chilean Socio-Economic Characterization Survey (CASEN) 1990–2011.
4. According to ECLAC statistics on gender, education, and training for women (2007), economically active women
(15 and over) in urban areas in Chile have an average of 11.6 years of schooling, placing them second in South America
behind Argentina, which presents an average of 11.8 years. The average years of schooling for women living in rural
areas of Chile is 9.3, placing the country first in South America for education levels of rural women.
3
Previous studies have found variables that affect female participation, such as age and
educational level, status as head of household, no labor income, and number and age of children
(Jaumotte 2005). The empirical evidence shows that the number and ages of children are the
most important variables that influence the likelihood of women's labor force participation.
Furthermore, evidence has identified additional, cultural, factors such as the level of machismo
and conservativeness, labor market-related factors such as lower salaries for women and rigidity,
as well as institutional factors such as a lack of childcare.
There are two main topics in the literature of the effects of childcare on labor incentives.
The first focuses on the relationships among the cost of childcare, female labor supply, and
government subsidies (Del Boca 2002; Del Boca and Vuri 2006; Blau and Currie 2007;
Lundin, Mörk, and Öckert 2008; Wrohlich 2011). Most of these studies show a small effect of
childcare government subsidies on female participation and high impact on the likelihood of
utilizing formal childcare. The second stems from the study of natural experiments, which
provides a better framework for analyzing how greater availability of childcare can affect
employment decisions of women with preschoolers (Gelbach 2002; Berlinki et al 2007; Lefebvre
and Merrigan 2008; Cascio 2009; Goux and Maurin 2010; Berlinki et al 2011; Havnes
and Mogstad 2011). Most of these studies suggest a positive effect on participation rates given
greater availability of childcare.5 We follow this second approach.
The increase in free time as a result of longer school day may impact the allocation of
time changing employment decisions or parental time investment.6 This article focus on the
5. In Chile, Encina and Martinez (2009) and Medrano (2009) have studied the effect of the increasing day care centers
on labor participation in Chile, finding that it does not induce any change on participation for low-income women.
6. Almuedo-Dorantes and Sevilla (2011), have studied the impact of low-skilled immigration, through lower prices
for commercial childcare, on parental investment. The authors find that low-skilled immigration to the United States
has contributed to substantial reductions in the time allocated to basic childcare by college-educated mothers of non-
4
effect of the extension of the school day, for example, increased availability of childcare for
younger school-aged children, on mother’s labor participation, employment, and hours worked
per week.
In 1996, the Chilean government announced the implementation of the Full School Day
program (FSD) as part of a series of measures designed to improve the quality and equality of
education in the country. This reform affected students in third through twelfth grades, for
example, children between 8 and 17 years of age. Previous to the reform, the school day was two
shifts, students attending either in the morning or the afternoon. The implementation of the
reform changed the educational structure so the schools must work on basis of one “shift.”7 In
general, before the extension of the school day, the students began classes around 8 a.m. in the
morning to 1 p.m. in the afternoon. After the reform students must to remain at school until 4:00,
decreasing the mothers’ time allocated to childcare in 3 hours per day.
But does this extension of the school day raise maternal labor supply? Which mothers
respond? The work decision is ultimately about how to allocate time between paid work, unpaid
work, and childcare.8 An increase in the time that children spent at school may change mothers’
choices, as they may spend fewer hours caring for children. However, this will also depend on
preferences regarding leisure and consumption. In other words, the effect of the extension of
school day on labor supply is therefore neither a substitution elasticity nor an income elasticity
but rather a combination of the two (Gelbach 2002). The size (and sign) of the effect relies on the
school-aged children. However, these mothers have not reduced the time allocated to more stimulating educational
and recreational activities with their Children.
7. Before the reform, many schools, elementary and secondary, provided two or even three half-day shifts, morning,
afternoon, and evening.
8. Gimenez-Nadal and Sevilla (2012) have studied the allocation of time in other context than in the context of labor
supply.
5
relative magnitude of these elasticities and preexisting distribution of hours, which may differ
across time and space.
Thus, following Card and Krueger (1992) and Dufflo (2001), our empirical strategy uses
the variation across municipalities and time in the implementation of the full school day reform
to predict labor supply among mothers of 8 through 13 year-old children in a difference-in
difference (DD) framework. Also, following Bryan and Sevilla (2007) we split the sample
between single and married mother to analyze if there are differential effects across marital
status.9 The reform affects children between 8 and17 years old. However, we consider a smaller,
younger group, because older children are less likely to need childcare. On the other hand,
following Cascio (2009) and Havnes and Mogstad (2011), among others, in a second stage we
use other mothers, who are not treated to construct comparison groups. To minimize bias, we
limit the comparison group to mothers with children slightly younger than the group of interest.
These triple-difference (DDD) models remove potential bias from municipality-specific shocks
to labor supply share by mothers with children around the same age. These biases could include
things like a change in the generosity of community welfare benefits.10 The source of exogenous
variation is the level of implementation of the reform at the municipal level, measured as share
of schools with FSD and available places at the municipal level.11 The key assumption is that the
implementation of the reform did not affect the demands placed on the schools. In other words, it
9. Bryan and Sevilla (2007) have studied the differential impacts of housework across marital
status for
women.
10. It is important to note that the reform’s installation has not been homogenous. Section V presents a more complete
analysis of how this phenomenon could impact our results.
11. See sub-section Research Strategy in section III for more details.
6
is assumed that the FSD implementation process did not provide an incentive for mothers to
choose schools that implemented the reform earlier.12
The data are drawn from the Chilean Socio-Economic Characterization Survey (CASEN)
and administrative information from the Ministry of Education from 1990 and 2011. The results
indicate that the introduction of FSD had a significant and positive impact on labor participation
for single mothers without younger children. We estimate that 5 percent of single mothers
without younger children entered the work force because of the implementation of FSD. This
relatively small effect may be explained by the fact the new school day is not totally compatible
with working hours. No significant labor supply responses are detected among other mothers
with eligible children.
The implementation of the reform was gradual and heterogeneous in terms of timing and
areas affected. Different regions and municipalities were integrated at different points in time
and with varying levels of implementation intensity. Given that the resources assigned in the
implementation of FSD mainly benefited at-risk municipalities and those with lower levels of
female labor participation, our results may underestimate the true impact of FSD on female labor
supply. On the other hand, the selection of school may be related to unobserved correlates of
maternal labor supply-demand of childcare.13
Even though the reform was to be implemented based on educational considerations
(exogenous to job market considerations), its introduction was not random. Following Kruger
and Berthelon (2011), we estimate the determinants of the implementation of FSD.14 The results
12. See section IV for more details.
13. However, Elacqua, Schneider, and Buckley (2006) and Gallego and Hernando (2008) show that there is not any
evidence suggesting a greater demand for schools with FSD.
14. The authors study the impact of full school days on adolescent pregnancy rates in Chile.
7
suggest a positive relationship between the vulnerability of the municipality and the installation
of the reform. In other words, if our results are biased, they have a lower bound than the true
value of the impact of FSD on the female labor supply.
I.
THE FULL SCHOOL DAY PROGRAM
The Chilean government has implemented two major reforms that affect the educational
system’s design. The first was introduced in 1981 and included decentralizing the educational
system by transferring the administration of public schools from the Ministry of Education to
Municipal Authorities. It also included a nationwide voucher system for both publicly and
privately administered schools, introducing a uniform demand-side subsidy in which parents are
free to choose among the schools in the market.15
As a result, the educational system in Chile shifted to three kinds of administrative
alternatives: public establishments funded by the student subsidy provided by the state and under
municipal administration; private subsidized establishments funded by the student subsidy and
administered by the private sector; and private fee-paying establishments funded and
administered by the private sector. The creation of voucher schools led to a dynamic education
sector that underwent fast growth in the supply of schools.
The second major reform took place in 1996 when the Chilean government announced a
set of new initiatives designed to improve educational quality. The measure that had the greatest
impact on the school system was the implementation of FSD. This program consisted of
15. The reform led to a sharp redistribution of the educational system, benefitting the private subsidized sector. In
fact, the percentage of students in private subsidized schools increased from 15 percent in 1981 to 47 percent in
2005.
8
extending the number of classroom hours by 30 percent annually without lengthening the school
year.16 The change involved a significant increase in the number of hours at school. Additionally,
it set a longer time of recess and lunch. As a result, the students are now required to remain on
school until 4:00 p.m. (Under the previous system the students remain in school until 1:00 p.m.).
Prior to the reform, many schools had a double school day that is two shifts of students,
one in the morning and another in the afternoon. The execution of the FSD program meant that
those schools transitioned to a single school day format.
The objectives of this program were to improve student learning and increase equality in
education. They were described as follows: “To contribute to the improvement of the quality of
education and provide equal learning opportunities to the boys, girls and adolescents throughout
the country by significantly increasing teaching time in order to better develop the new curricular
framework.”17
More time at school could positively affect learning, the technical work of teachers, and
the management of each school. In fact, Bellei (2009) analyzes the effects of the increase in the
length of the school day on academic performance in Chile and finds a small, positive, and
significant effect on academic performance in both language and mathematics tests.
On the other hand, FSD allowed for services to be provided to high-risk populations by
increasing opportunities for learning and significantly expanding the amount of time allotted for
schoolwork for all students in government-subsidized schools. Kruger and Berthelon (2011)
analyze the effect of the increased length of the school day on adolescent pregnancy rates in
16. The school year is divided into semesters. The first semester runs from the end of February or early March to July.
Following a two-week winter break school resumes and lasts until late November or early December, followed by
summer vacations.
17. The program was approved through Law No. 19,532.
9
Chile and find that increasing the amount of time that students spend in school diminishes the
likelihood of adolescent pregnancy by reducing risky sexual behavior.
The FSD format has been incorporated gradually since 1997. According to official
statistics from the Ministry of Education, 80 percent of primary schools, or some 6,834
institutions, had joined the system by 2011 (figure 1).18 The increase of the school day involved
adding 232 hours per year for third to sixth graders, 144 hours annually for seventh to eighth
graders, 261 for ninth and tenth graders, and 174 for students in their last two years of high
school. In addition, as a consequence of the increase in lecture hours, schools had to allocate
additional time for lunch. This may imply a positive income effect for those families. Therefore,
the effective time of children at schools increased from 8 a.m. through 1 p.m.; to 8 a.m. through
4 p.m.. However, the program’s implementation was gradual. Restrictions linked to operational
considerations and infrastructure meant that the incorporation of schools into the program was
not instantaneous or homogenous.
Operational costs are financed through a 30% increase in government subsidies19 while
infrastructure-related costs are financed through the “capital contribution” subsidy, which it
assigned to schools by the government through competition.20 Schools that did not have a full
school day prior to 1998 can apply for support to acquire the infrastructure necessary to
18. The Ministry of Education projected that FSD would be universal in municipal schools by 2007 and in private
subsidized schools by 2010. However, the process of incorporating municipal schools into the system did not end in
2007, which led to the extension of the period through 2010. The law requires that publicly funded schools created
after 1997 begin operations with a full school day.
19. This contribution is received once the Ministry of Education approves the implementation of FSD in the school.
20. In order to apply for this subsidy, the school must participate in a capital contribution competition held by Ministry
of Education, which normally takes place twice a year. Each school is evaluated on the basis of socioeconomic
vulnerability and the funds required for each student to join the program. Each component is assigned a score and the
projects with the highest scores are funded.
10
incorporate FSD. Schools created after 1998 can apply as long as there is a lack of schools in
their region. Public schools can also receive subsidies from regional or municipal governments.
The program was not introduced randomly. The first schools to change to the FSD format
were rural and smaller institutions that already had a single schedule. As such, increased
investment in infrastructure was not required. Furthermore, resources were focused on schools
with populations of students who were at a greater socioeconomic risk.
Table 1 describes the FSD implementation process between 1998 and 2011 in the
country’s 13 administrative regions.21 In 1998, the regions with the highest rates of incorporation
were IX and XI, with a percentage of FSD schools of 73% and 79%, respectively. In 2011, the
regions with the highest rates were IX regions which reached 88% and 92% enrollment,
respectively, which still represented the highest rates in the country.22
FSD schools in the Metropolitan Region were 17% in 1998, which was the lowest rate in
the country. Only 7% of the schools in the Metropolitan Region are of the rural type, which was
first addressed by the reform. In contrast, 68% and 38% of the schools in the IX and XI regions
are rural.23 Finally, only six municipalities had not incorporated FSD by 1998. The last to
21. Chile was divided into 13 regions, which are the country's first-level administrative division. Each region is headed
by an intendant, appointed by the President, and an indirectly-elected body known as regional board. Regions are
divided into provinces (second-level administrative division), each headed by a governor (gobernador), appointed by
the President. There are 54 provinces, in total. Provinces are further divided into municipalities (third and lowest level
administrative division), which are governed by mayor.
22. This percentage is based on total enrollment in the region.
23. Ministry of Education 1998–2011.
11
incorporate was the municipality of Rauco, which introduced FSD in 2004.24 It is important to
note that all municipalities were participating in FSD by 2006.
II.
DATA: SOURCE SAMPLE AND SUMMARY STATISTICS
To estimate the relationship between full day school reform and maternal labor supply we
use data from Chile’s National Socio-Economic Characterization Survey (CASEN) for the
period 1990–2011. We also use administrative data on enrollment and school compiled by the
Ministry of Education for 1998–2011. CASEN is a representative survey at the national,
regional, and urban-rural levels. It has been happened every two or three years since 1987 and
provides important data on health, education, housing, income, labor market, and demographic
variables at the household level.
This study considers women between the ages of 25 and 55 since they present the greatest
likelihood of being the mothers of 8–13 year-olds. Following Gelbach (2002), we estimate
separate models for a mother of an 8–13 year-old with and without younger children. Mothers
who have both an 8–13 year-old and a younger child must find childcare for the younger child
(even if the older child is in FSD), so throughout the article we split the samples according to
whether the woman’s 8–13 year-olds is her youngest child. We also split the sample by marital
status, so we can differentiate the effects of the FSD on married and single mothers. Mothers
were classified as single if listed as head of household or as the primary individual in a
subfamily.25
24. The last municipalities to join the program were Sierra Gorda, Rinconada, Isla de Pascua, Olivar, Rauco, and
Penco. Source: Ministry of Education 1998–2011.
25. We also estimate the results using the marital status reported by women. The results are quite similar and are
available from the authors upon request.
12
Figures 2 and 3 presents respectively mothers’ labor participation and employment rate by age of
the youngest child. As was expected, the higher labor participation is for mothers whose
youngest child is 14 to 15 years old (dashed line). Meanwhile, the lowest labor participation is
for the group of mothers whose youngest child is 0 to 5 years old (dotted line). All the groups
increased participation and employment. This can be explained by the increase in education
levels of women in Chile, the increased in the access to childcare institutions for children in
preschool age, among others.
Table 2, panel A, reports summary statistics for single and married mothers of 8–13 yearolds without younger children. Along all the labor outcomes- labor participation, employment,
and hours worked- the typical single mother consistently supplies more labor than her married
counterpart. However, there were large increases in labor supply for married mothers over the
sample period. The gain in employment was particularly large in 2000. The econometric models
described below allow us to test whether any of this gain was response to FSD implementation.
Table 2, panel B, shows that married mothers with children between 8 and 13 years old and with
younger children experienced similar gains in employment and hours over the same 20-year
period, though their employment levels were lower in each year, arguably due to the presence of
younger children. Generally, the ages and quantity of other children may affect labor supply
decisions.
Table 2 also shows trends based on the number of children in different age groups and in
other maternal demographic characteristics. Because these trends may underlie rising female
labor supply (Blau 1998), our models control for maternal observables. Demographic
characteristics of single mothers whose youngest child is 8–13 years old differ from similar
married mothers. Single mothers show more years of schooling, lower levels of poverty, lower
13
average age, and have a lower number of children. Additionally, they are more likely to live in
urban areas and have an older woman in their households.
III.
RESEARCH STRATEGY AND FINDINGS
Research Strategy
To examine how mothers’ behavior is affected by exposure to FSD, we first estimate a
model that is similar to the conventional difference in difference (DD) specification:
,
(1)
where y ijt represents labor participation, employment or hours for mother i in municipality j
in year t ; X ijt is the vector of maternal characteristics, including age, age squared, schooling,
number of children by age, marital status, no labor income, and dummy variables for rural areas,
poverty and whether there is another adult woman in the household; M jt is the vector of timevarying municipal characteristics; j represents municipality fixed effect and t is the time
fixed effect.
FSD jt is the policy variable described above. We use two different but closely related
measures of FSD to estimate equation (1). First, we include the proportion of primary schools in
the municipality that offer full-day schooling during a given year, while our second measure is
the share of total primary enrollment at the municipal-level that is under full-day schooling. The
parameter of interest in model 1 is , which measures the effects of the reform on mothers’ labor
supply and will be identified by ordinary least square (OLS) regression.
14
Our second approach is to estimate a triple difference (DDD) model on a sample that
includes treated and nontreated mothers:
∗
where
, (2)
is an indicator for whether mother i has an 8–13 year-old child (enrolled in third
to eighth grade of primary education). The coefficient
∗
is the difference in
model 1 coefficient on FSD jt between the treatment and comparison group. We limit the
comparison group to mothers with children slightly younger, that is, mothers whose youngest
child are 6–7 years old.26 In the next section, we show the results of the models presented above,
by dividing the samples into single mothers and married mothers. We control by time and
municipality fixed effect, maternal characteristics (described above) and standard errors are
clustered at municipality level.
Findings
Table 3 reports the results using the first measure of FSD (share of primary schools in the
municipalities that offer FSD). The second column of table 3 shows the estimates of (DD
model) for mothers whose youngest child was between 8 and 13 years old at the time of the
survey. For single mothers (panel A), the extension of the school day is associated with a
significant a positive effect in labor participation, and employment. Thus, it is found that the
extension of the school day is associated with a 4 percentage point increase in labor participation,
6 percentage point increase in employment, that is, a 5 percentage increase in employment in
labor participation (0.04/0.740.06), 8 percentage increase in employment (0.06/0.700.08),
26. The reform affects children between 8 and 17 years old.
15
when we compare with pre-initiative means.27 We also find a negative effect on hours worked
last week. A possible explanation for these last results is that women increase their participation
in part-time jobs that are compatible with the extension of the school day.28
For married mothers (column 2, panel B of table 3), we do not find any significant
effects. This could be explained because married women have greater household commitments
that may reduce the amount of effort available for market work or may be the outcome of intrahousehold choices. These results are consistent with those of Bryan and Sevilla (2007). The
authors argue that marriage is characterized by the presence of specialization and economies of
scale that not only change the actual time devoted to housework but also the type of housework
activities that may affect de productivity in the labor market. Married individuals might also be
constrained in the time of housework (and other activities) because of the need to synchronize
leisure activities with the spouse. The authors find a negative effect of housework on wages for
married female workers, but not for single workers or married male workers. Then, the
differential effect across marital status suggests that the factor behind the relationship between
housework and wages are the type and timing of housework activities as much as the actual time
devoted to housework. Similar findings emerge for married mothers of children between 8 and
13 years old who also have younger children, as shown in column 5 of table 3. In general, we do
not find any effects for mothers who have both an 8–13 year-old and a younger child (panels A
and B, column 6). This may be explained because these mothers must find childcare for younger
child, limiting participation in the labor market.
27. We compare with pre-initiative means, in order examine the increase of means after the reform taking as a base
the pre-initiative means.
28. Available data do not contain information on part-time jobs.
16
The conventional DD estimates can be biased to the true causal effect of the
implementation of FDS, if there are economic fluctuations specific to the treatment group that
are not fully accounted for. On the other hand, if the treated municipalities also initiated other
policies affecting maternal labor supply, the DD estimator may also be biased. We address this
concern by estimating equation (2). In this DDD estimation we use mothers with slightly
younger children as a control group. Thus, we can control for time-varying effects specific to the
treatment areas, correcting for sources of bias mentioned above.
The third column of table 3, panel A, presents the estimate comparing our treatment
group with the control group for single mothers whose youngest children is 6–7 years old.29 The
results indicate that when we compare with mothers whose youngest children are just outside
that age group, there is an increase of 4 percentage points in labor participation and
employment.30 In others words, there is a 5 percent increase in labor participation and
employment rate as a result of FSD implementation. Again, we find a negative effect on hours
worked last week.
Table 4 reports the effects of FSD implementation using the second measure of FSD, the
share of total primary enrollment at the municipal-level that is under FSD (children between 8
and 13 years old). Using the second measure, we do not find any effects using DD strategy, but
we do using DDD estimation. We find that when we compare with single mothers with children
6–7 years old, there is an increase in the labor participation and employment rate of single
mothers of 4 percentage points (table 4, panel A, column 3, rows a and b).
29. Figures A.4 and A.5 show the evolution of the municipality average of female labor participation and
employment rate of single mothers of 8–13 year-olds and six to seven with no younger children.
30. When we add interactions between the FSD and a large set of pre-reform municipality characteristics the results
remains stable. The estimations are available from the authors upon request.
17
Thus, we find effects of the FSD implementation on single mothers whose youngest child
is between 8 and 13 years old.31 These results are consistent with those of Havnes and Mogstad
(2011), Ludin et al. (2008), and Cascio (2009), in finding nearly no effects on the labor supply
among married mothers as a result of the increased access to (or lower prices of) childcare.
ROBUSTNESS: SPECIFICATION CHECKS
The correct identification of the effect of FSD on mothers’ labor outcomes can be limited
by various potential sources of bias. This section examines whether the FSD implementation was
in fact exogenous and discusses the results of several additional robustness checks.
School Choice
The key assumption behind specification (2) is that the reform’s implementation did not
affect the demand for schools. That is, mothers did not tend to choose schools that implemented
the reform earlier.32 Elacqua, Schneider, and Buckley (2006) show that the main reason for
choosing a school is its proximity or parents’ place of work or home. Additionally, Gallego and
Hernando (2008) conclude that there is no evidence to suggest a greater demand for schools with
FSD. Thus, we can conclude that the supply of schools with FSD at the municipal level is
exogenous to mother’s decision to participate in the labor force.33 In this sense, parameter
31. We also divide the sample between poor and nonpoor households. We found a positive and significant effect in
labor participation and employment rate for nonpoor single women with no younger children. Also we find a
negative and significant effect of FSD on hours worked last week, i.e., similar results that in the entire sample. On
the other hand, for the poor sample, we find no significant parameter related to the group that would be mainly
affected by the extension of the school day, i.e., women with no younger children. These results are available upon
request.
32. As was noted in section III, the Chilean education system allows parents to choose their children’s school.
33. As we stated in the previous sections, FSD was installed in order to improve student learning and achieve greater
educational equity, not to increase mothers’ labor participation.
18
represents the effect of mother’s exposure to the full school day in their municipality on the
decision to participate in the job market.
Was the Extension of School Day Exogenous?
The mechanism of assigning public resources for financing FSD and the characteristics of
the municipality could bias the estimates. As has been discussed in previous sections, the
implementation of the reform was not random. The Ministry of Education focused on the most
vulnerable schools located in municipalities with relatively poor populations. In other words, if
the schools located in municipalities with a low socio-economic level received priority in
funding for installing FSD and presented low levels of female labor participation, the coefficient
estimated by FSD underestimates the true effect.
Following Kruger and Berthelon (2009), we examine the presence of this potential bias.
The share of primary school that offer FSD and the share of total primary enrollment under FSD
at the municipal-level are modeled for a set of characteristics at the municipal level. The goal is
to model the criteria utilized by the Ministry of Education to assign funding for FSD.
Specifically:
,
(3)
where Lit is the vector that includes municipal level characteristics such as illiteracy, poverty,
and unemployment. This estimate also includes dichotomous variables by year to control for the
trend of the reform’s implementation. Table A.5 in the appendix presents the results of equation
(3). Column (1) shows the results of the estimation of equation (3) controlling for year and fixed
effect by municipality using the share of schools with FSD. The results indicate that
19
municipalities with greater female labor participation present lower level of schools ascribed to
FSD, that is, there is a negative correlation between female labor participation and the
implementation of FSD.
On the other hand, column 2 in the same table presents the results using FSD enrollment
as a dependent variable. The results indicate that municipalities with greater poverty rates present
a greater level of enrollment ascribed to FSD. The results show a positive correlation between
the poverty rate and the implementation of the reform. The evidence based on equation (3)
suggests that the administrative criterion of directing FSD funds to higher-risk municipalities has
been effective. That is, these results indicate that our estimates probably understate the true
impact of FSD on female labor participation, and that the results of the lineal estimate represent a
level that is lower than the true effect of FSD on mother labor participation.
Time Trend
In our DD approach we identify the childcare effects from the assumption of a common
time trend in maternal employment between treatment and comparison municipalities, in the
absence of the school day expansion. A concern is therefore that the estimated effects may reflect
differential time trend. To investigate this, in the model DD describe above (just for period
between 1990 and 2009) we include in the same regression the variables "Actual FSD" and
"Future FSD" (Share 2011). If we find that the share in the future does no matter, then we can
reject that "Actual FSD" and "Future FSD" are different. Thus, we can reject pre-trends.
Table A.6 in the appendix reports the placebo reform effect described above, on the
sample of head of family mothers and single mothers whose youngest child is between 8 and 13
years old in 1990. If there were differential secular time trends in the treatment and comparison
20
municipalities in the pre-reform period, then the estimated effect of the "Future FSD" should be
significantly different from zero. By contrast, the estimated placebo reform effect is
insignificant.
Does the Extension of School Day Predict Labor Supply in Nontreated Groups?
Another placebo reform to identify if there are time trends in maternal labor supply is to
estimate the effect of FSD on groups that should be not affected by the reform. To analyze this,
we estimate the effect of a placebo reform on mothers whose youngest child is 6 to 7 years old.
Table A.7 in the appendix reports the placebo reform effect on the sample of single mothers with
her youngest child being between 8 and 13 years old. Again, if there were differential secular
time trends in mother labor supply, then the estimated effect of the placebo reform should be
significantly different from zero. However, the results indicate that the FSD reform did not affect
this group.
IV.
CONCLUDING REMARKS
This article examines how a policy oriented towards a specific group within the
population can have collateral effects on the economic decisions of other groups. In 1996, Chile
began to introduce the Full School Day system, significantly increasing the hours spent in
school. The purpose of this study is to examine how greater availability of childcare via a longer
school day impacts women’s decisions to participate in the labor market.
The gradual implementation of the reform over time and in different regions of the
country is exploited by this study. A DD and a DDD strategy are used to obtain the causal effect
of exposure to the reform. The results show a positive and significant effect of the
21
implementation of FSD on single mothers’ access to the job market. The results suggest that
increasing the amount of time that children spend in school provides single mothers with more
opportunities to access labor market because they need to dedicate less time to childcare. In fact,
we estimate that 5 percent of single mothers without younger children entered the work force as
a consequence of the implementation of FSD. The result is small, which could be explained
because the extension of the school day provision only increased until 4 p.m. Thus, to increase
the labor force more, is necessary to increase the school day to be compatible with the working
hours of mothers.
We also find a negative and significant impact in hours worked per week. A possible
explanation for these results is that the increased length of the school day decreases women’s
spending on alternative childcare, thus increasing their disposable income and decreasing the
amount of hours that they are required to dedicate to the labor market. Another possible
explanation is that women are choosing part time jobs that are compatible with the extension of
the school day.
Thus, one important results, is that mothers are mostly constrained when they have
younger children. This result is especially interesting because the provision of FDS in 1st and
2nd grade is not mandated by the reform, and it suggests that increasing access to FDS in these
early levels would have the strongest impact on fostering female labor force participation.
Therefore, our results suggest that authorities should prioritize expansion in those two grade
levels.
On the other hand, it is important to note that, while this educational reform is exogenous
to individuals’ decisions in the labor market, its implementation was not random. The Ministry
22
of Education focused on the most vulnerable schools in municipalities with relatively poor
populations. The reform’s implementation was meant to give priority to these schools. In Chile,
these municipalities are those with the lowest levels of female labor participation. As a result of
the design of the reform’s implementation, our estimates probably underestimate the true impact
of FSD on female labor participation. These results should thus be interpreted as understating the
true effect of the Full School Day on mothers’ labor participation.
In conclusion, in this article we find that lengthening the school day has a positive and
significant effect on single mothers’ labor supply with no younger children. This result is
remarkably interesting because the adequacy of this policy both strengthens the benefits mother
enjoy from their participation in the labor market and improve the economic well-being of
families. In addition, these results are subject to a number of interpretations that highlight the
importance of future work in this area: for example, the need to give priority to greater
availability of childcare for young children and the complementary of FDS with these policies.
REFERENCES
Adser, A. 2005. “Where Are the Babies? Labor Market Conditions and Fertility in Europe.”
IZA Discussion Papers No. 1576.
Amuedo-Dorantes, C., and A. Sevilla. 2014. “Low-Skilled Immigration and Parenting
Investments of College-Educated Mothers in the United States Evidence from Time-Use
Data.” Journal of Human Resources 49 (3): 509–39.
Antecol, Heather. 2003. ‘‘Why Is There Cross-Country Variation in Female Labor Force
23
Participation Rates? The Role of Male Attitudes toward Family and Sex Roles.’’
Claremont Colleges Working Papers (03/2003), Department of Economics, Claremont
McKenna College, Claremont, CA.
Araújo, Clara, and Celi Scalon. 2005. ‘‘Genero, familia e trabalho no Brasil’’ [Gender, family
and work in Brasil]. In Clara Araújo and Celi Scalon, eds., Editora da fundação o getulio
vargas [Editors from Getulio Vargas Foundation], 1st ed. Rio de Janeiro: Getulio Vargas
Foundation.
Baker, M., J. Gruber, and K. Milligan. 2008. “Universal Childcare, Maternal Labor Supply,
and Family Well-Being.” Journal of Political Economy 116: 709–45.
Berlinski, S., S. Galiani, and P. MacEwan. 2011. “Preschool and Materal Labor Market
Outcomes: Evidence from a Regression Discontinuity Design.” Economic Development
and Cultural Change 59 (2): 313–44.
Berlinski, S., and S. Galiani. 2007. “The Effect of a Large Expansion of Pre-primary School
Facilities on Preschool Attendance and Maternal Employment.” Labour Economics 14:
665–80.
Bellei, C. 2009. “Does Lengthening the School Day Increase Students’ Academic
Achievement? Results from a Natural Experiment in Chile.” Economics of Education
Review 28 (5): 629–40.
Berthelon, M., and D. Kruger. 2011. “Risky Behavior among Youth: Incapacitation Effects of
School on Adolescent Motherhood and Crime in Chile.” Journal of Public Economics 95
(1–2): 41–53.
24
Blau, D., and J. Currie. 2007. “Who's Minding the Kids? Preschool, Day Care, and After School
Care.” In F. Welch and E. Hanushek, eds., The Handbook of Education Economics.
Amsterdam: North Holland.
Bordón, P. 2007. “El efecto de los jardines infantiles en la oferta laboral femenina. Análisis del
caso chileno.” Working Paper, CEA. Santiago, Chile.
Bravo, D., D. Contreras, and E. Puentes. 2008. “Female Labor Supply and Child Care
Supply in Chile.” Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of Chile.
Santiago, Chile.
Card, D., and A. Krueger. 1992. “Does School Quality Matter? Returns to Education and the
Characteristics of Public Schools in the United States.” Journal of Political Economy
100: 1–40.
Cascio, E. 2009. “Maternal Labor Supply and the Introduction of Kindergartens into American
Public Schools.” Journal of Human Resources 44: 140–70.
Contreras, D., and G. Plaza. 2010. “Female Labor Force Participation in Chile: How Important
Are the Cultural Factors?” Feminist Economics 16 (2): 27–46.
Choné, P., D. Le Blanc, and I. Robert-Bobée. 2004. “Female Labor Supply and Child Care.”
Économie and Prévision 162: 23–50.
Currie, J. 2001. “Early Childhood Education Programs.” Journal of Economic Perspectives
15 (2): 213–38.
Del Boca, D. 2002. “The Effect of Childcare and Part-Time Opportunities on Participation and
25
Fertility Decisions in Italy.” Journal of Population Economics 15: 549–73.
Del Boca, D., and D. Vuri. 2006. “The Mismatch between Employment and Childcare in Italy:
The Impact of Rationing.” Working paper No. 983, Institute for the Study of Labor
(www.iza.org).
Duflo, E. 2001. “Schooling and Labor Market Consequences of School Construction in
Indonesia: Evidence from an Unusual Policy Experiment.” American Economic Review
91 (4): 795–813.
Elacqua, G., M. Schneider, and J. Buckley. 2006. “School Choice in Chile: Is It Class or the
Classroom?” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 25 (3): 577–601.
Encina, J., and C. Martínez. 2009. “Efecto de una Mayor Cobertura de Salas Cuna en la
Participación Laboral Femenina: Evidencia de Chile.” Working Paper No. 303,
University of Chile, Department of Economics. Santiago, Chile.
Ganuza, E., and R. Paes de Barros. 2001. “Liberalización, Desigualdad y Pobreza: América
Latina y el Caribe en los 90.” UNDP, ECLAC.
Gallego, F., and A. Hernando. 2008. “School Choice in Chile: Looking at the Demand Side.”
Unpublished Manuscript, Pontificia Universidad Católica de Chile.
Gelbach, J. 2002. “Public Education for Young Children and Maternal Labor Supply.”
American Economic Review 92: 307–22.
Gimenez-Nadal, J. I., and A. Sevilla. 2012. “Trends in Time Allocation: A Cross-Country
Analysis.” European Economic Review 56 (6): 1338–59.
26
Goux, D., and E. Maurin. 2010. “Public School Availability for Two Year-olds and Mothers'
Labour Supply.” Labour Economics 17 (6): 951–62.
Havnes, T., and M. Mogstad. 2011. “Money for Nothing? Universal Child Care and Maternal
Employment.” Journal of Public Economics 95 (11–12): 1455–65.
Jaumotte, F. 2005. “Female Labour Force Participation: Past Trends and Main Determinants in
OECD Countries.” OECD, Paris.
Kruger, D., and M. Berthelon. 2011. “Risky Behavior among Youth: Incapacitation Effects of
School on Adolescent Motherhood and Crime in Chile.” Journal of Public Economics 95
(1–2): 41–53.
Lefebvre, P., and P. Merrigan. 2003. “Assessing Family Policy in Canada: A New Deal for
Families and Children.” Institute for Research on Public Policy. Montreal, Canada.
———. 2008. “Childcare Policy and the Labor Supply of Mothers with
Young Children: A
Natural Experiment from Canada.” Journal of Labor Economics 23: 519–48.
Lundin, D., E. Mork, and B. Ockert. 2007. “Do Reduced Child Care Prices Make Parents Work
More?” Working Paper 2007-2, Institute for Labour Market Policy Evaluation. Uppsala,
Sweden.
Medrano, P. 2009. “Public Day Care and Female Labor Force Participation:
Evidence from Chile.” Working Paper No. 306, University of Chile, Department of
Economics. Santiago, Chile.
Pires, T., and S. Urzúa. 2010. “Longer School Days, Better Outcomes?” Unpublished
Manuscript, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL.
27
Sevilla-Sanz, A., and M. L. Bryan. 2007. “Does Housework Lower Wages and Why? Evidence
for Britain.” Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series, No. 331. University of
Oxford. Oxford, United Kingdom.
Wrohlich, Katharina. 2011. “Labor Supply and Child Care Choices in a Rationed Child Care
Market.” DIW Berlin Discussion Papers, No. 1169. Berlin, Germany.
Figure 1. Number of Half-Day and Full Primary Schools
Source: Authors’ estimates based on administrative data from the Ministry of education.
28
Figure 2. Maternal Labor Participation Rates by Age of Youngest Child
Source: Authors’ estimates bases on CASEN 1990-2011.
Figure 3. Maternal Employment Rates by Age of Youngest Child
Source: Authors’ estimates bases on CASEN 1990–2011.
29
Table 1. Proportion of FSD Schools (%) by Administrative Region, 1998–2011
Region
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
I
2
47
46
50
57
50
52
52
56
56
60
61
71
71
71
II
2
42
44
53
58
52
55
59
67
67
63
64
62
64
64
III
53
62
61
68
68
67
70
72
70
75
79
84
80
80
83
IV
2
53
57
60
64
59
64
62
69
72
74
76
82
82
82
V
12
32
39
42
47
53
57
60
61
63
67
68
71
74
74
VI
2
39
43
48
55
59
62
64
68
71
73
75
79
78
77
VII
3
50
55
58
59
65
68
70
72
73
75
77
80
80
81
VIII
4
41
47
50
51
56
61
62
63
64
66
67
73
72
72
IX
8
73
76
81
85
84
82
84
85
84
85
86
88
89
88
X
40
79
80
84
84
86
86
87
87
88
88
89
92
92
92
XI
9
64
65
70
77
71
79
81
79
83
88
87
76
75
76
XII
11
33
48
53
62
45
49
49
59
61
64
62
60
64
61
RM
19
24
28
37
41
44
50
49
51
57
60
62
69
70
70
Average
13
49
53
58
62
61
64
65
68
70
72
74
76
Note: The table includes the proportions of primary schools in each of Chile’s administrative regions that had
76
76
implemented the FDS program in at least one of its grade levels. RM=Santiago metropolitan region.
Source: Authors’ estimates using Ministry of Education FSD database.
30
Table 2. Mothers’ Characteristics of 8- to 13-Year-Olds with and without Younger Children, by Marital Status.
1990–2011
Single mothers
A.
B.
No younger children
With younger children
1990
2000
2011
1990
2000
2011
Labor outcomes
Labor participation
Worked last week
Hours last week
Background
Schooling
Poor
Age
Number of children 8 to 13
Number of children 14 to 17
Urban
Other adult female in the household
Number of people working at
household
Labor outcomes
Labor participation
Worked last week
Hours last week
Background
Schooling
Poor
Age
Number of children 8 to 13
0.68
0.78
0.79
0.56
0.64
0.68
(0.47) (0.42) (0.41) (0.50) (0.48) (0.47)
0.63
0.70
0.75
0.52
0.55
0.63
(0.48) (0.46) (0.43) (0.50) (0.50) (0.48)
50.75 45.55 40.00 43.04 44.56 34.54
(17.16) (16.04) (15.29) (19.87) (18.26) (16.09)
8.54
(4.35)
0.48
(0.50)
39.40
(7.06)
1.08
(0.52)
0.48
(0.71)
0.89
(0.31)
0.57
(0.50)
10.51
(4.12)
0.22
(0.42)
39.34
(6.57)
1.09
(0.53)
0.39
(0.63)
0.91
(0.29)
0.60
(0.49)
1.43
(1.13)
1.54
(1.05)
11.12
(3.48)
0.21
(0.41)
40.37
(7.21)
1.07
(0.49)
0.38
(0.58)
0.91
(0.28)
0.75
(0.43)
7.67
(3.98)
0.73
(0.44)
33.40
(5.84)
1.28
(0.54)
0.26
(0.56)
0.84
(0.36)
0.59
(0.49)
9.97
(3.57)
0.44
(0.50)
34.01
(5.12)
1.26
(0.53)
0.28
(0.51)
0.89
(0.32)
0.51
(0.50)
11.01
(3.05)
0.41
(0.49)
34.45
(5.64)
1.16
(0.39)
0.24
(0.48)
0.91
(0.28)
0.67
(0.47)
1.54
1.25
1.39
1.39
(1.05) (1.08) (1.09) (1.08)
Married mothers
No younger children
With younger children
0.32
0.43
0.51
0.25
0.34
0.41
(0.46) (0.49) (0.50) (0.43) (0.47) (0.49)
0.30
0.39
0.48
0.24
0.30
0.37
(0.46) (0.49) (0.50) (0.42) (0.46) (0.48)
46.36 42.01 39.06 44.09 41.94 37.13
(17.00) (17.33) (15.23) (19.49) (18.30) (16.70)
8.28
(4.20)
0.38
(0.49)
40.49
(6.49)
1.24
9.91
(3.89)
0.19
(0.40)
40.60
(6.21)
1.15
10.70
(3.67)
0.11
(0.32)
42.22
(6.60)
1.07
9.10
(3.89)
0.54
(0.50)
33.50
(5.10)
1.35
10.39
(3.50)
0.32
(0.47)
34.72
(4.95)
1.27
11.21
(3.35)
0.23
(0.42)
35.17
(5.48)
1.16
31
Number of children 14 to 17
Urban
Other adult female in the household
(0.67)
0.70
(0.79)
0.84
(0.37)
0.35
(0.48)
(0.61)
0.58
(0.67)
0.86
(0.35)
0.31
(0.46)
(0.55)
0.45
(0.60)
0.85
(0.36)
1.00
(0.00)
(0.60)
0.30
(0.58)
0.83
(0.38)
0.19
(0.39)
(0.52)
0.26
(0.51)
0.86
(0.35)
0.19
(0.40)
(0.38)
0.21
(0.45)
0.84
(0.37)
1.00
(0.00)
Number of people working at
household
1.65
1.62
1.78
1.38
1.43
1.56
(0.96) (0.88) (0.88) (0.76) (0.78) (0.84)
Source: Underlying data are from the Chilean socio-economic household survey (CASEN) and administrative data
from the Ministry of Education for 1990–2011.
32
Table 3. Effect of Extension of School Day in Maternal Labor Supply, Single and Married Mothers of 8–13 yearolds, without and with Younger Children (FSD Proportion of School)
No younger children
Coefficient on
share
(FSD)*Mother
8–13 (model 2)
comparison
group
Preinitiative
mean
(1996)
1
Coefficient
on share
model 1
2
a. Labor participation (=1)
0.74
(0.44)
b. Worked last week(=1)
c. Hours last week
With younger children
Coefficient on
share
(FSD)*Mother
8–13 (model 2)
comparison
group
(Has) 6–7 year
old
3
Preinitiative
mean
(1996)
5
Coefficient
on share
model 1
6
(Has) 6–7 year
old
7
0.04
(0.03)*
0.04
(0.01)***
0.68
(0.47)
0.03
(0.04)
-0.01
(0.02)
0.70
(0.46)
0.06
(0.03)**
0.04
(0.02)**
0.62
(0.49)
0.01
(0.03)
-0.02
(0.02)
44.45
(15.96)
-0.80
(1.43)
-1.61
(0.79)**
44.17
(16.90)
-0.89
(1.85)
-0.66
(0.86)
a. Labor participation (=1)
0.38
(0.49)
0.00
(0.02)
-0.01
(0.01)
0.30
(0.46)
-0.02
(0.01)
-0.02
(0.01)**
b. Worked last week (=1)
0.36
(0.48)
0.00
(0.01)
0.00
(0.01)
0.28
(0.45)
-0.01
(0.01)
-0.01
(0.01
c. Hours last week
43.39
(18.15)
1.14
(1.09)
-0.06
(0.69)
43.05
(18.53)
-2.35
(1.37)*
-0.1
(0.76)
A. Single women
B. Married women
Controls
Municipality fixed effects
Yes
Yes
Yes
Time fixed effect
Yes
Yes
Yes
Notes: Each entry in panels A–B, rows a–c, columns 2–5 represents a coefficient from a different regression. All the
regression include municipality fixed effects, year fixed effects, a vector of maternal background, and a vector of
municipality characteristics. All the regressions control for cluster by municipality, and standard error are consistent
for heteroskedasticity and error correlation within municipalities over time.
*** p < .01 ** p < .05 * p < .1
Source: Underlying data are from the Chilean socioeconomic household survey (CASEN) and administrative data
from the Ministry of Education for 1990–2011.
33
Yes
Yes
Table 4. Effect of Extension of School Day in Maternal Labor Supply, Single and Married mothers of 8–13 year
olds, without and with Younger Children (FSD Proportion of Enrollment)
No younger children
Coefficient on
share
(FSD)*Mother
8–13 (model 2)
comparison
group
Preinitiative
mean
(1996)
1
Coefficient
on share
model 1
2
a. Labor participation (=1)
0.74
(0.44)
b. Worked last week (=1)
c. Hours last week
With younger children
Coefficient on
share
(FSD)*Mother
8–13 (model 2)
comparison
group
(Has) 6–7 year
old
3
Preinitiative
mean
(1996)
5
Coefficient
on share
model 1
6
(Has) 6–7 year
old
7
0.01
(0.02)
0.04
(0.02)**
0.68
(0.47)
0.05
(0.03)
0.00
(0.02)
0.70
(0.46)
0.04
(0.02)
0.03
(0.02)**
0.62
(0.49)
0.02
(0.03)
-0.02
(0.02)
44.45
(15.96)
-1.31
(1.25)
-1.37
(0.82)*
44.17
(16.90)
0.66
(1.73)
-0.98
(0.91)
a. Labor participation (=1)
0.38
(0.49)
-0.02
(0.01)
-0.01
(0.01)
0.30
(0.46)
0.00
(0.01)
-0.01
(0.01)
b. Worked last week (=1)
0.36
(0.48)
-0.02
(0.01)
-0.01
(0.01)
0.28
(0.45)
0.00
(0.01)
-0.01
(0.01)
c. Hours last week
43.39
(18.15)
1.13
(1.08)
0.10
(0.73)
43.05
(18.53)
-1.05
(1.30)
-0.5
(0.85)
A. Single women
B. Married women
Controls
Municipality fixed effects
Yes
Yes
Yes
Time fixed effect
Yes
Yes
Yes
Notes: Each entry in panels A–B, rows a–c, columns 2–5 represents a coefficient from a different regression. All the
regression include municipality fixed effects, year fixed effects, a vector of maternal background, and a vector of
municipality characteristics. All the regressions control for cluster by municipality, and standard error are consistent
for heteroskedasticity and error correlation within municipalities over time.
*** p < .01 ** p < .05 * p < .1
Source: Underlying data are from the Chilean socioeconomic household survey (CASEN) and administrative data
from the Ministry of Education for 1990–2011.
34
Yes
Yes
APPENDIX
Figure A.4. Municipality Average of Female Labor Participation of Single Mothers of 8–13
year-olds and 6–7 year-olds, Younger Children
Source: Underlying data are from the Chilean socioeconomic household survey (CASEN) and
administrative data from the Ministry of Education for 1990–2011.
35
Figure A.5. Municipality Average of Employment Rate of Single Mothers of 8–13 year-olds and
6–7 years-olds, Younger Children
Source: Underlying data are from the Chilean socio-economic household survey (CASEN) and
administrative data from the Ministry of Education for 1990–2011.
36
Table A.5. Determinants of Full Day Schooling Reform Implementation
Variables
FSD schools
Municipality female labor participation
Municipality poverty rate
Municipality literacy rate
Urban
Constant
Observations
Number of municipalities
R-squared
Controls
Municipality fixed effect
Time fixed effect
FSD enrollment
-0.24
(0.07)***
0.05
(0.05)
-0.17
(0.11)
0.01
(0.03)
0.09
(0.03)***
2665
336
0.87
-0.14
(0.07)
0.13
(0.05)*
-0.1
(0.15)
0.01
(0.03)
0.02
(0.04)
2665
336
0.81
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
*** p < .01 ** p < .05 * p < .1
Source: Underlying data are from the Chilean socioeconomic household survey (CASEN) and administrative data
from the Ministry of Education for 1990–2011.
37
Table A.6. Time Trend
Single mother
Coefficient on share model 1
FSD schools FSD enrollment
No younger children
Labor participation
Actual FSD
Future FSD
Worked last week
Actual FSD
Future FSD
Hours last week
Actual FSD
0.07
(0.02)***
0.03
(0.03)
0.04
(0.02)**
0.03
(0.02)
0.08
(0.02)***
0.00
(0.03)
0.05
(0.02)***
0.03
(0.02)
-0.79
(1.13)
-0.10
(1.33)
0.11
(0.97)
Future FSD
-0.70
(1.21)
*** p < .01 ** p < .05 * p < .1Source: Underlying data are from the Chilean socioeconomic household survey
(CASEN) and administrative data from the Ministry of Education for 1990–2011.
38
Table A.7. Does the Extension of School Day Predict Labor Supply in Nontreated Groups? Single Mothers
FSD schools
Coefficient on share
model 1
(Has) 0–5
(Has) 6–7
year-old
year-old
FSD enrollment
Coefficient on share
model 1
(Has) 0–5 (Has) 6–7
year-old
year-old
A. Single women
a. Labor participation (=1)
-0.01
(0.03)
-0.03
(0.07)
0.01
(0.03)
-0.02
(0.06)
b. Worked last week(=1)
0.02
(0.03)
0.01
(0.06)
0.03
(0.03)
-0.01
(0.06)
c. Hours last week
-0.66
(1.48)
4.49
(2.99)
-1.83
(1.36)
4.3
(2.71)
Controls
Municipality fixed
effects
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Time fixed effect
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Notes: Each entry in panels A–B, rows a–c, columns 2–5 represents a coefficient from a different regression. All the
regression include municipality fixed effects, year fixed effects, a vector of maternal background, and a vector of
municipality characteristics. All the regressions control for cluster by municipality, and standard error are consistent
for heteroskedasticity and error correlation within municipalities over time.
*** p < .01 ** p < .05 * p < .1Source: Underlying data are from the Chilean socio-economic household
survey (CASEN) and administrative data from the Ministry of Education for 1990–2011.
39