P.K. Ozili
Non-performing loans in European systemic and non-systemic banks
Peterson K. Ozili, PhD.
Abstract
I examine the behaviour of non-performing loans in European systemic and non-systemic
banks. The distinction between systemic banks (GSIBs) and non-systemic banks (non GSIBs) is
driven by policy reasons. The findings reveal that more profitable banks witness higher nonperforming loans regardless of whether they are systemic or non-systemic. Systemic banks
have fewer non-performing loans during economic booms and during periods of increased
lending while non-systemic banks experience higher NPLs during periods of increased lending.
I also observe that European non-systemic banks that exceed regulatory capital requirements
have higher NPLs. In the post-2007 financial crisis period, the NPL of systemic banks is
negatively associated with the economic cycle which imply that the NPL of systemic banks is
procyclical with the state of the economy, and the NPL of systemic banks are positively
associated with loan supply and bank profitability. On the other hand, the NPLs of non-systemic
banks is negatively associated with regulatory capital ratios, and is positively associated with
bank profitability for non-systemic banks in the post-2007 financial crisis period. The findings
have implications.
JEL codes: C33, E44, G21
Keywords: credit risk, non-performing loans, systemic banks, systemic risk, impaired loans,
asset quality; European banks, Europe, bank profitability.
This Version: 2019
I thank the editors, and two anonymous reviewers for constructive feedback
The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the
institution(s) the author is affiliated with.
Cite as: “Ozili, P.K. (2019). Nonperforming loans in European systemic and non-systemic banks.
Journal of Financial Economic Policy.”
1
P.K. Ozili
1. Introduction
This study investigates the behaviour of non-performing loans, focusing on the relationship
between non-performing loans (NPLs) and the economic cycle for European systemic and nonsystemic banks. The distinction between systemic banks (GSIBs) and non-systemic (non
GSIBs) is driven by policy reasons. In Europe, banking policy makers have growing concern for
high non-performing loans in the EU banking sector due to the interdependence between bank
financing and economic growth in the European Union (European Commission, 2013, 2014). Also,
high levels of NPLs in the European banking sector pose significant risks to financial stability in
the EU. The current levels of NPLs piled up in several parts of the EU banking sector are the
aftermath of the global financial crisis and sovereign crisis in recent years (European
Commission, 2018). Aiyar et al (2015), in an IMF study, show that non-performing loans in the
European Union (EU) stood at about €1 trillion (equivalent to over 9 percent of the GDP of the
entire EU region) at the end of 2014 - more than double the level in 2009. They point out that some
structural obstacles in the EU banking system discouraged EU banks from addressing their
non-performing loan problems, such as prudential supervision issues, legal obstacles,
distressed debt markets, informational obstacles, tax and other obstacles.
In addition to these issues, the credit risk of a systemic financial institution in the financial
system is crucial for financial system stability. A financial system regulator should be worried
if the top ten largest industry obligors or debtors are indebted to systemic banks especially
when these loans are non-performing. When high NPLs are concentrated among systemic
financial institutions, such losses will be charged against bank profits and can erode bank
capital, and the loss of bank capital can lead of the collapse of any financial institution. In recent
times, systemic European banks that have serious NPL problems often seek regulatory
forbearance from regulators which is a way for them to have more time to deal with their NPL
problems.
This study focus on the behaviour of NPLs in European systemic and non-systemic banks
because of the systemic risk that distressed too-big-to-fail financial institutions may pose to
the entire financial system. The collapse of a systemic bank can collapse the entire financial
system, and large non-performing loans can trigger the failure of a bank. Excess nonperforming loans in systemic banks can (i) send the wrong signal to outsiders about the stability
of other banks connected to systemic banks (ii) and can bring down any financial institutions if
the losses completely wipe out the capital of the bank. Therefore, it is in the best interest of EU
policy makers to understand this signalling problem, and they need to address the rising NPL
issues in the European banking sector.
One way to understand the behaviour of NPLs is to first identify the determinants of NPLs in
banks. Prior studies have identified some determinants such as business cycle fluctuation,
regulatory capital ratios, loan growth, etc. (see Nkusu 2011; Louzis et al, 2012; Klein 2013; Ozili,
2019, etc.). The next question is: do these determinants have similar or dissimilar impact on
systemic versus non-systemic banks? If yes, how and why? Under what economic (or bankspecific) conditions do systemic banks experience higher or fewer NPLs, as well as for nonsystemic banks.
2
P.K. Ozili
This study adopts the Financial Stability Board (FSB) and Basel Committee for Banking
Supervision (BCBS)’s distinction between systemic banks (GSIBs) and (non-GSIBs). This
classification is used to analyse the behaviour of nonperforming loans in the two bank groups.
I analyse European banks over the 2004 to 2013 period, and find that more profitable banks
witness higher non-performing loans. Systemic banks have fewer non-performing loans
during economic booms and during periods of increased lending while non-systemic banks
experience higher NPLs during periods of increased lending. The findings also reveal that
systemic banks keep higher regulatory capital ratios when they expect higher NPLs while nonsystemic banks that exceed regulatory capital requirements experience higher NPLs.
The study contributes to the literature in the following way. Firstly, this study contributes to the
recent literature on the determinants of non-performing loan (Espinoza and Prasad, 2010;
Fofack, 2005; Louzis et al, 2012; Ozili, 2019). This study adds to this literature by analysing the link
between non-performing loans and the business cycle, focussing on systemic banks and nonsystemic banks in Europe. An investigation into the behaviour of NPLs in systemic and nonsystemic banks is useful for micro-prudential regulation to help EU policy makers understand
the implication of large non-performing exposures in systemic and non-systemic banks.
Secondly, the analysis in this paper is useful to provide additional insights on the link between
problem loans and various states of the economy. Thirdly, this study can help policy makers
understand how non-performing loans build-up in systemic financial institutions, and can help
policymakers to devise pro-active policy response to quickly address the NPL issues in
systemic banks in Europe.
The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 discuss the literature review on
systemic risk measures and the determinants of non-performing loans. Section 3 presents the
data. Section 4 discuss the research design and methodology. Section 5 discuss the empirical
results. Section 6 concludes.
2. Related Literature
2.1. Measuring Systemic risk
A widely used measure of systemic risk is the conditional value-at-risk (CoVaR) proposed by
Adrian and Brunnermeier (2011) which capture risk spill-overs among financial institutions. The
CoVar is the value-at-risk (VaR) of the financial system conditional on one institution being in
distress (Karimalis and Nomikos, 2018). Another measure of systemic risk is the ‘distressed
insurance premium’ (DIP) measure. The distressed insurance premium (DIP) is a hypothetical
insurance premium to cover losses that exceed a certain threshold of banks’ total liabilities
(Huang et al, 2009; Huang et al, 2012). The higher the losses or risk of the bank, the higher the
distressed insurance premium. Black et al (2013) applied the DIP approach to evaluate systemic
risk in the European banking sector. The third measure of systemic risk is the CATFIN. CATFIN
is an aggregate measure of systemic risk in the financial sector. It measures the detrimental
effects of financial risk taking by the overall financial sector on the macroeconomy (see Allen
et al 2012). The CATFIN focus on forecasting macroeconomic developments in the economy
when measuring systemic risk. (Karimalis and Nomikos, 2018). CATFIN is estimated using both
value-at-risk (VaR) and expected shortfall (ES) methodologies, each of which are estimated
3
P.K. Ozili
using three approaches: one non-parametric and two different parametric specifications. In
comparison, the CATFIN attempts to predict or forecast the macroeconomic systemic risk in the
financial sector while the CoVaR and DIP only measure the cross-sectional (bank-level)
differences in banks’ contribution to systemic risk (Allen et al, 2012).
Another systemic risk measure is the component expected shortfall (Banulescu and
Dumitrescu, 2015). The component expected shortfall (CES) decompose the risk of the
aggregate financial system into several components while accounting for firm characteristics.
The CES assess the contribution of a firm to systemic risk at a precise date but also to forecast
its contribution over a certain period (Banulescu and Dumitrescu, 2015). The CES is a hybrid
measure that combines the ‘Too-Interconnected-To Fail’ and the ‘Too-Big-To-Fail’ logics. Also,
CES relies only on publicly available daily data and is similar to the popular ‘Marginal Expected
Shortfall’ measure. Another measure of systemic risk is the systemic expected shortfall (SES)
by Acharya et al. (2010). The SES is the expected capital shortage of an individual firm
conditional on a substantial reduction of the capitalization of the entire system. Under a number
of assumptions, SES can be expressed as a linear combination of marginal expected shortfall
(MES) and leverage where the parameters of such a combination are not known in general
(Brownlees and Engle, 2012). Another measure is the ‘SRISK’ which measures the amount of
capital an institution would need to survive a capital shortage in the financial system. It is the
amount of capital that a firm would need to survive when the entire system is undercapitalised
(Brownlees and Engle, 2012). Similarly, aggregate SRISK is the total amount of capital that the
government would need to provide to bailout the financial system in the event of a crisis
(Brownlees and Engle, 2012). Other measures include the marginal expected shortfall, etc.
Finally, systemic risk can be measured by whether a financial institution is a global systemically
important financial institution or whether it is a non-global systemically important financial
institution. The Financial Stability Board (FSB) in 2013 developed a classification for identifying
financial institutions that pose the greatest risks to the global financial system. They proposed
a G-SIB classification which classify all financial institutions according to their systemic risk
contribution to the global financial system. The criteria to determine whether a financial
institution is a GSIBs is based on a financial institution (FI)’s size, interconnectedness,
complexity, non-substitutability and cross-border activities (or global reach). This study
adopts the G-SIB classification to analyse the behaviour of non-performing loans in banks.
2.2. NPLs and Systemic Risk Regulation – Theoretical Perspectives
Prior to the distinction between G-SIBs vs non-GSIBs by the FSB/BCBS, the Basel risk-capital
regulation was adopted to mitigate credit risk in banks (Benink and Wihlborg, 2002; Basel II,
2004). Risk-capital regulation is achieved through the allocation of capital for all risky and
significant activities in financial institutions (Shrieves and Dahl, 1992; Besanko and Kanatas,
1996). For NPLs, the incurred loss provisioning model has traditionally been used to allocate
loan loss provisions as a cushion to absorb nonperforming loans when they become doubtful,
substandard or lost. Generally, the use of provisioning and risk-capital has been a fundamental
principle of Basel regulations even though critics argue that risk-capital and provisioning are
two sub-optimal solutions to mitigate bank risks because they only focus on risks arising from
banking activities rather than focusing on the root cause of risks in banks. However, there are
some disagreement in the literature regarding the risk-sensitivity of risk-capital regulation.
4
P.K. Ozili
For instance, Bleck (2018) argues that when a bank is better informed about its risk than the
regulator, any regulation designed to regulate banks would be subject to the Lucas
critique. Bleck (2018), building on the Lucas critique, argue that banks know and understand
their risk better than regulators, therefore, bank risk-capital regulations are a second-best
regulation and might be insensitive to risk. Bleck (2018) supports a leverage ratio-based
regulation, and suggest that the leverage ratio of financial institutions might be a better
measure for systemic riskiness than risk-based capital regulation.
2.3. Empirical Literature
High NPL ratios can affect bank's short-term and long-term performance through two main
channels. First, NPLs generate losses for banks thereby reducing bank profitability and can
diminish bank capital when non-performing loans are written-off. In severe cases, high NPLs
can make a bank become insolvent. Secondly, high NPLs tie up significant amount of banks'
resources, both human and financial, making it difficult for banks to provide new credit to
businesses and individuals (European Commission, 2018).
Studies linking credit risk to the state of the economy are not new in the literature (e.g. Carey,
1998; Ruckes, 2004; Salas and Saurina, 2002; Fofack, 2005; Louzis et al, 2012; Ozili and Thankom,
2018). These studies show that in good economic times, banks extend credit to low quality
debtors in order to generate higher revenue because the risk of financial distress is usually low
during boom years. However, when a recession sets in, non-performing loans are expected to
increase for banks. Pesaran (2006) examine the link between changes in credit portfolio and
the macroeconomy, and observe that loan default probabilities are strongly driven by the link
between firms and the economic cycle, implying that historical data on default probabilities can
help predict the likelihood of future non-performing loans. However, data on default
probabilities may be difficult to assess for decision making by outsiders. Beck et al (2013) also
confirm that data on default probabilities are largely unavailable publicly.
Other studies also use non-performing loan as a measure of bank credit risk. Nkusu (2011), in a
panel data analyses, examine the relationship between banks’ loan portfolio quality and macro
financial vulnerabilities for 26 countries during 1998 to 2009. Nkusu find a positive relationship
between asset quality and the macroeconomic variables used in the study. Glen and
Mondragón-Vélez (2011) examine banks from 22 developed countries from 1996 to 2008 and
observe that loan loss provisions (a proxy for credit risk) is driven by real GDP growth as well
as, low bank capitalisation and private sector leverage. Similarly, Pesola (2005) find a strong
link between credit risk and the macroeconomic environment while Drehmann (2005) show
that the link between credit risk and macroeconomic shocks may be non-linear. Cihak (2007)
and Wezel et al (2014) in their stress-testing analyses examine the resilience of bank balance
sheet to adverse economic conditions. These studies suggest that credit risk is strongly linked
to changes in the economic cycle.
Much of the studies that link credit risk or non-performing loans to the state of the economy are
mainly country specific studies. For instance, Salas and Saurina (2002) investigate the
determinants of problem loans in Spanish commercial and savings banks while controlling for
other factors such as capital ratio, bank size net interest margin and market power. They find
that problem loans are strongly linked to the economic cycle (i.e., real GDP growth).
5
P.K. Ozili
Quagliarello (2007) observe that the state of the economy is a determinant of non-performing
loans for Italian banks. Klein (2013) also document a strong negative relationship between nonperforming loans and the economic cycle proxy by change in gross domestic product for banks
in Central, Eastern and South- Eastern Europe (CESEE) countries. Fofack (2005) find similar
evidence for banks in sub-Saharan African countries while Louzis et al (2012) find similar
evidence in the Greek banking sector. Prior literature has not focussed on the link between nonperforming loans and the economic cycle for systemic banks compared to non-systemic banks.
This present study, in contrast, examine two categories of European banks: systemic banks and
non-systemic banks.
3. Data
Pooled cross-section and time series balance sheet data for European banks were collected
from the Van Dijk Bankscope database for 16 counties in Europe: United Kingdom, Germany,
Ireland, Luxemburg, Norway, Denmark, Finland, Greece, Portugal, Belgium, Netherland,
Sweden, Spain, France, Italy and Austria. The sample period covers 2004 to 2013. The rationale
for the choice of sample period is to allows us cross-check how the 2007-2008 financial crisis
affected systemic and non-systemic banks and also how they have changed since the crisis.
Also, since the 2004 to 2013 period precede the date the European Central Bank (ECB) assumed
responsibility for the Euro Area banking sector in November 4, 2014, the current sample period
will allow us to capture the behaviour of NPLs before the European Central Bank (ECB)
intervention.
To control for the 2008 financial crisis, 2008 bank-year observations were eliminated so that
the impact of the financial crisis would not affect the validity of the inference(s). A binary dummy
variable is introduced to distinguish between the pre-crisis and the post-crisis period. Data for
real gross domestic product growth rate, a proxy for economic cycle, is obtained from the World
Economic Forum database. The ∆GDP data allows us to detect whether the magnitude of nonperforming loans and its link to the economic cycle during the period warranted the full
intervention of the European Central Bank in the first place.
The European banks are then divided into systemic (G-SIBs) and non-systemic banks (non-GSIBs). The distinction between systemic and non-systemic banks is based on the joint Financial
Stability Board (FSB) and Basel BCBS’s classification of banks as global systemicallyimportant banks (G-SIBs). Banks that are not classified as global systemic banks in 2013 yearend are considered to be non-systemic banks. This is the only distinction made between banks
in this study. The resulting final sample yields 231 European bank sample containing 41 systemic
banks and 190 non-systemic banks as shown in Appendix A1. All sample banks have December
31 fiscal year ends. The data is an unbalanced panel.
6
P.K. Ozili
4. Methodology
The multivariate model employed to investigate the relationship between non-performing
loans and the economic cycle is a variation of the model used by Beck et al (2013) and Ozili (2019)
who examine the determinants of non-performing loans. The functional form of the model in
this study is given as
𝑁𝑃𝐿𝑖𝑡 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1𝐿𝑂𝐴𝑁𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽2𝐶𝐴𝑅𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽3𝐸𝐵𝑇𝑃𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝐺𝐷𝑃𝑖, 𝑡 − 1 + 𝛽5𝐺𝐷𝑃𝑖𝑡
+ 𝑃𝐸𝑅𝐼𝑂𝐷𝑑𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑖𝑒𝑠 + 𝑒𝑖𝑡.
Where
NPL = Non-performing loan to gross loan ratio for bank i at time t.
LOAN = Change in gross loan outstanding for bank i at time t
CAR = ratio of Tier 1 capital divided by risk-weighted assets for bank i at time t.
EBTP = ratio of earnings before tax and loan loss allowance divided by total assets for bank i at
time t.
∆GDP = Real gross domestic product growth rate.
The non-performing loans to gross loans ratio is the dependent variable and the measure of
asset quality in the study. The explanatory variables are LOAN, CAR, EBTP and ∆GDP. The LOAN
variable is introduced to control for the influence of bank lending on non-performing loans. A
negative sign for the LOAN coefficient is expected. The second explanatory variable is
regulatory capital ratio. Banks that keep higher regulatory capital ratios will restrain from
engaging in risky lending thereby minimising the amount of problem loans in their balance
sheet, which improves asset quality. When this is the case, a negative relationship between NPL
and CAR is expected. However, a positive relationship may be expected if banks that engage in
risky lending anticipate their high risks and keep more regulatory capital to compensate for
their high risk activities. The third explanatory variable is real gross domestic product growth
rate (∆GDP). The real gross domestic product growth rate variable measures the impact of
economic cycle fluctuation on bank non-performing loans. A negative relationship is predicted
between NPLs and ∆GDP because NPLs tend to be higher (lower) during recessions (booms).
The fourth explanatory variable is the earnings variable (EBTP). The earnings before tax and
provisions (EBTP) variable measures the association between non-performing loans and bank
earnings before loan loss provisions. A negative relationship between NPL and EBTP is
expected because high NPLs will be written-off as losses which will reduce bank profit.
Further tests were conducted: to determine whether the relationship between asset quality
(non-performing loans) and earnings is stronger when earnings (before loan loss adjustment)
are negative or high (substantial). To test for this, two dummy variables are introduced into the
model: ‘POS’ dummy variable that take the value ‘1’ when EBTP is above-the-median EBTP ratio
and zero otherwise; and ‘NEG’ dummy variable take the value ‘1’ when EBTP is a negative number
and zero otherwise. These two dummies are then interacted with the EBTP variable. Inference
is then drawn from the relationship between NPLs and ‘NEG*EBTP’ and ‘POS*EBTP earnings
interaction terms. Additionally, I test whether banks with above 8% tier 1 capital report higher
7
P.K. Ozili
or fewer non-performing loans. This test allows us to determine whether nonperforming loans
improves with sufficient or insufficient Tier 1 capital ratios. To test for this, the ‘WELL’ dummy
variable is introduced into the model which take the value ‘1’ if CAR is above 8% and zero
otherwise. The ‘WELL’ dummy is then interacted with the ‘CAR’ variable. Finally, I test whether a
positive increase in bank lending is significantly associated with higher nonperforming loans.
To test for this, I take the natural logarithm of the LOAN variable to capture only the positive
increase in outstanding loans over the period. Taking the natural logarithm of the LOAN variable
ln(LOAN) systematically eliminates the negative observations in the time series distribution for
the LOAN variables but retains all the positive observations of the LOAN variable. Inference is
then drawn from the relationship between NPL and ln(LOAN).
The model is estimated using panel data regression. The method of analysis follows a dynamic
specification of the model. The dynamic model includes the lagged dependent variable as an
explanatory variable in order to capture the persistence of NPL growth over time. Also, the
introduction of the lagged dependent variable into the model makes it inappropriate to estimate
the model using fixed effect least square regression approach. The Generalised-Method of
Moments (GMM) method with instrumental variables is considered to be more appropriate to
estimate the model. I use the Generalised Method of Moments (GMM) regression estimation
based on the approach of Arellano and Bond (1991). Beck et al (2013) and Ozili and Thankom (2018)
also use this approach. The AR (1) and AR (2) are Arellano-Bond GMM tests for first and second
order serial-correlation of the residuals. In the analysis, the number of instruments is below
the number of cross-section. The next section presents the results.
5. Empirical Results
5.1. Descriptive statistics and Correlations
Table 1 provides the summary of the descriptive statistics for systemic and non-systemic banks
for the 2004 to 2013 period. Regarding non-performing loans, NPLs are, on average, 4.51% for
the full sample, 3.46% for systemic banks and 4.76% for non-systemic banks, respectively,
implying that systemic banks report fewer NPLs, on average, and might suggest that systemic
banks have better asset quality than non-systemic banks. Improved credit risk management by
systemic banks can lower their credit risk exposure and reduce the amount of regulatory
capital (Tier 1 capital) they need to set aside for credit risks. Unsurprisingly, systemic banks
report a low CAR (10.48%) compared to non-systemic banks (11.18%). Regarding credit growth
(LOAN), LOANs are 5.34% for the entire bank sample and systemic banks record lower growth
in loans at 4.38% while non-systemic banks have about 5.55%. Finally, the difference of means
between systemic and non-systemic banks is low.
8
P.K. Ozili
Table 1: Descriptive statistics: Systemic vs Non Systemic Banks
Variable
Full Sample
Systemic
Non-Systemic Difference
Banks
Banks
of Means
Mean
S.D
Mean
S.D
Mean
S.D
NPL
4.513
5.44
3.456 2.989 4.762
5.848
-1.306
LOAN
5.340 16.726 4.384 18.06 5.550 16.418
-1.166
CAR
11.053 4.819 10.481 2.851
11.183
5.117
-0.702
EBTP
0.008 0.009 0.009 0.008 0.008
0.010
0.001
No of Banks
23
41
190
*S. D - Standard Deviation. Table 1 report the descriptive statistics obtained
from 231 bank samples from 16 European countries. Data cover the period
2004 to 2013. NPL is non-performing loans to gross loan. EBTP is earnings
before taxes and provision to total assets. LOAN is the change in gross loan.
CAR is bank capital divided by risk-weighted assets. ΔGDP is real gross
domestic product growth rate.
Table 2 A and B reports the Pearson correlation coefficients and the associated p-values. Table
2a reports the correlation results for systemic banks. NPLs are not significantly correlated
with EBTP. LOAN is significant and negatively correlated with NPLs for systemic banks,
implying that systemic banks that increase loan supply experience fewer non-performing
loans. CAR is significant and positively correlated with NPLs for systemic banks, implying that
well-capitalised systemic banks experience higher problem loans. ∆GDP is negative and
significantly correlated with NPLs, implying that problem loans are higher during bad times.
Table 2B reports the correlation results for non-systemic banks. NPLs are not significantly
correlated with EBTP. LOAN is significant and negatively correlated with NPLs for nonsystemic banks, implying that non-systemic banks that increase loan supply experience
fewer non-performing loans. CAR is significant and negatively correlated with NPLs for nonsystemic banks, implying that well-capitalised non-systemic banks experience higher
problem loans. ∆GDP is negative and significantly correlated with NPLs, implying that nonsystemic banks experience high problem loans during bad times. Overall, the correlation
coefficients in Table 2 A and B are sufficiently low to be concerned about multi-collinearity in
the study.
9
P.K. Ozili
2A: Correlation for Systemic Banks
Table 2a report the correlation matrix for systemic banks.
All bank level variables remain as previously defined. ***,
** and * represent significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level,
respectively. P-values are reported in parentheses.
Variable
NPL
NPL
1.000
LOAN -0.372***
(0.000)
LOAN
ΔGDP
EBTP
CAR
1.000
ΔGDP -0.245*** 0.321***
(0.000) (0.000)
0.262***
(0.000)
1.000
EBTP
0.009
(0.893)
-0.012
(0.862)
1.000
CAR
0.187*** -0.394*** -0.253*** -0.335*** 1.000
(0.005) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Table 2B: Correlation for Non-Systemic Banks
Table 2a report the correlation matrix for non G-SIBs. All
bank level variables remain as previously defined. ***, **
and * represent significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level,
respectively. P-values are reported in parentheses.
Variable
NPL
NPL
1.000
LOAN -0.221***
(0.000)
LOAN
CAR
-0.032
(0.334)
EBTP
CAR
1.000
ΔGDP -0.279*** 0.234***
(0.000) (0.000)
EBTP
ΔGDP
1.000
0.246*** 0.144***
(0.000) (0.000)
1.000
-0.065** -0.248*** -0.041
(0.047) (0.000) (0.204)
-0.051
(0.119)
1.000
10
P.K. Ozili
5.2. Regression Result
5.2.1. Full Sample Analysis
Column 1 of Table 3 and 4 report the dynamic (Arellano-Bond) regression estimations for
systemic banks and non-systemic banks. ∆GDP coefficient is negatively significant, implying
that systemic banks witness fewer NPLs during economic booms. But, the result is not
significant for non-systemic banks. This finding is similar with the result of Glen and
Mondragón-Vélez (2011) and Nkusu (2011) who show a link between non-performing loan and
∆GDP. The lagged GDP growth coefficient is negatively significant for both systemic and nonsystemic banks, indicating that lagged GDP growth is inversely and significantly associated
with growth of NPLs for both banks. This implies that banks’ asset quality deteriorates with a
lag in response to negative economic growth possibly due to the difficulty of debtors to meet
their obligation during bad economic times. The earnings coefficient (EBTP) reports a negative
sign for both banks although the result is weakly significant for systemic banks and
insignificant for non-systemic banks. This implies that NPLs are likely to impair the earnings of
systemic banks than non-systemic European banks, however, the results do not show a strong
link between NPLs and earnings before loan loss allowance (EBTP). Also, loan growth (LOAN)
has a negative and significant impact on the non-performing loans of systemic banks. This
suggest that systemic banks lend to less-risky borrowers, which leads to lower NPLs, and
imply that systemic banks probably have a strong and prudent credit risk management system
compared to non-systemic banks. Similarly, a negative relationship between NPLs and LOAN
is observed for non-systemic banks but this relationship is insignificant. Finally, the CAR
coefficient is positive and significant for systemic banks but is insignificant for non-systemic
banks, indicating that systemic banks keep higher regulatory capital when they expect higher
NPLs.
5.2.2. Behaviour of NPLs after the global financial crisis
Here, I introduce the ‘POST’ dummy variable that take the value ‘1’ for the post-financial crisis
period and ‘0’ otherwise. I interact the ‘POST’ variable with the NPL determinants in the model
to determine their effect on NPLs. The result is reported in column 2 to 5 of Table 3 and 4. For
systemic banks, NPL has a significant and negative relationship with the economic cycle in the
post-financial crisis period, implying that systemic banks tend to have higher NPLs during
economic recessions in the post-crisis period. On the other hand, NPL has a significant and
positive relationship with earnings and bank lending in the post crisis period, implying that
NPLs are higher among systemic banks that are profitable and among systemic banks with
higher loan supply in the post-crisis period. For non-systemic banks, NPL has a significant
and negative relationship with the regulatory capital in the post-financial crisis period,
implying that non-systemic banks with lower regulatory capital have higher NPLs in the postcrisis period. On the other hand, NPL has a significant and positive relationship with earnings,
implying that NPLs are higher among non-systemic banks that are profitable in the post-crisis
period. Overall, the post-crisis findings for systemic banks shows that regulatory capital
(CAR) did not have a significant effect on NPLs, and suggests that risk-capital regulation might
be insensitive to risk in systemic banks, which supports the argument of Bleck (2018).
11
P.K. Ozili
Variable
NPLt-1
EBTP
LOAN
CAR
∆GDP
∆GDPt-1
CRISIS
CRISIS*∆GDP
CRISIS*EBTP
CRISIS*CAR
CRISIS*LOAN
Table 3. European Systemic Banks
Arellano-Bond (1991) GMM estimation
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
0.602***
0.567***
0.583***
0.540
(9.13)
(11.04)
(10.49)
(9.16)
-30.509*
15.02
-63.95***
15.33
(-1.69)
(0.74)
(-3.49)
(0.82)
-0.026*** -0.028*** -0.024*** -0.026***
(-3.91)
(-2.59)
(-3.57)
(-3.33)
0.112*
(1.72)
-0.142***
(-2.88)
-0.353***
(-5.47)
0.06
(1.18)
0.931***
(5.93)
-0.144*
(-1.84)
4.620***
(6.47)
-0.928***
(-7.54)
-0.006
(-0.09)
-0.003
(-0.04)
-0.128*
(-1.75)
1.247**
(2.04)
-0.065
(-0.69)
0.042
(0.56)
-0.075
(-0.97)
2.783***
(3.36)
(5)
0.515***
(8.97)
0.667
(0.04)
0.035***
(-5.62)
-0.045
(-0.75)
-0.027
(-0.31)
-0.095
(-1.23)
2.210**
(2.42)
102.06***
(5.01)
0.025
(0.31)
0.022*
(1.81)
J-Statistic
23.01
21.13
21.75
18.62
17.67
P(J-statistic)
0.15
0.13
0.11
0.23
0.28
No of instrument
30
30
30
30
30
AR(1)
0.007
0.011
0.013
0.012
0.023
AR (2)
0.899
0.199
0.236
0.407
0.475
P-values in parentheses. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%
levels, respectively. Robust standard error is included. The number of
instruments is always kept below the number of groups. AR (1) and AR (2) are
the Arellano-Bond tests for first and second order autocorrelation of the
residuals, indicating that there is no serial correlation. NPL = Non-performing
loan to gross loan for bank. LOAN = change in gross loan outstanding for bank.
CAR = tier1 capital divided by risk-weighted assets for bank. EBTP = earnings
before tax and credit risk allowance for bank. ∆GDP = Gross domestic product
growth rate. ∆GDPt-1 = one-year lagged gross domestic product growth rate.
CRISIS = dummy variable that take the value of 1 for year-2009, 2010, 2011, 2012
and 2013 and zero otherwise
12
P.K. Ozili
Variable
NPLt-1
EBTP
LOAN
CAR
∆GDP
∆GDPt-1
CRISIS
CRISIS*∆GDP
CRISIS*EBTP
CRISIS*CAR
CRISIS*LOAN
Table 4. European Non Systemic Banks
Arellano-Bond (1991) GMM estimation
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
0.766***
0.742*** 0.731***
0.759***
(12.59)
(9.63)
(10.50)
(10.40)
-33.554
-25.13
-340.12*** -43.73
(-1.45)
(-1.03)
(-3.56)
(-1.50)
-0.009
-0.019
-0.013
-0.019
(-0.77)
(-1.39)
(-0.72)
(-0.93)
-0.060
-0.216*
0.133
1.373***
(-0.69)
(-1.67)
(0.83)
(3.94)
0.183
0.133
0.162
0.152
(1.57)
(0.72)
(1.29)
(0.84)
-0.668*** -0.614***
-0.607***
0.648*** (-5.81)
(-4.79)
(-5.32)
(-5.60)
3.138
-10.469*** 5.730
(1.20)
(-2.68)
(1.38)
0.342
(1.04)
297.23***
(3.30)
-1.279***
(-4.14)
(5)
0.799***
(11.38)
-35.128
(-1.56)
-0.012
(-0.35)
-0.068
(-0.63)
0.170
(1.22)
-0.612
(-4.72)
2.522
(0.96)
0.003
(-0.05)
J-Statistic
33.03
30.69
24.10
21.59
31.63
P(J-statistic)
0.06
0.06
0.23
0.36
0.05
No of instrument 35
35
35
35
35
AR(1)
0.0001
0.0001
0.0003
0.0004
0.001
AR (2)
0.766
0.945
0.846
0.589
0.638
P-values in parentheses. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%
levels, respectively. Robust standard error is included. The number of
instruments is always kept below the number of groups. AR (1) and AR (2) are
the Arellano-Bond tests for first and second order autocorrelation of the
residuals, indicating that there is no serial correlation. NPL = Non-performing
loan to gross loan for bank. LOAN = change in gross loan outstanding for bank.
CAR = tier1 capital divided by risk-weighted assets for bank. EBTP = earnings
before tax and credit risk allowance for bank. ∆GDP = Gross domestic product
growth rate. ∆GDPt-1 = one-year lagged gross domestic product growth rate.
CRISIS = dummy variable that take the value of 1 for year-2009, 2010, 2011, 2012
and 2013 and zero otherwise.
13
P.K. Ozili
5.3. Further Analyses
5.3.1. Size of Earnings Effect
Next, I analyse the behaviour of NPLs when banks have high profits or high loses. To test
whether non-performing loans are significantly associated with earnings when both banks
expect losses or high earnings, the NEG and POS dummy variables are interacted with EBTP.
The result is reported in Column 1 and 5 of Table 5. The results show that NPLs are positive and
strongly linked with EBTP when both banks are more profitable. This implies that, in the face of
high non-performing loans (i.e., declining asset quality), both banks remain profitable (before
adjustment for provisions) while column 2 and 6 show that NPLs are fewer for non-systemic
banks when they experience higher losses, and insignificant for systemic banks.
5.3.2. Higher Regulatory Capital Effect
Next, I analyse the behaviour of NPLs when banks have sufficient (regulatory) capital. To test
whether bank non-performing loans is significantly associated with Tier 1 capital when the
banks have sufficient Tier 1 regulatory capital ratio (i.e., above 8% tier 1 capital), WELL dummy
variable is interacted with the CAR variable. Column 3 report a negative relationship between
NPLs and WELL*CAR for systemic banks but this relationship is not significant for systemic
banks. One possible explanation for the weak relationship could be due to the fact that Tier 1
capital for systemic banks may be used more extensively to mitigate other risks (such as
market risk, interest rate etc.) rather than to mitigate only credit risk. On the other hand, Column
7 report a positive and significant relationship between NPLs and above-8% Tier 1 capital for
non-systemic banks. This indicates that non-systemic banks with sufficient regulatory capital
experience higher NPLs.
5.3.3. Excess Credit Supply Effect
Next, I analyse the behaviour of NPLs during periods of excess credit supply, or periods of
increased lending. To test whether bank non-performing loan is significantly associated with
positive credit growth, the natural logarithm of the LOAN variable is used. Inference is drawn
based on the relationship between ln(LOAN) and NPLs. Column 4 and 8 report a negative
relationship for systemic banks and a positive relationship for non-systemic banks,
respectively, and both are significant at 10% level. The former indicates that increased bank
lending for systemic banks leads to improved asset quality (fewer NPLs). This confirms the
earlier result in Table 2. While the positive relationship for non-systemic banks indicate that
non-systemic banks experience higher NPLs in response to increased lending among nonsystemic banks. This suggest that non-systemic banks engage in imprudent lending to
borrowers which possibly leads to higher default by borrowers.
14
P.K. Ozili
Table 5 - Sensitivity Analysis - Regression
Systemic Banks
Non-systemic
Variable
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
NPLt-1
0.583***
(7.56)
0.586***
(8.49)
0.701***
(9.62)
0.743***
(9.68)
0.794***
(12.48)
0.863*
(1.87)
0.697***
(8.77)
0.994***
(11.13)
EBTP
-163.78***
(-4.03)
-5.256
(-0.25)
-38.220
(-1.47)
-56.36**
(-2.01)
-85.396***
(-3.59)
184.42***
(2.52)
-6.199
(-0.16)
-69.024
(-1.14)
LOAN
-0.035***
(-4.97)
-0.020***
(-2.73)
-0.019***
(-2.63)
-0.009
(-0.56)
0.023
(1.01)
-0.023
(-1.05)
CAR
0.075
(1.27)
0.126
(1.24)
1.035
(1.29)
0.284**
(2.42)
-0.062
(-0.55)
-0.099
(-0.85)
-0.785*
(-1.89)
0.120
(1.29)
∆GDP
-0.158**
(-2.55)
-0.160***
(-2.64)
-0.217***
(-3.38)
-0.006
(-0.06)
0.409**
(2.49)
0.038
(0.22)
0.669***
(3.51)
-0.310***
(-4.20)
∆GDPt-1
-0.348***
(-5.56)
-0.275***
(-4.63)
-0.287**
(-2.07)
-0.159***
(-2.71)
-0.568***
(-4.08)
-0.504***
(-3.25)
-0.642***
(-4.93)
-0.076
(-0.63)
POS
0.316
(0.85)
-3.503***
(-3.25)
POS*EBTP
104.65***
(2.60)
350.23***
(4.22)
NEG
0.856*
(1.76)
7.805***
(2.78)
NEG*EBTP
-55.486
(-0.47)
-184.61**
(-2.36)
WELL
3.972
(0.76)
-1.576
(-0.69)
WELL*CAR
-0.851
(-1.08)
0.668*
(1.85)
In(LOAN)
-0.082*
(-1.80)
0.243*
(1.83)
J-Statistic
19.19
23.27
16.96
16.32
21.88
18.11
22.01
18.80
P(J-Stat)
0.21
0.08
0.32
0.29
0.35
0.580
0.34
0.65
No of
instrument
AR(1)
30
30
30
27
35
35
35
35
0.015
0.007
0.008
0.04
0.0001
0.004
0.0002
0.0005
AR (2)
0.578
0.418
0.055
0.852
0.639
0.687
0.796
0.130
P-values in parentheses. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. Robust standard error is
included. The number of instruments is always kept below the number of groups. AR (1) and AR (2) are the Arellano-Bond tests
for first and second order autocorrelation of the residuals, indicating that there is no serial correlation. NPL = Non-performing
loan to gross loan for bank i at time t. LOAN = change in gross loan outstanding. CAR = tier1 capital divided by risk-weighted
assets for bank i at time t. EBTP = earnings before tax and credit risk allowance. ∆GDP = Gross domestic product growth rate.
∆GDPt-1 = one-year lagged gross domestic product growth rate. POS = dummy variable that take the value 1 when EBTP is
above-the-median EBTP ratio and zero otherwise. NEG = dummy variable that take the value 1 when EBTP is a negative number
and zero otherwise. WELL = dummy variable that take the value 1 if CAR is above 8% and zero otherwise. Ln(LOAN) = natural
logarithm of loan growth.
15
P.K. Ozili
5. Concluding Remarks
The distinction between GSIBs and non GSIBs is driven by policy reasons. This study adopts this
policy classification to investigate the relationship between nonperforming loans (NPLs) and
the economic cycle for European systemic and non-systemic banks after controlling for
earnings before loan loss allowance, bank lending, and bank tier 1 capital ratios. The findings
reveal that systemic banks have fewer non-performing loans during economic booms. Also,
increased lending is associated with few NPL in systemic banks, implying that systemic banks
have a strong and prudent credit risk mitigation process that mitigates or reduce the risks in
their loan portfolio while higher lending is associated with higher NPLs for non-systemic banks.
Systemic banks keep higher regulatory capital when they expect higher NPLs while nonsystemic banks that exceed regulatory capital requirements experience higher NPLs. Nonsystemic banks have fewer NPLs when they experience higher losses. Finally, more profitable
banks witness higher NPLs regardless of whether they are systemic or non-systemic banks.
The implication of the findings is that national supervisors need to strengthen the microprudential supervision of systemic banks in their countries to reduce abnormal NPLs to the
lowest possible. To achieve this, supervisors can use a combination of micro- and macroprudential policies for banking supervision and regulation. Also, the observation that increased
lending is associated with few NPLs in systemic banks but not in non-systemic banks is
interesting. This calls for increased regulatory oversight on the lending practices of European
banks by bank supervisors. However, bank supervisors must also exercise caution and
understand that excessive focus on the supervision of systemic banks can have unintended
consequences if credit risks in non-systemic banks are not monitored properly by national
supervisors.
Another implication for bank supervisors is that bank supervisors should pressure all banks,
both systemic and non-systemic, to improve their credit risk management systems. Bank
supervisors may need to examine the credit policies of all banks and recommend a complete
overhaul of the credit policies of some banks found to be weak and insensitive to credit risk.
Finally, the observation that profitable banks have higher NPLs is worrying. Bank supervisors
should stress-test the balance sheets of European systemic and non-systemic banks to
assess whether they have sufficient capital to absorb abnormal non-performing loans without
becoming insolvent. National supervisors in Europe also need to stress test the earnings
power of European banks relative to the non-performing loans in their books. Future research
can investigate the political, regulatory and institutional factors that influence the level of
nonperforming loans in European banks such as government guarantees, regulatory
forbearance, investor protection and financial crises.
16
P.K. Ozili
Reference
Acharya, V., Pedersen, L., Philippe, T., and Richardson, M. (2010). Measuring systemic risk.
Technical report, Department of Finance, NYU
Adrian, Tobias, and Markus K. Brunnermeier, 2011, CoVaR, Staff Reports 348, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York.
Aiyar, M. S., Bergthaler, Garrido, Monaghan, M. D., et al (2015). A strategy for resolving Europe's
problem
loans.
International
Monetary
Fund.
Available
at:
https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/sdn/2015/sdn1519.pdf Accessed on 12 January, 2019.
Allen, L., Bali, T. G., & Tang, Y. (2012). Does systemic risk in the financial sector predict future
economic downturns? The Review of Financial Studies, 25(10), 3000-3036.
Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence
and an application to employment equations. The review of economic studies, 58(2), 277-297.
Banulescu, G. D., & Dumitrescu, E. I. (2015). Which are the SIFIs? A Component Expected
Shortfall approach to systemic risk. Journal of Banking & Finance, 50, 575-588.
Basel, II. (2004). International convergence of capital measurement and capital standards: a
revised framework. Bank for international settlements.
Beck, R., Jakubik, P., & Piloiu, A. (2013). Non-performing loans: What matters in addition to the
economic cycle? (February 11, 2013). ECB Working Paper No. 1515. Available at SSRN:
https://ssrn.com/abstract=2214971
Beck, R., Jakubik, P., & Piloiu, A. (2013). Non-performing loans: What matters in addition to the
economic cycle?
Besanko, D., & Kanatas, G. (1996). The regulation of bank capital: Do capital standards promote
bank safety? Journal of financial intermediation, 5(2), 160-183.
Benink, H., & Wihlborg, C. (2002). The new Basel capital accord: making it effective with stronger
market discipline. European Financial Management, 8(1), 103-115.
Black, Lamont, Ricardo Correa, Xin Huang, and Hao Zhou, 2013, The Systemic Risk of European
Banks during the Financial and Sovereign Debt Crises, Working Paper.
Bleck, A. (2018). Regulating bank leverage. Journal of Financial Economic Policy, 10(2), 264-274.
Brownlees, C. T., & Engle, R. (2012). Volatility, correlation and tails for systemic risk
measurement. Available at SSRN, 1611229.
Carey, M. (1998). Credit risk in private debt portfolios. The Journal of Finance, 53(4), 1363-1387.
Cihák, M. M. (2007). Introduction to applied stress testing (No. 7-59). International Monetary
Fund.
17
P.K. Ozili
Drehmann (2005) A Market Based Macro Stress Test for the Corporate Credit Exposures of UK
Banks. An unpublished article, Bank of England, March 2005.
Espinoza, R. A., & Prasad, A. (2010). Nonperforming loans in the GCC banking system and their
macroeconomic effects (No. 10-224). International Monetary Fund.
European Commission, EC, (2018). Proposal for a regulation of the European parliament and of
the council amending regulation (EU) No 575/2013 as regards minimum loss coverage for nonperforming exposure: Impact assessment. Accessed on: 5th June, 2018. Available at:
European Commission, 2013, Regulation No 575/2013 on prudential requirements for credit
institutions
and
investment
firms
(CRR).
http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/?uri=celex:32013R0575
European Commission, 2014, Proposal for a regulation on structural measures improving the
resilience of EU credit institutions, COM(2014) 043 final. http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/ALL/?uri=CELEX:52014PC0043
Fofack, H. L. (2005). Nonperforming loans in Sub-Saharan Africa: causal analysis and
macroeconomic implications. The World Bank.
Glen, J., & Mondragón-Vélez, C. (2011). Business cycle effects on commercial bank loan portfolio
performance in developing economies. Review of Development Finance, 1(2), 150-165.
Huang, Xin, Hao Zhou, and Haibin Zhu, 2009, A Framework for Assessing the Systemic Risk of
Major Financial Institutions, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 33, No. 11, 2036- 2049.
Huang, Xin, Hao Zhou, and Haibin Zhu, 2012, Systemic Risk Contributions, Journal of Financial
Services Research, Vol. 42, No. 1-2, 55-83
Karimalis, E. N., & Nomikos, N. K. (2018). Measuring systemic risk in the European banking
sector: A Copula CoVaR approach. The European Journal of Finance, 24(11), 944-975.
Klein, N. (2013). Non-performing loans in CESEE: Determinants and impact on macroeconomic
performance (No. 13-72). International Monetary Fund.
Louzis, D. P., Vouldis, A. T., & Metaxas, V. L. (2012). Macroeconomic and bank-specific
determinants of non-performing loans in Greece: A comparative study of mortgage, business
and consumer loan portfolios. Journal of Banking & Finance, 36(4), 1012-1027.
Nkusu, M. M. (2011). Nonperforming loans and macrofinancial vulnerabilities in advanced
economies (No. 11-161). International Monetary Fund.
Ozili, P. K. (2019). Non-performing loans and financial development: new evidence. The Journal
of Risk Finance, 20(1), 59-81.
Ozili, P.K & Thankom, A.G (2018). Income smoothing among European systemic and nonsystemic banks. The British Accounting Review, 50(5), 539-558.
18
P.K. Ozili
Pesaran, M.H., 2006. Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panel with a multifactor
error structure. Econometrica 74 (4), 967–1012.
Pesola (2005) Banking fragility and distress: An econometric study of macroeconomic
determinants. Bank of Finland Research Discussion Papers, No. 13.
Quagliariello, M. (2007). Banks’ riskiness over the business cycle: a panel analysis on Italian
intermediaries. Applied Financial Economics, 17(2), 119-138.
Ruckes, M. (2004). Bank competition and credit standards. Review of Financial Studies, 17(4),
1073-1102.
Salas, V., & Saurina, J. (2002). Credit risk in two institutional regimes: Spanish commercial and
savings banks. Journal of Financial Services Research, 22(3), 203-224.
Shrieves, R. E., & Dahl, D. (1992). The relationship between risk and capital in commercial
banks. Journal of Banking & Finance, 16(2), 439-457.
Wezel, T., Canta, M., & Luy, M. (2014). A practical example of the nonperforming loans projection
approach to stress testing. A Guide to IMF Stress Testing: Methods and Models, 473-483.
Appendix
A1: Summary of Sample Distribution
Country
G-SIBs
Non G-SIBs
United Kingdom
Germany
Ireland
Luxembourg
Norway
Denmark
Finland
Greece
Portugal
Belgium
Netherland
Sweden
Spain
France
Italy
Austria
13
2
1
2
1
1
1
0
2
1
3
2
2
7
2
1
22
24
9
5
6
10
3
4
4
9
9
9
8
28
27
13
#
Banks
35
26
10
7
7
11
4
4
6
10
12
11
10
35
29
14
Grand Total
41
190
231
19
P.K. Ozili
Non-performing loans in European systemic and non-systemic banks
Peterson K. Ozili, PhD.
Abstract
I examine the behaviour of non-performing loans in European systemic and non-systemic
banks. The distinction between systemic banks (GSIBs) and non-systemic banks (non GSIBs) is
driven by policy reasons. The findings reveal that more profitable banks witness higher nonperforming loans regardless of whether they are systemic or non-systemic. Systemic banks
have fewer non-performing loans during economic booms and during periods of increased
lending while non-systemic banks experience higher NPLs during periods of increased lending.
I also observe that European non-systemic banks that exceed regulatory capital requirements
have higher NPLs. In the post-2007 financial crisis period, the NPL of systemic banks is
negatively associated with the economic cycle which imply that the NPL of systemic banks is
procyclical with the state of the economy, and the NPL of systemic banks are positively
associated with loan supply and bank profitability. On the other hand, the NPLs of non-systemic
banks is negatively associated with regulatory capital ratios, and is positively associated with
bank profitability for non-systemic banks in the post-2007 financial crisis period. The findings
have implications.
JEL codes: C33, E44, G21
Keywords: credit risk, non-performing loans, systemic banks, systemic risk, impaired loans,
asset quality; European banks, Europe, bank profitability.
This Version: 2019
I thank the editors, and two anonymous reviewers for constructive feedback
The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the
institution(s) the author is affiliated with.
Cite as: “Ozili, P.K. (2019). Nonperforming loans in European systemic and non-systemic banks.
Journal of Financial Economic Policy.”
1
P.K. Ozili
1. Introduction
This study investigates the behaviour of non-performing loans, focusing on the relationship
between non-performing loans (NPLs) and the economic cycle for European systemic and nonsystemic banks. The distinction between systemic banks (GSIBs) and non-systemic (non
GSIBs) is driven by policy reasons. In Europe, banking policy makers have growing concern for
high non-performing loans in the EU banking sector due to the interdependence between bank
financing and economic growth in the European Union (European Commission, 2013, 2014). Also,
high levels of NPLs in the European banking sector pose significant risks to financial stability in
the EU. The current levels of NPLs piled up in several parts of the EU banking sector are the
aftermath of the global financial crisis and sovereign crisis in recent years (European
Commission, 2018). Aiyar et al (2015), in an IMF study, show that non-performing loans in the
European Union (EU) stood at about €1 trillion (equivalent to over 9 percent of the GDP of the
entire EU region) at the end of 2014 - more than double the level in 2009. They point out that some
structural obstacles in the EU banking system discouraged EU banks from addressing their
non-performing loan problems, such as prudential supervision issues, legal obstacles,
distressed debt markets, informational obstacles, tax and other obstacles.
In addition to these issues, the credit risk of a systemic financial institution in the financial
system is crucial for financial system stability. A financial system regulator should be worried
if the top ten largest industry obligors or debtors are indebted to systemic banks especially
when these loans are non-performing. When high NPLs are concentrated among systemic
financial institutions, such losses will be charged against bank profits and can erode bank
capital, and the loss of bank capital can lead of the collapse of any financial institution. In recent
times, systemic European banks that have serious NPL problems often seek regulatory
forbearance from regulators which is a way for them to have more time to deal with their NPL
problems.
This study focus on the behaviour of NPLs in European systemic and non-systemic banks
because of the systemic risk that distressed too-big-to-fail financial institutions may pose to
the entire financial system. The collapse of a systemic bank can collapse the entire financial
system, and large non-performing loans can trigger the failure of a bank. Excess nonperforming loans in systemic banks can (i) send the wrong signal to outsiders about the stability
of other banks connected to systemic banks (ii) and can bring down any financial institutions if
the losses completely wipe out the capital of the bank. Therefore, it is in the best interest of EU
policy makers to understand this signalling problem, and they need to address the rising NPL
issues in the European banking sector.
One way to understand the behaviour of NPLs is to first identify the determinants of NPLs in
banks. Prior studies have identified some determinants such as business cycle fluctuation,
regulatory capital ratios, loan growth, etc. (see Nkusu 2011; Louzis et al, 2012; Klein 2013; Ozili,
2019, etc.). The next question is: do these determinants have similar or dissimilar impact on
systemic versus non-systemic banks? If yes, how and why? Under what economic (or bankspecific) conditions do systemic banks experience higher or fewer NPLs, as well as for nonsystemic banks.
2
P.K. Ozili
This study adopts the Financial Stability Board (FSB) and Basel Committee for Banking
Supervision (BCBS)’s distinction between systemic banks (GSIBs) and (non-GSIBs). This
classification is used to analyse the behaviour of nonperforming loans in the two bank groups.
I analyse European banks over the 2004 to 2013 period, and find that more profitable banks
witness higher non-performing loans. Systemic banks have fewer non-performing loans
during economic booms and during periods of increased lending while non-systemic banks
experience higher NPLs during periods of increased lending. The findings also reveal that
systemic banks keep higher regulatory capital ratios when they expect higher NPLs while nonsystemic banks that exceed regulatory capital requirements experience higher NPLs.
The study contributes to the literature in the following way. Firstly, this study contributes to the
recent literature on the determinants of non-performing loan (Espinoza and Prasad, 2010;
Fofack, 2005; Louzis et al, 2012; Ozili, 2019). This study adds to this literature by analysing the link
between non-performing loans and the business cycle, focussing on systemic banks and nonsystemic banks in Europe. An investigation into the behaviour of NPLs in systemic and nonsystemic banks is useful for micro-prudential regulation to help EU policy makers understand
the implication of large non-performing exposures in systemic and non-systemic banks.
Secondly, the analysis in this paper is useful to provide additional insights on the link between
problem loans and various states of the economy. Thirdly, this study can help policy makers
understand how non-performing loans build-up in systemic financial institutions, and can help
policymakers to devise pro-active policy response to quickly address the NPL issues in
systemic banks in Europe.
The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 discuss the literature review on
systemic risk measures and the determinants of non-performing loans. Section 3 presents the
data. Section 4 discuss the research design and methodology. Section 5 discuss the empirical
results. Section 6 concludes.
2. Related Literature
2.1. Measuring Systemic risk
A widely used measure of systemic risk is the conditional value-at-risk (CoVaR) proposed by
Adrian and Brunnermeier (2011) which capture risk spill-overs among financial institutions. The
CoVar is the value-at-risk (VaR) of the financial system conditional on one institution being in
distress (Karimalis and Nomikos, 2018). Another measure of systemic risk is the ‘distressed
insurance premium’ (DIP) measure. The distressed insurance premium (DIP) is a hypothetical
insurance premium to cover losses that exceed a certain threshold of banks’ total liabilities
(Huang et al, 2009; Huang et al, 2012). The higher the losses or risk of the bank, the higher the
distressed insurance premium. Black et al (2013) applied the DIP approach to evaluate systemic
risk in the European banking sector. The third measure of systemic risk is the CATFIN. CATFIN
is an aggregate measure of systemic risk in the financial sector. It measures the detrimental
effects of financial risk taking by the overall financial sector on the macroeconomy (see Allen
et al 2012). The CATFIN focus on forecasting macroeconomic developments in the economy
when measuring systemic risk. (Karimalis and Nomikos, 2018). CATFIN is estimated using both
value-at-risk (VaR) and expected shortfall (ES) methodologies, each of which are estimated
3
P.K. Ozili
using three approaches: one non-parametric and two different parametric specifications. In
comparison, the CATFIN attempts to predict or forecast the macroeconomic systemic risk in the
financial sector while the CoVaR and DIP only measure the cross-sectional (bank-level)
differences in banks’ contribution to systemic risk (Allen et al, 2012).
Another systemic risk measure is the component expected shortfall (Banulescu and
Dumitrescu, 2015). The component expected shortfall (CES) decompose the risk of the
aggregate financial system into several components while accounting for firm characteristics.
The CES assess the contribution of a firm to systemic risk at a precise date but also to forecast
its contribution over a certain period (Banulescu and Dumitrescu, 2015). The CES is a hybrid
measure that combines the ‘Too-Interconnected-To Fail’ and the ‘Too-Big-To-Fail’ logics. Also,
CES relies only on publicly available daily data and is similar to the popular ‘Marginal Expected
Shortfall’ measure. Another measure of systemic risk is the systemic expected shortfall (SES)
by Acharya et al. (2010). The SES is the expected capital shortage of an individual firm
conditional on a substantial reduction of the capitalization of the entire system. Under a number
of assumptions, SES can be expressed as a linear combination of marginal expected shortfall
(MES) and leverage where the parameters of such a combination are not known in general
(Brownlees and Engle, 2012). Another measure is the ‘SRISK’ which measures the amount of
capital an institution would need to survive a capital shortage in the financial system. It is the
amount of capital that a firm would need to survive when the entire system is undercapitalised
(Brownlees and Engle, 2012). Similarly, aggregate SRISK is the total amount of capital that the
government would need to provide to bailout the financial system in the event of a crisis
(Brownlees and Engle, 2012). Other measures include the marginal expected shortfall, etc.
Finally, systemic risk can be measured by whether a financial institution is a global systemically
important financial institution or whether it is a non-global systemically important financial
institution. The Financial Stability Board (FSB) in 2013 developed a classification for identifying
financial institutions that pose the greatest risks to the global financial system. They proposed
a G-SIB classification which classify all financial institutions according to their systemic risk
contribution to the global financial system. The criteria to determine whether a financial
institution is a GSIBs is based on a financial institution (FI)’s size, interconnectedness,
complexity, non-substitutability and cross-border activities (or global reach). This study
adopts the G-SIB classification to analyse the behaviour of non-performing loans in banks.
2.2. NPLs and Systemic Risk Regulation – Theoretical Perspectives
Prior to the distinction between G-SIBs vs non-GSIBs by the FSB/BCBS, the Basel risk-capital
regulation was adopted to mitigate credit risk in banks (Benink and Wihlborg, 2002; Basel II,
2004). Risk-capital regulation is achieved through the allocation of capital for all risky and
significant activities in financial institutions (Shrieves and Dahl, 1992; Besanko and Kanatas,
1996). For NPLs, the incurred loss provisioning model has traditionally been used to allocate
loan loss provisions as a cushion to absorb nonperforming loans when they become doubtful,
substandard or lost. Generally, the use of provisioning and risk-capital has been a fundamental
principle of Basel regulations even though critics argue that risk-capital and provisioning are
two sub-optimal solutions to mitigate bank risks because they only focus on risks arising from
banking activities rather than focusing on the root cause of risks in banks. However, there are
some disagreement in the literature regarding the risk-sensitivity of risk-capital regulation.
4
P.K. Ozili
For instance, Bleck (2018) argues that when a bank is better informed about its risk than the
regulator, any regulation designed to regulate banks would be subject to the Lucas
critique. Bleck (2018), building on the Lucas critique, argue that banks know and understand
their risk better than regulators, therefore, bank risk-capital regulations are a second-best
regulation and might be insensitive to risk. Bleck (2018) supports a leverage ratio-based
regulation, and suggest that the leverage ratio of financial institutions might be a better
measure for systemic riskiness than risk-based capital regulation.
2.3. Empirical Literature
High NPL ratios can affect bank's short-term and long-term performance through two main
channels. First, NPLs generate losses for banks thereby reducing bank profitability and can
diminish bank capital when non-performing loans are written-off. In severe cases, high NPLs
can make a bank become insolvent. Secondly, high NPLs tie up significant amount of banks'
resources, both human and financial, making it difficult for banks to provide new credit to
businesses and individuals (European Commission, 2018).
Studies linking credit risk to the state of the economy are not new in the literature (e.g. Carey,
1998; Ruckes, 2004; Salas and Saurina, 2002; Fofack, 2005; Louzis et al, 2012; Ozili and Thankom,
2018). These studies show that in good economic times, banks extend credit to low quality
debtors in order to generate higher revenue because the risk of financial distress is usually low
during boom years. However, when a recession sets in, non-performing loans are expected to
increase for banks. Pesaran (2006) examine the link between changes in credit portfolio and
the macroeconomy, and observe that loan default probabilities are strongly driven by the link
between firms and the economic cycle, implying that historical data on default probabilities can
help predict the likelihood of future non-performing loans. However, data on default
probabilities may be difficult to assess for decision making by outsiders. Beck et al (2013) also
confirm that data on default probabilities are largely unavailable publicly.
Other studies also use non-performing loan as a measure of bank credit risk. Nkusu (2011), in a
panel data analyses, examine the relationship between banks’ loan portfolio quality and macro
financial vulnerabilities for 26 countries during 1998 to 2009. Nkusu find a positive relationship
between asset quality and the macroeconomic variables used in the study. Glen and
Mondragón-Vélez (2011) examine banks from 22 developed countries from 1996 to 2008 and
observe that loan loss provisions (a proxy for credit risk) is driven by real GDP growth as well
as, low bank capitalisation and private sector leverage. Similarly, Pesola (2005) find a strong
link between credit risk and the macroeconomic environment while Drehmann (2005) show
that the link between credit risk and macroeconomic shocks may be non-linear. Cihak (2007)
and Wezel et al (2014) in their stress-testing analyses examine the resilience of bank balance
sheet to adverse economic conditions. These studies suggest that credit risk is strongly linked
to changes in the economic cycle.
Much of the studies that link credit risk or non-performing loans to the state of the economy are
mainly country specific studies. For instance, Salas and Saurina (2002) investigate the
determinants of problem loans in Spanish commercial and savings banks while controlling for
other factors such as capital ratio, bank size net interest margin and market power. They find
that problem loans are strongly linked to the economic cycle (i.e., real GDP growth).
5
P.K. Ozili
Quagliarello (2007) observe that the state of the economy is a determinant of non-performing
loans for Italian banks. Klein (2013) also document a strong negative relationship between nonperforming loans and the economic cycle proxy by change in gross domestic product for banks
in Central, Eastern and South- Eastern Europe (CESEE) countries. Fofack (2005) find similar
evidence for banks in sub-Saharan African countries while Louzis et al (2012) find similar
evidence in the Greek banking sector. Prior literature has not focussed on the link between nonperforming loans and the economic cycle for systemic banks compared to non-systemic banks.
This present study, in contrast, examine two categories of European banks: systemic banks and
non-systemic banks.
3. Data
Pooled cross-section and time series balance sheet data for European banks were collected
from the Van Dijk Bankscope database for 16 counties in Europe: United Kingdom, Germany,
Ireland, Luxemburg, Norway, Denmark, Finland, Greece, Portugal, Belgium, Netherland,
Sweden, Spain, France, Italy and Austria. The sample period covers 2004 to 2013. The rationale
for the choice of sample period is to allows us cross-check how the 2007-2008 financial crisis
affected systemic and non-systemic banks and also how they have changed since the crisis.
Also, since the 2004 to 2013 period precede the date the European Central Bank (ECB) assumed
responsibility for the Euro Area banking sector in November 4, 2014, the current sample period
will allow us to capture the behaviour of NPLs before the European Central Bank (ECB)
intervention.
To control for the 2008 financial crisis, 2008 bank-year observations were eliminated so that
the impact of the financial crisis would not affect the validity of the inference(s). A binary dummy
variable is introduced to distinguish between the pre-crisis and the post-crisis period. Data for
real gross domestic product growth rate, a proxy for economic cycle, is obtained from the World
Economic Forum database. The ∆GDP data allows us to detect whether the magnitude of nonperforming loans and its link to the economic cycle during the period warranted the full
intervention of the European Central Bank in the first place.
The European banks are then divided into systemic (G-SIBs) and non-systemic banks (non-GSIBs). The distinction between systemic and non-systemic banks is based on the joint Financial
Stability Board (FSB) and Basel BCBS’s classification of banks as global systemicallyimportant banks (G-SIBs). Banks that are not classified as global systemic banks in 2013 yearend are considered to be non-systemic banks. This is the only distinction made between banks
in this study. The resulting final sample yields 231 European bank sample containing 41 systemic
banks and 190 non-systemic banks as shown in Appendix A1. All sample banks have December
31 fiscal year ends. The data is an unbalanced panel.
6
P.K. Ozili
4. Methodology
The multivariate model employed to investigate the relationship between non-performing
loans and the economic cycle is a variation of the model used by Beck et al (2013) and Ozili (2019)
who examine the determinants of non-performing loans. The functional form of the model in
this study is given as
𝑁𝑃𝐿𝑖𝑡 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1𝐿𝑂𝐴𝑁𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽2𝐶𝐴𝑅𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽3𝐸𝐵𝑇𝑃𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝐺𝐷𝑃𝑖, 𝑡 − 1 + 𝛽5𝐺𝐷𝑃𝑖𝑡
+ 𝑃𝐸𝑅𝐼𝑂𝐷𝑑𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑖𝑒𝑠 + 𝑒𝑖𝑡.
Where
NPL = Non-performing loan to gross loan ratio for bank i at time t.
LOAN = Change in gross loan outstanding for bank i at time t
CAR = ratio of Tier 1 capital divided by risk-weighted assets for bank i at time t.
EBTP = ratio of earnings before tax and loan loss allowance divided by total assets for bank i at
time t.
∆GDP = Real gross domestic product growth rate.
The non-performing loans to gross loans ratio is the dependent variable and the measure of
asset quality in the study. The explanatory variables are LOAN, CAR, EBTP and ∆GDP. The LOAN
variable is introduced to control for the influence of bank lending on non-performing loans. A
negative sign for the LOAN coefficient is expected. The second explanatory variable is
regulatory capital ratio. Banks that keep higher regulatory capital ratios will restrain from
engaging in risky lending thereby minimising the amount of problem loans in their balance
sheet, which improves asset quality. When this is the case, a negative relationship between NPL
and CAR is expected. However, a positive relationship may be expected if banks that engage in
risky lending anticipate their high risks and keep more regulatory capital to compensate for
their high risk activities. The third explanatory variable is real gross domestic product growth
rate (∆GDP). The real gross domestic product growth rate variable measures the impact of
economic cycle fluctuation on bank non-performing loans. A negative relationship is predicted
between NPLs and ∆GDP because NPLs tend to be higher (lower) during recessions (booms).
The fourth explanatory variable is the earnings variable (EBTP). The earnings before tax and
provisions (EBTP) variable measures the association between non-performing loans and bank
earnings before loan loss provisions. A negative relationship between NPL and EBTP is
expected because high NPLs will be written-off as losses which will reduce bank profit.
Further tests were conducted: to determine whether the relationship between asset quality
(non-performing loans) and earnings is stronger when earnings (before loan loss adjustment)
are negative or high (substantial). To test for this, two dummy variables are introduced into the
model: ‘POS’ dummy variable that take the value ‘1’ when EBTP is above-the-median EBTP ratio
and zero otherwise; and ‘NEG’ dummy variable take the value ‘1’ when EBTP is a negative number
and zero otherwise. These two dummies are then interacted with the EBTP variable. Inference
is then drawn from the relationship between NPLs and ‘NEG*EBTP’ and ‘POS*EBTP earnings
interaction terms. Additionally, I test whether banks with above 8% tier 1 capital report higher
7
P.K. Ozili
or fewer non-performing loans. This test allows us to determine whether nonperforming loans
improves with sufficient or insufficient Tier 1 capital ratios. To test for this, the ‘WELL’ dummy
variable is introduced into the model which take the value ‘1’ if CAR is above 8% and zero
otherwise. The ‘WELL’ dummy is then interacted with the ‘CAR’ variable. Finally, I test whether a
positive increase in bank lending is significantly associated with higher nonperforming loans.
To test for this, I take the natural logarithm of the LOAN variable to capture only the positive
increase in outstanding loans over the period. Taking the natural logarithm of the LOAN variable
ln(LOAN) systematically eliminates the negative observations in the time series distribution for
the LOAN variables but retains all the positive observations of the LOAN variable. Inference is
then drawn from the relationship between NPL and ln(LOAN).
The model is estimated using panel data regression. The method of analysis follows a dynamic
specification of the model. The dynamic model includes the lagged dependent variable as an
explanatory variable in order to capture the persistence of NPL growth over time. Also, the
introduction of the lagged dependent variable into the model makes it inappropriate to estimate
the model using fixed effect least square regression approach. The Generalised-Method of
Moments (GMM) method with instrumental variables is considered to be more appropriate to
estimate the model. I use the Generalised Method of Moments (GMM) regression estimation
based on the approach of Arellano and Bond (1991). Beck et al (2013) and Ozili and Thankom (2018)
also use this approach. The AR (1) and AR (2) are Arellano-Bond GMM tests for first and second
order serial-correlation of the residuals. In the analysis, the number of instruments is below
the number of cross-section. The next section presents the results.
5. Empirical Results
5.1. Descriptive statistics and Correlations
Table 1 provides the summary of the descriptive statistics for systemic and non-systemic banks
for the 2004 to 2013 period. Regarding non-performing loans, NPLs are, on average, 4.51% for
the full sample, 3.46% for systemic banks and 4.76% for non-systemic banks, respectively,
implying that systemic banks report fewer NPLs, on average, and might suggest that systemic
banks have better asset quality than non-systemic banks. Improved credit risk management by
systemic banks can lower their credit risk exposure and reduce the amount of regulatory
capital (Tier 1 capital) they need to set aside for credit risks. Unsurprisingly, systemic banks
report a low CAR (10.48%) compared to non-systemic banks (11.18%). Regarding credit growth
(LOAN), LOANs are 5.34% for the entire bank sample and systemic banks record lower growth
in loans at 4.38% while non-systemic banks have about 5.55%. Finally, the difference of means
between systemic and non-systemic banks is low.
8
P.K. Ozili
Table 1: Descriptive statistics: Systemic vs Non Systemic Banks
Variable
Full Sample
Systemic
Non-Systemic Difference
Banks
Banks
of Means
Mean
S.D
Mean
S.D
Mean
S.D
NPL
4.513
5.44
3.456 2.989 4.762
5.848
-1.306
LOAN
5.340 16.726 4.384 18.06 5.550 16.418
-1.166
CAR
11.053 4.819 10.481 2.851
11.183
5.117
-0.702
EBTP
0.008 0.009 0.009 0.008 0.008
0.010
0.001
No of Banks
23
41
190
*S. D - Standard Deviation. Table 1 report the descriptive statistics obtained
from 231 bank samples from 16 European countries. Data cover the period
2004 to 2013. NPL is non-performing loans to gross loan. EBTP is earnings
before taxes and provision to total assets. LOAN is the change in gross loan.
CAR is bank capital divided by risk-weighted assets. ΔGDP is real gross
domestic product growth rate.
Table 2 A and B reports the Pearson correlation coefficients and the associated p-values. Table
2a reports the correlation results for systemic banks. NPLs are not significantly correlated
with EBTP. LOAN is significant and negatively correlated with NPLs for systemic banks,
implying that systemic banks that increase loan supply experience fewer non-performing
loans. CAR is significant and positively correlated with NPLs for systemic banks, implying that
well-capitalised systemic banks experience higher problem loans. ∆GDP is negative and
significantly correlated with NPLs, implying that problem loans are higher during bad times.
Table 2B reports the correlation results for non-systemic banks. NPLs are not significantly
correlated with EBTP. LOAN is significant and negatively correlated with NPLs for nonsystemic banks, implying that non-systemic banks that increase loan supply experience
fewer non-performing loans. CAR is significant and negatively correlated with NPLs for nonsystemic banks, implying that well-capitalised non-systemic banks experience higher
problem loans. ∆GDP is negative and significantly correlated with NPLs, implying that nonsystemic banks experience high problem loans during bad times. Overall, the correlation
coefficients in Table 2 A and B are sufficiently low to be concerned about multi-collinearity in
the study.
9
P.K. Ozili
2A: Correlation for Systemic Banks
Table 2a report the correlation matrix for systemic banks.
All bank level variables remain as previously defined. ***,
** and * represent significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level,
respectively. P-values are reported in parentheses.
Variable
NPL
NPL
1.000
LOAN -0.372***
(0.000)
LOAN
ΔGDP
EBTP
CAR
1.000
ΔGDP -0.245*** 0.321***
(0.000) (0.000)
0.262***
(0.000)
1.000
EBTP
0.009
(0.893)
-0.012
(0.862)
1.000
CAR
0.187*** -0.394*** -0.253*** -0.335*** 1.000
(0.005) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Table 2B: Correlation for Non-Systemic Banks
Table 2a report the correlation matrix for non G-SIBs. All
bank level variables remain as previously defined. ***, **
and * represent significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level,
respectively. P-values are reported in parentheses.
Variable
NPL
NPL
1.000
LOAN -0.221***
(0.000)
LOAN
CAR
-0.032
(0.334)
EBTP
CAR
1.000
ΔGDP -0.279*** 0.234***
(0.000) (0.000)
EBTP
ΔGDP
1.000
0.246*** 0.144***
(0.000) (0.000)
1.000
-0.065** -0.248*** -0.041
(0.047) (0.000) (0.204)
-0.051
(0.119)
1.000
10
P.K. Ozili
5.2. Regression Result
5.2.1. Full Sample Analysis
Column 1 of Table 3 and 4 report the dynamic (Arellano-Bond) regression estimations for
systemic banks and non-systemic banks. ∆GDP coefficient is negatively significant, implying
that systemic banks witness fewer NPLs during economic booms. But, the result is not
significant for non-systemic banks. This finding is similar with the result of Glen and
Mondragón-Vélez (2011) and Nkusu (2011) who show a link between non-performing loan and
∆GDP. The lagged GDP growth coefficient is negatively significant for both systemic and nonsystemic banks, indicating that lagged GDP growth is inversely and significantly associated
with growth of NPLs for both banks. This implies that banks’ asset quality deteriorates with a
lag in response to negative economic growth possibly due to the difficulty of debtors to meet
their obligation during bad economic times. The earnings coefficient (EBTP) reports a negative
sign for both banks although the result is weakly significant for systemic banks and
insignificant for non-systemic banks. This implies that NPLs are likely to impair the earnings of
systemic banks than non-systemic European banks, however, the results do not show a strong
link between NPLs and earnings before loan loss allowance (EBTP). Also, loan growth (LOAN)
has a negative and significant impact on the non-performing loans of systemic banks. This
suggest that systemic banks lend to less-risky borrowers, which leads to lower NPLs, and
imply that systemic banks probably have a strong and prudent credit risk management system
compared to non-systemic banks. Similarly, a negative relationship between NPLs and LOAN
is observed for non-systemic banks but this relationship is insignificant. Finally, the CAR
coefficient is positive and significant for systemic banks but is insignificant for non-systemic
banks, indicating that systemic banks keep higher regulatory capital when they expect higher
NPLs.
5.2.2. Behaviour of NPLs after the global financial crisis
Here, I introduce the ‘POST’ dummy variable that take the value ‘1’ for the post-financial crisis
period and ‘0’ otherwise. I interact the ‘POST’ variable with the NPL determinants in the model
to determine their effect on NPLs. The result is reported in column 2 to 5 of Table 3 and 4. For
systemic banks, NPL has a significant and negative relationship with the economic cycle in the
post-financial crisis period, implying that systemic banks tend to have higher NPLs during
economic recessions in the post-crisis period. On the other hand, NPL has a significant and
positive relationship with earnings and bank lending in the post crisis period, implying that
NPLs are higher among systemic banks that are profitable and among systemic banks with
higher loan supply in the post-crisis period. For non-systemic banks, NPL has a significant
and negative relationship with the regulatory capital in the post-financial crisis period,
implying that non-systemic banks with lower regulatory capital have higher NPLs in the postcrisis period. On the other hand, NPL has a significant and positive relationship with earnings,
implying that NPLs are higher among non-systemic banks that are profitable in the post-crisis
period. Overall, the post-crisis findings for systemic banks shows that regulatory capital
(CAR) did not have a significant effect on NPLs, and suggests that risk-capital regulation might
be insensitive to risk in systemic banks, which supports the argument of Bleck (2018).
11
P.K. Ozili
Variable
NPLt-1
EBTP
LOAN
CAR
∆GDP
∆GDPt-1
CRISIS
CRISIS*∆GDP
CRISIS*EBTP
CRISIS*CAR
CRISIS*LOAN
Table 3. European Systemic Banks
Arellano-Bond (1991) GMM estimation
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
0.602***
0.567***
0.583***
0.540
(9.13)
(11.04)
(10.49)
(9.16)
-30.509*
15.02
-63.95***
15.33
(-1.69)
(0.74)
(-3.49)
(0.82)
-0.026*** -0.028*** -0.024*** -0.026***
(-3.91)
(-2.59)
(-3.57)
(-3.33)
0.112*
(1.72)
-0.142***
(-2.88)
-0.353***
(-5.47)
0.06
(1.18)
0.931***
(5.93)
-0.144*
(-1.84)
4.620***
(6.47)
-0.928***
(-7.54)
-0.006
(-0.09)
-0.003
(-0.04)
-0.128*
(-1.75)
1.247**
(2.04)
-0.065
(-0.69)
0.042
(0.56)
-0.075
(-0.97)
2.783***
(3.36)
(5)
0.515***
(8.97)
0.667
(0.04)
0.035***
(-5.62)
-0.045
(-0.75)
-0.027
(-0.31)
-0.095
(-1.23)
2.210**
(2.42)
102.06***
(5.01)
0.025
(0.31)
0.022*
(1.81)
J-Statistic
23.01
21.13
21.75
18.62
17.67
P(J-statistic)
0.15
0.13
0.11
0.23
0.28
No of instrument
30
30
30
30
30
AR(1)
0.007
0.011
0.013
0.012
0.023
AR (2)
0.899
0.199
0.236
0.407
0.475
P-values in parentheses. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%
levels, respectively. Robust standard error is included. The number of
instruments is always kept below the number of groups. AR (1) and AR (2) are
the Arellano-Bond tests for first and second order autocorrelation of the
residuals, indicating that there is no serial correlation. NPL = Non-performing
loan to gross loan for bank. LOAN = change in gross loan outstanding for bank.
CAR = tier1 capital divided by risk-weighted assets for bank. EBTP = earnings
before tax and credit risk allowance for bank. ∆GDP = Gross domestic product
growth rate. ∆GDPt-1 = one-year lagged gross domestic product growth rate.
CRISIS = dummy variable that take the value of 1 for year-2009, 2010, 2011, 2012
and 2013 and zero otherwise
12
P.K. Ozili
Variable
NPLt-1
EBTP
LOAN
CAR
∆GDP
∆GDPt-1
CRISIS
CRISIS*∆GDP
CRISIS*EBTP
CRISIS*CAR
CRISIS*LOAN
Table 4. European Non Systemic Banks
Arellano-Bond (1991) GMM estimation
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
0.766***
0.742*** 0.731***
0.759***
(12.59)
(9.63)
(10.50)
(10.40)
-33.554
-25.13
-340.12*** -43.73
(-1.45)
(-1.03)
(-3.56)
(-1.50)
-0.009
-0.019
-0.013
-0.019
(-0.77)
(-1.39)
(-0.72)
(-0.93)
-0.060
-0.216*
0.133
1.373***
(-0.69)
(-1.67)
(0.83)
(3.94)
0.183
0.133
0.162
0.152
(1.57)
(0.72)
(1.29)
(0.84)
-0.668*** -0.614***
-0.607***
0.648*** (-5.81)
(-4.79)
(-5.32)
(-5.60)
3.138
-10.469*** 5.730
(1.20)
(-2.68)
(1.38)
0.342
(1.04)
297.23***
(3.30)
-1.279***
(-4.14)
(5)
0.799***
(11.38)
-35.128
(-1.56)
-0.012
(-0.35)
-0.068
(-0.63)
0.170
(1.22)
-0.612
(-4.72)
2.522
(0.96)
0.003
(-0.05)
J-Statistic
33.03
30.69
24.10
21.59
31.63
P(J-statistic)
0.06
0.06
0.23
0.36
0.05
No of instrument 35
35
35
35
35
AR(1)
0.0001
0.0001
0.0003
0.0004
0.001
AR (2)
0.766
0.945
0.846
0.589
0.638
P-values in parentheses. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%
levels, respectively. Robust standard error is included. The number of
instruments is always kept below the number of groups. AR (1) and AR (2) are
the Arellano-Bond tests for first and second order autocorrelation of the
residuals, indicating that there is no serial correlation. NPL = Non-performing
loan to gross loan for bank. LOAN = change in gross loan outstanding for bank.
CAR = tier1 capital divided by risk-weighted assets for bank. EBTP = earnings
before tax and credit risk allowance for bank. ∆GDP = Gross domestic product
growth rate. ∆GDPt-1 = one-year lagged gross domestic product growth rate.
CRISIS = dummy variable that take the value of 1 for year-2009, 2010, 2011, 2012
and 2013 and zero otherwise.
13
P.K. Ozili
5.3. Further Analyses
5.3.1. Size of Earnings Effect
Next, I analyse the behaviour of NPLs when banks have high profits or high loses. To test
whether non-performing loans are significantly associated with earnings when both banks
expect losses or high earnings, the NEG and POS dummy variables are interacted with EBTP.
The result is reported in Column 1 and 5 of Table 5. The results show that NPLs are positive and
strongly linked with EBTP when both banks are more profitable. This implies that, in the face of
high non-performing loans (i.e., declining asset quality), both banks remain profitable (before
adjustment for provisions) while column 2 and 6 show that NPLs are fewer for non-systemic
banks when they experience higher losses, and insignificant for systemic banks.
5.3.2. Higher Regulatory Capital Effect
Next, I analyse the behaviour of NPLs when banks have sufficient (regulatory) capital. To test
whether bank non-performing loans is significantly associated with Tier 1 capital when the
banks have sufficient Tier 1 regulatory capital ratio (i.e., above 8% tier 1 capital), WELL dummy
variable is interacted with the CAR variable. Column 3 report a negative relationship between
NPLs and WELL*CAR for systemic banks but this relationship is not significant for systemic
banks. One possible explanation for the weak relationship could be due to the fact that Tier 1
capital for systemic banks may be used more extensively to mitigate other risks (such as
market risk, interest rate etc.) rather than to mitigate only credit risk. On the other hand, Column
7 report a positive and significant relationship between NPLs and above-8% Tier 1 capital for
non-systemic banks. This indicates that non-systemic banks with sufficient regulatory capital
experience higher NPLs.
5.3.3. Excess Credit Supply Effect
Next, I analyse the behaviour of NPLs during periods of excess credit supply, or periods of
increased lending. To test whether bank non-performing loan is significantly associated with
positive credit growth, the natural logarithm of the LOAN variable is used. Inference is drawn
based on the relationship between ln(LOAN) and NPLs. Column 4 and 8 report a negative
relationship for systemic banks and a positive relationship for non-systemic banks,
respectively, and both are significant at 10% level. The former indicates that increased bank
lending for systemic banks leads to improved asset quality (fewer NPLs). This confirms the
earlier result in Table 2. While the positive relationship for non-systemic banks indicate that
non-systemic banks experience higher NPLs in response to increased lending among nonsystemic banks. This suggest that non-systemic banks engage in imprudent lending to
borrowers which possibly leads to higher default by borrowers.
14
P.K. Ozili
Table 5 - Sensitivity Analysis - Regression
Systemic Banks
Non-systemic
Variable
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
NPLt-1
0.583***
(7.56)
0.586***
(8.49)
0.701***
(9.62)
0.743***
(9.68)
0.794***
(12.48)
0.863*
(1.87)
0.697***
(8.77)
0.994***
(11.13)
EBTP
-163.78***
(-4.03)
-5.256
(-0.25)
-38.220
(-1.47)
-56.36**
(-2.01)
-85.396***
(-3.59)
184.42***
(2.52)
-6.199
(-0.16)
-69.024
(-1.14)
LOAN
-0.035***
(-4.97)
-0.020***
(-2.73)
-0.019***
(-2.63)
-0.009
(-0.56)
0.023
(1.01)
-0.023
(-1.05)
CAR
0.075
(1.27)
0.126
(1.24)
1.035
(1.29)
0.284**
(2.42)
-0.062
(-0.55)
-0.099
(-0.85)
-0.785*
(-1.89)
0.120
(1.29)
∆GDP
-0.158**
(-2.55)
-0.160***
(-2.64)
-0.217***
(-3.38)
-0.006
(-0.06)
0.409**
(2.49)
0.038
(0.22)
0.669***
(3.51)
-0.310***
(-4.20)
∆GDPt-1
-0.348***
(-5.56)
-0.275***
(-4.63)
-0.287**
(-2.07)
-0.159***
(-2.71)
-0.568***
(-4.08)
-0.504***
(-3.25)
-0.642***
(-4.93)
-0.076
(-0.63)
POS
0.316
(0.85)
-3.503***
(-3.25)
POS*EBTP
104.65***
(2.60)
350.23***
(4.22)
NEG
0.856*
(1.76)
7.805***
(2.78)
NEG*EBTP
-55.486
(-0.47)
-184.61**
(-2.36)
WELL
3.972
(0.76)
-1.576
(-0.69)
WELL*CAR
-0.851
(-1.08)
0.668*
(1.85)
In(LOAN)
-0.082*
(-1.80)
0.243*
(1.83)
J-Statistic
19.19
23.27
16.96
16.32
21.88
18.11
22.01
18.80
P(J-Stat)
0.21
0.08
0.32
0.29
0.35
0.580
0.34
0.65
No of
instrument
AR(1)
30
30
30
27
35
35
35
35
0.015
0.007
0.008
0.04
0.0001
0.004
0.0002
0.0005
AR (2)
0.578
0.418
0.055
0.852
0.639
0.687
0.796
0.130
P-values in parentheses. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. Robust standard error is
included. The number of instruments is always kept below the number of groups. AR (1) and AR (2) are the Arellano-Bond tests
for first and second order autocorrelation of the residuals, indicating that there is no serial correlation. NPL = Non-performing
loan to gross loan for bank i at time t. LOAN = change in gross loan outstanding. CAR = tier1 capital divided by risk-weighted
assets for bank i at time t. EBTP = earnings before tax and credit risk allowance. ∆GDP = Gross domestic product growth rate.
∆GDPt-1 = one-year lagged gross domestic product growth rate. POS = dummy variable that take the value 1 when EBTP is
above-the-median EBTP ratio and zero otherwise. NEG = dummy variable that take the value 1 when EBTP is a negative number
and zero otherwise. WELL = dummy variable that take the value 1 if CAR is above 8% and zero otherwise. Ln(LOAN) = natural
logarithm of loan growth.
15
P.K. Ozili
5. Concluding Remarks
The distinction between GSIBs and non GSIBs is driven by policy reasons. This study adopts this
policy classification to investigate the relationship between nonperforming loans (NPLs) and
the economic cycle for European systemic and non-systemic banks after controlling for
earnings before loan loss allowance, bank lending, and bank tier 1 capital ratios. The findings
reveal that systemic banks have fewer non-performing loans during economic booms. Also,
increased lending is associated with few NPL in systemic banks, implying that systemic banks
have a strong and prudent credit risk mitigation process that mitigates or reduce the risks in
their loan portfolio while higher lending is associated with higher NPLs for non-systemic banks.
Systemic banks keep higher regulatory capital when they expect higher NPLs while nonsystemic banks that exceed regulatory capital requirements experience higher NPLs. Nonsystemic banks have fewer NPLs when they experience higher losses. Finally, more profitable
banks witness higher NPLs regardless of whether they are systemic or non-systemic banks.
The implication of the findings is that national supervisors need to strengthen the microprudential supervision of systemic banks in their countries to reduce abnormal NPLs to the
lowest possible. To achieve this, supervisors can use a combination of micro- and macroprudential policies for banking supervision and regulation. Also, the observation that increased
lending is associated with few NPLs in systemic banks but not in non-systemic banks is
interesting. This calls for increased regulatory oversight on the lending practices of European
banks by bank supervisors. However, bank supervisors must also exercise caution and
understand that excessive focus on the supervision of systemic banks can have unintended
consequences if credit risks in non-systemic banks are not monitored properly by national
supervisors.
Another implication for bank supervisors is that bank supervisors should pressure all banks,
both systemic and non-systemic, to improve their credit risk management systems. Bank
supervisors may need to examine the credit policies of all banks and recommend a complete
overhaul of the credit policies of some banks found to be weak and insensitive to credit risk.
Finally, the observation that profitable banks have higher NPLs is worrying. Bank supervisors
should stress-test the balance sheets of European systemic and non-systemic banks to
assess whether they have sufficient capital to absorb abnormal non-performing loans without
becoming insolvent. National supervisors in Europe also need to stress test the earnings
power of European banks relative to the non-performing loans in their books. Future research
can investigate the political, regulatory and institutional factors that influence the level of
nonperforming loans in European banks such as government guarantees, regulatory
forbearance, investor protection and financial crises.
16
P.K. Ozili
Reference
Acharya, V., Pedersen, L., Philippe, T., and Richardson, M. (2010). Measuring systemic risk.
Technical report, Department of Finance, NYU
Adrian, Tobias, and Markus K. Brunnermeier, 2011, CoVaR, Staff Reports 348, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York.
Aiyar, M. S., Bergthaler, Garrido, Monaghan, M. D., et al (2015). A strategy for resolving Europe's
problem
loans.
International
Monetary
Fund.
Available
at:
https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/sdn/2015/sdn1519.pdf Accessed on 12 January, 2019.
Allen, L., Bali, T. G., & Tang, Y. (2012). Does systemic risk in the financial sector predict future
economic downturns? The Review of Financial Studies, 25(10), 3000-3036.
Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence
and an application to employment equations. The review of economic studies, 58(2), 277-297.
Banulescu, G. D., & Dumitrescu, E. I. (2015). Which are the SIFIs? A Component Expected
Shortfall approach to systemic risk. Journal of Banking & Finance, 50, 575-588.
Basel, II. (2004). International convergence of capital measurement and capital standards: a
revised framework. Bank for international settlements.
Beck, R., Jakubik, P., & Piloiu, A. (2013). Non-performing loans: What matters in addition to the
economic cycle? (February 11, 2013). ECB Working Paper No. 1515. Available at SSRN:
https://ssrn.com/abstract=2214971
Beck, R., Jakubik, P., & Piloiu, A. (2013). Non-performing loans: What matters in addition to the
economic cycle?
Besanko, D., & Kanatas, G. (1996). The regulation of bank capital: Do capital standards promote
bank safety? Journal of financial intermediation, 5(2), 160-183.
Benink, H., & Wihlborg, C. (2002). The new Basel capital accord: making it effective with stronger
market discipline. European Financial Management, 8(1), 103-115.
Black, Lamont, Ricardo Correa, Xin Huang, and Hao Zhou, 2013, The Systemic Risk of European
Banks during the Financial and Sovereign Debt Crises, Working Paper.
Bleck, A. (2018). Regulating bank leverage. Journal of Financial Economic Policy, 10(2), 264-274.
Brownlees, C. T., & Engle, R. (2012). Volatility, correlation and tails for systemic risk
measurement. Available at SSRN, 1611229.
Carey, M. (1998). Credit risk in private debt portfolios. The Journal of Finance, 53(4), 1363-1387.
Cihák, M. M. (2007). Introduction to applied stress testing (No. 7-59). International Monetary
Fund.
17
P.K. Ozili
Drehmann (2005) A Market Based Macro Stress Test for the Corporate Credit Exposures of UK
Banks. An unpublished article, Bank of England, March 2005.
Espinoza, R. A., & Prasad, A. (2010). Nonperforming loans in the GCC banking system and their
macroeconomic effects (No. 10-224). International Monetary Fund.
European Commission, EC, (2018). Proposal for a regulation of the European parliament and of
the council amending regulation (EU) No 575/2013 as regards minimum loss coverage for nonperforming exposure: Impact assessment. Accessed on: 5th June, 2018. Available at:
European Commission, 2013, Regulation No 575/2013 on prudential requirements for credit
institutions
and
investment
firms
(CRR).
http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/?uri=celex:32013R0575
European Commission, 2014, Proposal for a regulation on structural measures improving the
resilience of EU credit institutions, COM(2014) 043 final. http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/ALL/?uri=CELEX:52014PC0043
Fofack, H. L. (2005). Nonperforming loans in Sub-Saharan Africa: causal analysis and
macroeconomic implications. The World Bank.
Glen, J., & Mondragón-Vélez, C. (2011). Business cycle effects on commercial bank loan portfolio
performance in developing economies. Review of Development Finance, 1(2), 150-165.
Huang, Xin, Hao Zhou, and Haibin Zhu, 2009, A Framework for Assessing the Systemic Risk of
Major Financial Institutions, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 33, No. 11, 2036- 2049.
Huang, Xin, Hao Zhou, and Haibin Zhu, 2012, Systemic Risk Contributions, Journal of Financial
Services Research, Vol. 42, No. 1-2, 55-83
Karimalis, E. N., & Nomikos, N. K. (2018). Measuring systemic risk in the European banking
sector: A Copula CoVaR approach. The European Journal of Finance, 24(11), 944-975.
Klein, N. (2013). Non-performing loans in CESEE: Determinants and impact on macroeconomic
performance (No. 13-72). International Monetary Fund.
Louzis, D. P., Vouldis, A. T., & Metaxas, V. L. (2012). Macroeconomic and bank-specific
determinants of non-performing loans in Greece: A comparative study of mortgage, business
and consumer loan portfolios. Journal of Banking & Finance, 36(4), 1012-1027.
Nkusu, M. M. (2011). Nonperforming loans and macrofinancial vulnerabilities in advanced
economies (No. 11-161). International Monetary Fund.
Ozili, P. K. (2019). Non-performing loans and financial development: new evidence. The Journal
of Risk Finance, 20(1), 59-81.
Ozili, P.K & Thankom, A.G (2018). Income smoothing among European systemic and nonsystemic banks. The British Accounting Review, 50(5), 539-558.
18
P.K. Ozili
Pesaran, M.H., 2006. Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panel with a multifactor
error structure. Econometrica 74 (4), 967–1012.
Pesola (2005) Banking fragility and distress: An econometric study of macroeconomic
determinants. Bank of Finland Research Discussion Papers, No. 13.
Quagliariello, M. (2007). Banks’ riskiness over the business cycle: a panel analysis on Italian
intermediaries. Applied Financial Economics, 17(2), 119-138.
Ruckes, M. (2004). Bank competition and credit standards. Review of Financial Studies, 17(4),
1073-1102.
Salas, V., & Saurina, J. (2002). Credit risk in two institutional regimes: Spanish commercial and
savings banks. Journal of Financial Services Research, 22(3), 203-224.
Shrieves, R. E., & Dahl, D. (1992). The relationship between risk and capital in commercial
banks. Journal of Banking & Finance, 16(2), 439-457.
Wezel, T., Canta, M., & Luy, M. (2014). A practical example of the nonperforming loans projection
approach to stress testing. A Guide to IMF Stress Testing: Methods and Models, 473-483.
Appendix
A1: Summary of Sample Distribution
Country
G-SIBs
Non G-SIBs
United Kingdom
Germany
Ireland
Luxembourg
Norway
Denmark
Finland
Greece
Portugal
Belgium
Netherland
Sweden
Spain
France
Italy
Austria
13
2
1
2
1
1
1
0
2
1
3
2
2
7
2
1
22
24
9
5
6
10
3
4
4
9
9
9
8
28
27
13
#
Banks
35
26
10
7
7
11
4
4
6
10
12
11
10
35
29
14
Grand Total
41
190
231
19