Urbanization and Economic Growth:
Panel Data Evidence from Africa
Prepared By:
Arega Getaneh
October 2018
2
Abstract
This paper focuses on Urbanization and Economics growth in Africa. The
method applied is panel data investigation to justify the endogeneity problem related to such variables, GMM. We included variables important for
economic growth and found that urbanization has both pros and cons for the
economic growth in the region which are supported by extended neoclassical
economic models. Some variables like government expenditure and Capital
formation has to modify to manage the dynamic estimation techniques. The
finding that urbanization impacted the economics growth of the region may
be explained by the slum and unorganized urban policy in Africa.
i
Contents
1
2
3
Introduction
1
1.1
Some Backgrounds . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
1
1.2
Questions to be answered . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
2
1.3
Endogenous Growth Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3
1.4
Growth at cross Countries level . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4
1.5
Variables in the Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4
1.5.1
6
Related Literature
7
2.1
Urbanization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
7
2.2
Urbanization issues in Africa . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
8
9
Model Specification
3.1
Estimation Techniques . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
3.2
Fixed Effect (FE) Estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
3.3
GMM as a Method of Estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
3.4
Why Dynamic Panel Analysis?
3.5
4
Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Testing for Serial Correlation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
19
Data Presentation and Analysis
4.1
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
Descriptive Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
4.1.1
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
4.1.2
Summary statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
ii
4.1.3
4.2
5
Measurement of Multicollinearity . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
Econometric Estimation Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
4.2.1 Pooled-OLS and Fixed Effects Result . . . . . . . . . . 24
4.2.2 GMM Estimation Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
30
Concluding Remarks
iii
List of Tables
4.1
4.2
4.3
4.4
4.5
Summary Statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Missing values summary statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . .
The Correlation between Variables . . . . . . . . . . . .
Pooled-OLS and Fixed Effects Result with logarithm and
One step system GMM and One step difference GMM . .
5.1
5.2
Dynamic panel-data estimation with levels . . . . . . . . . . . 35
Missing summary statistics for Dynamic panel-data estimation 36
iv
. . .
. . .
. . .
levels
. . .
20
21
22
26
28
List of Figures
4.1
4.2
Scatter plot for per capita GDP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
Scatter plot for Urbanization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
v
vi
Chapter 1
Introduction
1.1
Some Backgrounds
Urbanization is closely linked to economic development. As economies develop, relative and absolute changes in demand increase the relative and
absolute importance of the manufacturing and service sectors. The relationship between urbanization and economic growth across various countries in
Africa is unclear. As these economies urbanize and grow, it is difficult to
interpret what one can expect from such growth of urbanization.
Whether economic growth stimulates urbanization or vice-versa, or they
move together is debatable issue. Indeed, this project tries to investigate
the impact of urbanization on economic growth of African countries using
panel data and Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) as a method of estimation.
Urbanization in Africa has different trends and contentious in its contributions for economic growth. Currently, urbanization is in its high growth rate
and indeed, most of African countries economies grow as well. Therefore, it
is timely to investigate if urbanization can be important variable as evidences
show they grow simultaneously.
Cities encompass enormous control over national economies as they provide
jobs, access to the best cultural, educational and health facilities and also act
as hubs for communication and transports which are necessary conditions for
1
economic development of any nation (Polèse, 2005) On the other hand, cities
also cluster massive demand for energy, generate large quantities of waste
and concentrate pollution as well as social hardship. According to Sarker
et al. (2016), the economic and social crises that have enveloped in most of
the developing countries are a result of urban growth without proportionate
economic development. Some others also agree that the continuous increase
in the proportion of people living in cities as compared to rural areas in the
developing countries has resulted to large number of slums and deplorable
living conditions in the cities and in most cases worsening the economic circumstances of urban migrants of the countries.
1.2
Questions to be answered
The questions asked are; why urbanization which was a necessary condition
for economic development of developed countries has underestimated element to the development process of African countries? What explains the
relationship between urbanization and economic development in third world
nations? Should developing countries encourage urbanization as part of economic development strategy? Or is high rate of urbanization just a necessary
condition for economic growth? These and others are frequently asked by
scholars and researchers in the area. In this project, we try to answer the
last two questions.
Some try to answer these questions by applying different methods, for instance, McCoskey et al. (1998) employed OLS however, did not properly address the problem of endogenety.Barrios et al. (2003) employed semi-parametric
estimation techniques in their qualitative analysis, as a measure of urbanization and economic growth; their study suffered from the problem of perception bias, not to mention, measurement error. Other studies present
cross-sectional estimates, but did not adequately control the problem of endogeneity. Some findings reflect unobserved characteristics which do not vary
over time instead of being the consequences of urbanization or might reflect
reverse causality.
By considering these, in this project we try to answer some of the questions
2
and mainly we examine African data to answer:
• What looks like the relationship between urbanization and economic
growth in Africa?
• Do African countries experience an increasing economic growth and
urbanization growth simultaneously?
• Should African countries encourage urbanization as part of economic
development strategy?
Therefore, we revisit urbanization and economic growth in Africa by employing panel data and panel data models. The study avoids problems committed
by most of the studies reviewed using IV strategy during estimation of the
impact of urbanization on economic growth and we recommend and implicate
policy issues regarding urbanization in the continent.
1.3
Endogenous Growth Theory
In the 1960s, growth theory consisted mainly of the neoclassical model, as
developed by (Solow, 1956; Swan, 1956; Koopmans et al., 1965). Endogenous growth theories that include the discovery of new ideas and methods of
production are important for providing possible explanations for long-term
growth. Yet the recent cross-country empirical work on growth has received
more inspiration from the older neoclassical model, as extended to include
government policies, human capital, and the diffusion of technology. Theories of basic technological change seem most important for understanding
why the world can continue to grow indefinitely in per capita terms. But
these theories have less to do with the determination of relative rates of
growth across countries, the key element studied in cross-country statistical
analyses.
Recent extensions of the model suggest the inclusion of additional sources of
cross-country variation, especially government policies with respect to levels
of consumption spending, protection of property rights, and distortions of
domestic and international markets.
3
1.4
Growth at cross Countries level
The Neo classical model starts explaining economic growth as:
Y = f (K, L, A)
(1.4.1)
where Y is output, K is capital formation and L labor and A is technology.
For example, Barro and Lee (1993) and Barro and Sala-i Martin (1997)
include additional variables to determine the economic growth. With that
inspirations, our model incorporates urbanization among the explanatory
variables.
lnYit = lnGit +lnGEit +lnDGCit +lnOkit +lnUit +lnTit +lnEC +εit (1.4.2)
where lnYit economic growth (in logarithmic terms) of country i at time t,
GEit gross expenditure of country i at time t, CFit the difference between
gross expenditure and gross capital formation of country i, at time t, Okit
trade openness (degree of openness) of country i at time t, Uit urbanization
of country i at time t, Tit international tourism, receipts of country i at time
ECit and εit iid error terms.
1.5
Variables in the Model
GDP Per Capita (constant 2010 US$) is used as the dependent variable and
we use the logarithm of this variable as we can explain the elasticities of some
changes in explanatory variables
Gross Capital Formation (constant 2010 US$)
Gross capital formation (formerly gross domestic investment) consists of outlays on additions to the fixed assets of the economy plus net changes in the
level of inventories. Fixed assets include land improvements (fences, ditches,
drains, and so on); plant, machinery, and equipment purchases; and the construction of roads, railways, and the like, including schools, offices, hospitals,
private residential dwellings, and commercial and industrial buildings. In4
ventories are stocks of goods held by firms to meet temporary or unexpected
fluctuations in production or sales, and ”work in progress.” According to the
1993 SNA, net acquisitions of valuables are also considered capital formation.
Data are in constant 2010 U.S. dollars.
Gross National Expenditure (constant 2010 US$)
Gross national expenditure (formerly domestic absorption) is the sum of
household final consumption expenditure (formerly private consumption),
general government final consumption expenditure (formerly general government consumption), and gross capital formation (formerly gross domestic
investment). Data are in constant 2010 U.S. dollars.
Openness or Terms of Trade (% of GDP)
The relationship between openness and economic growth has long been a
subject of much interest and controversy in international trade literature.
Regarding a theoretical relationship between openness and growth most of
the studies provide support for the proposition that openness affects growth
positively. Romer (1986) and Barro and Sala-i Martin (1997) among others,
argue that countries that are more open have a greater ability to catch up
with leading technologies of the rest of the world. We will measure openness
with trade share ( (Import+Export)
) is used in this analysis ( Trade is the sum
GDP
of exports and imports of goods and services measured as a share of gross
domestic product.)
Urban Population (% age of national population)
Urban population refers to people living in urban areas as defined by national
statistical offices. The data are collected and smoothed by United Nations
Population Division.
International Tourism,Rreceipts (% of total exports)
International tourism receipts are expenditures by international inbound visitors, including payments to national carriers for international transport.
These receipts include any other prepayment made for goods or services re5
ceived in the destination country. They also may include receipts from sameday visitors, except when these are important enough to justify separate
classification. For some countries they do not include receipts for passenger
transport items. Their share in exports is calculated as a ratio to exports
of goods and services, which comprise all transactions between residents of
a country and the rest of the world involving a change of ownership from
residents to nonresidents of general merchandise, goods sent for processing
and repairs, nonmonetary gold, and services.
Renewable Energy Consumption (% of total final energy consumption)
Renewable energy consumption is the share of renewable energy in total final
energy consumption. Unemployment with advanced education (% of total labor force with advanced education). The percentage of the labor force with
an advanced level of education who are unemployed. Advanced education
comprises short-cycle tertiary education, a bachelor’s degree or equivalent
education level, a master’s degree or equivalent education level, or doctoral
degree or equivalent education level according to the International Standard
Classification of Education 2011 (ISCED 2011).
1.5.1
Data
Data for this project is extracted from World Development Indicators. We
include data of 40 African countries1 for 27 years (from 1990-2016). The
starting year 1990 is chosen due the the fact that most African countries
have some policy and regime changes in the 1990s.
1
Algeria, Angola, Benin, Botswana, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cape Verde, Djibouti,
Cameroon, Central African Republic, Congo, Dem. Rep., Comoros, Congo, Republic
of, Cote d‘Ivoire, Egypt, Equatorial Guinea, Eritrea, Gabon, Gambia, Ghana, Kenya,
Lesotho, Liberia, Libya, Malawi, Mali, Morocco, Namibia, Niger, Rwanda, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, South Africa, Sudan, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia and Zimbabwe
6
Chapter 2
Related Literature
2.1
Urbanization
Demographically, the term urbanization denotes the redistribution of population from rural to urban settlement over time. However, it is important
to acknowledge that the criteria for defining what is urban may vary from
country to country which cautions one against a strict composition of urbanization across countries. The fundamental difference between urban and
rural is that urban populations live in larger, denser, and more heterogeneous
places as opposed to small, sparse, and less differentiated rural places.
(Henderson, 2003).
Economically, it is a process that considers human, economic, social, amenities, etc. agglomeration, which translates an area of country side or a village,
into a town or part of one or further growth and expansion of already existing
urban centers. Urbanization occurs as countries switch sectoral composition
away from agriculture into industry and as technological advances in domestic agriculture release labor from agriculture to migrate to cities (Moomaw
and Shatter, 1993).
That said about the meaning of urbanization, it is worth noting the impacts
and/or determinants of urbanization and its impact on an economy. Result
of studies of both impacts/determinants and implications of urbanization at
cross country level have long been in the literature.
7
In terms of development and growth theory, urbanization occupies a puzzling
position. On the one hand, it is recognized as fundamental to the multidimensional structural transformation that low-income rural societies undergo
to modernize and to join the ranks of middle- and high-income countries.
Some models, such as Lucas (2004), explicitly consider how urbanization affects the growth process (primarily through the enhanced flow of ideas and
knowledge attributable to agglomeration in cities.
2.2
Urbanization issues in Africa
A growing literature argues that, in the period since independence, Africa’s
urbanization process has differed fundamentally from the rest of the developing world. This complements a large literature arguing that many economic
processes in Africa are different Binswanger and Townsend (2000); Acemoglu
and Robinson (2010). The urbanization literature suggests that two stylized
facts that hold for the rest of the world do not hold for Africa.
First, while rapid urbanization in other developing regions has been accompanied by fast macro-economic growth, Africa has seen urbanization without
growth (Gollin et al., 2016). Second, while, in the rest of the world, urbanization has generally been accompanied by a sector transformation from
agriculture to manufacturing, Africa is urbanizing without industrialization.
Empirical evaluation of both stylized facts is complicated by relatively low
quality data for Africa and by the issue of how to evaluate causal relationships.
Despite the region’s clear urbanization trend, national governments and development groups continue to direct their energies toward rural economic development. Economists attribute this focus to a widespread belief in “urban
bias,” the notion that urban groups receive preferential economic treatment
because, by virtue of their location, they are able to pressure the government
more effectively than rural groups.
8
Chapter 3
Model Specification
To meet the main objective of this project, urbanization is included as one of
the explanatory variables for economic growth. More specifically, the project
has the following model, adapted from the extended version of neo-classical
growth model:
Yit = αt + θ′ Xit + β ′ Uit + εit
(3.0.1)
where Yit measures the log of annual growth rate in real GDP per capita in
country i at time t; Xit is n × k vector of variables identified as the important determinants of economic growth in country i and at time t supposed to
have full column rank and E(x′it εit ) = 0; Uit is the interest variable which is
urbanization rate in country i and at time t with E(Uit′ εit ) 6= 0 hence, endogenous; α θ and, β are θ k ×n vector of coefficients; and εit is the iid error term.
Xit are extended Barro’s regression economic growth determinants which
include: gross capital formation, gross government expenditure, percentage of
total trade, FDI, international tourism and renewable energy consumption.
In addition, urbanization is defined as ratio of urban population to total
population.
More interestingly, the project have the following dynamic regression model:
Yit = αi + γ ′ Yit−1 + θ′ Xit + β ′ Uit + εit
9
(3.0.2)
where everything is the same as in (3.0.1), but in (3.0.2), we include the lag
of the dependent variable as explanatory.
3.1
Estimation Techniques
Pooled-OLS
To estimate the above econometric model, we apply Pooled-OlS as a benchmark to see the signs and magnitude of the estimations. Since in panel data
analysis, the assumptions underlying pooled-OLS are unlikely to be maintained (it will be heavily biased because of unobserved heterogeneity (Uit and
Xit would be correlated)).
This is due to the fact that pooled-OLS also relies on a between comparison
(variation). Compared with the cross-sectional OLS the bias is lower, because pooled-OLS also takes in-to account the within variation.
3.2
Fixed Effect (FE) Estimation
The number of years (T = 27). If T were larger than number of countries
(N = 40), one year shocks impact on the country’s apparent fixed effect
would dwindle and so would the endogeneity problem raise here. There are
two ways to deal with this endogeneity. One way to solve this problem is using Difference Generalized Methods of Moments (DGMM) since it transforms
the data to remove the fixed effects and the other is, to instrument (Yit ), and
any other similarly endogenous variables which have reverse causality using
System GMM (Greene, 2008).
An intuitive first attack on the fixed effects is to draw them out of the error
term by entering dummies for each individual-the so-called Least Squares
Dummy Variables (LSDV) estimator. To show how it works mathematically
consider the following:
If zi is unobserved, but correlated with Xit and Uit then the least squares estimator of γ, β and θ would be biased and inconsistent because of an omitted
10
variable. In this instance, the model:
Yit = ψi + γ ′ Yit−1 + θ′ Xit + β ′ Uit + εit
(3.2.1)
where ψi = zt′ αi , embodies all effects and specifies an estimable conditional
mean. This fixed effects approach takes αi to be a group-specific constant
term in the regression model. It should be noted that the term “fixed” as
used here signifies the correlation of αi and Xit , that αi is non-stochastic.
In applying Fixed Effects (FE) estimation, the important thing is that the
country specific errors have disappeared. There is no longer need of the
assumption that country specific error is uncorrelated with explanatory variables. i.e time-constant unobserved heterogeneity is no longer a problem.
Time-invariant country characteristics (fixed effects), such as geography and
demographics, may be correlated with the explanatory variables. The fixed
effects are contained in the error term in equation (3.2.1), which consists
of the unobserved country-specific effects, αi , and the observation-specific
errors, εit .
3.3
GMM as a Method of Estimation
As to Baltagi (2008), which this project employs, gives more information
and more variability in data since large numbers of data points are available.
These special features lead to less collinearity among variables, more degrees
of freedom and more efficiency. Furthermore, panel data method better controls heterogeneity among economic variables and allows one to construct
and test more complicated behavioral models than pure cross-sectional and
time series data.
However, looking at our models in equation (3.0.2) it includes the lagged
dependent variable as a regressor. From this growth equation, the unobservable country specific effect (αi ) affects the dependent variable lnYit . Due to
this relationship, lnYit−1 is a function of αi i.e (Yit−1 ǫit ) 6= 0. This econometric problem accompanied with the omitted variable bias, measurement
error, and endogeneity of other regressors, which are common problems in
11
panel data models, leads to inefficient estimates by standard econometric
techniques like OLS and FE.
The GMM method provides a solution to these problems as well as yielding
estimates of unobserved country-specific effects and dummy coefficients for
which the usual methods would be inappropriate given the dynamic nature of
the regression Bond (2002). There are two types of GMM estimators based
on the assumption made and resulting moment restriction, and thus variables
used as instruments in the estimation process: the difference GMM and the
system GMM.
The difference GMM estimator (DGMM) for dynamic panels was introduced
by Holtz-Eakin et al. (1988), Arellano and Bond (1991), and Arellano and
Bover (1995). It is based on differencing the series to eliminate unobserved
country specific effects and use lagged explanatory and dependent variables
as instruments, called-internal instruments to avoid autocorrelation problem.
So, let’s show how GMM estimation technique alleviates the problems faced
in the above standard estimation techniques like OLS and FE.
The difference and system GMM estimators can be seen as part of broader
historical trend in econometric practice toward estimators that make fewer
assumptions about the underlying data-generating process and use more complex techniques to isolate useful information.
The difference and system GMM estimators are designed for panel analysis,
and embody the following assumptions about the data-generating process:
1) There may be arbitrarily distributed fixed individual effects. This argues
against cross-section regressions, which must essentially assume fixed effects
are not problems, and in favor of a panel set-up, where variation over time
can be used to identify parameters.
2) The process may be dynamic, with current realizations of the dependent
variable influenced by past ones.
3) Some regressors may be endogenous.
4) The idiosyncratic disturbances (those apart from the fixed effects) may
have individual-specific patterns of heteroskedasticity and serial correlation.
5) The idiosyncratic disturbances are uncorrelated across individuals. In addition, some secondary worries shape the design: 6) Some regressors may
12
be predetermined but not strictly exogenous: even if independent of current
disturbances, still influenced by past ones. The lagged dependent variable is
an example. The number of time periods of available data, T, may be small
(panel is “small T, large N.”)
7) Finally, since the estimators are designed for general use, they do not assume that good instruments are available outside the immediate data set.
In effect, it is assumed that: The only available instruments are “internal”based on lags of the instrumented variables. However, the estimators do
allow inclusion of external instruments.
3.4
Why Dynamic Panel Analysis?
1) Static panel estimates, as do the OLS models, omit dynamics causing the
problem of dynamic panel bias Roodman (2015) and as such do not allow
one to study the dynamics of adjustment (Baltagi, 2008). Omitted dynamics
means that such models are wrongly specified, because they omit the entire
history of the right-hand-side variables (Bond, 2002).
2) In this panel, there are 40 countries (N) that are analyzed over a period
of 27 years (T). Accordingly, there are more countries (N) than years (T).
Many authors argue that the dynamic panel model is specially designed for
a situation where “T” is smaller than “N” to control for dynamic panel bias
(Bond, 2002; Baum and Christopher, 2006; Roodman, 2006).
3) The problem of potential endogeneity is also much easier to address in
the dynamic panel models than in the static and OLS models that do not
allow the use of internally generating instruments. An underlying advantage
of the dynamic GMM estimation is that all variables from the regression
that are not correlated with the error term (including lagged and differenced
variables) can be potentially used as valid instruments (Greene, 2008).
4) Finally, the OLS and static panel estimates do not allow a separate analysis of the short and long-run effects of urbanization on economic growth;
hence, an additional advantage of the dynamic panel model is its ability to
identify both short run impact and long-run urbanization effects (Baltagi,
2008; Roodman, 2006), which is particularly important for this project.
13
After identifying the dynamic panel model as the most appropriate econometric technique for the estimation, the we had to decide which dynamic panel
approach to apply. Notwithstanding that the General Method of Moments
(GMM) is the method of estimation of dynamic panel models that provides
consistent estimates, one still must decide whether to use: differenceGMM
or, system-GMM estimation. Before deciding which GMM method is appropriate to our model, it is rational to show how the GMM works.
To begin with, one step GMM estimator was used as it has been shown to
result in more reliable inferences Baltagi (2008). The selection of one-step
GMM was based on the fact that it ensures consistency and efficiency while
dealing with heteroscedasticity and serial correlation. Also, to avoid the potential endogeneity among variables, one-step difference GMM technique is
used.
Having introduced the various panel data tests and estimation techniques
to calculate growth of real GDP per capita and urbanization, we now able
to investigate the impact of urbanization on the economic performance. As
urbanization, which is the variable of interest in this project, is among the
explanatory variables in the theoretical growth regression equation.
Yit = αi + γ ′ Yit−1 + θ′ Xit + β ′ Uit + ηi + εit
(3.4.1)
εit = ηi + vit
E(µi ) = E(vit ) = (ηi vit ) = 0
(3.4.2)
Where ηi represents unobserved country-specific factors and εit is the error
term of the dynamic panel regression model.
Turning to the growth determinants, the model includes one period lagged
value of economic growth variable, urbanization which is the interest variable
and all the other determinants that are represented by a vector of Xit (i.e.,
gross capital formation, gross expenditure, interest payments, terms of trade,
FDI, and some institutional variables). Recall that the one period lagged
value of economic growth is also good explanatory variable for conditional
convergence.
14
The GMM method provides a solution to these problems using OLS and FE
estimation techniques as well as yielding estimates of unobserved country
specific effects and dummy coefficients for which the usual methods would
be inappropriate given the dynamic nature of the regression. From (3.4.1),
ηi is country specific effect. To eliminate the country-specific effect, let’s take
the first-differences of equation (3.4.3) below,
(Yit −Yit−1 ) = (αi −αi )+γ ′ (Yit−1 −Yit−2 )+θ′ (Xit −Xit−1 )+β ′ (Uit −Uit−1 )+(εit −εit−1 )
(3.4.3)
In the presence of the country specific effect αi , it is well known that the OLS
estimate of the coefficient on the lagged dependent variable γ is likely to be
biased upward since the lagged dependent variable is positively correlated
with αi (Blundell and Bond, 1998).
By transformation process, the country specific effects αi can be removed as
one can see from (3.4.3). A disadvantage of using the fixed effects model
is that it uses only the variation within countries and the cross-sectional
variation is discarded.
In addition, equation (3.4.3) contains a lagged endogenous variable, namely
the economic growth. Thus, with a small number of time series periods, the
model provides biased and inconsistent estimates even if data from many
countries are considered. In contrast to the OLS estimate, the fixed effects
estimate of the coefficient on the lagged dependent variable γ is likely to be
biased down ward (Arellano and Bond, 1991).
They suggest an alternative estimation technique that addresses the presence
of the lagged endogenous variable and permits a certain degree of endogeneity
in the other explanatory variables. Arellano and Bond (1991) use difference
GMM estimator to eliminate the country-specific effect, and then used all
possible lagged levels as instruments. Accordingly, we apply Arellano and
Bond’s difference equation and the model becomes:
∆Yit = γ ′ ∆Yit−1 + θ′ ∆Xit + β ′ ∆Uit + ∆εit
E(∆Yit−1 ∆εit ) 6= 0
15
(3.4.4)
where ∆ is a difference operator and the others as defined before. In the
first equation above, we got rid of αi , which is correlated with our regressors,
but we generated a new endogeneity problem. The second equation above
illustrates one of our regressors is related to our unobservables. The solution
is instrumental variables. Which instrumental variables? Arellano–Bond
suggest the second lags of the dependent variable and all the feasible lags
thereafter. This generates the set of moment conditions defined by
E(Yi,(t−2) ∆εit )
=
0
E(Xi(t−3) ∆εit )
=
0
···
E(Ui(t−j) ∆εit )
=
0
We have 27 time period which yield the following set of instruments:
t = 27 Yt−25 , Yt−24 , Yt−23 , Yt−22 , Yt−21 , Yt−20 , · · · , Yt−3 , Yt−2 , Yt−1
t = 26 Yt−24 , Yt−23 , Yt−22 , Yt−21 , Yt−20 , · · · , Yt−3 , Yt−2 , Yt−1
t = 25 Yt−23 , Yt−22 , Yt−21 , Yt−20 , · · · , Yt−3 , Yt−2 , Yt−1
..
.
···
t = 10 Yt−8 , Yt−7 , Yt−6 , Yt−5 , Yt−4 , Yt−3 , Yt−2 , Yt−1
t = 9 Yt−7 , Yt−6 , Yt−5 , Yt−4 , Yt−3 , Yt−2 , Yt−1
t = 8 Yt−6 , Yt−5 , Yt−4 , Yt−3 , Yt−2 , Yt−1
t = 7 Yt−5 , Yt−4 , Yt−3 , Yt−2 , Yt−1
t = 6 Yt−4 , Yt−3 , Yt−2 , Yt−1
t = 5 Yt−3 , Yt−2 , Yt−1
t = 4 Yt−2 , Yt−1
t = 3 Yt−1
Assuming that Xit are predetermined in the sense that Xit and εit are uncorrelated, but Xit may be correlated with εi,t−1 . and earlier errors, Xit lagged
one period or more are also used as valid instruments. Thus, the relevant
16
moment conditions are:
E(Yit−j ∆vit ) = 0 for j ≥ 2t;
t = 3, . . . ., T
E(Xit−j ∆vit ) = 0 for j ≥ 2t;
t = 3, . . . ., T
E(Uit−j ∆vit ) = 0 for j ≥ 2t;
t = 3, . . . ., T
where vit = αi + εit
The system GMM estimator combines the standard set of moment conditions
in first differences with lagged levels as instruments, with an additional set
of moment conditions derived from the equation in levels. The availability of
additional moment conditions depends on assumptions made about the correlation between Xit and the country-specific effect αi . Arellano and Bover
(1995), it is assumed that the difference of Xit is uncorrelated with the individual effects although Xit and αi can be correlated. Thus, the additional
moment conditions for the equation in levels are:
E(∆Yit−1 vit ) = 0
(3.4.5)
E(∆Xit−1 vit ) = 0
(3.4.6)
E(∆Uit−1 vit ) = 0
(3.4.7)
the difference GMM dynamic panel estimator uses the following moment
conditions:
E(Yit−j εit − εi,t−1 ) = 0 forj ≥ 2; t = j. . . T
(3.4.8)
E(Xit−j εit − εi,t−1 ) = 0forj ≥ 2; t = j. . . T
3.5
(3.4.9)
Testing for Serial Correlation
We can test these conditions in STATA. In essence, the differenced unobserved time-invariant component should be unrelated to the second lag of
the dependent variable and the lags thereafter. If this is not the case, we are
back to the initial problem, endogeneity. Again, a bit of math will help us
17
understand what is going on.
All is well if
∆ǫit = ∆vit
(3.5.1)
The unobservable is serially correlated of order 1 but not serially correlated
of orders 2 or beyond. But we are in trouble if
∆ǫit = ∆vit + ∆vi(t−1)
(3.5.2)
The second lag of the dependent variable will be related to the differenced
time-varying component ∆ǫit . Another way of saying this is that the differenced time-varying unobserved component is serially correlated with an
order greater than 1.
18
Chapter 4
Data Presentation and Analysis
4.1
4.1.1
Descriptive Analysis
Introduction
Under this section, which is the heart of the investigation, we present and
discuss the main results in accordance with answering the objectives of the
project. Before we conduct the GMM regressions of economic growth, we examine the summary statistics, intensity of collinearity, the degree of graphical
association, and the extent of normality for the economic growth variables
and urbanization.
Table (4.1) below reports the summary statistics for the dependent and independent variables of the specified growth model.
4.1.2
Summary statistics
As the summary statistics show, some of the variables have too many missing
values. Per capita GDP, openness, urbanization and energy consumption are
the variable with less missing values.
As far as economic growth is concerned, the real GDP per capita in PPP
(2011 US$) of African countries has on average grown by 4679.43 percent under the period taken into consideration. Compared to their economic status
and living condition, this per capita GDP could be taken as typical. When
19
Table 4.1: Summary Statistics
Variable
Mean
Std. Dev.
Min
Max
Obs.
PCI
overall
between
within
4679.43
6079.24
5979.606
2536.167
247.4365
642.2806
-13944.28
40015.82
24008.61
25113.19
Capital For
overall
between
within
7.81E+09
1.54E+10
1.23E+10
7.01E+09
-1.35E+07
5.83E+07
-2.09E+10
9.65E+10
5.51E+10
5.80E+10
N = 740
n = 37
bar = 20
Gross Exp
overall
between
within
3.47E+10
6.72E+10
5.68E+10
2.24E+10
2.92E+08
6.60E+08
-6.49E+10
4.26E+11
2.95E+11
1.65E+11
N = 739
n = 37
bar = 19.973
Openness
overall
between
within
74.52915
47.29362
38.14408
29.11954
11.08746
26.89246
-57.91608
531.7374
226.7788
379.4878
N = 998
n = 39
bar = 25.5897
Urban
overall
between
within
40.26608
17.74929
17.60246
3.711669
6.271
9.054963
28.40712
87.366
80.78674
51.92075
N = 1048
n = 39
T = 26.8718
Tourism
overall
between
within
13.69709
13.92816
13.62536
4.65538
0.0009562
0.1245983
-3.797377
67.43046
51.99502
41.66949
N = 686
n = 38
bar = 18.0526
Energy cons
overall
between
within
60.23018
30.2252
29.4626
7.919134
0.0589587
0.3537298
28.42465
98.3426
96.46798
107.7834
N = 1001
n = 39
T = 25.6667
20
N = 1031
n = 39
T = 26.4359
one explores the smallest and the greatest GDP per capita realized in Liberia
(247.44) in 1995 and Equatorial Guinea 40015.82 in 2008 respectively. Since
1995 most African countries began a major program of economic reform and
liberalization which helped the country to design favorable political, social
and economic conditions that enabled the nation to significantly increase and
achieve the highest level of GDP growth not only in Africa but also in the
world (Wiarda, 2018).
Urban Population (% of total) was 6.271% in Burundi in 1990 and still small
in 2016 (i.e. 11.2%). However, in 2016, 87.4% population of Gabon live in
cities which is by far large number compared to the whole average (40.3).
Table (4.2) shows the missing value summary statistics. From the Table, we
Table 4.2: Missing values summary statistics
Obs < .
Obs = .
Variable
PCI
Capital Formation
Gross Expenditure
Openness
Tourism
Energy Consumption
Urbanization
Obs > .
22
313
314
55
367
52
5
Obs < .
1,031
740
739
998
686
1,001
1,048
Unique
values
Min
Max
> 500
> 500
> 500
> 500
> 500
> 500
> 500
247.4365
-1.35e+07
2.92e+08
11.08746
.0009562
.0589587
6.271
40015.82
9.65e+10
4.26e+11
531.7374
67.43046
98.3426
87.366
can see that urbanization has more observation than other variables. Data
for International Tourism, Receipts (% of total exports) is the least available.
International tourism receipts are expenditures by international inbound visitors, including payments to national carriers for international transport and
this requires careful national records which are
4.1.3
Measurement of Multicollinearity
The dynamic GMM estimation method can help solve the problems of endogeneity, omitted variable bias, serial correlation and heteroskedasticity.
21
However, one crucial pre-estimation test that should be done is the test of
the approximate linear relationship among the explanatory variables (i.e.
multicollinearity).
Pair-wise correlation between regressors is one of the most commonly employed detection method to measure the problem of multicollinearity. The
correlation matrix (left for the sake of space) measures the severity of linear
relationship among the economic growth explanatory variables. In a nutshell, the outcome reveals the absence of the problem of multicollinearity.
The only highest pair-wise correlation occurred between Gross expenditure
and capital formation, 0.9466, which is large compared to correlation values
of 0.8 which are commonly taken as a Rule of Thumb to conclude the presence of multicollinearity problem.
Although the above descriptive analysis portrays the individual association between growth rate of real GDP per capita and its determinants, it
neither exposes the statistical significance of the relationship nor guarantees
whether this relationship can be maintained when other explanatory variables are simultaneously included. The most dependable and sophisticated
econometric analysis will be undertaken in the following subsection.
In addition to the pairwise correlation of variables, we can see the ecoTable 4.3: The Correlation between Variables
ln
ln
ln
ln
ln
ln
ln
PCI
CF
GE
Open
Ur
Tour
EC
ln PCI
ln CF
ln GE
ln Open
1.0000
0.6019
0.4734
0.3881
0.5978
0.0719
-0.7606
1.0000
0.9461
-0.1184
0.4012
-0.0595
-0.5279
1.0000
-0.2731
0.322
-0.0197
-0.4767
ln Ur
1.0000
0.4064 1.0000
-0.0594 -0.0745
-0.2879 -0.5552
ln Tour
ln EC
1.0000
-0.1785
1.0000
nomic growth and urbanization trend during the period we have taken into
consideration. The scatter plots (4.1 ) and (4.2) do not show whether there
exist relationship between the two variables though both of them are grow22
40015.819
40015.819247.43654
40015.819247.43654
40015.819247.43654
Benin
Botswana
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cabo Verde
Cameroon
Central African R.
Comoros
Congo, Dem. Rep.
Congo, Rep.
Cote d'Ivoire
Djibouti
Egypt, Arab Rep.
Equatorial Guinea
Eritrea
Gabon
Gambia, The
Ghana
Kenya
Lesotho
Liberia
Libya
Malawi
Mali
Morocco
Namibia
Niger
Senegal
Seychelles
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Sudan
Tanzania
1990
40015.819
247.43654
Pre Capita GDP
40015.819247.43654
Angola
247.43654
Algeria
Togo
1990
2000
2010
Uganda
2020 1990
2000
2010
Zambia
2020 1990
2000
2010
2000
2010
2020 1990
2000
2010
2020 1990
Zimbabwe
2020 1990
2000
2010
2020
Year
Figure 4.1: Scatter plot for per capita GDP
23
2000
2010
2020
100
Angola
Benin
Botswana
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cabo Verde
Cameroon
Central African R.
Comoros
Congo, Dem. Rep.
Congo, Rep.
Cote d'Ivoire
Djibouti
Egypt, Arab Rep.
Equatorial Guinea
Eritrea
Gabon
Gambia, The
Ghana
Kenya
Lesotho
Liberia
Libya
Malawi
Mali
Morocco
Namibia
Niger
Senegal
Seychelles
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Sudan
Tanzania
50
0
100
50
0
50
100
0
Urabanization
100
0
50
100
0
50
Algeria
1990
Uganda
Zambia
2010
2020 1990
2000
2010
2020 1990
2000
2010
2020
Zimbabwe
0
50
100
Togo
2000
1990
2000
2010
2020 1990
2000
2010
2020 1990
2000
2010
2020 1990
2000
2010
2020
Year
Figure 4.2: Scatter plot for Urbanization
ing during the period. Therefore, we can carry out the major econometric
estimation as most of the variables are normally distributed.
4.2
Econometric Estimation Results
4.2.1
Pooled-OLS and Fixed Effects Result
In this part of the analysis we discuss the determinants of Per capita GDP
(measure of economic growth). The output in Table (4.4) below will be
reviewed a bit more carefully. First, one can see that the F-test is statistically significant, which means, the model is working. The adjusted R2 of
24
0.937 means that more 90% of the variance of economic growth is accounted
for by the model and in this case, the adjusted R2 indicates that approximately about 0.927 of the variability of economic growth is accounted for
by the model, even after considering the number of predictor variables in
the model. The coefficient for each of the variable indicates the amount of
change one could expect in economic growth given a unit change in the value
of that variable, given that all other variables in the model are held constant.
Urbanization, the interest variable, (β = −0.005) in OLS and −0.008 in
FE estimations and significant in FE estimation. However, urbanization is
significant in level with (−0.826). The striking result is that the coefficient of
urbanization is negative which is unexpected. The lagged dependent variable
is significant and its sign is expected. The magnitude and the sign shows the
conditional convergence of poor countries have the tendency to grow faster
than rich countries(Barro and Sala-i Martin, 1997).
As it is mentioned in the methodology section, the fact that urbanization is
measured with error and urbanization and economic growth are measured
endogenously creates attenuation and may bias the Pooled-OLS estimates
downward. However, one can solve these problems using instrumental variable method of estimation. These instruments must be important factors
in accounting for the variation in urbanization rates that one observes, but
have no direct effect on economic growth. However, before considering the
instrumental variable method of estimation,the fixed effects results will be
discussed.
As far as the fixed effect result is concerned, the model controls for all timeinvariant differences between the individuals, so the estimated coefficients of
the fixed effects models cannot be biased because of omitted time-invariant
characteristics. One side effect of the features of fixed effects models is that
they cannot be used to investigate time-invariant causes of the dependent
variables. Technically, time-invariant characteristics of the countries are perfectly collinear with countries dummies. Substantively, fixed-effects models
are designed to study the causes of changes within a person (or countries). A
time-invariant characteristic cannot cause such a change, because it is constant for each person.
25
Table 4.4: Pooled-OLS and Fixed Effects Result with logarithm and levels
VARIABLES
OLS
FE
ln PCI(lagged)
0.987***
(0.00383)
0.0160***
(0.00489)
-0.00812
(0.00518)
0.0249***
(0.00500)
-0.00525
(0.00520)
0.00205
(0.00136)
-1.38e-05
(0.000106)
0.792***
(0.0218)
0.0172**
(0.00786)
0.0922***
(0.0177)
0.0153*
(0.00882)
-0.142***
(0.0353)
0.00704**
(0.00277)
-0.000257
(0.000371)
ln Capital Formation
ln Gross Expenditure
ln Openness
ln Urbanization
ln Tourism
ln Energy Consumption
PCI(lagged)
498
0.940
-0.422**
(0.198)
498
0.998
498
0.947
498
0.998
Openness
Urbanization
Tourism
Energy Consumption
∗
0.955***
(0.0170)
1.03e-08**
(5.06e-09)
-1.83e-09
(1.09e-09)
1.202
(0.860)
1.023
(8.092)
-0.0142
(1.855)
-3.030
(2.885)
294.3
(505.1)
-0.120**
(0.0576)
Gross Expenditure
Observations
R2
FE
1.000***
(0.00341)
7.13e-10
(1.58e-09)
-1.67e-11
(3.41e-10)
0.963***
(0.238)
-2.471***
(0.826)
-0.696
(0.811)
-2.782***
(0.524)
277.0***
(59.94)
Capital Formation
Constant
OLS
t statistics in parentheses
, p < 0.05,∗∗ p < 0.01,∗∗∗ p < 0.001
26
As far as our findings are concerned, urbanization and tourism become statistically significant which are not in OLS estimation. σu and σe are .238
and .032 respectively. F test that all ui = 0 : F (35, 455) = 8.01 with
P rob > F = 0.0000. Four countries due to country specific problems and
and more than 500 observations are dropped due to missing values. The
correlation of (Ui , βX) of F E result is 0.5329 and it indicates that the errors
are correlated with the regressors in the fixed effects model.
13.6% percent of the variance is due to differences across panels. (ρ = .65)
is known as the intra-class correlation. (σu = 262.04) is the standard deviation of residuals within groups and (σe = .032) is the standard deviation of
residuals (overall error term) εit . The problem in this fixed effect is that still
our interest variable, urbanization is not significant.
Finally, To see if time fixed effects are needed when running a FE model, the
joint test was computed to see if the dummies for all years are equal to 0.
Therefore, we reject the null that all year’s coefficients are jointly equal to
zero. Thus, no need of time fixed effects.
4.2.2
GMM Estimation Results
In this section we investigate the impact of urbanization on economic growth
using more advanced econometric estimation techniques which were provided
in the previous sections. To study the link between urbanization and economic growth, we estimate the specified economic growth model.
From Table (4.5) regression results, as matter of novelty, the study came
up with very interesting evidence that ranges from the presence of conditional convergence in African countries with all other statistically significant
regressors. We again confirm that the sign of urbanization is negative for
Per capita GDP in Africa. A recent empirical work in urbanization of Africa
supports of our findings. By Urban areas, growing both in population and
in land cover, pose threats to the integrity of the continent’s ecosystems and
biodiversity but their growth also create opportunities for conservation. The
burgeoning urban populations, especially in Sub-Saharan Africa, increase the
strain on already insufficient infrastructure and bring new governance chal27
Table 4.5: One step system GMM and One step difference GMM
VARIABLES
ln PCI(lagged)
ln Urbanization
ln Capital formation
ln Gross Expenditure
ln Openness
ln Tourism
ln Energy Consumption
SGMM
DGMM
0.992***
(0.0141)
-0.0972***
(0.0244)
0.0383**
(0.0176)
-0.0315*
(0.0174)
0.0632***
(0.0117)
0.0130**
(0.00549)
0.000838**
(0.000415)
0.601***
(0.0336)
-0.299***
(0.0645)
-0.00541
(0.0109)
0.208***
(0.0236)
0.0612***
(0.0128)
0.00296
(0.00418)
-0.00123**
(0.000561)
498
36
461
33
Observations
Number of Country
1
Arellano-Bond test for AR(1) in first differences:
z = −5.94 P r > z = 0.000
2
Arellano-Bond test for AR(2) in first differences:
z = −0.43 P r > z = 0.664
3
Sargan test of overid.
restrictions: χ234 =
93.14 P rob > χ2 = 0.000
4
The notes are for SGMM and we can do the same
for the DGMM.
28
lenges (Güneralp et al., 2017).
The coefficient of the first lag of per capita GDP is positive and significant
at 1%, it confirms that countries with lower per capita income grew faster
than countries with higher per capita income. The result is in line with the
theoretical prediction that was dealt in the previous chapters as well as the
empirical investigations of Barrios et al. (2003) and others.
Table (4.5) also shows difference GMM estimation results, where we use the
lagged and difference variables as instruments for country level economic
growth rates. And, the result shows that a a negative impact of urbanization
on economic growth.
As model specification part, the Sargan test of over identifying restriction
tests whether the instruments applied for the DGMM growth regressions
are correlated with the error terms. Hence, the validity of the SGMM
and DGMM growth regression results can be measured by the Sargan test
value. The Sargan test of over-identifying restriction, as we point in the
regression table notes above, supports the correctness of the SGMM and
DGMM methods of estimations. For instance, the Wald test for SGMM
χ252 = 51.13, ρ > χ252 = 0.508 indicates the regression coefficients are not
jointly zero. This is due to the fact that the research failed to reject the null
hypothesis which hypothesizes the regression coefficients are not jointly zero.
The lagged levels of these variables are weak instruments for equations in
difference especially in small samples. However, the sample is not small and
all the results are significant using DGMM and SGMM as well. Finally,
the Arellano-Bond test for zero autocorrelation in first-differenced error test
shows that H0 No autocorrelation.
29
Chapter 5
Concluding Remarks
In this project, we explored the impact of urbanization on the economic
growth of 40 African countries from the period 1990 to 2016, the impact of
urbanization on economic growth of those African countries is examined. To
achieve this, we use several statistical/econometric approaches.
As far as economic growth is concerned, the average Per capita real GDP in
PPP terms is 4679 for those countries in our model under the period taken
into consideration. Compared to their economic status and living condition,
this per capita GDP could be taken as typical but has to be invoked and
stimulated as some of the countries show positive steps (Güneralp et al.,
2017).
Different theoretical models and empirical investigations have demonstrated
how urbanization can generate incorrect/correct signals to economic development and thereby result in distortion which is due to unavailability of
data and methodological weaknesses. These and other related issues caught
our attention towards studying African urbanization and its effect on the
continent’s economic progress. And finally, we draw the following main conclusions.
First, the overall growth of urbanization is highly important and has been
shown to be quite robust to the inclusion of potentially relevant covariates
in regression as well as in different estimation methods though our finding
shows that urbanization has negatively correlated with economic growth in
30
the region.
Second, there is the presence of conditional convergence in Africa. Therefore,
poor countries have the tendency to grow faster than rich countries. Those
countries with the lowest growth rates are those who did not urbanize.
Therefore, we recommend the following points:
• During city planning it should be ensured that adequate infrastructures
and other utilities are available to support the urban residences. This
eliminates some of the negative aspects of urbanization and possible
to make urbanization having great impact on economic growth and
industrialization through agglomeration economic.
• This finding generally upholds the theoretical assertion of positive relationship between economic performance and openness, International
Tourism, Receipts (% of total exports), and grross expenditure (including interest payment). However, urbanization, capital formation and
Renewable Energy Consumption (% of total final energy consumption)
were found to stimulate economic growth in Africa.
• Thus, policy measures that enhance the growth of urban areas over
time which avoid the negative effects and promote open trade has the
potential of significantly stimulating economic growth in Africa. In
other words, sound urban development policies that support economic
openness with greater emphasis on liberalization policy since the continent stands to gain from this policy stance better off to be called
for.
31
Bibliography
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2010). Why is africa poor? Economic
history of developing regions, 25(1):21–50.
Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data:
Monte carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The
review of economic studies, 58(2):277–297.
Arellano, M. and Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable
estimation of error-components models. Journal of econometrics, 68(1):29–
51.
Baltagi, B. (2008). Econometric analysis of panel data. John Wiley & Sons.
Barrios, S., Bertinelli, L., Strobl, E., and Teixeira, A. C. (2003). Agglomeration economies and the location of industries: a comparison of three small
european countries.
Barro, R. J. and Lee, J.-W. (1993). International comparisons of educational
attainment. Journal of monetary economics, 32(3):363–394.
Barro, R. J. and Sala-i Martin, X. (1997). Technological diffusion, convergence, and growth. Journal of Economic growth, 2(1):1–26.
Baum, C. F. and Christopher, F. (2006). An introduction to modern econometrics using Stata. Stata press.
Binswanger, H. P. and Townsend, R. F. (2000). The growth performance of
agriculture in subsaharan africa. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 82(5):1075–1086.
32
Blundell, R. and Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions
in dynamic panel data models. Journal of econometrics, 87(1):115–143.
Bond, S. R. (2002). Dynamic panel data models: a guide to micro data
methods and practice. Portuguese economic journal, 1(2):141–162.
Gollin, D., Jedwab, R., and Vollrath, D. (2016). Urbanization with and
without industrialization. Journal of Economic Growth, 21(1):35–70.
Greene, W. H. (2008). The econometric approach to efficiency analysis. The
measurement of productive efficiency and productivity growth, 1(1):92–250.
Güneralp, B., Lwasa, S., Masundire, H., Parnell, S., and Seto, K. C. (2017).
Urbanization in africa: challenges and opportunities for conservation. Environmental Research Letters, 13(1):015002.
Henderson, V. (2003). The urbanization process and economic growth: The
so-what question. Journal of Economic growth, 8(1):47–71.
Holtz-Eakin, D., Newey, W., and Rosen, H. S. (1988). Estimating vector autoregressions with panel data. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric
Society, pages 1371–1395.
Koopmans, T. C. et al. (1965). On the concept of optimal economic growth.
Lucas, Jr, R. E. (2004). Life earnings and rural-urban migration. Journal of
Political Economy, 112(S1):S29–S59.
McCoskey, S., Kao, C., et al. (1998). A panel data investigation of the relationship between urbanization and growth. United State Naval Academy
and Syracuse University, pages 1–24.
Moomaw, R. and Shatter, A. M. (1993). Urbanization as a factor in economic
growth. Journal of Economics, 19(2):1–6.
Polèse, M. (2005). Cities and national economic growth: a reappraisal. urban
Studies, 42(8):1429–1451.
33
Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of
political economy, 94(5):1002–1037.
Roodman, D. (2006). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference
and system gmm in stata.
Roodman, D. (2015). xtabond2: Stata module to extend xtabond dynamic
panel data estimator.
Sarker, S., Khan, A., and Mannan, M. M. (2016). Urban population and economic growth: South asia perspective. European Journal of Government
and Economics, 5(1):64–75.
Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. The
quarterly journal of economics, 70(1):65–94.
Swan, T. W. (1956). Economic growth and capital accumulation. Economic
record, 32(2):334–361.
Wiarda, H. (2018). Civil society: The American model and third world development. Routledge.
34
Appendix
Table 5.1: Dynamic panel-data estimation with levels
Capital Formation
Gross Expenditure
(1)
GMM
2.74e-09
(0.62)
1.69e-08∗∗∗
(14.50)
Openness
3.814∗∗∗
(7.87)
Urbanization
65.03∗∗∗
(16.46)
Tourism
12.83∗∗∗
(6.95)
Energy Consumption
-32.66∗∗∗
(-19.03)
Constant
2389.7∗∗∗
(10.45)
498
Observations
t statistics in parentheses
∗
p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < 0.01, ∗∗∗ p < 0.001
35
Table 5.2: Missing summary statistics for Dynamic panel-data estimation
country Freq.
Algeria
Angola
Benin
Botswana
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cabo Verde
Cameroon
Comoros
Congo, Dem. Rep.
Congo, Rep.
Cote d’Ivoire
Egypt, Arab Rep.
Equatorial Guinea
Eritrea
Gabon
Gambia, The
Ghana
Kenya
Lesotho
Liberia
Malawi
Mali
Morocco
Namibia
Niger
Senegal
Seychelles
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Sudan
Tanzania
Togo
Uganda
Zambia
Zimbabwe
Total
Percent
Cum.
11
1
21
21
11
19
7
21
10
11
20
8
21
2
6
11
12
10
21
9
10
14
20
21
21
10
20
1
15
21
21
21
21
21
1
7
2.21
0.2
4.22
4.22
2.21
3.82
1.41
4.22
2.01
2.21
4.02
1.61
4.22
0.4
1.2
2.21
2.41
2.01
4.22
1.81
2.01
2.81
4.02
4.22
4.22
2.01
4.02
0.2
3.01
4.22
4.22
4.22
4.22
4.22
0.2
1.41
2.21
2.41
6.63
10.84
13.05
16.87
18.27
22.49
24.5
26.71
30.72
32.33
36.55
36.95
38.15
40.36
42.77
44.78
49
50.8
52.81
55.62
59.64
63.86
68.07
70.08
74.1
74.3
77.31
81.53
85.74
89.96
94.18
98.39
98.59
100
498
100
36