Discussion Papers in Economics
India’s Tryst with Technology: The Way Forward
Amit Shovon Ray and Sabyasachi Saha
June, 2009
Discussion Paper 09-11
Centre for International Trade and Development
School of International Studies
Jawaharlal Nehru University
India
*
INDIA’S TRYST WITH TECHNOLOGY: THE WAY FORWARD
Amit Shovon Ray
and
Sabyasachi Saha
INTRODUCTION
The post-independence technology trajectory for India had two broad objectives. First, it
aimed at building up strategic technological capability, and secondly, it strived to acquire
industrial technological capability through learning and catch-up. Achievements on these
fronts are quite often judged by contrasting the first with the second. If we analyse India’s
technological progress in terms of its achievements on the strategic technology front in
comparison with its technological effort towards industrial competitiveness and economic
growth, we get somewhat mixed and conflicting signals about India’s technological
accomplishments.
The national level endeavour to build up strategic technological capability turned out to
be successful on several counts. We get to see significant achievements in Space
Research, Atomic Energy and Defence – evidently all under government patronage.
Aryabhatta, India’s first satellite was launched way back in 1975 and an indigenously
fabricated satellite launch vehicle was ready by 1980. India exploded its first
underground nuclear device in 1974 and could set up nuclear power plants at Trombay
and Kalapakkam. Later in 1985, the installation of a fast-breeder test reactor at
Kalapakkam indeed marked a big step forward. These milestones, in a way, became the
brightest examples that were cited quite often in support of a larger policy framework
aimed at self-reliance adopted by India after independence. These milestones indeed
deserve special mention because achievements of this order were somewhat unthinkable
in the context of any other LDCs with similarly low levels of GDP per capita in those
years. However, apart from these indicative achievements, it remains to be established
how far India’s success in strategic technology can be compared with the existing global
frontiers in these fields, generally benchmarked by the achievements of the West. But
there is no denial that India’s achievements commanded a lot of awe and admiration from
the entire world, especially given the fact that India was still a poor developing economy
with very limited material capability.
On the industrial front, the Soviet model of a planned economy for India, especially from
the Second Five Year plan onwards, did aspire to mimic the development trajectories of
the advanced industrialised nations. Accordingly, India adopted an inward looking
development strategy and meticulously planned out a diversified industrial production
base ranging from simple consumer items to sophisticated capital goods and heavy
machinery. Therefore building up of indigenous technological capabilities as well as
technological learning for catch-up became extremely important for its industrial and
economic aspirations.
1
However, the flipside of the protectionist trade policy regime revealed itself in the form
of inefficiencies of various kinds. India’s low but steady rate of growth during the initial
years suffered a serious blow during the years of industrial deceleration, the saviour
green revolution in agriculture notwithstanding. There was practically no incentive to
keep pace with the fast changing global technology frontier in many of the manufacturing
sectors, which resulted in Indian industry becoming technologically backward and
inefficient with respect to global standards of costs and quality. Prolonged practice of
inward-looking development policies discouraged competition and therefore killed the
prospects for innovations and competitiveness at all levels of production. The public
sector used technologies in a most cost-inefficient manner, while the private sector lacked
both the initiative and the competence to advance technologies for greater efficiency in
production and quality. Therefore perceived capabilities that the planners had in mind
could not be transformed into actual competitive advantage. The Indian industry failed to
keep pace with the fast moving frontiers of global technology and protectionist policy
environment fostered such an incentive structure whereby there was no attempt to
upgrade technologies or acquire new technologies from the global frontier. The form of
technological capability building by the Indian industry during the first three decades
post-independence remained by and large confined to routine activities of production and
trouble shooting.
Accordingly, India’s experience with technological progress has been varied and
contrasting. During the first few decades of India’s development experience, the level of
its industrial technology was in no way comparable with its achievements on the strategic
technology front, however isolated and sporadic. Contrasts persisted even during the later
decades of the nineties and beyond when India could actually showcase some of its
technological capabilities in the high-tech sectors like Information Technology (IT) and
subsequently was directly catering the world market, although its IT infrastructure back
home remained seriously deficient.
In this paper we focus only on India’s experience with innovations and technology
generation for competitiveness and economic growth. However, India’s experiments with
strategic technology demand a separate analysis and shall not be covered here.
THE ROLE OF TECHNOLOGY IN GLOBAL ECONOMIC EMERGENCE
The Productivity Story
Economic theory, for long, highlighted capital and labour as the two primary factors of
production and recognised them to be the key driving force behind production and
growth. It was only in the 1950s that technological advancement as an important source
of growth was brought into the discussion of mainstream economic theory. Solow’s
(1957) pioneering attempt to estimate the contribution of physical factors to growth, by
introducing the technique of growth accounting, revealed that only 1/8th of the growth of
the US economy during the first half of the last century could be explained by the growth
of its endowments of physical factors, leaving the remaining to a “residual” (termed as
technical progress or total factor productivity (TFP) growth). Such breakthrough
revelation thereafter shifted the focus from physical factors to the role of technology in
2
economic progress. It is fairly well established now that technological advancement
resulting from R&D is the most important factor behind today’s productivity growth in
most industrialised countries across the globe.
However, equating productivity growth with technological progress a la Solow (1957)
can also be somewhat problematic in understanding the growth successes of developing
nations. Not all productivity growth is derived “pure” technological advancement.
Rather, a large part of productivity growth may arise out of improvements in labour force
and human capital accumulation leading to high levels of cognitive skills of the labour
force that permit better firm level adoption, adaptation and mastery of “given”
technologies. In fact, Young (1995) makes an exemplary attempt to control for all
changes in inputs, including improvement of the labour force as well as sustained capital
accumulation, and found the residual TFP contribution to the growth of the East Asian
Tigers between 1966 and 1990 to be abysmally low. It was 2.3 percent in Hong Kong, 2.1
percent in Taiwan, 1.7 percent in South Korea and 0.2 percent in Singapore. Hence
“technological improvement” in the neoclassical sense was perhaps not that important in
facilitating the East Asian Miracle.
TFP Calculations for the Indian Economy
Against the backdrop of India’s technological effort, we explore its experience with total
factor productivity growth (TFPG). There have been several attempts to measure TFPG
in Indian industry in different time periods. Ahluwalia (1991) summarises the results
pertaining to the period up to mid 1980s. Long term TFP growth in this period has been
negligible in India. Later studies extended the period and came up with similar
pessimistic conclusions. Balakrishnan and Puspangadan (1994), for instance, find TFPG
to be 0.33 during 1970-71 to 1988-89. Unfortunately most of these estimates relate to
TFPG at the aggregate industry.
In a study undertaken for the Department of Science & Technology, Government of
India, we attempted a more disaggregated analysis at the level of 29-industry
classification. 1 Using a panel of 29 industries over 1975-76 to 1994-95, it estimated the
following robust random effects model of Cobb-Douglas production function corrected
for multicollinearity (using the ratio form) after confirming the hypothesis of constant
returns to scale. From the estimates we see an overall TFP growth of 0.024 (2.4%) during
this period. However, the study also registers substantial variation of TFPG across
industries and over time and sought to explain this variation in terms of R&D effort by
estimating a panel model. R&D came up as a significant determinant of TFP growth. The
time variable appears negative and significant over this entire period. This is indeed
alarming. We find a distinct structural break in the growth of TFP in 1982. After a long
period of decline and stagnation, productivity in Indian industry displayed an upward
movement. This break coincided with a similar break identified by Ahluwalia (1991) in
Cobb-Douglas production function estimation of the Indian industry.
More importantly, wide variations in TFP growth experience of different industries in our
29 classification structure, are also observed. Only 8 out of 29 industries recorded
1
Ray et. al. (1999), Ray and Bhaduri (2002)
3
positive TFP growth. Among these, E&E (Electrical and Electronics) achieved a
phenomenal 137% growth in TFP during this period. TFP growth in fertiliser and telecom
sectors were 73% and 50% respectively. Sugar and fermentation industries displayed
moderate TFPG of around 30%. It may be worth noting that almost all sectors
constituting the chemical industry experienced negative TFPG with the exception of
fertilisers. Interestingly, in the three sectors registering highest TFPG (E&E, fertilisers
and telecom), public sector’s contribution in total R&D expenditure is fairly high (43%,
82% and 69% respectively).
These calculations show that technological progress (a la Solow) did not contribute
significantly to India’s industrial growth. However, this does not mean that technology
had no role in India’s development experience. It is this context that we attempt to
technological progress taking it beyond neo-classical perspectives.
Beyond Neo-Classical Perspectives
Neoclassical theory identifies technological progress with major breakthroughs in science
and technology resulting in a shift of the frontier. 2 The important contribution to
technical progress made in diffusion, adaptation and application of new technologies,
which are particularly important in the context of LDCs, has therefore remained underemphasized in the neoclassical tradition. The stages of technological capability
acquisition can be described as a process of path dependent evolution. 3 It begins with
learning by doing followed by learning by adapting, aiming at augmenting productivity
through efficient utilisation and adaptation of technologies at the shop floor. We call this
the stage of production engineering. Next comes learning by design and learning by
improved design, aiming at replicating processes and designs for better understanding and
further improvement of given technologies. This stage is described as reverse
engineering. All this culminates into learning by setting up complete production systems
and learning by designing new processes which ultimately sets the stage for basic
(frontier) R&D capabilities.
Following Lall (1985), it is useful to categorise technological capability as “know-how”
and “know-why”. Know-how is acquired through “not only the assimilation of imported
techniques (which itself can be a lengthy and active learning process) but also quality
control (which also involves active technical effort), improved plant layout and
production practices, slight modifications to equipment and tooling, troubleshooting, the
use of different raw materials and so on”, 4 all of which can be summarised as production
engineering. Know-why is the next stage of technological development, which involves
the understanding of the nature of the process and product technologies leading to the
2
See, for instance Schumpeter (1934, 1939). Note that Rosenberg (1976) has strongly criticized the
Schumpeterian usage of the term “innovation” on four grounds: “(1) We confine our thinking about
innovations to characteristics which are likely to be true only of major innovations, (2) we focus
disproportionately upon discontinuities and neglect continuities in the innovative process, (3) we attach
excessive importance to the role of scientific knowledge and insufficient importance to engineering and
other ‘lower’ forms of knowledge, and (4) we attach excessive significance to early stages in the process of
invention and neglect the crucial later stages”.
3
Lall (1978)
4
Lall (1985), page 116.
4
development of new improved designs. Applied research and frontier R&D leading to
major innovations follow this stage.
Following such notions that takes us beyond neo-classical conceptualisation to
appropriately understand the process of technological capability acquisition of the LDCs,
it can broadly be summarised that know-how is expected to bring about rapid and
immediate productivity growth in LDCs. Know-why, on the other hand, is absolutely
necessary (but by no means sufficient) to create and strengthen the technological
foundation of LDCs. By-passing this phase of know-why oriented technological learning,
LDCs can never possibly aspire to reach the global frontiers of technology to catch up
with the levels of technological advancement of developed countries in the long run.
However, there may not be any immediate pay-off of know-why oriented technological
effort in terms of immediate productivity gains in the short and medium terms.
What then are the technological options available to LDCs? In very broad and simple
terms, there are two alternatives, not necessarily mutually exclusive:
1. Bring in latest imported technology (exploit the global frontier) and focus on
know-how to reap maximum productivity gains.
2. Concentrate on know-why and applied research to create capabilities to generate
new technology and attempt to catch up with the advanced nations on their own
footing.
Historically, LDCs have usually opted for different combinations of the above two,
depending on their initial conditions and policy focus. Accordingly we may find intercountry variations in the levels of technological capability acquired by LDCs. Evenson
and Johnson (1998) have classified developing countries into six levels of technological
capability. Countries belonging to the lowest three levels of technological capability
generally do not undertake any R&D work. Though a little bit of R&D work is visible in
the third level, it is mostly directed towards pirating of trade marks and design. In these
three levels production technology is essentially purchased in an “inter-linked”
contractual form. In the fourth and fifth levels of technological capability, the dominant
objective of firm level R&D is to facilitate technology purchase, directly (licensing) or
indirectly. Here the role of R&D is to create absorptive capacity to understand and adapt
and implement the purchased technology successfully. Some adaptive invention is
undertaken, usually stimulated by domestic intellectual property rights. The technological
competence developed through R&D in these countries is instrumental in initiating
activities of reverse engineering or imitation. In the sixth level of technological
infrastructure, imitation is generally taken up as a conscious policy of technology
generation through a more structured “buy-then-imitate” strategy. According to this
classification by Evenson and Johnson (1998), India falls into the fifth level of
technological capability while Korea belonged to the sixth level.
5
INDIA’S TRYST WITH TECHNOLOGY: ROLE OF THE GOVERNMENT
While strategic technology remained exclusively with the government to be developed
and used, the government did also play a proactive role in the domain of industrial
technology. It is in this context that one finds it extremely important to understand the
role of the Indian government in defining national strategies for technology generation, in
terms of its objectives, magnitude and channels in areas other than strategic technology.
India’s Technology Policy: A Brief Overview
The basic objective of India’s post independence technology policy was “the
development of indigenous technology and efficient absorption and adaptation of
imported technology appropriate to national priorities and resources.” 5 Attainment of
technological competence and self reliance was placed at the heart of India’s
technological development. The aim was to achieve breakthroughs in indigenous
technological development “appropriate to national priorities and resources” (i.e.,
maximum utilisation of human resources, efficient use of energy, increasing productivity,
maintenance of ecological balance).
In fact, prior to 1990, the Indian economy operated within the broad framework of an
inward looking policy regime of protection and interventions. Restrictions and
regulations on trade and industrial production were pervasive. Against this backdrop of
the overall policy framework, the main focus of India’s technology policy was not only to
build up search-, selection-, implementation- and absorptive- capability, but also to
acquire technological capabilities of adaptation and minor innovation through reverse
engineering.
Apart from the direct policies to promote indigenous technology development, the
Government had also adopted indirect policies for restricting and regulating technology
imports and technology transfer. Till 1991, import substitution and technological selfreliance constituted the core of India’s technology policy, which was in line with its
inward looking overall policy regime. Import of technologies in the form of licensing as
well as foreign direct investment (FDI) was severely restricted in order to promote
indigenous technology. The importer of technology had to obtain a clearance from
appropriate government authorities after a thorough screening to make sure that there are
no objections on grounds of high cost, “inappropriateness”, availability of local
substitutes or even the long term building up of indigenous R&D capability. The onus lay
on the prospective importer to show that the technology was necessary (in terms of plan
priorities), not available locally and fairly priced (Lall 1984).
As far as in-house industrial R&D is concerned, the import substituting policy regime
typically fostered several conditions – no direct need to keep up with the global frontiers
of technology, small size of operations, various input scarcities, and lack of adequate
competitive pressures with respect to cost and quality – all of which dampened the effort
to build up sustained technological capability at the frontiers. The absence of competition
in any of the three key dimensions (domestic or internal competition, import competition,
5
Technology Policy Statement of 1983, Govt of India (1983), page 3.
6
export rivalry) encouraged conservative technological behaviour on the part of the Indian
firms preventing technological upgrading, let alone major innovations and breakthroughs.
Moreover, restrictions on technology imports resulted in failure to promote effective
transfer and absorption (know-how) of latest global technologies. Although, many Indian
firms did manage to assimilate a lot of basic technology and even improved upon it, they
remained far behind the global frontiers of technology.
India’s technology policies have included both direct policies for indigenous
technological development as well as indirect policies for restricting and regulating
technology imports and technology transfer. The decade of 1990s started with the
ongoing thrust of integrating the Indian economy with the global economy in the GATTWTO framework. From 1991, with the liberalisation of the Indian economy, restrictions
on imports, FDI and technology transfer have been progressively removed. The
technology policy also had to be moderated, and attuned to meet the new challenges of
global competition. In fact, the Science and Technology Policy 2003 states that, “It is
recognised that these objectives (of S&T policy 2003) will be best realised by a dynamic
and flexible Science and Technology Policy, which can readily adapt to the rapidly
changing world order. This policy, reiterates India’s commitment to participate as an
equal and vigorous global player….” The first Scientific Policy Resolution was published
as early as 1958 and the latest Technology Policy Statement appeared in 2003. Over this
half a century, there has been a major shift in India’s policy stance towards technology
development, roughly coinciding with India’s economic reforms and trade liberalisation
in the 1990s. Accordingly, India’s technology policy environment has been distinctly
different in the pre and post-reforms period.
Channels of Technology Generation in India
We can primarily identify four channels through which the government intended to
advance the cause of technology generation (R&D) in India: (1) investing in applied
industrial research, (2) promoting science education and fundamental academic research,
(3) public-sector production and (4) offering fiscal and non-fiscal R&D incentives to the
private sector.
Applied Industrial Research
If we look at the R&D expenditure incurred in India before 1990s we find that the share
of national R&D expenditure in gross national product (GNP) had increased steadily
from 0.17% in 1958-59 to 0.98% in 1987-88, the major share of which was borne by the
Government. 6 The overwhelming majority of government R&D expenditure was
allocated to various public sector research laboratories, under the auspices of the CSIR
(Council of Scientific and Industrial Research) engaged in applied research in a wide
range of fields including areas like aeronautics, experimental medicine, environment,
oceanography and structural engineering.
Public sector (institutional R&D) played the dominant role, especially during the prereforms period (pre-1990). In this phase, much of the technological effort went into
6
Even as late as 1998-99, 75.5% of the national R&D expenditure in India was borne by the Government.
7
creating technologies first time in the country rather than breakthroughs first time in the
world and that too pre-dominantly in the public sector institutions. 7 This is perhaps
expected as it conformed to the broad objective of creating technological self reliance in
the pre-reform period. However, it is doubtful whether these efforts of the public research
laboratories have had “much impact on technological development in large scale
organised industry, though it claims to have provided hundreds of technologies for use to
small scale enterprises”. 8 More importantly, it is doubtful how efficient these
indigenously developed “new” technologies were, by international standards of costs and
quality.
Science Education and Fundamental Research
The grand vision of building up indigenous capabilities in India was thought could be
achieved not only by imparting science education to the coming generations to constitute
a large pool of highly skilled workforce but by also improving the conditions for
fundamental research in the country. The higher education policy post-independence
envisaged setting up of several Indian Institutes of Technology, Regional Engineering
Colleges and Central Universities across the country. The IITs went a long way in
providing the country with highly-skilled technical manpower over the next decades, so
much so that India’s relatively recent transition to a global economic power based on
some of the high-tech sectors like the IT is often attributed to the indirect role of these
institutions.
However, it remains debatable whether the above mentioned publicly funded institutions
were equally focussed on fundamental research. It is agreed that these establishments
were mandated to conduct fundamental research, but for long these institutions failed to
live up to such research aspirations. Although the newly modelled ‘technology’ education
institutes along with the traditional university system did succeed enormously in their
endeavour to generate high skilled human resources, they lacked appropriate initiative to
take forward fundamental or cutting-edge research.
Public Sector Production
As mentioned in the introduction, public-sector production inspired by the Soviet model
of a planned economy was seriously considered in India post-independence, especially
from the Second Five Year plan onwards. The Indian government perhaps aspired to
mimic the development trajectories of the advanced industrialised nations. Accordingly,
inward looking development strategy and a meticulously planned out diversified
industrial production base ranging from simple consumer items to sophisticated capital
goods and heavy machinery was adopted in India. This implied heavy investments on
import substituting industries across the board on the part of the government. Indeed, it is
through such a process that building up of indigenous technological capabilities as well
as technological learning for catch-up became extremely important for India’s industrial
and economic aspirations.
7
In very few cases in which “pioneering” technologies were created were those using typically Indianised
raw materials, e.g. Amul Spray – a baby food technology from buffalo milk.
8
Lall (1984), page 233.
8
However, through direct intervention in industrial production on the basis of a priori
planning, the government seemed to ignore the notion of natural comparative advantage.
The protectionist trade policy regime practically left no incentive to keep pace with the
fast changing global technology frontier in many of the manufacturing sectors most of
them in the public sector, which resulted in Indian industry becoming technologically
backward and inefficient with respect to global standards of costs and quality.
R&D incentives to the private sector
The above three channels clearly indicate that India’s technology policy in the pre
reforms era was essentially grounded on building up of national level capabilities through
the public institutions. But, at the same time, industry (private and public sector) was
encouraged to actively engage in R&D activities to develop absorptive and adaptive
capabilities. To this end, the government also offered specific R&D incentives with the
objective of building up domestic technological capability for rapid industrialisation
going beyond spending directly on R&D. Prior to the 1990s, the main thrust of the R&D
incentives was to generate indigenous technologies primarily in the institutional sector
(public funded R&D institutions) and facilitate effective commercialisation, transfer and
absorption of such technologies in the industrial sector. There were very few incentives at
the firm level with the explicit aim of augmenting technology-creating capabilities. Inhouse R&D was encouraged only to facilitate acquisition of technological capabilities of
absorption, adaptation and assimilation. Special incentives were given to firms using
indigenous technologies developed by R&D institutions.
The decade of the 1990s saw a departure in the sense that government attempted to
distinguish between fundamental R&D and commercial R&D, both in the private R&D
units. One contrasting feature is the shift of focus of fiscal incentives from national R&D
institutions to R&D carried out by the industry either in in-house R&D units or in the
SIROs (Scientific and Industrial Research Organization). Indeed, post 1991, the thrust of
R&D incentives showed a clear shift away from the institutional sector to technology
generation by the industrial sector.
R&D Expenditure and R&D Outcomes in India: Macro Trends
Against the backdrop of a well articulated technology policy over the last half a century,
India’s share of national R&D expenditure in gross national product (GNP) had increased
steadily from 0.17% in 1958-59 to 0.91% in 1988-89. Thereafter it started declining
reaching a low of 0.71% in 1995-96 and finally it has settled around 0.8% as per the
latest available information. 9 This is rather alarming, especially in the context of the new
economic policy regime of reforms and globalisation. In spite of a clear mandate of the
Science and Technology Policy of 2003 to strengthen India’s in-house industrial R&D in
the post “liberalisation” period by raising the above share to at least 2% of India’s GNP
by the end of the Tenth Plan, India has not even been able to reach the 1% target. It is
worth noting that among the newly industrialised Asian countries, South Korea spends as
9
R&D Statistics, Dept of Science & Technology, Government of India.
9
much as 2.8% of its GNP on R&D, which is at par with industrialised nations, like US,
Japan, UK and Germany.
The Government’s R&D expenditure takes two forms: institutional R&D in Central and
State Government laboratories and industrial in-house R&D in public sector enterprises,
accounting for 62.6%, 8.5% and 4.5% of total (national) R&D expenditure respectively.
There is small portion (4.1%) going to higher education, bringing the total share of the
government in India’s R&D expenditure to 79.7%. The share of private sector R&D
remains around 20%. Industrial R&D (public + private sector) constitute only 24.8% of
total R&D. 10 This share is remarkably low compared to some of the East Asian countries,
e.g. Singapore (60% in 1992), Korea (around 80% in 1992) and Taiwan (50% in 1993).
A comparison of aggregate nominal R&D expenditure also reveals some interesting
turnarounds. While every sector has witnessed a growth in the nominal R&D expenditure
their growth rates are far from being uniform. Moreover, there is also evidence of
contrasting growth rate of a particular sector during the 1980s and 1990s. Overall during
the entire period, the growth rate of the private sector R&D expenditure has been the
highest followed by the growth of the state sector, central sector and public sector.
However, during the 1980s, the state sector witnessed the highest rate of increase in R&D
expenditure followed by private sector, public sector and central institutes. The decade of
1990s saw a reversal in this trend. Private sector emerges as the fastest growing sector,
followed by the central R&D institutes. The rate of increase of public sector R&D
expenditure fell from 0.75 in the 1980s to 0.57 in the 1990s. This picture seems to be
compatible with the overall decline in the policy attention towards public sector
enterprises. On the other hand, co-operative R&D between the private sector and central
R&D institutes seems to have taken-off resulting in high growth rates of R&D
expenditure in both the sectors. State sector growth rate also increased marginally.
However, it appears that central R&D institutes has performed better than the state
institutes in the decade of 1990s, may be due to better inflow of sponsored research
received by some of them, which has been a key feature of the R&D incentive structure
in the 1990s.
India’s post-independence inward looking policy regime did manage to generate a
considerable amount of technological effort and development. To understand India’s
trajectory of technological learning and technological capability acquisition, let us take a
quick look at the technological achievements in terms of R&D output.
Fiscal incentives for R&D took a new turn in the era of globalisation with the focus
shifting from institutional to industrial R&D. Ray (2004) takes a closer look at the profile
and composition of R&D expenditure and outputs in terms of institutional versus
industrial R&D over the period 1986-2000 and attempts to relate this with the structural
changes in incentives. The Department of Science and Technology (DST), Government
of India identifies various technological outputs and publishes it in their biennial R&D
Statistics volumes. The study on the basis of the mentioned database have categorized
10
See R&D Statistics 2004-05, Department of Science &Technology, Government of India.
10
these outputs in two groups: Type-1 output includes R&D outcomes like patents, product
development, process development, development of new designs and import substitutes,
which directly augment firm-level productivity and profitability. Type-2 output consists
of R&D outputs like consultancy services rendered and publication of books, papers and
reports, which reflect technological capability through augmenting knowledge-base, but
do not directly enter the firm’s production function, at least, in the short run.
It is quite understandable that the institutional sector puts more emphasis on type-2
output while industry puts more emphasis on type-1 output. The industry is more
concerned with type-1 output for immediate gains in profitability and productivity. But
the institutional sector during the 1980s perhaps followed a social mandate of enriching
the public domain of R&D knowledge by producing and disseminating type-2 output.
The situation has somewhat changed in the last decade. The study finds that industry’s
share of type-2 output in total R&D output is increasing. This increase can be attributed
to the changes in the R&D incentive structure, which does not intend to portray the public
sector R&D institutes as the sole source of indigenous technologies and knowledge-base.
Industry, in the changed scenario, has to appreciate the complementarities between the
two types of R&D outputs – instant productivity gains through type-1 and augmenting
knowledge base through type-2.
One interesting finding relates to the relative importance of import substitutes developed
by the institutional and industrial sectors. The share of import substitutes in Type-1
output produced by the institutional sector declined from around 0.81 in the 1980s to
around 0.3-0.4 in the 1990s. The industry, however, has maintained its share of import
substitutes (perhaps a marginal increase) in Type-1 output at 0.2. Note that the decade of
1980s had a clear mandate to develop import substitutes in both sectors which has been
removed in the 1990s. We, however, conclude that the scope of cost effective import
substitution by industry, especially in a profit maximizing framework, continues even
with globalization and economic reforms.
IPR Policy and Technological Learning in India
The debate on optimum IPR policy continues, one is tempted to conclude that a weak IPR
policy would perhaps be preferred over a stronger one in the initial stages of
technological learning and economic development. But, once a country reaches
technology maturity to achieve major breakthroughs, the benefits of protecting
knowledge through strong IPR (incentive to innovate) might outweigh the benefits of
diffusion. Hence, a strong IPR policy that encourages innovation may be necessary at a
later stage after the country in question acquires innovative capability through learning.
This essentially reflects that IPR policy can not remain static or invariant over time. It
needs to be modified, fine-tuned and adjusted at various points in the technological
learning trajectory of a nation, according to the nature and level of technological
capability already acquired through this learning process. At the same time the nature and
extent of technological learning will also definitely be shaped by the IPR policy adopted.
In other words, technological learning and IPR policy have a strong mutual interface in
11
the way they evolve. Technological learning begins with know-how oriented production
engineering followed by know-why oriented reverse engineering (RE) under weak IPR till
sufficient innovative capability is acquired for basic research. At this point IPR regime is
made stronger to enable firms to adopt basic research as a viable (and sustainable)
strategic option. Without the introduction of a strong IPR as a negotiated order at this
juncture, the transition to basic research will perhaps prove to be difficult and
unsustainable. 11
The Intellectual Property Rights (IPR) Regime adopted by India has acted as an indirect
policy for the Indian industry. The Patent Act of 1970 did promote considerable
technological learning and acquisition of technological capability through reverse
engineering activities. However, the technological trajectory of sectors like the E&E was
essentially targeted towards achievement of high TFP (based on know-how capabilities)
with little emphasis on acquisition of adaptive and designing (know-why) capabilities and
therefore, IPR policy had perhaps little role to play in this regard. The pharmaceutical
industry, on the other hand, focused on building up of know-why oriented technological
capability, even at the cost of immediate productivity gains in the short or medium terms.
Here the IPR regimes did matter. Indeed, the process revolution in the Indian
pharmaceutical industry reflecting significant learning and technological catch up can be
largely attributed to the Patent Act of 1970 allowing only process (and not product)
patents for pharmaceutical substances. One may, of course, further argue that India’s
transition in 2005 into a stronger IPR regime, compatible with the TRIPS agreement, is
perhaps the right moment to leverage its innovative capacity to take a leap towards basic
research (new drug discovery).
UNDERSTANDING THE PROCESS OF TECHNOLOGICAL CAPABILITY
ACQUISITION BY THE INDIAN INDUSTRY
The econometric results obtained by Ray and Bhaduri (2001) presented new and
interesting insights into the process of technology generation and learning in the Indian
pharmaceutical and electronics sectors. They made a clear distinction between R&D
inputs and R&D outputs in a research production function framework to understand the
process of technology generation. We found that the conventional determinants of R&D,
like firm-size, technology import or ownership, appear significant only in explaining
R&D effort in line with existing empirical studies. However, when sought to explain the
variations in research output, none of these factors, not even research effort on its own,
appears to be statistically significant. Here in fact, learning, both experience-based as
well as interaction (or spillover) based, proved to be the only important determinant of
the research production process. According to Ray and Bhaduri (2001), therefore,
technological learning has been the most important determinant of technology generation
in Indian industry.
11
However, a pre-mature imposition of strong IPR, suppressing the evolutionary interface between TC and
IPR, will not merely put a halt to the technological catch up process but will actually revert the learning
trajectory back to the stage of production engineering. See Ray and Bhaduri (2008).
12
First of all, learning through interaction (spillover) proved to be important in the research
production process for both sectors. The effect of spillover on research output appeared to
be non-linear. In both industries there was evidence of an optimum level of spillover
(national as well as international). Learning through experience also entered the research
production function for both sectors, although the way in which it augments research
output differs across the two industries.
Indeed, the two sectors have followed two distinct trajectories of technological learning,
resulting in different kinds of technological capability generation. In the electronics
industry in India (characterized primarily by “screw-driver” technology), assembly
operations, production engineering, shop-floor practices and quality control could prove
to be the key elements of technological effort. In-depth technological learning of product
designs and processes have perhaps been less important for electronics firms in India.
Their technological effort lay primarily in gaining operational efficiency and productivity
augmentation through shop-floor practices, day-to-day trouble shooting and customer
servicing. Hence, it is know-how rather than know-why that best describes the learning
trajectory of electronics industry in India.
The pharmaceutical industry in India, on the other hand, followed a rather different
trajectory of technological learning based on reverse engineering. 12 This essentially
implies decoding an original process for producing a bulk drug. This involves a detailed
understanding of the chemical properties of the active molecule, the excipients used and
the chemical process of conversion from the active molecular compound to the final bulk
drug. A chemical process incorporates a complex set of parameters, e.g., solvent
conditions, temperature, time, stirring methods, use of various chemical and physical
substances with different levels of purity etc., all of which have to be simultaneously
optimised in order to arrive at the optimum process specification. It is possible to decode
all of these parametric specifications of a process through reverse engineering.
Indeed, from the decade of the 1970s, the industry acquired substantial technological
capability of process development through reverse engineering, both infringing processes
for off-patented molecules and non-infringing processes for patented molecules. This
phenomenon has been often been referred to as the process revolution in the Indian
pharmaceutical sector.
Effectively then, the learning process has been largely know-why oriented in the
pharmaceutical sector, while in electronics, it has perhaps been simpler and more know
how oriented. We may expect a significant role of formal R&D in the learning process of
the former. Learning in electronics, on the other hand, is likely to be less dependent on
formal R&D. 13 It will be more learning by doing and learning through experience in this
sector.
12
Ray (2005)
The results of estimated production functions with R&D as third input for the two sectors reported above
vindicate this hypothesis.
13
13
Implications for Export Competitiveness
To explain India’s technological advantages in exporting, we again refer to the distinction
between know-how and know-why capabilities. Know-how is acquired through “not only
the assimilation of imported techniques (which itself can be a lengthy and active learning
process) but also quality control (which also involves active technical effort), improved
plant layout and production practices, slight modifications to equipment and tooling,
troubleshooting, the use of different raw materials and so on”, 14 all of which can be
summarised as production engineering. Hence know-how oriented technological effort
leads to greater production efficiency and therefore reduced marginal costs. Know-why is
the next stage of technological development, which involves the understanding of the
nature of the process and product technologies, ultimately, leading to the development of
new improved processes and designs. Clearly, reduction of marginal cost may not be the
overriding, or even an important consideration for such know-why oriented technological
activities, at least initially.
However, technology creating know-why capabilities (reverse engineering) may actually
reduce export competitiveness since reverse engineered processes and designs do not
usually lead to greater production- and cost-efficiency, at least in the short run. Sustained
effort towards know-why activities may eventually lead to technology creating
capabilities to invent around cost-effective processes or designs. 15 This could then act as
a major fillip to the LDC firms’ competitive edge in the long run and prove to be a key
determinant of their export success. Indeed, international competitive strength of Japan’s
automobile industry and Korean semi-conductor industry was hidden in its capability to
invent around, which evolved out of conscious long-term research effort on creating
know-why capabilities.
Econometric results in Bhaduri and Ray (2004), capturing the impact of these various
facets of technological capability on export performance, revealed striking inter-industry
differences found that know-how (or production engineering) augments export
performance in both sectors but know-why (or reverse engineering) was important for
pharmaceutical exports, not E&E. Indeed, as argued earlier, it is know-how oriented
capabilities (production engineering, quality control for instance) that augments
production efficiency and enables an LDC firm to remain internationally competitive.
Know-why capabilities, on the other hand, raises export competitiveness only in the long
run after a gestation lag of successful learning.
One may of course ask why the E&E firms in India, unlike pharmaceuticals, are unable to
augment exports through know-why capabilities. The reason perhaps lies in the different
characters of the two products. While in both cases the global technological frontier is
moving fast, in E&E the rate of product obsolescence is very high, whereas an old drug is
never quite pushed out of the market even in the long run when a new “better”
replacement arrives. Therefore there is ample scope and incentive to carry out sustained
know-why activities of inventing around cost efficient processes and designs keeping in
14
15
Lall (1985), page 116.
Dore (1984).
14
mind the off-patent segment of the international pharmaceutical market. Such long run
prospects of pay-off from know-why do not exist in case of E&E characterized by high
rate of product obsolescence.
CONCLUDING REMARKS: THE WAY FORWARD
To conclude our paper, we note that India missed the opportunity to join the other labour
surplus Asian economies in the so-called Asian miracle of the 1970s and 1980s that was
essentially a growth process spearheaded by massive expansion of labour intensive
manufactured exports. Despite India’s vast pool of labour resources, India was left
behind, when the rest of labour surplus Asia was getting integrated with the world
economy based on low labour cost advantages. Fortunately, however, the advantage
conferred by low labour costs in India has been pervasive, extending well beyond the
realm of traditional labour-intensive goods into new industries and services, like software
and IT, biotechnology, pharmaceuticals and long-distance communication-based services,
where skills and technological capability play a vital role in shaping competitive
advantage. India’s strength in quite a few industries within the manufacturing sector
which requires process, product and capital engineering skills is now well demonstrated.
If we look at the Indian manufacturing experience we find that India has several
advantages in skill-intensive industries, such as auto-components, pharmaceuticals,
forgings (both for automotive and non-automotive sectors), power and transport
machinery, high-end electrical and electronics and specialty chemicals. Apart from the
abundance of skills, these advantages include technological capability (process, product
and capital engineering) plus established raw material bases, a mature supply base and a
growing domestic demand. This has lead to India being considered as a design house, a
tooling centre, a components base, and a manufacturing hub by many MNEs. Indeed,
from the experience of India’s economic progress in the last decade or so, it is quite
evident that knowledge intensive sectors have been driving India’s growth, be it IT,
Biotech or Pharmaceuticals among many more skill intensive service sectors.
However, India’s technological advantages in these skill intensive areas have still by and
large remained confined to the domain of minor as opposed to major innovative
capabilities. India has demonstrated significant competitive strength in routine (through
skill intensive) tasks like coding (in software) or process development (in
pharmaceuticals), and perhaps less so in creativity and innovativeness. At this critical
juncture when India is imminently poised for a successful transition to a knowledge
economy, it becomes all the more important to revitalise India’s technological capability
building through the most appropriate coupling of creative pursuits (especially through
public funded research) with applications for industrial R&D. It is in this context, we
need to take a fresh look at the role of universities and other institutions of higher
learning.
While India’s advantage in high end human capital may be primarily attributed to its
persistent policy thrust on higher education (especially technical and scientific) creating
an extensive network of universities and institutions of higher learning (IITs and IIMs),
the Indian university system has failed to contribute adequately to the process of
15
technological learning and catch up. Even though the universities and institutions have
been quite active in their research pursuits, university-industry interface in this regard has
remained sub-optimum (Ray 2003). It has often been felt that India’s transition to a
knowledge driven economy would be much easier if the “rich” research potential of its
huge pool of premier universities and institutions could be harnessed for effective
commercial application and industrial development.
Having said so, we suggest that while carving out an appropriate (optimum) technology
strategy for India, one can not afford to ignore other sectors of the economy, especially
the labour intensive mass manufacturing where productivity augmentation through knowhow capabilities may prove to be crucially important for sustained TFP growth and
industrial development. While India has nurtured and succeeded (to a large extent) with
high-end human capital for technological capability in the skill intensive sectors, it has
been accompanied with a tragic neglect of low end human capital investment (in primary
education and health) for productivity gains in mass manufacturing sectors. 16 By
stimulating broad based expansion of these sectors through low end human capital and
technological capability building, India could bring on board its 300 million poor who
have been completely left out of India’s prosperity through its emergence as a major
economic player in the world economy. Such an “inclusive” technology strategy would
be of critical importance for the sustainability of India’s growth process.
16
Guha and Ray (2004), Ray (2006).
16
REFERENCES
Alhluwalia, I.J. (1991), Productivity and Growth in Indian Manufacturing, Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
Balakrishnan, P. and Puspangadan, K. (1994) ‘Total Factor Productivity Growth in
Manufacturing Industry: A Fresh Look’, Economic and Political Weekly, July.
Bhaduri, S. and Ray, A.S. (2004), ‘Exporting through Technological Capability:
Econometric Evidence from India’s Pharmaceutical and Electrical/Electronics Firms’,
Oxford Development Studies, 32 (1), pp 87-100.
Dore, R. (1984) ‘Technological Self Reliance: Sturdy Ideal or Self Serving Rhetoric’, in
M. Fransman and K. King (eds.) Technological Capability in the Third World, London:
Macmillan.
Evenson, R. E. and Johnson, D. K. N. (1998) ‘Invention in Developing Countries’,
Unpublished mimeo.
Guha A. and Ray A.S. (2004), ‘India and Asia in the World Economy: The Role of
Human Capital and Technology’, International Studies, vol.41 (3), pp 300-311.
Lall, S. (1978), ‘Developing Countries as Exporters of Technology: A Preliminary
Analysis’, in Giersch (ed.) International Economic Development and Resource Transfer
Workshop, Tubingen: J.C.B. Mohr.
Lall, S. (1984) ‘India’s Technological Capacity: Effects of Trade, Industrial, Science &
Technology Policies’ In M. Fransman and K. King (ed.) Technological Capability in the
Third World, London: Macmillan.
Lall, S. (1985). Multinationals, Technology and Exports, London: Macmillan.
Ray, A.S. (2004), ‘The Changing Structure of R&D Incentives in India: The
Pharmaceutical Sector’, Science Technology and Society, 9 (2), pp 297-317.
Ray, A.S. (2005) ‘The Indian Pharmaceutical Industry at Crossroads: Implications for
India’s Health Care’, in Amiya Bagchi and Krishna Soman (eds) Maladies, Preventives
and Curatives: Debates in Public Health in India, New Delhi: Tulika Books.
Ray, A.S. (2006), ‘Going Global: India’s Economic Aspirations and Apprehensions in
the New Millennium’ in F.Villares (ed.) India, Brazil and South Africa: Perspectives and
Alliances, Sao Paulo: Editora UNESP.
Ray, A.S. and Bhaduri S. (2001), ‘R&D and Technological Learning in Indian Industry’,
Oxford Development Studies, 29 (2), pp. 155-171.
17
Ray, A.S. and Bhaduri, S. (2002) ‘Technological Development in Indian Industry:
Challenges and Options after the East Asian Crisis’, Richard Hooley and J.H.Yoo (ed.),
The Post Financial Crisis Challenges for Asian Industrialization, Oxford: Elsevier
Science.
Ray, A.S. and Bhaduri, S. (2008), ‘Co-evolution of IPR Policy and Technological
Learning in Developing Countries: A Game-theoretic Model’, Paper for Globelics 6th
International Conference, Mexico City, September 2008.
Ray, A.S., et al (1999), The Role of In-House R&D in Indian Industry, Report prepared
for the Department of Science & Technology, Govt. of India, July.
Rosenberg, N. (1976), Perspective on Technology, New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1980 (1934)), The Theory of Economic Development, London: Oxford
University Press.
Schumpeter, J.A. (1939), Business Cycles, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Solow, R.M. (1957) ‘Technical change and the aggregate production function’, Review of
Economics and Statistics, August, pp. 312-320.
Young, A (1995), ‘The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the
East Asian Growth Experience’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, August.
18