Blackwell Publishing Ltd.Oxford, UKEJEDEuropean Journal of Education0141-8211Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2006June 2006412••••Original ArticlesEuropean Journal of EducationBronwyn
Davies, Michael Gottsche &
Peter Bansel
European Journal of Education, Vol. 41, No. 2, 2006
The Rise and Fall of the Neo-liberal University
BRONWYN DAVIES, MICHAEL GOTTSCHE & PETER BANSEL
Introduction
The current Australian Federal Government has been systematically restructuring
the economy, the labour market and the workplace according to the neo-liberal
mantra of deregulation, privatisation and market freedom. Universities have been
extensively restructured and re-regulated: indeed, it might be argued that they are
currently more highly regulated than ever before — which is somewhat at odds
with the neo-liberal emphasis on deregulation. Recently, the government has
passed legislation that imposes requirements on universities that are in excess of
those required by the workforce in general: increases in federal funds are tied to
compliance, with a specified percentage of individual workplace agreements to be
introduced by a specified date. These are to replace collectively bargained
and union negotiated working conditions. Further, the Minister for Education
reserves the right to disallow funding for particular universities if he does not
approve the form their particular negotiated agreements take. Funding will also
be withheld from any university that makes available any resources (rooms, equipment and so on) to any union organisation. The date set for compliance and
release of funds takes effect once the academic year has begun — meaning that
universities are beginning the 2006 academic year without confirmation of funding — severely compromising sound economic management. These coercive technologies are cynically described by government as voluntary — universities may,
after all, choose to forego government funding if they don’t want to comply.
Given that universities are already highly flexible workplaces, with many staff on
individual performance-based contracts, and are compliant with all necessary
workplace legislation, such micro-management and increasing regulation seem
extraordinary.
Despite the extent of re-structuring and regulating, the rise of neo-liberalism
in universities, both in Australia and elsewhere, has been met by an ambivalent
struggle on the part of academics. As successive governments in the globalised
world have taken on the task of ‘reforming’ workplaces and transforming them
into neo-liberal institutions, academics have been hard pressed to generate a
collective position of resistance. On the contrary, some have welcomed the transformation, seeing it as offering a solution to problems they had with the traditional
workings of power in the universities of the 1960s and 1970s (Davies & Petersen,
2005a and b). Hand in hand with the ‘declared inevitability’ of global economics
(Saul, 2005, p. 3) neo-liberal managerialism has come to be widely understood
as a set of practices that is necessary for individual, institutional, and national
economic survival. Workers have tended to accept the governmental rationality
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd., 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4
2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
306 European Journal of Education
that money is (always) scarce and that responsible workers must, in the name of
continuous improvement, produce (ever) more with less and less. Few guessed,
as they embraced various aspects of neo-liberalism and grumbled about others,
the extent to which the systemic transformations within universities, and between
universities and government, would transform both their subjectivities and their
work in a range of detrimental ways (Davies & Petersen, 2005a; 2005b). Perhaps
it is only now that the steady and increasing regulation of the academy has become
visible as something more than adjustments to past problems; and only now that
the equally steady adaptation of academic workers to successive reforms and
restructures has begun to make visible the dissonance between the rhetoric of
the new economy and its lived effects on both the academy and on the lives of
academic workers.
Our analysis draws on interviews undertaken by the first author. These interviews were a detailed exploration of the impact of neo-liberal management practices on the intellectual work of academics. The 26 interviewees were selected on
the basis of their positive reputations as teachers and researchers. They were
from universities varying in status and size, in both major metropolitan universities and regional universities in Australia, New Zealand, Sweden and the US.
Their status ranged from Senior Lecturer to Professor, with many of them having had major administrative responsibilities at some time in their career. Their
disciplines were in the Sciences and the Social Sciences. Our analysis is situated
within the theoretical terrain of governmentality and focuses on the emergence,
in the 70s, of neo-liberalism as an historically specific set of economic discourses
and practices.
Foucault uses the term governmentality to mean the art of government, and
to signal the historical emergence of distinctive types of rule (Foucault, 1978;
Peters, 1999). Neo-liberalism, as a specific mode of government, is variously
articulated as advanced liberalism, neo-conservatism, economic liberalism and
economic rationalism. It has geographically localised iterations, with the term neoliberalism more widely used in Europe, economic rationalism in Australia, and
neo-conservatism in the US. These various iterations are constituted from the
conjoined thematics of: a liberal humanity expressed as philosophy (a relation
between the individual and the social, in terms of character, ethics and morality,
and the exercise of autonomy, responsibility, freedom and choice); a liberal economics (a relation between the individual, government and the market); and a
conservative form of government (generally associated with a right politics that
emphasises a withdrawal of government from the welfare state).
These various iterations share a trend towards globalised markets, tariff reductions, deregulation, taxation reform, privatisation, competition, casualisation of
the work force and reduced public spending (Deakin, 2001; Dean, 1999; Gamble,
2001; Hay, 1999; Watson et al., 2003). As many costs as possible are shifted from
the State back on to individuals, and markets, particularly labour markets, are
made as flexible as possible. This is achieved through concerted efforts to deunionise and deregulate workplaces, wages and conditions. Perhaps the most
significant shift wrought by the emergence of neo-liberalism is the profound
disengagement of government from the social or public domain, and its emphasis
on privatisation. Responsibility for education welfare, hospitals, transport, telecommunications, and so on, are separated from the public domain and attached
to the domain of the market and private enterprise.
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Bronwyn Davies, Michael Gottsche & Peter Bansel
307
The emergence of neo-liberalism was characterised by the transformation of
the administrative state responsible for human well-being and for the economy
into one that gave power to global corporations and installed apparatuses and
knowledges through which the people could be reconfigured as economic units.
Neo-liberal forms of management require a highly individualised, responsibilised
subject; one who, in Saul’s words, is characterised by ‘loyalty, belonging and
acceptance, compensated by the rewards of self-interest and marked by the promotion of efficiency in the service of the inevitable’ (2005, p. 13). Neo-liberalism
involves not only a configuration of individual subjects as ‘individual entrepreneurial actors across all dimensions of their lives, [but also the] reduction of civil society
to a domain for exercising this entrepreneurship’ (Brown, 2003, p. 38). This
reconfigured subject is governed through the installed belief in the inevitability
(and desirability) of globalisation, its desirability being accomplished with the
perception of ‘an expanding economy, national security and [in the US] global
power’ (Brown, 2003, p. 38).
The Failure to Resist
The discourses, practices and technologies of neo-liberal governance have been
strategically aligned with discourses and practices of globalisation, which support
the regulation, management and reach of global capital(ism). This has been in
part achieved through those organisations such as the World Trade Organisation,
the World Bank and the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development standardising and naturalising their particular repertoire of economic discourses and managerial practices, and in part through the market dominance of
geographically dispersed multinational corporations.
This diffuse installation of technologies and practices has produced docile neoliberal subjects who are tightly governed and at the same time, ideally, successful
entrepreneurs. In the interests of making workers more governable the collective
power of unions has been eroded at the same time as individualism has been
heightened through competition, responsibilisation and the transfer of risk from
the State to individuals. The curious combination of beliefs that government has
left no room for choice on the part of individuals and institutions, and that the
changes are voluntary strategies implemented in the interest of protecting workers,
emerges in the following interview:
I would hate to be a Vice-Chancellor in the current funding climate . . . I
hate what’s happened but I don’t actually think that our Vice-Chancellor’s
had any choice. I think, basically what he’s said is that we’re going to do
what we have to do to ensure that staff numbers don’t decrease and I don’t
see how he had any choice but to do what he’s done. And that was forced
on him by government. (Australian female scientist)
Seen in this way, it cannot make sense for academics to debate within the institution whether the changes are desirable. To the extent that they appear inevitable
there is nothing to discuss. Claims to an unquestionable truth, that there is no
other way, locate neo-liberalism as a fundamentalist discourse (Saul, 2005). Further, to the extent that loyalty is a feature of neo-liberal subjects, debate can be
construed as disloyal and as a failure to support the manager, who, in turn, will
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
308 European Journal of Education
work to keep the institution afloat economically, and so protect workers’ jobs.
Neo-liberalism’s heightened focus on the individual and its de-emphasis of the
social and of the moral combine with the sense of vulnerability to job loss and to
institutional demise to persuade individuals that, if they have problems with the
changes, the problems are strictly their own. The acceptance of the necessity of
work on the self rather than on the institution is accomplished by incremental
changes in governmental practices, rather than through the conscious will to
change on the part of the participants. This heightened individualism entails an
intensification of some aspects of liberal subjectivities, rather than the radical break
with them that postmodernism or post-structuralism might have envisaged (Davies
et al., 2006).
Neo-liberalism as a form of governmentality works, then, by convincing
workers that there is no choice at a systemic level. Instead, their power lies in their
individual choices to become appropriate and successful within that inevitable
system. Part of our task, then, in this project, is to challenge that inevitability and
to open up the possibility of choice at the systemic level by making visible neoliberalism’s work on academic subjects to transform them, to transform what is
thinkable, and to transform the nature of academic work.
In what follows, we consider the related domains of government and of the
university. We provide a brief historical sketch of those economic narratives
through which the project of neo-liberalism has been advanced. We look at the
ways they mobilise concepts of the individual, the social, and education, and at
how they produce different sets of relations among them. We trace the changes
that have made the idea ‘that the market should be allowed to make major social
and political decisions’ (George, 1999, p. 1), not only thinkable, but so standardised and so naturalised that the belief that there is no alternative can be accepted
as a self-evident truth that it is not in need of investigation. We will then go on to
ask whether neo-liberalism might be seen, as Saul suggests, to have arrived at its
(unheralded) use-by date.
Neo-liberalism, we suggest, is not based on fundamental eternal truths, notwithstanding its claims to that effect. As Saul observes, ‘economics is a romantic,
tempestuous business, rather theatrical, often dependent on the willing suspension
of disbelief by the rest of us. As with other fashions, its truths change more often
than in more concrete sectors . . . [and as far as neoliberalism is concerned] a
quarter of a century is a good run’ (2005, p. 7). Its apparent inevitability was
accomplished, he says, by the ‘international economic debate being flooded with
work funded around the world by largely American neo-conservative foundations
holding $2 billion in assets and neo-conservative think-tanks with $140 million to
spend every year. This was and remains a gold mine for professors of economics
everywhere’ (Saul, 2005, pp. 33–4).1
The Domain of Government: a brief history
In the early decades of the 20th century, the dominant economic narrative was
informed by classical or liberal economic theory, which held that economies
cyclically go up and down according to the ebb and flow of market forces. The
inevitable cyclic downturns were managed through business taking responsibility,
using such measures as cutting the size of the workforce and freezing or reducing
wages. The responsibility for recovery in this model lay with business while the
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Bronwyn Davies, Michael Gottsche & Peter Bansel
309
burden of recovery was carried by workers. In the 1930s, business failed to
engineer the ‘upswing’. The economic recession deepened and turned into what
became known as the Great Depression.
There were two competing narratives explaining the Depression. The first of
these came from classical economics. It held that the rise of organised labour
within mass-production industries (such as mining and manufacturing) was
responsible. The union movement was guilty as it would not submit itself to needs
of the market and was obstructing the recovery of the economy. The competing
narrative shifted responsibility away from business and onto government, and
argued that workers did not have to take the brunt of recoveries. Rather, workers’
conditions could go on improving, as could business profits, if business submitted
to the demand for greater productivity. This was the Keynesian solution.
The new storyline generated by Keynes was that a high wage policy would
force the restructuring of industry around businesses that had the highest productivity. This would allow for the mutual rise in business profits and the wages of
workers. Government would facilitate this process by increasing expenditure, and
thereby enlarging the market, and by inducing business to increase investment.
The leaders of business and industry were resistant to this change and it was
necessary for governments to introduce legislation to bring about the shift to the
Keynesian model. In the US, for example, Roosevelt’s New Deal regulated wages
and taxed uninvested corporate money.
This change placed the control of the economy in the hands of the State.
Through legislation, fiscal policy, fixed exchange rates, trade barriers etc., it was
the State — and no longer business and the market — that took responsibility for
adjusting and stabilising the economy and steering the country through the ebb
and flow of economic growth (Cleaver, 1981). Further, the experience of democracy could be extended from representative government to workers being empowered through unions to negotiate better conditions of work and of life for
themselves.
Economic texts describe the Keynesian system as the basis for the stability and
prosperity of Western countries in the post World War II period and up to the
1970s. By the late 1970s, however, this narrative of stability and prosperity was
being overshadowed by another narrative that characterised Keynesian economics
as a threat to the Western world. Wages, it was argued, had been increasing at a
faster rate than productivity and this was undermining the Keynesian principle in
which wages and productivity should grow in accord. Inflation was spiralling.
Business attempted to pass on costs to consumers, which led to wage increase
demands from workers, which led to increased prices and so on.
The inflationary crisis was an opportunity for classical liberal theorists, most
influentially Hayek and Friedman, to re-gain dominance. In the US it gave Carter
(and, later, Reagan) the opportunity to (re)vitalise the discourses of (neo)liberal
economics (Tabb, 1980). In this new order big business once again gained the
upper hand, workers’ wages and conditions were reined in, and the global market
dominated government decision-making. Governance became not only the activity
of government, but also of quasi governmental bodies such as the WTO and the
OECD, and privately funded corporate bodies such as the Trilateral Commission.
Founded in 1973 by David Rockefeller and Zbigniew Brzezinski, the Trilateral
Commission had, by 1980, 300 members made up of some of the worlds most
powerful and wealthy, including people in international business and banking,
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
310 European Journal of Education
from US, Japanese and Western European governments, and from academia,
media and conservative Labour (Sklar, 1980). As Sklar points out, ‘The Commission’s purpose is to engineer an enduring partnership among the ruling classes of
North America, Western Europe, and Japan — hence the term trilateral — in order
to safeguard the interests of Western capitalism in an explosive world’ (Sklar, 1980,
p. 2).
The shift to neo-liberal governance refigured relations between government,
private enterprise and society, with the economic imperatives of the private sector becoming central to government economic and social policy. This shift was
so substantial that it is not unreasonable to say that it involved a change in the
meaning of what a democracy is. Brown (2003, p. 41) analyses the shift to
neo-liberalism as eviscerating not only social/liberal democratic principles but
also democratic morality. The impact on the poor throughout the world has
been scandalous, yet these scandals are dismissed within neo-liberal and neoconservative rhetoric as no more than a matter of ‘miscalculations or political
manoeuvring’.
The Domain of the University: a brief history
Public institutions, previously supported as essential to collective well-being, were
reconstituted under neo-liberalism as part of the market. ‘Within this view there
is nothing distinctive or special about education or health; they are services and
products like any other, to be traded in the marketplace’ (Peters, 1999). Many
countries’ public sectors were early targets of this ideology in the 1980s and were
either privatised or transformed by neo-liberal management technologies. These
included increased exposure to competition, increased accountability measures
and the implementation of performance goals in the contracts of management. A
decade or so later, in the mid- and late 1980s and early 1990s, the same measures
were introduced into universities. The dates vary depending on the country.
Whereas New Zealand, Australia and the US were early entrants to the new
system, Swedish universities were only just beginning to implement neo-liberal
strategies at the time of the interviews.
When the Keynesian system was seen to be working well — particularly in
the early 1960s — Western governments invested in social institutions that would
contribute to the improvement of ‘human capital’, such as education and health.
Informing this link between quality of workers and productivity was a belief
that much of the economic growth of recent times had come from improvements in the quality of capital and labour. Education was one of the central
means by which the ‘quality of capital and labour’ was understood to have been
improved.
The generous funding of universities in this period was made on the basis of
the belief that knowledge and education were valuable to the state and society for
the purposes of defence and for ensuring that all members of society were able to
participate and to contribute. The role of government as generous and unobtrusive
patron of higher education was established on the presumption that universities
would, more or less, support the government’s model of a productive society and
of a State that could defend itself. What this economic narrative did not allow for
was that knowledge and education might work against utilitarian models of the
economic subject and the subject’s relation to the State.
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Bronwyn Davies, Michael Gottsche & Peter Bansel
311
A significant challenge to this idealistic narrative of universities and governments working for a common cause came in 1968 when students in many Western
capitalist democracies violently opposed the idea, for example, that universities
should support, without question, the link between university research and the
military-industrial complex. Students and workers also united in open rebellion
against oppressive regimes and the exploitation of the poor. Their rebellion was
met with a great deal of support from academics on the left. During the ensuing
period, the idea(l) took root in university culture not only of freedom to criticise
government but of a moral responsibility to do so. Students began to look less and
less like docile workers-in-training and more and more like revolutionaries and
rebels.
The events of 1968 resulted in a commitment to greater and more equitable
student access to tertiary education and to moving beyond patriarchal and elite
attitudes within the organisational practices of universities. It was during this
period that the storyline of irresponsible academics abusing the freedom and
autonomy of their positions came to be accepted by many as a morally ascendant
truth (Davies, 2005c). It was also a time of idealistic, moralistic and passionate
commitment to intellectual work, a commitment to a kind of Hegelian or Age of
Enlightenment ethos where through an ongoing dialectical process knowledge
improves on itself — knowledge is teleological — and works towards the betterment of society and of humanity generally. The flourishing of the individual
intellectual worker and of the students was understood to contribute to the
flourishing of the social/economic good. Alongside what we have characterised as
an Hegelian ethos emerged a post-structuralist critique of the foundations, truths,
values and knowledges that such an ethos produced.
What was not visible to many academics pursuing their idealistic and radical
agendas was that if conservative and utilitarian values were the implicit basis for
funding of the university system, it followed that the same utilitarian ideals could
become the basis on which funding could be withheld. Few imagined how dangerous their work with students might seem to be to those in government or to
the global leaders of big business and industry. Those leaders who joined hands
to form the Trilateral Commission, for example, had begun to see democracies as
ungovernable, and as unaffordable. They believed that they must establish a new
order to make the world more predictable, and they saw those radical intellectuals
— both academics and journalists — as contributing to the dangerous disorder
(Sklar, 1980).
In the implementation of the neo-liberal agenda, the idealistic and moral
commitments and perceptions of the 1960s and 1970s, particularly as they related
to equity and social justice, were colonised in an ‘affirmative tokenism’ (Sklar,
1980, p. 45) that made neo-liberalism not only palatable for some, but even
desirable (Lakoff, 2005; Davies, 2005c). However, despite such token affirmative
action programmes, neo-liberalism’s re-conceptualisation of capitalist democracy
as a relation between government, the individual and the market, withdraws value
from the collective and the social good. The free, autonomous, responsible individual of neo-liberalism is no longer located within a community of others: as
Margaret Thatcher famously declared, ‘there is no society — there is only the
market, and competition among individuals within it’. In this revised liberal
model, economic productivity was seen to come not from government investment
in education, but from transforming education into a product that could be bought
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
312 European Journal of Education
and sold like anything else — and in a globalised market, Western education can
be sold as a valuable commodity in developing countries. Within universities the
meaning of ‘productivity’ was shifted away from a generalised social and economic
good towards a notional dollar value for particular government-designated products and practices. Where these products are graduating students, or research
published, government could be construed as funding academic work as usual.
When the ‘products’ to be funded are research grant dollars, with mechanisms in
place to encourage collaboration with industry, this can be seen as straightforward
manipulation of academics to become self-funding and to service the interests of
business and industry.
With the advent of neo-liberalism, following the downfall of Keynesian economics, the mode of conversation between universities and governments shifted
from arguments on the part of each university for increased government funding
to automatically reduced funding combined with heavy (and costly) demands on
accounting for how that funding was used. The elaborate neo-liberal paraphernalia of surveillance, auditing and control was introduced with each change tied
to funding. It was never clear within universities what drove the changes, or
where they began and ended. What was clear, however, was that it was necessary
to know what changes were being demanded and to implement them if government funding was to be secured. In this new relationship between universities
and government, between academics and the State, trust in professional values
and practices was no longer the basis of the relationship (Davies, 2003; Rose,
1999).
The required reforms of the management of universities were heavily dependent on arguments that drew upon two particular economic narratives. First, it
was argued that governments’ budgets could not cope with the massive expansion of the university system in the post-war period; and second, that universities
could be run much more efficiently (where efficiency is equated with doing more
with less), by replacing the unbusinesslike collegial system of university government by a form of managerialism modelled on that of the private sector. Management replaced leadership as the primary role of University Presidents and
Vice- Chancellors. ‘Efficiency in local management’ was to be achieved through
strategies such as ‘reorganisation within the system, breaking up old fiefdoms
and subjecting subordinates to vigorous review’ (Marginson & Considine, 2000,
p. 35). The new model installed ‘System-level changes [that] created a more
competitive relationship between individual institutions, installed efficiency
imperatives in day-to-day conduct, and encouraged the emergence of entrepreneurial managements focused on the economic “bottom-line’’’ (Marginson &
Considine, 2000, p. 28).
The primary aim of government, we suggest, was not simply to do more with
less, since the surveillance and auditing systems are extraordinarily costly and
ineffective, but to make universities more governable and to harness their energies
in support of programmatic ambitions of neo-liberal government and big business.
A shift towards economics as the sole measure of value served to erode the status
and work of those academics who located value in social and moral domains.
Conversely, the technocratic policy-oriented academics, who would serve the ends
of global corporate capital, were encouraged and rewarded.
The interview narratives of the participants describe changes that have taken
place in universities since the 60s. These are characterised through a binary
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Bronwyn Davies, Michael Gottsche & Peter Bansel
313
construction of the moral order of an ‘old’ and a ‘new’ university, one in which
the ‘new’ university is situated as a necessary address (and redress) to the problems
of the ‘old’. What is absent or occluded in these narratives is any account of the
ways in which the discourses and practices of neo-liberal governance may themselves have been implicated in both discursively constituting and problematising
the ‘old’ university, and systematically installing the ‘new’ university through the
economic imperatives and technologies of neo-liberal government. In constituting
‘the old university’ as problematic, neo-liberalism provided the solution from
which the ‘new’ emerged as necessity and inevitability. This is a tactic of managerialism through which successive institutional restructures and reforms are situated as necessary improvements on the old — constituting past practices and older
workers as redundant in the process.
Among the 26 interviewees there are, interestingly, similar patterns in their
personal and professional beliefs and commitments and in their experiences of
neo-liberalism, despite the different history and detail of transformation of the
university system in each country. All of them visibly struggle with the task of
becoming appropriate(d) neo-liberal subjects. All of them express some distress,
no matter how successful they are or how willingly they have entered into some
aspects of neo-liberalism. Higher education, they say, is not in good shape.
Most talk about their university as in a state of financial crisis and many also
talk about it as in a state of ethical crisis. Most describe levels of stress that are
bad for their health (Winefield et al., 2002). Despite the bad shape of their
universities and despite their stress, they talk about academic work as a reward
in itself. Most (all but one) agree that they support the ethos of commitment to
truth, reason, free speech, free enquiry, collegiality and public responsibility and
that they are committed to the idea that universities should be critical incubators for intellectual life. They also said that being free to disagree with those in
positions of authority was important and that they should critique popular
ideas. The majority did not agree with the corporatisation of universities nor did
they agree that university management and decision-making should be driven
by the market. The majority of those interviewed said that their research had
not benefited from the neo-liberal insistence on making research links with
industry. They were not cynical about their own research, however, even though
they claimed that their capacity for innovation and creativity was being damped
down.
Interestingly, and notwithstanding the negative impacts they described of the
neo-liberal system, none of the interviewees expressed a desire to return to the
past, which they saw as seriously flawed. As one of the most outspoken critics of
the pre-neo-liberal university said:
We can mourn as much as we want the passing of the old universities but
the old university was as inimical to me and probably more so than this
University because I was more excluded from any kind of channels of action.
(Australian female social scientist)
While the ‘old university’ had many desirable features that were mourned in the
interviews, it was also seen to have systemic faults. The interviewees’ depiction of
the differences between the system of the 1960s and 1970s and the present neoliberal system show favourable and unfavourable elements in both:
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
314 European Journal of Education
Narratives and discourses employed by interviewees to describe the university of the 60s–
70s and the neo-liberal university of the 80s–00s
The University of the 60s, 70s and early 80s
The Neo-liberal University of the late 80s to the
present
Smaller/More elite/More personal, more trust
Larger/More accessible/Impersonal, less trust
Collegial and democratic/Exclusive and
Discriminatory/Inefficient
Managerial and hierarchical/ Bureaucratic,
endless paperwork/Equitable, more favourable
for women
More stable role in the culture/Fewer
competing views and claims for university
knowledge and expertise/Based on a range of
principles
Unstable role in culture, relativity of knowledge,
more questions about value of academic work/
More claims from industry for university
knowledge and expertise/Based on monetary
principles
More academic autonomy/More room for
irresponsible academics/ More time for
students/ neglect of students’ needs
Less academic autonomy/Less room for
irresponsible academics/ Less time for students/
More accountable to students
Elite and exclusive student body/students as
learners/mostly full time students/fixed career
paths; pre-determined, socially determined
area of study
Large and diverse student body/students as
consumers/increasingly part time/uncertain
career paths, more choice in area of study
The advantages perceived in the current university system were, predictably,
increased accessibility and equity, less room for irresponsible individuals, greater
accountability, greater diversity of the student body, more choice in career paths
for students. This was weighed against a perception of neo-liberalism’s impersonal
style, lack of trust, increased hierarchy and managerialism, endless paperwork,
lower funding, reduction in autonomy, reduced time for students and greater
government control.
The ‘old’ traditional, liberal university (including its more radical elements
following 1968) was characterised as smaller, more personal, with more trust, but
also elite and exclusive. It was more collegial and democratic, but discriminatory.
It was more stable and adhered to a range of principles beyond economic principles. There was more funding, more autonomy, but also more room for individual
abuses. There was more time for students and also occasional neglect. Students
were from elite backgrounds and their choices of what to study were based on
social background. There was little perceived government interference and academics experienced a great deal of authority. The many tensions between the
radical push of the 60s and early 70s, the endurance of features of the traditional
university, and the neo-liberal desire for greater governability are evident in the
interviewees’ depictions of the changes they have observed.
While the perceptions of earlier inefficiencies may have been accepted as a
reason to change, the solutions provided by the neo-liberal system are generally
perceived as bringing with them an array of new inefficiencies with individual
workers now preoccupied with excessive bureaucracy and endless paperwork. The
belief that accountability might lead to better teaching and better treatment of
students is not one shared by the interviewees. They cannot see that it has
produced much that is better for students. Many see the neo-liberal university as
‘dumbing down’ knowledge and as giving them less time for individual students.
What is produced is simply a greater extent of ‘accounting’ in monetary terms —
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Bronwyn Davies, Michael Gottsche & Peter Bansel
315
who delivers what services for how many less dollars in how much reduced time.
One of the interviewees, a scientist who describes himself as very critical of the
old system, nevertheless claimed:
Teaching assessment is a joke. It’s a bit of window dressing and it happens
I do very well at it, but that’s just my good luck in a way and I don’t mind
it. But, I don’t think anyone could seriously think that we assess teaching
now. We just go through the motions. (Australian male scientist).
So who is this window dressing for? Under neo-liberal systems ‘quality’ has to be
demonstrated by going through a number of motions before funding is secured.
This can be, as the following interviewee suggests, a deeply cynical exercise:
We put more and more regulations in and the consequences of those are
more and more unpredictable things that in turn need more and more
regulations and you get a spiraling that you are basically spending 90% of
your effort at regulating the system and only 10% of it at the system actually
doing anything. (American male social scientist).
The voices of despair about the overwhelming nature of workloads featuring the
excessive demands of meeting the requirements of surveillance and auditing are
intensified by the elevation of the dollar as the single or dominant indicator of
value. This induced a feeling of despair in some of the interviewees:
It is all filling in grids, and gathering statistics and then we have to put in
place an evaluation system, or assessment system that tracks graduates for
five years, it is nitty gritty stuff like this . . . So I have to say that in the last
two years my writing is virtually non-existent, and my research, and I am
getting very angry now. And I am wondering if I can stay here or if I have
to walk away from academe totally. (American female social scientist).
Given all these negative features of neo-liberalism, it is interesting to ask how it
was that academics were so thoroughly taken over (and taken in) by it. Are its
positive features enough to explain the extent to which it dominates academic
lives? In the analyses of the interviews undertaken so far (Davies, 2003, 2005a,
2005b; Davies & Bansel, 2005; Davies & Petersen, 2005a, 2005b; Davies et al.,
2005) it becomes evident that academic workers are struggling with more, or
sometimes, less success to become the docile subjects who give government what
it wants. And at the same time, taken up as they are by the discourses through
which they are defined as free, autonomous and responsible, they disavow their
own docility and see themselves as choosing to work in the ways they are working
— as responsible for their own misery and for the inferior nature of their products
(Davies & Bansel, 2005). In what follows we will suggest that it is precisely this
(disavowed) docility that serves the programmatic ambitions of neo-liberal
government.
For this docile subject, the excesses of productivity (combined with anxiety
that it is never enough) have seriously negative impacts on health (Winefield et al.,
2002). These doubly negative impacts could suggest that no rational government
could want this if it is concerned either about the health and well-being of the
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
316 European Journal of Education
workers (if only for the negative impact on health costs), or the quality of what
they produce. We suggest, however, that within a particular economic narrative,
located within a particular historical context, these so-called negative impacts can
actually seem desirable if they increase both docility and the new ‘productivity’.
And indeed, we could say that neo-liberalism is successful within those narrow
terms since within the new order, academic communities engaging in critique and
potential rebellion are generally perceived by academics themselves to have
become an unaffordable luxury. The talk that informs critique and the development of a counter-discourse takes time–time that no-one any longer has (Davies
& Bansel, 2005).
Because of the deep commitment expressed about continuing to do work that
is valued for its intellectual rather than monetary worth (and despite the imposition of neo-liberal technologies), the interviewees often seriously over-worked
themselves, giving up their private lives, for example, in order to continue to
produce the work that they were passionate about. Others drew back from the 80hour weeks worked before the advent of neo-liberalism, seeing their family lives
at risk from the ever-increasing pressure. Whilst they were reluctant to describe
their work as of lesser quality than previously, they claimed without hesitation that
the new system was forcing them into inferior work (Davies & Petersen, 2005a,
2005b; Davies & Bansel, 2005). Many recounted negative impacts on their work:
And I’d say, yes, there were those times when I certainly felt that my capacity
for innovation and creativity and even capacity to engage in some sort of
thought that had some intellectual stretch were being washed down the tubes.
(New Zealander female social scientist).
As Marginson and Considine suggest, universities may have needed reinvention
but this should not be done by punitive denial of those aspects of academic culture
that facilitate excellence in teaching and research. They argue that if, ‘reinvention
worked through academic cultures, actively engaging them, a larger, more exciting
and more educationally enriching range of reinventions might become possible’
(Marginson & Considine, 2000, p. 237).
Moving Forward to the 21st Century: fertile ground for the fall of
neo-liberalism
In considering the question of where to next, it is important not to lose sight of
what the interviewees saw as some of the advantages of neo-liberalism. At the same
time, it is also important that we make its negative workings visible and available
for critique. We have attempted in these sketches of the rise of neo-liberalism and
neo-liberal governance of the academy to signal the imperatives and strategies
through which neo-liberalism emerged in its historical context. We have also
sketched the ways in which these historical shifts mobilised certain desires and
commitments (including equity, freedom, responsibility, transparency, access and
choice) as a means of securing a re-conceptualisation of the relationship between
government, society and the subject in economic terms.
In addressing the policies and practices through which the programmatic
ambitions of neo-liberal governance have been realised, we have foregrounded the
ways in which economic discourses and imperatives have reshaped social relations
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Bronwyn Davies, Michael Gottsche & Peter Bansel
317
and subjects, both within the university and beyond. Academic subjects have been
constituted and managed as successful or appropriate subjects on terms that have
been increasingly driven by externalised, globalised economic relations. Academic
work, along with academic worker subjectivities, have been reshaped through
practices that emphasise and privilege some relations and performances and foreclose others. The imperatives of the practises through which academic subjects are
governed have turned away from the intellectual work of critique and innovation
towards managing workloads and meeting the terms of workplace agreements as
measured through publication outputs, research funding, the establishment of
relationships with industry partners, etc.
There is a growing global tendency to recognise, name and respond to neoliberalism as a system of governmentality, making it visible where it was previously
an unnamed set of technologies aimed at privileging corporate capital. The illusion
that we have had some choice in embracing neo-liberal policies and practices and
have willingly and knowingly brought it on ourselves is being disassembled in this
work and in the work of authors like George and Saul. We have arrived at a time
when it is possible to analyse the ways in which the technologies of neo-liberalism
rely on (and generate) little more than an illusion of voluntarism, autonomy and
freedom.
How then, might we both understand and resist the specific mechanisms,
modalities, techniques and discourses through which neo-liberalism is constituted
as inevitable? And in anticipating its fall, what will that look like? We know that it
is likely to be neither sudden nor announced. The end of neo-liberalism will, no
doubt, be as piecemeal and diffused as its implementation, and it will be peppered
with neo-liberal zealots pressing their neo-liberal reforms with more determination
than ever.
In this article, we have analysed the rise of neo-liberalism in universities,
showing what has been foreclosed by neo-liberal regulation of the academy, of
academic work and of academic workers. Being able to see how the conditions
through which this rise has been discursively and materially installed as inevitable
and necessary allows us to imagine and mobilise strategic action towards acts
which in turn forestall the appropriation of our work and our lives by neo-liberal
ideals. And as Sartre wrote to the students at the end of May ’68: ‘You have an
imagination . . . Something has emerged from you which surprises, which astonishes and which denies everything that has made our society what it is today. That
is what I would call the extension of the field of possibility. Do not give up’ (cited
in Ali & Watkins, 1998, p. 105).
In understanding the conditions of possibility through which neo-liberalism
has done its work in, on and through us, we might begin to reshape the academy,
academic work and ourselves through interventions that resist the master narratives and technologies of neo-liberal governance. We can begin, in Barthes’ (1977)
term, to ‘decompose’ the individualistic neo-liberal subjects we have become. Neoliberalism, as rationality, as necessity, as inevitability can be turned on itself and
shown to be less than rational, less than necessary, less than inevitable. It will take
individual and collective imagination and profound courage to re-envisage and recreate the university of the 21st century as a place that sustains scholarly intellectual work.
Neither the rise of neo-liberalism, nor its downfall, are understood here as the
product of a coordinated, coherent set of intentions, or linear and massively
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
318 European Journal of Education
orchestrated events. Rather, they are understood as emergent from local re/iterations of ideologies, discourses, reactions and tactics, from ‘what we might call the
efficacy of dispersed and discontinuous offensives’ (Foucault, 1969/2003, p. 5).
Similarly, dispersed and discontinuous offensives can undo the ‘astonishing efficacy of totalitarian theories, or at least — what I mean is — all-encompassing and
global theories’ (1969/2003, p. 6). Just as the rise of neo-liberalism cannot be
traced to linear and massively orchestrated events, so it is with its fall. The fall is
emerging from a series of small, local and co-extensive critiques that are discontinuous and yet astonishing in their overall power to lead to the crumbling of
something that has seemed so total and impregnable. What we might look forward
to will include anything positive that was generated during the last 25 years of
neo-liberalism; and while we do not imagine a romantic reversion to the old, we
would hope for a recovery of those values that situated universities as vital to the
practice of social/liberal democratic principles.
How we choose, individually and collectively, to act now will in itself be
constitutive of the emergence of what is to come: ‘we can’t be sure of what is
coming next, although we can almost certainly influence the outcome’ (Saul,
2005, p. 3).
NOTE
1. It is interesting to note that these critiques from George and Saul that have
captured the public imagination come from outside the university system.
REFERENCES
ALI, T. & WATKINS, S. (1998) 1968. Marching in the Streets (New York, The Free
Press).
BARTHES, R. (1977) Roland Barthes by Roland Barthes (Berkeley, University of
California Press).
BROWN, W. (2003) Neo-liberalism and the end of liberal democracy, Theory and
Event, 7, pp. 1–43
CLEAVER, H. (1981) Supply side economics: The new phase of capitalist strategy
in the crisis, Babylone, Fall edition.
DAVIES, B. (2003) Death to critique and dissent? The policies and practices of
new managerialism and of ‘evidence-based practice’, Gender and Education,
15, pp. 89–101.
DAVIES, B. (2005a) The fairy who wouldn’t fly: a story of subjection and agency,
Journal of Early Childhood Literacy, 5, pp. 58–80.
DAVIES, B. (2005b) Winning the hearts and minds of academics in the service of
neoliberalism, Dialogue, 24, pp. 26–37.
DAVIES, B. (2005c) The impossibility of intellectual work in neoliberal regimes,
Discourse, 26, pp. 3–16.
DAVIES, B. & BANSEL, P. (2005) The time of their lives? Academic workers in
neoliberal time(s), Sociology of Health Review, 14, pp. 47–58.
DAVIES, B. & PETERSEN, E. (2005a) Intellectual workers (un)doing neoliberal
discourse, International Journal of Critical Psychology, 13, pp. 32–54.
DAVIES, B. & PETERSEN, E. (2005b) Neoliberal discourse in the academy: the forestalling of collective resistance, Learning and Teaching in the Social Sciences, 2.
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Bronwyn Davies, Michael Gottsche & Peter Bansel
319
DAVIES, B., BROWNE, J., GANNON, S., HONAN, E. & SOMERVILLE, M. (2005)
Embodied women at work in neoliberal times and places, Gender, Work and
Organization, 12, pp. 343–362.
DAVIES, B., BROWNE, J., GANNON, S., HOPKINS, L., MCCANN, H. &
WIHLBORG, M. (2006) Constituting ‘the subject’ in poststructuralist
discourse, Feminism & Psychology.
DEAN, M. (1999) Governmentality: Power and Rule in Modern Society (London,
Sage).
DEAKIN, N. (2001) In Search of Civil Society (Houndsmills, Palgrave).
FOUCAULT, M. (1978) On governmentality, Ideology & Consciousness, 6, pp. 5–22.
FOUCAULT, M. (1969/2003) The Archaeology of Knowledge (London, Routledge).
GAMBLE, A. (2001) Neoliberalism, Capital and Class, 5, pp.127–134.
GEORGE, S. (1999) A Short History of Neoliberalism. Conference on Economic
Sovereignty in a Globalising World, Global Policy Forum (March 24–26).
HAY, C. (1999) The Political Economy of New Labour: labouring under false pretences?
(Manchester, Manchester University Press).
LAKOFF, G. (2005) Don’t Think of an Elephant (Carlton North, Victoria, Scribe).
MARGINSON, S. & CONSIDINE, M. (2000) The Enterprise University. Power, Governance and the Reinvention in Australia (Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press).
PETERS, M (1999) Neoliberalism, in The Encyclopedia of Philosophy of Education
http://www.vusst.hr/ENCYCLOPAEDIA/neoliberalism.htm.
ROSE, N. (1999) Powers of Freedom (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).
SAUL, J. R. (2005) The Collapse of Globalism and the Reinvention of the World
(Camberwell, Viking).
SKLAR, H. (1980) Overview, in: H. SKLAR (Ed) Trilateralism. The Trilateral
Commission and Elite Planning for World Management (Montreal, Black Rose
Books) pp. 1–58.
TABB, W. (1980) The trilateral imprint on domestic economies, in: H. SKLAR
(Ed) Trilateralism. The Trilateral Commission and Elite Planning for World Management (Montreal, Black Rose Books) pp. 212–237.
WINEFIELD, H. W., GILLESPIE, N., STOUGH, C., DUA, J., & HAPUARARCHCHI,
J. (2002) Occupational Stress in Australian Universities: A National Survey. A
report to the Vice-Chancellors, National Tertiary Education Union, Faculty
and Staff of Australian Universities, and The Ministers for Education and
Health.
WATSON, I., BUCHANAN, J., CAMPBELL, I. & BRIGGS, C. (2003) Fragmented
Futures: New challenges in working life (Annanadale, The Federation Press).
© 2006 The Authors. Journal compilation © 2006 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.