Fro
Politi al Crisis to Europe’s Se o d Re aissa e?
Hardy Hanappi
There is no doubt: The European unification project currently is in a terrible state. Politically
the governments of EU member states are following more and more explicitly their own
national priorities, considering the EU rather as a side constraint than as a shared project. In
several countries there even is the danger that extreme nationalists conquer state power
and actively work against any European unification project, though in most EU countries the
goal of EU critiques rather concerns the way top-level EU institutions take decisions and
prescribe economic policy. There national governments still believe in the possibility to
redesign European governance and economic integration. To produce more than just a
vague vision of this latter political goal it is mandatory to take a closer look at the problems
that the current institutional framework of the European Union is struggling with.
In short, the main problems are unemployment in Mediterranean EU member countries,
sovereign debt crisis everywhere (except in Germany) and more recently the large inflow of
emigrants from North Africa and the Middle East. All three central topics are highly
interdependent. They all have been around in a more or less latent form already for a longer
term and have manifested themselves massively since 2009 – triggered by the global
financial crisis in 2008. To understand their dynamic interplay it is of particular importance
to analyze the sequence of events, to investigate the causal structure of the main forces that
have been at work.
Still the best – though somewhat too general - explanation of the trigger event in September
2008 is that large scale financial activities are built on expectations including the expected
manipulation of expectations, which are characterized by surprisingly fast self-amplifying
cascades and even faster over-night break-downs1. What made the 2008 crash so special
were the extraordinary size and the global territorial span that financial webs had developed
since the end of the bi-polar world in the early 90-ties. While small bubbles at the many
financial markets around the world are their main driver and are part of their daily business,
big disturbances (with the exception of the ICT bubble in 2001) could be prevented for a
rather surprisingly long time. That it then happened probably needed only a little bit of
additional insecurity. The foreseeable end of the Bush era in US governance certainly
contributed to that.
As soon as the events in the thin air of financial expectations of autumn 2008 translated into
the material activities of physical actors in the real economy in 2009, this year became the
1
I a paper alled O the E e of Glo al Fi a ial Collapse that e rote i the su
er of 2008 efore the
fall of Lehmann in September) and which was published in November 2008, we provide a summary of four
typical explanations of a collapse; see [Hanappi and Rengs, 2008].
deepest downturn of the global economy since the Great Depression of the interwar period.
Did we enter a new interwar period?
In 2009 the impact of the financial meltdown on investment and employment in Europe was
dramatic. What is even more spectacular is the fact that since then it is persistent (compare
figure 1).
200000
7000000
180000
160000
6000000
140000
5000000
4000000
WW 1
3000000
120000
100000
WW 2
80000
60000
2000000
40000
1000000
20000
0
1900
1905
1910
1915
1920
1925
1930
1935
1940
1945
1950
1955
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
0
12 European Countries
1990 International Geary Khamis Dollars (for Greece)
8000000
Great
Depression
1990 International Geary Khamis Dollars (for 12
countries)
GDP (constant 1990 GK $)
Greece
2
Figure 1: Real GDP in 12 European Countries (left scale) and Greece (right scale)
Source: Angus Maddison, University of Groningen
The sudden fall in expected demand, including investment demand therefore was the first
step in the sequence of events. With expected revenues going down most firms had only
one choice to maintain their profit rate: reduce cost. This became the omnipresent credo
throughout the business community; if a firm can manage to survive then eventually it might
take over market shares from less lucky competitors. And since the largest part of total cost
usually is wage cost it is straight forward that these came under fire. Firing employees, or at
least utti g their salaries leads right i to Europe s pro le area u er o e, the
unemployment problem.
But what about employment in the public sector? There the provision of infrastructural
goods and services seemed to be the central goal variable and not profit maximization,
though financial feasibility always was a side constraint to be observed. But with decreasing
tax revenues from a shrinking private sector and labor contracts of public employees that
2
Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, UK.
made wage cost reductions more difficult, this side constraint quickly became binding.
Moreover an older ideological conflict amplified this process: Some governments still were
following Keynesian policy rules that advised to compensate decreasing private demand
(and employment) by increasing public demand (and employment). Conservative politicians
since the Thatcher-Reagan-Kohl era were advocating exactly the opposite, namely to close
down or to privatize as many infrastructural units as possible. State institutions were
thought to be ineffective compared to private enterprises and often superfluous. As far as
conservative policy was executed unemployment was additionally fueled by former public
employees, and as far as old Keynesians had a say the crisis immediately transpired as a
public debt problem.
It has to be noted that this transmission from lowered demand to sovereign debt crisis did
take place differently in different EU countries. As a closer look into the European firm size
structure shows the southern affiliates of large private firms of northern countries caused a
lot of unemployment in the south in 2009, delaying the increase of unemployment in the
north. Moreover the inertness of consumer behavior and firm behavior often was supported
by a national private banking sector and local politicians that used their own shorter time
horizons to enable long-run indebtedness of their clients. This disastrous institutional design
failure occurred in different ways and with different consequences in different EU countries.
But where it occurred it inevitably led into problem 2, the sovereign debt crisis, since
bankruptcy of large local banks from 2010 onwards could be expected to be avoided by state
interventions, i.e. bailouts. Unemployment had already risen in a way that made
governments tremble if they thought about mass layoffs in the financial sector. Within two
years the government debt crisis had surfaced as another consequence of the 2008 financial
meltdown. The difference between EU member countries due to their different internal
institutional and social framework as well as due to their different position in the European
(and global) division of labor became more accentuated.
Figure 2: Real GDP Growth in 4 Mediterranean Countries, OECD data
At this point in time the situation in Greece became a prominent topic in many European
media. The Greek economy had not been of particular interest for European policy-makers
before, it was just another Mediterranean country comparable to Italy, Spain and Portugal
(compare fig. 2). It had joined the EU later than Italy but earlier than Spain (mainly for global
military reasons, see [Hanappi, 2014, pp. 154-168]) and in 2010 still contributed only 2.69 %
to the total GDP of the Eurozone (in 2013 this share has even fallen to 2.23%). So why was
Greece suddenly so important?
The Great Greek State Robbery
In 1963 a gang of 16 men in the UK carried out what today is famously known as the Great
Trai ‘o er . With a sophisti ated pla a d ithout sheddi g lood the stole a
substantial amount of money from a train between Glasgow and London. Though some of
the gang members were caught most of the money was never found. So despite the result
that for some people the robbery was a highly profitable activity it nevertheless clearly was a
criminal act.
In several other cases, mainly in the USA, a less clear-cut type of money-stealing action
occurred. Its basic scheme can easily be summarized: Assume that entity A (say a member of
top management) is able to organize a large credit by using the reputation of the larger legal
entity B (say a firm) of which A is part of. To get this credit it will be necessary that B can
offer a collateral. Once the credit is given and the money can be used inside B entity A will
start to transfer it to its own private account somewhere outside B (say by getting personal
extra premium or option payments etc.). The final step then is to let entity B die, i.e. to go
bankrupt. Creditors as well as other remaining employees of B suddenly discover how
difficult it is to transform an obsolete collateral into money. Meanwhile entity A might
restart the same game at a new entity C. Supported by a careful lawyer the actions of entity
A can often remain on the legal side of the concerned national law system, despite the fact
that the essence of the process looks like robbery: entity A gets away with the money of
creditors who accepted the collateral B.
In both examples the amounts of money that are at stake are high, and eventually some
robbers succeed – at the expense of creditors and damage done to the general public. The
Greek economy is a rather small part of the European economy, its domestic population is
almost comparable to the number of employees of a large transnational corporation. Credit
provided for the Greek government (entity B) by large European financial intermediaries
before the financial crash could count on the monopoly of a nation state to use coercive
power to raise taxes – a perfect collateral. The first part of the transfer of this money to
some local owners (elements of entity A) was initiated by the Greek government in a variety
of ways, an outstanding role evidently was played by the tycoons in the construction sector3
and the shipping industry. Missing controls from the side of creditors as well as the
particularly tightly knit web of corruption in the elites of the two leading political parties, the
Greek Orthodox Church and the military also made this practice a sure game for the involved
parties. A further consequence of this setting became a rather special characteristic of the
attitude of the general public with respect to state institutions: The fact that the network of
powerful top decision-makers in government agencies (and business) worked so frictionless
became public knowledge and caused a widespread fatalism among those not involved. In
other words, state institutions were seen as purely negative entities serving only for the
personal enrichment of the state functionaries; the role of the state as a provider of
infrastructure for all vanished in the background of the consciousness of the general public.
The extremely high tax evasion rate in Greece was one direct consequence of this
development.
In contrast to a firm, agent A in a national economy is an entity composed of a conglomerate
coming from rather heterogeneous groups. Using a term of classical political economy it
could be called the national ruling class, which consists of heterogeneous factions – the state
faction, the (large) fir o ers fa tio , the a kers fa tio
o pare [Hanappi, 2014, p.
156]). These factions are not just heterogeneous, in several respects they also have
contradicting goals, e.g. with respect to interest rates. In a continental entity like the
European Union the different national ruling classes typically form coalitions, the Greek
agent A thus was able to coordinate its actions with banking factions of other countries.
While the first part of the state robbery described above was running well up to 2008, the
sudden interruption in 2009 was becoming a problem for the Greek state faction of the
national ruling class. In October 2009 state power in Greece was transferred away from the
conservative ND to the social democratic PASOK, which first seemed to be in a better
3
Remember the construction initiatives for the Olympic Games in Athens in 2004 and the support program for
subsidies to build 5-star hotels.
position to ameliorate the situation and to calm down the growing unrest in the population
– a rapidly vanishing illusion. In contrast to these internal troubles the international coalition
of banking factions quickly realized that these difficulties opened up the possibility of a
second step of Greek state robbery. The basic mechanism was simple, it just exploited the
difference between the credit-worthiness of the entire Eurozone and the credit-worthiness
of Greece that was already severely damaged by Greek state robbery step 1. This difference
was nicely mirrored in the difference between (low) interest rates to be paid for additional
credit from the ECB and (high) interest rates to be paid by the Greek government. At the
time (2009-2010) this difference was more than 10 percentage points and the coalition of
international banking factions thus was taking cheap credit from one side and gave it to the
other side at substantially higher interest rates. As a result interest payments of Greece
exploded, the special role of the Greek government debt situation emerged. As shown in
figure 3 high interest payments preceded the further strong increase in government debt.
Even when this second step of the Great Greek State Robbery was stopped in 2012 and
lower interest rates were made available the old high stock variable government debt
remained.
Figure 3: Interest rate on Greek government debt and Greek debt, OECD data
With the stratification of frontiers of coalitions of the factions of national ruling classes in
Europe – and with respect to finance including also the USA – the case of the small Greek
economy became a major European problem. The sequence of events again is revealing: The
second step of state robbery initiates a self-amplifying downward trend of Greek creditworthiness. Banks still borrow money to the Greek government since the Greek national
agent A has already transferred large amounts of cash to secure foreign havens4 that can be
4
The amount of savings of Greek citizens in Swiss banks has been estimated to be some 200 billion Euro.
taken as additional collateral. More important, international finance expects that the
continuous rise of Greek government debt at some point in time will be stopped by a (at
least partial) moratorium agreed upon by European governments. Until this will happen the
European private banking networks had to try hard to get rid of Greek government debt, the
logical task being the national state factions. These attempts were impressively successful.
Today the owners of the this debt are mainly European nation states and their collateral, of
course, is their constitutional right to enforce taxes even if their monopoly on the use of
coercive power is necessary. On the other hand the owners of the money that this debt
produced, called agent A in this story, are spread all over financial centers of the world. Like
in the case of the Great Train Robbery in 1963 it cannot be expected that the money will
ever be found.
The Great Greek State Robbery therefore has been a demonstration of how legal loopholes,
ill-designed institutional controls, in short, an unfinished framework for a political
continental unit can boost contradictions not only between usual suspects - workers facing
exploding unemployment rates and super-rich members of the ruling class – but also
between national and international class factions of the ruling class. The latter conflict is
exactly the material on which new nationalisms in Europe thrive. It is this play with fire, of a
national return of extreme right-wing policies that is the most dangerous aspect of the
existing deficiencies of the design of European unification5. The deep divide between citizens
in southern EU members and those in Germany that has emerged as a consequence of a
comparably small amount of credit money – 300 billion Euro of Greek debt have to be
compared to the annually produced GDP of the EU of some 14000 Euro – shows how urgent
a re-design of an institutional framework that enables such a disaster really is 6.
The Return of Democracy
In the course of the crisis since 2010 the pressure on the Greek population to pay back a
debt that to a considerable extent had been already consumed or transferred to foreign
accounts (by the group that above was called Agent A) steadily increased. It was quite clear
from the outset that the surplus produced by Greece was way too small to get rid of this
debt in a reasonable time-span. Moreover those who were pushed to produce this national
surplus in general were not the ones that had taken advantage of the credit money. Average
wages in Greece fell to two thirds of the EU average, the social security net was dissolved,
and a wide range of measures aiming at a reduction of government expenditure was
introduced. From November 2011 onwards political power again was shifted towards the
conservative ND, but the economic impossibility to squeeze out profits of a dramatically
impoverished population, implying a breakdown of demand and the emigration of whole
cohorts of better educated young Greeks, could not be mastered by this government.
5
The fight against nationalism is dealt with in [Hanappi, 2015b].
Some ideas on how to fight European unemployment by new institutional efforts can be found in [Hanappi,
2015a].
6
The local national government only adjusted to the completely misconceived austerity
program that the creditor countries wanted to see being implemented.
Based on a dubious macroeconomic model that any serious scholar would have immediately
refuted the policy consultants of creditor states by and large prescribed policy measures that
in retrospect can be said to have made things worse. The continuous suffering of the Greek
population, in particular in the big cities, was in sharp contrast to the use of the largest part
of the additional credit money of the EU, namely to pay interest to international creditors, in
the meantime state institutions of other EU countries. The net support thus was small and
was overcompensated by the continuing spiral of demand decrease7.
With no improvement in sight, standard austerity argumentation evidently being wrong, a
rather confused debate on GREXIT came up. Wild speculations about possible future
dynamics that clearly were missing any possibility of quantitative econometric justification –
how could a unique event with a new institutional setting happening for the first time in
history be derived from past data – were the battleground on which predetermined
emotional attitudes clashed. Since an exit of Greece from the Eurozone would primarily have
caused an additional risk that Italy and Spain also might come under fire it was international
finance, personalized as the ECB boss and former Goldman-Sachs man Mario Draghi, which
calmed down the situation in 2012. A little bit of turmoil is fueling the daily business of
financial intermediaries – as long as they are on the profitable side of trade disturbances –
but a large disaster in Southern Europe would not be advantageous. In a sense the ECB
saved Greece from GREXIT and indeed initiated its own entry into a more active European
economic policy. The German government was not too happy with this development, there
the hardliners of the unsuccessful austerity policy were still the most influential group. But
Angela Merkel accepts to turn away from GREXIT and starts a different polemic8: Greece
ust e o e o petiti e . Co petiti e ess usuall is easured
produ ti it , hi h is
the ratio between output and input of a production process, both expressed in money
terms. If a more productive firm by competition at the marketplace can eliminate the less
productive firm, then this gain in more output (with the same input) eventually can be
transformed in an overall welfare increase. With respect to nation states this story is
completely inadequate. Countries simply are not firms producing the same product. A high
productivity of tourism in Greece and heavy industry in Germany do not compete with their
respective counterparts in the other country – international division of labor and
ooperatio
as the a e of the ga e that ade Europe s e o o i su ess after World
War 2 possible. The growth of labor productivity within each country, the only variable that
can reasonably be compared across different parts of the divided labor, is not different to
the o e i Europe s largest ou tries see fig. 4 . Boiled down to its ideological essence
Merkel s ad i e is thus just a restatement of austerity policy: reduce inputs (employment,
wages, public infrastructure) and squeeze out as much as possible from remaining
7
8
Even in the latest package the use of 80% of the money for payback of credit is prescribed.
See [Gammelin and Löw, 2014, p.149] for a detailed description.
employees (later retirement age etc.). No surprise that all this did not help the misery
spreading in Greece.
Labor Productivity Growth
15.0%
10.0%
Greece
Spain
percent
5.0%
Italy
France
0.0%
UK
Germany
-5.0%
Real GDP growth
1961
1964
1967
1970
1973
1976
1979
1982
1985
1988
1991
1994
1997
2000
2003
2006
2009
2012
2015
-10.0%
Figure 4: Comparison of Labor Productivity Growth, OECD data
Fortunately enough democratic states are not private firms, disappointed and impoverished
voters can elect a new government; in January 2015 the Greek elections brought a new party
into power, SYRIZA. For many heads of state in European countries this was a shock, the new
prime minister and his team were not part of the well-established political elite that
oordi ated Europe s state fa tio of the respe ti e atio al ruli g lasses. In particular the
German government, which in the years of crisis had become a kind of informal hegemon of
European politics, from the very beginning clearly had the – not officially admitted - goal to
get SYRIZA out of Greek government. To re-install a government with the two former parties
ND and PASOK would have been the easiest way to assure austerity measures and the silent
backflow of EU money with the help of a willing Greek prime minister. But so far these
German ideas have remained wishful thinking.
The Greek Prime Minister Tsipras has successfully maintained his position, surviving
challenges from the conservative Greek mass media in the referendum campaign as well as
the split-off of a pro-GREXIST group within SYRIZA. The most interesting feature of his recent
policy is the turn towards a radical re-orientation to support the immediate needs of all
citizens – call it populism or call it radically democratic service. At the referendum that
SYRIZA initiated in spring 2015 Greeks were asked if they support austerity policy. The result
that 61% are against – and not 95% as the actual economic position of citizens would
suggest – shows the strength of the influence of conservative mass media, which hawked
rumors that the referendum was about staying in the European Union. As a response to this
defeat the Troika, representing the ruling classes of the other EU countries that were afraid
to be forced to share the loss incurred by agent A, was restricting liquidity for Greek citizens.
The tactic was to force Tsipras to choose between two alternatives that both would let
Tsipras appear to be untrustworthy in the public opinion: If he signed the new austerity
package he would betray those whom he promised to put an end to austerity - but liquidity
would be there; if he would not sign he would betray those whom he promised that the
economic situation would improve – but he would neutralize those within SYRIZA who
already doubted his loyalty to anti-austerit poli . I oth ases SY‘I)A s ha es to e reelected in a new parliamentary election would be substantially reduced, at least this was the
plan. Still it was the final goal, the hidden agenda, to drive Tsipras out of government.
SYRIZA decided to accept that both threats, a 3 rd austerity package as well as restricted
liquidity, are of immediate importance for Greek citizens. To be close to the will of people
meant to determine the relative weights of two bad things, including the counter-measures
that are available to a national government. With respect to the latter it was clear that the
national influence on monetary policy within the Eurozone was minimal, while on the other
hand the list of austerity measures always was finite and could be supplemented by
countervailing new policy measures. Some of the new rules of the Troika were even useful
fro SY‘I)A s perspe ti e too. The de isio thus as e ide t, the pa kage as signed. To
see if he really had made the decision that was closest to the public will, Tsipras stepped
down and a new election was called – the hopes of those represented by the Troika were
high again. But on 20th of September 2015 SYRIZA was re-elected again, the turn to the
immediate needs of all citizens, to radical democracy, had proved to be successful.
Note that Tsipras de isio to for a oalitio
ith ANEL, a atio alist part o the right,
also can be interpreted as a o e loser to the ill of Greek s people; there is a o sidera le
share of conservative citizens for whom it is important to be represented in government.
Moreover the choice of ANEL and the decision to link this partner to the military might be a
reaction to the particularly dangerous development in the winter 2011 to 2012. After
Papandreou (PASOK) had resigned in November 2011 and German politics seemed to be so
stubborn with respect to immediate debt repayment, the possibility of a military coup in
Greece was in the air. Even some influential circles in the German banking sector were
reported to have been in favor of such a solution 9. The Greek left, of course, was alarmed.
How should they react, how could these tendencies be controlled? In late spring 2012 it
turned out that a return of ND to government was sufficient to calm down creditor countries
and international finance.
There now is a general tendency of new left-wing parties to i itate SY‘I)A s strateg ,
PODEMOS is Spain and several others, including some voices in Green parties, find it
important to shift priority towards the immediate needs of the population even if some
9
Since openly declared military dictatorship would not qualify for EU membership a more sophisticated
political construct secured by the Greek army would have been the alternative to the return of Nea
Democratia.
ideological long-run goals are in conflict with them. Despite Tsipras preliminary success in
the Greek case – the German government has not given up its primary goal yet – it has to be
warned that such a strategy means walking on thin ice. Public opinion and (seemingly)
immediate needs can be treacherous signs, in particular since they are easily manipulated by
modern mass media technologies. It becomes very important for progressive political
strategists to combine the signals coming from the sensors in the general public with
profound theoretical work on political economy. Without such a permanent interaction a
blind populism that eventually is directed by a handful of media moguls and their friends who actually blind the population – can be the outcome. The turn to a new understanding of
democracy therefore is a risky project, but birth processes always bear the risk to fail. In the
ase of Europe s stale ate si e eight lo g ears the irth pro ess already has passed the
critical threshold, there is no way back to the system of the long reconstruction period after
World War 2. The best we can do is to learn from the failures and successes of the national
experiences in countries like Greece.
The Possi ility of Europe’s Se o d Re aissa e
An immediate lesson to be learned is that a more consistent institutional framework with
less loopholes in its legal counterpart is urgently needed. This involves a lot of detailed,
specialized work as well as work on the accompanying general vision. Both need much more
resources, personnel and money, than are currently available in the European Union. Parts
of tax authority and social policy will have to be transferred to the center to enable this. But
how is the political center to be democratically determined, i.e. elected? Also the current
practice of policy-making is rather frightening: In urgent cases the center consists of the two
heads of state of Germany and France who in a telephone conversation take a decision. The
president of the EU then simply is informed by the German Chancellor of what happened.
This type of procedure just reflects the fact that indirect democracy reigns at best on the
national level, European democracy is still in its infancy.
A most important part of the institutional redesign concerns the continent-wide subsidiarity
design. What is to be decided on which level? To assume that for each task there exists a
level at which a question can be solved best is a serious mistake. The current wave of
immigration provides a vivid example for a problem where national decision-making and
continental strategy are tightly interwoven. This is precisely the point where a well-designed
institutional framework should be at hand to guide action plans, avoiding useless meetings
of rather randomly invited politicians. To implement a new and more useful institutional
framework, of course, means to take away political power from some currently powerful
institutions and to redistribute it to some still less experienced new agencies. In other words,
there will be resistance that only can be overcome if the pressure from a currently
unbearable situation is strong enough – remember the Greek example. There are good
reaso s to e pe t that the pressure o Europe s orkfor e ill i rease o ti uousl i the
next decade. Increases in labor productivity that could spur growth are not in sight (see fig.
4), there just is the la or sa i g progress of the se o d a hi e age that soon will be
fueling unemployment. No advance towards balancing the living conditions of Europe, North
Africa and the Middle East is currently on the agenda, the waves of immigration thus will
continue. There is a serious surge of ilitar e pe diture aki g Europe s Easter a d
South-Eastern borders look unstable. The danger of public employment strategies based on
the recruitment of soldiers for possible warfare can become a – seemingly logical consequence. Again – are we already in a new interwar period? With all these threats
building up, the European populace often looks in its own future with a somewhat naïve,
mostly myopic, but sometimes nevertheless optimistic attitude. Times of fundamental
changes also open up the chance to jump on the next level of social development.
A pilot project Europe, the plan to master the above mentioned difficulties in a civilized way
– without (civil) war – has to be on top of the agenda of European social scientists. Contrary
to the USA, Europe has not really emerged as a unique global player on the landscape of
global politics yet. Europe still is in the process of being born, and this dangerous process
brings with it the promising feature of a still possible flexible adaption to the needs of the
populatio as ell as to the k o ledge of its s ie tists. This pri ar so ializatio of our
continent, the making of pilot project Europe, if su essful ould ell e its se o d
‘e aissa e .
References
Demetriou K. (ed.), 2015, The European Union in Crisis, Springer.
Gammelin C. and Löw R., 2014, Europas Drahtzieher, Econ Verlag.
Hanappi H., 2014a, Embedded in Global Politics, in: [Hanappi, 2014b, pp. 141-174].
Hanappi H. (ed.), 2014b, South-East Europe in Evolution, Routledge.
Hanappi H., 2015a, Unemployment in Mediterranean EU Countries, in: [Katsikides and Koktsidis (eds.), 2015,
pp. 39-56].
Hanappi H., 2015b, Defeating Nationalism in Europe, in: [Demetriou (ed.), 2015, pp. 141-154].
Hanappi H. and Rengs B., 2008, On the Eve of Global Financial Collapse. Explanations, necessity, and policy
conclusions, Proceedings of the annual conference of EAEPE 2008 in Rome. Available on at
http://www.econ.tuwien.ac.at/hanappi/Papers/EAEPE2008.pdf
Katsikides S. and Koktsidis P. (eds.), 2015, Societies in Transition, Springer.