JOIJRNALOF
ELSEVIER
Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314
Incentives, downsizing, and value creation at
General Dynamics
Jay Dial,
Harvard
Kevin
University,
J. Murphy*
Boston,
MA 02163.
USA
(Received April 1994; final version received July 1994)
Abstract
In 1991,defensecontractor General Dynamics engageda new managementteam
which adopted an explicit corporate objective of creating shareholdervalue. The company tied executive compensationto shareholderwealth creation, and subsequently
implementeda strategy that includeddownsizing,restructuring,and exit. Paying large
executivecashbonusesamidlayoffs ignited controversy. However,by 1993shareholders
realized gains approaching $4.5 billion, representinga dividend-reinvestedreturn of
553%.The study showshow incentivesassistin shapingstrategy,illustratesthe political
costsand economicbenefitsof downsizingand demonstrates
that evenfirmsin declining
industrieshave substantialopportunities for value creation.
Key words:Incentives;Compensation;Restructuring;Strategy; Defenseindustry
G31; G34; G35; 533
JEL classijication:
1. Introduction
In the post-Cold War era of 1991, defense contractor General Dynamics
Corporation (GD) faced declining demand in an industry saddled with current
*Corresponding author.
Data and quotes provided by GD officials are from the teaching case(Murphy and Dial, 1993) which
was approved and released by GD management; additional material in this article are from publicly
available sources. We are particularly grateful to GD officials Bill Anders, Paul Hesse, Jim Cunnane,
Ray Lewis, and Al Spivak for their time and helpful comments. George Baker, Linda DeAngelo,
Myra Hart, Michael Jensen, Scott Keating, Karen VanNuys,KarenWruck,andespecially
Harry
DeAngelo (the referee) provided useful comments. Financial support was provided by the Division
of Research at the Harvard Business School.
0304-405X/95/.$09.50 0 1995 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved
SSDI
0304405X9400803
9
262
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
qf Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
and projected excess capacity. While other contractors made defense-related
acquisitions or diversified into nondefense areas, GD adopted an objective of
creating shareholder value through downsizing, restructuring, and partial liquidation. Facilitating GD’s new strategy were a new management team and
compensation plans that closely tied executive pay to shareholder wealth
creation, including a Gain/Sharing
Plan that paid large cash rewards for
increases in the stock price. As GD’s executives reaped rewards amid announcements of layoffs and divestitures, the plans became highly controversial, fueling
a nationwide attack on executive compensation by politicians, journalists, and
shareholder activists. Nonetheless, GD managers credit the incentive plans with
helping to attract and retain key managers and for motivating the difficult
strategic decisions that were made and implemented: GD realized a dividendreinvested three-year return of 553% from 1991 to 1993-generating $4.5 billion
in shareholder wealth from a January 1991 market value of just over $1 billion.’
In the process, GD returned more than $3 billion to shareholders and
debtholders through debt retirement, stock repurchases, and special distributions.
Following William A. Anders’ appointment as Chairman and Chief Executive
Officer (CEO) on January 1,1991, GD reversed a four-year slide in market value
and subsequently outperformed other firms in the defense industry and in the
Standard & Poor’s S&P 500. Fig. 1 shows the value of an investment worth
$100 upon Anders’ appointment as CEO. As shown in the figure, GD stock
significantly underperformed the industry and the market, and shareholders had
lost 59% in the four years prior to Anders’ appointment. Following Anders’
appointment, the $100 investment in GD stock grew to $653 by December 1993,
far exceeding the returns on a $100 investment in a value-weighted defense
industry portfolio (excluding GD) and the S&P 500 which grew to $214 and
$155, respectively.
In this clinical study of compensation and strategy at General Dynamics, we
examine GD’s compensation system and document its role in determining and
achieving GD’s corporate objective. Critics of GD’s compensation system
contend that GD’s optimal strategy was obvious and that its managers should
have carried out this strategy without high-powered incentives: the reduction in
defense spending seemed an inevitable consequence of changing world events,
and GD’s CEO was already paid an annual base salary of $800,000 to fulfill his
fiduciary responsibility to shareholders. Although the strategic options available
to GD were also available to its competitors, GD was the only defense
‘The three-year return of 553% is the return on a share of stock (with reinvested dividends and
special distributions) not repurchased in the 1992 Dutch auction. The return to all shareholders over
this period (assuming that cash from the repurchase, dividends, and distributions is not reinvested
and earns zero returns thereafter) is 426%.
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
263
261-314
smo-
$%a -
other defense fm
SZld
S&P 500
1-l 994
Fig 1. Value of investment worth $100 on January 1, 1991 in General Dynamics, other defense
firms, and the S&P 500, 1987-1993.
Returns assume that dividends and proceeds from repurchases are reinvested. Other defense firms
include those listed in Table 7 (excluding General Dynamics). Weights for industry value-weighted
returns are l/1/91 market capitalizations.
contractor that responded promptly to the declining world market by taking
substantial resources out of the industry. We therefore interpret GD’s performance (measured relative to the market and industry) as reflecting in large part
GD’s incentive systems, its articulated objective of creating value for shareholders, and the vision of GD’s management.
Although some of the $4.5 billion increase in wealth for GD’s shareholders
from 1991-1993 reflected either exogenous events in the market or defense
industry or GD-specific events not under management’s control, we estimate
that between $2.3 and $3.5 billion of the increase was due to actions taken by
GD’s managers. Although it is impossible to prove that GD’s incentive system
‘caused’ these wealth-increasing actions, we present evidence that the system
provided meaningful incentives to undertake particular actions, that these
actions were taken, and that the managers themselves believe that GD’s restructuring and ultimate downsizing could not have been accomplished without the
incentives in place.
Viewing this clinical study in a broader context, GD’s situation is similar
to that confronting firms in other industries characterized by excess capacity,
such as automotive, retail trade, steel, and computers. Excess capacity in the
264
J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
defense industry is related to the Reagan-era build-up and the post-Cold War
downsizing, while in other industries excess capacity arises from changes in
technology and demand, deregulation, increases in global and nonunionized
competition, and managers’ tendency to overinvest in growth. Economic efficiency suggests that human as well as physical capital should be transferred
from industries with excess capacity to alternative sectors. Few managers,
however, have been able to accomplish the necessary resource redirection until
their organizations face crises in the product, factor, or capital markets (Jensen,
1993). Even though GD’s situation is replicated in many firms and industries, its
response and ultimate achievements are remarkable, and serve as perhaps the
preeminent management and shareholder success story of the early 1990s.
The paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 offers a conceptual framework
relating to the importance and difficulty of providing appropriate managerial
incentives in industries saddled with excess capacity. In Section 3, we describe
the compensation policies and strategic initiatives at GD under CEO Anders,
and examine the political consequences of GD’s Gain/Sharing Plan. The data
presented were obtained from public sources and from discussions with Anders
and other GD executives during 1993. Section 4 contrasts GD’s strategy and
incentives with those adopted by other major defense contractors. We show
that, although other contractors also espoused and eventually adopted consolidation and downsizing, GD’s response in moving resources out of the industry
was significantly quicker and more dramatic than its competitors. In addition,
we show that GD had substantially more stock-based incentives than the
average of other firms in the industry or in the S&P 500. Section 5 analyzes the
source of GD’s value gain, and examines several of the criticisms and concerns
relating to GD’s compensation and strategy voiced by politicians, academics,
shareholder groups, and the media. Section 6 concludes.
2. Value creation and incentives in tbe defense-industry
Excess capacity in an industry implies that increased investment in the
industry earns less than the cost of capital, and therefore destroys value for
shareholders and for society. However, excess capacity offers important opportunities to create value even in the absence of profitable investment opportunities. In particular, creating value under excess capacity involves diverting
resources from activities that earn less than the cost of capital (Stewart, 1991),
which in turn implies transferring human as well as physical capital from
industries with excess capacity to alternative sectors. Stock repurchases, dividends, special distributions, and cash acquisitions within an industry create
value under excess capacity by paying out cash to shareholders rather than
spending it unproductively
(Jensen, 1986). Similarly, workforce reductions
through layoffs and attrition create value by facilitating the transfer of workers
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
265
to sectors where their skills and effort are more highly valued by society. The
transfer of human resources, unfortunately, often imposes real costs on redeployed workers-especially
in the short run- but is nonetheless an efficient and
necessary response to excess capacity. Moreover, as we discuss below in Section 5, the fact that redeployed workers earn lower wages in alternative sectors
does not necessarily imply that implicit contracts have been breached or that
wealth has been transferred from workers to shareholders.
The end of the Cold War and the resultant decline in the demand for major
weapons platforms generated excess capacity among defense contractors. Assuming that the demand shift is permanent, the economically efficient response
is to move both human and physical capital from the defense sector to alternative higher-valued uses. Market pressures will inevitably force resources out of
the defense industry in the long run. In the shorter run, however, many defense
firms can maintain their current production with only small declines in employment and investment. Major defense contractors typically maintain large ‘backlogs’ of current orders for future deliveries: GD’s 1990 backlog, for example, was
$23 billion. Profit margins on these backlogs are sufficiently high to guarantee
large cash flows and solvency for several years. Many defense contractors also
have large nondefense-related businesses that can subsidize inefficient resource
utilization in defense businesses. Alternatively, nondiversified defense contractors can use current cash flows to diversify gradually by retraining their
workforce to produce nondefense products or by acquiring nondefense businesses.
Yet another strategy-rational
for an individual defense firm but not viable for
the industry as a whole-is to enhance the probability of surviving the impending shake-out in the global defense industry by investing and growing in the
defense area.
Traditional executive incentive packages-characterized
by high base salaries,
accounting-based bonuses, and low levels of stock ownership (Jensen and
Murphy, 1990)-do not provide effective incentives to downsize. These traditional pay practices may work well in strong growth economies where the
actions that create size and growth are closely correlated with the actions that
create value (Baker, 1992). These same practices, however, provide incentives for
continued growth even when it is not warranted by the market, and thus have
contributed to excess capacity in many industries.
There are several reasons why managers paid under traditional systems are
unlikely to adopt downsizing strategies even when these strategies produce the
highest benefits for shareholders and society:
1. Managerial compensation is typically tied to firm size and/or span of control.
Economic theory predicts that CEO compensation will increase with firm
size only to the extent that size is a proxy for the skills and abilities required
for the position (Rosen, 1982). The pay-size relation has been institutionalized, however, by widely utilized compensation surveys that use size as the
266
J. Dial,
primary,
Murphy,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
if not the only, determinant
1988).
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
of pay levels (Baker, Jensen, and
2. Managerial
compensation is typically tied to short-run accounting profits
(Healy, 1985). Downsizing often involves large restructuring charges that
reduce accounting profits in the short run.’ Encouraging voluntary attrition
through early retirement, severance programs, and retraining programs also
increases current expenses, thereby decreasing current accounting profits. In
addition, gains associated with sales of plants or divisions are often not
included in net income. Thus, managers pursuing downsizing strategies will
realize immediate reductions in their annual accounting-based bonuses.
3. Nonmonetary
compensation- including power, prestige, and community
standing- tends to be linked to firm size and survivability and not to wealth
creation. Managers involved in downsizing and layoffs will be subject to
media criticism and loss of community standing.
4. Laying off employees and leaving communities is personally painful for
managers (particularly those with long company tenures). It is relatively easy
to provide incentives for growth: Managers intrinsically enjoy opening new
plants, hiring new workers, and announcing new investment programs. In
contrast, few managers enjoy downsizing: it’s simply less fun than growing.3
In addition, affected employees and communities impose large nonpecuniary
costs on managers, which further reduces the managers’ incentives to downsize.
5. Managers often embrace survival and not value creation as the ultimate
objective of the organization (Smale, 1989). Many managers don’t understand and too easily dismiss exit as an appropriate long-term strategy for an
organization, even when this strategy creates the most value for shareholders
and society. Managers focused on corporate survival will resist exit and
pursue costly and inefficient diversification into product lines where they
have no expertise or competitive advantages.
6. Moving resources out of an industry reduces the value of managers’ industry-specific human capital, and may ultimately cost managers their own jobs.
The tendency for managers to resist downsizing and restructuring highlights
both the difficulty and importance of providing appropriate incentives in the
defense industry and other industries with excess capacity. Resistance to downZDechow, Huson, and Sloan (1994) present evidence that compensation committees may implicitly
adjust accounting-based bonuses for the negative consequences of restructuring charges.
%ee, for example, ‘The Pain of Downsizing’, Business Week, May 9, 1994.
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
261
sizing can be mitigated by explicitly adopting a corporate objective of creating
value, and by tying managers’ wealth to shareholder value creation-not
to size, employment, accounting profitability, or survival. Stockbased incentives-such as stock options, restricted stock, stock ownership, and
compensation plans tied to stock prices rather than profits-are natural ways to
reward value creation. Because the decision to downsize and transfer resources
from an industry is made at the top of the organization, stock-based compensation can be concentrated among top managers, and not diluted by pushing
incentives throughout the organization.4 Bringing in managers from outside the
firm may also be appropriate: outside managers have weaker personal relationships with employees, customers, suppliers, and communities affected by workforce reductions, and the loss of firm-specific capital associated with outside
hires is less important under downsizing and exit strategies. Spinning-off unrelated subsidiaries and avoiding new diversification can mitigate cross-subsidization tendencies. In the following sections, we show how GD followed these
prescriptions, creating nearly $4.5 billion in shareholder wealth in the process.
The hypothesis that stock-based incentives are most important in declining
industries with little potential for future growth appears counter to Smith and
Watts (1993), Gaver and Gaver (1993), and others who argue that stock-based
incentives are most important in companies with growth opportunities, based
on the premise that managerial discretion is more important in growing industries. But, managerial discretion is important in declining industries such as
defense as well as in growing ones: there can be significant opportunities to
create wealth even when there are few opportunities to create growth. Moreover,
under the hypothesis that managers will naturally pursue growth opportunities
but will resist downsizing, it is more important to provide financial incentives to
downsize than to provide incentives to grow.
shareholder
3. Compensation
and strategy
under CEO William
Anders
3. I. Company background
General Dynamics began in 1899 as the Electric Boat Company and became
a major supplier of submarines and cargo ships to the U.S. Navy during both
World Wars. Following World War II, the company adopted a strategy of
building the ‘General Motors of the weapons industry’ through acquisition,
diversification, and internal development. By 1960, the company was a major
aircraft, booster rocket, and missile manufacturer, and dominated the nuclear
4Downsizing
lower-level
or exit strategies may be unique in this respect: most strategies require ‘buy-in’ from
employees which in turn requires some form of incentive compensation
at lower ranks.
268
J. Dial, K.J. MurphyJJournal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
submarine business. The company was renamed General Dynamics Corporation to reflect the firm’s diversified defense operations.
GD continued to grow and expand during the next three decades, establishing
itself as the only defense contractor to supply major weapons systems to all three
branches of the U.S. military. GD also expanded into foreign sales. Its F-16 jet
was adopted as the preeminent lightweight fighter jet by the U.S. Air Force and
several foreign countries. GD’s Electric Boat division expanded its dominance of
the nuclear submarine business; its Convair division added the ‘Tomahawk’
sea-launched cruise missile to its arsenal of standard missile products. During
the early 198Os, GD bought Chrysler’s M-l ‘Abrams’ and M-60 tank business
and acquired Cessna, a leading manufacturer of civilian aircraft.
GD also became involved in several major fracases with the federal government. While GD steadfastly denied accusations of illegal actions (ranging from
faulty workmanship to fraudulent claims and illegal gifts), the firm was barred
by the Navy for a brief period from receiving new contracts. Unfavorable press
coverage damaged GD’s public image. Although GD remained profitable
throughout the 198Os, continuing profitability was threatened in the latter half
of the decade by changes in the government’s procurement practices, including
more dual-source supply, lower progress payments, and greater focus on price
competition and fixed-price contracts.
3.2. GD hires Anders as vice chairman
On September 27, 1989 GD announced the hiring of William A. Anders as its
next Chairman and Chief Executive Officer. The 55-year-old Anders, handpicked by CEO Stanley Pace, agreed to join GD as vice chairman on January 1,
1990 and succeed Pace as Chairman and CEO at his retirement on January 1,
1991. Anders was a former Air Force pilot and Apollo 8 astronaut who orbited
the moon on Christmas 1968. He had served as executive secretary of the
National Aeronautics and Space Council in Washington (1963-72), commissioner of the Atomic Energy Commission (1973-74), head of the Nuclear
Regulatory Commission (197576), and Ambassador to Norway (1976-77). In
1977, he joined General Electric as general manager of its nuclear energy
products division and then its aircraft equipment division. In 1984, Anders was
named senior executive vice president for operations at Textron, a Rhode
Island-based conglomerate. He headed Textron’s defense businesses as well as
several consumer products lines.
According to Anders, one of the chief concerns in his contract negotiation was
assuring his independence from GD’s largest shareholder, the Crown family.
Although the Crowns were not directly involved in selecting or recruiting
Anders to GD, they had established a reputation for influencing CEO employment decisions. Self-made millionaire Henry Crown originally gained control of
three GD board seats in 1959 as the result of the merger between GD and
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
269
Crown’s Material Service Corporation. In 1962, following GD’s disastrous foray
into manufacturing commercial airliners, Crown ousted the CEO. In 1966,
Crown lost a boardroom power struggle with his personally selected CEO, and
was forced to sell his shares and leave the board. Just three years later, Crown
and his allies quietly accumulated 18% of GD’s common stock, and Crown
effectively regained control of the corporation. Once again he replaced the
incumbent CEO.
Although Henry Crown died in late 1990, three representatives of the Crown
family remained on GD’s board of directors, including corporate Executive Vice
President Lester Crown. As of February 1991, the Crown family held over nine
million shares of GD stock-about 22% of the 41.9 million outstanding shares
(see Appendix A). Anders viewed the existence of a major shareholder as an
obstacle rather than a benefit. Anders reflected on the contract negotiations:5
I negotiated a great contract because I wanted total independence. I realized the risk involved in working for a large shareholder [the Crown family]
and I wanted to be independent from that risk. First, I wanted GD to make
me whole from what I was giving up at Textron. Then, I wanted an
agreement so that I would be able to retire on the day I walked in here.
That is the kind of independence I wanted so that I could make the changes
that were needed and I would not have to be looking over my shoulder at
the big shareholder.
To lure Anders from Textron, GD ultimately guaranteed a base salary of not
less than $550,000 in 1990, increased to not less than $600,000 in 1991. (His
actual salary for 1991 was $800,000.) His employment agreement also specified
that he would receive annual retirement payments of $250,000 to $500,000 for
life, depending on the length of his tenure with GD. Anders also received 30,940
shares of GD stock (worth $1.4 million on January 1, 1990) and 103,746 stock
options (with an exercise price of $44.94 and a l/1/90 Black-&holes
value of
$1.9 million) to offset fringe benefits and deferred compensation associated with
his departure from Textron.6
Corporations hiring CEOs from other firms often pay ‘sign-on bonuses’ to
compensate for lost benefits: For example, IBM paid Louis Gerstner $5 million
for benefits he lost at RJR Nabisco, and Kodak paid George Fisher $5 million
for benefits lost at Motorola. An interesting difference in Anders’ case is that his
5Unless otherwise sourced, quotes from Anders are from the teaching
and are based on a personal interview
conducted
in April 1993.
case (Murphy
and Dial,
1993)
6The number of restricted shares granted was based on the amount Anders would have received if he
had stayed at Textron (which in turn depended on Textron’s
performance):
Anders’ received 13,740
shares, 16,586 shares, and 4,614 shares in 1990, 1991, and 1992 respectively.
210
J. Dial,
K.J. MurphyJJoumal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
sign-on bonus was paid in GD stock options and restricted stock, rather than in
cash. This stock-based sign-on bonus also ensured that Anders’ option and
stockholdings would approximate those of his predecessor, Stanley Pace.
3.3. Company and industry outlook upon Anders’ appointment
Anders spent 1990, his first full year with GD (but before he became CEO),
undertaking a comprehensive assessment of the company’s strategy, its operations and markets, and its financial structure. Realizing that it was no longer
‘business as usual’, he quickly concluded that GD was heading towards serious
financial trouble. GD’s monthly closing stock price had fallen from a high of $79
in February 1987 to $25.25 at the end of 1990; accounting returns had also
declined over the same time period. The company absorbed a $578 million net
loss in 1990 (on $10.2 billion in sales). These losses were driven by over $1.3
billion in unusual charges, including $700 million in write-offs over its troubled
A-12 Navy attack jet program. GD announced 8,500 layoffs in 1990, and both
Moody’s and S&P downgraded the firm’s debt ratings, citing its weak financial
condition. In December 1990, the Pentagon announced that its audits revealed
GD to be in ‘weak’ financial condition with ‘ . . . a possible chance for bankruptcy?
World events in 1989 and 1990 had profound implications for the entire
U.S. defense industry. In 1989, the U.S.S.R. completed its withdrawal from
Afghanistan, allowed Poland’s first free elections, and saw Soviet-backed regimes fall in Hungary, East Germany, Czechoslovakia, Bulgaria, and Romania.
In November 1989, the Berlin Wall fell. During 1990, Germany was reunified
and the Soviet Union distintegrated. In November 1990, U.S. President George
Bush and Soviet President Mikhail Gorbachev, along with other leaders from
NATO and the Warsaw Pact, announced the official end of the half-century-old
Cold War, promising ‘a new era of democracy, peace, and unity’. Arms-control
agreements between the U.S. and the (former) Soviet Union dramatically reduced the current and projected future demand for major defense platforms. The
prospects for peace carried particularly harsh ramifications for GD: While other
major defense contractors had diversified operations outside of the defense
industry, GD received more than 80% of its revenues from the Pentagon.
Anders believed that the collapse of the Soviet Union and the end of the Cold
War signaled a watershed in defense funding that would permanently affect
GD’s market opportunities. This conclusion was reached, in part, by analyzing
patterns of U.S. defense spending during wartime and peacetime since 1900,
which suggested that Cold War defense spending levels were an aberration not
‘David J. Jefferson and Andrew Pasztor, ‘Pentagon Audits Show Contractors Owe U.S. Hundreds
of Millions in A-12 Job’, Wall Street Journal, December 19, 1990.
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
271
sustainable in ‘true’ peacetime. Anders’ prediction of future cuts was supported
by federal projections released in early 1991. While the 1991 federal budget
authorized $86 billion in procurement spending, the 1992 federal budget
(delivered to Congress in January 1991) had revised the 1991 and 1992 budget
authority for procurement downward to just $64 billion and $63 billion, respectively.8
3.4. Anders ’ early initiatives as CEO
Anders took office as Chairman and CEO on January 1, 1991, and his
explicitly stated goal was to transform GD into a shareholder-driven enterprise.
He sought to improve company financial performance by maximizing margins
from its $23 billion backlog, increase returns, and generate a sharper focus on
investments through higher margins, better progress payment rates, and higher
hurdle rates. In order to facilitate these operational changes, Anders believed he
needed to bring in a new management team, fundamentally alter the corporate
culture, and institute compensation systems for the top management team that
more closely tied pay to shareholder wealth creation.
In spite of the planned reductions in government spending and the warning
signals emanating from within GD, Anders faced a major hurdle in convincing
his board of directors and existing top managers that GD was, indeed, heading
for a crisis. He found that most of the managers at GD (and at other defense
firms as well) believed they could maintain the status quo and survive the
impending shake-out in the defense industry. Anders brought in a Wall Street
analyst to alert the top managers and directors to the severity of GD’s situation.
The analyst noted that GD’s price-earnings ratio ranked 497 in the S&P 500. In
his ensuing discussions with directors, Anders stressed the need to build a new
management team, but emphasized the difficulty of attracting, retaining, and
motivating managers in the declining defense industry.
Soon after Anders’ appointment as CEO, GD made wholesale management
changes at its upper echelons. Eighteen of the top 25 executives were either new
to GD or new to their positions. Anders promoted Executive Vice President
James Mellor (who had been in charge of submarines, tanks, and overseas sales)
to president and chief operating officer. Anders and Mellor were members of
GD’s board of directors, which included five top managers, two former
Chairman/CEOs,
and nine outside directors (see Appendix A).
sProcurement
appropriations
of the Department
of Defense finance the acquisition
of weapons,
equipment,
munitions,
spares, and modifications
of existing equipment.
Budget authorityfor
procurement includes appropriations
for the year enacted as well as spending which is earmarked
for future
years. Actual spending
(which includes
budget authority
for the year enacted in addition
to
appropriations
carried over from prior years) was estimated at $79 and $74 billion for 1991 and
1992, respectively;
actual spending was projected
to fall to $67 billion by 1994.
212
J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
Mellor was in charge of operationalizing Anders’ objective of creating wealth
for shareholders. An industry analyst lauded the Anders-Mellor team: ‘Anders
provides the cold, calculated decision-making needed at the strategic level, and
Mellor is very good at getting a lot of people rowing together in the right
direction’.’ Anders commented on Mellor’s role:
We talked a lot about focusing on shareholder value and each of our top
executives was committed to this objective. Even though that was our
focus, it was not our strategy because ‘maximize shareholder value’ is
difficult to operationalize.
Mellor really helped the managers understand how to run their businesses.
Just accepting the idea of shareholder value isn’t enough. For a lot of the
managers, it was a case of ‘OK, I believe in shareholder value, but what
should I do tomorrow?’ Mellor taught them how to manage for cash.
Anders’ new business plan called for dividing the company into business areas
and pushing decision-making
authority further down into the hierarchy. To
assist its managers in adjusting to their expanded responsibilities amid the
company’s new business approach, GD commissioned Northwestern University’s Kellogg School of Management to develop a special one-week seminar for
150 of its top managers. According to Anders, the intensive training sessions
focused on teaching business basics and investment analysis so that GD’s
managers would ‘ . . . think like business people, not like aerospace engineers’.
3.5. Executive compensation at General Dynamics
Anders sought to focus his management team on maximizing
value. He describes the company’s approach:
shareholder
When we started to build a new management team, we wanted partners, not
high salaried people. We needed to attract good people from outside and to
entice good insiders to change to different divisions. These managers came
here for about the same salaries they had been making, but they needed
additional inducements because their careers were riskier at GD. To attract
good people and then to change behavior, you have to compensate them
well.
I didn’t want to take the company private, but I wanted a private-company
mentality. I wanted to break out of the ‘hired hand’ mentality. There is an
enormous difference between being a smart hired hand and being a partner.
‘Anthony
L. Velocci,
& Space Technology,
Jr., ‘General Dynamics
August 5, 1991.
Shakeup
Aims for Solid Fiscal Footing’,
Aviation
Week
J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314
213
They brought me in as a hired hand and I changed it to a partnership
arrangement. I wanted to develop a management/shareholder
partnership
and create an environment where there was no doubt in anyone’s mind
about what we were here to do: create shareholder value.
In addition to defining the corporate objective and building a new and
better-trained management team, Anders decided it was crucial for GD’s executive compensation policies to provide meaningful and appropriate incentives for
its top-level managers. GD’s existing compensation packages included base
salaries, bonuses tied to the company’s accounting return on equity, and stock
options. Anders felt that relying on accounting-based bonuses provided inappropriate incentives for a shareholder-value-focused company requiring dramatic changes in its strategy and culture. Furthermore, the outstanding stock
options-granted
in prior years at exercise prices far exceeding the current stock
price-also failed to provide meaningful incentives.
Under Anders’ recommendation to the compensation committee, approximately 25 top executives would earn cash ‘Gain/Sharing’
bonuses for improvements in the stock price, 150 upper-level executives would receive accelerated
stock option and restricted stock grants, and 1,150 managers and executives
would be eligible to participate in an ‘option exchange’ program in which
previously granted options could be exchanged for new options at a lower
exercise price. The proposal also included changes in the company’s savings and
investment plan (SIP) to encourage lower-level employees to hold GD stock
(approximately 62,000 employees). These proposals were accepted (with minor
modifications) by the four outside directors who comprised the compensation
committee, approved by the full board of directors on February 15, 1991, and
approved by shareholders at the May 1, 1991 annual meeting.
3.5.1. Incentives, bonuses, restricted stock, and stock options
At its February 15, 1991 meeting, the committee approved approximately
1.6 million shares of stock option awards in addition to bonuses of $19 million
in cash and restricted stock for the 1,150 eligible employees. Table 1 shows the
base salaries, bonus awards, and 1991 restricted stock and stock option awards.
Each option, exercisable beginning August 1992 and expiring in February 2001,
gave the recipient the right to buy one share of common stock at an exercise
price of $25.5625 (the market price on the February 15 grant date). Shares of
restricted stock vested over time: 40% became unrestricted four years after the
grant date, and thereafter at a rate of 10% per year, contingent on continued
employment. In accordance with Anders’ proposal to accelerate option and
restricted stock grants for the company’s top 150 executive officers, option
grants were approximately
three times the normal annual award for each
individual, and the committee ‘promised’ that a similar number of restricted
shares would be awarded in 1992 and 199.3. In contrast to typical restricted
Table
1
Salaries,
bonuses,
restricted
stock,
and stock
options
awards
approved
Incentive
awards
granted
by General
in February
Restricted
1991 base
salary
Executive
William Anders
Chairman/CEO
James Mellor
President/COO
Lester Crown
Executive
VP
. .
.
.
.
.
. .
. .
.
.
Other
“Some
Shares
grantedb
Shares
promised’
Number
of stock
optio&
Total
options after
new grants
and exchange
271,359
$650,000
$300,000
15,000
30,OQO
120,000
13,613
133,613
$303,000
$200,000
5,550
13,250
48,500
11,862
60,362
.
. .
.
1991 and December
(including
.
,
$2,632,000
94,260
253,410
829,350
249,206
. ..
1,078,556
$11,371,749
.
.
93,880
. . .. .
150,450
. . ... .. .. .
134,230
288,556
1,022,786
$14,009,749
188,140
1,563,580
537,762
2,101,342
.
.
1991 proxy
$180,000
to Mr.
‘Restricted
promised
awards
New options
acquired by
exchanging
old options
stock
51,479
given at the fair market
stock
1991
219,880
bRestricted stock awards
price of $24.3125.
dOptions granted
of $24.3125.
15, 1991
44,910
$9,416,100
cash awards
on February
20,850
All participants
March
committee
S500,OOO
participants
Source:
compensation
$800,0000
.
Executive
officers
as a group’
1991 cash
bonuses”
Dynamics
.
. .
.
.
. . .
. . .
. . .
. .
.
I
.
. .
. .
403,860
statements.
Crown)
made in unrestricted
price of $25.5625.
for 1992 and 1993. These
at an exercise price of $25.5625.
‘Amounts
based on 36 executives
1991 proxy statement).
.
(from
shares of common
of executives
shares were ultimately
Some options
for 1991 base salary
Some awards
for executives
December
conveyed
stock.
other
than those listed made on March
in December
1991
other than those listed were granted
6, 1991 proxy
statement)
5, 1991, at a market
and 29 executives
on March
for incentive
5, 1991, at an exercise
awards
(from
March
price
28.
J. Dial, K.J. MurphyJJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314
275
stock awards in which the manager receives a fixed dollar value of stock each
year, GD’s fixed-share promise means that those shares start providing incentives in 1991, years before they are conveyed.
In addition to the option award program, the compensation committee also
approved an ‘option exchange’ program that allowed executives to exchange
their ‘out-of-the-money’
options (i.e., options with an exercise price above the
February 1991 market price) for a lesser number of ‘at-the-money’ options (i.e.,
options with an exercise price equal to the market price). The 1,150 executives
holding options elected to exchange approximately 1.94 million options with
average exercise prices of about $55 for about 538,000 new options with an
exercise price of $25.5625. The exchanges were prorated on the basis of the
Black-Scholes (1973) value of options already held versus the Black-&holes
value at the new lower strike prices. For example, Anders exchanged the 103,746
options granted upon his appointment at an exercise price of $44.94 (with an
aggregate Black-Scholes value of $388,000) for 51,479 options at an exercise
price of $25.5625 (with an aggregate Black-Scholes value of $388,000, based on
stock volatility of 24.25%, dividend yield of 4%, risk-free rate of 8%, and
expiration periods of nine and ten years for the old and new options, respectively).
In addition, as shown in Table 1, Anders received 219,800 ‘new’ options, giving
him a total of 271,359 options, each with an option price of $25.5625.
Although it is common for companies to reprice options following declines in
stock prices, CD’s option exchange program was unusual because it yielded
repriced options at no additional cost to shareholders. [We note that by
reducing the number of options upon exchange, GD’s exchange program was
‘acceptable’ according to the criteria outlined in Crystal and Foulkes (1988).]
Anders’ financial incentives to increase stock prices declined, however. Prior to
the exchange, each $1 increase in GD’s stock price (from $25.5625) increased the
Black-Scholes value of Anders’ 103,746 old options by $39,000, compared to an
increase of only $28,000 for his 51,479 new options. Moreover, based on the
subsequent increase in GD’s stock prices to ($142 by year-end 1993, including
special distributions) Anders’ participation in the exchange program personally
cost him more than $4 million ex post.
3.5.2. The Gain/Sharing Plan
The most unusual and ultimately controversial part of the compensation
program proposed by Anders and approved by the compensation committee at
the February 15 meeting was the Gain/Sharing Plan. In contrast to typical
bonus plans based on accounting performance, GD’s plan was based on stockprice performance, awarding cash bonuses for each $10 increase in the company’s stock price (representing a $417 million increase in shareholder value).
Under the program, GD’s top executives would receive a bonus equal to 100%
of their base salaries if GD’s stock price closed at or above $35.5625 (i.e.,
$10 above the February 15 price) and stayed at or above this level for ten
276
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
consecutive trading days. For each subsequent $10 increase sustained for ten
consecutive trading days, the executives would receive additional bonuses equal
to 200% of their base salaries.
The 25 executives- with combined base salaries of $6.3 million- who ultimately participated in Gain/Sharing would receive approximately 1.5% of the
increase in shareholder value for the first $10 increase, and 3% for subsequent
$10 increases in GD’s stock price. There was no limit on the number of bonuses
as long as the stock price continued to climb. The expiration date of the
program was February 15, 1994. Half of each award was to be deferred until
retirement; the other half would be paid in cash, although the amount could be
deferred at the recipient’s request. The deferred portion would accrue interest at
a rate of five percentage points above the prime interest rate (or Moody’s
corporate bond rate, if higher). At the committee’s discretion, the interest rate
would be reduced if the firm’s share prices fell below certain levels in the days
immediately following announcements of company earnings.
Executives participating
in the committee’s proposed Gain/Sharing
Plan
included Anders, Mellor, CFO James Cunnane, nine corporate vice presidents
responsible for functional business performance, four operating group executive
vice presidents, and several division and business-area heads. Executive Vice
President Lester Crown endorsed the plan but voluntarily elected not to
participate. Anders conceived of the Gain/Sharing Plan as a means to institute
his ‘partnership’ approach to the management of the firm. Anders, who believed
GD’s stock price could climb to at most $45 by 1994, described the initial
discussions with the board on the Gain/Sharing initiative:
Keep in mind that originally
upside. When we developed
asked to be left out of it. I felt
the plan that I had conceived.
in which I didn’t participate.
it didn’t look like there was that great an
and presented it to the Board, I originally
somewhat uncomfortable including myself in
However, the Board wouldn’t hear of a plan
Anders confided that GD honestly hadn’t much thought about the appropriateness of the ten-day window; it was recommended by compensation committee chairman Elliot Stein, who had employed a similar window in a plan at
Ralston-Purina.”
3.5.3. Savings and stock investmentplan
To encourage a partnership mentality among lower-level employees, Anders
recommended, and the compensation committee approved, charfges in the
“In the Ralston-Purina plan, the CEO received a large grant of restricted stock for achieving
a stock price of $100 for ten days. The plan was ultimately controversial, not because of the ten-day
window but rather because the $100 hurdle was met during a period in which the company was
underperforming the industry and market (Campbell and Wasley, 1994).
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (199.5) 261-314
217
company’s Savings and Stock Investment Plan (SIP), which covered approximately 62,000 employees. Prior to 1991, the company contributed 75# for each
$1 invested by the employee and allowed employees to designate how the
company’s contribution was invested. Under the new plan, GD would match
employees dollar-for-dollar
for investments in the company’s common stock
while the company’s contribution would be only 50# for every dollar placed in
any investment other than the GD common stock fund.
Prior to the introduction of the new SIP, 20,600 GD employees held 3.7 million shares of company stock. This represented 23% of GD’s employees and
8.8% of the shares outstanding. By June 1991, the number of employees
participating in the program jumped to 48,300 (54%) and the shares held by
these employees increased to 4.3 million (10.3%). By June 1992, employees held
6.2 million shares, representing almost 15% of the shares outstanding.
3.6. General Dynamics under William Anders, 1991
After Anders was named CEO on January 1, 1991, he moved swiftly to
streamline operations and improve profitability. Consistent with his belief that
increased expenditures in the defense industry were inefficient, Anders reduced
GD’s capital expenditures to $82 million in 1991 from $321 million in 1990 and
$419 million in 1989. Similarly, R&D spending was cut to half of the $390 million spent in 1990. GD also emphasized reductions in inventories and working
capital in order to reduce costs and improve returns.
A chronology of GD events from 1991 through 1993-including
three-day
industry and market-relative stock-price reactions surrounding each event-is
reported in Appendix B. As described in this Appendix, GD’s stock fell to about
$20 early in 1991 when the Navy’s A-12 jet fighter program was canceled. Soon
after, the United States and 27.other nations joined in Operation Desert Storm,
the military response to Iraq’s August 1990 invasion of Kuwait. The air war
began on January 17, and the four-day ground war ensued on February 24.
GD’s marquee products (‘Tomahawk cruise missiles, F-16 fighters, and M-l
‘Abrams’ tanks) performed spectacularly, but Anders discounted the long-term
effect on firm profitability, arguing that the war’s cost would ultimately reduce
development budgets for new weapons.’ ’
In early February 1991, the federal government allowed GD and McDonnell
Douglas to delay repayment of $1.4 billion in unliquidated progress payments
made on the canceled A-12. The companies claimed that repayment would cause
extreme financial pressures. Later that month, following the February 15 board
meeting approving the new compensation programs, Anders bought 10,000 GD
“William Saporito, ‘America’s Arsenal: This War Doesn’t Mean a Windfall: General Dynamics’,
Fortune, February 25, 1991.
278
J. Dial,
so
)
Jan
I
Feb
K.J. Murphy/Journal
I
Mar
,
*er
of Financial
1
May
I
Jlul
Economics
I
Jul
I
*w
3 7 (I 995) 261-3
1
Sep
I
Ott
I4
I
Nov
I
Dee
Fig. 2. Stock-price performance of General Dynamics, 1991.
Daily stock prices from Dow Jones News Retrieval and Compustat. GD-related events from
company press releases, analyst reports, and the Wall StreetJournal. Industry and S&P 500 prices
are determined by appreciating GD’s January 1, 1991 price by the cumulative returns on the
industry and S&P 500 portfolios.
shares at $25.25, and Mellor bought 5,000 shares at $25.00 (these purchases are
included in Appendix A).i2
As shown in Fig. 2 and Appendix B, GD’s stock jumped over 20% (from
$23.75 to over $29, representing an industry-adjusted gain of $218 million) in the
space of a few days in mid-March 1991 on the strength of ‘buy’ recommendations from three Wall Street investment banks. The analysts noted Anders
willingness to take ‘dramatic actions’ and recommended the stock on the basis
of three key points: GD’s new incentive plans throughout the ranks (especially
those that gave managers incentives to focus on shareholder value), reductions
in capital and R&D spending, and the possibility of stock repurchases to return
cash to shareholders. Within days, GD announced that it would lay off 2,000
employees at its Fort Worth, Texas F-16 jet fighter plant. In late March, South
Korea ‘stunned observers’ when it awarded GD a $5.2 billion order of 120 F-16
‘*Alexandra
1991.
Peers, ‘Some Insiders, Bucking Trend, Buy Stock’, Wall
Street
Journal,
April 10,
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 11995) 261-314
219
jet fighters, reversing a prior award to McDonnell Douglas for their F-18 fighter
and pushing GD’s stock price up 7%.13
On April 23, the federal government selected the team led by Lockheed, which
included GD and Boeing, to build the Air Force’s next generation advanced
tactical fighter (ATF). The program was expected to generate $60 billion in
revenues for the companies. Following the announcement, GD’s stock closed up
6.4% to $36.875, surpassing the Gain/Sharing hurdle of $35.5625.
3.61.
The first Gain/Sharing payofs
On May 1, a majority of shareholders (78%) voted their approval of the new
Executive Compensation Program, which included the Gain/Sharing
provisions. The same day, GD’s President Mellor made an announcement widely
interpreted as predicting massive layoffs at the defense giant: ‘Our current
workforce is just over 90,000 employees. In response to the decline in the defense
market, present projections indicate that this may be reduced by about 30%
over the next four years.’ GD’s stock price closed at $39, up over 3%. Just five
days later, on May 6, GD’s stock closed above $35.56 for the tenth consecutive
trading day, triggering $5.1 million in Gain/Sharing bonuses for 19 executives.
The next day, Anders bought another 5,000 shares at $39.50.
The announcement of the bonuses within a week of shareholder ratification
drew howls of protest. Business Week dubbed the company ‘Generous Dynamics’, and quoted a Pentagon official warning Anders not to bill the ‘outrageous’
compensation to government contracts. The media was particularly harsh to
former outside director and compensation committee member Harvey Kapnick,
who qualified for inclusion in the bonus plan when he was named vice chairman
in April 1991.14 His cash bonus was prorated for the difference between GD’s
$33.50 average share price on the day he began work (April 15) and the closing
price on May 6; thus, Kapnick received a Gain/Sharing bonus equal to 20.625%
of his $600,000 salary, or $123,750.
3.6.2. The second Gain/Sharing payof
In spite of the negative publicity, the stock market continued to be enamored
with the changes occurring at GD. As shown in Fig. 2, the share price leveled out
in late summer at $44 as GD won a $750 million contract to build 641 M-l
tanks. GD continued to announce layoffs, 1,500 more in 1992 in addition to the
2,500 already slated for 1991.
On September 22, with the stock price hovering in the low $4Os, GD announced the sale of its Data Systems unit to Computer Sciences for $184 million.
13Rick Wartzman
and Damon
Darlin,
Journal, March 29, 1991, p. A3.
14James E. Ellis, ‘More
‘South
Cash than a Lottery’,
Korea,
Business
in a Reversal,
Week,
May
Picks
F-16
Jet’, Wall
20, 1991, p. 42.
Street
280
J. Dial,
K.J. MurphyJJournal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
Two days later, Anders addressed Morgan Stanley’s Aerospace/Defense and
Multi-Industry
Conference and made two startling announcements. First, he
dismissed diversification as a viable strategy for GD, citing a McKinsey study
that claimed an 80% failure rate for nondefense acquisitions by defense contractors. Second, he predicted that cash flows would be in excess of that required
to fund the firm’s current liquidity and investment needs. He suggested returning
‘excess’ cash to shareholders using unspecified methods that might include stock
buybacks, increased dividends, special distributions, or self tenders. These announcements- which the Washington Post, citing Anders’ potential bonus,
dubbed ‘the $1.6 million speech’-caused the stock price to jump $7.75 over two
days (reflecting an industry-adjusted increase in shareholder wealth of $343 million), rocketing past the Gain/Sharing bonus target and closing at $49.50. Ten
trading days later, October 8, GD announced a second Gain/Sharing payout of
$12.6 million (200% of the top managers’ base salaries), bringing the total
payout to the 25 participants in the plan to almost $18 million (or about 2.1% of
the $833 million increase in GD’s market value).
Both Gain/Sharing payoffs generated widespread criticism among politicians,
labor unions, GD employees, and shareholder groups. For the most part,
shareholder groups voiced concerns about the mechanics of the plan, questioning in particular the appropriateness of the ten-day window. Criticism from
other sectors focused on the political ‘incorrectness’ of paying large cash
bonuses amid announcements of layoffs and downsizing.
3.63. Reaction to Gain/Sharing’s ten-day window
Gain/Sharing’s
ten-day window prompted criticism that managers would
make announcements or take actions that increase short-term, but not longterm, stock prices. For example, Howard Sherman, vice president of Institutional Shareholder Services, argued that ‘ . . . a ten-day plateau is nowhere near
a good measure of long-term success’.l5 Institutional proxy advisor Anne Faulk
agreed, calling the plan ‘ . . . a bastardization of a good idea. Ten days just isn’t
a very long time, and you won’t see management’s salaries going down when the
share price falls’.’ 6
Although managers may be able to manipulate prices in the very short term
by deliberately misleading analysts and investors, there is no evidence that
Anders ever attempted to mislead investors: indeed, the ‘$1.6 million speech’
that triggered the second bonus was presented to industry stock-market analysts
who were keenly aware of the possibility of being misled. It is worth noting that,
relative to conventional bonus plans based on accounting returns, it is easier to
“Robert J. McCartney, ‘A Most Unusual Executive Bonus Plan’, Washington Post, October 21,
1991, p. Al.
16James E. Ellis, ‘More Cash than a Lottery’, Business Week, May 20, 1991, p. 42.
.I Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 3 7 (I 995) 261-314
281
manipulate annual earnings for several consecutive years than it is to manipulate stock prices for two business weeks. It is also worth noting that in conventional stock appreciation rights plans, which pay in cash the difference between
the current stock price and a given exercise price, it is sufficient to increase stock
prices for a single day or a single moment. Thus, the ten-day window, while
admittedly short, arguably provides better long-term incentives than conventional bonus and stock appreciation right plans. Still, a longer window would
have provided the same financial payments to GD executives, while generating
substantially less criticism among the media and shareholder groups.
3.6.4. Reaction to paying Gain/Sharing bonusesamid layoffs
GD’s unionized work force was openly critical of the Gain/Sharing bonuses.
A UAW: official said: ‘They’re really slopping at the trough’.”
Employees
expressed their feelings in the Mole, an underground newsletter circulated at
GD’s jet plant in Fort Worth, commenting: ‘Anders promises ‘gut wrenching
cultural change’ throughout the corporation. It isn’t clear whose gut he proposes to wrench, but it won’t be the brave 25 that have had the courage to
fearlessly look out for themselves’.18
Many were outraged that the bonuses were being paid while thousands of the
rank and file were being laid off. Others protested that the bonuses were much
too concentrated among a tiny cadre of senior executives. Dean Girardot, GD’s
coordinator for the International
Association of Machinists, asked: ‘Why is
there just Gain/Sharing for the 255most of them relative newcomers- while
people who have worked in the trenches for many years are losing their
jobs?“’
One outspoken critic of GD’s compensation policies was former compensation consultant Graef Crystal, who claimed that ‘ . . . this ill-conceived plan
smacks of the Marie Antoinette school of management’, a reference to the
extravagant French monarch who showed callous disregard for the poor people
in her country. *O Crystal justified his attack:
First of all, the stock rose from a ‘trough’, . . . and all these bonuses came
while General Dynamics was ‘downsizing’. . . . It’s a scenario that hits you
in the gut. This is not a case where somebody’s making a lot of money
r7Robert
October
“Rick
J. McCartney,
9, 1991, p. Fl.
Wartzman,
‘Defense
‘General
Wall Street Journal, October
“Robert
October
J. McCartney,
9, 1991.
“James E. Ellis, ‘Layoffs
1991, p. 34.
Firm’s
Executives
Dynamics
Head Outlines
31, 1991, p. A3.
‘Defense
Firm’s
Executives
on the Line, Bonuses
Reap
Bonus
Plan to Cope
Reap
in the Executive
Bonanza’,
with Falling
Bonus
Suite’,
Bonanza’,
Washington Post,
Defense
Budgets’,
Washington Post,
Business Week, October
21,
282
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
ofFinancial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
because the company’s doing great. This is a case of a guy getting lots of
money, and he’s an island of prosperity in a sea of misery.. . 21
. . . The CEO of General Dynamics must be the laziest man in the world.
Look at all the incentive plans they have to give him to go to work in the
morning.22
The outrage over GD’s Gain/Sharing bonuses illustrates the important distinction between the politics and the economics of executive compensation.
Providing incentives to create value under excess capacity virtually mandates
paying bonuses during layoffs. In addition, concentrating incentive rewards at
the top management level can be economically justified in GD’s situation, since
the decision to downsize is made and implemented exclusively by top management and can be accomplished without ‘buy-in’ and meaningful incentives for
rank-and-file employees. But the criticisms of Gain/Sharing were largely political rather than economic: CD’s management was accused of being ‘insensitive to
outside perceptions’23 by not suffering along with its workers.
Some critics noted that the high payments to GD executives negatively
affected employee morale. GD employees demonstrated at GD’s San Diego
plant, for example, carrying placards that read: ‘No Bogus Bonus for Bill’. We
speculate that declining morale among the rank-and-file employees had more to
do with bleak long-term employment prospects in the defense industry than
with Anders’ pay: Employee morale in growing firms (such as Disney) does not
appear to be affected by high top-management
pay, and we suspect morale
would have suffered at GD even if Anders worked for free.
As an interesting contrast to the GD situation, DeAngelo and DeAngelo
(1991) find that labor concessions in the steel industry were routinely coupled
with cuts in top management’s cash compensation: management pay is significantly lower during years with union negotiations than in years without negotiations. The authors argue that the managerial pay cuts are implemented as
‘ . . . symbolic sacrifices that encourage all stakeholders to participate in the
concessions needed to salvage the firm’. An important difference between the
domestic steel industry in the 1980s and the defense industry in the 1991 is that
the steel industry was already in a crisis (generated in part by ignoring the
implications of nonunionized global competition developing over the course of
the previous several decades) while GD was responding to early warning signs of
a potential crisis in the future. Critics who argued that GD’s management
21Peter Carlson, ‘Chairmen of the Bucks’, Washington Post Magazine, April 5, 1992, p. 15.
22Alison Leigh Cowan, ‘The Gadfly CEOs Want to Swat’, New York Times, February 2, 1992.
23Richard Ullman of Institutional Shareholder Services, quoted in Aviation Week & Space Technology, November 18, 1991, p. 58.
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
283
should have suffered along with its workers beg the question (we return to this in
Section 5): Could GD’s ultimate performance have been obtained without the
high-powered incentives that generated large bonuses amid layoffs?
3.6.5. The compensation committee’s response
Even as the firm’s stock price continued to climb, GD’s board of directors was
bombarded by criticism. The compensation committee (which met 15 times in
1991, compared to only six times during 1990) was keenly aware of the negative
reaction to the company’s compensation policies. Moreover, given Anders’
public intention to ‘return excess cash’ to shareholders, the committee was
concerned that future announcements of special distributions might cause stock
prices to jump past another Gain/Sharing hurdle, further fueling the media
criticism.
The compensation committee settled on a revised plan at a meeting on
December 3, at which point the stock price was $49. Shareholders approved the
plan at a special meeting on January 15, 1992. Under the new plan, executives
received final Gain/Sharing bonuses for the increase in share value between the
second bonus payout in October and $49 (the stock price on December 3). As
shown in Table 2, the 25 participating executives received final bonuses of $4.5
million, bringing the total payments under the plan to $22.3 million. In addition,
the executives received stock options with exercise prices of $49 in lieu of the
Gain/Sharing Plan. The numbers of options were chosen to provide a gain upon
exercise equivalent to the bonus each participant would have received had the
Gain/Sharing Plan remained in effect. For example, Anders received 160,000
options. A $10 increase in stock price would thus equate to a $1.6 million
increase in the exercise value of the option, twice Anders’ annual salary. Finally,
the executives received the restricted stock awards promised in February, but
not scheduled to be conveyed until 1992 and 1993 (see Table 1).
During the period in which the Gain/Sharing Plan was in effect (February 15
to December 3), GD’s stock price rose from $25.5625 to $49 per share, a wealth
gain of $1,022 million for shareholders. Based on the methodology described in
Table 9, about $99 million of this gain reflects general market stock-price
movements, $35 million reflects industry-specific movements, and - $15 million
reflects world events and announcements related to GD that cannot be directly
attributed to GD’s new strategy and incentives.24 Approximately $614 million
of the increase can be directly traced to announcements related to GD’s strategic
initiatives, and much of the ‘unexplained’ $289 million is plausibly linked indirectly with GD’s initiatives. The total Gain/Sharing payouts of $22.3 million
to GD’s executives amounts to 2.18% of the total shareholder gain, and between
2.5% and 3.6% of the gain attributable to the action’s of GD’s management.
24Table 9 provides estimates for the entire 1991 calendar year, while the data in this paragraph refer
only to the period from February 15 to December 3, 1991.
Table 2
Gain/Sharing awards for General Dynamics top executives
Executive
May award
William A. Anders
Chairman
Dec. award
Total
Gain/Sharing
Options
at $49.00
$800,000
$1600,000
rS550,000a
S2,950,000
160,000
$650,000
%1,300,000
$446,875
%2,396,875
130,000
$123,750
%1,200,000
$412,500
$1,736,250
120,000
$0
SO
$0
$0
0
and CEO
James R. Mellor
President
Oct. award
and COO
Harvey Kapnick
Vice Chairman
Lester Crownb
Executive
VP
... ... .... ... ... .. .... ... ... .... ... ... ... ... .... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... .... ... .. ... ... ... ... ... .. ... ... ... ... ... ..................................
.... ..... ....................................................................................................................................
Number of executives
19
25
25
5
25
included
.. . ...................................................................................................................................
...............
...........................I..................................................................................................
Executive officers
$5,168,750
$4,513,438
$22,334,876
1,313,000
$12,652,688
as a group
Source: GD Special Meeting Proxy Statement, December 6, 1991.
“Since the increase at this time to $49 represented 34.375% of the $10 interval between $45.5625 and $55.5625, Anders’ received a final Gain/Sharing bonus
of $550,000 (or 34.375% of twice his $800,000 base sakrry).
bMr. Crown elected not to participate in the Gain/Sharing Plan,
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
285
The vehement public reaction to GD’s Gain/Sharing bonuses, coupled with
the boards response to replace Gain/Sharing with conventional stock options,
are evidence of the importance of political forces in shaping compensation
policies (Jensen and Murphy, 1990). The GD experience is also consistent with
the hypothesis that gains from options are politically more acceptable than
gains paid in cash. In particular, criticism regarding GD’s compensation policies
largely evaporated after GD replaced Gain/Sharing with conventional stock
options, even though the payouts under the two plans were virtually identical
(apart from the discontinuities imbedded in Gain/Sharing). Moreover, while
Anders was heavily criticized for his Gain/Sharing
bonuses of $2.95
million (accounting for approximately 0.3% of the total gain to shareholders),
the $8.6 million appreciation of his restricted stock and options over the same
time period escaped media attention. Similarly, the media focused on the $22.3
million Gain/Sharing payments to GD’s top management team, but ignored the
$37 million appreciation the team realized on their options and restricted stock
over the same ten months.25 The gains that top managers and the Crown family
earned on their individual stockholdings also eluded notice, even though these
gains were large relative to the Gain/Sharing payouts and were also associated
with layoffs and downsizing.
3.7. Anders articulates and implements GD ‘s strategy
Although Anders had embraced the corporate objective of creating shareholder value upon his January 1991 appointment, the corporate strategy he
developed to achieve this objective evolved during 1991 and 1992. An early
indicator of the strategy- his pledge to not pursue diversification into nondefense businesses-was revealed at the September 1991 Morgan Stanley
conference. Three weeks later, on October 16, GD announced that its largest
nondefense subsidiary, Cessna Aircraft, was for sale. Later that month, in GD’s
third-quarter report to shareholders, Anders announced that GD was studying
all of its nondefense operations to determine if they should be separated from the
company.
By the end of 1991, Anders was publicly urging the industry to both downsize
and consolidate its businesses in order to ‘rationalize excess capacity’. He argued
that only the top one or two contractors in a particular segment could survive
the coming shake-out in defense. Anders stressed that no one should invest and
grow in the defense industry (with the exception of a few market niches); only the
strongest competitors should maintain investments; and that most should be
ZSCalculations based on options and current and promised restricted stock in Table 1 plus restricted
stock held prior to February 1991, including 30,326 shares for Anders and 110,620 shares for all
other top executives.
286
J. Dial,
K.J. MurphyJJournal
of Financial
Economics
37 (199s)
261.-314
managing for cash and taking money out of the defense segment. Some should
simply exit the industry.26
In May 1992, Anders announced GD’s strategy within its defense businesses.
Anders said GD would remain in businesses only where it could be # 1 or # 2 in
the market, and only if it could achieve ‘critical mass’ with production large
enough to justify dedicated factories. Anders announced that GD was prepared
to buy businesses from, or sell businesses to, other parties in order to meet these
‘market leadership’ and ‘critical mass’ criteria. He identified four businesses
within GD’s core defense capabilities that passed these two screens-military
aircraft, nuclear submarines, land systems (tanks), and space systems-and
announced a formal ‘plan of contraction’ in which the company would seek to
sell units outside these four core defense businesses.
Anders discussed the rationale for this strategy and the reasoning behind the
definition of the core segments:
When we assessed our businesses, we didn’t look at them in terms of core
businesses, we looked at our core competencies.Our core competence is in
heavy-weight defense platforms.
We also looked at efficiencies. The first test was whether we were or could
be # 1 or # 2 in a market. The second test was whether each of these
businesses could pass the criticaZ mass test. Could we justify dedicated
factories for these products based on the scale we could achieve? The tank
plant makes sense, subs make it, and tactical aircraft make it. Missiles did
not make it. They are not our core competence; they are a commodity
business where supply far exceeds demand.
The difference between GD and the rest of the defense industry is that we
wanted to sell nondefense businesses. And we were willing to fix any
business by buying, selling, or merging. We were dedicated to shareholders
and building franchises. Too many executives at other defense contractors
are fixated on bigger is better. But, when the industry has excess capacity,
the focus on continued growth just doesn’t work.
3.7.1. Salesof divisions and subsidiaries
Table 3 summarizes GD’s sales of divisions between November 1991 and
December 1993. GD sold the Data Systems Unit to Computer Sciences Corp.
for $184 million, the Cessna Aircraft subsidiary to Textron for $600 million, its
missile business to GM’s Hughes Electronics subsidiary for $450 million, its
Electronics Division to Carlyle Group for $52 million, and the lime and brick
operations of its Material Services businesses for $46 million.
*‘See, for example, William A. Anders, ‘Rationalizing America’s Defense Industry’, keynote address
at the 12th annual Defense Week conference, October 30, 1991.
J. Dial,
Table 3
General Dynamics
K.J. Murphy/Journal
divisions
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
Division
Buyer
1 l/91
2192
8192
11192
3193
12/93
12193
Data Systems
Cessna
Missiles
Electronics
Military
Aircraft
Material
Services’
Space Systems
csc
Sale price
($ millions)
0
Martin
“Total
bFigure
‘Lime
1991 revenues
($ millions)
$12b
797
1,385
218
2,719
nia
363
$184
600
450
52
1,525
46
209
Textron
Hughes Aircraft
Carlyle Group
Lockheed
Marietta
Total
$3,066
GD
annual
1991 GD
287
sold in 1991-1993
Disposition
date
Source:
261-314
$5,494
reports.
revenues
were $9.548
million.
is for 1990.
and brick
operations
only.
1991 revenues
and buyer’s
identity
not available.
To achieve the ‘critical mass’ goal in GD’s core businesses, Anders began
discussions with Lockheed to acquire its tactical military aircraft business to
pair with GD’s Fort Worth Division. Lockheed rebuffed GD’s overtures but
agreed that consolidation was necessary, and in December 1992 offered to
acquire GD’s jet business for $1.525 million. The divestiture of one of the
company’s ‘core businesses’ prompted speculation that GD was on a liquidation
path. 27 In December 1993, GD agreed to sell another of its core businessesSpace Systems- to Martin Marietta for $209 million. Anders stressed that
although human and physical assets would ultimately have to leave the industry, GD’s assets were in general being consolidated into other companiesz8
After the dispositions, GD is a much smaller and more-focused company with
two core divisions (submarines, tanks). In 1993, GD reported sales from continuing operations of $3.2 billion, a 66% decline from its $9.5 billion sales two
years earlier.
3.7.2. Employment
Along with the sale of business units, GD continued to reduce its work force
in its remaining units. As shown in Table 4, total employment at year-end 1993
“Jeff
Cole, ‘Lockheed
December
10, 1992.
*‘Jeff Cole,
Wall Street
‘Swords
Journal,
to Buy
General
into Shares: General
November
3, 1992.
Dynamics
Fighter
Plane
Dynamics
Contemplates
Unit’,
Selling
Wall
Street
Journal,
Its Remaining
Units’,
288
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
Table 4
General Dynamics work force reductions by business segment, 1991-1993
Business segment
Core defense
Military aircraft
Nuclear submarines
Tanks
Space systems”
Total core defense
Noncore defense
Nondefenseb
Corporate staff
. . ..
Total
1990
employment
28,400
22,500
7,200
5,200
.
63,000
14,300
19,900
650
.
.
98,150
Employment
reductions
through layoffs
and attrition
Units sold:
Employment
at disposition
Units retained:
1993
employment
7,200
5,500
2,200
1,500
21,200
16,400
3,000
7,400
450
.
.
27,250
24,900
11,300
7,900
0
17,000
5,ooo
0
.
22,000
0
4,600
200
3,700
.
.
44,100
26,800
Annual reports and company estimates.
“Employees in the space-systemsdivision are restated as leaving in 1993, although the sale to Martin
Marietta was not completed until April 1994.
‘Classified as discontinued operations.
Source:
stood at 26,800, a 73% reduction from the 98,150 employees at GD when
Anders was appointed in 1991. The exhibit shows that 28% of GD’s 1990
workforce left through attrition or were laid off (most occurring in 1991), while
45% were active employees when their business units were sold (mostly in 1992
and 1993). The company has not estimated the number of employees laid off
subsequent to these sales. The corporate headquarters staff fell from 650 to about
200. In order to reduce the overhead burden on the remaining businesses, the
company announced plans to cut the corporate staff to just 50 by the end of 1994.
The company offered basic outplacement services for its discharged employees, including counseling, help with resumes, and compiling and posting job
opportunities. Most of GD’s discharged employees received three to six months
salary upon dismissal (pursuant to labor agreements), and some corporate staff
employees who had been recently relocated received additional compensation.
Apart from offering limited computer tutoring at some locations, GD offered no
formal training programs for its discharged employees.
3.7.3. Shareholders and shareholders ’ distributions
As shown in Table 5, GD’s cash balance (before distributions) grew from
$100 million in January 1991 to over $4 billion by the end of 1993. GD used its
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
289
261-314
Table 5
Simplified statement of sources and uses of cash for General Dynamics, 1991-1993
Sources of cash
$ billions
Uses of cash
Cash balance (l/91)
From operations
From dispositions
Transactions costs and taxes
.
.
. . ..... ..... .. . .
Total
$0.1
1.6
3.0
(0.7)
..
Debt retired
Dividends
Share repurchase (6/92)
Special distributions
. .
. .
.
$4.0
Subtotal
Cash balance ( 12/93)
% billions
$0.6
0.2
1.0
1.6
.. . . ... .
.
$3.4
$0.6
cash balance to:
l
l
l
l
retire approximately 94% ($575 million) of the company’s debt, bringing GD’s
total debt to just $38 million by December 1993;
increase annual dividends from $1 per share to $1.60 in March 1992 and to
$2.40 in October 1993; in March 1994, GD increased its annual dividend to
$2.80 (prior to a 2: 1 stock split);
repurchase over 13.2 million shares for $960 million (at an average of $72.75
per share) through a Dutch auction in June 1992;
return $50 per share to shareholders in 1993 through special distributions in
March ($20/share), June ($18/share), and October ($12/share).
By December 1993 the company had returned $3.4 billion to shareholders and
debtholders, and had a remaining cash balance of nearly $600 million (approximately six times its cash balance in January 1, 1991).
The composition of CD’s shareholders changed substantially in the summer
of 1992. During the course of the Dutch auction in June, the Crown family
tendered almost 4.9 million shares, reducing their stake in GD from 22% to
14.3%. Employees who held shares through GD’s SIP reduced their aggregate
holdings from 14.7% to about 10% during the June auction. On July 24,
investor Warren Buffett of Berkshire Hathaway announced the purchase of
4.35 million shares for about $73/share. He amassed a 15% stake in GD,
thus surpassing the Crown family as GD’s largest shareholder. In a show
of confidence in GD’s management, he gave the company his proxy to vote
his shares ‘ . . . as long as Mr. Anders remains as chief executive officer of General
Dynamics’.29
29’Business Brief: Warren Buffett Gives General Dynamics a Proxy to Vote Berkshire’s 15% stake’,
Wall Street Journal, September 18, 1992. In May 1993, Buffet revised his grant of proxy to last ‘as
long as Mr. Anders remains as chairman of General Dynamics’.
J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal
290
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
$60
$50
Jan Feb Mu Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Ott NW Dee J~tF&b
1992
Mar
Fig. 3. Stock-price performance of General Dynamics, 1992-1993.
Daily stock prices from Dow Jones News Retrieval and Compustat. GD-related events from
company press releases, analyst reports, and the Wall Street Journal. Industry and S&P 500 prices
are determined by appreciating GD’s January 1, 1992 price by the cumulative returns on the
industry and S&P 500 portfolios.
As shown in Fig. 3, GD’s stock price rose from $55 to over $92 between
January 1992 and December 1993-even after %3.25/share in dividends and
$50/share in special distributions. The market capitalization of GD grew from
$1.05 billion in January 1991 to $2.87 billion in December 1993, during which
time shareholders received $154 million in dividends, $1.55 billion in special
distributions, and $960 million through the Dutch auction. Thus, ignoring
reinvestment of the proceeds from dividends and other distributions, shareholders gained almost $4.5 billion from 1991 through 1993, representing
a three-year return of 426%. Individual shareholders not participating in the
repurchase and reinvesting dividends in GD stock realized a return of 553%.
The remarkable success of GD’s strategy silenced many critics. For example,
in October 1992, Prudential Bathe fired aerospace analyst (and GD critic) Paul
Nisbet, citing poor stock-picking performance. In early 1991, Nisbet urged
investors to sell their GD stock (priced at about $30), arguing that the stock was
overvalued. After providing 22 ‘sell’ recommendations, N&bet went to a ‘hold
recommendation in July 1992, after the price soared past $70 and Warren Buffet
bought his 15% stake. 3o That same month, pay-critic Graef Crystal admitted in
3oJetTCole, ‘Prudential’s
November 5, 1992.
Nisbet, Aerospace Analyst, Says He Was Fired’, Wall Street Journal,
J. Dial,
Table 6
Distribution
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
291
261-314
of value gain at General Dynamics, 1991-1993 ($ millions)
Gain/
Sharing
CEO Williams Anders
25 top executives (excl. Anders)
1,300 lower-level executives
48,000 SIP participants”
Subtotal for GD employees
$3
19
0
. .... ..
$22
Crown family
Warren Buffett
Other shareholders
Stocki’
Option?
$15
40
64
450
. . .
$315
143
283
2,932
Total
$22
$4,521
$315
Percent of
total gain
$54
258
144
450
1.1%
5.3%
3.0%
9.3%
$906
18.7%
143
283
2,932
.
$4,864d
15.3%
5.8%
60.2%
$36
199
80
.
$569
Total
.
.
100.0%
“GD Stock Investment Plan (SIP). Includes participation of managers and executives.
‘Stock for GD employees includes appreciation on restricted stock, on shares retained after
exercising options, and on shares purchased through the SIP, but excludes appreciation on stock
purchased by employees in private transactions.
‘Options include amounts realized from exercising options plus the December 1993 exercisable
value of unexercised options. Exercise data are available only for the top five executives. In
December 1992, these five executives exercised all options granted in February 1991 at $103.5625,
and retained 57% of the shares. In estimating gains to other employees, we assume that all February
1991 options were exercised in December 1991, and that 57% of all exercised options were retained.
dIncludes the $4,486 million gain to shareholders (including SIP participants) plus $22 million
Gain/Sharing payments, $315 million payouts from options, and $41 in special distributions paid on
restricted stock.
his monthly newsletter, ‘ . . . if we had spent less time criticizing [Anders’] pay
package and more time increasing our investment in GD [shares], we would
have been a lot better off financially’.31
Table 6 shows how the value gain was distributed among executives, employees, and shareholders. Anders received $54 million through Gain/Sharing
and appreciation on his restricted stock and options, representing about 1.1% of
the total gain to shareholders. The other members of Anders’ top management
team realized $258 million (approximately $11 million each, or 5.3% of the total
gain), while 1,300 lower-level executives received $144 million (approximately
$111,000 each). Employee participants in the SIP realized more than $450
million (approximately $10,000 per participant) over the 1991-1993 period, or
3’The
Crystal
Report
on Executive
Compensation,
Vol. 4, No. 8, October 1992.
292
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
about 10% of the total gain. The Crown family-despite selling a large part of their
GD stake-gained $743 million from their GD investment from 1991 to 1993, while
Buffet’s stake-held for just 17 months-increased
in value by $283 million.
3.8. Anders resigns as CEO
In March 1993, in addition to announcing its first special distribution,
GD announced the resignation of three of its top executives-Chairman
and
CEO William A. Anders, Vice Chairman Harvey Kapnick, and Executive Vice
President Lester Crown. ‘We have basically done the major part of the turnaround job for which this team was assembled’, explained Anders.32 The three
executives would remain on GD’s Board of Directors, and Anders would
continue to serve as a nonemployee chairman of the board. James Mellor was
named to succeed Anders as CEO. In March 1994, Anders resigned from the
board, and Mellor assumed the additional role of chairman.
4. Strategies, incentives, and performance of other defense contractors
Having analyzed in detail GD’s strategy, incentives, and performance, we now
briefly summarize the experience of other defense contractors subsequent to the
end of the Cold War. This industry analysis is relevant to our study of GD for
several reasons: First, supporting the hypothesis that GD’s actions were driven,
in part, by its new management team and incentives, we establish that GD led,
rather than followed, the industry in responding to anticipated cuts in defense
expenditures. Second, we offer circumstantial evidence that Anders set the
strategic objective for the industry: By 1993, most defense firms were adopting
the strategy Anders outlined in industry speeches in late 1991 (see Section 3.7
above). Third, we show that Anders had significantly more stock-based financial
incentives than the average firm in the industry or the S&P 500. Finally, we
show that the industry’s ultimate consolidation, which was facilitated by GD,
moved resources out of the industry and generated substantial shareholder
wealth. The industry return from 1991-1993 (even excluding GD) more than
doubled the return on the S&P 500, illustrating that opportunities to create
wealth exist even in declining industries with few growth opportunities.
4.1. Strategic alternatives and choices of other contractors
Table 7 summarizes the strategies selected by GD and eight other defense
contractors from 1990 through 1993, based on an analysis of quantitative
32JeffCole, ‘Three Officers to Quit General Dynamics Corp.: End of Turnaround
a Cash Payout, Cuts at Headquarters’, Wall Street Journal, March 19, 1993.
Plan Brings
J. Dial,
K.J. MurphyJJournal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
293
financial data as well as our qualitative interpretation of annual reports, press
releases, and news articles. The table includes nine of the eleven largest domestic
defense contractors (ranked by cumulative 1989-1992 defense contracts) - missing are General Electric and Boeing because their defense operations account
for less than 10% of total firm revenues. Some of the strategic options adopted
by these firms include: Acquisitions to achieve critical mass; diversification into
nondefense areas or converting defense operations to commercial products and
services; globalization, i.e., finding international markets for defense operations;
downsizing and consolidation; and exit (Lundquist, 1992; Minnich, 1993).
to achieve critical mass. Five of the eight defense contractors in
Table 7 adopted Anders’ critical mass criteria, and sought to achieve critical
mass in production through acquisitions. GM Hughes acquired GD’s missile
division for $450 million in 1992, and Lockheed acquired GD’s aircraft division
for $1.5 billion in 1993. Martin Marietta acquired GE Aerospace for $3 billion
in 1992 and GD’s Space Systems for $209 million in 1994. Northrop purchased
LTV’s aircraft division for $225 million in 1992, and won a bidding war with
Martin Marietta to acquire Grumman for $2.17 billion in 1994. Although not
included in Table 7, Loral acquired Ford Aerospace for $715 million in 1990,
LTV’s missile business for $240 million in 1992, and IBM’s Federal Systems
division for $1.5 billion in 1994. Also in 1994, Lockheed and Martin Marietta
agreed to a merger via a stock swap that created the U.S.’ largest defense
contractor and led to further consolidation in the industry. By merging, acquiring,
and consolidating businesses, these defense contractors have lowered overhead
costs and avoided duplication of research and development expenses (Lundquist,
1992). In addition, these acquisitions, financed largely with cash, have created
value by transferring over $10 billion from the industry to target-firm shareholders who can reinvest in more productive sectors (Jensen, 1983).
Acquisitions
Diversijication and commercialization.
A 1992 survey of 148 defense companies
sponsored by a defense/aerospace consulting firm found that more than half of
the respondents report past attempts to ‘commercialize’ (i.e., applying defense
technologies to commercial products) and more than three-quarters predict
future commercialization.33
For example, Hughes is applying its satellite technology in a commercial venture called satellite direct TV, designed to compete
directly with cable television. Lockheed is pursuing commercial satellite and
satellite launch customers, and is converting its defense systems businesses into
systems for collecting child support payments and traffic tickets, and bar coding
applications for the postal service. Other firms are adopting more traditional
33Rick
Work’,
War&man,
‘Peace Initiative:
Wall Street Journal, February
Lockheed
Navigates
10, 1992.
the Tricky
Transition
to More
Civilian
Table 7
Summary
of defense revenues,
strategy,
capital
expenditures,
and employment
Dept. of Defense
prime contracts=
($ billions)
Company
GM
Hughes
19891992
As % of
total rev.
of major
defense contractors
Capital expenditures/depreciation”
(defense segments only)
Strategyb
1989
Critical
mass, diversification,
conversion,
downsizing,
exit
$12.3
26.1%
Grumman
$9.6
64.3%
Critical
56.0%
48.4%
Lockheed
$14.5
36.5%
Critical
mass, conversion,
globalization,
downsizing
109.4%
93.4%
Martin
Marietta
$11.9
49.6%
Critical
mass, diversification,
globalization,
downsizing
127.6%
114.8%
McDonnell
Douglas
$30.2
45.3%
Critical
mass, globalization,
conversion,
downsizing,
exit
112.2%
10.0%
mass, downsizing,
exit
64.2%
1990
53.5%
1991
44.3%
Employmentd
(defense/aerospace
1992
1990
1991
segments)
1992
% change
1990-92
57,000
- 15.1%
23,600
21,200
- 18.8%
72,300
71,700
- 1.8%
48.4%
61,114
63,204
59.1%
49.2%
26,100
93.7%
93.1%
73,000
88.8%
72.9%
32,900
32,000
31.9%
63.5%
121,190
109,123
e
87,377
N/A
- 27.9%
Northrop
$9.5
43.4%
Conversion,
downsizing
Raytheon
$14.8
40.6%
Conversion,
downsizing
globalization,
United
Technologies
$12.0
14.4%
Globalization,
$114.8
34.4%
$25.5
76.3%
Total
.
(w/o GD)
General
Dynamics
downsizing
86.2%
64.6%
58.1%
65.2%
135.0%
117.1%
84.7%
71.3%
131.9%
136.4%
128.3%
108.3%
89.4%
108.8%
84.9%
38,200
33,600
c
- 12.0%
-e
36,200
.~e
100.7%
45,700
44,400
41,000
- 10.3%
16.3%
78.7%
565,964
539,927
460,477
17.9%
16.3%
98,150
80,600
35,650
. .
N/A
.
Downsizing,
exit
“Department
of Defense, ‘100 Companies
Receiving the Largest Dollar Volume of Prime Contract
Awards’, various issues (excludes sales to foreign
thus defense business is understated
in terms of total revenue and as a percentage
of firm revenue); firm revenues from company
annual reports.
“Subjectively
‘Data
from
‘Figures
determined
annual
reported
from
reports
and Aircraft
by Aerospace
‘Segment
data not available.
‘Excludes
Martin
Marietta
a variety
Industries
and Raytheon
of sources,
Owners
including
and Pilots
analysts
Association
Association.
from
summary
total.
reports,
Industry
trade
publications,
Sector
Analysis
business
Data
press, and company
Base, provided
reports.
to us by General
Dynamics.
..
- 13.6’
- 63.7%
countries,
296
J. Dial,
K.J. MurphylJournal
qf‘Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
26lb314
diversification strategies: Raytheon, for example, diversified into corporate jets
by acquiring British Aerospace’s business-jet unit. Martin Marietta CEO
Norman Augustine, however, cautioned his industry counterparts about wandering too far from their areas of expertise:
Our industry’s record at defense conversion is unblemished by success.
Why is it rocket scientists can’t sell toothpaste? Because we don’t know the
market, or how to research, or how to market the product. Other than that,
we’re in good shape.34
Globalization.
A number of firms are retaining a defense focus, attempting to
bolster sales through globalization,
selling U.S. built weapons abroad. This
strategy is unlikely to yield dramatic growth, since the demand for weapons is
declining world-wide and many foreign countries have their own national
producers who are also faced with excess capacity (Lundquist, 1992). Nevertheless, augmenting domestic sales with foreign contracts can help to build critical
mass in businesses with waning support from the U.S. government. Raytheon,
one of the few defense contractors that is successfully pursuing a globalization
strategy, hopes to achieve 40% of military sales outside of the U.S., principally
on sales of its Patriot missile in the Mideast.
Downsizing,
consolidation, and exit.
Table 7 shows that while most contractors
adopted a combination of strategies, all adopted some form of downsizing or
consolidation to reduce excess capacity. However, while a few contractors
(including GM Hughes, Grumman, and McDonnell Douglas) have divested
unprofitable noncore businesses where they had little chance of building strategically competitive positions, only General Electric (not included in Table 7)
followed GD in exiting key segments of the defense industry. Interestingly, it was
General Electric (where Anders held his first general management position) that
pioneered the ‘# 1 or # 2’ criterion as a strategic assessment for the composition
of its portfolio of business units.
Table 7 reports the ratio of capital expenditures to depreciation within the
defense segments of major defense contractors from 1989 through 1992. Ratios
exceeding 100% indicate that firms are investing more than is required to
replace depreciating assets, while ratios less than 100% indicate that firms are
not fully replacing depreciating assets. The table shows that a composite
(weighted average) ratio among eight key contractors fell from 108% in 1989 to
just 79% in 1992. However, the table shows that GD cut its capital spending
faster and deeper than other defense contractors: GD’s ratio of capital expenditures to depreciation approximated the industry average in 1989 and 1990, but
34‘Still
Waiting
for the Bang’,
The Economist,
October
2, 1993.
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
297
plummeted to just 17.9% and 16.3% in 1991 and 1992, respectively. Table 7 also
shows that total employment within the defense/aerospace segments of these
same contractors fell by 13.6% from 1990 to 1992. Meanwhile, GD reduced its
employment by 63.7% over the same period through layoffs, sell offs, and
attrition (see also Table 4).
Goyal, Lehn, and Racic (1993) also analyze investment policies in the defense
industry. They report evidence that defense contractors began transferring
resources from the industry as early as 1989-90 through increased leverage,
dividends, and share repurchases. Our complementary evidence suggests that
although other contractors also espoused and eventually adopted consolidation
and downsizing, GD’s response in moving resources out of the industry was
quicker and more dramatic. To draw an analogy: While other defense contractors engaged in a high-stakes game of musical chairs- hoping to be seated
when the music stopped-GD
pursued a strategy of offering its chair to the
highest bidder.
4.2. Incentives and performance
in the defense industry
Table 8 compares Anders’ stock-based incentives to those of CEOs in other
major defense contractors and in the S&P 500, using data from corporate proxy
statements covering the 1992 fiscal year. 35 Financial incentives to create value
come predominantly from stock options, restricted stock, and stock ownership
(Jensen and Murphy, 1990; Murphy, 1993). Cash compensation plans explicitly
based on stock prices-such as GD’s Gain/Sharing Plan which was ultimately
converted to stock options -are unusual. Therefore, we focus on these three
components of incentives and ignore incentives associated with salaries, bonuses,
and other cash plans. We define ‘incentives’ as the fraction of the shareholder gain
‘paid’ to the CEO through appreciation of his stock and option holdings.
Table 8 shows that Anders held stock options on 1.39% of GD’s outstanding
shares (including the options granted when Gain/Sharing was discontinued),
substantially more than the average holdings in the industry (0.29%) or the S&P
500 (0.20%). In addition, Anders held restricted stock on 0.32% of GD’s shares,
compared to industry and market averages of 0.05% and 0.03%, respectively.
Together-assuming
the options are sufficiently in-the-money- these two components imply that Anders’ receives approximately 1.7% of the gains to GD
shareholders, between five and seven times the average percentage in the
industry (0.34%) and market (0.23%), respectively. [Anders’ estimated incentives of 1.7% are higher than the 1.1% reported in Table 6 because Anders
exercised and sold 150,000 shares in December 1992. The 1.7% represents his
marginal incentives at the end of 1992 (prior to the exercise) rather than the
35Pro~y
data were unavailable
for 74 S&P
500 companies.
Table 8
Stock-based
incentives
and shareholder
returns
Percentage
fiscal 1992
in the defense industry
of outstanding
and the S&P
shares held by CEO,
500
Rate of return
reinvested)
realized
by shareholders
(dividends
1992
1993
80%
47
31
20
- 32
36
27
-8
.. . .
55%
66
25
31
126
14
31
33
Stock
options
Restricted
stock
Stock
owned
Total
19871990
GM Hughes”
Grumman
Lockheed
Martin
Marietta
McDonnell
Douglas
Northrop
Raytheon
United Technologies
0.00%
0.24
0.33
0.35
0.00
1.05
0.08
0.48
.. .. . ..
0.00%
0.06
0.00
0.05
0.00
0.04
0.12
0.05
. ...
0.02%
0.12
0.02
0.02
3.34
0.68
0.03
0.05
... .
0.02%
0.42
0.35
0.42
3.34
1.77
0.23
0.63
... . . ..
0%
-2
- 21
27
- 35
-46
18
20
..
Industry
average
0.29%
0.05%
0.31%
0.61%
11%
29%
16%
41%
110%
General
Dynami&
1.39%
0.32%
0.05%
1.76%
- 59%
118%
97%
48%
537%
0.20%
0.03%
0.75%
0.98%
56%
30%
8%
10%
55%
Company
S&P 500
Industry
and S&P 500 averages are value-weighted.
Weights for industry
performance
are 1 l/91 market
from fiscal 1992 proxy statements;
proxy data were available for 426 of the S&P 500 companies.
“Incentive
data reflects GM’s
CEO’s
holdings
of GM
Hughes
stock; ownership
1991
- 13%
-5
40
39
93
59
22
18
..
capitalizations.
data for the head of GM’s
Hughes
Data
subsidiary
on stock-based
1991p
1993
143%
131
130
118
197
147
103
44
. .
incentives
are not available.
‘Anders’ stock-based
incentives are calculated
before his December
1992 option exercise. They reflect 431,359 stock options, 15,500 purchased shares, and
100,700 restricted shares (including
30,940 shares granted in lieu of benefits he would have received at Textron;
these shares were held in a GD deferred
account until late 1992, when Anders received the value of the shares in cash). Anders’ incentives
from Gain/Sharing
discontinued
in December
1991~ are not included, but the incentives from the options that replaced Gain/Sharing
are included.
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
299
‘average’ incentives over the 1991-1993 period.] As a new CEO, Anders held
substantially less stock than the average CEO in the industry and market; these
shares provide incentives even though they are not controlled by the compensation committee. Anders’ overall incentives (including stock owned) are about
three times the average incentives for CEOs in the industry and twice the
average incentives for CEOs in the market.
We also compared the 1992 incentives for defense-firm CEOs to incentives
four years earlier, based on 1989 proxy statements. Incentives for GD’s CEO
(Anders in 1992, Stanley Pace in 1988) increased 1.47% from 0.29% to 1.76%. In
contrast, the change in incentives in the other eight firms ranged from - 1.07%
to 0.29%, with a median change of 0.1%. Although the estimates of 1988 and
1992 incentives are not strictly comparable due to changes in CEOs and reporting
requirements, our results suggest that, measured relative to changes in other
defense firms, CEO incentives at GD increased substantially from 1988 to 1992.36
Although Anders’ stock-based incentives of 1.7% seem small in absolute
value, it is worth noting that the 25 members of his top management team have
stock-based incentives exceeding 6% (see Table 6). In addition, his pay-related
incentives (options and restricted stock) are exceeded by less than 4% of the
S&P 500, and his total incentives (including stock) are exceeded by only 15% of
the S&P 500. The only CEO in the industry with more stock-based incentives is
McDonnell
Douglas’ founding-family-member
John McDonnell.
Although
McDonnell has no options or restricted stock, his family stock holdings account
for over 3% of the outstanding stock. While his company was slow to respond to
the pending industry decline, its stock price more than doubled in 1993 after it
closed several fabrication plants, reduced capital expenditures by more than
half, and cut employment 18% to just 72,000 by the end of 1993.
The final columns of Table 8 show the shareholder returns (with reinvested
dividends) earned by GD, other major defense contractors, and the S&P 500
from January 1987 through December 1993. GD shareholders received lower
returns than the industry and market prior to Anders’ appointment as CEO,
and earned substantially higher returns than the industry and market in 1991
and 1992. The defense market rebounded in 1993, earning an average 41%
compared to the 10% return on the S&P 500, but still below GD’s 48% return.
GD contributed to the 1993 wealth creation among other defense firms by
facilitating a consolidation of the industry and leading the wave of defenserelated layoffs and acquisitions that had returned over $10 billion to shareholders by early 1994. Focusing on core businesses, shedding underperforming
assets, closing facilities, consolidating divisions, reducing debt, and cutting
361n particular,
firms did not disclose outstanding
stock options
outstanding
options as the sum of 1988 grants and options exercisable
firms did not uniformly
report restricted
shareholdings
in 1988.
in 1988. We estimate
1988
within 60 days. In addition,
300
J. Dial, K.J. Murphy
JJournal
of’ Financial
Economics
3 7 (1995)
261-3
14
capital expenditures and employment has substantially strengthened the competitive position of many contractors as they have reduced both financial and
operating leverage.
5. Sources of GD’s value gain
Table 9 decomposes the sources of GD’s $4.486 billion value gain from
1991-1993. It estimates the fraction of the value gain that plausibly reflects GD’s
new management team and incentives, and the fraction that is best explained by
market and industry stock-price movements and by events affecting GD’s stock
price that are unrelated to the implementation
of GD’s strategy. The estimates
in the table are based on the S&P 500 Index, performance of the industry in
excess of the S&P 500, and the industry-adjusted
three-day announcement
returns of events affecting GD’s stock price (as reported in Appendix B).
Each event in Appendix B includes a designation of exogenous, earnings,
distributions, downsizing, or strategy. Exogenous events-such as the Gulf War,
the Soviet Coup, awards (or cancellations) of CD contracts-are events not
plausibly driven by GD’s new management team and incentives. Earnings
includes earnings announcements. Distributions includes events related to dividends, share repurchases, and special distributions (including ex-divided dates).
Downsizing includes announcements related to layoffs and sales of divisions. The
final category, Strategy, includes events related to Gain/Sharing,
Anders’
speeches, analyst reports, and other announcements directly related to GD’s
strategy. We consider that events related to earnings, distributions, downsizing,
and strategy plausibly reflect GD’s new management team and incentives.
Table 9 shows that $956 million of GD’s gain (21% of the total) can be
explained by general market movements, while $1.076 billion (24% of the total)
can be explained by industry-specific movements. Exogenous events not directly
linked to Anders’ strategy account for $21 million, bringing the total gain explained by market, industry, and exogenous factors to $2.053 billion, or about
46% of the total gain to shareholders. Announcement returns related to earnings,
distributions, downsizing, and strategy account for $2.322 billion (or 52% of the
total). Together, the market and industry adjustments and the announcement
returns explain 98% (all but $111 million) of the total gain to GD shareholders.
The $2.3 billion estimate of value gain explained by Anders’ strategy excludes
the $111 million ‘unexplained’ component and the $1.1 billion explained by
industry-specific movements (in excess of the market). In estimating the fraction
of GD’s value gain plausibly driven by its management team and incentive
structure, it seems appropriate to exclude exogenous factors affecting the entire
industry. For example, if the 41% industry return in 1993 (see Table 8) reflected
increased demand for new weapons systems, it would be inappropriate
to
attribute that demand shift to actions taken by GD’s managers. However, the
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
301
261-314
Table 9
Sources of value gain at General Dynamics, 1991-1993 ($ millions)
1991
Beginning market value
Regular dividends
Special distributions, share repurchase
Ending value
1992
of value change attributed
to exogenous
General market movements’
Industry-specific movement?
Industry-adjusted response to announcements
not related to GD’s new strategyi’.’
$2,253
56
960
3,204
$ 420
8
- 128
$ 228
300
149
1991-1993
$3,204
$1,052
56
154
1,554
2,514
2,870
2,870
.
Change in value
$1,243
$1,967
$1,276
$4,486
.. ... ................. ........... .................................. ................................................................................................................
Amount
$1,052
42
0
2,253
1993
factors
$ 308
768
0
$ 956
1,076
21
... . ... .. . ..... .
.
Value change from exogenous factors
$ 300
$ 611
$ 1,076
$2,053
.....
...... ....... ............. ...........................................................................................................................................
Amount
strategy
of value change attributed
(industry-adjusted)
to GD’s new
Earnings announcements
Cash distribution announcements“
Downsizing announcementse
Other strategy-related announcementsf
Value change from strategy
..... .................
..... ..
Unexplained change in value
.
$ - 74
0
18
671
$ 134 $ 182 $ 242
258
351
609
225
23
266
534
0 $1,205
... ..
$ 615
$1,151 $ 556 $2,322
................................................................................................................
% 328
$ 139 $-356
S 111
“General market movements am calculated daily as V,- r r ,,,L,where V, - 1 is GD’s market value on day
t - 1, and r,, is the return on the S&P 500 index on day t. Industry-specific movements are calculated
daily as V,- i(r,, - r,), where 4, is the value-weighted return on the eight defensefirms in Tables 7 and 8.
“Includes announcements of defense contracts, world events (such as the Gulf War and the Soviet
Coup), and other announcements as designated in Appendix B.
“Industry-adjusted responses (as reported in A * ppendix B) are calculated as V,_ *(R1 - Ri,), where
R, and Ri, are the three-day returns surrounding each announcement for GD and the industry,
respectively, and V,-, is GD’s market value two days prior to the announcement.
%cludes announcements related to dividends, share repurchases, and special distributions (including ex-dividend dates) as designated in Appendix B.
‘Includes announcements related to layoffs and sales of divisions as designated in Appendix B.
‘Includes responses to Gain/Sharing, Anders’ speeches, analyst reports, and other announcements
designated in Appendix B.
stellar performance of the defense industry in 1992-1993 was not driven by an
increase in weapons contracts, but by explicit managerial responses to declining
demand, including mergers, consolidations, and downsizing. GD was an active
player, not an innocent bystander, in this process, and both GD’s and the
302
J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
industry’s returns would plausibly have been lower without Anders’ active
participation. Therefore, depending on how the industry and unexplained components are interpreted, our estimates of the value gain attributable to GD’s
management and incentive structure range from $2.3 billion to $3.5 billion.
The evidence presented in this paper, including Table 9, support the hypotheses
that GD’s remarkable shareholder performance was driven in large part by its
top management team and its incentive structure. In the remainder of this
section, we address three questions related to the sources and disposition of the
value gain. First, was the value gain simply a transfer of wealth from (former)
GD employees to shareholders? Second, rather than returning cash to shareholders, should GD have used its excess cash to diversify or to retain workers?
Finally, could GD’s results have been achieved with fewer executive incentives?
5.1. Did the value gain at General Dynamics come at the expense of GD workers?
GD, with a January 1991 market capitalization of $1 billion and less than
$1 billion in long-term debt, generated almost $4.5 billion in wealth for shareholders in less than three years. The underlying theme in this study is that value
was created as resources used in defense were diverted to more highly valued
uses. The fact that the diversion was associated with large increases in stock
prices suggests that the stock market expected that efficient resource allocation
was unlikely. The fact that GD had a 1991 market value (including debt) of less
than $2 billion while having over $10 billion in revenues, a $23 billion backlog,
over $6 billion in assets, 98,000 employees, and annual capital and R&D
spending in excess of $700 million, is further evidence that the market expected
GD to e z mploy its resources inefficiently.
Fig. 1 suggests that the market began anticipating cuts in future defense
spending as early as 1987: GD’s shareholders realized a 59% loss from January
1987 through December 1990. Moreover, the industry (excluding GD but
including the other firms in Table 8) managed a meager cumulative 11% return
over the same four years, far less than the 56% return on the S&P 500 from
1987-1990. The market evidently discounted the probability that the defense
industry would respond efficiently to the changing defense market.
The increase in GD’s value reflects, in part, the gain to society from diverting
capital resources to more highly valued uses (e.g., GD’s drastic cuts in capital
expenditures). In addition, part of the increase in GD’s value reflects the gain
from diverting human resources to more highly valued uses, and part reflects
a wealth transfer from employees to shareholders. Employees are worse off by the
differences between their wages at GD and the wages in their next-best alternatives; however, society is better off by the differences in the employees’ value at
their next-best alternative and their value as defense workers at GD. To the extent
that employees could earn a similar wage in the nondefense sector, the increase
in GD’s value represents a dollar-for-dollar
increase in societal wealth. To the
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (199.5) 261-314
303
extent that employees must accept much lower wages, the relevant issue is why
they had originally been paid a premium to work in the competitive defense
industry. Presumably, this premium reflected the specialized skills required for
the industry, and also reflected a compensating differential for risky employment
in an industry with historically variable demand. In addition, the premium reflects
the wealth transfer from taxpayers to employees that occurred when defense
contractors passed high labor costs directly to taxpayers under contracts awarded
on a cost-plus basis. By shifting to fixed-price contracts in the late 1980s Congress
shifted the burden of overpaid employees from taxpayers to shareholders. The
elimination of the subsidized overpayment to defense employees will harm affected employees, but generally benefit shareholders and society.
We have not attempted to separate quantitatively the portions of the increase
in GD’s shareholder wealth that reflect societal gains versus transfers from
employees. It is worth stressing, however, that the fact that some of the gain
reflects transfers does not imply that shareholders were expropriating wealth from
defense workers who had ‘rights’ to perpetual wage premiums. There is no
evidence that GD had an implicit or explicit contractual obligation to continue
paying rents to employees following the end of the Cold War. There is evidence,
however, that the market expected the company to waste resources by paying
workers high rents to continue producing products that society no longer valued.
5.2. Should General Dynamics have used its excess cash to diver@
workers?
or retain
Although politicians, journalists, and labor leaders argued that GD should
have retrained their defense-specific employees, Anders believed that retraining
programs would be an inappropriate use of shareholder money:
I do not see that we have a special obligation to our employees. This is an
issue of excess human capacity that had to leave the defense industry. We
trained our people to have specific skills and paid for that training. Then we
paid them for their skills. What are we to do when those skills are no longer
required? We have a lot of very skilled welders at Electric Boat that earn
about twice what they can earn on the outside where that level of skill is not
required. We are not going to start to build bridges. That’s not our business
and not our obligation.
The loss of jobs at GD is actually better for America if we redeploy those
assets appropriately. We have done more than any other defense contractor
in creating new jobs by putting $3.4 billion back into investments - by
letting shareholders redeploy those resources in new industries for new
products.
304
J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
Academic proponents of company-sponsored retraining programs argue that
such programs are part of the optimal implicit contract between employees and
employers. It is difficult to disprove the existence of implicit contracts, since
these contracts by definition are not written, but exist only in the minds of the
employees and the employer. We argue, however, that rational employees would
not expect a firm to honor this type of implicit contract in the event the firm
downsizes or exits particular business lines. Implicit contracts are enforced
through reputational concerns: Reneging on contracts with current workers
makes it more costly to enter into similar contracts in the future. However, when
the likelihood of future contracting is substantially reduced (or nonexistent in
the case of a full liquidation), enforcing the implicit contract becomes more
difficult. Consequently, implicit promises by a firm to provide retraining coincidental to downsizing or liquidation are not credible. Employees who desire this
type of employment insurance would not likely rely on implicit contracts, but
would instead demand explicit contracts specifying employment guarantees,
severance payments, and retraining programs in the event of liquidation. Although GD did write (and honor) explicit contracts with some union workers
and top managers, these contracts did not include retraining provisions.
The relevant question is not whether defense workers should be retrained, but
who should provide the retraining. Retraining will have to occur, since the specific
skills required in the defense industry are not readily transferable to other
industries. The worker has the best information to determine how to retain, and to
choose the industrial sectors promising the best alternative employment opportunities. In contrast, the company has neither the information nor the expertise
to be an efficient provider of retraining for unemployed defense workers.
5.3. Could General Dynamics ’ results have been achieved with fewer executive
incentives?
One of the more important issues raised by the GD case is whether the
strategy it ultimately adopted could have been developed and implemented
without the large ex post rewards to top managers. Anders, after all, was already
paid an annual salary of $800,000 to act in the interest of GD shareholders. Why
did he need additional incentives to do what he was hired to do?
The strategies adopted by GD - including downsizing, restructuring, liquidation, and returning excess cash to shareholders-seem
obvious, given the
projected reductions in defense budgets associated with the end of the Cold War.
However, despite ample evidence of a changing defense market available to all
defense contractors, only GD followed the ‘obvious’ strategy. While other
contractors reduced their work forces to some degree, no one took the drastic
actions that GD did in 1991 and 1992 to reduce capital expenditures and
employment, and no other firm elected to convert their assets to cash and return
financial resources to shareholders.
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
305
The new management team and new incentive programs were introduced
simultaneously. It is therefore difficult to identify the relative importance of
incentives versus the particular individuals in the team. It is worth noting,
however, that Anders and the other top executives believe that the Gain/Sharing
Plan and other plans linked to value creation were crucial elements of GD’s
ultimate success. Anders stresses the importance of creating the ‘partnership
mentality’ among top managers, who began to think like owners rather than
hired hands. The decisions GD managers made were not easy, and the incentives
had to be strong enough to attract and retain the right executives, ensure timely
and comprehensive disclosure of critical information, and motivate the right
decisions. Ultimately,
the incentives had to be strong enough to make the
executives willing to sacrifice their own jobs and positions. Several top GD
executives (including Anders) have left the company, and many of those remaining (including new CEO Mellor) have accepted substantial pay reductions to
reflect the reduced complexity of the smaller corporation they now manage.
Such voluntary turnover and pay cuts are unusual in U.S. corporations.
The argument that high-salaried managers should take actions that benefit
shareholders-even without high-powered incentives-is at odds with the evidence in a growing number of corporate giants, including IBM, General Motors,
Kodak, Westinghouse, and Sears. In these firms, as well as many others, creating
value for shareholders means downsizing and moving human and physical
capital out of the industry. Managers in these firms resisted major changes until
the changes were forced upon them by market pressure; IBM, for example,
brought in a new manager to make meaningful changes only after shareholders
lost over $50 billion in less than two years.
6. Conclusion
Jensen (1993) argues that rapid increases in technology, declines in regulation,
growing worldwide capitalism, and globalization of trade have created massive
excess capacity in many of the world’s industries. GD’s response to excess
capacity in the defense industry has important implications for many firms
across a wide range of industries facing similar economic pressures.
First, the GD case suggests the importance of stock-based compensation in
firms characterized by excess capacity: GD downplayed accounting-based
bonuses and focused on stock options, restricted stock, and other compensation
plans tied to value creation. Second, GD’s experience illustrates the large
political costs associated with success when success mean downsizing and
layoffs, and also suggests that these costs can be mitigated by avoiding cash
payments, relying instead on gains through ownership. Third, appropriate
incentives must be coupled with the appropriate managers: Anders believes that
his strategy could not have been implemented without the incentives, but the
306
J. Dial,
K.J. Murphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
case facts also suggest that Anders’ actions transcended his individual incentives.
Finally, although declining industries with excess capacity offer relatively few
opportunities for revenue growth, the GD case suggests that these industries
may offer large potential opportunities for value creation.
Even though GD’s situation is replicated in many firms and industries, its
response and ultimate achievements are remarkable. Excess capacity necessitates downsizing and transferring resources to higher-valued uses. However, few
managers have been able to accomplish the necessary resource redirection until
their organizations faced crises in the product, factor, or capital markets. GD’s
board and top management team were remarkably consistent in pursuing their
objective of creating shareholder wealth in spite of enormous pressures from
employees, unions, the media, and the government to do otherwise. Overall, GD
stands out as the preeminent shareholder success story of the early 1990s and
may serve as a blueprint for compensation and strategy decisions in other
industries with excess capacity.
Appendix A
General Dynamics board of directors and stock ownership, February 15, 1991
Restricted and
unrestricted
shares held
Director
CURRENT
MANAGEMENT
William A. Anders (age 57, director since 1990)
Chairman
and CEO
Lester Crown (age 65, director since 1974)
Executive
Chairman
and
Chief Operating
-d
271,359
60,412
76,469
133,613
15,071
0
44,323
22,157
53,450
0
47,701
22,190
Officer
Russell W. Meyer, Jr. (age 58, director since 1986)
Executive
Chairman
106,586’
Vice President
of Material
Service subsidiary
James R. Mellor (age 60, director since 1981)
President
Stock
options
heldb
Vice President of the Corporation
of Cessna Aircraft
subsidiary
Herbert F. Rogers (age 65, director since 1987)
Vice Chairman
of the Corporation
FORMER MANAGEMENT
David S. Lewis (age 73, director since 1970)
Former Chairman and CEO
Stanley C. Pace (age 70, director since 1985)
Former
Chairman
and CEO
J. Dial,
K.J. h4urphy/Journal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261-314
Restricted
and
unrestricted
shares held”
Director
307
Stock
options
held”
-
CROWN
FAMILY
James S. Crown (age 37, director since 1987)
General Partner, Henry Crown and Company
Charles H. Goodman
(age 57, director since 199kl)
Vice President, Henry Crown and Company
Vice President, CC Industries,
Inc.
9.187,149’
i
0
NONMANAGEMENT
Thomas G. Ayers (age 76, director
since 1980)’
Former Chairman
and CEO of Commonwealth
Edison
Frank C. Carlucci (age 60, director since 1991)
Vice Chairman,
The Carlyle Group
Former Secretary of Defense
Harvey
Kapnick
(age 65, director since 1980)’
President, Kapnick Investment
Co.
Alien E. Puckett (age 71, director
since 1987)’
Chairman
Emeritus of Hughes Aircraft
Company
Bernard W. Rogers (age 69, director
since 1987)
Retired General, former Chief of Staff
Former Supreme Allied Commander
Europe, U.S. Army
Elliot H. Stein (age 72, director since 1978)’
Chairman
Emeritus of Stiefel Financial
Corporation
Cyrus R. Vance (age 74, director since 1987)
Chairman,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Former Secretary
of State
Source:
2/15/91.
GD
“Includes
1991 Proxy
restricted
Statement,
shares granted
“Includes options granted
of $25.5625 per share.
March
28, 1991. There
or promised
(and exchanged)
were 41,870,868
on (or before)
on February
February
15; all options
300
0
1,050
0
500
0
1,000
0
300
0
2.500
0
300
0
shares outstanding
on
15, 1991.
listed have an exercise
price
‘Anders shares include 500 shares purchased before 1991,10,000
shares purchasedin
February
1991,
30,326 shares of restricted stock granted in lieu of benefits he would have received at Textron (held in
a deferred account), and 65,760 restricted shares granted or promised in February
1991.
%ee Crown
family
holdings
below.
‘Includes
Lester Crown’s
24,310 restricted
shares. Many of the shares owned by Lester Crown,
James S. Crown, and Charles Goodman
are jointly owned through
Crown family trusts. The total
ownership
by the Crown family amounts
to approximately
22% of General
Dynamics
common
stock.
‘Member
of compensation
committee.
Appendix B
Stock market reactions and shareholder value changes in response to announcements and events for General Dynamics, aerospace/defense industry, and the S&P
500, 1991-1994
Three-day value changes
($ millions)
Three-day returns
Announcement
type
Date
9127189 Anders hiring announced
l/1/91
Anders takes over as
Chairman and CEO
l/8/91
Defense Secretary Cheney
cancels A-12
l/17/91 Gulf War lasts from l/17/91 to
through 2/28/91, creating substantial
2128191 volatility among defenserelated stocks
l/17
Air war begins over Iraq
Defense budget announced,
214
cuts in planned purchases of
F-165
GD and McDonnell Douglas
217
are permitted to defer
repayment on A-12
2115
GD’s Board of Directors
adopts Gain/Sharing Plan
and other new compensation
initiatives
2124
Ground war begins in Iraq
2128 - Gulf war ends
l
l
l
l
l
GD share
price
Exogenous
$22+
Exogenous
%21$
to
$25
Genera1
Dynamics
Industry
return
Market
return
Genera1
Dynamics
Industryadjusted
Marketadjusted
- 16.3%
- 4.9%
- 2.6%
- $172
- $120
- $145
16.0%”
0.8%”
- 4.2%”
$141”
$7”
- $37”
3113191 Goldman Sachs, Morgan
Stanley, and Paine Webber
recommend GD stock, citing
managerial incentives and
changes underway
3,‘20/9 1 GD lays off 2,000 at jet plant
3128191 South Korea cancels purchase
of McDonnell Douglas
fighters and surprises
observers in announcing
$5.2 billion purchase of
F-16s
413191
ECgyptbuys 46 more F-16s
4117191 First quarter earnings down
56% (excluding 1990 onetime gain, earnings down
21%)
4/23/9 1 Lockheed/GD/Boeing team wins
ATF award
5/l/91
Shareholders ratify Gain/
Sharing Plan, Mellor says
GD to cut 30,000 jobs by
1994
516191
Navy awards Seawolf nuclear
sub to GD, first Gain/Sharing
payoff
s/9/9 1 Judge halts Seawolf award
7117191 Second quarter earnings
($211 M), up from $240 M
loss in 1990
Strategy
$284
22.0%
0.1%
0.0%
$220
$218
$220
Downsizing
Exogenous
$29$
$33%
- 0.8%
7.0%
0.5%
1.8%
1.4%
1.4%
- $10
$94
- $4
$118
$7
$112
Exogenous
Earnings
$342
$35
- 2.9%
6.0%
2.8%
1.1%
2.3%
2.0%
- $42
$84
- $82
$99
- $74
$56
Exogenous
$36$
6.4%
0.4%
$94
$84
$100
Strategy
$39
3.0%
1.9%
$47
$35
$18
Exogenous
Strategy
$391
4.2%
0.8%
$68
$82
$82
Exogenous
Earnings
$39$
$44
3.8%
- 0.3%
0.4%
0.8%
- $63
- $5
- $61
~ $93
- $51
- $20
0.8%
Three-day value changes
(S millions)
Three-day returns
Announcement
type
GD share
price
General
Dynamics
Industry
return
Market
return
Industryadjusted
Marketadjusted
$16
$12
$27
- 6.0%”
- $79”
- $127”
- $111”
1.1%
- 0.3%
$361
$343
$366
Date
Event
8/9/9 1
GD gets contract to build tanks
for Army
Soviet Coup lasts from g/19/91
to B/21/91
Exogenous
0.2%
- 0.6%
Exogenous
6.8 %”
Anders addresses defense analyst
conference, GD sells data unit
to CSC for S184 M (9/22),
more Wall Street firms say ‘Buy’
10/8/91 Second Gain/Sharing payoff
10/17/91 GD announces plan to divest
Cessna
10/21/91 Third-quarter earnings ($71 M)
up 4%
10129191 Anders speech outlines strategic
options
l/9/92
U.S. seeks to settle suit over
A-12
l/21/92 GD announces sale of Cessna
to Textron
213192 Fourth-quarter earnings
($166 M), up from $530 M
loss in 1990
Strategy
Downsizing
a/19/91
through
8/21/91
9124191
General
Dynamics
-
$4
Strategy
Downsizing
S4ti
- 3.6%
4.4%
1.1%
3.3%
- 1.1%
0.5%
- $73
$89
- $50
$22
- $52
$80
Earnings
$50
0.0%
3.8%
- 1.0%
$0
- $80
$21
Strategy
%5Oi
7.0%
2.9%
2.4%
$141
$83
$93
Exogenous
ssc$
- 1.5%
2.8%
- 0.5%
- $37
- $105
~ $24
Downsizing
No+
- 1.2%
1.8%
- 0.1%
- $31
$14
- $29
Earnings
$58:
0.6%
0.9%
0.6%
St6
- S5
$1
M
&e
Three-day value changes
(8 millions)
Three-day returns
Date
Event
10/2/92
Conferees clear defense budget
-GD benefits as defense
priorities change
GD to sell electronics unit to
Carlyle Group
GD gets 81.5 B tank sale
Thirdquarter earnings ($120 M)
up 70%
GD lays off 1680 at Convair,
40% of work force
Rumors of safe of jet business
to Lockheed
GD announces sale of jets to
Lockheed
Fourth-quarter earnings
($174 h@ up 5%
GD announces $20 special
dividend, Anders and two
other top officers resign
Exdividend date for $20 special
dividend
Firstquarter earnings ($687 M)
up 58%
10/7/92
10/13/92
10/16/92
10/20/92
10/27/92
1219192
l/27/93
3119193
3130193
4121193
Announcement
type
GD share
price
General
Dynamics
Industry
return
Market
return
General
Dynamics
Industryadjusted
Marketadjusted
Exogenous
$884
3.7%
- 3.0%
- 2.5%
$92
$169
$155
Downsizing
%9&
4.7%
- 1.8%
0.1%
$122
$167
$120
Exogenous
Earnings
%94i
%96+
0.7%
4.9%
1.1%
1.2%
1.7%
1.4%
$18
$136
- $11
$103
- $28
$97
Downsizing
$97;
0.9%
- 1.2%
1.0%
$26
$59
~ $2
Downsizing
$983
4.4%
2.7%
1.5%
$125
$49
$82
Downsizing
$1034
7.4%
3.4%
- 0.1%
$220
$120
$224
Earnings
$115
0.9%
- 2.6%
- 0.3%
$31
$I20
$40
Distributions
$118f
0.4%
0.5%
0.2%
$16
- $2
$10
Distributions
$984
2.8%
0.5%
0.9%
$101
$84
$69
Earnings
$974
0.8%
- 2.6%
- 1.8%
$23
$100
$17
Distributions
$954
2.5%
1.9%
0.6%
$74
$18
$57
Distributions
SSG
1.6%
0.3%
0.1%
$49
$39
$46
Earnings
%9@
2.3%
1.7%
- 0.3%
$62
$15
$71
Downsizing
$94;
0.4%
- 0.1%
0.6%
$12
$14
- $5
CD announces
$12 special
dividend,
increases dividend
from 40# to 60$
Distributions
S99+
3.1%
0.9%
~ 0.2%
$93
$67
$100
9122193
Ex-dividend
dividend
Distributions
%9c+
5.1%
0.5%
0.6%
$159
$145
$139
10/20/93
Third-quarter
down 39%
Earnings
$956
~ 3.0%
- 1.2%
- 0.6%
- $89
- $53
12123193
GD sells Space Systems
Martin
Marietta
1.5%
1.2%
1.1%
$43
$9
$10
l/26/94
Fourth-quarter
($62 M) down
1.8%
0.5%
1.1%
$51
$38
$19
318194
Anders
- 2.6%
2.1%
0.5%
- $78
- $138
- $93
612193
GD announces
dividend
6115193
Ex-dividend
dividend
l/21/93
Second-quarter
earnings
down 29%, but exceed
analysts’ estimates
8/30/93
GD lays off 700 more
plant
9116193
“Three-day
returns
$18 special
date for $18 special
($61 M)
at tank
date for $12 special
earnings
($73 M)
Downsizing
to
earnings
64%
steps down
Earnings
as Chairman
and value changes
include
rs91;
$92
one day before
and one day after the start and finish
dates listed for the Gulf
War period
and the Soviet
-$71
coup.
314
J. Dial,
K.J. MurphyJJournal
of Financial
Economics
37 (1995)
261~-314
References
Baker, George P., 1990, Pay for performance for middle managers: Causes and consequences,
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 3, no. 3.
Baker, George P., Michael C. Jensen, and Kevin J. Murphy, 1988, Compensation and incentives:
Practice vs. theory, Journal of Finance, July.
Black, Fischer and Myron Scholes, 1973, The pricing of options and corporate liabilities, Journal of
Political Economy 81, no. 3.
Campbell, Cynthia J. and Charles E. Wasley, 1994, Executive compensation: The case of Ralston
Purina Company (Washington University, St. Louis, MO).
Crystal, Graef S. and Fred K. Foulkes, 1988, Don’t bail out underwater options, Fortune, March 14.
DeAngelo, Harry and Linda DeAngelo, 1991, Union negotiation and corporate policy: A study
of labor concessions in the domestic steel industry during the 1980s Journal of Financial
Economics 30, no. 1.
Dechow, Patricia, Mark Huson, and Richard Sloan, 1994, The effect of restructuring charges on
executives’ cash compensation, Accounting Review 69, no. 1.
Gaver, Jennifer J. and Kenneth M. Gaver, 1993, Additional evidence on the association between the
investment opportunity set and corporate financing, dividend, and compensating policies,
Journal of Accounting and Economics 16, no. l-3.
Goyal, Vidhan, Kenneth Lehn, and Stank0 Racic, 1993, Investment opportunities, corporate
finance, and compensation policy in the U.S. defense industry (University of Pittsburgh,
Pittsburgh, PA).
Healy, Paul, 1985, The effect of bonus schemes on accounting decisions, Journal of Accounting and
Economics 7, no. l-3.
Jensen, Michael C., 1986, Agency costs of free cash flow: Corporate finance and takeovers, American
Economic Review 76, no. 2.
Jensen, Michael C., 1989, Eclipse of the public corporation, Harvard Business Review, Sept./Ott.
Jensen, Michael C.; 1991, Corporate control and the politics of finance, Journal of Applied
Corporate Finance, Summer.
Jensen, Michael C., 1993, The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control
systems,Journal of Finance 48, no. 3.
Jensen, Michael C. and Kevin J. Murphy, 1990a, Performance pay and top-management incentives,
Journal of Political Economy 98, no. 2.
Jensen, Michael C. and Kevin J. Murphy, 1990b, A new survey of executive compensation: Full
survey and technical appendix, Working paper 90-067 (Harvard Business School, Boston, MA).
Lundquist, Jerrold T., 1992, Shrink fast and smart in the defense industry, Harvard Business Review,
Nov./Dee.
Minnich, Richard T., 1993, U.S. defense industry in transition: Can the leopard change its spots?,
Business Forum, Winter/Spring.
Murphy, Kevin J., 1993, Executive compensation in corporate America (United Shareholders
Association, Washington, DC).
Murphy, Kevin J. and Jay Dial, 1993, General Dynamics: Compensation and strategy, (A) and (B),
HBS case nos. 9-494-048 and 9-494-049 (Harvard Business School, Boston, MA).
Rosen, Sherwin, 1982, Authority, control, and the distribution of earnings, Bell Journal of Economics 13, no. 2.
Smale, John, 1989, Takeovers and the public interest, The Corporate Board, Sept./Ott.
Smith, Clifford W. and Ross L. Watts, 1992, The investment opportunity set and corporate
financing, dividend, and compensation policies, Journal of Financial Economics 32, no. 3.
Stewart, G. Bennett, 1991, The quest for value: A guide for senior managers (HarperCollins
Publishers, New York, NY).