Academia.eduAcademia.edu

Incentives, downsizing, and value creation at general dynamics

1995, Journal of Financial Economics

In 1991, defense contractor General Dynamics engaged a new management team which adopted an explicit corporate objective of creating shareholder value. The company tied executive compensation to shareholder wealth creation, and subsequently implemented a strategy that included downsizing, restructuring, and exit. Paying large executive cash bonuses amid layoffs ignited controversy. However, by 1993 shareholders realized gains approaching $4.5 billion, representing a dividend-reinvested return of 553%. The study shows how incentives assist in shaping strategy, illustrates the political costs and economic benefits of downsizing and demonstrates that even firms in declining industries have substantial opportunities for value creation.

JOIJRNALOF ELSEVIER Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 Incentives, downsizing, and value creation at General Dynamics Jay Dial, Harvard Kevin University, J. Murphy* Boston, MA 02163. USA (Received April 1994; final version received July 1994) Abstract In 1991,defensecontractor General Dynamics engageda new managementteam which adopted an explicit corporate objective of creating shareholdervalue. The company tied executive compensationto shareholderwealth creation, and subsequently implementeda strategy that includeddownsizing,restructuring,and exit. Paying large executivecashbonusesamidlayoffs ignited controversy. However,by 1993shareholders realized gains approaching $4.5 billion, representinga dividend-reinvestedreturn of 553%.The study showshow incentivesassistin shapingstrategy,illustratesthe political costsand economicbenefitsof downsizingand demonstrates that evenfirmsin declining industrieshave substantialopportunities for value creation. Key words:Incentives;Compensation;Restructuring;Strategy; Defenseindustry G31; G34; G35; 533 JEL classijication: 1. Introduction In the post-Cold War era of 1991, defense contractor General Dynamics Corporation (GD) faced declining demand in an industry saddled with current *Corresponding author. Data and quotes provided by GD officials are from the teaching case(Murphy and Dial, 1993) which was approved and released by GD management; additional material in this article are from publicly available sources. We are particularly grateful to GD officials Bill Anders, Paul Hesse, Jim Cunnane, Ray Lewis, and Al Spivak for their time and helpful comments. George Baker, Linda DeAngelo, Myra Hart, Michael Jensen, Scott Keating, Karen VanNuys,KarenWruck,andespecially Harry DeAngelo (the referee) provided useful comments. Financial support was provided by the Division of Research at the Harvard Business School. 0304-405X/95/.$09.50 0 1995 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved SSDI 0304405X9400803 9 262 J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal qf Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 and projected excess capacity. While other contractors made defense-related acquisitions or diversified into nondefense areas, GD adopted an objective of creating shareholder value through downsizing, restructuring, and partial liquidation. Facilitating GD’s new strategy were a new management team and compensation plans that closely tied executive pay to shareholder wealth creation, including a Gain/Sharing Plan that paid large cash rewards for increases in the stock price. As GD’s executives reaped rewards amid announcements of layoffs and divestitures, the plans became highly controversial, fueling a nationwide attack on executive compensation by politicians, journalists, and shareholder activists. Nonetheless, GD managers credit the incentive plans with helping to attract and retain key managers and for motivating the difficult strategic decisions that were made and implemented: GD realized a dividendreinvested three-year return of 553% from 1991 to 1993-generating $4.5 billion in shareholder wealth from a January 1991 market value of just over $1 billion.’ In the process, GD returned more than $3 billion to shareholders and debtholders through debt retirement, stock repurchases, and special distributions. Following William A. Anders’ appointment as Chairman and Chief Executive Officer (CEO) on January 1,1991, GD reversed a four-year slide in market value and subsequently outperformed other firms in the defense industry and in the Standard & Poor’s S&P 500. Fig. 1 shows the value of an investment worth $100 upon Anders’ appointment as CEO. As shown in the figure, GD stock significantly underperformed the industry and the market, and shareholders had lost 59% in the four years prior to Anders’ appointment. Following Anders’ appointment, the $100 investment in GD stock grew to $653 by December 1993, far exceeding the returns on a $100 investment in a value-weighted defense industry portfolio (excluding GD) and the S&P 500 which grew to $214 and $155, respectively. In this clinical study of compensation and strategy at General Dynamics, we examine GD’s compensation system and document its role in determining and achieving GD’s corporate objective. Critics of GD’s compensation system contend that GD’s optimal strategy was obvious and that its managers should have carried out this strategy without high-powered incentives: the reduction in defense spending seemed an inevitable consequence of changing world events, and GD’s CEO was already paid an annual base salary of $800,000 to fulfill his fiduciary responsibility to shareholders. Although the strategic options available to GD were also available to its competitors, GD was the only defense ‘The three-year return of 553% is the return on a share of stock (with reinvested dividends and special distributions) not repurchased in the 1992 Dutch auction. The return to all shareholders over this period (assuming that cash from the repurchase, dividends, and distributions is not reinvested and earns zero returns thereafter) is 426%. J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 263 261-314 smo- $%a - other defense fm SZld S&P 500 1-l 994 Fig 1. Value of investment worth $100 on January 1, 1991 in General Dynamics, other defense firms, and the S&P 500, 1987-1993. Returns assume that dividends and proceeds from repurchases are reinvested. Other defense firms include those listed in Table 7 (excluding General Dynamics). Weights for industry value-weighted returns are l/1/91 market capitalizations. contractor that responded promptly to the declining world market by taking substantial resources out of the industry. We therefore interpret GD’s performance (measured relative to the market and industry) as reflecting in large part GD’s incentive systems, its articulated objective of creating value for shareholders, and the vision of GD’s management. Although some of the $4.5 billion increase in wealth for GD’s shareholders from 1991-1993 reflected either exogenous events in the market or defense industry or GD-specific events not under management’s control, we estimate that between $2.3 and $3.5 billion of the increase was due to actions taken by GD’s managers. Although it is impossible to prove that GD’s incentive system ‘caused’ these wealth-increasing actions, we present evidence that the system provided meaningful incentives to undertake particular actions, that these actions were taken, and that the managers themselves believe that GD’s restructuring and ultimate downsizing could not have been accomplished without the incentives in place. Viewing this clinical study in a broader context, GD’s situation is similar to that confronting firms in other industries characterized by excess capacity, such as automotive, retail trade, steel, and computers. Excess capacity in the 264 J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 defense industry is related to the Reagan-era build-up and the post-Cold War downsizing, while in other industries excess capacity arises from changes in technology and demand, deregulation, increases in global and nonunionized competition, and managers’ tendency to overinvest in growth. Economic efficiency suggests that human as well as physical capital should be transferred from industries with excess capacity to alternative sectors. Few managers, however, have been able to accomplish the necessary resource redirection until their organizations face crises in the product, factor, or capital markets (Jensen, 1993). Even though GD’s situation is replicated in many firms and industries, its response and ultimate achievements are remarkable, and serve as perhaps the preeminent management and shareholder success story of the early 1990s. The paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 offers a conceptual framework relating to the importance and difficulty of providing appropriate managerial incentives in industries saddled with excess capacity. In Section 3, we describe the compensation policies and strategic initiatives at GD under CEO Anders, and examine the political consequences of GD’s Gain/Sharing Plan. The data presented were obtained from public sources and from discussions with Anders and other GD executives during 1993. Section 4 contrasts GD’s strategy and incentives with those adopted by other major defense contractors. We show that, although other contractors also espoused and eventually adopted consolidation and downsizing, GD’s response in moving resources out of the industry was significantly quicker and more dramatic than its competitors. In addition, we show that GD had substantially more stock-based incentives than the average of other firms in the industry or in the S&P 500. Section 5 analyzes the source of GD’s value gain, and examines several of the criticisms and concerns relating to GD’s compensation and strategy voiced by politicians, academics, shareholder groups, and the media. Section 6 concludes. 2. Value creation and incentives in tbe defense-industry Excess capacity in an industry implies that increased investment in the industry earns less than the cost of capital, and therefore destroys value for shareholders and for society. However, excess capacity offers important opportunities to create value even in the absence of profitable investment opportunities. In particular, creating value under excess capacity involves diverting resources from activities that earn less than the cost of capital (Stewart, 1991), which in turn implies transferring human as well as physical capital from industries with excess capacity to alternative sectors. Stock repurchases, dividends, special distributions, and cash acquisitions within an industry create value under excess capacity by paying out cash to shareholders rather than spending it unproductively (Jensen, 1986). Similarly, workforce reductions through layoffs and attrition create value by facilitating the transfer of workers J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 265 to sectors where their skills and effort are more highly valued by society. The transfer of human resources, unfortunately, often imposes real costs on redeployed workers-especially in the short run- but is nonetheless an efficient and necessary response to excess capacity. Moreover, as we discuss below in Section 5, the fact that redeployed workers earn lower wages in alternative sectors does not necessarily imply that implicit contracts have been breached or that wealth has been transferred from workers to shareholders. The end of the Cold War and the resultant decline in the demand for major weapons platforms generated excess capacity among defense contractors. Assuming that the demand shift is permanent, the economically efficient response is to move both human and physical capital from the defense sector to alternative higher-valued uses. Market pressures will inevitably force resources out of the defense industry in the long run. In the shorter run, however, many defense firms can maintain their current production with only small declines in employment and investment. Major defense contractors typically maintain large ‘backlogs’ of current orders for future deliveries: GD’s 1990 backlog, for example, was $23 billion. Profit margins on these backlogs are sufficiently high to guarantee large cash flows and solvency for several years. Many defense contractors also have large nondefense-related businesses that can subsidize inefficient resource utilization in defense businesses. Alternatively, nondiversified defense contractors can use current cash flows to diversify gradually by retraining their workforce to produce nondefense products or by acquiring nondefense businesses. Yet another strategy-rational for an individual defense firm but not viable for the industry as a whole-is to enhance the probability of surviving the impending shake-out in the global defense industry by investing and growing in the defense area. Traditional executive incentive packages-characterized by high base salaries, accounting-based bonuses, and low levels of stock ownership (Jensen and Murphy, 1990)-do not provide effective incentives to downsize. These traditional pay practices may work well in strong growth economies where the actions that create size and growth are closely correlated with the actions that create value (Baker, 1992). These same practices, however, provide incentives for continued growth even when it is not warranted by the market, and thus have contributed to excess capacity in many industries. There are several reasons why managers paid under traditional systems are unlikely to adopt downsizing strategies even when these strategies produce the highest benefits for shareholders and society: 1. Managerial compensation is typically tied to firm size and/or span of control. Economic theory predicts that CEO compensation will increase with firm size only to the extent that size is a proxy for the skills and abilities required for the position (Rosen, 1982). The pay-size relation has been institutionalized, however, by widely utilized compensation surveys that use size as the 266 J. Dial, primary, Murphy, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial if not the only, determinant 1988). Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 of pay levels (Baker, Jensen, and 2. Managerial compensation is typically tied to short-run accounting profits (Healy, 1985). Downsizing often involves large restructuring charges that reduce accounting profits in the short run.’ Encouraging voluntary attrition through early retirement, severance programs, and retraining programs also increases current expenses, thereby decreasing current accounting profits. In addition, gains associated with sales of plants or divisions are often not included in net income. Thus, managers pursuing downsizing strategies will realize immediate reductions in their annual accounting-based bonuses. 3. Nonmonetary compensation- including power, prestige, and community standing- tends to be linked to firm size and survivability and not to wealth creation. Managers involved in downsizing and layoffs will be subject to media criticism and loss of community standing. 4. Laying off employees and leaving communities is personally painful for managers (particularly those with long company tenures). It is relatively easy to provide incentives for growth: Managers intrinsically enjoy opening new plants, hiring new workers, and announcing new investment programs. In contrast, few managers enjoy downsizing: it’s simply less fun than growing.3 In addition, affected employees and communities impose large nonpecuniary costs on managers, which further reduces the managers’ incentives to downsize. 5. Managers often embrace survival and not value creation as the ultimate objective of the organization (Smale, 1989). Many managers don’t understand and too easily dismiss exit as an appropriate long-term strategy for an organization, even when this strategy creates the most value for shareholders and society. Managers focused on corporate survival will resist exit and pursue costly and inefficient diversification into product lines where they have no expertise or competitive advantages. 6. Moving resources out of an industry reduces the value of managers’ industry-specific human capital, and may ultimately cost managers their own jobs. The tendency for managers to resist downsizing and restructuring highlights both the difficulty and importance of providing appropriate incentives in the defense industry and other industries with excess capacity. Resistance to downZDechow, Huson, and Sloan (1994) present evidence that compensation committees may implicitly adjust accounting-based bonuses for the negative consequences of restructuring charges. %ee, for example, ‘The Pain of Downsizing’, Business Week, May 9, 1994. J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 261 sizing can be mitigated by explicitly adopting a corporate objective of creating value, and by tying managers’ wealth to shareholder value creation-not to size, employment, accounting profitability, or survival. Stockbased incentives-such as stock options, restricted stock, stock ownership, and compensation plans tied to stock prices rather than profits-are natural ways to reward value creation. Because the decision to downsize and transfer resources from an industry is made at the top of the organization, stock-based compensation can be concentrated among top managers, and not diluted by pushing incentives throughout the organization.4 Bringing in managers from outside the firm may also be appropriate: outside managers have weaker personal relationships with employees, customers, suppliers, and communities affected by workforce reductions, and the loss of firm-specific capital associated with outside hires is less important under downsizing and exit strategies. Spinning-off unrelated subsidiaries and avoiding new diversification can mitigate cross-subsidization tendencies. In the following sections, we show how GD followed these prescriptions, creating nearly $4.5 billion in shareholder wealth in the process. The hypothesis that stock-based incentives are most important in declining industries with little potential for future growth appears counter to Smith and Watts (1993), Gaver and Gaver (1993), and others who argue that stock-based incentives are most important in companies with growth opportunities, based on the premise that managerial discretion is more important in growing industries. But, managerial discretion is important in declining industries such as defense as well as in growing ones: there can be significant opportunities to create wealth even when there are few opportunities to create growth. Moreover, under the hypothesis that managers will naturally pursue growth opportunities but will resist downsizing, it is more important to provide financial incentives to downsize than to provide incentives to grow. shareholder 3. Compensation and strategy under CEO William Anders 3. I. Company background General Dynamics began in 1899 as the Electric Boat Company and became a major supplier of submarines and cargo ships to the U.S. Navy during both World Wars. Following World War II, the company adopted a strategy of building the ‘General Motors of the weapons industry’ through acquisition, diversification, and internal development. By 1960, the company was a major aircraft, booster rocket, and missile manufacturer, and dominated the nuclear 4Downsizing lower-level or exit strategies may be unique in this respect: most strategies require ‘buy-in’ from employees which in turn requires some form of incentive compensation at lower ranks. 268 J. Dial, K.J. MurphyJJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 submarine business. The company was renamed General Dynamics Corporation to reflect the firm’s diversified defense operations. GD continued to grow and expand during the next three decades, establishing itself as the only defense contractor to supply major weapons systems to all three branches of the U.S. military. GD also expanded into foreign sales. Its F-16 jet was adopted as the preeminent lightweight fighter jet by the U.S. Air Force and several foreign countries. GD’s Electric Boat division expanded its dominance of the nuclear submarine business; its Convair division added the ‘Tomahawk’ sea-launched cruise missile to its arsenal of standard missile products. During the early 198Os, GD bought Chrysler’s M-l ‘Abrams’ and M-60 tank business and acquired Cessna, a leading manufacturer of civilian aircraft. GD also became involved in several major fracases with the federal government. While GD steadfastly denied accusations of illegal actions (ranging from faulty workmanship to fraudulent claims and illegal gifts), the firm was barred by the Navy for a brief period from receiving new contracts. Unfavorable press coverage damaged GD’s public image. Although GD remained profitable throughout the 198Os, continuing profitability was threatened in the latter half of the decade by changes in the government’s procurement practices, including more dual-source supply, lower progress payments, and greater focus on price competition and fixed-price contracts. 3.2. GD hires Anders as vice chairman On September 27, 1989 GD announced the hiring of William A. Anders as its next Chairman and Chief Executive Officer. The 55-year-old Anders, handpicked by CEO Stanley Pace, agreed to join GD as vice chairman on January 1, 1990 and succeed Pace as Chairman and CEO at his retirement on January 1, 1991. Anders was a former Air Force pilot and Apollo 8 astronaut who orbited the moon on Christmas 1968. He had served as executive secretary of the National Aeronautics and Space Council in Washington (1963-72), commissioner of the Atomic Energy Commission (1973-74), head of the Nuclear Regulatory Commission (197576), and Ambassador to Norway (1976-77). In 1977, he joined General Electric as general manager of its nuclear energy products division and then its aircraft equipment division. In 1984, Anders was named senior executive vice president for operations at Textron, a Rhode Island-based conglomerate. He headed Textron’s defense businesses as well as several consumer products lines. According to Anders, one of the chief concerns in his contract negotiation was assuring his independence from GD’s largest shareholder, the Crown family. Although the Crowns were not directly involved in selecting or recruiting Anders to GD, they had established a reputation for influencing CEO employment decisions. Self-made millionaire Henry Crown originally gained control of three GD board seats in 1959 as the result of the merger between GD and J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 269 Crown’s Material Service Corporation. In 1962, following GD’s disastrous foray into manufacturing commercial airliners, Crown ousted the CEO. In 1966, Crown lost a boardroom power struggle with his personally selected CEO, and was forced to sell his shares and leave the board. Just three years later, Crown and his allies quietly accumulated 18% of GD’s common stock, and Crown effectively regained control of the corporation. Once again he replaced the incumbent CEO. Although Henry Crown died in late 1990, three representatives of the Crown family remained on GD’s board of directors, including corporate Executive Vice President Lester Crown. As of February 1991, the Crown family held over nine million shares of GD stock-about 22% of the 41.9 million outstanding shares (see Appendix A). Anders viewed the existence of a major shareholder as an obstacle rather than a benefit. Anders reflected on the contract negotiations:5 I negotiated a great contract because I wanted total independence. I realized the risk involved in working for a large shareholder [the Crown family] and I wanted to be independent from that risk. First, I wanted GD to make me whole from what I was giving up at Textron. Then, I wanted an agreement so that I would be able to retire on the day I walked in here. That is the kind of independence I wanted so that I could make the changes that were needed and I would not have to be looking over my shoulder at the big shareholder. To lure Anders from Textron, GD ultimately guaranteed a base salary of not less than $550,000 in 1990, increased to not less than $600,000 in 1991. (His actual salary for 1991 was $800,000.) His employment agreement also specified that he would receive annual retirement payments of $250,000 to $500,000 for life, depending on the length of his tenure with GD. Anders also received 30,940 shares of GD stock (worth $1.4 million on January 1, 1990) and 103,746 stock options (with an exercise price of $44.94 and a l/1/90 Black-&holes value of $1.9 million) to offset fringe benefits and deferred compensation associated with his departure from Textron.6 Corporations hiring CEOs from other firms often pay ‘sign-on bonuses’ to compensate for lost benefits: For example, IBM paid Louis Gerstner $5 million for benefits he lost at RJR Nabisco, and Kodak paid George Fisher $5 million for benefits lost at Motorola. An interesting difference in Anders’ case is that his 5Unless otherwise sourced, quotes from Anders are from the teaching and are based on a personal interview conducted in April 1993. case (Murphy and Dial, 1993) 6The number of restricted shares granted was based on the amount Anders would have received if he had stayed at Textron (which in turn depended on Textron’s performance): Anders’ received 13,740 shares, 16,586 shares, and 4,614 shares in 1990, 1991, and 1992 respectively. 210 J. Dial, K.J. MurphyJJoumal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 sign-on bonus was paid in GD stock options and restricted stock, rather than in cash. This stock-based sign-on bonus also ensured that Anders’ option and stockholdings would approximate those of his predecessor, Stanley Pace. 3.3. Company and industry outlook upon Anders’ appointment Anders spent 1990, his first full year with GD (but before he became CEO), undertaking a comprehensive assessment of the company’s strategy, its operations and markets, and its financial structure. Realizing that it was no longer ‘business as usual’, he quickly concluded that GD was heading towards serious financial trouble. GD’s monthly closing stock price had fallen from a high of $79 in February 1987 to $25.25 at the end of 1990; accounting returns had also declined over the same time period. The company absorbed a $578 million net loss in 1990 (on $10.2 billion in sales). These losses were driven by over $1.3 billion in unusual charges, including $700 million in write-offs over its troubled A-12 Navy attack jet program. GD announced 8,500 layoffs in 1990, and both Moody’s and S&P downgraded the firm’s debt ratings, citing its weak financial condition. In December 1990, the Pentagon announced that its audits revealed GD to be in ‘weak’ financial condition with ‘ . . . a possible chance for bankruptcy? World events in 1989 and 1990 had profound implications for the entire U.S. defense industry. In 1989, the U.S.S.R. completed its withdrawal from Afghanistan, allowed Poland’s first free elections, and saw Soviet-backed regimes fall in Hungary, East Germany, Czechoslovakia, Bulgaria, and Romania. In November 1989, the Berlin Wall fell. During 1990, Germany was reunified and the Soviet Union distintegrated. In November 1990, U.S. President George Bush and Soviet President Mikhail Gorbachev, along with other leaders from NATO and the Warsaw Pact, announced the official end of the half-century-old Cold War, promising ‘a new era of democracy, peace, and unity’. Arms-control agreements between the U.S. and the (former) Soviet Union dramatically reduced the current and projected future demand for major defense platforms. The prospects for peace carried particularly harsh ramifications for GD: While other major defense contractors had diversified operations outside of the defense industry, GD received more than 80% of its revenues from the Pentagon. Anders believed that the collapse of the Soviet Union and the end of the Cold War signaled a watershed in defense funding that would permanently affect GD’s market opportunities. This conclusion was reached, in part, by analyzing patterns of U.S. defense spending during wartime and peacetime since 1900, which suggested that Cold War defense spending levels were an aberration not ‘David J. Jefferson and Andrew Pasztor, ‘Pentagon Audits Show Contractors Owe U.S. Hundreds of Millions in A-12 Job’, Wall Street Journal, December 19, 1990. J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 271 sustainable in ‘true’ peacetime. Anders’ prediction of future cuts was supported by federal projections released in early 1991. While the 1991 federal budget authorized $86 billion in procurement spending, the 1992 federal budget (delivered to Congress in January 1991) had revised the 1991 and 1992 budget authority for procurement downward to just $64 billion and $63 billion, respectively.8 3.4. Anders ’ early initiatives as CEO Anders took office as Chairman and CEO on January 1, 1991, and his explicitly stated goal was to transform GD into a shareholder-driven enterprise. He sought to improve company financial performance by maximizing margins from its $23 billion backlog, increase returns, and generate a sharper focus on investments through higher margins, better progress payment rates, and higher hurdle rates. In order to facilitate these operational changes, Anders believed he needed to bring in a new management team, fundamentally alter the corporate culture, and institute compensation systems for the top management team that more closely tied pay to shareholder wealth creation. In spite of the planned reductions in government spending and the warning signals emanating from within GD, Anders faced a major hurdle in convincing his board of directors and existing top managers that GD was, indeed, heading for a crisis. He found that most of the managers at GD (and at other defense firms as well) believed they could maintain the status quo and survive the impending shake-out in the defense industry. Anders brought in a Wall Street analyst to alert the top managers and directors to the severity of GD’s situation. The analyst noted that GD’s price-earnings ratio ranked 497 in the S&P 500. In his ensuing discussions with directors, Anders stressed the need to build a new management team, but emphasized the difficulty of attracting, retaining, and motivating managers in the declining defense industry. Soon after Anders’ appointment as CEO, GD made wholesale management changes at its upper echelons. Eighteen of the top 25 executives were either new to GD or new to their positions. Anders promoted Executive Vice President James Mellor (who had been in charge of submarines, tanks, and overseas sales) to president and chief operating officer. Anders and Mellor were members of GD’s board of directors, which included five top managers, two former Chairman/CEOs, and nine outside directors (see Appendix A). sProcurement appropriations of the Department of Defense finance the acquisition of weapons, equipment, munitions, spares, and modifications of existing equipment. Budget authorityfor procurement includes appropriations for the year enacted as well as spending which is earmarked for future years. Actual spending (which includes budget authority for the year enacted in addition to appropriations carried over from prior years) was estimated at $79 and $74 billion for 1991 and 1992, respectively; actual spending was projected to fall to $67 billion by 1994. 212 J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 Mellor was in charge of operationalizing Anders’ objective of creating wealth for shareholders. An industry analyst lauded the Anders-Mellor team: ‘Anders provides the cold, calculated decision-making needed at the strategic level, and Mellor is very good at getting a lot of people rowing together in the right direction’.’ Anders commented on Mellor’s role: We talked a lot about focusing on shareholder value and each of our top executives was committed to this objective. Even though that was our focus, it was not our strategy because ‘maximize shareholder value’ is difficult to operationalize. Mellor really helped the managers understand how to run their businesses. Just accepting the idea of shareholder value isn’t enough. For a lot of the managers, it was a case of ‘OK, I believe in shareholder value, but what should I do tomorrow?’ Mellor taught them how to manage for cash. Anders’ new business plan called for dividing the company into business areas and pushing decision-making authority further down into the hierarchy. To assist its managers in adjusting to their expanded responsibilities amid the company’s new business approach, GD commissioned Northwestern University’s Kellogg School of Management to develop a special one-week seminar for 150 of its top managers. According to Anders, the intensive training sessions focused on teaching business basics and investment analysis so that GD’s managers would ‘ . . . think like business people, not like aerospace engineers’. 3.5. Executive compensation at General Dynamics Anders sought to focus his management team on maximizing value. He describes the company’s approach: shareholder When we started to build a new management team, we wanted partners, not high salaried people. We needed to attract good people from outside and to entice good insiders to change to different divisions. These managers came here for about the same salaries they had been making, but they needed additional inducements because their careers were riskier at GD. To attract good people and then to change behavior, you have to compensate them well. I didn’t want to take the company private, but I wanted a private-company mentality. I wanted to break out of the ‘hired hand’ mentality. There is an enormous difference between being a smart hired hand and being a partner. ‘Anthony L. Velocci, & Space Technology, Jr., ‘General Dynamics August 5, 1991. Shakeup Aims for Solid Fiscal Footing’, Aviation Week J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 213 They brought me in as a hired hand and I changed it to a partnership arrangement. I wanted to develop a management/shareholder partnership and create an environment where there was no doubt in anyone’s mind about what we were here to do: create shareholder value. In addition to defining the corporate objective and building a new and better-trained management team, Anders decided it was crucial for GD’s executive compensation policies to provide meaningful and appropriate incentives for its top-level managers. GD’s existing compensation packages included base salaries, bonuses tied to the company’s accounting return on equity, and stock options. Anders felt that relying on accounting-based bonuses provided inappropriate incentives for a shareholder-value-focused company requiring dramatic changes in its strategy and culture. Furthermore, the outstanding stock options-granted in prior years at exercise prices far exceeding the current stock price-also failed to provide meaningful incentives. Under Anders’ recommendation to the compensation committee, approximately 25 top executives would earn cash ‘Gain/Sharing’ bonuses for improvements in the stock price, 150 upper-level executives would receive accelerated stock option and restricted stock grants, and 1,150 managers and executives would be eligible to participate in an ‘option exchange’ program in which previously granted options could be exchanged for new options at a lower exercise price. The proposal also included changes in the company’s savings and investment plan (SIP) to encourage lower-level employees to hold GD stock (approximately 62,000 employees). These proposals were accepted (with minor modifications) by the four outside directors who comprised the compensation committee, approved by the full board of directors on February 15, 1991, and approved by shareholders at the May 1, 1991 annual meeting. 3.5.1. Incentives, bonuses, restricted stock, and stock options At its February 15, 1991 meeting, the committee approved approximately 1.6 million shares of stock option awards in addition to bonuses of $19 million in cash and restricted stock for the 1,150 eligible employees. Table 1 shows the base salaries, bonus awards, and 1991 restricted stock and stock option awards. Each option, exercisable beginning August 1992 and expiring in February 2001, gave the recipient the right to buy one share of common stock at an exercise price of $25.5625 (the market price on the February 15 grant date). Shares of restricted stock vested over time: 40% became unrestricted four years after the grant date, and thereafter at a rate of 10% per year, contingent on continued employment. In accordance with Anders’ proposal to accelerate option and restricted stock grants for the company’s top 150 executive officers, option grants were approximately three times the normal annual award for each individual, and the committee ‘promised’ that a similar number of restricted shares would be awarded in 1992 and 199.3. In contrast to typical restricted Table 1 Salaries, bonuses, restricted stock, and stock options awards approved Incentive awards granted by General in February Restricted 1991 base salary Executive William Anders Chairman/CEO James Mellor President/COO Lester Crown Executive VP . . . . . . . . . . . . Other “Some Shares grantedb Shares promised’ Number of stock optio& Total options after new grants and exchange 271,359 $650,000 $300,000 15,000 30,OQO 120,000 13,613 133,613 $303,000 $200,000 5,550 13,250 48,500 11,862 60,362 . . . . 1991 and December (including . , $2,632,000 94,260 253,410 829,350 249,206 . .. 1,078,556 $11,371,749 . . 93,880 . . .. . 150,450 . . ... .. .. . 134,230 288,556 1,022,786 $14,009,749 188,140 1,563,580 537,762 2,101,342 . . 1991 proxy $180,000 to Mr. ‘Restricted promised awards New options acquired by exchanging old options stock 51,479 given at the fair market stock 1991 219,880 bRestricted stock awards price of $24.3125. dOptions granted of $24.3125. 15, 1991 44,910 $9,416,100 cash awards on February 20,850 All participants March committee S500,OOO participants Source: compensation $800,0000 . Executive officers as a group’ 1991 cash bonuses” Dynamics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . I . . . . . 403,860 statements. Crown) made in unrestricted price of $25.5625. for 1992 and 1993. These at an exercise price of $25.5625. ‘Amounts based on 36 executives 1991 proxy statement). . (from shares of common of executives shares were ultimately Some options for 1991 base salary Some awards for executives December conveyed stock. other than those listed made on March in December 1991 other than those listed were granted 6, 1991 proxy statement) 5, 1991, at a market and 29 executives on March for incentive 5, 1991, at an exercise awards (from March price 28. J. Dial, K.J. MurphyJJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 275 stock awards in which the manager receives a fixed dollar value of stock each year, GD’s fixed-share promise means that those shares start providing incentives in 1991, years before they are conveyed. In addition to the option award program, the compensation committee also approved an ‘option exchange’ program that allowed executives to exchange their ‘out-of-the-money’ options (i.e., options with an exercise price above the February 1991 market price) for a lesser number of ‘at-the-money’ options (i.e., options with an exercise price equal to the market price). The 1,150 executives holding options elected to exchange approximately 1.94 million options with average exercise prices of about $55 for about 538,000 new options with an exercise price of $25.5625. The exchanges were prorated on the basis of the Black-Scholes (1973) value of options already held versus the Black-&holes value at the new lower strike prices. For example, Anders exchanged the 103,746 options granted upon his appointment at an exercise price of $44.94 (with an aggregate Black-Scholes value of $388,000) for 51,479 options at an exercise price of $25.5625 (with an aggregate Black-Scholes value of $388,000, based on stock volatility of 24.25%, dividend yield of 4%, risk-free rate of 8%, and expiration periods of nine and ten years for the old and new options, respectively). In addition, as shown in Table 1, Anders received 219,800 ‘new’ options, giving him a total of 271,359 options, each with an option price of $25.5625. Although it is common for companies to reprice options following declines in stock prices, CD’s option exchange program was unusual because it yielded repriced options at no additional cost to shareholders. [We note that by reducing the number of options upon exchange, GD’s exchange program was ‘acceptable’ according to the criteria outlined in Crystal and Foulkes (1988).] Anders’ financial incentives to increase stock prices declined, however. Prior to the exchange, each $1 increase in GD’s stock price (from $25.5625) increased the Black-Scholes value of Anders’ 103,746 old options by $39,000, compared to an increase of only $28,000 for his 51,479 new options. Moreover, based on the subsequent increase in GD’s stock prices to ($142 by year-end 1993, including special distributions) Anders’ participation in the exchange program personally cost him more than $4 million ex post. 3.5.2. The Gain/Sharing Plan The most unusual and ultimately controversial part of the compensation program proposed by Anders and approved by the compensation committee at the February 15 meeting was the Gain/Sharing Plan. In contrast to typical bonus plans based on accounting performance, GD’s plan was based on stockprice performance, awarding cash bonuses for each $10 increase in the company’s stock price (representing a $417 million increase in shareholder value). Under the program, GD’s top executives would receive a bonus equal to 100% of their base salaries if GD’s stock price closed at or above $35.5625 (i.e., $10 above the February 15 price) and stayed at or above this level for ten 276 J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 consecutive trading days. For each subsequent $10 increase sustained for ten consecutive trading days, the executives would receive additional bonuses equal to 200% of their base salaries. The 25 executives- with combined base salaries of $6.3 million- who ultimately participated in Gain/Sharing would receive approximately 1.5% of the increase in shareholder value for the first $10 increase, and 3% for subsequent $10 increases in GD’s stock price. There was no limit on the number of bonuses as long as the stock price continued to climb. The expiration date of the program was February 15, 1994. Half of each award was to be deferred until retirement; the other half would be paid in cash, although the amount could be deferred at the recipient’s request. The deferred portion would accrue interest at a rate of five percentage points above the prime interest rate (or Moody’s corporate bond rate, if higher). At the committee’s discretion, the interest rate would be reduced if the firm’s share prices fell below certain levels in the days immediately following announcements of company earnings. Executives participating in the committee’s proposed Gain/Sharing Plan included Anders, Mellor, CFO James Cunnane, nine corporate vice presidents responsible for functional business performance, four operating group executive vice presidents, and several division and business-area heads. Executive Vice President Lester Crown endorsed the plan but voluntarily elected not to participate. Anders conceived of the Gain/Sharing Plan as a means to institute his ‘partnership’ approach to the management of the firm. Anders, who believed GD’s stock price could climb to at most $45 by 1994, described the initial discussions with the board on the Gain/Sharing initiative: Keep in mind that originally upside. When we developed asked to be left out of it. I felt the plan that I had conceived. in which I didn’t participate. it didn’t look like there was that great an and presented it to the Board, I originally somewhat uncomfortable including myself in However, the Board wouldn’t hear of a plan Anders confided that GD honestly hadn’t much thought about the appropriateness of the ten-day window; it was recommended by compensation committee chairman Elliot Stein, who had employed a similar window in a plan at Ralston-Purina.” 3.5.3. Savings and stock investmentplan To encourage a partnership mentality among lower-level employees, Anders recommended, and the compensation committee approved, charfges in the “In the Ralston-Purina plan, the CEO received a large grant of restricted stock for achieving a stock price of $100 for ten days. The plan was ultimately controversial, not because of the ten-day window but rather because the $100 hurdle was met during a period in which the company was underperforming the industry and market (Campbell and Wasley, 1994). J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (199.5) 261-314 217 company’s Savings and Stock Investment Plan (SIP), which covered approximately 62,000 employees. Prior to 1991, the company contributed 75# for each $1 invested by the employee and allowed employees to designate how the company’s contribution was invested. Under the new plan, GD would match employees dollar-for-dollar for investments in the company’s common stock while the company’s contribution would be only 50# for every dollar placed in any investment other than the GD common stock fund. Prior to the introduction of the new SIP, 20,600 GD employees held 3.7 million shares of company stock. This represented 23% of GD’s employees and 8.8% of the shares outstanding. By June 1991, the number of employees participating in the program jumped to 48,300 (54%) and the shares held by these employees increased to 4.3 million (10.3%). By June 1992, employees held 6.2 million shares, representing almost 15% of the shares outstanding. 3.6. General Dynamics under William Anders, 1991 After Anders was named CEO on January 1, 1991, he moved swiftly to streamline operations and improve profitability. Consistent with his belief that increased expenditures in the defense industry were inefficient, Anders reduced GD’s capital expenditures to $82 million in 1991 from $321 million in 1990 and $419 million in 1989. Similarly, R&D spending was cut to half of the $390 million spent in 1990. GD also emphasized reductions in inventories and working capital in order to reduce costs and improve returns. A chronology of GD events from 1991 through 1993-including three-day industry and market-relative stock-price reactions surrounding each event-is reported in Appendix B. As described in this Appendix, GD’s stock fell to about $20 early in 1991 when the Navy’s A-12 jet fighter program was canceled. Soon after, the United States and 27.other nations joined in Operation Desert Storm, the military response to Iraq’s August 1990 invasion of Kuwait. The air war began on January 17, and the four-day ground war ensued on February 24. GD’s marquee products (‘Tomahawk cruise missiles, F-16 fighters, and M-l ‘Abrams’ tanks) performed spectacularly, but Anders discounted the long-term effect on firm profitability, arguing that the war’s cost would ultimately reduce development budgets for new weapons.’ ’ In early February 1991, the federal government allowed GD and McDonnell Douglas to delay repayment of $1.4 billion in unliquidated progress payments made on the canceled A-12. The companies claimed that repayment would cause extreme financial pressures. Later that month, following the February 15 board meeting approving the new compensation programs, Anders bought 10,000 GD “William Saporito, ‘America’s Arsenal: This War Doesn’t Mean a Windfall: General Dynamics’, Fortune, February 25, 1991. 278 J. Dial, so ) Jan I Feb K.J. Murphy/Journal I Mar , *er of Financial 1 May I Jlul Economics I Jul I *w 3 7 (I 995) 261-3 1 Sep I Ott I4 I Nov I Dee Fig. 2. Stock-price performance of General Dynamics, 1991. Daily stock prices from Dow Jones News Retrieval and Compustat. GD-related events from company press releases, analyst reports, and the Wall StreetJournal. Industry and S&P 500 prices are determined by appreciating GD’s January 1, 1991 price by the cumulative returns on the industry and S&P 500 portfolios. shares at $25.25, and Mellor bought 5,000 shares at $25.00 (these purchases are included in Appendix A).i2 As shown in Fig. 2 and Appendix B, GD’s stock jumped over 20% (from $23.75 to over $29, representing an industry-adjusted gain of $218 million) in the space of a few days in mid-March 1991 on the strength of ‘buy’ recommendations from three Wall Street investment banks. The analysts noted Anders willingness to take ‘dramatic actions’ and recommended the stock on the basis of three key points: GD’s new incentive plans throughout the ranks (especially those that gave managers incentives to focus on shareholder value), reductions in capital and R&D spending, and the possibility of stock repurchases to return cash to shareholders. Within days, GD announced that it would lay off 2,000 employees at its Fort Worth, Texas F-16 jet fighter plant. In late March, South Korea ‘stunned observers’ when it awarded GD a $5.2 billion order of 120 F-16 ‘*Alexandra 1991. Peers, ‘Some Insiders, Bucking Trend, Buy Stock’, Wall Street Journal, April 10, J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 11995) 261-314 219 jet fighters, reversing a prior award to McDonnell Douglas for their F-18 fighter and pushing GD’s stock price up 7%.13 On April 23, the federal government selected the team led by Lockheed, which included GD and Boeing, to build the Air Force’s next generation advanced tactical fighter (ATF). The program was expected to generate $60 billion in revenues for the companies. Following the announcement, GD’s stock closed up 6.4% to $36.875, surpassing the Gain/Sharing hurdle of $35.5625. 3.61. The first Gain/Sharing payofs On May 1, a majority of shareholders (78%) voted their approval of the new Executive Compensation Program, which included the Gain/Sharing provisions. The same day, GD’s President Mellor made an announcement widely interpreted as predicting massive layoffs at the defense giant: ‘Our current workforce is just over 90,000 employees. In response to the decline in the defense market, present projections indicate that this may be reduced by about 30% over the next four years.’ GD’s stock price closed at $39, up over 3%. Just five days later, on May 6, GD’s stock closed above $35.56 for the tenth consecutive trading day, triggering $5.1 million in Gain/Sharing bonuses for 19 executives. The next day, Anders bought another 5,000 shares at $39.50. The announcement of the bonuses within a week of shareholder ratification drew howls of protest. Business Week dubbed the company ‘Generous Dynamics’, and quoted a Pentagon official warning Anders not to bill the ‘outrageous’ compensation to government contracts. The media was particularly harsh to former outside director and compensation committee member Harvey Kapnick, who qualified for inclusion in the bonus plan when he was named vice chairman in April 1991.14 His cash bonus was prorated for the difference between GD’s $33.50 average share price on the day he began work (April 15) and the closing price on May 6; thus, Kapnick received a Gain/Sharing bonus equal to 20.625% of his $600,000 salary, or $123,750. 3.6.2. The second Gain/Sharing payof In spite of the negative publicity, the stock market continued to be enamored with the changes occurring at GD. As shown in Fig. 2, the share price leveled out in late summer at $44 as GD won a $750 million contract to build 641 M-l tanks. GD continued to announce layoffs, 1,500 more in 1992 in addition to the 2,500 already slated for 1991. On September 22, with the stock price hovering in the low $4Os, GD announced the sale of its Data Systems unit to Computer Sciences for $184 million. 13Rick Wartzman and Damon Darlin, Journal, March 29, 1991, p. A3. 14James E. Ellis, ‘More ‘South Cash than a Lottery’, Korea, Business in a Reversal, Week, May Picks F-16 Jet’, Wall 20, 1991, p. 42. Street 280 J. Dial, K.J. MurphyJJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 Two days later, Anders addressed Morgan Stanley’s Aerospace/Defense and Multi-Industry Conference and made two startling announcements. First, he dismissed diversification as a viable strategy for GD, citing a McKinsey study that claimed an 80% failure rate for nondefense acquisitions by defense contractors. Second, he predicted that cash flows would be in excess of that required to fund the firm’s current liquidity and investment needs. He suggested returning ‘excess’ cash to shareholders using unspecified methods that might include stock buybacks, increased dividends, special distributions, or self tenders. These announcements- which the Washington Post, citing Anders’ potential bonus, dubbed ‘the $1.6 million speech’-caused the stock price to jump $7.75 over two days (reflecting an industry-adjusted increase in shareholder wealth of $343 million), rocketing past the Gain/Sharing bonus target and closing at $49.50. Ten trading days later, October 8, GD announced a second Gain/Sharing payout of $12.6 million (200% of the top managers’ base salaries), bringing the total payout to the 25 participants in the plan to almost $18 million (or about 2.1% of the $833 million increase in GD’s market value). Both Gain/Sharing payoffs generated widespread criticism among politicians, labor unions, GD employees, and shareholder groups. For the most part, shareholder groups voiced concerns about the mechanics of the plan, questioning in particular the appropriateness of the ten-day window. Criticism from other sectors focused on the political ‘incorrectness’ of paying large cash bonuses amid announcements of layoffs and downsizing. 3.63. Reaction to Gain/Sharing’s ten-day window Gain/Sharing’s ten-day window prompted criticism that managers would make announcements or take actions that increase short-term, but not longterm, stock prices. For example, Howard Sherman, vice president of Institutional Shareholder Services, argued that ‘ . . . a ten-day plateau is nowhere near a good measure of long-term success’.l5 Institutional proxy advisor Anne Faulk agreed, calling the plan ‘ . . . a bastardization of a good idea. Ten days just isn’t a very long time, and you won’t see management’s salaries going down when the share price falls’.’ 6 Although managers may be able to manipulate prices in the very short term by deliberately misleading analysts and investors, there is no evidence that Anders ever attempted to mislead investors: indeed, the ‘$1.6 million speech’ that triggered the second bonus was presented to industry stock-market analysts who were keenly aware of the possibility of being misled. It is worth noting that, relative to conventional bonus plans based on accounting returns, it is easier to “Robert J. McCartney, ‘A Most Unusual Executive Bonus Plan’, Washington Post, October 21, 1991, p. Al. 16James E. Ellis, ‘More Cash than a Lottery’, Business Week, May 20, 1991, p. 42. .I Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 3 7 (I 995) 261-314 281 manipulate annual earnings for several consecutive years than it is to manipulate stock prices for two business weeks. It is also worth noting that in conventional stock appreciation rights plans, which pay in cash the difference between the current stock price and a given exercise price, it is sufficient to increase stock prices for a single day or a single moment. Thus, the ten-day window, while admittedly short, arguably provides better long-term incentives than conventional bonus and stock appreciation right plans. Still, a longer window would have provided the same financial payments to GD executives, while generating substantially less criticism among the media and shareholder groups. 3.6.4. Reaction to paying Gain/Sharing bonusesamid layoffs GD’s unionized work force was openly critical of the Gain/Sharing bonuses. A UAW: official said: ‘They’re really slopping at the trough’.” Employees expressed their feelings in the Mole, an underground newsletter circulated at GD’s jet plant in Fort Worth, commenting: ‘Anders promises ‘gut wrenching cultural change’ throughout the corporation. It isn’t clear whose gut he proposes to wrench, but it won’t be the brave 25 that have had the courage to fearlessly look out for themselves’.18 Many were outraged that the bonuses were being paid while thousands of the rank and file were being laid off. Others protested that the bonuses were much too concentrated among a tiny cadre of senior executives. Dean Girardot, GD’s coordinator for the International Association of Machinists, asked: ‘Why is there just Gain/Sharing for the 255most of them relative newcomers- while people who have worked in the trenches for many years are losing their jobs?“’ One outspoken critic of GD’s compensation policies was former compensation consultant Graef Crystal, who claimed that ‘ . . . this ill-conceived plan smacks of the Marie Antoinette school of management’, a reference to the extravagant French monarch who showed callous disregard for the poor people in her country. *O Crystal justified his attack: First of all, the stock rose from a ‘trough’, . . . and all these bonuses came while General Dynamics was ‘downsizing’. . . . It’s a scenario that hits you in the gut. This is not a case where somebody’s making a lot of money r7Robert October “Rick J. McCartney, 9, 1991, p. Fl. Wartzman, ‘Defense ‘General Wall Street Journal, October “Robert October J. McCartney, 9, 1991. “James E. Ellis, ‘Layoffs 1991, p. 34. Firm’s Executives Dynamics Head Outlines 31, 1991, p. A3. ‘Defense Firm’s Executives on the Line, Bonuses Reap Bonus Plan to Cope Reap in the Executive Bonanza’, with Falling Bonus Suite’, Bonanza’, Washington Post, Defense Budgets’, Washington Post, Business Week, October 21, 282 J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal ofFinancial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 because the company’s doing great. This is a case of a guy getting lots of money, and he’s an island of prosperity in a sea of misery.. . 21 . . . The CEO of General Dynamics must be the laziest man in the world. Look at all the incentive plans they have to give him to go to work in the morning.22 The outrage over GD’s Gain/Sharing bonuses illustrates the important distinction between the politics and the economics of executive compensation. Providing incentives to create value under excess capacity virtually mandates paying bonuses during layoffs. In addition, concentrating incentive rewards at the top management level can be economically justified in GD’s situation, since the decision to downsize is made and implemented exclusively by top management and can be accomplished without ‘buy-in’ and meaningful incentives for rank-and-file employees. But the criticisms of Gain/Sharing were largely political rather than economic: CD’s management was accused of being ‘insensitive to outside perceptions’23 by not suffering along with its workers. Some critics noted that the high payments to GD executives negatively affected employee morale. GD employees demonstrated at GD’s San Diego plant, for example, carrying placards that read: ‘No Bogus Bonus for Bill’. We speculate that declining morale among the rank-and-file employees had more to do with bleak long-term employment prospects in the defense industry than with Anders’ pay: Employee morale in growing firms (such as Disney) does not appear to be affected by high top-management pay, and we suspect morale would have suffered at GD even if Anders worked for free. As an interesting contrast to the GD situation, DeAngelo and DeAngelo (1991) find that labor concessions in the steel industry were routinely coupled with cuts in top management’s cash compensation: management pay is significantly lower during years with union negotiations than in years without negotiations. The authors argue that the managerial pay cuts are implemented as ‘ . . . symbolic sacrifices that encourage all stakeholders to participate in the concessions needed to salvage the firm’. An important difference between the domestic steel industry in the 1980s and the defense industry in the 1991 is that the steel industry was already in a crisis (generated in part by ignoring the implications of nonunionized global competition developing over the course of the previous several decades) while GD was responding to early warning signs of a potential crisis in the future. Critics who argued that GD’s management 21Peter Carlson, ‘Chairmen of the Bucks’, Washington Post Magazine, April 5, 1992, p. 15. 22Alison Leigh Cowan, ‘The Gadfly CEOs Want to Swat’, New York Times, February 2, 1992. 23Richard Ullman of Institutional Shareholder Services, quoted in Aviation Week & Space Technology, November 18, 1991, p. 58. J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 283 should have suffered along with its workers beg the question (we return to this in Section 5): Could GD’s ultimate performance have been obtained without the high-powered incentives that generated large bonuses amid layoffs? 3.6.5. The compensation committee’s response Even as the firm’s stock price continued to climb, GD’s board of directors was bombarded by criticism. The compensation committee (which met 15 times in 1991, compared to only six times during 1990) was keenly aware of the negative reaction to the company’s compensation policies. Moreover, given Anders’ public intention to ‘return excess cash’ to shareholders, the committee was concerned that future announcements of special distributions might cause stock prices to jump past another Gain/Sharing hurdle, further fueling the media criticism. The compensation committee settled on a revised plan at a meeting on December 3, at which point the stock price was $49. Shareholders approved the plan at a special meeting on January 15, 1992. Under the new plan, executives received final Gain/Sharing bonuses for the increase in share value between the second bonus payout in October and $49 (the stock price on December 3). As shown in Table 2, the 25 participating executives received final bonuses of $4.5 million, bringing the total payments under the plan to $22.3 million. In addition, the executives received stock options with exercise prices of $49 in lieu of the Gain/Sharing Plan. The numbers of options were chosen to provide a gain upon exercise equivalent to the bonus each participant would have received had the Gain/Sharing Plan remained in effect. For example, Anders received 160,000 options. A $10 increase in stock price would thus equate to a $1.6 million increase in the exercise value of the option, twice Anders’ annual salary. Finally, the executives received the restricted stock awards promised in February, but not scheduled to be conveyed until 1992 and 1993 (see Table 1). During the period in which the Gain/Sharing Plan was in effect (February 15 to December 3), GD’s stock price rose from $25.5625 to $49 per share, a wealth gain of $1,022 million for shareholders. Based on the methodology described in Table 9, about $99 million of this gain reflects general market stock-price movements, $35 million reflects industry-specific movements, and - $15 million reflects world events and announcements related to GD that cannot be directly attributed to GD’s new strategy and incentives.24 Approximately $614 million of the increase can be directly traced to announcements related to GD’s strategic initiatives, and much of the ‘unexplained’ $289 million is plausibly linked indirectly with GD’s initiatives. The total Gain/Sharing payouts of $22.3 million to GD’s executives amounts to 2.18% of the total shareholder gain, and between 2.5% and 3.6% of the gain attributable to the action’s of GD’s management. 24Table 9 provides estimates for the entire 1991 calendar year, while the data in this paragraph refer only to the period from February 15 to December 3, 1991. Table 2 Gain/Sharing awards for General Dynamics top executives Executive May award William A. Anders Chairman Dec. award Total Gain/Sharing Options at $49.00 $800,000 $1600,000 rS550,000a S2,950,000 160,000 $650,000 %1,300,000 $446,875 %2,396,875 130,000 $123,750 %1,200,000 $412,500 $1,736,250 120,000 $0 SO $0 $0 0 and CEO James R. Mellor President Oct. award and COO Harvey Kapnick Vice Chairman Lester Crownb Executive VP ... ... .... ... ... .. .... ... ... .... ... ... ... ... .... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... .... ... .. ... ... ... ... ... .. ... ... ... ... ... .................................. .... ..... .................................................................................................................................... Number of executives 19 25 25 5 25 included .. . ................................................................................................................................... ............... ...........................I.................................................................................................. Executive officers $5,168,750 $4,513,438 $22,334,876 1,313,000 $12,652,688 as a group Source: GD Special Meeting Proxy Statement, December 6, 1991. “Since the increase at this time to $49 represented 34.375% of the $10 interval between $45.5625 and $55.5625, Anders’ received a final Gain/Sharing bonus of $550,000 (or 34.375% of twice his $800,000 base sakrry). bMr. Crown elected not to participate in the Gain/Sharing Plan, J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 285 The vehement public reaction to GD’s Gain/Sharing bonuses, coupled with the boards response to replace Gain/Sharing with conventional stock options, are evidence of the importance of political forces in shaping compensation policies (Jensen and Murphy, 1990). The GD experience is also consistent with the hypothesis that gains from options are politically more acceptable than gains paid in cash. In particular, criticism regarding GD’s compensation policies largely evaporated after GD replaced Gain/Sharing with conventional stock options, even though the payouts under the two plans were virtually identical (apart from the discontinuities imbedded in Gain/Sharing). Moreover, while Anders was heavily criticized for his Gain/Sharing bonuses of $2.95 million (accounting for approximately 0.3% of the total gain to shareholders), the $8.6 million appreciation of his restricted stock and options over the same time period escaped media attention. Similarly, the media focused on the $22.3 million Gain/Sharing payments to GD’s top management team, but ignored the $37 million appreciation the team realized on their options and restricted stock over the same ten months.25 The gains that top managers and the Crown family earned on their individual stockholdings also eluded notice, even though these gains were large relative to the Gain/Sharing payouts and were also associated with layoffs and downsizing. 3.7. Anders articulates and implements GD ‘s strategy Although Anders had embraced the corporate objective of creating shareholder value upon his January 1991 appointment, the corporate strategy he developed to achieve this objective evolved during 1991 and 1992. An early indicator of the strategy- his pledge to not pursue diversification into nondefense businesses-was revealed at the September 1991 Morgan Stanley conference. Three weeks later, on October 16, GD announced that its largest nondefense subsidiary, Cessna Aircraft, was for sale. Later that month, in GD’s third-quarter report to shareholders, Anders announced that GD was studying all of its nondefense operations to determine if they should be separated from the company. By the end of 1991, Anders was publicly urging the industry to both downsize and consolidate its businesses in order to ‘rationalize excess capacity’. He argued that only the top one or two contractors in a particular segment could survive the coming shake-out in defense. Anders stressed that no one should invest and grow in the defense industry (with the exception of a few market niches); only the strongest competitors should maintain investments; and that most should be ZSCalculations based on options and current and promised restricted stock in Table 1 plus restricted stock held prior to February 1991, including 30,326 shares for Anders and 110,620 shares for all other top executives. 286 J. Dial, K.J. MurphyJJournal of Financial Economics 37 (199s) 261.-314 managing for cash and taking money out of the defense segment. Some should simply exit the industry.26 In May 1992, Anders announced GD’s strategy within its defense businesses. Anders said GD would remain in businesses only where it could be # 1 or # 2 in the market, and only if it could achieve ‘critical mass’ with production large enough to justify dedicated factories. Anders announced that GD was prepared to buy businesses from, or sell businesses to, other parties in order to meet these ‘market leadership’ and ‘critical mass’ criteria. He identified four businesses within GD’s core defense capabilities that passed these two screens-military aircraft, nuclear submarines, land systems (tanks), and space systems-and announced a formal ‘plan of contraction’ in which the company would seek to sell units outside these four core defense businesses. Anders discussed the rationale for this strategy and the reasoning behind the definition of the core segments: When we assessed our businesses, we didn’t look at them in terms of core businesses, we looked at our core competencies.Our core competence is in heavy-weight defense platforms. We also looked at efficiencies. The first test was whether we were or could be # 1 or # 2 in a market. The second test was whether each of these businesses could pass the criticaZ mass test. Could we justify dedicated factories for these products based on the scale we could achieve? The tank plant makes sense, subs make it, and tactical aircraft make it. Missiles did not make it. They are not our core competence; they are a commodity business where supply far exceeds demand. The difference between GD and the rest of the defense industry is that we wanted to sell nondefense businesses. And we were willing to fix any business by buying, selling, or merging. We were dedicated to shareholders and building franchises. Too many executives at other defense contractors are fixated on bigger is better. But, when the industry has excess capacity, the focus on continued growth just doesn’t work. 3.7.1. Salesof divisions and subsidiaries Table 3 summarizes GD’s sales of divisions between November 1991 and December 1993. GD sold the Data Systems Unit to Computer Sciences Corp. for $184 million, the Cessna Aircraft subsidiary to Textron for $600 million, its missile business to GM’s Hughes Electronics subsidiary for $450 million, its Electronics Division to Carlyle Group for $52 million, and the lime and brick operations of its Material Services businesses for $46 million. *‘See, for example, William A. Anders, ‘Rationalizing America’s Defense Industry’, keynote address at the 12th annual Defense Week conference, October 30, 1991. J. Dial, Table 3 General Dynamics K.J. Murphy/Journal divisions of Financial Economics 37 (1995) Division Buyer 1 l/91 2192 8192 11192 3193 12/93 12193 Data Systems Cessna Missiles Electronics Military Aircraft Material Services’ Space Systems csc Sale price ($ millions) 0 Martin “Total bFigure ‘Lime 1991 revenues ($ millions) $12b 797 1,385 218 2,719 nia 363 $184 600 450 52 1,525 46 209 Textron Hughes Aircraft Carlyle Group Lockheed Marietta Total $3,066 GD annual 1991 GD 287 sold in 1991-1993 Disposition date Source: 261-314 $5,494 reports. revenues were $9.548 million. is for 1990. and brick operations only. 1991 revenues and buyer’s identity not available. To achieve the ‘critical mass’ goal in GD’s core businesses, Anders began discussions with Lockheed to acquire its tactical military aircraft business to pair with GD’s Fort Worth Division. Lockheed rebuffed GD’s overtures but agreed that consolidation was necessary, and in December 1992 offered to acquire GD’s jet business for $1.525 million. The divestiture of one of the company’s ‘core businesses’ prompted speculation that GD was on a liquidation path. 27 In December 1993, GD agreed to sell another of its core businessesSpace Systems- to Martin Marietta for $209 million. Anders stressed that although human and physical assets would ultimately have to leave the industry, GD’s assets were in general being consolidated into other companiesz8 After the dispositions, GD is a much smaller and more-focused company with two core divisions (submarines, tanks). In 1993, GD reported sales from continuing operations of $3.2 billion, a 66% decline from its $9.5 billion sales two years earlier. 3.7.2. Employment Along with the sale of business units, GD continued to reduce its work force in its remaining units. As shown in Table 4, total employment at year-end 1993 “Jeff Cole, ‘Lockheed December 10, 1992. *‘Jeff Cole, Wall Street ‘Swords Journal, to Buy General into Shares: General November 3, 1992. Dynamics Fighter Plane Dynamics Contemplates Unit’, Selling Wall Street Journal, Its Remaining Units’, 288 J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 Table 4 General Dynamics work force reductions by business segment, 1991-1993 Business segment Core defense Military aircraft Nuclear submarines Tanks Space systems” Total core defense Noncore defense Nondefenseb Corporate staff . . .. Total 1990 employment 28,400 22,500 7,200 5,200 . 63,000 14,300 19,900 650 . . 98,150 Employment reductions through layoffs and attrition Units sold: Employment at disposition Units retained: 1993 employment 7,200 5,500 2,200 1,500 21,200 16,400 3,000 7,400 450 . . 27,250 24,900 11,300 7,900 0 17,000 5,ooo 0 . 22,000 0 4,600 200 3,700 . . 44,100 26,800 Annual reports and company estimates. “Employees in the space-systemsdivision are restated as leaving in 1993, although the sale to Martin Marietta was not completed until April 1994. ‘Classified as discontinued operations. Source: stood at 26,800, a 73% reduction from the 98,150 employees at GD when Anders was appointed in 1991. The exhibit shows that 28% of GD’s 1990 workforce left through attrition or were laid off (most occurring in 1991), while 45% were active employees when their business units were sold (mostly in 1992 and 1993). The company has not estimated the number of employees laid off subsequent to these sales. The corporate headquarters staff fell from 650 to about 200. In order to reduce the overhead burden on the remaining businesses, the company announced plans to cut the corporate staff to just 50 by the end of 1994. The company offered basic outplacement services for its discharged employees, including counseling, help with resumes, and compiling and posting job opportunities. Most of GD’s discharged employees received three to six months salary upon dismissal (pursuant to labor agreements), and some corporate staff employees who had been recently relocated received additional compensation. Apart from offering limited computer tutoring at some locations, GD offered no formal training programs for its discharged employees. 3.7.3. Shareholders and shareholders ’ distributions As shown in Table 5, GD’s cash balance (before distributions) grew from $100 million in January 1991 to over $4 billion by the end of 1993. GD used its J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 289 261-314 Table 5 Simplified statement of sources and uses of cash for General Dynamics, 1991-1993 Sources of cash $ billions Uses of cash Cash balance (l/91) From operations From dispositions Transactions costs and taxes . . . . ..... ..... .. . . Total $0.1 1.6 3.0 (0.7) .. Debt retired Dividends Share repurchase (6/92) Special distributions . . . . . $4.0 Subtotal Cash balance ( 12/93) % billions $0.6 0.2 1.0 1.6 .. . . ... . . $3.4 $0.6 cash balance to: l l l l retire approximately 94% ($575 million) of the company’s debt, bringing GD’s total debt to just $38 million by December 1993; increase annual dividends from $1 per share to $1.60 in March 1992 and to $2.40 in October 1993; in March 1994, GD increased its annual dividend to $2.80 (prior to a 2: 1 stock split); repurchase over 13.2 million shares for $960 million (at an average of $72.75 per share) through a Dutch auction in June 1992; return $50 per share to shareholders in 1993 through special distributions in March ($20/share), June ($18/share), and October ($12/share). By December 1993 the company had returned $3.4 billion to shareholders and debtholders, and had a remaining cash balance of nearly $600 million (approximately six times its cash balance in January 1, 1991). The composition of CD’s shareholders changed substantially in the summer of 1992. During the course of the Dutch auction in June, the Crown family tendered almost 4.9 million shares, reducing their stake in GD from 22% to 14.3%. Employees who held shares through GD’s SIP reduced their aggregate holdings from 14.7% to about 10% during the June auction. On July 24, investor Warren Buffett of Berkshire Hathaway announced the purchase of 4.35 million shares for about $73/share. He amassed a 15% stake in GD, thus surpassing the Crown family as GD’s largest shareholder. In a show of confidence in GD’s management, he gave the company his proxy to vote his shares ‘ . . . as long as Mr. Anders remains as chief executive officer of General Dynamics’.29 29’Business Brief: Warren Buffett Gives General Dynamics a Proxy to Vote Berkshire’s 15% stake’, Wall Street Journal, September 18, 1992. In May 1993, Buffet revised his grant of proxy to last ‘as long as Mr. Anders remains as chairman of General Dynamics’. J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal 290 of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 $60 $50 Jan Feb Mu Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Ott NW Dee J~tF&b 1992 Mar Fig. 3. Stock-price performance of General Dynamics, 1992-1993. Daily stock prices from Dow Jones News Retrieval and Compustat. GD-related events from company press releases, analyst reports, and the Wall Street Journal. Industry and S&P 500 prices are determined by appreciating GD’s January 1, 1992 price by the cumulative returns on the industry and S&P 500 portfolios. As shown in Fig. 3, GD’s stock price rose from $55 to over $92 between January 1992 and December 1993-even after %3.25/share in dividends and $50/share in special distributions. The market capitalization of GD grew from $1.05 billion in January 1991 to $2.87 billion in December 1993, during which time shareholders received $154 million in dividends, $1.55 billion in special distributions, and $960 million through the Dutch auction. Thus, ignoring reinvestment of the proceeds from dividends and other distributions, shareholders gained almost $4.5 billion from 1991 through 1993, representing a three-year return of 426%. Individual shareholders not participating in the repurchase and reinvesting dividends in GD stock realized a return of 553%. The remarkable success of GD’s strategy silenced many critics. For example, in October 1992, Prudential Bathe fired aerospace analyst (and GD critic) Paul Nisbet, citing poor stock-picking performance. In early 1991, Nisbet urged investors to sell their GD stock (priced at about $30), arguing that the stock was overvalued. After providing 22 ‘sell’ recommendations, N&bet went to a ‘hold recommendation in July 1992, after the price soared past $70 and Warren Buffet bought his 15% stake. 3o That same month, pay-critic Graef Crystal admitted in 3oJetTCole, ‘Prudential’s November 5, 1992. Nisbet, Aerospace Analyst, Says He Was Fired’, Wall Street Journal, J. Dial, Table 6 Distribution K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 291 261-314 of value gain at General Dynamics, 1991-1993 ($ millions) Gain/ Sharing CEO Williams Anders 25 top executives (excl. Anders) 1,300 lower-level executives 48,000 SIP participants” Subtotal for GD employees $3 19 0 . .... .. $22 Crown family Warren Buffett Other shareholders Stocki’ Option? $15 40 64 450 . . . $315 143 283 2,932 Total $22 $4,521 $315 Percent of total gain $54 258 144 450 1.1% 5.3% 3.0% 9.3% $906 18.7% 143 283 2,932 . $4,864d 15.3% 5.8% 60.2% $36 199 80 . $569 Total . . 100.0% “GD Stock Investment Plan (SIP). Includes participation of managers and executives. ‘Stock for GD employees includes appreciation on restricted stock, on shares retained after exercising options, and on shares purchased through the SIP, but excludes appreciation on stock purchased by employees in private transactions. ‘Options include amounts realized from exercising options plus the December 1993 exercisable value of unexercised options. Exercise data are available only for the top five executives. In December 1992, these five executives exercised all options granted in February 1991 at $103.5625, and retained 57% of the shares. In estimating gains to other employees, we assume that all February 1991 options were exercised in December 1991, and that 57% of all exercised options were retained. dIncludes the $4,486 million gain to shareholders (including SIP participants) plus $22 million Gain/Sharing payments, $315 million payouts from options, and $41 in special distributions paid on restricted stock. his monthly newsletter, ‘ . . . if we had spent less time criticizing [Anders’] pay package and more time increasing our investment in GD [shares], we would have been a lot better off financially’.31 Table 6 shows how the value gain was distributed among executives, employees, and shareholders. Anders received $54 million through Gain/Sharing and appreciation on his restricted stock and options, representing about 1.1% of the total gain to shareholders. The other members of Anders’ top management team realized $258 million (approximately $11 million each, or 5.3% of the total gain), while 1,300 lower-level executives received $144 million (approximately $111,000 each). Employee participants in the SIP realized more than $450 million (approximately $10,000 per participant) over the 1991-1993 period, or 3’The Crystal Report on Executive Compensation, Vol. 4, No. 8, October 1992. 292 J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 about 10% of the total gain. The Crown family-despite selling a large part of their GD stake-gained $743 million from their GD investment from 1991 to 1993, while Buffet’s stake-held for just 17 months-increased in value by $283 million. 3.8. Anders resigns as CEO In March 1993, in addition to announcing its first special distribution, GD announced the resignation of three of its top executives-Chairman and CEO William A. Anders, Vice Chairman Harvey Kapnick, and Executive Vice President Lester Crown. ‘We have basically done the major part of the turnaround job for which this team was assembled’, explained Anders.32 The three executives would remain on GD’s Board of Directors, and Anders would continue to serve as a nonemployee chairman of the board. James Mellor was named to succeed Anders as CEO. In March 1994, Anders resigned from the board, and Mellor assumed the additional role of chairman. 4. Strategies, incentives, and performance of other defense contractors Having analyzed in detail GD’s strategy, incentives, and performance, we now briefly summarize the experience of other defense contractors subsequent to the end of the Cold War. This industry analysis is relevant to our study of GD for several reasons: First, supporting the hypothesis that GD’s actions were driven, in part, by its new management team and incentives, we establish that GD led, rather than followed, the industry in responding to anticipated cuts in defense expenditures. Second, we offer circumstantial evidence that Anders set the strategic objective for the industry: By 1993, most defense firms were adopting the strategy Anders outlined in industry speeches in late 1991 (see Section 3.7 above). Third, we show that Anders had significantly more stock-based financial incentives than the average firm in the industry or the S&P 500. Finally, we show that the industry’s ultimate consolidation, which was facilitated by GD, moved resources out of the industry and generated substantial shareholder wealth. The industry return from 1991-1993 (even excluding GD) more than doubled the return on the S&P 500, illustrating that opportunities to create wealth exist even in declining industries with few growth opportunities. 4.1. Strategic alternatives and choices of other contractors Table 7 summarizes the strategies selected by GD and eight other defense contractors from 1990 through 1993, based on an analysis of quantitative 32JeffCole, ‘Three Officers to Quit General Dynamics Corp.: End of Turnaround a Cash Payout, Cuts at Headquarters’, Wall Street Journal, March 19, 1993. Plan Brings J. Dial, K.J. MurphyJJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 293 financial data as well as our qualitative interpretation of annual reports, press releases, and news articles. The table includes nine of the eleven largest domestic defense contractors (ranked by cumulative 1989-1992 defense contracts) - missing are General Electric and Boeing because their defense operations account for less than 10% of total firm revenues. Some of the strategic options adopted by these firms include: Acquisitions to achieve critical mass; diversification into nondefense areas or converting defense operations to commercial products and services; globalization, i.e., finding international markets for defense operations; downsizing and consolidation; and exit (Lundquist, 1992; Minnich, 1993). to achieve critical mass. Five of the eight defense contractors in Table 7 adopted Anders’ critical mass criteria, and sought to achieve critical mass in production through acquisitions. GM Hughes acquired GD’s missile division for $450 million in 1992, and Lockheed acquired GD’s aircraft division for $1.5 billion in 1993. Martin Marietta acquired GE Aerospace for $3 billion in 1992 and GD’s Space Systems for $209 million in 1994. Northrop purchased LTV’s aircraft division for $225 million in 1992, and won a bidding war with Martin Marietta to acquire Grumman for $2.17 billion in 1994. Although not included in Table 7, Loral acquired Ford Aerospace for $715 million in 1990, LTV’s missile business for $240 million in 1992, and IBM’s Federal Systems division for $1.5 billion in 1994. Also in 1994, Lockheed and Martin Marietta agreed to a merger via a stock swap that created the U.S.’ largest defense contractor and led to further consolidation in the industry. By merging, acquiring, and consolidating businesses, these defense contractors have lowered overhead costs and avoided duplication of research and development expenses (Lundquist, 1992). In addition, these acquisitions, financed largely with cash, have created value by transferring over $10 billion from the industry to target-firm shareholders who can reinvest in more productive sectors (Jensen, 1983). Acquisitions Diversijication and commercialization. A 1992 survey of 148 defense companies sponsored by a defense/aerospace consulting firm found that more than half of the respondents report past attempts to ‘commercialize’ (i.e., applying defense technologies to commercial products) and more than three-quarters predict future commercialization.33 For example, Hughes is applying its satellite technology in a commercial venture called satellite direct TV, designed to compete directly with cable television. Lockheed is pursuing commercial satellite and satellite launch customers, and is converting its defense systems businesses into systems for collecting child support payments and traffic tickets, and bar coding applications for the postal service. Other firms are adopting more traditional 33Rick Work’, War&man, ‘Peace Initiative: Wall Street Journal, February Lockheed Navigates 10, 1992. the Tricky Transition to More Civilian Table 7 Summary of defense revenues, strategy, capital expenditures, and employment Dept. of Defense prime contracts= ($ billions) Company GM Hughes 19891992 As % of total rev. of major defense contractors Capital expenditures/depreciation” (defense segments only) Strategyb 1989 Critical mass, diversification, conversion, downsizing, exit $12.3 26.1% Grumman $9.6 64.3% Critical 56.0% 48.4% Lockheed $14.5 36.5% Critical mass, conversion, globalization, downsizing 109.4% 93.4% Martin Marietta $11.9 49.6% Critical mass, diversification, globalization, downsizing 127.6% 114.8% McDonnell Douglas $30.2 45.3% Critical mass, globalization, conversion, downsizing, exit 112.2% 10.0% mass, downsizing, exit 64.2% 1990 53.5% 1991 44.3% Employmentd (defense/aerospace 1992 1990 1991 segments) 1992 % change 1990-92 57,000 - 15.1% 23,600 21,200 - 18.8% 72,300 71,700 - 1.8% 48.4% 61,114 63,204 59.1% 49.2% 26,100 93.7% 93.1% 73,000 88.8% 72.9% 32,900 32,000 31.9% 63.5% 121,190 109,123 e 87,377 N/A - 27.9% Northrop $9.5 43.4% Conversion, downsizing Raytheon $14.8 40.6% Conversion, downsizing globalization, United Technologies $12.0 14.4% Globalization, $114.8 34.4% $25.5 76.3% Total . (w/o GD) General Dynamics downsizing 86.2% 64.6% 58.1% 65.2% 135.0% 117.1% 84.7% 71.3% 131.9% 136.4% 128.3% 108.3% 89.4% 108.8% 84.9% 38,200 33,600 c - 12.0% -e 36,200 .~e 100.7% 45,700 44,400 41,000 - 10.3% 16.3% 78.7% 565,964 539,927 460,477 17.9% 16.3% 98,150 80,600 35,650 . . N/A . Downsizing, exit “Department of Defense, ‘100 Companies Receiving the Largest Dollar Volume of Prime Contract Awards’, various issues (excludes sales to foreign thus defense business is understated in terms of total revenue and as a percentage of firm revenue); firm revenues from company annual reports. “Subjectively ‘Data from ‘Figures determined annual reported from reports and Aircraft by Aerospace ‘Segment data not available. ‘Excludes Martin Marietta a variety Industries and Raytheon of sources, Owners including and Pilots analysts Association Association. from summary total. reports, Industry trade publications, Sector Analysis business Data press, and company Base, provided reports. to us by General Dynamics. .. - 13.6’ - 63.7% countries, 296 J. Dial, K.J. MurphylJournal qf‘Financial Economics 37 (1995) 26lb314 diversification strategies: Raytheon, for example, diversified into corporate jets by acquiring British Aerospace’s business-jet unit. Martin Marietta CEO Norman Augustine, however, cautioned his industry counterparts about wandering too far from their areas of expertise: Our industry’s record at defense conversion is unblemished by success. Why is it rocket scientists can’t sell toothpaste? Because we don’t know the market, or how to research, or how to market the product. Other than that, we’re in good shape.34 Globalization. A number of firms are retaining a defense focus, attempting to bolster sales through globalization, selling U.S. built weapons abroad. This strategy is unlikely to yield dramatic growth, since the demand for weapons is declining world-wide and many foreign countries have their own national producers who are also faced with excess capacity (Lundquist, 1992). Nevertheless, augmenting domestic sales with foreign contracts can help to build critical mass in businesses with waning support from the U.S. government. Raytheon, one of the few defense contractors that is successfully pursuing a globalization strategy, hopes to achieve 40% of military sales outside of the U.S., principally on sales of its Patriot missile in the Mideast. Downsizing, consolidation, and exit. Table 7 shows that while most contractors adopted a combination of strategies, all adopted some form of downsizing or consolidation to reduce excess capacity. However, while a few contractors (including GM Hughes, Grumman, and McDonnell Douglas) have divested unprofitable noncore businesses where they had little chance of building strategically competitive positions, only General Electric (not included in Table 7) followed GD in exiting key segments of the defense industry. Interestingly, it was General Electric (where Anders held his first general management position) that pioneered the ‘# 1 or # 2’ criterion as a strategic assessment for the composition of its portfolio of business units. Table 7 reports the ratio of capital expenditures to depreciation within the defense segments of major defense contractors from 1989 through 1992. Ratios exceeding 100% indicate that firms are investing more than is required to replace depreciating assets, while ratios less than 100% indicate that firms are not fully replacing depreciating assets. The table shows that a composite (weighted average) ratio among eight key contractors fell from 108% in 1989 to just 79% in 1992. However, the table shows that GD cut its capital spending faster and deeper than other defense contractors: GD’s ratio of capital expenditures to depreciation approximated the industry average in 1989 and 1990, but 34‘Still Waiting for the Bang’, The Economist, October 2, 1993. J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 297 plummeted to just 17.9% and 16.3% in 1991 and 1992, respectively. Table 7 also shows that total employment within the defense/aerospace segments of these same contractors fell by 13.6% from 1990 to 1992. Meanwhile, GD reduced its employment by 63.7% over the same period through layoffs, sell offs, and attrition (see also Table 4). Goyal, Lehn, and Racic (1993) also analyze investment policies in the defense industry. They report evidence that defense contractors began transferring resources from the industry as early as 1989-90 through increased leverage, dividends, and share repurchases. Our complementary evidence suggests that although other contractors also espoused and eventually adopted consolidation and downsizing, GD’s response in moving resources out of the industry was quicker and more dramatic. To draw an analogy: While other defense contractors engaged in a high-stakes game of musical chairs- hoping to be seated when the music stopped-GD pursued a strategy of offering its chair to the highest bidder. 4.2. Incentives and performance in the defense industry Table 8 compares Anders’ stock-based incentives to those of CEOs in other major defense contractors and in the S&P 500, using data from corporate proxy statements covering the 1992 fiscal year. 35 Financial incentives to create value come predominantly from stock options, restricted stock, and stock ownership (Jensen and Murphy, 1990; Murphy, 1993). Cash compensation plans explicitly based on stock prices-such as GD’s Gain/Sharing Plan which was ultimately converted to stock options -are unusual. Therefore, we focus on these three components of incentives and ignore incentives associated with salaries, bonuses, and other cash plans. We define ‘incentives’ as the fraction of the shareholder gain ‘paid’ to the CEO through appreciation of his stock and option holdings. Table 8 shows that Anders held stock options on 1.39% of GD’s outstanding shares (including the options granted when Gain/Sharing was discontinued), substantially more than the average holdings in the industry (0.29%) or the S&P 500 (0.20%). In addition, Anders held restricted stock on 0.32% of GD’s shares, compared to industry and market averages of 0.05% and 0.03%, respectively. Together-assuming the options are sufficiently in-the-money- these two components imply that Anders’ receives approximately 1.7% of the gains to GD shareholders, between five and seven times the average percentage in the industry (0.34%) and market (0.23%), respectively. [Anders’ estimated incentives of 1.7% are higher than the 1.1% reported in Table 6 because Anders exercised and sold 150,000 shares in December 1992. The 1.7% represents his marginal incentives at the end of 1992 (prior to the exercise) rather than the 35Pro~y data were unavailable for 74 S&P 500 companies. Table 8 Stock-based incentives and shareholder returns Percentage fiscal 1992 in the defense industry of outstanding and the S&P shares held by CEO, 500 Rate of return reinvested) realized by shareholders (dividends 1992 1993 80% 47 31 20 - 32 36 27 -8 .. . . 55% 66 25 31 126 14 31 33 Stock options Restricted stock Stock owned Total 19871990 GM Hughes” Grumman Lockheed Martin Marietta McDonnell Douglas Northrop Raytheon United Technologies 0.00% 0.24 0.33 0.35 0.00 1.05 0.08 0.48 .. .. . .. 0.00% 0.06 0.00 0.05 0.00 0.04 0.12 0.05 . ... 0.02% 0.12 0.02 0.02 3.34 0.68 0.03 0.05 ... . 0.02% 0.42 0.35 0.42 3.34 1.77 0.23 0.63 ... . . .. 0% -2 - 21 27 - 35 -46 18 20 .. Industry average 0.29% 0.05% 0.31% 0.61% 11% 29% 16% 41% 110% General Dynami& 1.39% 0.32% 0.05% 1.76% - 59% 118% 97% 48% 537% 0.20% 0.03% 0.75% 0.98% 56% 30% 8% 10% 55% Company S&P 500 Industry and S&P 500 averages are value-weighted. Weights for industry performance are 1 l/91 market from fiscal 1992 proxy statements; proxy data were available for 426 of the S&P 500 companies. “Incentive data reflects GM’s CEO’s holdings of GM Hughes stock; ownership 1991 - 13% -5 40 39 93 59 22 18 .. capitalizations. data for the head of GM’s Hughes Data subsidiary on stock-based 1991p 1993 143% 131 130 118 197 147 103 44 . . incentives are not available. ‘Anders’ stock-based incentives are calculated before his December 1992 option exercise. They reflect 431,359 stock options, 15,500 purchased shares, and 100,700 restricted shares (including 30,940 shares granted in lieu of benefits he would have received at Textron; these shares were held in a GD deferred account until late 1992, when Anders received the value of the shares in cash). Anders’ incentives from Gain/Sharing discontinued in December 1991~ are not included, but the incentives from the options that replaced Gain/Sharing are included. J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 299 ‘average’ incentives over the 1991-1993 period.] As a new CEO, Anders held substantially less stock than the average CEO in the industry and market; these shares provide incentives even though they are not controlled by the compensation committee. Anders’ overall incentives (including stock owned) are about three times the average incentives for CEOs in the industry and twice the average incentives for CEOs in the market. We also compared the 1992 incentives for defense-firm CEOs to incentives four years earlier, based on 1989 proxy statements. Incentives for GD’s CEO (Anders in 1992, Stanley Pace in 1988) increased 1.47% from 0.29% to 1.76%. In contrast, the change in incentives in the other eight firms ranged from - 1.07% to 0.29%, with a median change of 0.1%. Although the estimates of 1988 and 1992 incentives are not strictly comparable due to changes in CEOs and reporting requirements, our results suggest that, measured relative to changes in other defense firms, CEO incentives at GD increased substantially from 1988 to 1992.36 Although Anders’ stock-based incentives of 1.7% seem small in absolute value, it is worth noting that the 25 members of his top management team have stock-based incentives exceeding 6% (see Table 6). In addition, his pay-related incentives (options and restricted stock) are exceeded by less than 4% of the S&P 500, and his total incentives (including stock) are exceeded by only 15% of the S&P 500. The only CEO in the industry with more stock-based incentives is McDonnell Douglas’ founding-family-member John McDonnell. Although McDonnell has no options or restricted stock, his family stock holdings account for over 3% of the outstanding stock. While his company was slow to respond to the pending industry decline, its stock price more than doubled in 1993 after it closed several fabrication plants, reduced capital expenditures by more than half, and cut employment 18% to just 72,000 by the end of 1993. The final columns of Table 8 show the shareholder returns (with reinvested dividends) earned by GD, other major defense contractors, and the S&P 500 from January 1987 through December 1993. GD shareholders received lower returns than the industry and market prior to Anders’ appointment as CEO, and earned substantially higher returns than the industry and market in 1991 and 1992. The defense market rebounded in 1993, earning an average 41% compared to the 10% return on the S&P 500, but still below GD’s 48% return. GD contributed to the 1993 wealth creation among other defense firms by facilitating a consolidation of the industry and leading the wave of defenserelated layoffs and acquisitions that had returned over $10 billion to shareholders by early 1994. Focusing on core businesses, shedding underperforming assets, closing facilities, consolidating divisions, reducing debt, and cutting 361n particular, firms did not disclose outstanding stock options outstanding options as the sum of 1988 grants and options exercisable firms did not uniformly report restricted shareholdings in 1988. in 1988. We estimate 1988 within 60 days. In addition, 300 J. Dial, K.J. Murphy JJournal of’ Financial Economics 3 7 (1995) 261-3 14 capital expenditures and employment has substantially strengthened the competitive position of many contractors as they have reduced both financial and operating leverage. 5. Sources of GD’s value gain Table 9 decomposes the sources of GD’s $4.486 billion value gain from 1991-1993. It estimates the fraction of the value gain that plausibly reflects GD’s new management team and incentives, and the fraction that is best explained by market and industry stock-price movements and by events affecting GD’s stock price that are unrelated to the implementation of GD’s strategy. The estimates in the table are based on the S&P 500 Index, performance of the industry in excess of the S&P 500, and the industry-adjusted three-day announcement returns of events affecting GD’s stock price (as reported in Appendix B). Each event in Appendix B includes a designation of exogenous, earnings, distributions, downsizing, or strategy. Exogenous events-such as the Gulf War, the Soviet Coup, awards (or cancellations) of CD contracts-are events not plausibly driven by GD’s new management team and incentives. Earnings includes earnings announcements. Distributions includes events related to dividends, share repurchases, and special distributions (including ex-divided dates). Downsizing includes announcements related to layoffs and sales of divisions. The final category, Strategy, includes events related to Gain/Sharing, Anders’ speeches, analyst reports, and other announcements directly related to GD’s strategy. We consider that events related to earnings, distributions, downsizing, and strategy plausibly reflect GD’s new management team and incentives. Table 9 shows that $956 million of GD’s gain (21% of the total) can be explained by general market movements, while $1.076 billion (24% of the total) can be explained by industry-specific movements. Exogenous events not directly linked to Anders’ strategy account for $21 million, bringing the total gain explained by market, industry, and exogenous factors to $2.053 billion, or about 46% of the total gain to shareholders. Announcement returns related to earnings, distributions, downsizing, and strategy account for $2.322 billion (or 52% of the total). Together, the market and industry adjustments and the announcement returns explain 98% (all but $111 million) of the total gain to GD shareholders. The $2.3 billion estimate of value gain explained by Anders’ strategy excludes the $111 million ‘unexplained’ component and the $1.1 billion explained by industry-specific movements (in excess of the market). In estimating the fraction of GD’s value gain plausibly driven by its management team and incentive structure, it seems appropriate to exclude exogenous factors affecting the entire industry. For example, if the 41% industry return in 1993 (see Table 8) reflected increased demand for new weapons systems, it would be inappropriate to attribute that demand shift to actions taken by GD’s managers. However, the J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 301 261-314 Table 9 Sources of value gain at General Dynamics, 1991-1993 ($ millions) 1991 Beginning market value Regular dividends Special distributions, share repurchase Ending value 1992 of value change attributed to exogenous General market movements’ Industry-specific movement? Industry-adjusted response to announcements not related to GD’s new strategyi’.’ $2,253 56 960 3,204 $ 420 8 - 128 $ 228 300 149 1991-1993 $3,204 $1,052 56 154 1,554 2,514 2,870 2,870 . Change in value $1,243 $1,967 $1,276 $4,486 .. ... ................. ........... .................................. ................................................................................................................ Amount $1,052 42 0 2,253 1993 factors $ 308 768 0 $ 956 1,076 21 ... . ... .. . ..... . . Value change from exogenous factors $ 300 $ 611 $ 1,076 $2,053 ..... ...... ....... ............. ........................................................................................................................................... Amount strategy of value change attributed (industry-adjusted) to GD’s new Earnings announcements Cash distribution announcements“ Downsizing announcementse Other strategy-related announcementsf Value change from strategy ..... ................. ..... .. Unexplained change in value . $ - 74 0 18 671 $ 134 $ 182 $ 242 258 351 609 225 23 266 534 0 $1,205 ... .. $ 615 $1,151 $ 556 $2,322 ................................................................................................................ % 328 $ 139 $-356 S 111 “General market movements am calculated daily as V,- r r ,,,L,where V, - 1 is GD’s market value on day t - 1, and r,, is the return on the S&P 500 index on day t. Industry-specific movements are calculated daily as V,- i(r,, - r,), where 4, is the value-weighted return on the eight defensefirms in Tables 7 and 8. “Includes announcements of defense contracts, world events (such as the Gulf War and the Soviet Coup), and other announcements as designated in Appendix B. “Industry-adjusted responses (as reported in A * ppendix B) are calculated as V,_ *(R1 - Ri,), where R, and Ri, are the three-day returns surrounding each announcement for GD and the industry, respectively, and V,-, is GD’s market value two days prior to the announcement. %cludes announcements related to dividends, share repurchases, and special distributions (including ex-dividend dates) as designated in Appendix B. ‘Includes announcements related to layoffs and sales of divisions as designated in Appendix B. ‘Includes responses to Gain/Sharing, Anders’ speeches, analyst reports, and other announcements designated in Appendix B. stellar performance of the defense industry in 1992-1993 was not driven by an increase in weapons contracts, but by explicit managerial responses to declining demand, including mergers, consolidations, and downsizing. GD was an active player, not an innocent bystander, in this process, and both GD’s and the 302 J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 industry’s returns would plausibly have been lower without Anders’ active participation. Therefore, depending on how the industry and unexplained components are interpreted, our estimates of the value gain attributable to GD’s management and incentive structure range from $2.3 billion to $3.5 billion. The evidence presented in this paper, including Table 9, support the hypotheses that GD’s remarkable shareholder performance was driven in large part by its top management team and its incentive structure. In the remainder of this section, we address three questions related to the sources and disposition of the value gain. First, was the value gain simply a transfer of wealth from (former) GD employees to shareholders? Second, rather than returning cash to shareholders, should GD have used its excess cash to diversify or to retain workers? Finally, could GD’s results have been achieved with fewer executive incentives? 5.1. Did the value gain at General Dynamics come at the expense of GD workers? GD, with a January 1991 market capitalization of $1 billion and less than $1 billion in long-term debt, generated almost $4.5 billion in wealth for shareholders in less than three years. The underlying theme in this study is that value was created as resources used in defense were diverted to more highly valued uses. The fact that the diversion was associated with large increases in stock prices suggests that the stock market expected that efficient resource allocation was unlikely. The fact that GD had a 1991 market value (including debt) of less than $2 billion while having over $10 billion in revenues, a $23 billion backlog, over $6 billion in assets, 98,000 employees, and annual capital and R&D spending in excess of $700 million, is further evidence that the market expected GD to e z mploy its resources inefficiently. Fig. 1 suggests that the market began anticipating cuts in future defense spending as early as 1987: GD’s shareholders realized a 59% loss from January 1987 through December 1990. Moreover, the industry (excluding GD but including the other firms in Table 8) managed a meager cumulative 11% return over the same four years, far less than the 56% return on the S&P 500 from 1987-1990. The market evidently discounted the probability that the defense industry would respond efficiently to the changing defense market. The increase in GD’s value reflects, in part, the gain to society from diverting capital resources to more highly valued uses (e.g., GD’s drastic cuts in capital expenditures). In addition, part of the increase in GD’s value reflects the gain from diverting human resources to more highly valued uses, and part reflects a wealth transfer from employees to shareholders. Employees are worse off by the differences between their wages at GD and the wages in their next-best alternatives; however, society is better off by the differences in the employees’ value at their next-best alternative and their value as defense workers at GD. To the extent that employees could earn a similar wage in the nondefense sector, the increase in GD’s value represents a dollar-for-dollar increase in societal wealth. To the J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (199.5) 261-314 303 extent that employees must accept much lower wages, the relevant issue is why they had originally been paid a premium to work in the competitive defense industry. Presumably, this premium reflected the specialized skills required for the industry, and also reflected a compensating differential for risky employment in an industry with historically variable demand. In addition, the premium reflects the wealth transfer from taxpayers to employees that occurred when defense contractors passed high labor costs directly to taxpayers under contracts awarded on a cost-plus basis. By shifting to fixed-price contracts in the late 1980s Congress shifted the burden of overpaid employees from taxpayers to shareholders. The elimination of the subsidized overpayment to defense employees will harm affected employees, but generally benefit shareholders and society. We have not attempted to separate quantitatively the portions of the increase in GD’s shareholder wealth that reflect societal gains versus transfers from employees. It is worth stressing, however, that the fact that some of the gain reflects transfers does not imply that shareholders were expropriating wealth from defense workers who had ‘rights’ to perpetual wage premiums. There is no evidence that GD had an implicit or explicit contractual obligation to continue paying rents to employees following the end of the Cold War. There is evidence, however, that the market expected the company to waste resources by paying workers high rents to continue producing products that society no longer valued. 5.2. Should General Dynamics have used its excess cash to diver@ workers? or retain Although politicians, journalists, and labor leaders argued that GD should have retrained their defense-specific employees, Anders believed that retraining programs would be an inappropriate use of shareholder money: I do not see that we have a special obligation to our employees. This is an issue of excess human capacity that had to leave the defense industry. We trained our people to have specific skills and paid for that training. Then we paid them for their skills. What are we to do when those skills are no longer required? We have a lot of very skilled welders at Electric Boat that earn about twice what they can earn on the outside where that level of skill is not required. We are not going to start to build bridges. That’s not our business and not our obligation. The loss of jobs at GD is actually better for America if we redeploy those assets appropriately. We have done more than any other defense contractor in creating new jobs by putting $3.4 billion back into investments - by letting shareholders redeploy those resources in new industries for new products. 304 J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 Academic proponents of company-sponsored retraining programs argue that such programs are part of the optimal implicit contract between employees and employers. It is difficult to disprove the existence of implicit contracts, since these contracts by definition are not written, but exist only in the minds of the employees and the employer. We argue, however, that rational employees would not expect a firm to honor this type of implicit contract in the event the firm downsizes or exits particular business lines. Implicit contracts are enforced through reputational concerns: Reneging on contracts with current workers makes it more costly to enter into similar contracts in the future. However, when the likelihood of future contracting is substantially reduced (or nonexistent in the case of a full liquidation), enforcing the implicit contract becomes more difficult. Consequently, implicit promises by a firm to provide retraining coincidental to downsizing or liquidation are not credible. Employees who desire this type of employment insurance would not likely rely on implicit contracts, but would instead demand explicit contracts specifying employment guarantees, severance payments, and retraining programs in the event of liquidation. Although GD did write (and honor) explicit contracts with some union workers and top managers, these contracts did not include retraining provisions. The relevant question is not whether defense workers should be retrained, but who should provide the retraining. Retraining will have to occur, since the specific skills required in the defense industry are not readily transferable to other industries. The worker has the best information to determine how to retain, and to choose the industrial sectors promising the best alternative employment opportunities. In contrast, the company has neither the information nor the expertise to be an efficient provider of retraining for unemployed defense workers. 5.3. Could General Dynamics ’ results have been achieved with fewer executive incentives? One of the more important issues raised by the GD case is whether the strategy it ultimately adopted could have been developed and implemented without the large ex post rewards to top managers. Anders, after all, was already paid an annual salary of $800,000 to act in the interest of GD shareholders. Why did he need additional incentives to do what he was hired to do? The strategies adopted by GD - including downsizing, restructuring, liquidation, and returning excess cash to shareholders-seem obvious, given the projected reductions in defense budgets associated with the end of the Cold War. However, despite ample evidence of a changing defense market available to all defense contractors, only GD followed the ‘obvious’ strategy. While other contractors reduced their work forces to some degree, no one took the drastic actions that GD did in 1991 and 1992 to reduce capital expenditures and employment, and no other firm elected to convert their assets to cash and return financial resources to shareholders. J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 305 The new management team and new incentive programs were introduced simultaneously. It is therefore difficult to identify the relative importance of incentives versus the particular individuals in the team. It is worth noting, however, that Anders and the other top executives believe that the Gain/Sharing Plan and other plans linked to value creation were crucial elements of GD’s ultimate success. Anders stresses the importance of creating the ‘partnership mentality’ among top managers, who began to think like owners rather than hired hands. The decisions GD managers made were not easy, and the incentives had to be strong enough to attract and retain the right executives, ensure timely and comprehensive disclosure of critical information, and motivate the right decisions. Ultimately, the incentives had to be strong enough to make the executives willing to sacrifice their own jobs and positions. Several top GD executives (including Anders) have left the company, and many of those remaining (including new CEO Mellor) have accepted substantial pay reductions to reflect the reduced complexity of the smaller corporation they now manage. Such voluntary turnover and pay cuts are unusual in U.S. corporations. The argument that high-salaried managers should take actions that benefit shareholders-even without high-powered incentives-is at odds with the evidence in a growing number of corporate giants, including IBM, General Motors, Kodak, Westinghouse, and Sears. In these firms, as well as many others, creating value for shareholders means downsizing and moving human and physical capital out of the industry. Managers in these firms resisted major changes until the changes were forced upon them by market pressure; IBM, for example, brought in a new manager to make meaningful changes only after shareholders lost over $50 billion in less than two years. 6. Conclusion Jensen (1993) argues that rapid increases in technology, declines in regulation, growing worldwide capitalism, and globalization of trade have created massive excess capacity in many of the world’s industries. GD’s response to excess capacity in the defense industry has important implications for many firms across a wide range of industries facing similar economic pressures. First, the GD case suggests the importance of stock-based compensation in firms characterized by excess capacity: GD downplayed accounting-based bonuses and focused on stock options, restricted stock, and other compensation plans tied to value creation. Second, GD’s experience illustrates the large political costs associated with success when success mean downsizing and layoffs, and also suggests that these costs can be mitigated by avoiding cash payments, relying instead on gains through ownership. Third, appropriate incentives must be coupled with the appropriate managers: Anders believes that his strategy could not have been implemented without the incentives, but the 306 J. Dial, K.J. Murphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 case facts also suggest that Anders’ actions transcended his individual incentives. Finally, although declining industries with excess capacity offer relatively few opportunities for revenue growth, the GD case suggests that these industries may offer large potential opportunities for value creation. Even though GD’s situation is replicated in many firms and industries, its response and ultimate achievements are remarkable. Excess capacity necessitates downsizing and transferring resources to higher-valued uses. However, few managers have been able to accomplish the necessary resource redirection until their organizations faced crises in the product, factor, or capital markets. GD’s board and top management team were remarkably consistent in pursuing their objective of creating shareholder wealth in spite of enormous pressures from employees, unions, the media, and the government to do otherwise. Overall, GD stands out as the preeminent shareholder success story of the early 1990s and may serve as a blueprint for compensation and strategy decisions in other industries with excess capacity. Appendix A General Dynamics board of directors and stock ownership, February 15, 1991 Restricted and unrestricted shares held Director CURRENT MANAGEMENT William A. Anders (age 57, director since 1990) Chairman and CEO Lester Crown (age 65, director since 1974) Executive Chairman and Chief Operating -d 271,359 60,412 76,469 133,613 15,071 0 44,323 22,157 53,450 0 47,701 22,190 Officer Russell W. Meyer, Jr. (age 58, director since 1986) Executive Chairman 106,586’ Vice President of Material Service subsidiary James R. Mellor (age 60, director since 1981) President Stock options heldb Vice President of the Corporation of Cessna Aircraft subsidiary Herbert F. Rogers (age 65, director since 1987) Vice Chairman of the Corporation FORMER MANAGEMENT David S. Lewis (age 73, director since 1970) Former Chairman and CEO Stanley C. Pace (age 70, director since 1985) Former Chairman and CEO J. Dial, K.J. h4urphy/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261-314 Restricted and unrestricted shares held” Director 307 Stock options held” - CROWN FAMILY James S. Crown (age 37, director since 1987) General Partner, Henry Crown and Company Charles H. Goodman (age 57, director since 199kl) Vice President, Henry Crown and Company Vice President, CC Industries, Inc. 9.187,149’ i 0 NONMANAGEMENT Thomas G. Ayers (age 76, director since 1980)’ Former Chairman and CEO of Commonwealth Edison Frank C. Carlucci (age 60, director since 1991) Vice Chairman, The Carlyle Group Former Secretary of Defense Harvey Kapnick (age 65, director since 1980)’ President, Kapnick Investment Co. Alien E. Puckett (age 71, director since 1987)’ Chairman Emeritus of Hughes Aircraft Company Bernard W. Rogers (age 69, director since 1987) Retired General, former Chief of Staff Former Supreme Allied Commander Europe, U.S. Army Elliot H. Stein (age 72, director since 1978)’ Chairman Emeritus of Stiefel Financial Corporation Cyrus R. Vance (age 74, director since 1987) Chairman, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Former Secretary of State Source: 2/15/91. GD “Includes 1991 Proxy restricted Statement, shares granted “Includes options granted of $25.5625 per share. March 28, 1991. There or promised (and exchanged) were 41,870,868 on (or before) on February February 15; all options 300 0 1,050 0 500 0 1,000 0 300 0 2.500 0 300 0 shares outstanding on 15, 1991. listed have an exercise price ‘Anders shares include 500 shares purchased before 1991,10,000 shares purchasedin February 1991, 30,326 shares of restricted stock granted in lieu of benefits he would have received at Textron (held in a deferred account), and 65,760 restricted shares granted or promised in February 1991. %ee Crown family holdings below. ‘Includes Lester Crown’s 24,310 restricted shares. Many of the shares owned by Lester Crown, James S. Crown, and Charles Goodman are jointly owned through Crown family trusts. The total ownership by the Crown family amounts to approximately 22% of General Dynamics common stock. ‘Member of compensation committee. Appendix B Stock market reactions and shareholder value changes in response to announcements and events for General Dynamics, aerospace/defense industry, and the S&P 500, 1991-1994 Three-day value changes ($ millions) Three-day returns Announcement type Date 9127189 Anders hiring announced l/1/91 Anders takes over as Chairman and CEO l/8/91 Defense Secretary Cheney cancels A-12 l/17/91 Gulf War lasts from l/17/91 to through 2/28/91, creating substantial 2128191 volatility among defenserelated stocks l/17 Air war begins over Iraq Defense budget announced, 214 cuts in planned purchases of F-165 GD and McDonnell Douglas 217 are permitted to defer repayment on A-12 2115 GD’s Board of Directors adopts Gain/Sharing Plan and other new compensation initiatives 2124 Ground war begins in Iraq 2128 - Gulf war ends l l l l l GD share price Exogenous $22+ Exogenous %21$ to $25 Genera1 Dynamics Industry return Market return Genera1 Dynamics Industryadjusted Marketadjusted - 16.3% - 4.9% - 2.6% - $172 - $120 - $145 16.0%” 0.8%” - 4.2%” $141” $7” - $37” 3113191 Goldman Sachs, Morgan Stanley, and Paine Webber recommend GD stock, citing managerial incentives and changes underway 3,‘20/9 1 GD lays off 2,000 at jet plant 3128191 South Korea cancels purchase of McDonnell Douglas fighters and surprises observers in announcing $5.2 billion purchase of F-16s 413191 ECgyptbuys 46 more F-16s 4117191 First quarter earnings down 56% (excluding 1990 onetime gain, earnings down 21%) 4/23/9 1 Lockheed/GD/Boeing team wins ATF award 5/l/91 Shareholders ratify Gain/ Sharing Plan, Mellor says GD to cut 30,000 jobs by 1994 516191 Navy awards Seawolf nuclear sub to GD, first Gain/Sharing payoff s/9/9 1 Judge halts Seawolf award 7117191 Second quarter earnings ($211 M), up from $240 M loss in 1990 Strategy $284 22.0% 0.1% 0.0% $220 $218 $220 Downsizing Exogenous $29$ $33% - 0.8% 7.0% 0.5% 1.8% 1.4% 1.4% - $10 $94 - $4 $118 $7 $112 Exogenous Earnings $342 $35 - 2.9% 6.0% 2.8% 1.1% 2.3% 2.0% - $42 $84 - $82 $99 - $74 $56 Exogenous $36$ 6.4% 0.4% $94 $84 $100 Strategy $39 3.0% 1.9% $47 $35 $18 Exogenous Strategy $391 4.2% 0.8% $68 $82 $82 Exogenous Earnings $39$ $44 3.8% - 0.3% 0.4% 0.8% - $63 - $5 - $61 ~ $93 - $51 - $20 0.8% Three-day value changes (S millions) Three-day returns Announcement type GD share price General Dynamics Industry return Market return Industryadjusted Marketadjusted $16 $12 $27 - 6.0%” - $79” - $127” - $111” 1.1% - 0.3% $361 $343 $366 Date Event 8/9/9 1 GD gets contract to build tanks for Army Soviet Coup lasts from g/19/91 to B/21/91 Exogenous 0.2% - 0.6% Exogenous 6.8 %” Anders addresses defense analyst conference, GD sells data unit to CSC for S184 M (9/22), more Wall Street firms say ‘Buy’ 10/8/91 Second Gain/Sharing payoff 10/17/91 GD announces plan to divest Cessna 10/21/91 Third-quarter earnings ($71 M) up 4% 10129191 Anders speech outlines strategic options l/9/92 U.S. seeks to settle suit over A-12 l/21/92 GD announces sale of Cessna to Textron 213192 Fourth-quarter earnings ($166 M), up from $530 M loss in 1990 Strategy Downsizing a/19/91 through 8/21/91 9124191 General Dynamics - $4 Strategy Downsizing S4ti - 3.6% 4.4% 1.1% 3.3% - 1.1% 0.5% - $73 $89 - $50 $22 - $52 $80 Earnings $50 0.0% 3.8% - 1.0% $0 - $80 $21 Strategy %5Oi 7.0% 2.9% 2.4% $141 $83 $93 Exogenous ssc$ - 1.5% 2.8% - 0.5% - $37 - $105 ~ $24 Downsizing No+ - 1.2% 1.8% - 0.1% - $31 $14 - $29 Earnings $58: 0.6% 0.9% 0.6% St6 - S5 $1 M &e Three-day value changes (8 millions) Three-day returns Date Event 10/2/92 Conferees clear defense budget -GD benefits as defense priorities change GD to sell electronics unit to Carlyle Group GD gets 81.5 B tank sale Thirdquarter earnings ($120 M) up 70% GD lays off 1680 at Convair, 40% of work force Rumors of safe of jet business to Lockheed GD announces sale of jets to Lockheed Fourth-quarter earnings ($174 h@ up 5% GD announces $20 special dividend, Anders and two other top officers resign Exdividend date for $20 special dividend Firstquarter earnings ($687 M) up 58% 10/7/92 10/13/92 10/16/92 10/20/92 10/27/92 1219192 l/27/93 3119193 3130193 4121193 Announcement type GD share price General Dynamics Industry return Market return General Dynamics Industryadjusted Marketadjusted Exogenous $884 3.7% - 3.0% - 2.5% $92 $169 $155 Downsizing %9& 4.7% - 1.8% 0.1% $122 $167 $120 Exogenous Earnings %94i %96+ 0.7% 4.9% 1.1% 1.2% 1.7% 1.4% $18 $136 - $11 $103 - $28 $97 Downsizing $97; 0.9% - 1.2% 1.0% $26 $59 ~ $2 Downsizing $983 4.4% 2.7% 1.5% $125 $49 $82 Downsizing $1034 7.4% 3.4% - 0.1% $220 $120 $224 Earnings $115 0.9% - 2.6% - 0.3% $31 $I20 $40 Distributions $118f 0.4% 0.5% 0.2% $16 - $2 $10 Distributions $984 2.8% 0.5% 0.9% $101 $84 $69 Earnings $974 0.8% - 2.6% - 1.8% $23 $100 $17 Distributions $954 2.5% 1.9% 0.6% $74 $18 $57 Distributions SSG 1.6% 0.3% 0.1% $49 $39 $46 Earnings %9@ 2.3% 1.7% - 0.3% $62 $15 $71 Downsizing $94; 0.4% - 0.1% 0.6% $12 $14 - $5 CD announces $12 special dividend, increases dividend from 40# to 60$ Distributions S99+ 3.1% 0.9% ~ 0.2% $93 $67 $100 9122193 Ex-dividend dividend Distributions %9c+ 5.1% 0.5% 0.6% $159 $145 $139 10/20/93 Third-quarter down 39% Earnings $956 ~ 3.0% - 1.2% - 0.6% - $89 - $53 12123193 GD sells Space Systems Martin Marietta 1.5% 1.2% 1.1% $43 $9 $10 l/26/94 Fourth-quarter ($62 M) down 1.8% 0.5% 1.1% $51 $38 $19 318194 Anders - 2.6% 2.1% 0.5% - $78 - $138 - $93 612193 GD announces dividend 6115193 Ex-dividend dividend l/21/93 Second-quarter earnings down 29%, but exceed analysts’ estimates 8/30/93 GD lays off 700 more plant 9116193 “Three-day returns $18 special date for $18 special ($61 M) at tank date for $12 special earnings ($73 M) Downsizing to earnings 64% steps down Earnings as Chairman and value changes include rs91; $92 one day before and one day after the start and finish dates listed for the Gulf War period and the Soviet -$71 coup. 314 J. Dial, K.J. MurphyJJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 261~-314 References Baker, George P., 1990, Pay for performance for middle managers: Causes and consequences, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 3, no. 3. Baker, George P., Michael C. Jensen, and Kevin J. Murphy, 1988, Compensation and incentives: Practice vs. theory, Journal of Finance, July. Black, Fischer and Myron Scholes, 1973, The pricing of options and corporate liabilities, Journal of Political Economy 81, no. 3. Campbell, Cynthia J. and Charles E. Wasley, 1994, Executive compensation: The case of Ralston Purina Company (Washington University, St. Louis, MO). Crystal, Graef S. and Fred K. Foulkes, 1988, Don’t bail out underwater options, Fortune, March 14. DeAngelo, Harry and Linda DeAngelo, 1991, Union negotiation and corporate policy: A study of labor concessions in the domestic steel industry during the 1980s Journal of Financial Economics 30, no. 1. Dechow, Patricia, Mark Huson, and Richard Sloan, 1994, The effect of restructuring charges on executives’ cash compensation, Accounting Review 69, no. 1. Gaver, Jennifer J. and Kenneth M. Gaver, 1993, Additional evidence on the association between the investment opportunity set and corporate financing, dividend, and compensating policies, Journal of Accounting and Economics 16, no. l-3. Goyal, Vidhan, Kenneth Lehn, and Stank0 Racic, 1993, Investment opportunities, corporate finance, and compensation policy in the U.S. defense industry (University of Pittsburgh, Pittsburgh, PA). Healy, Paul, 1985, The effect of bonus schemes on accounting decisions, Journal of Accounting and Economics 7, no. l-3. Jensen, Michael C., 1986, Agency costs of free cash flow: Corporate finance and takeovers, American Economic Review 76, no. 2. Jensen, Michael C., 1989, Eclipse of the public corporation, Harvard Business Review, Sept./Ott. Jensen, Michael C.; 1991, Corporate control and the politics of finance, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Summer. Jensen, Michael C., 1993, The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems,Journal of Finance 48, no. 3. Jensen, Michael C. and Kevin J. Murphy, 1990a, Performance pay and top-management incentives, Journal of Political Economy 98, no. 2. Jensen, Michael C. and Kevin J. Murphy, 1990b, A new survey of executive compensation: Full survey and technical appendix, Working paper 90-067 (Harvard Business School, Boston, MA). Lundquist, Jerrold T., 1992, Shrink fast and smart in the defense industry, Harvard Business Review, Nov./Dee. Minnich, Richard T., 1993, U.S. defense industry in transition: Can the leopard change its spots?, Business Forum, Winter/Spring. Murphy, Kevin J., 1993, Executive compensation in corporate America (United Shareholders Association, Washington, DC). Murphy, Kevin J. and Jay Dial, 1993, General Dynamics: Compensation and strategy, (A) and (B), HBS case nos. 9-494-048 and 9-494-049 (Harvard Business School, Boston, MA). Rosen, Sherwin, 1982, Authority, control, and the distribution of earnings, Bell Journal of Economics 13, no. 2. Smale, John, 1989, Takeovers and the public interest, The Corporate Board, Sept./Ott. Smith, Clifford W. and Ross L. Watts, 1992, The investment opportunity set and corporate financing, dividend, and compensation policies, Journal of Financial Economics 32, no. 3. Stewart, G. Bennett, 1991, The quest for value: A guide for senior managers (HarperCollins Publishers, New York, NY).