The Emergence of Rural Artistic Havens:
A First Look
Timothy R. Wojan, Dayton M. Lambert, and David A. McGranahan
Nearly all applied research on arts activity has examined phenomena in metropolitan areas.
Findings from this past research confirm an arts specialization in a limited number of cities.
This paper finds a similar pattern in nonmetropolitan areas, where a limited number of counties maintain or develop a distinct specialization in the arts. We document the emergence of
these “rural artistic havens” and identify county characteristics associated with the attraction
of performing, fine, and applied artists. The implications of these findings for rural development strategies focusing on the arts are discussed.
Key Words: arts activity, built amenities, creative class, logistic regression, natural amenities,
tourism development
The belief that the arts are quintessential central
place functions—overwhelmingly concentrated in
the largest or most distinctive cities—is widely
held. Empirical work examining the location of
arts activity often starts from this premise (Florida 2002a, Heilbrun 1992, Markusen, Cameron,
and Schrock 2004). Richard Florida’s (2002a)
work on the “economic geography of bohemia”
examines the fifty largest Metropolitan Statistical
Areas (MSAs) and concludes that the arts are
highly concentrated in only a handful of places,
such as New York, Los Angeles, San Francisco,
Seattle, and Washington. The research discussed
in this paper arrives at a similar conclusion with
an important caveat—namely, that the arts are
highly concentrated, yet this is true across nearly
all tiers of the settlement hierarchy.
The possibility that some rural areas serve as
magnets for artistic activity has not been comprehensively investigated. Yet, two developments
_________________________________________
Timothy Wojan is Regional Economist and David McGranahan is Senior Economist at the Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of
Agriculture, Washington, D.C. Dayton Lambert is Assistant Professor
in the Department of Agricultural Economics at the University of Tennessee in Knoxville. Some of the findings from this paper were presented at the Opportunities and Challenges Facing the Rural Creative
Economy Workshop, sponsored jointly by the Northeastern Agricultural
and Resource Economics Association and the Northeast Regional Center for Rural Development, in Mystic, Connecticut, on June 13–14, 2006.
The workshop received financial support from the Northeast Regional
Center for Rural Development.
The views expressed here are the authors’ and not necessarily those
of the Economic Research Service, the U.S. Department of Agriculture,
or the University of Tennessee, nor of the workshop’s sponsoring
agencies.
suggest strong economic rationales for some artists choosing rural addresses. From the demand
side, the growth of tourism in some rural areas
may support arts markets despite relatively low
population density. Alternatively, footloose artists
supplying regional or national markets may choose
to live in amenity-rich rural areas, similar to other
footloose creative professionals (McGranahan
and Wojan 2007). The analysis will address two
questions posed by these developments. First, are
artists becoming more prevalent in rural areas? In
those particular rural areas where artists cluster,
what role do demand and supply factors play in
explaining this phenomenon?
The interest in these questions goes beyond
filling a gap in the academic literature. The substantial and growing number of rural initiatives
that have made arts and culture the centerpiece of
development efforts provides a strong motivation
for analysis. Examples of these initiatives include
the Arts Build SmART Communities Project at
the University of Wisconsin in Platteville, the effort to brand Paducah, Kentucky, as the “SoHo of
the South” through its Artist Relocation Program,
and the effort in Maine to anchor its statewide
creative economy initiatives in arts and culture.1
The interest that these and similar examples are
generating in town halls, economic development
1
See http://www.uwplatt.edu/cont_ed/artsbuild/welcome.html, http://
paducahtourism.org/content.asp?Content=Arts+%26+Culture, and http://
www.maine.gov/governor/baldacci/vision/culture.html, respectively.
Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 36/1 (April 2007) 53–70
Copyright 2007 Northeastern Agricultural and Resource Economics Association
54 April 2007
consultancies, county extension offices, and state
houses makes clear the need for analyzing the
location of artists in rural areas.
Central to our analysis is the notion of an “arts
community” that flows out of an agglomeration
of artists in a place. The location of some artists
in rural areas is unremarkable. The anticipated
benefits from arts or cultural tourism promotion,
or the consumption amenities associated with a
lively arts sector, are more likely found in places
securing a minimum critical mass of artists or
performers. We arrive at reasonable, though necessarily arbitrary, criteria for defining “rural artistic havens” that conform to this notion of an arts
community, using detailed occupational data from
decennial censuses. We then investigate countylevel characteristics that differentiate artistic havens from all other nonmetro counties using a logistic regression model.
Our findings document the presence and genesis of artistic havens, thus reinforcing claims that
some rural areas are capable of attracting creative
talent. Results from the logistic regression model
provide insight as to which rural areas are most
likely to develop as artistic havens. These results
have implications for the feasibility of arts-based
tourism strategies and creative economy strategies
more generally.
Trends in Artists’ Migration to
Nonmetropolitan Counties
For the purposes of this study, arts occupations
are defined by the most detailed occupational
classification available at the county level for
2000. Within the 93 detailed occupations included in the Census STF4 file, “art and design
workers” and “entertainers and performers, sports,
and related workers” are the only two categories
that are not substantially commingled with nonarts occupations. Fortunately, 511 detailed occupations are available at the county level for 1990
from the Equal Employment Opportunity Commission (EEOC) special tabulation of the Census,2 which allows constructing comparable measures for the two years. The corresponding 1990
occupational categories are “designers,” “paint2
In 2000, this information was provided only for counties or groups
of counties with populations of more than 50,000, to meet new nondisclosure rules.
Agricultural and Resource Economics Review
ers, sculptors, craft-artists, and artist printmakers,” “photographers,” “musicians and composers,”
“actors and directors,” “dancers,” “athletes,” and
“artists, performers, and related workers, n.e.c.”
The 2000 aggregation does not allow for purging
athletes from the data series, though they comprise a minimal share of the total, nor does it allow the inclusion of authors who are commingled
with the considerably larger number of technical
writers.
The national arts employment share increased
marginally, from 1.14 percent to 1.16 percent,
between 1990 and 2000. However, the growth in
this share was due almost exclusively to growth
in nonmetro arts, as the metro share was 1.26
percent in both years. In 1990, the nonmetro arts
employment share was roughly half (0.64 percent) that of the metro share, increasing to 0.71
percent by 2000.
Table 1 provides information on the distribution of arts occupations by settlement size, using
the 1993 Economic Research Service’s RuralUrban Continuum code. Within metropolitan counties, central counties of large metro areas contain
the largest share of artists, comprising close to 1.5
percent of total employment. This share remained
constant between 1990 and 2000. The substantially lower arts share in all nonmetro settlement
types confirms the perception of arts as a central
place function. The data also suggest that growth
in arts employment shares has been more rapid in
nonadjacent counties. In fact, for each of the size
classes, the 2000 arts share in the nonadjacent
counties surpassed that of the corresponding adjacent counties.
The salient feature of Table 1 is a surprising
similarity in arts occupation shares throughout the
settlement hierarchy given priors of a highly
concentrated economic sector. At least at the aggregate level, it appears that some share of arts
employment can be characterized as a nonbasic
sector that serves the local population. The fact
that very few counties had no artists in 1990
(114) or 2000 (80) reinforces this characterization. At the other extreme, very few counties
(metro or nonmetro) have arts employment shares
of more than 2 percent.
Florida’s (2002a) interpretation of a highly
concentrated spatial distribution of artists makes
more sense in considering the surplus in artists in
a particular place above a common basal level. In
Wojan, Lambert, and McGranahan
The Emergence of Rural Artistic Havens: A First Look 55
Table 1. The Spatial Distribution of Arts Occupations
Settlement Type
U.S. Total
1990
2000
% Change
Arts Occs.
Total Empl.
Share
1,282,119
112,304,720
1.14%
1,464,999
126,376,878
1.16%
14.26%
12.53%
1993 Rural-Urban Continuum Code
METRO COUNTIES
0
Central counties of metro areas of 1 million
population or more
Arts Occs.
Total Empl.
Share
796,538
54,813,418
1.45%
859,633
59,384,093
1.45%
7.92%
8.34%
-0.39%
1
Fringe counties of metro areas of 1 million
population or more
Arts Occs.
Total Empl.
Share
37,358
4,302,519
0.87%
52,781
5,626,721
0.94%
41.28%
30.78%
8.03%
2
Counties in metro areas of
250,000 to 1 million population
Arts Occs.
Total Empl.
Share
260,267
25,184,100
1.03%
306,817
28,868,027
1.06%
17.89%
14.63%
2.84%
3
Counties in metro areas of fewer than
250,000 population
Arts Occs.
Total Empl.
Share
81,005
9,001,699
0.90%
99,700
10,372,818
0.96%
23.08%
15.23%
6.81%
NONMETRO COUNTIES
4
Urban population of 20,000 or more,
adjacent to a metro area
Arts Occs.
Total Empl.
Share
32,471
4,181,671
0.78%
39,605
4,726,285
0.84%
21.97%
13.02%
7.92%
5
Urban population of 20,000
or more, not adjacent to a metro area
Arts Occs.
Total Empl.
Share
21,806
2,778,443
0.78%
28,048
3,170,849
0.88%
28.63%
14.12%
12.71%
6
Urban population of 2,500 to
19,999, adjacent to a metro area
Arts Occs.
Total Empl.
Share
39,957
6,773,514
0.59%
50,335
7,860,997
0.64%
25.97%
16.05%
8.55%
7
Urban population of 2,500 to
19,999, not adjacent to a metro area
Arts Occs.
Total Empl.
Share
32,235
5,304,523
0.61%
42,090
5,971,691
0.70%
30.57%
12.58%
15.98%
8
Completely rural or less than
2,500 urban population, adjacent to a metro
area
Arts Occs.
Total Empl.
Share
5,846
1,033,342
0.57%
7,231
1,240,179
0.58%
23.69%
20.02%
3.06%
9
Completely rural or less than
2,500 urban population, not adjacent to a
metro area
Arts Occs.
Total Empl.
Share
6,839
1,400,894
0.49%
9,787
1,575,792
0.62%
43.11%
12.48%
27.22%
Source: 1990 EEOC special tabulation of the Census, and 2000 Census STF4.
the fifty largest metropolitan areas, Florida finds a
significant surplus in only a handful of cities. Examining the distribution of arts employment
shares across all settlement types provides a much
fuller picture of bohemia in America. This exercise (Figure 1) demonstrates that the recognized
large metro centers in New York, Los Angeles,
and San Francisco have peers in nearly all of the
settlement types, starting with smaller metro areas
(e.g., Santa Fe), the largest nonmetro counties
(e.g., Ulster County, New York, containing Woodstock), and extending down to completely rural
counties (e.g., San Juan and San Miguel counties
in Colorado, containing Silverton and Telluride,
respectively). Figure 1 compels a closer examination of the genesis of rural areas with relatively
high shares of arts occupations.
56 April 2007
a
Agricultural and Resource Economics Review
See Table 1 for category descriptions.
Figure 1. Box Plot Comparing Arts Employment Shares Across the Rural-Urban Continuum,
with Outliers
Defining and Delineating Artistic Havens
Figure 1 makes clear that some rural counties are,
or have become, magnets for artists. Anecdotal
accounts (Markusen and Johnson 2006, Villani
1998) have examined the existence of “arts communities” that flow out of the agglomeration of
artists in a place. The idea is that a minimum
critical mass of artists or performers is required
such that members of the community benefit from
substantial interaction among themselves and the
group is large enough to affect culture of the
wider community.
Two quantitative criteria delineate the artistic
haven construct: (i) artists comprise a substantive
share of total employment, and (ii) artists are sufficiently numerous to create the critical mass required of an arts community. Establishing thresholds for these criteria is clearly subjective, but we
will argue that the thresholds chosen are reasonable. It is important to note that the thresholds
define an empirical construct helpful in analyzing
an interesting phenomenon. This approach emphasizes identifying assets that may be valuable
in local development strategies.
We first set an absolute minimum screen of 40
artists as a criterion for classification as an artistic
haven. This absolute threshold reinforces the “arts
community” aspect of the construct and it substantially reduces the likelihood of false positives
in the classification based on sampling error. This
is because occupational census data are based on
the 1-in-6 long form sample, so the relative scarcity of arts employment may lead to large errors
in counties with very small employment bases.
Given the expectation that artistic havens are
relatively rare, false positives are of greater concern than false negatives in the estimations that
follow.
Arriving at the second quantitative criterion—
the threshold that constitutes a substantive share
of arts employment—is also highly subjective.
Wojan, Lambert, and McGranahan
However, statistics does provide an objective
criterion for determining when a threshold is too
restrictive (Hsieh 1989). From this perspective,
the optimal arts share threshold is one that is as
high as possible to ensure that these employment
shares are in fact distinctive, but not so high that
there are too few artistic havens for the results to
be statistically powerful.
We use the presence of a 4-year college as the
explanatory variable of interest given anecdotal
evidence of the importance of colleges to local
arts communities and the ease of interpreting the
odds ratio of a binary variable.3 In concrete terms,
our statistical test should be able to detect whether
the presence of a 4-year college increases the
odds of being classified as an artistic haven by 50
percent. Entering these various parameters, we
arrive at a threshold arts employment share corresponding to the 95th percentile of the arts employment share distribution, or an employment
share of 1.07 percent in the 1990 data.4 A comparison of means presented later in the paper
(Table 4) confirms that the arts employment share
in our delineated havens is three times the arts
share in other nonmetro counties, providing assurance of their distinctiveness.
We examine two distinct phenomena in the
data independently—counties that are classified
as artistic havens in 1990 and counties that
achieved the threshold arts employment share
with at least 40 artists in 2000. See box for construction of the samples used in these analyses.
We classify the 90 counties meeting artistic haven
thresholds in 1990 as established havens. Sixteen
additional counties met the employment share
3
In the regressions that follow, we use the share of the 18–24 population enrolled in college to represent the relative importance of colleges
in a county. Given the strong correlation between the presence of a 4year college and student enrollment, the sample size calculations using
either variable are similar.
4
To apply this criterion, we define an acceptable type I error
probability at 0.05 and an acceptable type II error probability at 0.10,
in accordance with standard rules of thumb. Using the sample size in
Table III from Hsieh (1989, p. 798), we arrive at this 5th percentile
cutoff by first computing the multiple correlation coefficient (ρ) for the
presence of a 4-year college with all other covariates. Dividing the column entries associated with detecting a 1.5 odds ratio by (1 – ρ) provides the minimum required sample size. Our sample size of roughly
2,100 counties will in fact provide powerful results for an event probability as small as 4 percent, but we use the threshold corresponding
with the 95th percentile as a conservative measure that is commonly
applied. The required sample size is highly sensitive to the effect size
the test is intended to detect. For example, detecting a minimal effect
size of a 10 percent increase in likelihood with an event probability of
5 percent would require a sample nearly twenty times larger.
The Emergence of Rural Artistic Havens: A First Look 57
threshold but had fewer than 40 artists in 1990,
and so were not classified as established havens.
These same counties also failed to meet the 40
artist minimum screen in 2000 and so were excluded from the emerging havens analysis, along
with the 90 established havens from 1990. Counties that had very small employment bases (fewer
than 1,066 employees) were excluded from the
analysis, as these counties would fail to meet the
absolute threshold even with the largest arts employment shares observed in these data. There
were 109 counties meeting identical artistic haven
thresholds in 2000 that were classified as emerging havens. This structure allows us to differentiate havens from nonhavens in 1990, and then to
differentiate counties that became havens from
those that remained nonhavens in 2000.
Artistic havens represented as places are mapped
in Figure 2, with the corresponding county names
provided in Table 2. Most notably, the Mountain
West and the Northeastern United States contain
contiguous counties of artistic havens. However,
artistic havens are found throughout the United
States. Particularly notable is the recent vintage of
many of these artistic havens. With only a few
exceptions (e.g., Branson, Missouri; Leelanau
County, Michigan; and Door County, Wisconsin,
on Lake Michigan), the diffusion of havens
throughout the middle of the country is a recent
phenomenon. The map confirms that artistic
SAMPLE SIZES IN ESTABLISHED HAVEN AND
EMERGING HAVEN ANALYSIS
Total number of nonmetropolitan counties in
1990
minus Alaska and Hawaii counties
minus counties with very small employment base
(fewer than 1,066 workers)
Sample size for established haven analysis
2,260
-6
-113
2,141
minus counties classified as established havens
-90
minus counties meeting artist employment share
threshold but failing the 40 artist minimum
screen in 1990 and 2000
-16
Sample size for emerging haven analysis
2,035
Counties classified as emerging havens
109
Total number of established and emerging havens
199
58 April 2007
Agricultural and Resource Economics Review
Figure 2. Map of Established and Emerging Rural Artistic Havens, 2000
havens as defined are geographically dispersed
phenomena. Those county characteristics associated with the genesis of artistic havens are examined next.
Attributes Associated with Artist Location
We review research examining the location of artists from the cultural economics literature, the
emerging literature on the creative economy, and
anecdotal accounts of rural arts communities in
the academic and popular literature to arrive at
our specification of an econometric model for
characterizing rural artistic havens.
Heilbrun (1996) analyzed state-level characteristics associated with the level of arts activity,
proxied by the number of artists per 10,000 residents. Activity in the performing arts was positively associated with metropolitan area size, the
size of the tourism sector (using hotel receipts as
a proxy), income per capita, and ethnic diversity,
measured as the share of the population made up
of Hispanics and non-whites. All of these results
confirmed the importance of various demand factors as predicted. In contrast, with the exception
of ethnic diversity, none of these factors was associated with visual arts activity, consistent with
the expectation that visual artists are more footloose and not as dependent on local market demand. However, visual arts activity was associated with the educational attainment of the population (while performing arts activity was not).
Heilbrun interprets educational attainment as a
proxy for area attractiveness to footloose professionals, effectively increasing the supply of visual
artists.
Factors affecting the supply of creative professionals are the focus of the emerging creative
economy literature (e.g., New England Council
2001, Florida 2002a, Florida 2002b, Markusen,
Cameron, and Schrock 2004, Markusen and Johnson 2006). Florida (2002a) examines the correlation between the employment share in the arts
(his bohemian index includes performing artists,
visual artists, and authors) and various indices
constructed for the 50 largest Metropolitan Statistical Areas (MSAs) with a population of more
than 700,000. Arts activity is strongly correlated
with a talent index (percentage of the population
with at least a bachelor’s degree), a melting pot
Wojan, Lambert, and McGranahan
The Emergence of Rural Artistic Havens: A First Look 59
Table 2. List of Nonmetropolitan Established and Emerging Haven Counties
ESTABLISHED HAVENS RANKED BY 1990 ARTS EMPLOYMENT SHARE
Blaine, ID
Pitkin, CO
Gilpin, CO
Sagadahoc, ME
Teton, WY
Taos, NM
Taney, MO
Nantucket, MA
San Miguel, CO
Dickinson, KS
Knox, ME
Dukes, MA
Linn, MO
Jefferson, IA
Yavapai, AZ
Eagle, CO
Lamoille, VT
Leelanau, MI
Maui, HI*
Lincoln, ME
Nevada, CA
Ulster, NY
Park, WY
Teller, CO
Mariposa, CA
Summit, CO
Garfield, CO
Rappahannock, VA
Hawaii, HI*
Torrance, NM
Clay, SD
Park, CO
Monroe, FL
Latah, ID
Swisher, TX
Gallatin, MT
Columbia, NY
Litchfield, CT
Jack, TX
Greene, NY
Douglas, NV
Custer, SD
La Plata, CO
Terrell, GA
Tompkins, NY
Cook, MN
Mendocino, CA
Windham, VT
Bandera, TX
Polk, NC
Washington, VT
Lake, MT
Amador, CA
Story, IA
Door, WI
Dickinson, IA
Cheshire, NH
Routt, CO
Summit, UT
Windsor, VT
Benton, OR
Cedar, MO
Franklin, MA
Carroll, AR
Brown, IN
Missoula, MT
Addison, VT
Jefferson, MT
Dare, NC
Delaware, NY
Chariton, MO
Carroll, NH
Appomattox, VA
Clear Creek, CO
Ramsey, ND
Glynn, GA
Roberts, SD
Rio Arriba, NM
Walworth, WI
Yankton, SD
Jackson, NC
Dawson, GA
Kauai, HI*
Tuolumne, CA
Grand Traverse, MI
Jo Daviess, IL
Citrus, FL
McDonough, IL
Humboldt, CA
Calaveras, CA
Cochise, AZ
Fremont, CO
Newport, RI
EMERGING HAVENS RANKED BY 2000 ARTS EMPLOYMENT SHARE
Haines, AK*
Mono, CA
Gunnison, CO
Jefferson, WA
Lincoln, NM
Grand, CO
Teton, ID
Whitman, WA
Albany, WY
Lincoln, GA
Indian River, FL
Gillespie, TX
Walton, FL
Northumberland, VA
Oktibbeha, MS
Decatur, IA
Grafton, NH
Watauga, NC
Mitchell, NC
Beaufort, SC
Rio Grande, CO
Hood River, OR
Llano, TX
Park, MT
Chaffee, CO
Kent, MD
Wasatch, UT
Bennington, VT
Forrest, MS
Riley, KS
Stevens, MN
McCormick, SC
Stone, MO
Bayfield, WI
Emmet, MI
Bonner, ID
Carbon, MT
Ravalli, MT
Moore, NC
Crawford, KS
Comanche, TX
Rutland, VT
Nodaway, MO
Lafayette, MS
Deschutes, OR
Colfax, NM
Delta, CO
Grand, UT
Archuleta, CO
Lincoln, LA
Kerr, TX
Cache, UT
Roosevelt, NM
Hancock, ME
Brewster, TX
Silver Bow, MT
Kendall, TX
Bulloch, GA
Wayne, PA
Erath, TX
Adair, MO
Kittitas, WA
Clark, AR
Payne, OK
Swain, NC
Bremer, IA
Towns, GA
Sioux, IA
Orange, VT
Source: Authors’ tabulation.
Note: * denotes county not included in regression analysis.
Steele, MN
Skagit, WA
Putnam, TN
Ralls, MO
Nicollet, MN
Buffalo, NE
Rice, KS
Lake, CO
Beaverhead, MT
Madison, ID
Lewis, TN
Montgomery, VA
Sawyer, WI
Crow Wing, MN
Portage, WI
Lee, AL
Leflore, MS
Klickitat, WA
York, ME
Pocahontas, WV
Essex, NY
Vilas, WI
Jefferson, TN
Flathead, MT
Prince Edward, VA
George, MS
Jay, IN
Plumas, CA
Coconino, AZ
Garland, AR
Union, PA
Matanuska-Susitna, AK*
Izard, AR
Henderson, NC
Mitchell, IA
Brookings, SD
Monongalia, WV
Houghton, MI
Marquette, MI
Worcester, MD
Washington, UT
Rockbridge, VA
60 April 2007
index (percentage of the population that is foreign-born), a gay index (percentage of households
in which a householder and an unmarried partner
are both of the same sex), and a high-tech or techpole index (a composite measure that includes the
percentage of national high-tech output and a
high-tech location quotient).
Markusen and Johnson (2006) examine the distribution of arts occupations throughout the entire
state of Minnesota, with a special emphasis on the
role that artists’ centers play in promoting and
sustaining a local arts community. The study provides a detailed look at the importance of an arts
infrastructure (e.g., gallery, performance, and rehearsal space, and focal points for arts education,
for interaction of professional and amateur artists,
and for exchange with the wider community). Data
on artist location by age cohort in Minnesota confirms that Minneapolis is a draw for artists aged
16–34, but that Greater Minnesota gains artists in
the 35–44 and over-65 age cohorts. They conclude that lower cost of living and environmental
amenities may attract mature artists who have established their careers.
The description is consonant with findings from
an analysis of the rural creative class (McGranahan and Wojan 2007). Natural and recreational
amenities were strongly associated with the share
of highly creative occupations in a county. Rural
creative class workers were older and more likely
to be married than their urban peers.
The strongest evidence that artists are concentrating in some rural areas comes from the popular literature. John Villani’s (1998) frequently updated guide, The 100 Best Small Art Towns in
America, identifies a number of genuine rural
towns that contain distinctive arts communities.
Written as a travel guide, the book provides a rich
description of what to expect on an arts excursion
in the country, providing anecdotal evidence of
arts markets existing in a limited number of rural
areas. In addition to galleries and performance
spaces, special note is made of microbreweries
(or the infrequent absence of any), historic buildings and old town squares, charming bed and
breakfasts, and stirring vistas or waterfront.
Variable Selection
We combine the statistical and anecdotal analysis
of artist and creative class location decisions sum-
Agricultural and Resource Economics Review
marized above to select variables for our logistic
regression model. We classify these variables as
supporting either the supply (quality of life) or
demand (arts market) rationales for the rural residential choices of artists. For ease of exposition,
the variables are grouped in conceptual categories
relating to settlement patterns, economic structure, natural amenities, built amenities, arts infrastructure, tourism, cost of living, and ethnic diversity. Descriptive statistics are provided in
Table 3.
Settlement Patterns
Past work on the rural creative class confirms that
footloose professionals prefer rural counties with
moderate population density to support a range of
consumer services, but not so densely populated
as to emulate urban environments. A measure of
1990 population density (Population density, expected sign +) is included in the regression, along
with the square of this measure (expected sign -),
both of which are hypothesized to influence the
supply of creative professionals, including artists.
Population growth in the preceding decade (Population change) indicates more favorable demand
conditions for nascent arts markets and is anticipated to be positively associated with the likelihood of being an artistic haven. A variable that
may affect both the supply of artists and the local
demand for the arts is the percentage of the adult
population over 62 years of age (Population over
62). Baby-boomers winding down their occupational careers may find artistic havens attractive
places to retire, either because they are seeking
rural locations with consumption amenities related to culture, or because they envision taking
up new careers in the arts. The expected sign of
this variable is positive and, as with population
growth, exogeneity of this variable is tested given
a strong conceptual argument that the variable
may be endogenous. Distance (in road miles) to
the nearest metropolitan county is included in the
regression (Road distance, expected sign -). The
final settlement pattern variable also measures
proximity effects. It is the spatial lag of the art
employment share of a county in 1990 (Spatial
lag arts share, expected sign +). Neighboring
counties were identified using a scaled inverse
distance matrix (details are below in the Methods
section). Potential “cultural spillover” effects could
Wojan, Lambert, and McGranahan
The Emergence of Rural Artistic Havens: A First Look 61
Table 3. Variables and Descriptive Statistics
Variable Name
Population density
Variable Description
Ln of population density, 1990
Source
Census STF4
N
2260
Mean
5.06
Std. Error
0.026
Population change
Ln of population change, 1980–1990
Census STF4
2260
4.60
0.003
Population over 62
Percent population above 62, 1990
Census STF4
2260
18.95
0.097
Road distance
Road distance (miles) to nearest
metropolitan county
ESRI, ERS
2260
57.30
1.035
Spatial lag arts share
Spatial lag of 1990 arts employment
share
Census STF4
2141
1.38
0.009
Arts share 1990
Share of artist employment, 1990
Census STF4
2260
0.005
0.00007
Arts share 2000
Share of artist employment, 2000
Census STF4
2260
0.006
0.00009
Median income
Ln of median household income, 1990
Census STF4
2260
3.05
0.004
Out commuters
Percent commute outside county,
1990
Census STF4
2260
25.35
0.318
Business services
Percent business services, 1990
Census STF4
2260
4.16
0.034
Manufacturing
Percent manufacturing, 1990
Census STF4
2260
18.43
0.238
B.A./B.S. degree
Percent of 25–44 with at least 4-year
degree, 1990
Census STF4
2260
14.56
0.122
Topography
Multiplicative measure of topography
and elevation
McGranahan 1999
2260
6.05
0.106
Land in forest
Percent of land in forest, state-level
surveys 1987–1992
Forest Service
2260
37.40
0.670
Water area
Ln of water area (z-score)
McGranahan 1999
2260
-0.10
0.020
January temperature
January temperature (z-score)
McGranahan 1999
2260
-0.07
0.021
January sun
January days of sun (z-score)
McGranahan 1999
2260
0.04
0.021
July temperature
July residual temperature
McGranahan 1999
2260
-0.04
0.021
McGranahan 1999
2258
0.10
0.022
Presence of winery (0–1), 1990
1990 county business
patterns (CBP)
2260
0.03
0.003
Bike trails
Openings for rail to trail conversions
before 1993
Rail to Trails
Conservancy
2244
0.14
0.010
Historic places
Entries in National Register of
Historic Places, 1990
National Park Service
2260
9.52
0.301
Big box retail
Department stores with > 100
employees
1990 county business
patterns (CBP)
2260
0.46
0.020
College enrollment
Enrolled college students, 1990
Census STF4
2260
21.38
0.290
Nonprofit organizations
Number of nonprofit
organizations/associations, 1990
Rupasingha, Goetz,
& Freshwater 2006
2260
9.69
0.298
Hotel and restaurant
employment
Percent employment hotels and eating
establishments, 1990
Census STF4
2260
5.23
0.054
Lodging size structure
Modified Herfindahl of lodging
establishments, 1990
1990 county business
patterns (CBP)
2257
16.13
0.805
Seasonal homes
Seasonal homes over total, 1990
Census STF4
2260
6.90
0.218
Median rent
Median gross housing rent
Census STF4
2260
286.26
1.317
Foreign born
Percent foreign born, 1990
Census STF4
2260
0.02
0.001
Ethnic diversity
Ethnolinguistic fractionalization, 1990
Census STF4
2260
0.18
0.004
July humidity
July humidity (-1 × z-score)
Wine county
62 April 2007
work through both the demand side, by increasing
the effective size of the local arts market, and the
supply side, by representing unobserved regional
factors that are especially attractive to artists.
Economic Structure
Following Heilbrun (1996), we include the natural log of 1990 county median income (Median
income) to assess whether higher incomes are associated with artistic haven status. The 1990 employment shares of Manufacturing and Business
services are included to assess whether these sectors systematically increase or decrease the likelihood of developing as an artistic haven. Artists
may be averse to the disamenities associated with
industrial development, suggesting an expected
negative sign on the Manufacturing variable coefficient estimate, while higher employment shares
in Business services may indicate attractiveness to
creative professionals and the coefficient estimate
is expected to be positive. The share of workers
who commute out of the county (Out commuters)
is also included in the regression. We include a
variation of Florida’s talent index, comprised of
the share of workers, aged 25–44, with at least a
4-year college degree (B.A./B.S. degree, expected
sign +). Our choice of the 25–44 age group data
is driven by the need to reduce the influence of
potentially large older populations in some rural
areas that can depress educational attainment. The
variable should capture the influence of human
capital along with the attractiveness of the place
to footloose professionals, increasing the supply
of artists.
Natural Amenities
Natural amenities attract the rural creative class,
so it is reasonable to assume that amenities are
also important to the rural location decisions of
artists. An array of attributes is included in the regression to provide insight regarding the impact
of particular amenities. A multiplicative measure
that combines the “peakedness” of the local landscape with its elevation assesses the attraction of
mountains (Topography, expected sign +).5 The
5
These data come from The National Atlas of the United States of
America, U.S. Department of Interior, U.S. Geological Survey, Washington, D.C. (1937). The map legend contained two kinds of
scales. The first of these was a 5-point scale describing the basic topo-
Agricultural and Resource Economics Review
percentage of land in forests (Land in forest, expected sign +) and its squared term (expected sign
-) tests the hypothesis from the landscape preference literature that people prefer combinations
of forest and open space (Ulrich 1986). The value
of waterfront amenities is assessed using the
natural log of the proportion of county area that is
water, limited to a maximum of 250 square miles
(Water area, expected sign +) (from McGranahan
1999). Climatic variables related to January and
July temperatures (January temperature and July
temperature) and the amount of winter sunshine
(January sun) and summer humidity (July humidity) round out the natural amenity measures.
Two intermediate variables between natural
and built amenities are the classification as a wine
county—defined by the presence of one or more
wineries in 1990 (Wine county, expected sign
+)—and the presence of recreational bike trails
that opened by 1992 (Bike trails, expected sign
+). Villani (1998) makes special note of the winemaking traditions that are associated with a number of small arts towns. Wine tourism and arts
tourism may appeal to tourists seeking out cultural experience, suggesting a positive influence
on local arts markets. Florida (2002b) notes the
importance of an active lifestyle for the creative
class. Establishing a bike trail by 1992 (federal
funding for rail-to-trail conversion began in 1990)
may indicate an interest in promoting in a county
recreational amenities that are valued by footloose professionals.
Built Amenities
Florida (2002b) discusses the authenticity of
place as an important allure to the creative class,
using the dictum from Jane Jacobs (1961) that
“old ideas can sometimes use new buildings; new
ideas must use old buildings.” To assess the importance of authenticity to artistic havens, the
number of county entries in the National Register
of Historic Places as of 1990 (Historic places,
________________________________________________________
graphy, which ranged from “plains” to “plains with hills and mountains” to “hills and mountains.” The second kind was 4-point scales
that described incidental variation. Thus, one could have plains with
high mountains as well as generally varied (hills and mountains) areas
with high mountains. In general, variation within the basic categories
was greater at the top end of the basic scale than at the bottom. For instance, the basic “plains” category ranged only from “flat” to “irregular,” while the hills and mountains category ranged from “low hills” to
“high mountains.” We multiplied the basic by the incidental scores to
create our scale
Wojan, Lambert, and McGranahan
expected sign +) is included in the regression. To
assess possible negative contributions to authenticity (or town plans which are more automobiledependent), the number of large retail establishments (Big box retail, defined as the number of
retail establishments with more than 100 employees in 1990, expected sign -) is included in the
regression.
We include the percentage of 18–25 year olds
enrolled in college (College enrollment) to differentiate counties with substantial college towns
from counties lacking a significant college population. Colleges may either contribute to the built
amenities in a place, increase the demand for the
arts by supporting demographics typically attuned
to arts and culture, or be an important component
of the local arts infrastructure. The presence of
colleges was strongly associated with the attraction of rural creative class workers (McGranahan
and Wojan 2007). A similar impact is expected
for artistic havens, given the multiple roles colleges may play in increasing local demand for the
arts and in increasing the local supply of artists.
The Emergence of Rural Artistic Havens: A First Look 63
may employ substantial numbers of performers, is
included (Hotel and restaurant employment, expected sign +). A variable characterizing the composition of the lodging sector (Lodging size structure, expected sign +) is included to assess the anecdotal evidence that arts town accommodation
tends to be small-scale. It is computed as the
number of lodging establishments divided by the
Herfindahl employment concentration index for
all lodging establishments in a county (see Wojan
and Lackey 2000). The variable increases by the
square of the number of lodging establishments if
these establishments are of equal employment
size, but only linearly if employment is highly
concentrated in a small number of establishments.
We include the percentage of seasonal homes
(Seasonal homes, expected sign +) as another indicator of the attractiveness of the county in the
form of recreational opportunities, other consumption amenities, or the ease of access to major metropolitan areas. This variable may also capture
factors contributing to a high quality of life even
if these factors are not compelling enough to support a large local tourism industry.
Arts Infrastructure
Cost of Living
The potential role of nonprofit organizations in
promoting the arts is assessed by including the
total number of organizations in the National
Center for Charitable Statistics’ master file on or
before 1990 (Nonprofit organizations, expected
sign +).6 More generally, the variable provides an
indicator of local social capital. More specific data
on nonprofit arts organizations were not included
in the analysis due to problems of endogeneity.
Tourism Sector
The local tourism sector is the main channel
through which otherwise thin rural arts markets
become viable. At the state level, Heilbrun (1996)
includes lodging receipts as a proxy for the size
of the tourism sector in his analysis of the distribution of arts activity. Nondisclosure rules make
the inclusion of this variable infeasible at the
county level. However, data on employment in
the recreation sector, limited to hotels and restaurants in order to exclude detailed industries that
6
Derived from Rupasingha, Goetz, and Freshwater 2006, and available
at http://www. nercrd.psu.edu/Social_Capital/index.html.
Cost of living in a county is proxied by the 1990
median gross housing rent from the Census of
Housing (Median rent). Given low average incomes in the arts sector, it is anticipated that a
higher cost of living may reduce the attractiveness of a place to artists.
Diversity
Two variables are included to address whether
more ethnically diverse populations characterize
artistic havens. The percentage of the population
that was foreign-born (Foreign born, expected
sign +) recreates Florida’s melting pot index. Ethnic diversity is measured using the ethno-linguistic fractionalization measure (Ethnic diversity)
discussed in Alesina and La Ferrara (2004). It is
computed as
Ethnic Diversity = 1 – Σ i s i 2 ,
where si equals the share of population classified
as white, Hispanic, black, Asian, or Native American. Populations that are more diverse may sup-
64 April 2007
Agricultural and Resource Economics Review
port a larger number of artists, needed to serve
distinct cultural communities (Heilbrun 1996) or
indicate openness to alternative ways of thinking
(Florida 2002b). However, any association between diversity and openness may be less evident
in nonmetro areas, where many persistent poverty
counties contain large minority populations.
Empirical Model and Estimation
We use a logistic regression model to examine
county characteristics associated with the presence of a substantial artistic community. The extension of random utility maximization to this
analysis is not direct given that the “event” of
interest does not result from individual choice but
from the cumulative location decisions of a number of artists. The event also requires that a
county is relatively more attractive to artists than
to workers as a whole. We interpret the results as
representative of the location calculus of artists
seeking inclusion in an artistic community related
to the supply and demand factors described earlier. Standard errors of the logistic regressions
were estimated with Davidson and MacKinnon’s
(1993) jackknife heteroskedastic-consistent covariance matrix.
Given the inherently spatial nature of the data,
a modified Moran’s I test for spatial dependence
suitable for discrete choice models was used to
test for spatial dependence in the residuals (Munroe, Southworth, and Tucker 2002, Kelejian and
Prucha 2001). The statistic resembles the conventional Lagrange Multiplier test for spatial error
dependence, and is based on the residuals eˆi = yi –
F(xi′ β̂ ), where F( ) is a cumulative density function. The statistic is calculated as
I = eˆ ′Weˆ tr ( W * W * + W *′ W*) ,
where W* = W Σ̂ , and Σ̂ is a diagonal matrix
with the elements F(xi′ β̂ )[1 – F(xi′ β̂ )]. Our results are only approximate because this statistic is
based on the normal distribution. We rescaled the
logistic coefficients by
(
)
3 π β̂
to approximate probit estimates, and proceeded to
calculate the statistic (Maddala 1983). The statis-
tic is distributed as N(0,1). Connectivity between
counties was defined using an inverse distance
matrix. The elements of W are wij = dij −δ , where
dij is the distance between the centroid of county i
to neighbor j, and δ is a decay parameter describing the 1990 bohemian residential patterns over
space. When the scaling parameter (δ) is 0.5, then
the weight is the simple (inverse) Euclidean norm
distance between county i and j. Larger values of
δ mean that the influence of intercounty spillover
effects decreases more rapidly. The scaling parameter was estimated using the non-parametric
procedure of Fotheringham, Brunson, and Charlton (2002). The estimated scaling parameter was
1.25, suggesting that a simple Euclidean distance
measure would overestimate the importance of intercounty influence across space. The matrix was
row-standardized so that the elements of each row
of W summed to one. Spatial error dependence
was not detected at the 1 percent level in either
the emerging or established haven logistic regressions (I = 0.18 and 2.41).
Results
We begin our discussion by comparing the means
of the independent variables across the three relevant categories: emerging havens, established havens, and all other nonmetro counties included in
the regression analysis in Table 4. The comparisons of most interest are those relating to natural
and built amenities and to tourism, as these variables tend to be more evocative than those relating to settlement patterns, economic structure, or
diversity. Both emerging and established havens
tend to be located in more mountainous regions
(Topography), with a larger college-going population (College enrollment), with a larger lodging
and restaurant sector (Hotel and restaurant employment), and where the lodging sector is also
more diverse (Lodging size structure). In fact,
nearly all of the comparisons of the amenities and
tourism variables are as expected with the exception of the presence of large-scale retailing (Big
box retail). The descriptive statistics suggest that
both supply and demand factors play a role in the
formation of artistic havens. We now turn to the
logistic regression results to assess the net effects
of these variables on the likelihood of being classified as an artistic haven.
Wojan, Lambert, and McGranahan
The Emergence of Rural Artistic Havens: A First Look 65
Table 4. Means Comparison of Local Factors for Nonmetro Counties
ARTS EMPLOYMENT SHARES FOR 1990 AND 2000 USED TO CONSTRUCT DEPENDENT VARIABLE
Variable
Emerging (A)
Established (B)
Non-Haven (C)
Arts share 1990
0.007
B, C
0.015
A, C
0.004
A, B
Arts share 2000
0.014
C
0.015
C
0.005
A, B
5.45
C
5.08
A, B
INDEPENDENT VARIABLES
Population density
5.34
C
Population change
4.67
B, C
4.75
A, C
4.59
A, B
Population over 62
17.90
C
16.53
C
19.09
A, B
Road distance
52.77
43.75
C
57.47
B
Spatial lag arts share
1.21
C
1.12
C
1.39
A, B
Median income
3.11
B, C
3.27
A, C
3.04
A, B
Out commuters
19.52
C
23.17
25.78
A
Business services
5.29
B, C
6.96
A, C
3.99
A, B
Manufacturing
14.77
C
13.13
C
19.10
A, B
B.A./B.S. degree
21.74
B, C
24.00
A, C
13.70
A, B
Topography
9.44
B, C
11.67
A, C
5.58
A, B
Land in forest
48.59
C
53.33
C
36.32
A, B
Water area
0.12
C
0.23
C
-0.12
A, B
January temperature
-0.22
C
-0.35
C
-0.05
A, B
January sun
-0.02
0.25
C
0.03
B
July temperature
0.59
B, C
0.95
A, C
-0.12
A, B
July humidity
0.36
C
0.46
C
0.06
A, B
Wine county
0.01
B
0.14
A, C
0.02
B
Bike trails
0.32
C
0.34
C
0.12
A, B
Historic places
17.78
B, C
25.43
A, C
8.51
A, B
Big box retail
0.82
C
0.77
C
0.44
A, B
College enrollment
38.32
B, C
29.54
A, C
20.23
A, B
Nonprofit organizations
20.13
B, C
30.54
A, C
8.39
A, B
Hotel and restaurant employment
8.01
C
8.30
C
4.93
A, B
Lodging size structure
59.16
B, C
87.46
A, C
10.73
A, B
Seasonal homes
13.11
C
14.75
C
6.07
A, B
Foreign born
0.027
0.032
C
0.02
B
Ethnic diversity
0.18
0.14
A, C
0.19
A, B
B, C
Note: Letters A, B, and C indicate significant column differences based on pairwise two-tailed t-statistics at a 90 percent confidence level or higher. Equality of variances was tested using a folded F-test. When the null hypothesis of equal variances was rejected, Satterwaithe’s approximation was used to adjust the degrees of freedom for the t-tests.
66 April 2007
Results on population density parallel those
found for the rural creative class (McGranahan
and Wojan 2007), at least for established havens,
which were more likely in nonmetro counties of
moderate population density (Table 5). However,
this characteristic was not associated with emerging havens. Faster rates of population growth in
the 1980s also increased the likelihood of being
an established haven but were not significant in
the emerging havens regression. In fact, the only
settlement variable that was significant in both
the emerging and established havens regressions
was the Population over 62 variable. This is one
result that is at odds with the comparison of means
(Table 4), suggesting that retirement destination
counties are more likely to be artistic havens, ceteris paribus. We do not know whether this result
is explained by increased arts demand in retirement destination counties, by the mutual attraction of a place to artists and retirees (supply), or
by a growing numbers of artists in the rural over62 cohort (supply), suggesting an interesting topic
for future research.
Population change, Population over 62, and
Median rent are potentially endogenous variables.
While there are no direct tests for endogeneity,
exogeneity is a testable hypothesis. The VuongRivers test for exogeneity (Wooldridge 2002) was
used to test the hypothesis that the variables mentioned above were exogenous variables in our
models. The Type I error rate of the multiple tests
for exogeneity were adjusted using Bonferroni’s
procedure (Mittelhammer, Judge, and Miller 2000).7
The null hypothesis of exogeneity could not be
rejected for these variables at the 10 percent level
in the emerging haven equation (P = 0.70, 0.53,
and 0.08 for Population change, Population over
62, and Median rent, respectively). These results
corroborate those obtained from joint F-tests on
the residual coefficients for these variables in the
emerging haven model (F = 4.03, P = 0.25). In
the established havens model, the null hypothesis
of exogeneity was rejected at the 10 percent level
(P = 0.62, 0.88, and 0.01 for Population change,
Population over 62, and Median rent, respectively). The results are consistent with joint F-tests on
the residual coefficients for these variables in the
7
At α = 10 percent, with three restrictions in each equation, the adjusted Type-I error rate is 0.033. This approach is useful for specifically identifying which variable (s) fail the exogeneity test, which is
not possible with the joint F test.
Agricultural and Resource Economics Review
established haven equation (F = 8.83, P = 0.03).
While these results are encouraging for the emerging haven equation, there is reason to suspect that
Median rent is not exogenous in the established
haven model. To attend to this problem, the predicted values of Median rent were used as an instrument in the established haven equation.8
Results from the economic structure variables
confirm the importance of a highly educated
population in explaining artistic haven status. The
coefficient estimate on B.A./B.S. degree is both
highly precise and of relatively large magnitude
for both emerging and established havens regressions. This result is consistent with Florida’s study
of bohemia in large cities (2002a) and Heilbrun’s
study of arts activity across states (1996), explained in both cases as the attraction of a place
to highly educated and relatively footloose workers, including artists. For emerging havens, the
employment share in Manufacturing is positively
associated with the likelihood of being a haven,
an unexpected result made more interesting by
the seeming contradiction with the pairwise comparisons (Table 4).
One of the broadest distinctions between established and emerging havens is the relative importance of the natural amenity coefficient estimates. Mountains (Topography), mixed forest
cover (Land in forest and Land in forest squared),
and dry winters (January sun) are all associated
with established haven status, but none of these
variables is associated with emerging haven
status. In this respect, the locational preferences
associated with established havens more closely
resemble factors attracting creative class workers
more generally (McGranahan and Wojan 2007).
Referencing the descriptive statistics (Table 4), it
would be incorrect to characterize emerging havens as flat and deforested; yet, after controlling
8
The instruments used in the Vuong-Rivers test included all exogenous variables (excluding Population change, Population over 62, and
Median rent), and lagged socio-demographic and economic variables,
including the percentage of the population aged 7–17 (1980), the percentage commuting outside a county (1980), the percentage of the
workforce between 15 and 64 (1980), percentage of establishments in
the recreation industry (except hotels, 1980), percentage black, Native
American, and Hispanic (1980), the percentage of households with
children (1980), the percentage of the population above 62 years of age
(1980, used only in the Population over 62 test), and economic indicators of whether a county was designated a poverty-persistent county
or a retirement destination county, or if the county was dependent on
mining or manufacturing in 1979. The same instruments were used to
generate predicted values of Median rent.
Wojan, Lambert, and McGranahan
The Emergence of Rural Artistic Havens: A First Look 67
Table 5. Logistic Regression Results, p-Values, and Log Odds
Established Haven
Emerging Haven
Variable
Estimate
p-Value*
Constant
-30.232
0.0068
Odds
Estimate
p-Value
-28.584
0.0056
Odds
Population density
0.812
0.4533
2.52
0.0477
12.43
Population density squared
-0.058
0.5992
-0.299
0.0221
0.74
Population change
2.466
0.3033
3.00
0.1189
Population over 62
0.14
0.0023
Road distance
-0.005
Spatial lag arts share
Median income
1.15
0.105
0.0061
0.2753
-0.004
0.3493
1.039
0.1523
0.803
0.3278
0.188
0.9032
-2.77
0.3869
Out commuters
0.012
0.4058
0.0003
0.9809
Business services
0.191
0.1082
0.203
0.111
Manufacturing
0.055
0.0209
1.056
0.006
0.8437
B.A./B.S. degree
0.242
0
1.274
0.151
0.0001
1.11
1.162
Topography
0.065
0.129
0.123
0.0132
1.131
Land in forest
-0.009
0.7099
5.109
0.0798
165.6
Land in forest squared
0.0002
0.3914
-5.547
0.0601
0.004
Water area
0.1
0.6335
0.375
0.1217
January temperature
-0.024
0.9335
-0.556
0.1698
January sun
0.259
0.2108
0.537
0.0195
July temperature
0.301
0.1938
-0.049
0.8039
July humidity
0.574
0.0523
Wine county
-1.728
Bike trails
Historic places
Big box retail
1.775
-0.431
0.1682
0.1435
1.485
0.0066
0.338
0.1752
0.223
0.3052
0.007
0.3616
0.005
0.6222
-0.272
0.2003
-0.215
0.3071
College enrollment
0.036
0.0029
Nonprofit organizations
-0.013
0.4451
Hotel and restaurant employment
0.212
0.007
1.236
Lodging size structure
0.0106
0.0244
1.011
0.003
0.368
Seasonal homes
0.0194
0.2609
-0.051
0.0898
Median rent
-0.004
0.522
0.025
0.1945
Foreign born
9.083
0.0474
Ethnic diversity
1.952
0.2351
Number of havens (%)
1.037
1.09
-0.005
0.7012
-0.013
0.4344
-0.036
0.6792
-6.021
0.4459
-0.439
0.8085
109 (5.09)
90 (4.42)
N
2035
2141
Log likelihood (Lr)
-233
-189
Estrella’s adjusted R2 **
0.18
0.21
Source: Authors’ estimates.
* t tests based on jackknifed standard errors (Davidson and MacKinnon 1993).
** Estrella’s (1998) adjusted R2.
Note: In the established havens model, Median rent is predicted values because this variable failed the exogeneity test.
1.71
4.417
0.95
68 April 2007
for other factors, these variables are not powerful
in distinguishing emerging havens from other
nonmetro counties.
The relative importance of a local wine industry (Wine county) casts the strongest distinction
between established and emerging havens. While
a wine county was more than four times more
likely to be classified as an established haven, the
coefficient estimate in the emerging havens regression is negative and large in absolute value, albeit
failing to meet conventional levels of significance. The other built amenities variables have
the expected sign, but most (Bike trails, Historic
places, and Big box retail) are not estimated with
enough precision to be significantly different from
zero.
The findings on the impact of the percentage of
18–25 year olds enrolled in college (College enrollment) is particularly interesting given the
number of plausible explanations for a positive
association with haven status. Thus, for emerging
havens, the association might be explained by
greater demand for the arts, the positive impact
on the built environment, a substantial role in
supporting local arts infrastructure, or an increase
in the supply of artists. Yet none of these possible
channels appears to apply to established havens,
as the estimate is negative, though not significant.
Perhaps the best way to interpret this result is that
established havens in 1990 had significantly smaller
college enrollment share than many of the nonmetro counties that would become emerging havens in 2000.
The results confirm the importance of the tourism sector to arts activity, first identified by Heilbrun (1996), at least for emerging havens. The
impact of the share of Hotels and restaurant employment is significant only in the emerging havens regression. Again, the pairwise comparisons
are instructive as both emerging and established
havens have relatively high mean level hotel and
restaurant employment shares (Table 4). The composition of the lodging sector (Lodging size structure) is also positively associated with emerging
haven status—suggesting that smaller and more
intimate lodging options may be an important
asset in developing arts-based tourism promotion
strategies.
Ethnic diversity was not significantly associated with artistic haven status. However, a higher
percentage of a foreign-born population increased
Agricultural and Resource Economics Review
the likelihood of being classified as an emerging
haven. The emerging havens display similarities
with the large metropolitan arts magnets examined by Florida (2002a). The finding reinforces
the claim in Christopherson, Loker, and Monagan
(2006) that diversity has the potential to increase
the artistic and cultural vitality of rural places.
Conclusions
The decision to partition the analysis to examine
rural places that had attained an arts specialization in 1990, and those rural places that developed that specialization through the 1990s, was
driven initially by a sense that these places were
qualitatively different. Although the established
havens category contains some surprises, the majority of these counties are located in places of
spectacular natural beauty and/or located near distinctive cities such as New York or San Francisco. Comparing results from these analyses help
to illuminate the relative importance of supply
and demand factors in characterizing artistic havens.
Although variables related to either supply or
demand factors are significant in both the established and emerging havens regressions, supply
factors clearly dominate in the characterization of
established havens. Natural amenities and moderate population density required to support consumption amenities were significantly related to
established haven status. These same factors were
associated with the attraction of creative professionals in general (McGranahan and Wojan 2007).
While these natural amenities may also be important in attracting tourists, neither the composition
of the lodging sector nor the level of tourism activity were significantly related to established haven status. The strong association between established havens and a local wine industry reinforces
the impression that highly distinctive places appeal to footloose creative professionals.
In contrast, factors related to the demand for
the arts dominate in the emerging havens regression. Most importantly, both the level of tourism
activity and the composition of the lodging sector
are significantly related to the likelihood of supporting an arts community in 2000. College enrollment and the share of the population that is
foreign-born or over 62 years of age are other
factors that may increase local demand for the
Wojan, Lambert, and McGranahan
arts. While these variables may also increase the
supply of artists, independent of the effects on local demand for the arts, a clear distinction with
established havens emerges. Emerging havens appear to be much less reliant on the existence of an
irreproducible factor—such as the Rocky Mountains—in attracting artists to rural areas.
The implication of these findings is not that the
success of arts-based development strategies is no
longer dependent on the attractiveness of the rural
environment. The descriptive statistics (Table 4)
confirm that emerging havens are distinguished
from other nonmetro counties by the level of
natural amenities.9 What appears to matter most is
the opportunity for a high quality of life. The
strongest evidence for this claim comes from the
magnitude of the coefficient estimate on the percentage of 25–44 year olds with a college degree
in both the emerging and established havens
regressions. Since highly educated workers forfeit
the largest earnings premium by working in a
rural area, the opportunity for a high quality of
life can compensate for lower income. Clearly, a
high quality of life is not the only explanation of
this phenomenon, but inclusion of the B.A./B.S.
degree variable in our estimations often reduces
the magnitude or significance of other amenity
variables. This suggests that the locational sorting
of highly educated workers may be a very powerful proxy for quality of life. The implications of
these findings are that counties that have been
unable to retain highly educated workers are less
likely to attract artists in sufficient numbers to
constitute an arts community.
References
Alesina, A., and E. La Ferrara. 2004. “Ethnic Diversity and
Economic Performance.” NBER Working Paper No. 10313,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Christopherson, S., S. Loker, and S. Monagan. 2006. “The
Creative Economy Practitioner’s Toolkit: Taking Advantage of Campus and Community Resources.” Paper presented at the “Opportunities and Challenges of the Rural
Creative Economy” post-conference workshop at the Northeastern Agricultural and Resource Economics annual meetings in Mystic, Connecticut, on June 13, 2006.
9
An alternative specification not reproduced here finds that a composite natural amenities measure that captures the attractiveness of the
local landscape is significantly associated with emerging haven status.
The Emergence of Rural Artistic Havens: A First Look 69
Davidson, R., and J.G. MacKinnon. 1993. Estimation and Inference in Econometrics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Estrella, A. 1998. “A New Measure of Fit for Equations with
Dichotomous Dependent Variables.” Journal of Business &
Economic Statistics 16(2): 198–205.
Florida, R. 2002a. “Bohemia and Economic Geography.” Journal of Economic Geography 2(1): 55–71.
____. 2002b. The Rise of the Creative Class: And How It’s
Transforming Work, Leisure, Community, and Everyday Life.
New York: Basic Books.
Fotheringham, A.S., C. Brunson, and M. Charlton. 2002. Geographically Weighted Regression. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.
Heilbrun, J. 1992. “Art and Culture as Central Place Functions.” Urban Studies 29(2): 205–215.
____. 1996. “Growth, Accessibility, and the Distribution of
Arts Activity in the United States: 1980 to 1990.” Journal
of Cultural Economics 20(4): 283–296.
Hsieh, F.Y. 1989. “Sample Size Tables for Logistic Regression.” Statistics in Medicine 8(7): 795–802.
Jacobs, J. 1961. The Death and Life of Great American Cities.
New York: Random House.
Kelejian, H., and I.R. Prucha. 2001. “On the Asymptotic Distribution of the Moran I-Test Statistic with Applications.”
Journal of Econometrics 104(2): 219–257.
Maddala, G.S. 1983. Limited Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Markusen, A., M. Cameron, and G. Schrock. 2004. “The Artistic Dividend Revisited.” Working Paper No. 315, Project
on Regional and Industrial Economics, University of Minnesota.
Markusen, A., and A. Johnson. 2006. “Artists’ Centers: Evolution and Impact on Careers, Neighborhoods and Economies.” Project on Regional and Industrial Economics, University of Minnesota.
McGranahan, D.A. 1999. “Natural Amenities Drive Rural
Population Change.” AER-781, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Washington, D.C.
McGranahan, D.A., and T.R. Wojan. 2007. “Recasting the
Creative Class to Examine Growth Processes in Rural and Urban Counties.” Regional Studies 41(2): 197–217.
Mittelhammer, R.C., G.G. Judge, and D.J. Miller. 2000.
Econometric Foundations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Munroe, D.K., J. Southworth, and C.M. Tucker. 2002. “The
Dynamics of Land-Cover Change in Western Honduras:
Exploring Spatial and Temporal Complexity.” Agricultural
Economics 27(3): 355–369.
New England Council. 2001. “The Creative Economy Initiative: A Blueprint for Investment in New England’s Creative
Economy.” Report of the New England Council, Boston,
MA.
Rupasingha, A., S. Goetz, and D. Freshwater. 2006. “The Production of Social Capital in U.S. Counties.” Journal of
Socio-Economics 35(1): 83–101.
70 April 2007
Ulrich, R.S. 1986. “Human Responses to Vegetation and
Landscapes.” Landscape and Urban Planning 13(1): 29–
44.
Villiani, J. 1998. The 100 Best Small Art Towns in America
(3rd edition). Berkeley, CA: John Muir Publications.
Agricultural and Resource Economics Review
Wojan, T., and S. Lackey. 2000. “Manufacturing Specialization in the Southeast: Rural Necessity, Rural Possibility or
Rural Vestige?” Review of Regional Studies 30(2): 167–188.
Wooldridge, J. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section
and Panel Data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.