Fish: A Global Value Chain Driven
onto the Rocks
John Wilkinson
Abstract
This article discusses the fish sector in the light of the global value chain (GVC) approach
and particularly its demand- versus supply-driven typology. It is argued that especially in
the case of long-established food chains, such as fish, where multiple actors both public
and private have cumulatively defined and redefined policies and strategies, clear patterns of governance are less easy to establish than in the ideal-typical case of the fresh
fruit and vegetables sector. The article analyses the crisis of the capture fishing sector,
together with the regulatory systems put into place, and traces the explosive growth of
fish-farming, situating both within a redefinition of North-South relations in this global
value chain. Special attention is given to the role of catering and retail in the growth of
fish-farming and it is argued that retail is now committed to the latter’s promotion to a
degree which compromises its ‘consumer-oriented’ image. The article concludes that the
future of the fish sector cannot be left in the hands of the supermarkets’ putative capacity
to internalise consumer demand, but requires the direct involvement of the consumer–
citizen for the implementation of national and global regulation.
Introduction
Much recent literature on the globalisation of the agrofood system has been influenced by ‘global commodity chain’ (GCC) and ‘global value chain’ (CVC) research
(Gereffi 1994; Kaplinsky 2000), which has focused on the shift from supply to
demand-driven forms of governance. A similar line of analysis has been developed by
those who focus specifically on the hegemonic role of large-scale retail, particularly as
this latter has begun to impose its control also on the food systems of developing
countries. The evidence in favour of the ‘demand-driven’ thesis is especially forceful
when dealing with new food chains, particularly those whose production systems are
characterised by flexibility and low degrees of food processing. Not surprisingly, the
fresh fruit and vegetable sector has become a paradigm of the demand-driven thesis
and a rich analytical literature has emerged on the profile of this newcomer to global
value chains (Dolan et al. 2001; and Berdegué 2002, Reardon et al. 2003). We would
argue, however, that long-established food chains, where multiple actors, both public
and private, have cumulatively defined and redefined policies and strategies through
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Published by Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
ISSN 0038–0199
140
Wilkinson
complex procedures of conflict and compromise, may often assume a more systemic
dynamic that is less amenable than sectors such as fresh fruit and vegetables to clear
governance, whether by supply or demand.1
The shift to demand considerations is also associated with the redefinition of
markets according to quality criteria, leading to a mutually reinforcing association
between quality and demand-driven value chains. The food system is particularly
suited to such an analysis, as retail, which emerges as the hegemonic actor, is
characteristically unencumbered by the sunk costs of any particular food chain and
therefore singularly well placed to reorganise the agrofood system around the mobilisation of quality-based consumer demand, whether or not this conflicts with
entrenched supply side interests. While responsiveness to consumer demand has
become a powerful justification of retail strategy, a growing literature is contributing
to the creation of a more complex notion of the construction of consumer demand
(Warde and Martens 2000; Callon et al. 2002; Cochoy 2002; Harvey 2002). The
present article contributes to these debates on the role of quality and demand and will
concern itself with large-scale retail’s degree of autonomy in relation to other actors
and interests in the food chain. It will also consider the degree to which retail is itself
becoming locked-in to particular supply options which, in turn, limits its capacity for
demand responsiveness.
To explore these issues, we have chosen to analyse a particularly complex sector –
fish – which has re-emerged as a decisive component in the globalisation of the food
system, and a strategic, non-traditional export option for developing countries in the
form of fish-farming. Perhaps more than any other food product, the fish chain has
mobilised an array of public and private actors spanning nations and centuries and,
far from adjusting to strategic governance, whether of supply or demand, conforms
more to Giddens’ (1991) image (used as a generic description of high modernity) of a
juggernaut out of control. In addition, in this sector retail reveals itself to have
accumulated vested interests in the form of fish-farming supply systems, which in
turn makes it less responsive to consumer concerns in face of current doubts surrounding the health qualities of fish products.
In the following sections we will explore these issues by characterising the unique
features which have informed the specific patterns of globalisation in the fish chain.
Firstly, we consider trends in world production and the decisive role of world trade in
the characterisation of the fisheries sector. This is followed by a review of the features
leading to the current crisis of capture fishing. The third section evaluates the emergence of global patterns of fish-farming. In each of these sections we examine the
relative influence of different actors along the value chain in the restructuring of the
global fish economy, arguing that supply or demand characterisations must give way
to cumulative multi-causal analyses if current developments in this sector are to be
properly appreciated.
Global patterns of fish production, consumption and trade
World trade in processed, semi-processed or prepared food products as a proportion
of total world production for core diet foods such as milk, meats, fruit and vegetables
ranges from as low as 5 per cent up to 15 per cent. In 1995 the value of total trade in
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
Fish: a global value chain driven onto the rocks
141
horticulture products was US$15 billion, with meat at US$22 billion and tropical
beverages reaching US$29 billion (UNCTAD 1997). Global trade in fish products in
the same year reached US$46 billion and by 2001 that figure was over US$56 billion.
Almost 40 per cent of total fish production in live weight equivalent is incorporated
into world trade, with 50 per cent of this coming from developing countries. The net
revenue from fish exports by developing countries reached US$18 billion in 2001,
more than the combined net value of their rice, coffee, sugar, tea, banana and meat
exports (Ruckes 2003). On the other hand, Japan, the US and the EU are responsible
for almost 80 per cent of total imports. Over the last 20 years, trade flows have
completely reversed, with the developed world shifting from being a net exporter of
818,000 tons of food fish in 1973 to a net importer to the tune of 4,045,000 tons by
1997 (Delgado et al. 2003).
The trends in production are no less marked. Fish production based on capture
had its boom period in the 1950s and 1960s with an average 6 per cent annual growth
rate. From there on, however, growth slowed down dramatically to around 2 per cent
in the next 20 years and went into absolute decline in the 1990s. Aquaculture (inland
and marine), on the other hand, led by salmon and especially shrimp farming, has
had an astonishing record of annual growth: 5 per cent in the 1950s and 1960s, 8 per
cent in the 1970s and 1980s and 10 per cent in the 1990s (Sundar 2002). From being
a basically subsistence activity combined with rice production, aquaculture was
responsible for 37.5 million tons of production in 2001, equivalent to 40 per cent of
total capture fishery in that year (97.6 million tons). It is projected that by 2020
aquaculture will account for 40 per cent of total fish production (Delgado et al. 2003).
Initially overwhelmingly based on shrimp production in Asia and salmon in Chile,
Canada, Norway and Scotland, fish farming is now extending to white fish species and
is advancing into the Mediterranean (sea bass, bream) and Oceania (tuna, kingfish),
with an experimental development of off-shore aquaculture (halibut, haddock) in the
US (Staniford 2003).
Given this dramatic shift-around in trade, the global fish chain could well be
analysed within the parameters of the out-sourcing of production phases to developing countries, which has been a common practice in other activities, exploiting the
advantages in such countries of cheap labour, abundant and cheap resources and lax
regulatory regimes (Gereffi 1994). There is much truth in this perspective, but it
should be noted that salmon fish farming from the northern hemisphere is now the
prime source of supermarket sales for this product in the developed countries. The
regulation of fish farming in the developed world has in fact been equally lax,
primarily because it has been seen as the only viable solution to the intractable
problem of marine fish stock depletion. If the experiments in offshore fish farming
prove viable, it may well signal a return of production to the waters of the developed
countries.
The shift from capture to aquaculture brings with it all the characteristics of
intensive farming systems, thoroughly analysed in the agrofood literature, particularly in the case of feed-lots, pigs and poultry, and involving similar, if not even greater,
problems related to the environment, waste-product pollution, chemicals, veterinary
products (antibiotics, hormones) and intensive feeding systems. These latter have
been singled out as the Achilles heel of fish farming to the extent that there is no ready
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
142
Wilkinson
substitute for fishmeal based on pelagic, oily fish species which constitutes a crucial
component of capture fishing. It is estimated that 35 per cent of fishmeal and 70 per
cent of fish oil is already dedicated to aquaculture, figures which are projected to rise
to 56 per cent and 98 per cent respectively by 2010 (Staniford 2003). It comes as no
surprise that soymeal is already being experimented with as an alternative feed
supply, although the effects on final food taste may be a limiting factor. This shift from
capture to aquaculture has been legitimised by analogy with the evolution from
extractivism to the intensive production paradigm of the green revolution, and, to
push home the point, has been baptised as the ‘blue revolution’ (The Economist 2003).
The progressive convergence of animal protein production systems has led to an
ever greater involvement in the fish sector by leading players from other food chains
situated at different stages along the production process. The first move in this
direction was the result of the application of canning technology (Shephard 2000),
but in this case, while the technology was generic, firms tended to remain specialised
in accordance with the origin of the raw material in question. With the advent of
frozen and prepared foods, pioneered by Birds Eye,2 fish products became one option
within a portfolio of ‘main meal’ dishes, leading to the direct involvement of firms
from different food-chain backgrounds – Unilever, Tyson and ConAgra. Fish farming,
in its turn, has attracted global firms in animal feed, such as Ralston Purina, together
with upstream inputs and genetics firms, among whom Monsanto is very much in
evidence. Nutreco, the largest global fish-farm firm, is equally involved in pig, poultry
and animal feed production (Friends of the Earth 2002).
Global fish consumption patterns are as striking as trade flows, showing symmetrically inverse tendencies. In 1973 developed countries were responsible for 55 per
cent of global fish consumption, declining to 31 per cent by 1997. This increase in
developing country share has been largely due to China (11 per cent to 36 per cent in
the same period), with India and Southeast Asia doubling their share, whereas in
sub-Saharan Africa consumption stagnated and declined in the 1990s. Fish is a much
more decisive component of the protein diet in developing countries, representing an
average of 20 per cent in less developed countries, but rising to as much as 50 per cent
in some countries (Bangladesh), whereas in developed countries, also with sharp
variations, it represents an average of 13 per cent. Per capita consumption in the
developing world (excluding China), however, was calculated at 9.2 k per capita, as
against 21.7 k in the developed world, (Delgado et al. 2003). While developing countries, therefore, are more dependent on fish for their protein needs, there is a net flow
of fish from these countries for consumption in the developed world (Sundar 2000).
The depletion of capture fish resources in northern waters and the extraordinary
surge in fish capture and especially fish-farming in the south, almost exclusively,
(with the decisive exception of China), devoted to exports for northern consumers, in
addition to acute social and environmental issues, starkly poses the risks for global
food security/sovereignty.
Capture fishing: who is piloting: a food chain out of control?
Transatlantic trade in cod was already well established in the sixteenth century,
replacing the Icelandic routes. French boats, better provisioned with salt could each
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
Fish: a global value chain driven onto the rocks
143
carry back a 25,000 kg catch of processed and prepared cod, while the British, with
salt in short supply, had to dry their cod on land before setting back. The Newfoundland settlements which emerged were based on the cod economy, and this, with time,
would become an important motive in the events leading to the Boston Tea Party
(Kurlansky 1999). On the Pacific coast, already in the early nineteenth century, the
Hudson Bay Company promoted trade in salmon, which was exported to England
(Dawson 2003).
The icing of fish, a technology learned by the British from the Chinese, began to be
used as early as the 1780s to open up trade in fresh salmon from Scotland to London.
This technology, initially used for the marketing of landed fish, was rapidly applied to
preserving fish at sea, allowing for larger fleets, longer fishing times and deep sea
fishing. In their turn, these changes provoked adaptations in the ships and the gear
(Shephard 2000).
As early as the 1870s the US Congress, concerned with the decline in New England
fish, created the Commission of Fish and Fisheries. Before the end of the century,
regulation controlling fishing in its own waters began to be put into place, including
net restrictions, closed seasons and spawning escapement requirements. Technologies developed during the World War II and, applied to trawler fleets, transformed the
nature of international fishing in the 1950s and 1960s. These included the application
of radar and sonar to locate and follow migratory stocks. The use of diesel engines
permitted cheap fuel, allowing fleets to stay out longer and fish deeper (Safina 2003).
The factory trawlers made their appearance in the early 1950s as an adaptation
from whale fishing and by the 1970s they dominated the world’s fishing, with the
Soviet Union sporting 400 such trawlers, Japan, 125, Spain 75 and France and
England 40 each (Rogers 2003). These trawlers could scoop up 400 tons of fish in a
single haul and could stay at sea for months and process the fish into frozen filleted
slabs. This mass, primary processing production system promoted the development
of the quick frozen convenience fish food sector, which in its turn was transformed by
the consolidation of large-scale retail. The supermarket format itself owed much to
the revolutionary implications of the cold food chain. Such a development was already
predicted in a Birds Eye advert of 1930, which argued that frozen foods would change
the way people shopped and that there would be a new kind of store in the future: ‘not
a grocery store or a meat market or a fish market or a delicatessen, but all four rolled
into one. It is a food store in the broadest sense of the word’ (Shephard 2000). Today,
Birds Eye is one of Unilever’s three leading frozen fish brands.
Six per cent annual growth rates of capture during the first two decades after World
War II were the result of this revolution in fishing practices, leading to the serious
depletion of world fish stocks on the high seas. The factory trawler fleets also threatened stocks in coastal waters and with them, domestic supplies and the livelihoods of
artisan fishing communities, which were the key units of many national fishing
economies. In particular they threatened the traditional combination of fishing and
on-land primary fish processing which together had guaranteed the viability of these
fishing communities (Alcock 2002).
Territorial disputes (of which perhaps the most famous were the British-Iceland
cod wars) became common, not now within the three nautical mile range, which was
seen to be part of national sovereignty, but over rights to fishing on a nation’s
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
144
Wilkinson
continental shelf and to migratory fish whose origins were in the bays and rivers of a
particular country. A series of Law of the Sea conferences attempted to impose limits
on catches and these were followed by the enactment of national 200-mile exclusive
economic zones (EEZs) which were to change the rules of the game, but not necessarily to slow down the rate of fish stock depletion. Although it had been preceded by
a similar but unilateral action by Iceland, the US Magnuson Law of 1976 instituting
the EEZ, was the landmark for worldwide national legislation. While rich in fish,
when compared to Japan, the Nordic countries and the then Soviet bloc, the US was
essentially a meat (initially red and then increasing white) consuming country and it
had no fleet to compete with the factory trawlers (Buck 1995).
The Magnuson legislation led to replacing the open sea regime with national and
regional fishing management schemes, but it did not change the fishing model.
Rather it allowed the US to become a competitor and by 1999 it also had 50 factory
trawlers. Each trawler cost now anything from US$40–65 million dollars and the
largest could net and process 450 metric tons of fish a day, everyday. Four or five firms
are responsible for 20–30 per cent of the world fish catch, with the largest of them, the
Norwegian, American Seafoods/KRG1, controlling 10 per cent of the global white fish
market and 40 per cent of the pollock quota in the Baring Straits (Buck 1995). With
the decline in cod, pollock became a key new product, which was transformed into
surimi for the Japanese market. As artificial crab it also became an important input for
the burgeoning seafood restaurant chains in the US. By 1996, the top eight seafood
chains in the US had a turnover in excess of US$3 billion ( Jakle and Sculle 1999).
In addition to accelerating the depletion of the principal fish stock, the trawlers
were responsible for enormous waste in the form of bycatch, calculated in 1994 in the
case of New England as 145 per cent of the total ground fish landings (Greenpeace News
2003). It is also thought that they may be causing irrevocable damage to the ocean’s
ecosystems as they drag up the biomass from the seabed. The combined pressures of
depletion and threat to long-term sustainability led to restrictive legislation on catch
and gear in Northern waters, involving bans and quotas. One important consequence
was a shift to the waters of the developing world. Unlike the US, these countries may
have acquired EEZ rights, but their ships were unable to take advantage of them and
financing new fleets was for most of these countries prohibitive. Either rights to fish
were rented out or foreign fleets were allowed to fish under national flags. For the EU,
this was an ideal alternative to selling off their fleet capacity, and Spanish trawlers took
over the Argentine/Uruguay hake grounds with the incentive to these countries of
tariff exemptions for the import of the catch to Europe (Thorpe et al. 2003).
In many zones, a total allowable catch was imposed, but without individual quotas
this led to a race for fish based on ever larger boats and shorter fishing seasons,
favouring the international fleets and further threatening the ice chilling fleets and
local fish processors. By the 1990s the management systems in most developing
countries were in disarray, which, particularly in a climate of liberalisation policies,
pointed the way to privatising strategies. The introduction of often transferable individual fishing quotas might in principle have mitigated the pressures of the ‘race-tofish’ syndrome. By then, however, the fleets were dominated by large firms allied to
foreign capital and most countries exhibited a high degree of regulatory capture, with
powerful interest groups influencing fishing policy (Thorpe et al. 2003). In the Nordic
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
Fish: a global value chain driven onto the rocks
145
countries, particularly Iceland, and the US, some success seems to have been
achieved in defending local fishing systems through the design of the quota system
(Sylvia and Munroe, 1993, but this is less feasible where management systems are
weaker.
With 70 per cent of capture stocks either fully fished or over-fished the pressure for
change increased along two lines – from quotas to sustainable management systems,
and from the capture fishing to aquaculture. The two options could be considered as
complementary, although aquaculture was increasingly represented as a substitute
for capture fishing (The Economist 2003). Yet others saw in aquaculture a radicalisation of the industrialisation of fishing, with even more pronounced social and environmental consequences (Greenpeace 1997).
On the international regulatory front, the Oceans chapter of the Rio Summit’s
Agenda 21 was followed by the FAO Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries, the
UN Agreement on Straddling Stocks and Highly Migratory Fish Stocks, and the
United Nation Convention on the Law of the Sea. Within the fishing industry by far
the most significant initiative was the establishment of the Marine Stewardship
Council (MSC), which emerged from a joint initiative between Unilever and the
World Wide Fund for Nature (WWF). The MSC, which is now independent and
financed by charitable trusts, has adopted three basic principles as the criteria for its
certification:
A fishery must be conducted in a manner that does not lead to over-fishing or depletion of
the exploited populations and, for those populations that are depleted, the fisheries must be
conducted in a manner that demonstrably leads to their recovery. Fishing operations should
allow for the maintenance of the structure, productivity, function and diversity of the
ecosystem (including habitat and associated dependent and ecologically related species) on
which the fishery depend. The fishery is subject to an effective management system that
respects local, national and international laws and standards and incorporates institutional
and operational frameworks that require use of the resource to be responsible and sustainable. (Heap 2000, p. 135)
Unilever is the world leader in final frozen food products and its three brands, Findus,
Birds Eye and Igloo, account for some 25 per cent of the frozen fish market in Europe
and the US (www.unilever.com). While aquaculture is beginning to move into these
species, it offers no short-term perspective for a firm such as Unilever, which has
therefore become a proponent of sustainable capture fishing, planning to source all its
fish from such certified systems by 2005. To date, it claims to obtain 25 per cent of its
fish from sustainable certified sources and MSC certificates have now been attributed
to the salmon fish from Alaska, hoki from New Zealand and rock lobster from
Australia (Marine Stewardship Council n.d.).
Another major development has been the adoption of flagged vessel schemes by
the Asda/Walmart and Tesco supermarkets in Britain. While the contracts are triangulated through suppliers or processors, the supermarkets commit themselves to
taking the whole catch. The principal motivation in this case seems to be improvements in supply chain management, particularly to ensure fresh supplies seven days
a week. The quality of the supplied fish is also guaranteed through the stipulation of
fishing practices for fresh fish – maximum times at sea and storage and icing
practices. In the House of Lords inquiry the question was raised whether quality in
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
146
Wilkinson
this sense might not in fact increase discards. Whether or not this is the case, it is the
issue of consumer-oriented quality rather than sustainability which seems to be to the
fore. Along a similar consumer-driven logic ‘locally caught’ supplies are being promoted in certain regions (House of Lords 1999).
As with other food products, scares are leading to the implementation of traceability systems and the EU has financed a programme, Tracefish, for the elaboration of
voluntary industry standards on quality and traceability, which was projected to be
implemented as from 2004 (Seafish Industry Authority n.d.). Initiatives are already in
place which involve the use of electronic weighing scales, enabling catches to be
bar-coded for weight, time and place of capture, together with water temperature
(MacDubhghaill 2003). As in the flagship examples, however, it is not clear that the
quality and the traceability in question take on board the issues of sustainability which
are the basis of the MSC certification schemes.
Fish-farming: retail and catering in alliance with the intensive
(soy) protein complex?
Perceptions of the tragedy of ocean fish-stock depletion have to a great extent been
mitigated by the promotion of a sentiment of inevitability, viewing capture fishing as
the counterpart to hunting and extractivism in agriculture, both of which would now
be replaced by increasingly convergent intensive production practices. The notion of
the ‘blue revolution’ (The Economist 2003) captures this vision perfectly, presenting
fish-farming as an evolution to more efficient practices, the more so as these systems
extend beyond salmon, trout and shrimps to white fish species. In addition, a conjunction of powerful economic and political interests has reinforced and accelerated
this shift. As we saw earlier, the single most important food export from developing
countries is now fish, increasingly in the form of fish-farming, and aquaculture has
received decisive support from international financing, most notably the World Bank
and the Asian Development Bank. In addition, this sector has been seen to provide
opportunities for less developed countries such as Bangladesh and has led to the
emergence of developing country transnationals, of which the Thai CP Group is the
most notable (Bursch and Gross 2005). More generally, fish farming provides decisive
new markets for the global food industry players in the genetics, inputs and feeds
sectors – Nutreco, Monsanto and Ralston Purina. Lastly, and perhaps most importantly, large-scale retail and catering have seized on salmon and shrimps as the ideal
fresh fish alternatives and have committed themselves heavily to the promotion of
these markets, based largely on fish farming both in the North and the South.
Shrimps and salmon have been the most spectacular examples of the growing
importance of fish farming which is now almost exclusively responsible for the
increase in world trade of these products. Shrimps provide a paradigm case for
critiques of North-South trade. With the shift to aquaculture, a traditional extensive,
subsistence, mixed cropping regime of shrimps and rice in the South was replaced by
intensive export monoculture for luxury consumption in the North. In the US, the
second largest importer after Japan, 70 per cent of shrimps are consumed outside the
home, particularly in the seafood restaurant chains dominated by the Red Lobster
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
Fish: a global value chain driven onto the rocks
147
group, which alone consumes 5 per cent of world exports ( Jakle and Sculle 1999).
According to the President of ICEC Seafood Corporation:
Red Lobster’s advertising of shrimp has stimulated all consumption and in part made
possible the 250 per cent increase in US shrimp consumption since the advent of aquaculture. (Greenpeace 1997)
Asian developing countries have provided the major supply base, followed by Central
America and more recently Brazil. With the development of aquaculture, labour is
shifted off the land to the processing factories in much the same way as other
outsourced labour-intensive stages of global production chains. In 1980, eight Asian
countries were responsible for 76,000 metric tons, a figure which had risen to
448,000 by 1997. Ecuador, the leading Central American producer, increased its
production from 9,000 to 130,000 metric tons in the same period (Goss et al. 2000).
This explosive growth has been accompanied by sharp price oscillations, farreaching environmental impacts (such as the elimination of mangroves, water pollution, diminishing biodiversity), conflicts over land use and threats to local
communities, together with devastating outbreaks of disease. A combination of
untried technology and the prospect of huge short-term gains has led to the emergence of a ‘boom and bust’ profile for the industry. Taiwan, initially the leading
shrimp-farming exporter, suffered a crippling disease outbreak in the late 1980s from
which it only began to recover in 2000. In compensation, it exported its technological
know-how to Thailand, which quickly transformed itself into Asia’s leading exporter,
giving rise to the first developing country transnational in the sector, the Charoen
Pokphand (CP) Group. Strong support from the World Bank and the Asian Development Bank, together with the growth of the CP Group made shrimp production an
irresistible option for most Asian countries – Indonesia, Bangladesh, India and
Vietnam. Disease, the search for ever cheaper labour costs and the Asian financial
crisis, accentuated this nomadic tendency, which extended beyond Asia to Central and
South America and, in the most recent period, also to Africa (Greenpeace 1997).
On the other hand, as with the case of fruit and vegetables, the transnationalisation
of retail has also stimulated domestic demand, with battered fried shrimps, together
with other fish specialities, now experiencing 10–20 per cent annual growth rates in
Thai and Singapore supermarkets. A more complex globalisation is replacing the
North-South paradigm, with the frontiers between export and domestic markets
becoming more fluid (UNCTAD 1997).
While global players have stimulated the development of shrimp farming exports
from developing countries, protectionist measures in the forms of tariff escalation,
which has been as high as 30 per cent for some products, and more rigid quality
standards (implementation of hazard and critical control points systems) imposed
formidable barriers to access, particularly to the US and EU markets. Tariff escalation
has tended to decline, however, and less developed countries have benefited from
tariff exemption. Countries such as Bangladesh have shown the viability and benefits
of adjusting to more stringent quality controls, although these can be activated for
purely protectionist motives, as would seem to be the case in the current measures
being taken against Brazil, which has emerged as the latest developing country
exporting shrimps to the US market (Cato and Subasinge 2003; Josupeit et al. 2003).
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
148
Wilkinson
New quality standards may lead to greater control over contaminants (such as
antibiotics) detectable in the final product, but they do not necessarily address the
broader issues of environmental and social sustainability. There are some indications,
however, that the more opportunistic features of the industry are ceding ground
under the joint impact of local struggles (particularly in the case of India); the ‘busts’
which have followed the ‘booms’ and the Asian financial crisis, which led to the crisis
of big players such as the Thailand CP Group. As a result, there is now a greater
presence of small shrimp-farming operations, a greater concern with hatchery operations to ensure shrimp stocks and a shift to lower density production systems (Cyriac
2003). This would not seem to be the case, however, with new entrants such as Brazil,
whose drive to become a world leader in shrimp exports is based on very high per
hectare production, which may reproduce the disease and pollution syndrome of
earlier Asian shrimp farming, although Brazil is now in a position to benefit from the
collective learning of this global industry, together with the new technologies and
know-how now available (Rocha 2003).
If catering in Japan and the US has been primarily responsible for the growth of
the shrimp economy, supermarkets have played a decisive role in the dramatic popularisation of salmon consumption which, from having been a high priced luxury in
the 1970s, is now an everyday fresh fish option and a staple of the booming, readymade sandwich sector. Some 90 per cent of salmon supplied to British supermarkets
now comes from salmon farms (Edwards 2002). While Chile is fast on its way to
becoming the leading exporter of salmon, the majority of farmed salmon still comes
from the north – Norway and Scotland. Chile’s exponential expansion of salmon
production in the 1990s, however, (involving a 20-fold increase) has led to rapidly
falling prices and bankruptcy for many Norwegian producers (Milliken 2003). More
recently, salmon farming has become a major focus of health concern, as research has
pointed to high levels of contamination, leading the EU to require labelling to distinguish between farmed and wild salmon (Environmental Defense 2004). Supermarkets have resisted this move, both calling in question their consumer sovereignty
orientation and suggesting that they have increasingly become stakeholders in the
move to fish-farming (Blythman 2002)
If salmon farming were under attack solely for environmental factors we might
anticipate a decisive shift to the South, especially as Chile plans to double its production over the next 10 years. It should be said, however, that environmental opposition
is also gaining ground in Chile as salmon farming moves further south into regions
of the country valued particularly for their tourism (Ecooceanos 2001). In Scotland the
environmental critique has been particularly forceful, focusing on pollution levels (a
sewage equivalent of 9.4 million people), the threat to shellfish sites, algal blooms and
the escapes of farm fish into the wild. It has also been calculated that the economic
value of salmon angling (£235 million), which is particularly threatened by escapes
and pollution, is on a par with salmon farming. Its beneficiaries, however, are more
diffuse (tackle, clothing, hotels, travel), and have less clout than the highly concentrated salmon farming sector where two firms – Norsk Hydro (Norway) and Nutreco
(via Marine Harvest) – control two-thirds of the 340 farms in Scotland. Globally, the
top seven companies control 40 per cent of world farmed salmon production (Friends
of the Earth 1999).
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
Fish: a global value chain driven onto the rocks
149
The challenge to salmon farming goes beyond environmental issues and reaches
the central vulnerability of all fish farming – dependence on concentrated fishmeal
and oil pellets made from capture-fish pellagic species, which are both highly contaminated and rapidly becoming depleted, as ‘fishing down the food web’ increases
with the exhaustion of large white-fish stocks. High levels of contamination in
farmed salmon have been officially recognised by the European Commission and
British government advisors have declared salmon to be the most contaminated
food sold by British supermarkets. Similarly US research on Scottish farmed
salmon has concluded that it is a serious cancer health risk, based on the levels
of dioxins and PCBs that have been detected (Environmental Defense 2004).
Although the British Food Standards Agency (n.d.) maintains that the health
benefits of fish consumption outweigh any risks, the European Union has
determined that farmed fish must be labelled (European Inland Fisheries Advisory
Commission 2001). This measure has been resisted by supermarkets, calling in
question their self-proclaimed responsiveness to consumer interests and suggesting
that they have may be becoming locked-in to certain supply chain solutions
(Blythman 2002).
Threatened by competition from Chile, Scottish fish farming is now moving into
the production of cod and haddock with the direct support of supermarkets such as
Marks and Spencer (British Marine Finfish Association n.d.). From being a highly
specialised activity, therefore, fish-farming is increasingly being adopted as a generalised solution to the dwindling supplies of large white fish species from capturefishing, attracted also by the high prices which this decline provokes. It is estimated
that by 2006, most large fillets of cod consumed in Britain (total consumption
170,000 tons) will be from fish farming. Cod, it should be added, consume twice the
feed of salmon with an equivalent expected increase in pollution (Owen 2003). Sea
cage farming of carnivorous finfish has now become a global business from Norway
to New Zealand, from the Mediterranean to Mexico and from the Americas to Australia, and includes sea bass, bream, barramundi, halibut, tuna and other more exotic
species. In spite of the setbacks provoked by disease and environmental regulation
and the uncertainties of the market, the move to farm the principal white fish species
is being promoted by leading multinationals Monsanto, Nutreco, Stolt, Cermaq and
Ralston Purina (Staniford 2003).
In a devastating indictment of this tendency, Staniford points to five fundamental
flaws in sea cage fishing: untreated waste, mass escapes, diseases and parasites, toxic
chemicals and fish feed. He argues that in theory new practices and technologies may
mitigate the first four flaws, although only inland, closed containment systems such
as those used by Future SEA Farms and Fish Protech in Australia offer guaranteed
protection, so much so that Fish Protech has received authorisation to locate in
drinking-water collection areas. The fifth flaw, however, fish meal and oil, has no
‘acceptable’ solution. By 2010 it is estimated that at current rates of growth, 56 per
cent of fish meal and 98 per cent of fish oil will be consumed in fish farming. Rather
than being an alternative to capture fishing, the oceans are being drained of their oily,
pellagic species to service the expansion of fish farming. Already many species are
disappearing and ocean biomass collection is developing to compensate for the
depletion of fishmeal stocks (Staniford 2003).
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
150
Wilkinson
Within the trajectory of the fish-farming alternative, many solution are being
explored to deal with the first four flaws identified by Staniford, involving off-shore
farming in deep water to deal with pollution and disease, with a consequent reduction
in chemicals, together with genetic control of reproduction to deal with escapes (an
adaptation of ‘Terminator’ technology). Until these options are operational or financially attractive, however, the dominant tendency will be to move from over-polluted
areas into pristine waters, imitating the frontier mine-farming of yesteryear, in spite
of increasing opposition from environmentalists, local communities and tourist interests. As for the fifth flaw, the solution currently being explored is soybean pellets,
closing the loop with white meat production and unifying the production matrix of
the animal protein complex. Transforming carnivorous fish into vegetarians is the
obverse of feeding animal meats to cows, and although it may be less of a health risk,
its effect on taste has proved to date an important obstacle. But for how long? The
evolution of chicken taste is a ready reminder of consumer adaptability. Staniford’s
optimal solution would be the elimination of finfish carnivorous sea farming and the
promotion of inland shellfish farming. Barring that, he argues, the only solution is
closed containment systems or ‘close-down’.
Conclusion
Global value chain analysis, with its distinction between supply- and demandoriented production systems, and parallel work on the globalisation of food retailing,
have opened up important insights into the current dynamics of agrofood system
globalisation. The one has highlighted the way in which demand-driven considerations have redesigned food chains almost from scratch, while the second approach
has also showed the need to go beyond a simple North-South divide as large-scale
retail breaks down the frontiers between export and domestic markets even in developing countries. The paradigm for analysing these tendencies has been the fruit and
vegetables sector, where backward linkages have been recreated and redesigned in
accordance with the evolution of logistics and quality-demand criteria. The fish food
chain can be usefully analysed using this perspective. The shift of supermarkets
towards direct contracting with trawler ships for capture fishing and their leading
role in the creation of a popular salmon, fresh fish market are clear confirmation of
the way retail is currently piloting changes in the global organisation of agrofood
systems.
At the same time, the fish sector demonstrates a much more complex interplay of
interests even at the demand end of the chain, where catering has played a more
autonomous role, particularly in the promotion of shrimp and similar seafood products. More decisively, the fish sector displays enormous inertial characteristics based on
the historical accumulation and consolidation of interests around different segments
of the global food chain, which have erupted in conflicts and even wars and have only
been partially contained by increasing regulation. Faced with this out-of-control juggernaut where advanced technologies are harnessed to short-term but longconsolidated interests, the supermarket’s involvement in capture fishing has been
limited to the fine-tuning of logistics and the quality (freshness) of supplies. The most
farsighted initiatives to date have come from the fish-processing sector, dependent on
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
Fish: a global value chain driven onto the rocks
151
globally sourced white fish supplies, in the form of the Management Stewardship
Council, jointly promoted by Unilever and the WWF.
On the other hand, the retail sector has played a decisive role in the promotion of
the fresh salmon market based on fish farming. Unlike the fruit and vegetable sector,
which is more readily subject to surveillance and consumer-friendly practices, fish
farming is dominated by powerful global upstream players and by a complex, still
untried technological base with enormous social and environmental externalities. The
evidence to date would suggest that the retail sector itself has now become locked-in
to a production system, initially seen as the guarantor of idealised consumer demand
for quality (organoleptic and nutritional) and convenience but now transformed into
an object of suspicion and confusion. The supermarkets’ refusal to label salmon
‘fish-farmed’ perhaps spells the end of its innocent courtship of the consumer, based
on demand satisfaction.
As retail assumes a more and more direct role in the organisation of the value
chain, it also loses the flexibility to respond in an uncommitted way to fluctuations in
consumer perception. At the same time, its commitment to final product quality falls
far short of consumer demand, once this takes on board the more conflict-ridden
issues of sustainability. A satisfactory solution to the dilemmas of the global fish chain
cannot be left to the supermarket’s putative capacity to internalise consumer demand,
but requires the direct involvement of the consumer–citizen in a complex mix of
direct action, new consumer practices, negotiated initiatives with industry and pressure for public, national and global, regulation.
Acknowledgement
My thanks go to Zina Angelica Caceres Benavides for her valuable help as research assistant.
Notes
1
2
A very interesting critique of the GCC approach, which also focuses on the limitations of its
over-simplified typology is provided by Sverrison (2004). In addition to incorporating
Gibbon’s (2001) ‘trader driven global commodity chain’, it is argued that the proposed
typology is inadequate both for analysing many high technology sectors and for capturing
the scope for local entrepreneurship.
Originally developed by Mr Birdseye and his wife, Eleanor, in their ambitiously named
General Seafoods Company, which was bought by Postum, a large food processing company,
changing its name first to General Foods Corporation and then to Birds Eye (Shephard
2000).
References
Alcock, F. (2002) Scale conflicts and sectoral crisis: the fisheries development dilemma. Pp.
441–449 in F. Biermann, R. Brohm and K. Dingwerth eds, Proceedings of the 2001 Berlin
conference on the human dimension of global environmental change (Potsdam: Institute for
Climate Impact Research)
Blythman, J. (2002) Supermarkets mislead public over seafood. Sunday Herald 17 March.
Available online at www.sundayherald.com/14198
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
152
Wilkinson
British Marine Finfish Association Ltd (n.d.) available online at http://www.bmfa.uk Accessed
November 2003
Buck, E.H. (1995) Individual transferable quotas in fishery management. Congressional
Research Service Report for Congress (Washington DC: National Library for the Environment)
Callon, M., C. Méadel and V. Rabóharisoa (2002) The economy of qualities. Economy and Society
31 (2) pp. 194–217
Cato, J.C. and S. Subasinge (2003) Food safety in food security and food trade. Focus 10
(Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute)
Cochoy, F. (2002) Une sociologie du packaging (Paris: Presses universitaires de France)
Cyriac, K.J. (2003) The marine products export development authority, India (Rio de Janeiro: FAO)
Dawson, R. (2003) Vertical integration in commercial fisheries. Unpublished Ph.D. thesis
(Blacksburg, VC: Virginia Tech)
Delgado, C., N. Wada, M.W. Rosegrant, S. Meijer and M. Ahmed et al. (2003) Outlook for fish to
2020 (Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute)
Dolan, C., J. Humphrey and C. Harris-Pascal (1999) Horticulture commodity chains: the impact of
the UK market on the African fresh vegetable industry Working Paper 96 (Sussex: Institute of
Development Studies)
Economist (2003) The blue revolution. 7 August
Ecooceanos (n.d.) available online at http://www.ecooceanos.cl/categoria3.shtml Accessed
November 2003
Edwards, R. (2002) Farm salmon is now the most contaminated food on the shelf. Sunday
Herald 20 September Available online at http://www.sundayherald.com. Newsquest Ltd
Environmental Defense (2004) available online at http://www.torontobeach.ca/about/
aboutedc.htm Accessed October 2004
European Inland Fisheries Advisory Committee (2001) Report of the ad hoc EIFA/EC working
party on market perspectives for European freshwater aquaculture (Brussels: EIFA/AC)
Food Standards Agency (n.d.) available online at http://www.food.gov.uk Accessed November
2003
Friends of the Earth (1999) The one that got away (Scotland: Friends of the Earth)
Friends of the Earth (2002) The filthy five: salmon from Nutreco. The salmon industry in Chile’s
waters (Amsterdam: Friends of the Earth)
Gereffi, G. (1994) The organisation of buyer driven global commodity chains. Pp. 95–122 in G.
Gereffi and M. Korzeniewicz eds, Commodity chains and global capitalism (Westport, CT:
Praeger)
Giddens, A. (1991) The consequences of modernity (Cambridge: Polity Press)
Goss, J., D. Burch and R.E. Rickson (2000) Third World corporate transnationals: the case
of Charoen Pokphand, Thailand and the global shrimp industry. World Development 28 (3)
pp. 513–530
Greenpeace (1997) Shrimp: the devastating delicacy. A Greenpeace report. Available online at
http://www.greenpeace.org
Greenpeace News (2003) available online at http://www.greenpeace.org
Harvey, M. (2002) Markets, supermarkets and the macro-social shaping of demand. Pp. 187–
208 in A. McMeekin, K. Green, M. Tomlinson and V. Walsh eds, Innovation by demand
(Manchester: Manchester University Press)
Heap, S. (2000) The Marine Stewardship Council: a business–NGO partnership for sustainable
marine fisheries. Pp. 130–142 in S. Heap ed, NGOs engaging with business (INTRAC)
House of Lords (1999) Examination of witnesses. Available online at http://www.
publications.parliament.uk Accessed Nov 2003
Jakle, J.A. and K.A. Sculle (1999) Fast food (Baltimore, MD and London: John Hopkins University Press)
Josupeit, H., A. Lem and H. Lupin (2000) Aquaculture products: quality, safety, marketing and
trade. Pp. 43–48 in R.P. Subasinghe, B.P. Bueno, M.J. Phillips, C. Hough, S.E. McGladdery
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006
Fish: a global value chain driven onto the rocks
153
and R.J. Arthur eds, Aquaculture in the next millennium: Proceedings of the conference on
aquaculture in the third millennium Bangkok 20–25 February (Bangkok: NACA and Rome:
FAO)
Kaplinsky, R. (2000) Spreading the gains from globalisation: what can be learned from value chain
analysis? IDS working paper 110 (Sussex: IDS)
Kurlansky, M. (1999) Cod (London: Vintage)
MacDubhghaill, U. (2003) The outlook for the UK fishing industry. IntraFish.com Industry
Report available online at http://www.intrafish.com/intrafish-analysis/uk2000.48eng/
Marine Stewardship Council (n.d.) available online at http://www.msc.org Accessed 4 April 2006
Milliken, M. (2003) Salmon farms spawn fortunes and critics in Chile (Santiago: Reuters) available
online at http://www.terram.cl/index2/htm
Owen, J. (2003) Environmentalist fight plans to farm cod in Scotland. National Geographic News
28 October Available online at http://news.national geographic.com/news/2003/10/1028
Reardon, T. and J.A. Berdegué (2002) The rapid rise of supermarkets in Latin America.
Development Policy Review 20 (4) pp. 371–388
Reardon, T., P. Timmer, C. Barret and J.A. Berdegué (2003) The rise of supermarkets in Africa,
Asia and Latin America. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 85 (5) pp. 1140–1146
Rocha, I. de Paiva (2003) Advantages and constraints of the Brazilian fishery industry (Rio de
Janeiro: FAO)
Rodgers, R.A. (2003) Mesh flesh: fish farms and environment/equity issues (York: University of
York) Available online at http://www.earthisland.org/map/ltfrn_128.htm
Ruckes, E. (2003) World fish trade, demand forecasts and regulatory framework (Rome: FAO)
Safina, C. (2003) Fishing off the deep end – and back. Pp. 8–12 in Multinational Monitor 24 Blue
Ocean Institute
Seafish Industry Authority (n.d.) available online at www.seafish.org Accessed November 2003
Shephard, S. (2000) Pickled, potted and canned (London: Simon & Schuster)
Staniford, D. (2003) Closing the net on sea cage fish farming. Paper delivered to the Queensland Conservation Council and the Australian Marine Conservation Society, Queensland
Sundar, A. (2000) Marine resources. Marketing the Earth: The World Bank and Sustainable
Development (Washington and Halifax Initiative: Friends of the Earth) Available online at
http://www.halifaxinitiative.org
Sverrisson, A. (2004) Local and global commodity chains. Pp. 17–35 in C. Pietrobelli and Á.
Sverrisson eds, Linking local and global economies (London and New York: Routledge)
Sylvia, G. and H. Munroe (1999) Pacific Whiting Conservation Cooperative. Powerpoint
presentation available online at http://www.iser.uss.alaska.edu/projects/workshop/
presentation Accessed November 1993
Thorpe, A., A.A. Ibarra and C. Reid (2003) The new economic model and fisheries development
in Latin America. Unpublished paper. Marine environmental politics in the 21st century
(Berkeley, CA: University of Berkley)
UNCTAD (1997) Opportunities for vertical diversification in the food processing sector in developing
countries (Vienna: UNCTAD)
Unilever (n.d.) Annual reports (misc.) Available at http://www.unilever.com Accessed Nov 2003
Warde, A. and L. Martens (2000) Eating out – social differentiation, consumption and pleasure
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)
John Wilkinson
Graduate Centre on Development, Agriculture and Society (CPDA)
Rural Federal University
Rio de Janeiro
e-mail:
[email protected]
© 2006 The Author. Journal Compilation © 2006 European Society for Rural Sociology.
Sociologia Ruralis, Vol 46, Number 2, April 2006