Economy and Society Volume 29 Number 1 February 2000: 54–79
Shareholder value in an
adverse environment: the
German case
Ulrich Jürgens, Katrin Naumann and Joachim Rupp
Abstract
The German political economy has often been cited as a classical case of non-shareholder value orientation. Its productionist, long-term, consensus orientation has often
been contrasted with the ‘Anglo-Saxon approach’. The inuence of shareholders who
press for shareholder value and the importance of the equity market have traditionally been low. But there are signs of change. In this article we describe some of these
changes and try to assess the dynamics of this change process.
First we show that the limited role of the equity market for company nancing and
for private household savings still provides a very narrow base for a shareholder value
economy in Germany. The central pillars of the German system of corporate governance – the dominating role of banks, the system of co-determination and the companycentred management system – are not crumbling. Change in the direction of
shareholder value is therefore limited.
Keywords: shareholder value; corporate governance; Germany; co-determination;
nancial markets.
Introduction
Germany has often been cited as a classical case of non-shareholder value orientation whose productionist, long-term and consensus values have often been
contrasted with the ‘Anglo-Saxon approach’. The inuence of shareholders who
press for shareholder value and the importance of the equity market have traditionally been low.
Ulrich Jürgens, Katrin Naumann and Joachim Rupp, Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin für
Sozialforschung (WZB), Reichpietschufer 50, D-10785 Berlin. E-mail:
[email protected];
[email protected];
[email protected]
Copyright © 2000 Taylor & Francis Ltd 0308-5147
Ulrich Jürgens et al.: Shareholder value in an adverse environment
55
But there are signs of change. In this article we will describe some recent
changes and try to assess the dynamics of this change process. The forces
currently driving the German political economy towards a shareholder value
orientation include a whole range of factors:
state measures to deregulate nancial markets;
the nancial problems of the German welfare state especially with the pensions system;
the need to develop new management control systems for decentralized
company structures;
the wave of mergers and acquisitions;
pressure from managers of investment funds and pension funds, in particular from the USA; and
the debate about a new corporate charter for European companies and about
‘best practice corporate governance’.
Shareholder value has become a topic of media debate in Germany only since
around 1996. In this media debate about a new development, three different positions can be distinguished. The rst position is critical and negative: the shareholder value orientation is identied with intensied rationalization, an increase
in unemployment, a ‘colder climate’ of social relations in companies, and an
incipient ‘short-termism’ which threatens the fundamental strengths of the
German economy. The second position is positive appreciation: shareholder
value is represented as a pressure on company management to increase the competitiveness of their companies and to move faster into new areas of business.
The third position is reluctant acceptance of the inevitable: here shareholder
value is situated as a result of the developments of global nancial markets and
difficulties of nancing the public pension system.
If the media response and representation is divided and mixed, it is difficult
to gauge the broader public response inside Germany. Impressionistically, the
negative response to shareholder value seems to prevail. It should, however, be
emphasized that the topic of shareholder value does not yet gure prominently
in public perception and discussion because shareholder value has made limited
inroads into the German political economy and is not yet associated with major
changes in, for example, the pensions system.
In Germany, shareholder value is thus a recent, interesting and ambiguous
development in a generally hostile environment where the national political
economy has previously respected different principles. In the German case, the
overwhelming question is what does shareholder value portend? Will it initiate
a major and permanent change in operating principles or is it a fashionable
rhetoric which will quickly be superseded?
Our article explores these issues in a preliminary way at a point in time when
it is not possible to provide a denitive answer as to what shareholder value portends. The article is structured in a straightforward way. Section one provides
an essential empirical context by presenting evidence on the limited role of the
equity market in company nancing and on patterns of private household saving.
56
Economy and Society
The implication is that Germany provides a very narrow base for any shareholder
value economy. The second section turns to institutional issues and describes the
central pillars of the German system of corporate governance. In orthodox terms
these include the dominant role of banks, the system of co-determination and
the company-centred management system. Against this background, section
three takes up the issue of the nature and direction of change: are the pillars of
the German corporate governance system crumbling with the emergence of a
shareholder value economy? The fourth and nal section offers a summary and
interim conclusion.
The narrow base for a shareholder value economy in the
German system
Whatever a shareholder value economy is or might be, it has denite material
preconditions. First, the stock market can inuence management behaviour
directly on an economy-wide basis only where a large part of the corporate sector
is stock-market quoted. Second, the value orientation requires a stock market
and a corporate governance system where value-orientated investors are major
players. In the British and American cases, the dominance of the value-orientated
investor is guaranteed by the large-scale ow of household savings into professionally managed funds. As we will now argue, in the German case, none of these
conditions is met, although there are interesting recent changes in a system
where traditionally shareholders have played a minor role in the German corporate governance system.
The rst, most obvious peculiarity of the German stock market is that it is
relatively small in relation to the national economy. This point emerges very
clearly from international comparisons of stock-market capitalization against
national income. In Germany in 1997, the value of the stock market accounted
for no more than 31.4 per cent of gross domestic product. The comparable
percentages were signicantly higher in France and Japan at 40.6 and 58.1 per
cent respectively; and massively higher in the USA and UK where stock-market
capitalization accounts for 100.9 and 154.4 per cent of GDP (Deutsches
Aktieninstitut 1998: table 05-2).
The German stock market is relatively small. In 1997, only 700 German companies were public corporations with stock-market listings. In terms of market
capitalization a few large companies dominate the German stock exchange and
they account for a small subset of all quoted companies. From a total of 700 companies quoted, thirty-ve companies (or just 5 per cent of the total) accounted
for some 73 per cent of total market capitalization (Deutsches Aktieninstitut
1998: table 06-4). This dominant group includes more or less exactly the same
companies as the DAX 30 listing of the thirty largest German blue-chip companies.
If the Dax 30 is the German stock market in terms of market capitalization,
much of corporate Germany is of course not stock-market listed. This does mean
Ulrich Jürgens et al.: Shareholder value in an adverse environment
57
that there is considerable scope for extending the public, quoted form of organization. Signicantly, a new type of stock market for start-up companies has
recently opened in Germany. This Neue Markt (New Market) has grown rapidly
from small beginnings but, in terms of market capitalization, still plays a minor
role. We shall return to this later.
The next major point concerns the pattern of shareholding in Germany and
the implications for shareholder personality and motivations. In Britain and
America, the dominant shareholders are funds that consolidate household
savings. In Germany, share ownership is heavily concentrated with over half of
all shares owned by (non-nancial) companies, banks and insurance companies.
Whether the other companies are nancial or non-nancial, they are often part
of networks of cross-holdings where the main motive of shareholding is to
strengthen long-term relationships and business interdependencies and this
behaviour involves long-term commitment. In Germany, there has been only a
minor role for the value orientation which focuses on return on equity and the
value behaviour of trading stocks. This point is recognized in a recent OECD
report on the German system of corporate governance: ‘The importance of
cross-holdings of shares both among non-nancial enterprises and between
banks and non-nancial enterprises is a principal feature of German corporate
governance aimed at cementing long-term relationships between rms’ (OECD
1995: 97). These cross-holdings support a form of governance relying on longterm implicit contracts.
The pattern of share ownership is worth considering in some detail because
such consideration brings out the strength and stability of the existing system
as well as some interesting recent changes in behaviour and motivation.
As Table 1 shows, private households, investment funds and the ‘rest of the
world’ – the types of shareholder who supposedly pursue shareholder value –
account for no more than 40 per cent of share ownership in Germany in 1998.
This pattern of share ownership above all reects the fact that, directly and indirectly, share ownership is much less important to German citizens and German
households than in many other advanced capitalist countries.
Only 6 per cent of the German adult population owned shares in 1998. This
is a very low percentage compared to Sweden and the USA where 53 per cent
Table 1 Share ownership in Germany in 1998
Shares held by
Non-nancial companies
Private households
Insurance companies
Investment funds
Banks
Public households
Rest of the world
Source: Deutsches Aktieninstitut (1999: 5)
Percentage of all shares
30.5
15.0
13.7
12.9
10.3
1.9
15.6
58
Economy and Society
and 40 per cent of the adult population own shares; even in Japan, some 9 per
cent of adults own shares (Sanghera 1999: 9). Understandably, therefore, shares
are not the largest element in the portfolio of nancial assets held by private
German households. In 1998, shares and investment fund certicates made up
almost 19 per cent of this household portfolio whereas short-term savings
deposits accounted for 28 per cent and insurance policies for 19 per cent
(Deutsche Bundesbank 1999a: 50–1). Thus, private households have a reasonably stable but minority role on the share registers of German companies. Private
households owned 15 per cent of all shares in 1998. This gure has remained
quite stable over the years and has recently declined slightly. The importance of
shares in the household nancial assets portfolio, however, has been increasing
from 5.5 per cent in 1990 to 8.7 per cent in 1998 (Deutsche Bundesbank 1999a:
50–1).
In Germany, industrial companies remain the largest owners of public
company shares. As Table 1 showed, in 1998 their 30 per cent share is twice as
large as that of any other category of owner. Insurance companies also play an
important role in Germany. In 1998, they held almost 14 per cent of the total
shares with the two companies Allianz and Münchner Rückversicherung controlling the greatest market value (Boehmer 1998: 41).
There are however interesting changes in behaviour as the relative share of
industrial companies is declining at the same time as some nancial companies
are increasing their equity holdings. The relative share of industrial companies
may be large but it is also declining rapidly. The ownership of shares by other
non-nancial companies in Germany has declined from 41.6 per cent in 1990 to
30.5 per cent in 1998 (Deutsche Bundesbank 1999a: 105).1 As industrial companies are liquidating their holdings, German insurance companies are buying
more ordinary shares. In the past, insurance companies managed their asset portfolio very much as banks did and favoured diversied portfolios. Very recently
they have changed their policy however and are increasingly investing in equities.
If this change could be critical in shifting the balance towards a shareholder
value orientation, the second important change is the rise of investment funds.
Between 1990 and 1998, these investment funds rapidly increased their share from
a small base: their share increased from 4 per cent in 1990 to nearly 13 per cent in
1998 (Deutsche Bundesbank 1999a: 105). New kinds of institutional investors,
such as investment and private pension funds, play an increasingly important role
in Germany’s political economy. Foreign-controlled pension funds, in particular
USA controlled, are also becoming more important and dominate the foreign
holdings which now account for 15 per cent of all German shares.
The effects of these changes are magnied because the new kinds of institutional investor, like other nancial institutions, concentrate their inuence on
just a very small group of companies. In 1997, institutional investors for
instance owned 48 per cent of Daimler-Benz, 51 per cent of MAN, 85 per cent
of Preussag, 65 per cent of Deutsche Babcock, 85 per cent of Linde, 71 per cent
of Lufthansa, and 50 per cent of Hoechst (Deutsches Aktieninstitut 1998: table
08.5–1, 1997).
In summary, on the argument so far, shareholder value in Germany still has a
Ulrich Jürgens et al.: Shareholder value in an adverse environment
59
narrow economic base because it is focused on a very small group of agship companies. The structure of share ownership still supports non-value orientations,
although the balance is shifting towards private and institutional shareowners
whose primary interest is the increase of shareholder value. To understand what
all this means we must now turn to analysis of the institutional structure.
The German system of corporate governance
If there are changes in the personality and motivations of shareholders, these
changes will act through the institutional structures of corporate governance. In
this section, we aim to describe these structures and, more importantly, explain
how they work through reviewing research on the implications of these structures for business conduct and performance. This is not an excursus or distraction as our subsequent arguments on shareholder value rest on the basis of this
analysis. The traditional German system of corporate governance rests on three
pillars: rst, the dominating role of the banks in company nancing and supervisory boards; second, the system of industrial co-determination; and, third, the
productionist, company-centred management system. In this section, they are
described in turn, beginning with the dominant role of banks.
The banks directly held 10.3 per cent of all German shares in 1998, much the
same as in 1990 (Deutsche Bundesbank 1999a: 105). Deutsche Bank and
Dresdner Bank are the two banks controlling the greatest market value (Boehmer
1998: 40). While the ownership stake of the banks is substantial, their dominating role is based on a system of proxy voting (Depotstimmrecht) under which they
cast votes for other shareholders. Under this system, private shareholders
authorize the banks that hold their shares in custody to represent their interests
at the annual general meetings of the companies. Baums and Fraune investigated
the bankers’ importance in twenty-four out of the top 100 listed rms in Germany
in 1992. Banks had 13 per cent of the voting rights by virtue of their own shareholdings; 10 per cent of voting rights by virtue of their own subsidiary investment funds; and no less than 61 per cent of voting rights by virtue of proxy votes
(Baums and Fraune 1995: 103).2 They controlled 84 per cent of voting rights on
the average in the twenty-four companies studied, and the percentage was even
higher in the case of some household name companies. Banks controlled 95 per
cent or more of voting rights in Siemens, Hoechst or Mannesmann and more than
90 per cent in the case of BASF and Bayer. An interesting exception was Volkswagen which, for historical reasons, is to a large extent state owned so that banks
controlled only 44 per cent of the voting rights (Baums and Fraune 1995: 103).
The status of banks as dominant shareholder (mainly by proxy) explains the
fact that bank representatives can be found on most companies’ supervisory
boards. This way, banks and insurance companies – both in close cross-holding
relationships– have become the spiders in a dense network of cross-holdings and
mutual supervisory board representation. The resulting network of crossholdings is shown in Figure 1 which describes the situation at the beginning of
the 1990s.
60
Economy and Society
This gure has often been reproduced and brings out the dominant roles of
banks and insurance companies by showing part of the cross-shareholdings of
sixteen of the DAX 30 companies. The direct cross-shareholdings are immediately noticeable; as, for example, in the case of the insurance companies Münchner Rückversicherung, which owns 26 per cent of the shares of Allianz, and
Allianz, which owns 25 per cent of the shares of Münchner Rückversicherung.
The banks and insurance companies also have large indirect shareholdings
through their independent holding companies. These Verwaltungsgesellschaften
often bring together several banks and companies and are marked in the gure
by an oval circle around the name. Indirect shareholdings play an especially
important role in Germany: via holding companies, a company such as the
energy conglomerate VIAG even has indirect shareholdings in itself.
A system of cross-holdings leads to a system of interlocking directorates as a
company with a signicant ownership stake in another company usually has a
representative on the supervisory board of that company. The extremely close
relationships and interdependencies between board members of different companies is problematic:
The members of the supervisory board have to control company management
and to prevent the misuse of power. At the same time, they are part of an
encompassing network which functions as a means of social integration and
cohesion among the business elites and to which they owe the position they
have.
(Windolf and Beyer 1995: 25, our translation)
The position of banks is further strengthened by their role in company
nancing. As in the corporate sectors of other advanced capitalist countries,
retained earnings and internal funds are the most important source of nancing for German companies which typically draw half to two-thirds of their
funding requirements from this source. But, as Table 2 shows, banks are by far
the most important external nancing source; short- and long-term banking
credits typically account for up to 25 per cent of the corporate funding requirement. Financing via new issues on the equity market has traditionally played a
minor role, although the share of funding supplied by issues has been volatile
in the 1990s. For 1998 the data may indicate a paradigm shift with regard to
nancing via new issues, but it is still too early to tell whether this is really the
case.
There is ongoing debate about the merits and demerits of the prominent role
of banks in the German corporate governance system. The potential benets
were emphasized in a recent OECD report:
Through their continued presence at shareholders’ meetings, banks provide
an independent outside monitor of corporate decision-making. Outside monitoring is widely regarded as one of the building blocks of an efficient system
of corporate governance because such monitoring serves to alleviate the
so-called ‘free-rider problem’ which arises whenever many small sharehold-
Source: Adams (1999: 107)
Figure 1 The German network of cross-holdings
Economy and Society
62
Table 2 External and internal nancing of German companies from 1991 to 1998 (in
percentages)
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
Long-term
bank credits
Short-term
bank credits
Shares
Other
external
Total
external
Total
internal
17.2
21.7
20.6
6.7
13.2
13.7
13.5
16.7
12.7
4.1
–2.6
3.3
12.8
4.7
3.5
8.0
1.7
2.2
2.4
4.4
7.3
6.0
1.9
11.9
14.3
17.0
20.4
23.1
1.9
9.3
9.8
10.0
45.9
45.0
40.8
37.5
35.2
33.7
28.7
46.6
54.1
55.0
59.2
62.5
64.8
66.3
71.3
53.4
Source: Deutsche Bundesbank (1999b: 25)
so-called ‘free-rider problem’ which arises whenever many small shareholders have to form a common standpoint vis-a-vis top management.
(OECD 1995: 96)
In a recent essay, Wenger and Kaserer oppose this view:
In reality, large German banks are sheltered from outside pressures by a dense
network of cross-holdings, proxy votes, and underdeveloped disclosure obligations. Therefore, bank managers are not forced to pursue a value-maximising investment and monitoring policy.
(Wenger and Kaserer 1998: 531)
In summary, banks play a critical role in the system of corporate governance
for two reasons: rst, because of their direct ownership of shares and the system
of proxy votes; and, second, because industrial companies still nance themselves mostly via long- and short-term bank credits. They are not however the
only inuence on conduct and performance.
The system of co-determination makes the German system of corporate
governance unique. The system exists under German corporate law that creates
a dual board structure where the managing board and the supervisory board are
separate entities. Various laws determine the proportion of labour and capital
representatives on the supervisory board and dene the respective rights and
duties of the managing board, the supervisory board and the shareholders’
meeting (Markovits 1982; Streeck 1995; Leminsky 1998).3 More broadly, the codetermination system means that elected worker representatives have rights of
information, consultation and rights of veto on certain issues above and beyond
those which exist in a country like Britain where the one board of directors exists
to represent the interests of shareholders. These rights of workers/employees
are legally institutionalized on several levels:
At the level of individual plants, in companies with ve or more employees,
the employees have the right to elect a works council.
In companies with more than 500 employees (whatever the legal form),
Ulrich Jürgens et al.: Shareholder value in an adverse environment
63
representation of workers on the supervisory boards is mandated by the plant
constitution law of 1952. Under that law, one-third of the supervisory board
members are employee representatives. In companies with more than 2,000
employees, the Co-Determination Act of 1976 stipulates that ‘labour’ should
take half the seats on the board. The representatives of capital retain the right
to nominate the head of the supervisory board who has the casting vote when
the two sides are deadlocked.
At the corporate level, general works councils also can be established.
If the representation of labour on company boards is an essential element of
Germany’s industrial relations system, it was highly controversial in its formative years in the 1950s and, for a short period, in the 1970s when the system was
revised by new legislation. Since then it has become a widely accepted, almost
uncontroversial element of the German system.
Experts take very different positions on the merits and demerits of the system
of co-determination. In its evaluation of the German system of corporate
governance, the OECD pays a half-hearted tribute to co-determination:
There is little doubt that compared to the Anglo-American ‘model’ of corporate
governance, German employees have more inuence on decision-making in
rms. However, inuence ows in both directions, with employee views and
attitudes being affected by their board representation and thereby potentially
helping to foster the more consensual relationship.
(OECD 1995: 98)
But this endorsement is challenged by other more critical views of this peculiarly German institution. In a much cited article, Jensen and Meckling (1979)
long ago questioned the rationale of co-determination from a shareholder value
point of view:
If co-determination is benecial to both stockholders and labour, why do we
need laws which force rms to engage in it? Surely, they would do so voluntarily. The fact that stockholders must be forced by law to accept co-determination is the best evidence we have that they are adversely affected by it.
(Jensen and Meckling 1979: 474)
Some empirical studies on the effect of co-determination on company performance claim to nd evidence of a negative impact. FitzRoy and Kraft (1993)
investigated the effect of the co-determination law of 1976 and came to the conclusion that the return on equity of the company sample affected by the law
decreased by about 5 per cent compared with a sample of companies not affected
by the law. Schmid and Seger (1998), who studied the development of companies
under the co-determination law of 1976 concluded that the market value of the
equities of these rms until 1991 could have been up to 24 per cent higher if
half-parity co-determination had not been introduced. According to another
study by Baums and Frick (1996), the enactment of the co-determination law
had no adverse effects on the share prices of the companies falling under the law.
Altogether, empirical research has not generated consistent and convincing
64
Economy and Society
evidence about the impact of co-determination on performance and innovation
(Sadowski 1997: 9). Much the same is true for research on the effects of the codetermination law concerning labour representation on company boards as well
as on the effects of the works council system.4 One of the underlying problems
is that most of the quantitatively oriented studies on the impact of the 1976 codetermination law are methodologically awed.
One general problem is the absence of an appropriate control group of companies that would allow researchers to isolate the impact of co-determination.
The research studies cited above have either distinguished between the
situation before and after the introduction of co-determination, in 1976, or
distinguished between companies which fall under the co-determination law
and those which do not because they have fewer than 2,000 employees. Both
approaches are problematic: due to the oil price shocks in mid-1970s, the situation after 1976 was different for all companies. Furthermore, the distinction
between larger and smaller companies compares two quite different classes of
companies that are dissimilar but not unrelated when the smaller companies
are often suppliers to the larger ones.
Supervisory boards in these quantitative studies are conceptualized as a ‘black
box’ so that the research studies do not analyse the composition of the
supervisory board and the strategies of the members on the ‘capital bench’
(Sadowski 1997: 72).
Gerum’s (1991) study is signicant because it recognized the second complication about the politics of the supervisory board and developed both a taxonomy and an argument about the possibility of different outcomes. Gerum
analysed the inuence of the supervisory board on company policy in seventyone publicly quoted companies selected in 1979. He differentiated between (a)
supervisory boards dominated by shareholders or by other stakeholders and (b)
supervisory boards seeking to inuence business policy5 and those conning
themselves to their formal legally stipulated role. On this basis, he distinguished
four types of supervisory board–management board relations:
1 In the ‘dominating supervisory board’ the representatives of capital have the
majority of the seats in the supervisory board and determine the chairman on
the supervisory board. By dening a detailed list of decisions requiring their
assent, the supervisory board exerts complete control over the management
board.
2 In the ‘controlling supervisory board’ shareholders dominate the supervisory
board and the board refrains from dening decisions requiring assent. Thus,
the supervisory board controls management board decisions only ex post.
3 In the ‘company-policy-oriented supervisory board’ the shareholders do not
dominate the supervisory board and labour representatives have a dominating
inuence; at the same time, the supervisory board makes dened decisions
requiring assent and by this means actively inuences company policy.
4 In the ‘consultative supervisory board’ the supervisory board is again
Ulrich Jürgens et al.: Shareholder value in an adverse environment
65
dominated by labour. In this case, the supervisory board connes itself to an
advisory and supportive role vis-à-vis the management board.
If there are four types of companies in this classication, Gerum identied
two-thirds of the companies he investigated as type three or four, that is, not
dominated by shareholders. The largest single group, some 37 per cent of the
sample, were type three policy-oriented companies in which representatives of
labour actively inuenced company policy. Overall, only 13 per cent of the companies were type one; or, only in one out of ten companies did shareholders exert
control over company policy via the management board. More often, according
to Gerum, management boards just use supervisory boards as an instrument to
legitimate their policies (Gerum 1998: 56). Gerum concludes that the balance of
power in companies underlying the co-determination law of 1976 clearly tilts in
favour of company management; and for this reason:
Co-determination has to be seen as an additional mean of control besides the
capital and product markets. In addition to its consultative function, codetermination by employees remains the only structurally secured form of an
(internal) outside control.
(Gerum 1991: 729, our translation)6
In summary, the empirical evidence as we have seen does not support the
Jensen/Meckling (1979) supposition that legal co-determination has had a
principally negative effect on shareholder wealth. The existence of co-determination per se has no denite implications for shareholders, mainly because the
system can be implemented and operated in so many different ways.
If we turn to an additional feature, that of a productionist, company-centred
management orientation, it adds a further element of specicity in the German
case. This characteristic of German management was much emphasized in the
literatures that addressed the contrast between German manufacturing success
and British industrial decline through the 1970s and 1980s. Lawrence provided
a classic epitome of managers in West Germany:
The somewhat ‘de-economised’ view which German managers have of the
business enterprise is central. The idea that a rm is not a ‘money-making
machine’ but a place where products get designed, made and eventually sold,
with prots ensuing, tends in Germany to restrict the allure of accountants
and nancial controllers and to dignify the makers and those associated with
them.
(Lawrence 1980: 131)
‘Technik’7 has a central place in his account of German management: because,
according to Lawrence:
Technik exerts a pervasive inuence on German rms and on German managerial thinking. . . . The German company is Technik in organisational form.
The skilled worker, the foreman, the superintendent, the technical director
are all participants in Technik. Of course, there are many things which they do
66
Economy and Society
not have in common, but Technik is something which transcends hierarchy. It
may also transcend particular functions in the company.
(Lawrence 1980: 98)
One manifestation of the centrality of Technik is the high status of engineers
in German companies. As Millar observed in her Anglo-German comparative
study, this contrasts with the high status of nance and marketing people in the
UK (Millar 1979: 63). In another Anglo-German comparison, Eberwein and
Tholen (1993) concluded that engineers ‘are represented more in German
industrial management, also at the top of the company, in numerical terms much
more than in England, and indeed not only in the technical but also in the nontechnical functions’ (Eberwein and Tholen 1993: 173).
In the context of Anglo-German comparisons and explanation of British
industrial decline, the German orientation to Technik and the status of engineers
tended to be somewhat idealized. Furthermore, as Porter observed, the grip of
Technik on German management loosened by the end of the 1980s as nancially
trained executives took the helm in more companies (Porter 1990: 717). Nevertheless, the culture and objectives of German management were and are different, so that even the most recent surveys disclose signicant differences in
management priorities. Table 3 presents recent survey results about the relative
importance of nancial and productionist objectives for British and German
management boards. Differences of orientation have obviously persisted as the
British respondents attach so much more importance to meeting nancial objectives and managing merger, acquisition and divestment.
In summary, the argument so far shows how changes in ownership patterns
and investor behaviour coexist with structural stability because the three longstanding pillars of the German system of corporate governance continue to exist
in various forms. The system sustains national priorities and behaviours and may
create value for stakeholders but it does not put nancial value for shareholders
at the top of the list of business policy objectives.
Movement towards a shareholder value orientation
If the summary above is correct, we must show how government and company
management, through a variety of policy measures since the mid-1990s, have
Table 3 Management board priorities in British and German companies (1998)
Percentage of management boards ranking
these in the top three items of importance:
UK
(Sole board system)
Germany
(Dual board system)
72
46
53
28
15
15
36
36
Meeting nancial goals
Acquisitions, mergers, joint ventures
& divestments
Reducing costs
Improving productivity
Source: Korn/Ferry International (1998: g 21a: 35)
Ulrich Jürgens et al.: Shareholder value in an adverse environment
67
tried to move nancial objectives up the list of policy objectives. Consequently,
in their different ways, both are encouraging the development of a more shareholder value oriented economy. We begin this section by giving an account of
these measures.
Government measures in the area of nancial regulation and company law
have been incremental and mostly marginal: there has been no ‘big bang’ liberalization of the nancial markets in Germany. In the area of nancial regulation,
the second and third law on promotion of nancial markets, together with other
measures, went some way towards creating a more American-style regulatory
agency. As a result, the changes facilitated the development of a wider range of
investment funds and consequently fostered both the demand and supply for
risk capital. 8
The second law on promotion of nancial markets (Zweites Finanzmarktförderungsgesetz) was introduced in 1995 and set up the Federal Supervisory
Office for Securities Trading,9 a German equivalent to the US Securities and
Exchange Commission. But the German government has not yet met requests
to regulate (hostile) takeovers in order to protect small shareholders. The current
policy on this issue is to rely on voluntary enforcement of the strengthened code
adopted by the commission of stock-exchange experts in October 1997.
However, to date a number of rms have still not adopted the code, and the nonadopters include some of those in the DAX 30 (OECD 1998: 121).
The third law (Drittes Finanzmarktförderungsgesetz) of 1998 created a more
liberal framework so that German nancial markets could respond to competitive pressures. The operations of German venture capital were facilitated by
changes in the regulations governing investment companies that allowed them
to operate under a more exible regime. The most important changes include
capital gains that are tax-free after one year (not six years), majority holdings in
companies can be retained for up to eight years (not two years), investment companies are no longer obliged to go public within ten years and rules about the
minimum number of shareholders have been eased. The operations of nancial
intermediaries were facilitated by changes in the rules on liability: investment
companies and nancial advisors are now liable for prospectus information and
for nancial advice only for three years (instead of thirty years as previously)
(OECD 1998: 188). In a parallel development, German nancial regulations
were also reformed in an attempt to deal with a perceived problem about the
funding of pensions. Thus regulations were changed to allow the creation of
private pension funds.
More broadly, several of the new nancial measures represent compromises
between interest groups and lobbies with different agendas and the end result
includes both compromise and signicant unintended changes. Thus, pressure
for reforms in company law originally came from the Social Democratic Party
(SPD) in 1995 which aimed to reduce the power of the banks after a number of
scandals about corporate control in metal-working companies. Due to resistance
by companies and banks, the 1998 law on Control and Transparency in Companies10 did not greatly change the responsibilities of supervisory boards or
68
Economy and Society
encourage greater transparency. Under the new legislation, supervisory boards
must meet at least four times a year (previously two) and voting rights were put
on an equal basis as shares with multiple voting rights were abolished. It also
made major pro-shareholder value changes in the framework of rules about how
rms could use their own equity. Before 1998, conservative and traditional rules
designed to discourage fraud and share-price manipulation had, in Germany (as
in other countries like the Netherlands), prevented companies from dealing in
their own shares. The changes introduced by the law of 1998 can properly be
seen as a signicant change because stock options may now be used as compensation for directors and rms are permitted to buy back their shares.
As to major companies, since the mid-1990s several major agship companies
in the German economy have proclaimed shareholder value to be their central
goal (Vitols et al. 1997). This new orientation is identied with, and linked to,
top management personalities such as Schrempp (CEO of DaimlerChrysler
Germany) and von Pierer (CEO of Siemens), so that shareholder value in
Germany stands for the programmes of radical corporate change11 which have
been introduced by these active, celebrity chief executives.
Specic measures taken by individual companies to foster shareholder value
orientation include (SGZ Bank 1997):
share buy-back: about sixty companies have now obtained the necessary
authorization from shareholders which allows shares buy-back; but, so far,
only the pharmaceutical companies Bayer and Schering have put this into
practice;
quarterly reporting: this has been introduced by twenty out of the DAX 30
companies;
adoption of international accounting standards: these have now been adopted
by ten out of the DAX 30 companies;
the introduction of new management control systems with protability goals
specied by division or activity and sometimes expressed in terms of return
on capital or assets;
increased emphasis on investor relations activities. 12
Table 4 presents an overview of measures taken by individual companies to foster
shareholder value orientation. It shows that some champions of shareholder
value, such as DaimlerChrysler and Hoechst, have made substantial changes and
set aggressive targets. If we consider the whole group of DAX 30 companies, the
advance of shareholder value is uneven. Only one-third have set an explicit
protability target while 60 per cent have introduced stock options for managers.
To sum up, on the evidence and argument so far, the increased emphasis on
shareholder value represents something more than just lip service to a new
Anglo-Saxon management fad. But the extent and nature of the change is uncertain. The key question is whether shareholder value does or will change any of
the political economic fundamentals of the German system. If we wish to answer
this question we must look beyond the evidence on government regulation and
corporate adoption of shareholder value and pose a much larger institutional
Ulrich Jürgens et al.: Shareholder value in an adverse environment
69
Table 4 Shareholder value related measures by the DAX 30 companies and selected
examples
Protability
goal
All DAX
33.3%
30 companies
in % (1997)
Daimler
Return on capital 12%
Chrysler
(by 1999); RONA:
Return on net assets:
15.5%
Hoechst
(Revenue increase of
20%)
Siemens
Return on equity 15%
(by 2000)
Veba
(Revenue increase of
7.6% by 2002)
International Employee
Stock
Quarterly
accounting
share
options for reporting
standard
ownership managers
programme
43.3%
33.3%
60.0%
66.7%
US GAAP
X
X
Yes
IAS
X
X
Yes
–
X
X
Yes
IAS
X
–
Yes
Source: Annual reports of all DAX 30 companies (1997) and various newspaper articles; own calculation
question about whether the pillars of the German corporate governance system
are crumbling. In the rest of this section, we address this larger question and
start by considering the changing role of banks.
There is no doubt that the role of German banks has been changing rapidly
since the mid–1990s driven by a whole series of internal and external changes.
Their role has been changed by the increasing importance of stock-market new
issues in company nance as well as by the creation of the Neue Markt. The
major banks and insurance companies have also strategically (re)dened share
ownership as an asset management and investment fund business. This constitutes a major shift from ‘patient capital’ to shareholder value orientation in the
German banking sector. Both shifts are reinforced by the increasing importance
of pension funds of domestic origin and, more especially, foreign origin. These
developments will now be discussed in more detail, beginning with the Neue
Markt.
Until recently, only a very small number of large German companies were
quoted on the stock exchange and they rarely used new equity issues as a means
of company nance. The introduction of the Neue Markt indicates a signicant
change in several respects.
The Deutsche Börse AG created the Frankfurt-based Neue Markt in 1997
with the aim of allowing new and developing companies to make Initial Public
Offerings (IPO) and supporting the ow of venture capital. It was an immediate success. By June 1999, there were 120 companies listed on the Neue Markt,
and new companies were joining daily (DG Bank Research 1999: 4). It is, of
course, much smaller than the long-established main market; in 1999, the overall
70
Economy and Society
market capitalization of the Neue Markt amounted to 6.7 per cent of the capitalization of the DAX 30 who are quoted on the main market. But, in terms of
share price appreciation, the Neue Markt has outperformed the DAX by more
than 400 per cent in its rst two years of existence. And, currently, the Neue
Markt is the leading European growth bourse: its trading volume makes up
about 80 per cent and its market capitalization about 50 per cent of all European
growth bourses (Harnischfeger 1999a: x). The unexpected dynamic development of the Neue Markt has often been cited as a sign of major change in
Germany. Thus, the Financial Times saw it as an indication of ‘a new business
culture . . . which has little in common with the traditional consensus driven
company, typical of the Mittelstand or medium sized business sector. The “Neue
Markt” . . . reects the changing face of German capitalism’ (Harnischfeger
1999a: x).
Through the Neue Markt, and other changes, the banks have been partly
bypassed. As the OECD observed, the Neue Markt brought several important
changes to Germany. First, other nancial intermediaries, as well as banks, have
been active in introducing rms to the exchange. It has often been argued in the
past that, although the large banks dominated the business of initial public offerings, they had no real incentive to promote stock-market listings because IPOs
could reduce their traditional lending activities. A second feature has been to
accompany each newly listed rm with a ‘market maker’, thereby attempting to
improve market liquidity. Improving liquidity is also important from the viewpoint of ensuring exit possibilities for initial risk investors in the company (OECD
1998: 119). The major German banks did not foresee the dynamic development
of the Neue Markt and have missed much of the small- and medium-sized IPO
business. Much the same is true for businesses related to the unprecedented international wave of mergers and acquisitions since the mid-1990s.
The banks are however now seeking to re-enter some of these activities. In
recent banking sector restructuring, investment banking has been a major focus
in banking strategy. At the same time, banks (and insurance companies) have
begun to loosen the system of cross-shareholding and interlocking directorates
that were central to the conduct of ‘patient shareholders’. The number of such
directorates has been declining for more than ten years: between 1986 and 1993,
private banks reduced the number of seats held on the supervisory boards of the
100 largest German companies from 114 to ninety-nine (Deutsch 1997: 22). The
chief nancial officer of Deutsche Bank declared publicly that his bank had for
some years not lled all the supervisory board positions which it was offered by
other companies and would, in future, provide even fewer directors. Instead, he
recommended the practice of foreign pension funds managers who meet with
company management boards on a one-to-one basis. 13
The banks have started to behave like pension and investment funds.
Deutsche Bank, Dresdner Bank and Münchner Rückversicherung have
recently begun to spin off their ownership stakes in other German companies
into separately managed holdings. And the banks are quite explicit that these
holdings shall be run on the basis of a shareholder value orientation. Thus, at
the end of 1998, Deutsche Bank established a subsidiary, ‘DB-Investor’ to
Ulrich Jürgens et al.: Shareholder value in an adverse environment
71
manage the industrial assets owned by the bank. The CEO of Deutsche Bank
Breuer states that ‘with the new structure, we can control our industrial
shareholdings in a more active and much more protable way. This is good news
for our shareholders’ (Deutsche Bank press release 1998, our translation).14
Meanwhile, DWS (the investment fund of Deutsche Bank, founded in 1956 and
Europe’s largest investment company) had already become one of the most outspoken protagonists of shareholder value orientation in Germany. Its former
chief manager Strenger had pronounced its independent shareholder value
oriented position on many occasions. Independent asset management companies were also launched by the other major German banks and by the big
insurance companies such as Allianz which launched Allianz Asset Management GmbH in 1998.
The other signicant development is the emergence of German-owned
private pension funds which are growing rapidly from a very small base. German
public pensions are funded through a pay-as-you-go system (Jackson and Vitols
1999).15 Private pensions in Germany represent a supplement to this longestablished statutory regime whose nances appear to be endangered by the
demographic changes and by the increasing life expectancies of people. Private
pension funds are relatively new because they were only formally recognized in
1998 under the 3rd Financial Markets Promotion Law.16 Specic pension funds
outside the public pensions system had existed previously in various forms but
they were of minor importance. In terms of nancial weight the signicance of
private and semi-public pensions in Germany is minor (see Baums and Fraune
1995: 97). The fund value equated to only 6 per cent of GDP in Germany in
1996 whereas in the US they equate to 57.5 per cent of GDP and in the UK 93.2
per cent of GDP (Nürk 1998: 181). Payments into pension funds are not tax
deductible in Germany, as they generally are in the Anglo-Saxon countries.
Nevertheless, these funds are growing rapidly.
What we are seeing is the emergence of a new kind of institutional investor
with an explicit shareholder value motivation as German-owned and run
pension funds join the American funds who invest American savings in German
companies. By 1999 there were thirty-four investment funds offering private
pensions in Germany and twenty-ve of these were owned and run by German
nancial institutions. The position of pension funds as institutional investors is
becoming stronger and the funds are mainly interested in the DAX 30 rms
which are guided by shareholder value principles. They are joined by US
pension funds which are increasingly engaged in buying shares and putting pressure on company management to act on behalf of shareholder interests (The
Conference Board 1999).
The increasing inuence of these funds is controversial and their future role
is uncertain. Some observers from the nancial community already see pension
funds as ‘a sea change in German old-age provision’.17 By way of contrast, Nürk
nds that ‘Pension funds and other forms of funding via external institutions . . .
play only a minor role in the nancing of old-age provision’ (Nürk 1998: 181).
Much depends on political decisions which have not yet been taken. The
German labour minister recently proposed a funded system of capital formation
72
Economy and Society
complementary to the pay-as-you-go system. If this idea nds approval the
German pension funds will denitely have a large growth potential.
While the nancial system is changing very rapidly, as new actors, motivations
and behaviours assert themselves, it is much more difficult to nd signs of
erosion within the system of co-determination. Indeed, the system of codetermination is seldom attacked openly by company management.18 On the
contrary, quite a few top managers praise the system warmly when confronted
by institutional investors. A cynic might observe that German managers have
ulterior motives for praising a system which serves as a protection for incumbent management against hostile takeovers which is, of course, partly why AngloSaxon management has reservations about co-determination.
Hostile takeovers are indeed a rare phenomenon in the German context. One
of the peculiarities of the German case is management commitment to shareholder value without the threat of takeover or dismemberment for corporations
which disappoint the market. A recent research report by J. P. Morgan identied 222 hostile bids in Europe since 1990. But, only four of these bids involved
German companies, and the only successful hostile bid was Krupp’s $1.0 billion
acquisition of Hoesch in 1991 (Gibbs 1999: 7). Most of the hostile European
bids during this period involved British rms who made no fewer than 148
hostile bids. These gures are more remarkable if we remember that German
companies have been active participants in the recent European merger and
acquisition wave. The low number of hostile takeovers in Germany seems to
indicate that co-determination has indeed served as a ‘poison pill’ for potential
predators whether foreign owned or German.
On the whole it seems that co-determination still stands strong and criticism
of co-determination is almost taboo.19 However, a variety of tendencies that are
working to hollow out the principle cannot be overlooked:
Relocation of manufacturing operations to overseas sites and the shift to a
service economy are undermining the strongholds of union power in the companies.
The discussions about a European corporate charter and about ‘best practice
corporate governance’ carried out at the OECD, IMF and World Bank level
serve to problematize German arrangements.
These developments are recognized in the research programme on ‘codetermination and new company cultures’ (Bertelsmann Stiftung; Hans-BöcklerStiftung 1998) which nevertheless broadly defends the status quo. In this
programme a Commission on Co-determination was constituted as a steering
board which included high-ranking representatives from employer federations,
unions, government and academia. The Commission’s executive report unanimously endorsed co-determination in its existing form. It recognized that codetermination could be only one element of corporate governance for companies
engaged in competitive markets who have to take into account the interests and
needs of all stakeholders. More signicantly it concluded that ‘Co-determination
today is no longer questioned especially by the employer side’ (Bertelsmann
Stiftung; Hans-Böckler-Stiftung 1998: 7, our translation). And, after reviewing
Ulrich Jürgens et al.: Shareholder value in an adverse environment
73
the recent debate about best practice and corporate governance, the report concluded that ‘New regulation of co-determination to improve the functionality of
the supervisory board will not be necessary’ (ibid.: 17, our translation).
However, if the report endorsed existing institutions, it also drew attention to
the way in which co-determination is being structurally eroded by economic
restructuring and the trend towards a service economy, just as the capital market
makes new demands. One index of structural change is the size of the ‘codetermination-free zone’ at both the company level (supervisory board) and the
plant level (works councils): this co-determination-free zone has grown from 51
per cent to 61 per cent of the employees in the private sector during the mid1990s. At the same time there are new pressures for value on the companies and
workers inside the co-determination system. Thus, the report concludes:
The expansion and internationalization of capital markets forces the codetermined German companies to orient themselves towards increasingly
demanding, short-term oriented, less loyal investors who are less prepared to
compromise and who are used to signal their preferences with regard to companies’ strategies and company protability primarily via the capital market.
(ibid.: 12, our translation)
In the nature of things it is more difficult to generalize with condence about
the orientation of managers than it is about the role of the banks or the coverage of co-determination. But this is an interesting and important topic not least
because it brings out the continuing importance of product markets and managerial initiative which, in the German case, appear to have been more important
initiators of change than capital markets and shareholders.
In the rst half of the 1990s, German companies went through a period of
profound changes. To get over a short, sharp recession and meet product-market
challenges, lean production and business process re-engineering were implemented widely. Many companies segmented their operations into business units
or decentralized parts of the company to prot centres. Companies also changed
from functional to product- and process-oriented types of organization and outsourced ‘non-core’ activities. This restructuring was often linked to company
strategies of developing new businesses with higher growth potential.
As Vitols (1999) argues, the challenge was product-market change and not
capital-market pressure and the strategic response of changes in orientation and
company restructuring were initiated by company management acting on its own
initiative not under pressure from institutional investors. Thus, we have the
paradoxical situation that shareholder value orientation in Germany was initiated to a great extent by company management in the industrial sector.
The modied company structures and strategies required new controlling and
management incentive systems which used the language and techniques of
management for shareholder value and suited the agenda of the capital market.
The executive boards could no longer directly manage individual business units.
Careers could no longer be made within the functional chimneys of giant
companies. New criteria for resource allocation and management promotion were
74
Economy and Society
needed: this is where shareholder value came in as the answer to an industrial
problem. It is in this context that we nd the rapid spread of innovations such as
the xing of nancial targets for evaluating management performance, new controlling and accounting systems, and stock options as management incentives.
As Table 4 shows, one third of the DAX 30 companies now publish nancial
targets which often go along with the declaration that under-performing
company units will be sold off. Many of these targets are specied in terms of
return on capital or assets, as recommended by the American consultants and
academics who sell shareholder value and as required by the new kind of valueoriented investor.
Thus, for instance, DaimlerChrysler in March 1999 introduced a value orientated controlling system (DaimlerChrysler 1999). The new system set a Return
on Net Assets (RONA) of 15.5 per cent before tax for the twenty-three to
twenty-four business units of DaimlerChrysler and all 5,000 top managers of the
company have recently been trained on the subject. Another example is
Metallgesellschaft, a heavy industry combine. Metallgesellschaft announced that
its forty-four business units had, as a matter of policy, to achieve a leading position in their line of business and a 14 per cent return on capital employed
(Harnischfeger 1999d: 14). More recently Siemens has also introduced a valueoriented measure called GWB (Geschäftswertbeitrag – contribution to business
value). Each business unit has to calculate if its earnings are higher than capital
costs. The total capital costs for Siemens AG are 8 per cent (after tax) and there
are different capital costs for individual business units which trade in different
markets. The net result is that ‘each of the 16 operating divisions is measured by
its earnings on net capital employed’ (Harnischfeger 1999b: xiv).
Another signicant development is stock options or shares for management
which, as Table 4 shows, have now been introduced in more than half of the DAX
30 companies. The rationale for stock-options stakes is that they encourage managers to ‘think like owners’ (Donkin 1999: 9). But, so far, they are a matter of
limited experiment and different in each company. Generally, they are not very
widely spread and offered only to top management in large German companies,
especially those which are oriented towards the shareholder value principle;
some high tech companies on the Neue Markt also use them. Stock options in
Germany are generally only a supplement to normal salaries. 20
To summarize the changes in the orientation of company management: as we
have noted, top German managers are starting to implement shareholder value
principles in their companies. Protability goals, controlling systems, stock
options, core business strategies and stock-market listing of company divisions
are manifestations of new shareholder-oriented activities whose origins paradoxically go back to industrial recession in the early 1990s. If institutional
investors try to further the changes made by top management, their pressure is
sometimes resisted. Thus, the CEO of a pharmaceutical company has recently
openly criticized the growing inuence of investment funds: ‘I suggest taking a
stronger line against some capital market actors who want to force companies to
adopt their rules of playing the game’ (Weishaupt 1999: 19, our translation).
Ulrich Jürgens et al.: Shareholder value in an adverse environment
75
Summary and outlook
This article has reviewed the empirical evidence and signs of movement towards
a shareholder value economy in the German political economy. Our cautious
conclusion is that, at this point in time, there are changes but the impact is marginal. Even in comparison with other countries in continental Europe, Germany
seems to be moving very slowly in the direction of a shareholder value economy.
At the current stage in Germany, the most visible manifestations of change in
the direction of shareholder value are the internal changes initiated by company
management who are introducing shareholder value oriented management
control and incentive systems. However, the recent changes affect primarily a
handful of large companies, like DaimlerChrysler or Siemens, and, as we have
seen, the economic base for a shareholder value economy in Germany is very
narrow. Of course these are agship companies whose internal changes may ow
through the many linkages they have with the rest of the economy. However, so
far these seem to be isolated cases in companies where new practices are only
being established and a point of no return has not been reached yet.
Another recent phenomenon, within broader changes in the nancial markets,
is the growing dynamic of changes in the role of the banks. The loosening up of
the traditional cross-holding/interlocking directorate structures is a signicant
development. But it seems to be part of gradual processes and so far no ‘big bang’
is in sight. The same is true for the growing inuence of institutional investors
with value motivations. Their inuence can be observed in the case of individual
companies, but overall it is less than in other countries, even on the European
continent. We must expect that savings for retirement through private pension
funds will become more important in Germany because of problems with the
existing pensions system. But, so far, Germany is unlike the Anglo-Saxon countries where the interests and behaviour of private households drive shareholder
value orientation.
In conclusion, we cannot agree with the claims made by Ulrich Steger, a
former executive board member of Volkswagen, who believes that a paradigm
shift has already occurred in Germany because ‘The investors have won the
power struggle against the managers’ (Balzer and Jensen 1999: 130). But the very
fact that such a claim is being made shows that substantial change is underway
in Germany.
Notes
1 In Germany, non-nancial companies held 42 per cent of the shares of other
companies in 1995. Their share is less than in France where non-nancial companies hold
58 per cent but much more than in the USA where non-nancial companies hold 15 per
cent and the UK where they hold 4 per cent (Deutsche Bundesbank 1997: 29).
2 Baums and Fraune investigated voting rights of banks at annual general shareholder
meetings in twenty-four of the top 100 listed rms where ownership was dispersed among
more than 50 per cent of shareholders. In general, it is difficult to obtain empirical information about proxy voting because banks regard it as condential (Dohmen 1998: 14).
76
Economy and Society
3 The legal basis for the relationship between the managing board, the supervisory
board and the shareholders’ meeting is dened by the law of co-determination (MitbestG
1976), the Montan-Mitbestimmungsgesetz (Montan-MitbestG 1951), the Betriebsverfassungsgesetz (BetrVG 1952, 1972) and the joint-stock company law (AktG 1965).
4 The situation is somewhat different with regard to research on the impact of works
councils on company performance. Earlier research by Addison et al. (1993) and Addison
et al. (1996) came to contradictory results: the 1993 study concluded that co-determination has no statistically signicant inuence on net earnings, while the 1996 study found
a statistically signicant negative inuence on protability. More recent research
produces more consistent results. According to Jirjahn (1997) and Jirjahn and Klodt
(1999), the existence of a works council has a positive inuence on productivity and a
negative inuence on protability. This nding could be explained by the inuence of
works councils on the distribution of prots. Other studies have found that works councils
have a signicant positive inuence on wage levels (see Dilger 1999).
5 According to German law on joint stock companies, supervisory boards can dene
and specify a list of assent requiring decisions (§111 Abs. 4 AktG). By this means, the
supervisory board can inuence strategic decisions in functional areas such as nance,
personnel, investment, etc.
6 Therefore ‘stylized’ interpretations about the general and invariant merits of the codetermination system can be quite misleading. This judgement applies to the OECD’s
misleading interpretation and verdict:
a stylised version of the German model is that it relies on continuous monitoring of
managers by other stakeholders, who have a long-term relationship with the rm and
engage permanently in important aspects of decision-making and, in case of dissatisfaction, take action to correct management decisions through internal channels.
(OECD 1995: 85).
7 The German term ‘Technik’ which Lawrence uses has no real equivalent in English
though it has recently entered British consciousness as a result of VAG advertising
campaigns for the Audi brand.
8 Demand and supply for risk capital was further promoted by the creation of the Neue
Markt.
9 Bundesaufsichtsamt für den Wertpapierhandel; BAWe: http://www.bawe.de
10 Gesetz zur Kontrolle und Transparenz im Unternehmensbereich (KonTraG).
11 This linkage between restructuring and shareholder value has negative associations
to shareholder value. In consequence, the term shareholder value is being avoided by
some of the protagonists. The CEO of VEBA announced in an interview: ‘I don’t use the
expression shareholder value any longer. The connotation is too negative. For me the
debate is about value-oriented company policy’ (Schumacher 1996: 27, our translation).
12 Investor relations departments in German companies were quite rare before the
1990s (Burgmaier 1999: 74). In 1989, only nine of the 30 DAX companies and only ve
of the seventy MDAX companies had investor relations (IR) departments. By 1998 no
fewer than twenty-six companies of the DAX had IR departments and fty-one of the
MDAX. Of seventy-ve companies of the Neue Markt forty-six had IR departments in
1998.
13 Speech by Dr Thomas R. Fischer, Deutsche Bank chief nancial officer, at the ‘First
Humboldt-Forum on Economics and Management of Corporate Governance’ at the
Humboldt University, Berlin, 4-5 June 1999.
14 In terms of market capitalization DB-investor ranks among the top fteen DAX
companies. Industrial assets make up 45 per cent of the total market value of the Deutsche
Bank AG (Press release, Deutsche Bank, 16 December 1998, our translation).
15 Employer and employee each contribute 8.85 per cent of gross earnings up to a
maximum of DM 6,500. In addition to these earnings-related contributions, the budget
Ulrich Jürgens et al.: Shareholder value in an adverse environment
77
of the federal government provides a subsidy that amounts to roughly 18 per cent of
expenditures.
16 These funds are called ‘Altersvorsorge Sondervermögen’.
17 This is the opinion of Manfred Laux, chief of the German Investment Society
(Deutsche Investment Gesellschaft, DVI), reported in the Wall Street Journal, 20 April 1998,
which can be found at: http://www.bvi.de/as/11-rechtsuntern.html
18 However, Eberwein and Tholen (1990), in their study of manager mentality, found
that a majority of company CEOs were less than enthusiastic about co-determination.
Only 9 per cent of managers regarded co-determination as a support for implementing
important decisions and 27 per cent saw it as a disruption in their company. However, 34
per cent accepted co-determination ‘as a necessary element of a pluralistic society’
(Eberwein and Tholen 1990: 259, our translation).
19 The OECD, for example, in its recommendations does not adopt a position of opposition in principle to the two-tier system. Thus, the OECD concludes that ‘Although the
structure of corporate boards for publicly traded corporations differs among OECD
nations – for example, by including both single- and two-tier boards – board independence can be promoted in any type of board system’ (1998: 22).
20 By international standards top German managers earn relatively little. The average
CEO of a DAX 30 company earned ‘only’ 1.7 million DM in 1997 (Balzer and Sommer
1998: 212). Standardized international compensation is becoming an issue due to the
growing number of global mergers of German companies. In the case of the newly merged
DaimlerChrysler, the German CEO Jürgen Schrempp earns about 3 million DM
annually while his American counterpart, Chrysler CEO Bob Eaton, earns about seven
times as much. Ulrich Hartmann, CEO of VEBA, believes that ‘German companies are
going to orient their remuneration systems more towards the American model’ (Balzer
and Sommer 1998: 215, our translation).
References
Adams, M. (1999) ‘Cross holdings in
Germany’, Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics 1(155): 80–109.
Addison, J., Kraft, K. and Wagner, J.
(1993) ‘German works councils and rm
performance’, in B. Kaufmann and M.
Kleiner (eds) Employee Representation:
Alternatives and Future Directions,
Madison, WI: Industrial Relations
Research Association, pp. 305–38.
Addison, J., Schnabel, C. and Wagner,
J. (1996) ‘German works councils, prots
and innovation’, Kyklos 49(4): 555–82.
Balzer, A. and Jensen, S. (1999)
‘Europa-Meister’, Managermagazin
February: 130.
Balzer, A. and Sommer, C. (1998)
‘Mehr Geld für die Chefs’,
Managermagazin September: 214–28.
Baums, T. and Fraune, C. (1995)
‘Institutionelle Anleger und
Publikumsgesellschaft: Eine empirische
Untersuchung’, Die Aktiengesellschaft 3:
97–112.
Baums, T. and Frick, B. (1996) ‘Codetermination in Germany: the impact on
the market value of the rm’, Working
Paper, University of Osnabrück.
Bertelsmann Stiftung; Hans-BšcklerStiftung (eds) (1998) Mitbestimmung und
neue Unternehmenskulturen – Bilanz und
Perspektiven: Bericht der Kommission
Mitbestimmung, Gütersloh: Bertelsmann
Stiftung.
Boehmer, E. (1998) ‘Who controls
Germany? An exploratory analysis’,
Working Paper, Institut für Bank- und
Versicherungswesen HumboldtUniversität zu Berlin.
Bundesverband Deutscher
Investment-Gesellschaften e.V. (BVI)
Investment 98. Daten, Fakten,
Entwicklungen.
Burgmaier, S. (1999) ‘Persönliche
Betreuung’, Wirtschaftswoche 14: 74.
The Conference Board (1999) ‘U.S.
institutional investors continue to
dominate overseas markets’. 6 May – http:
78
Economy and Society
www.conmmferenceboard.org/search/dpress.cfm?pressid=44
84.
DaimlerChrysler mit
wertorientiertem Controllingsystem
(Zus). (1999) 15 March, http:
//www.vwd.de/nal/26101.html
Deutsch, K. (1997) ‘Corporate
governance in Germany’, Deutsche Bank
Research, Bulletin 4: 18–26.
Deutsches Aktieninstitut e.V. (eds)
(1998) DAI-Factbook 1998 Frankfurt a.M.
—— (eds) (1999) Privater Aktienbesitz in
Deutschland: Aufwärtstrend setzt sich fort,
DAI-Kurzstudie 1/99, Frankfurt a.M.
Deutsche Bank (1998) Press release, 16
December.
Deutsche Bank Research (1997)
‘Corporate governance in Germany’,
Bulletin 4: 18–29.
Deutsche Bundesbank (1999a)
‘Ergebnisse der gesamtwirtschaftlichen
Finanzierungsrechnung für Deutschland
1990 bis 1998’, Statistische
Sonderveröffentlichung 4, Frankfurt a.M.
Ð Ð (1999b) ‘Die gesamtwirtschaftlichen
Finanzierungsströme im Jahr 1998’,
Monatsbericht Juni 1999, Frankfurt a.M.
Deutsche Bundesbank Monthly
Report (1997) ‘Shares as nancing and
investment instruments’, January: 27–40.
DG Bank Research (1999) Neuer Markt
– Juni 1999. Frankfurt a.M.
Dilger, A. (1999) ‘Erträge bei
differenzierter Betriebsratsbetrachtung –
Erste Ergebnisse einer Untersuchung des
NIFA-Panels’, in L. Bellmann, S. Kohaut
and M. Lahner (eds) Zur Entwicklung von
Lohn und Beschäftigung auf der Basis von
Betriebs- und Unternehmensdaten,
Nürnberg: Institut für Arbeitsmarkt- und
Berufsforschung der Bundesanstalt für
Arbeit, pp. 55–75.
Dohmen, F. (1998) Die Macht der
Banken: Das Netzwerk der Deutschland
AG, Supplement der Zeitschrift
Sozialismus, Hamburg: VSA-Verlag.
Donkin, R. (1999) ‘Riches for the few’,
Financial Times 26 February: 9.
Eberwein, W. and Tholen, J. (1990)
Managermentalität: Industrielle
Unternehmensleitung als Beruf und Politik,
Frankfurt/M.: Frankfurter Allgemeine
Zeitung.
—— and —— (1993) Euro-manager or
Splendid Isolation? International
Management – An Anglo-German
Comparison, Berlin and New York: de
Gruyter.
FitzRoy, F. and Kraft, K. (1993)
‘Economic effects of codetermination’,
Scandinavian Journal of Economics 95(3):
365–75.
Gerum, E. (1991) ‘Aufsichtsratstypen –
Ein Beitrag zur Theorie der Organisation
der Unternehmensführung’, Die
Betriebswirtschaft 51(6): 719–31.
—— (1995) ‘Führungsorganisation,
Eigentümerstruktur und
Unternehmnsstrategie’, Die
Betriebswirtschaft 55(3): 359–79.
—— (1998) Mitbestimmung und
Corporate Governance, Expertise for the
project ‘Mitbestimmung und neue
Unternehmenskulturen’ of the
Bertelsmann Stiftung and the HansBöckler-Stiftung, Gütersloh: Verlag
Bertelsmann Stiftung.
Gibbs, P. (1999) ‘Mergers and
acquisitions research’, Report of 15
April, JP Morgan Securities,
unpublished.
Harnischfeger, U. (1999a) ‘A different
way of doing business’, Financial Times
(special edition) 1 June: x.
—— (1999b) ‘Siemen’s chief is no
stereotype’, Financial Times (special
edition) 1 June: xiv.
—— (1999c) ‘Victim of its own success’,
Financial Times 30 June: 10.
—— (1999d) ‘Metallgesellschaft
considers US listing’, Financial Times 30
June: 14.
Hirsch-Kreinsen, H. (1999)
‘Shareholder value: Zum Wandel von
Unternehmensstrukturen und
Kapitalmarktbedingungen’, WSI
Mitteilungen 5: 322–30.
Jackson, G. and Vitols, S. (1999)
‘Pension regimes and nancial systems:
between social security, market liquidity,
and corporate governance’, unpublished.
Jensen, M. and Meckling, W. (1979)
‘Rights and production functions: an
application to labour-managed rms and
codetermination’, Journal of Business
52(4): 469–506.
Jirjahn, U. (1997) ‘Effizienzwirkungen
Ulrich Jürgens et al.: Shareholder value in an adverse environment
von Erfolgsbeteiligung und Partizipation
– eine mikroökonomische Analyse’,
Dissertation, Universität Hannover.
—— and Klodt, T. (1999) ‘Lohnhöhe,
industrielle Beziehungen und
Produktmärkte’, in L. Bellmann, S.
Kohaut and M. Lahner (eds) Zur
Entwicklung von Lohn und Beschäftigung
auf der Basis von Betriebs – und
Unternehmensdaten , Nürnberg: Institut
für Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsforschung
der Bundesanstalt für Arbeit, pp. 27–54.
Korn/Ferry International (eds) (1998)
European Boards of Directors Study 1998.
Lawrence, P. (1980) Managers and
Management in West Germany, London:
Croom Helm.
Leminsky, G. (1998) Bewährungsproben
für ein Management des Wandels:
Gewerkschaftliche Politik zwischen
Globalisierungsfalle und Sozialstaatsabbau,
Berlin: Edition Sigma.
Lutter, M. (1997) ‘Eine größenabhängige
und zwingende Unternehmensverfassung
in Europa?’ Die Aktiengesellschaft 12:
538–40.
Markovits, A. (1982) Political Economy of
West Germany: The Model of Deutschland,
New York: Praeger.
Millar, J. (1979) British Management
Versus German Management: A
Comparison of Organisational Effectiveness
in West German and UK Factories,
Farnborough: Saxon House.
NŸrk, B. (1998) ‘Institutional investors
and their implications for nancial
markets in Germany’, in OECD (ed.)
Institutional Investors in the New Financial
Landscape, OECD, pp. 179–95.
OECD Economic Surveys (1995)
Germany, Paris: OECD.
OECD Economic Surveys (1998)
Germany, Paris: OECD.
Porter, M. (1990) The Competitive
Advantage of Nations, New York: The
Free Press.
Sadowksi, D. (1997) Mitbestimmung –
Gewinne und Investitionen, Expertise für
das Projekt ‘Mitbestimmung und neue
Unternehmenskulturen’, Gütersloh:
Bertelsmann Stiftung.
Sanghera, S. (1999) ‘Most Britons shun
share ownership, says report’, Financial
Times 2 June: 9.
79
Schmid, F. and Seger, A. (1998)
‘Arbeitnehmermitbestimmung, Allokation
von Entscheidungsrechten und
Shareholder Value’, Zeitschrift für
Betriebswirtschaft 68(5): 453–73.
Schulte, D. (1999) ‘Mitbestimmung in
Bewegung’, Gewerkschaftliche
Monatshefte: Mitbestimmung in Bewegung
3: 129–38.
Schumacher, O. (1996) ‘Eine furchtbare
Diskussion: Zeit-Interview mit Veba-Chef
Ulrich Hartmann über das schwierige
Verhältnis von Aktionären und
Arbeitnehmern’, Die Zeit 37 (6
September): 27.
SGZ Bank (eds) (1997) Die Umsetzung
des Shareholder-Value-Konzeptes durch die
DAX-Unternehmen , Stuttgart.
Streeck, W. (1995) ‘Works councils in
Western Europe: cooperation through
representation’, in J. Rogers and W.
Streeck (eds) Works Councils, Consultation,
Representation, and Cooperation in
Industrial Relations, Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, pp. 313–48.
Vitols, S. (1999) ‘The reconstructing of
German corporate governance: capital
market pressures or managerial
initiatives?’, paper prepared for the
conference ‘The Political Economy of
Corporate Governance in Europe and
Japan’, European University Florence,
10–11 June.
Vitols, S. et al. (1997) Corporate
Governance in Large British and German
Companies: Comparative Institutional
Advantage or Competing for Best Practice,
London: Anglo-German Foundation.
Weishaupt, G. (1999) ‘Vorstände
kritisieren die Macht der Fonds’,
Handelsblatt 89 (10 May): 19.
Wenger, E. and Kaserer, C. (1998)
‘German banks and corporate governance:
a critical view’, in K. Hopt, H. Kanda, M.
Roe, E. Wymeersch and S. Prigge (eds)
Comparative Corporate Governance: The
State of the Art and Emerging Research,
Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Windolf, P. and Beyer, J. (1995)
‘Kooperativer Kapitalismus:
Unternehmensverechtungen im
internationalen Vergleich’, Kölner
Zeitschrift für Soziologie und
Sozialpsychologie 1(47): 1–36.