The Origins of Money, evidence from the ancient Near East and
Egypt
Joe Cribb, Keeper of Coins and Medals, British Museum, London
And Money, that most pure imagination,
Gleams only through the dawn of its creation.
(Byron, Don Juan, Canto 12, II)
Money fits so tightly into the pattern of everyday life that it is hard to imagine an
organised human society without it. The use of money is a natural part of social life
and seems as though it must have evolved as part of man's social development as a
subconscious expression of human nature itself. This is not the case; a search
through the history of the human race will in fact provide examples of societies
which were totally unaware of money or of the need for it. Some societies, like the
native people of Australia before colonisation, lacked money because their economic
development had not risen above a very low level, while others, as in the case of the
Incas who ruled Peru and Bolivia before the Spanish conquest, appear to have
developed their economy under a powerful central authority in such a way that
money was unnecessary.
These are of course exceptions. For the most part the human societies which are
chronicled in history were already aware of the practical advantages of money before
they came to be noticed. If they were ever like those few recorded moneyless
societies, it must have been long before history began. At some time in prehistory
they all discovered money, either for themselves or from one of their neighbours
who had already made the discovery. This makes it difficult to examine money's
origins, as the discoveries mostly took place in a period from which little or no
evidence of money survives.
Even though our knowledge of human society in prehistoric times is continually
expanding, money at that period remains obscured. This is because of the nature of
money. Archaeologists cannot identify the objects they find as money, because
money is not a particular distinctive object, but any object to which a particular idea
has been applied. It is the evidence of that idea which is lacking in prehistory.
So an alternative to looking for the actual discovery of money has to be sought in
order to attempt an understanding of money's origins. The question of when and
where money began have to be abandoned in favour of asking how and why. The
search must be for actual reports of the use of money, and those closest in time or
their nature to prehistory ought to give the most accurate explanation. The accounts
of money nearest in time to its origins are those contained in the earliest written
records and oral traditions of man's activities; those nearest in their nature are more
recent reports of the economic life of tribal societies, who live in conditions similar to
those endured by prehistoric man.
It was precisely by examining such evidence that Aristotle, the Greek philosopher
(384-322 BC), formed the first scientific account of the origins of money. He
explained the discovery of money by imagining a scene in which traders, unable to
cope with the difficulties of exchanging goods by barter, invented money as a means
of solving their problems. In his Politics he looked at the role of money in the
organisation of the state, asking himself the question why had the concept of money
arisen in society:
… barter introduced the use of money … for a convenient place from whence to import what
you wanted or to export what you had a surplus of being often at a distance, money
necessarily made its way into commerce … (traders) invented something to exchange with
each other, which they should mutually give and take, that, being really valuable itself,
should have the additional advantage of being easy of conveyance for the purpose of life. …
Money thus being established as the necessary medium of exchange …
Aristotle also addressed the question of what money means in his Ethics where he
examined its social and legal aspects, once again in the context of its origins:
… all products that are exchanged must be in some way comparable. It is this that has led to
the introduction of money, which serves as a sort of mean, since it is a measure of everything,
and so a measure of the excess and deficiency of value informing us for example how many
shoes are equivalent to … so much food. Apart from this formula there can be no exchange
… and the formula cannot be applied unless the products are somehow equated.
This view of Aristotle explaining money in terms of its origin is persuasively simple.
Aristotle's personal experiences of money were in the form of coins, but he had a
knowledge of money before the invention of coinage from Greek literature and from
information on contemporary trade with tribal areas on the edge of the Greek world
where coins were not yet known. He was aware that the coins he used were a
relatively recent invention. He would have learnt from the 5th century BC historian
Herodotus how trade without money was still carried out beyond the Greek world.
Herodotus himself would have learnt about it from the people who conducted it,
The Carthaginians also tell us that they trade with a race of men who live in a part of
Libya beyond the Pillars of Heracles [i.e. West Africa]. On reaching this country, they
unload their goods, arrange them tidily along the beach and then, returning to their boats,
raise a smoke. Seeing the smoke, the natives come down to the beach, place on the ground a
certain quantity of gold in exchange for the goods, and go off again to a distance. The
Carthaginians then come ashore and take a look at the gold; and if they think it represents a
fair price for their wares, they collect it and go away; if, on the other hand, it seems too little
they go back aboard and wait, and the natives come and add to the gold until they are
satisfied.
(Histories VI 196)
Aristotle also knew from the poet Homer that the Greeks of an earlier age were
unfamiliar with coins, but traded among themselves by exchanging gifts, the value
of which they estimated in terms of cattle. He was able to quote from Homer's Iliad
the story of an exchange of armour between the Lycian prince Glaucus and
Diomedes king of Argos, in which Glaucus got a bad deal,
Gold arms for bronze, a hundred oxen's price for price of nine
(Ethics V 9, Iliad VI 234-6)
Unfortunately, Aristotle's sources of information on the subject were very limited
and he interpreted the little that he knew in the light of his own theory that money's
primary function was in trade. His explanation of how money was discovered is
therefore predictably narrow.
Today a better informed view of money before coinage than Aristotle's can be
formed. The information now available not only from modern scholarship, but also
from our own diverse experiences, is very much more than what was accessible in
Greece in the fourth century BC. We can now call upon the written records of the
ancient civilisations of Mesopotamia, Mycenaean Greece and China as well as the
oral traditions of biblical Palestine, Homeric Greece and Vedic India. Access to the
detailed accounts of the economies of tribal societies reported by travellers and by
ethnographers has also broadened our insight of what money might have been like
before the dawn of civilisation. Archaeologists and collectors have also enlarged this
understanding by making available the objects described as money in both ancient
and tribal societies.
The most ancient objects which can now be identified as money are from
archaeological excavations in the area of Iraq known as Mesopotamia which
straddles the rivers Tigris and Euphrates. From the ruins of the ancient cities of
Mesopotamia archaeologists have recovered both written documents describing
monetary payments and examples of the objects with which those payments were
made. These objects are pieces of silver in the form of rings, ingots and scraps. The
documents used to identify them as money are contracts, business accounts and legal
codes written cuneiform characters on baked clay tablets or stone monuments.
Money is one of the first details of every day life to be mentioned once man had
discovered the ability to describe his action in writing. By the mid third millennium
B.C. (i.e. about four and a half thousand years ago) the inhabitants of ancient
Mesopotamia were recording in writing details of monetary payments. Typical
examples of documents describing money in use at this time have been discovered in
the temple archives of the ancient Mesopotamian city of Lagash, where clay tablets
inscribed in cuneiform list the charges made to inhabitants of the city for the lease of
temple land for agricultural use. Among the surviving tablets is the record made of
the details of a lease agreement made in the twenty fourth century BC in the reign of
Urukagina, king of Lagash. The lease gave the tenant farmer of one particular
parcel of land the use of it to grow barley and to graze his goats on condition that he
made three separate payments to the temple treasury:
1 a number of basketfuls of barley, representing a proportion of the grain harvested
from the land, to be paid as rent;
2 a weighed amount of silver to pay for his right to graze goats on the land;
3 a specified number of goats paid to cover the costs the temple had incurred in
irrigating the land.
Such documents clearly recorded the making of payments in a context where we
would now expect to use money. Rent, pasturage fees and local authority rates would
all today be paid with money in pounds either in the form of bank notes or through a
bank account. Should the barley, silver and goats paid for them in Ancient
Mesopotamia also be considered in the same light? Could it be said that these
objects were selected for making payments because the Mesopotamians had
conventions which guaranteed their value and their reuse in other payments, i.e.
because they used them as money?
The temple accepted payments in barley because it was the staple food of the region.
The employees of the temple were fed with the barley gathered from the land it
owned either directly from land farmed by those employees or indirectly from rent
paid, as in this instance, by its tenants. The temple was also obliged to hold a store of
grain as a precaution against times of bad harvests and famines. The goats were
received in the same way, for use both as food and as other animal products such as
hides. The silver, however, was acceptable to the temple for quite different reasons.
It appears that the temple was willing to receive payments of silver because it could
use it to make other payments itself. Documents of the same period as the land lease
records have survived which report silver being paid out by temple employees
during the reign of Urukagina king of Lagash. These documents also tell how
Urukagina laid down two aspects of the convention within which these payments
were made. He indicated that certain obligations of the temple officials, such as the
compulsory purchase of houses and animals, had to be settled by payments of silver,
and he also fixed the official weight standard by which it was to be measured in all
payments. (The official weights of ancient Mesopotamia were as follows:
The mina (about half a kilo) which was divided into 60 shekels;
each shekel (about 8.3 grams) was divided into 180 grains;
each grain (about 0.046 grams) represented the average weight of a grain of barley.)
These texts describing Urukagina's actions imply that he set up the regulations to
safeguard the common people who were involved in these transactions.
The situation described in these records of ancient Lagash fit precisely a definition
of money which describes its role today:
Money is any object (or record of that object) which is regularly used to make payments
according to a law (or convention) which guarantees its value and ensures its acceptability
(J. Cribb Money from Cowrie Shells to Credit Cards, London, 1986, p. 12).
One of the payments made according to the terms of the lease was made using an
object, i.e. silver, within a law, i.e. the regulations set up by Urukagina, which not
only ensured the circumstances of its acceptability, but also guaranteed its value in
future regular use in payments.
As some of the lease documents in the Lagash archive were drawn up before the
reign of Urukagina, it is evident that money was not brought into being as a
consequence of the regulations he laid down. It can be assumed that money only
came into being in the circumstances the cuneiform documents describe because in
ancient Mesopotamian society at that time it was expected that certain things would
be paid for.
In the four centuries from the time of Urukagina down to the end of the 3rd
millennium BC there is much evidence of payments of many kinds being made with
money in the cities of Mesopotamia. The fullest record is of the kingdom of Ur
during its 3rd dynasty. In excavation at Ur and Nippur clay tablets have been
discovered containing about 20 laws from a legal code drawn up by the founder of
this dynasty king Ur-Nammu (c. 2112-2095 B.C.). The code shows how he fixed
the standard weight for silver and the standard measure for barley:
Then did Ur-Nammu, the mighty warrior, King of Ur, King of Sumer and Akkad …
establish equity in the land … He fashioned the bronze sila measure [a capacity measure
for barley], He standardised the one mina weight and standardised the stone weight of a
shekel of silver in relation to the one mina...
It also shows how he set the amounts due in certain payments,
as compensation:
law 5. If a man proceeded by force and deflowered the virgin slave woman of another man,
that man must pay five shekels of silver.
law 17. If someone severed the nose of another man with a copper knife he must pay two
thirds of a mina of silver.
as a fine:
law 25. If a man appeared as a witness in a lawsuit and was shown to be perjured he must
pay 15 shekels.
as a reward:
law 8. If a slave woman . . . crossed beyond the territory of the city and another man
brought her back, the owner of the slave shall pay to the one who brought her back two
shekels of silver.
Although the payments described in Ur-Nammu's code mostly represent, as one
would expect, legal payments, there are other clay tablets surviving from the same
period which describe commercial, social and fiscal payments. The most revealing of
these are 21st century B.C. documents from Ur containing the balanced accounts of
merchants who were using silver and barley to pay for a wide variety of wares,
mostly food, but also cloth, metals and luxury goods. Each item in the accounts was
given a price in silver by weight, even though payments were not necessarily made
with it.
It is clear, therefore, from the written records of Ur in the late 3rd millennium B.C.
that silver was in use as money. It could be paid and received in the knowledge that
it could be reused to make further payments. Royal edicts also ensured its value by
fixing the means of measuring it.
From another legal code written at the end of the 3rd millennium B.C. by a king of
the Northern city of Eshnunna the extent can be seen to which the use of silver as
money had developed. The Eshnunnan code is more complete than Ur-Nammu's
and among its 59 surviving laws the whole range of payments in silver can be seen.
Law 1 of the code is an official price list giving the silver value of nine commodities.
1 kor of barley
3 qa of best oil
1 seah 2 qa of sesame oil
1 seah 5 qa of lard
4 seah of river oil
6 mina of wool
2 kor of salt
3 mina of copper
2 mina of refined copper
}
}
}
}
} each priced at
} 1 shekel of silver
}
}
}
Other laws described payments like those in Ur-Nammu's code.
For example:
law 42: If a man bites the nose of another man and severs it, he shall pay 1 mina of silver,
for an eye he shall pay 1 mina of silver; for a tooth a 1/2 mina; for an ear a 1/2 mina; and
for a slap in the face 10 shekels of silver.
The Eshnunna code also includes silver being paid which cannot nowadays be
thought of as other than money. Law 21 describes a loan with interest
If a man gives silver as a loan at face value he shall receive the silver and its interest, one
sixth of shekel and 6 grains per shekel.
and law 7 the payment of wages:
The wages of a harvester are 2 seah of barley; if they are paid in silver, his wages are 12
grains.
Apart from telling us that the price of noses had risen by a 1/3 mina since the time of
Ur-Nammu, the Eshnunna code provides a very significant clue as to how money
developed in Ancient Mesopotamia.
The last law of the code quoted above describes wages as being paid in silver instead
of grain. The use of grain to make payments was not unusual in Ancient
Mesapotamia. An example in the code of Ur-Nammu, shows it being paid as
compensation:
Law 28: If a man flooded the field of another man with water, he shall measure out for him
3 kor of barley per iku [c. 0.33 hectare] of land.
and the earliest document quoted above, a land lease agreement from the time of
Urukagina, records it being paid as rent.
Grain was used to make such payments because they all involved either land or
labour and therefore either the production or the consumption of grain. It was
simple to measure the amount of grain to be paid for the use of a piece of land, or to
compensate for its damage, by making the payment a proportion of the potential
harvest yielded by the land. A man's labour could also be priced in grain by the
amount he and his dependents would consume during the period of work done. The
quantity and value of the grain to be paid could be precisely reckoned because
official measurements of grain were laid down by Royal edicts such as the Code of
Ur-Nammu shows.
Does this evidence suggest that grain was also used as money? Where the
consumption of the grain paid followed immediately after its receipt, the transaction
has to be described as a payment in kind. It can be certain that this normally
happened, as barley was the staple food of Mesopotamia. However, some
documents suggest that once paid it could be reused in further payments.
After it had been laid down the silver price of commodities the Code of Eshnunna,
quoted above, added the prices of three of these commodities in terms of barley:
Law 2: 1 qa of sesame oil, its value in barley is 3 seah.
1 qa of lard, its value in barley is 2 seah 5 qa.
1 qa of river oil, its value in barley is 8 qa.
The same code also describes the payment of barley for the return of a loan and its
interest substituting it for the silver in terms of which the loan was negotiated.
law 20: If a man gives a loan expressing the value of the silver loaned in barley, he shall at
harvest time receive the barley and its interest 1 massiktum 4 seah per kor.
The use of grain in these contexts and in those mentioned before show grain being
used as money within the terms of the definition used above. When used in
payments both social custom and Royal edict provided grain with a convention
within which it could be paid out again at a value determined by official measures of
volume. In those circumstances it was used in exactly the same manner as silver and
the two were often interchangeable as the means of payment, except that silver prices
were assessed by weight and grain by volume.
Grain's role as money was nevertheless more restricted than that of silver. It was not
so easily used for payments outside the context of land and labour. In the price lists
of the code of Eshunna grain is only used to set the value of foodstuff, whereas silver
is also used to rate wool, salt, and copper. It only substitutes for silver in
circumstances where it would normally be expected, i.e. in payments related to the
production or consumption of food.
In every context the use of grain as money can be explained as a natural expansion of
its role in Mesopotamian society as the most important food stuff. Grain was suited
to use as money because it was the natural means of assessing the level of payments
in these contexts and because the importance of its role as food ensured its
acceptability. It is not difficult to see that once Mesopotamian society had developed
a broad enough range of situations in which a payment was necessary, the object
most widely used to settle such payments was in a position to develop into a form of
money.
The development of silver into money in Mesopotamia cannot be explained in the
same way. It was not a necessity of life and payments relating to its production or
consumption rarely arose. Even so by the end of the 3rd millennium B.C. its use as
money was broader in range than that of grain even to the extent that payments
naturally made in grain could also now be made in silver. An insight into how silver
came to be used as money can only be gained by looking at the type of payments in
which it was used. The small selection from the vast array of contemporary records
of daily life in Ancient Mesopotamia made above show silver being used in many
circumstances with examples of it being paid as compensation, rewards, fines, loans,
rent, wages, and for the purchase of goods.
Starting from use in the payment of compensation an explanation emerges of how
silver came to have such a general use as a means of payment.
In many non-urban societies it was normal for a person who has caused someone
else damage to compensate that person by having the same damage inflicted upon
themselves. The biblical "an eye for an eye, a tooth for a tooth" (Exodus, 21, 24) is a
clear example of this. The Ancient Mesopotamians were aware of this principle and
in an exact parallel can be seen in the later Code of Hammurabi king of Babylon (c.
1782-1686 B.C.):
Law 196: If a man has destroyed the eye of a member of the aristocracy, they shall destroy
his eye.
This sort of natural justice could be applied in most situations where one person had
an obligation to another. Some of the payments of grain described above can be
explained in such a way. Grain was paid as compensation for the damage of land,
according to law 28 of Ur Namma's Code because the injury suffered by the land
owner was the loss of the grain he would have derived from it if it had not been
damaged.
The introduction of silver as a means of compensating personal cases of injury can
be explained as a humane alternative to exacting payment in kind. It must also have
been a more practical solution, as the injured party received his compensation in a
form which was of more long term benefit to him than the sense of justice which was
all he could have got out of inflicting a similar injury. This was particularly so when
it was his property and not his person that was damaged. There were also
circumstances in which the injury committed could not be done in return, such as
rape or divorce. Both of these offences demanded retribution, but no obvious
remedy emerges in either case. The Mesopotamians' solution of using silver greatly
simplified such problems. By fixing in their codes of law the rates at which injuries
could be settled, the rulers of Mesopotamia not only established (in the words of Ur
Nammu's code) "equity in the land", but also provided the simplest possible means
of maintaining it.
There were various factors which influenced the choice of silver as the means by
which payments of not only compensation, but any other obligation, could be settled.
The choice had to be of something which was suited by its availability, and its
acceptability to function in this way. If payments were to be made in a particular
commodity there needed to be enough of it to serve the needs of all the situations
where its payment was called for. It also had to be something which the recipients of
the payment would have no hesitation in accepting. Silver was precisely the one
commodity that fitted such criteria. Silver is not naturally found in quantity in
Mesopotamia from earliest times. It was a major import into the area. Together with
its natural attributes of beauty and durability, the fact that sources of this metal were
limited gave the inhabitants of Mesopotamia a desire to acquire it to adorn their
temples, for use as jewellery and as a symbol. This desire led them to import more
and more silver into the area, paying for it with the excess natural wealth of
Mesopotamia, in particular from its production of food and textiles. Its high value
also ensured that only relatively small amounts of the stock of silver were needed to
settle any particular obligation. These factors ensured that there was enough of this
metal in the Mesopotamian economy for it to fulfill its acquired role as money.
Another factor was the ease with which the quantity of silver to be paid could be
precisely measured. The Mesopotamians had discovered the use of balances to
assess the weight of objects. The weights which had been officially standardised by
Urukagina, Ur Nammu and other Mesopotamian rulers, were made to sit on the
pan on one side of a balance to estimate the quantity of silver placed in the other pan.
Official inscribed weights from before the time of Urukagina have survived. By the
use of these weights and balances amounts of silver were measured out from the
mina (about 0.5 kilogram) to pay for a nose down to the twelve grains (about 0.5
gram) for a day's work. The mina consisted of 60 shekels and each shekel (about 8.1
gram) of 180 grains.
The texts describing payments do not tell us much about the actual appearance of
the silver being used. The silver is normally described as being weighed out to make
the payment and the amount weighed is specified. Occasionally the silver being paid
is referred to as "sibirtum" measuring cut up or broken. One can presume that it was
a convenient way to measure out a particular weight of silver by adjusting the
amount in the balance by adding or subtracting small bits of silver. This implies that
some of the silver used must have originally been in larger pieces so that it could be
cut up into smaller bits.
To discover what these fragments of silver, and the larger pieces from which they
were cut, looked like it is possible to examine a hoard of silver found by American
archaeologists at the site (near Baghdad in modern Iraq) of Eshnunna (the city from
which the legal code discussed above came). This hoard was found in the remains of
a domestic building of about the same period as the code. It contained a large slab
shaped ingot of silver, some bent wire and various scraps cut from ingots or wire,
also from broken vessels or jewellery. It is impossible to say for certain that this
hoard of silver was money, as one could imagine several other reasons why its owner
gathered together these bits of silver. He might have been a silversmith preparing to
make them back into jewellery or vessels or a thief who had just stolen them from
the silversmith. Nevertheless the contemporary documents do show that the objects
in this hoard could also have been used as money. The use of scraps has been
explained above, what they were derived from was of little importance to the user.
Ingots would have been used as this is the form into which silver is normally
processed when it has first been refined. The use of wire, however, suggests
something more purposeful.
Two of these pieces of wire in the hoard are ring shaped and in excavations on
ancient Mesopotamian sites a large number of rings like these have been found
sometimes in hoards. It has been suggested that these coiled rings of silver wire were
made specifically for use as money. There are many cuneiform documents which
talk about rings like these being manufactured to weigh so many shekels each and a
mathematical text discusses the means of calculating fractions in terms of cutting
pieces off rings of silver. In some records of payments on cuneiform tablets from the
early second millennium BC the silver used is specified as “ring silver”. It is clear
that they do offer a very satisfactory means of using silver as money and as we shall
see many other cultures have in fact used metal rings in that way. Their usefulness
as money is manifold:- it is reasonably effortless to break a piece off a ring of wire
simply by bending it repeatedly or to cut it off by hitting it with a sharp blade, and if
the wire is of a known weight and of even thickness it is equally easy to calculate
where to break it in order to obtain a required fraction of it. Moreover because the
coiled wire can be threaded onto a string or linked together with other rings to make
a chain, it is by far the most convenient way of carrying the metal around. The fact
that many of the plain wire were metal rings found in Mesopotamia show signs of
having had an end cut off again points to their use as money.
By the early 2nd millennium B.C. money was such an integral part of
Mesopotamian society that the temple treasures had developed into bank like
institutions. An eighteenth century B.C. cuneiform tablet documenting a loan from
the temple of the sun god Shamash in the city of Sippar illustrates how like modern
banks they had become.
5 shekels of pure silver, at the Shamash rate, Idin Rammay, son of Shamash-Mutabli, and
his wife Huntani have borrowed from the god Shamash and from Idin-Jatum. When they
see the notice on the wall (of the city?) they shall weigh out the silver and its interest to the
bearer of this document. (Signed by) 3 witnesses. Date: the month of Elul (mid summer)
35th year of the King's (Hammurabi) rule (i.e. about 1758 B.C.).
This loan agreement not only points to the temple treasury investing its capital in
order to earn interest, but also suggests that the loan could be transferred to
elsewhere to be collected, as it is payable on demand not to the temple, but to the
current owner, i.e. bearer of the document.
The opening phrase "5 shekels . . . at the Shamash rate" also indicates that the
temple controlled the use of money to the extent of providing its own standard
weights for the measurement of the silver loaned. All this suggests a very
sophisticated appreciation of the intricacies of banking practice on the part of the
temple and its officials.
It is not difficult for us now to recognise from this and the other cuneiform
documents quoted above the degree to which the Mesopotamians had developed the
concept of money and its uses by the early 2nd millennium B.C. The extent of their
achievement is confirmed by the readiness of nations coming into contact with them,
such as the Hittites and Assyrians, to adopt these discoveries. A vivid example of
their assimilation by one of the Mesopotamia's neighbours is to be found in the oral
traditions of ancient Palestine, preserved in the Bible.
The familiarity of the stories in the Bible gives us a ready access into how the ancient
peoples of Palestine put into practice the experiences of money they derived from
Mesopotamia. By examining some of the episodes in the Bible a literary dimension
can be added to the legalistic accounts of the use of money documented in
cuneiform on Mesopotamian clay tablets.
When Abraham the father of the Jewish race set out in the second millennium B.C.
from Ur to seek the new home promised him by his god he took along with him the
concepts of money which were then prevalent in his old home. The Bible describes
payments made by him after his arrival in Palestine which precisely fits those
Mesopotamian practices. When Sarah his wife died Abraham set about acquiring
some land in which to bury her. He approached the local people and their leader
Ephron agreed to sell him a piece of land for the purpose.
Abraham rose and bowed to the ground before the people of the land, the sons of Heth, and
spoke to them ‘If you are willing …. Intercede with Ephron Zohar's son to give me the cave
he owns at Machpelah, which is on the edge of his land. Let him make it over to me in your
presence at its full price, for me to own as a burial plot’ ... Ephron the Hittite answered
Abraham in the hearing of the sons of Heth(?) and of all the citizens of the town ‘My Lord
… I give you the land and I give you the cave on it; I make this gift in the sight of the sons
of my people. Bury your dead.’ Abraham ... spoke to Ephron ... ‘I will pay the price of the
land; accept it from me’ ...
Ephron answered Abraham ‘My Lord listen to me. A property worth 400 shekels of silver,
what is a little thing like that between me and you’ ... Abraham agreed to Ephron's terms,
and Abraham weighed out for Ephron the silver he had stipulated, in the hearing of the sons
of Heth, namely 400 shekels of silver, according to the current commercial rate.
(Genesis 17.13)
This passage gives a graphic account of the use of money, made credible by the
detail preserved in its telling. Removed from Ur, Abraham could no longer rely on
the laws of that city to guarantee the receipt of the metal he offers, nor could royal
standard weights be used to fix the price. The conventions now controlling his
payment of silver were no longer legal but were purely those of social custom.
Abraham had to call upon the people present to witness his agreement to make the
payment and Ephron's to accept it, and the weights in every day use in trade were
those which have to be used to set on price. As in Mesopotamia the silver used was
"weighed out". It is significant that the first use of money described in detail in the
Biblical tradition was not this sale but a payment of compensation, like those listed
in the Mesopotamian legal codes, to Abraham by Abimelech, the local king of Gerar
(in southern Palestine). Abimelech deceived into thinking that Sarah was Abraham's
sister and therefore free to marry, had taken her as a wife. He was threatened as a
consequence with divine retribution and to escape it he handed Sarah back to
Abraham saying to her
Look I am giving 1,000 pieces of silver to your brother. For you this will be compensation in
the eyes of all those with you.
(Genesis 20.16)
This passage also reveals another aspect of the customary use of silver as a means of
payment. The words "1,000 pieces of silver" represent a misinterpretation by the
translator, as the original text says "1,000 silver". The ancient Jews were so used to
making payments with silver by weight, that the actual weight unit could be left
understood. The amount paid by Abimlech should therefore be understood as 1,000
shekels of silver. Similarly, the twenty pieces of silver for which Joseph was sold by
his brothers into slavery should in fact be 20 shekels of silver (Genesis 37.28).
By the time of the Exodus (the late second millennium B.C.) the Jews can be seen
from Biblical tradition to have developed the use of silver and money in much the
same way as their neighbours in Mesopotamia. The details of the laws by which the
Jews lived contain examples of legal compensation virtually identical to those in the
Code of Ur Nammu and Eshnunna.
If a man meets a virgin, who is not betrothed, and seizes her and lies with her and is caught
in the act the man who has lain with her must give the girl's father 50 shekels.
(Deuteronomy 22.28-29)
If the ox gores a slave, male or female, the owner must pay over to their master a sum of
money -30 shekels and the ox must be stoned.
(Exodus 21,32)
The laws also insisted on the use of fair standards for the weighing of the silver used
in payments.
Your measures - length, weight and capacity - must all be just, your scales and weights must
be just
(Leviticus 19.35)
and warned against breaches of the convention:
You are not to keep two different weights in your bag, one heavy, one light . . . you must keep
the weights full and accurate. For anyone who does things of this kind and acts dishonestly is
detestable to Yahweh our God.
(Deuteronomy 25.13)
At a later date (8th century B.C.) Yahweh himself added his own voice, via the
prophet Micah, to uphold the conventions within which money was used.
Must I hold the man honest who measures with false scales and a bag of faked weights
(Micah 6.11)
To guard against such malpractice the Temple set its own weight standards and
13th century legal texts contained in the Bible stipulated that the Temple standard
alone should be used in monetary transactions
All valuations must be made in sanctuary shekels.
(Leviticus 27.25)
Evidence in the Bible about the form in which silver was used is very meagre, but
gives concrete evidence of the payment of both scrap silver and gold rings. Influence
from Mesopotamia suggests that the same scraps, ingots and rings were in use and a
hoard found in Northern Palestine at the ancient site of Megiddo confirms it. This
hoard is datable on archaeological grounds to the same period as the laws quoted
above. It contains a large quantity of scraps, cut from vessels, jewellery, ingots and
wire rings. Some biblical references to the use of silver as money of a slightly later
date can also be interpreted to correspond with the use of scraps like these. The
Hebrew word agorot translated as piece in the following 11th century B.C. text
implies a twentieth part of a shekel.
And all that survive of your house will come and beg him on their knees for a silver piece or
a loaf of bread.
(I Samuel 2.36)
The implication here is that the silver being sought is a tiny amount, of a value
comparable to a loaf. Another text of the same period talks of a similar, but slightly
larger piece of silver
And the servant answered Saul. 'Look' he said 'I have a quarter of a shekel here; I will give
it to the man of God and he shall tell us our road'
(I Samuel 9.8)
The wide use of silver in this form is further illustrated by a 9th century B.C.
account of the Temple's income and expenditure which describes the acceptance of
small pieces of silver as offerings from the faithful.
Jehoiada the priest procured a chest, bored a hole in the lid of it, and placed it beside the
pillar, to the right as you enter the Temple of Jahweh; in it the priests who guarded the
threshold put all the money that was given to the Temple of Yahweh. Whenever they saw
there was a lot of money in the chest, the king's secretary would come and they would melt
down and reckon the money there in the Temple of Yahweh.
(2 Kings 12 5-16)
In only two instances does the Bible mention precious metal rings specifically as
being given in payment, and they are rings of gold not silver. At the end of the story
of Job his relations and friends restore to him his wealth each giving him a piece of
silver and a gold ring. There is no mention of the value of the rings here, but in the
other reference to rings their weight is specified. This is in Genesis where the story
is told of Abraham's sending out his servant to look for a suitable wife for his son
Isaac. When the servant found Rebekah he bestowed on her gifts from Abraham
The man took a gold ring weighing half a shekel, and put it through her nostrils, and put on
her arms two bracelets weighing ten gold shekels …"
(Genesis 24.22)
However without further details it is difficult to conclude that in either of these
payments were the rings paid as money, even though in the second case the value of
the rings is indicated.
There is, however, much more concrete evidence from the neighbouring land of
Egypt that precious metal rings were used as money in the ancient Middle East.
Most of this evidence comes from Ancient Egyptian monumental inscriptions of the
period of Pharaoh Thutmosis III
(1504-1450 B.C.) of the Eighteenth Dynasty. The official chronicle of the reign of
this Pharaoh, inscribed in hieroglyphics on the temple of Amon at Karnak, describes
the capture of a huge treasure of gold and silver from cities to the north of Palestine.
List of that which was afterwards taken by the king, of the household goods of that foe who
was in Yenoan, Nug and Herenkeru [in modern Lebanon] … Besides flat dishes of
costly stone and gold … amounting to 784 deben. Gold in rings, found in the hands of the
artificers, and silver in many rings, 966 deben and 1 kidet.
The deben and kidet mentioned in this text are measurements of weight. The deben
is generally thought to weigh about 95 grams and the kidet (kite) is its tenth
weighing about 9.5 grams. The word deben is written with a hieroglyph in the form
of a coiled ring, possibly to indicate that this unit was used to weigh metal in that
form. Another monument of the period of Thutmosis III provides illustrations of
both the payment and the weighing of rings of gold and silver in ancient Egypt.
The walls of the tomb of Reck-mi-re Vizier of the Pharaoh Thutmosis III are
adorned with a written and pictorial record of his duties as a principle officer of the
state. Reck-mi-re is shown there conducting the affairs of state accepting tribute
from the foreign vassals and taxes from the subjects of the Pharaoh. Missions from
Syria, Crete and from Libya are pictured in procession bringing offerings of native
produce to the Pharaoh including precious metals, both gold and silver in rings and
bars as well as ingots of copper. Another procession is depicted showing local
officials and their attendants bringing tax payments to the Vizier. The inscriptions
record the title of the official responsible for paying in tax and the amounts due.
The Mayor of Nekken 4 deben of gold
3 deben of silver
1 ox
1 two year old (cow)
The Rural Councillor of Nekken 3 deben of gold
1 gold necklace
2 oxen
4 chest of mt linen
1 chest of d'w linen
The town ruler of Esneh 12 deben of gold
8 deben of silver
2 oxen
3 chests of cloth
grain
gum
matting
The paintings show the described items being delivered. The precious metals are
painted in the form of rings. The numbers of rings shown does not correspond with
the number of debens, nor does the colour always match that of the metal described.
The town ruler of Esneh's contribution is pictured as 5 gold rings and 3 silver, that
of the Rural Counsellor of Nekken as 3 gold rings and of its Mayor as 6 gold rings.
The painting also shows the Vizier supervising the receipt of these payments into the
treasury where the gold and silver rings are shown being weighed on a balance. The
text of the inscriptions refers to the gold and silver being measured according to "the
tribute weight" suggesting that, as in Mesopotamia and Palestine, the state dictated
a particular weight standard to be used in the measurement of metal for payment.
The metals paid here have all the attributes of money except that it is not clear
whether they were to be used in future payments. The only use of the metal shown
in the tomb is for the manufacture of vessels. However, from the tomb of another
servant of Thutmosis III there is a glimpse of the way in which the Pharoah might
have paid out the previous metal once again. On the walls of the tomb of Thutmosis
III's general Amenemhab it is recorded that
I fought hand to hand before the king (in the battle of Senzas). He gave me the gold of
honour; list thereof ... 2 silver rings ... (and after the capture of Kadess) He gave me gold,
because of bravery, before the whole people ... of the finest gold a lion, 2 necklaces, 2 flies (?)
4 arm rings.
A hoard of gold and silver buried in Egypt at this period survives as an illustration
of the sort of gold and silver objects with which payments could be made. The hoard
was found by archaeologists in a pot on the site of the ancient city founded by the
Pharaoh Akenaten (c. 1370-1360 B.C.). Because of this a precise date for the hoard
can be fixed at this city was abandoned shortly after this Pharaoh's death. Its
contents were remarkably like those of the hoards of silver from Mesopotamia and
Palestine described above, except that it contains gold as well as silver. The gold in
the pot was in the form of bar shaped ingots. Several of the ingots were complete but
many were cut fragments from larger ingots. The ingots were not cast to an accurate
weight standard, but all the more complete ones seem to weigh about 3 deben, as six
of them are concentrated around that weight (c. 280 grams, within a range 265-286
grams). Two of the fragments are rough halves of this, i.e. 1 deben 5 kite (c. 140
gr.) and six are approximate thirds, i.e. 1 deben (c. 95 gr.). The original bars and
the cut-up fractions are not very precise in their weights, but they seem to have been
intended to represent given amounts of metal.
Some of the silver is in the form of ingots like the gold weighing approximately 3
and 5 deben or their fractions and some consist of scraps of broken vessels and
jewellery, but the rest is in the shape of wire rings about 40 in number. A few of the
rings seem, from ornamentation on them, to be pieces of jewellery, but the majority
are the same coil-shaped pieces of thick plain wire seen in the hoards from
Mesopotamia and Palestine. Most of the rings have had their ends cut off, but
several still represent approximate weights - 5 kite, 3 1/2 kite, 3 kite, 1 kite, 1/2 kite,
etc.
From this hoard and from the texts and wall paintings mentioned above, it is
therefore clear that in the 18th dynasty the ancient Egyptians had all that was
necessary to run a monetary system like that of Ancient Mesopotamia or Biblical
Palestine. The limited nature of documents of the 18th dynasty period restricts our
present day view of the extent to which the metals were then paid as money.
Information from the 19th and 20th dynasties fills that gap and shows clearly the
range and the nature of the every day use of weighed amounts of metal as a means of
making payments.
A papyrus document (the Papyrus Harris) of this period has preserved the official
report of offerings made by the 20th Dynasty Pharaoh Ramases III (about 11981166 B.C.) to Amun, Ptah and the other gods of the Egyptian pantheon. It records
that the gold, silver and copper paid over to the temple of each god by the pharaoh,
stating the amount of each metal by weight in deben and the form in which it was
given, as either vessels, rings or scraps.
But even more significant is a papyrus in the British Museum, datable to the 20th
Dynasty, containing several references to the payment of silver and gold which can
only be described as monetary payments in terms of the definition described above.
This papyrus is a lengthy account of the court proceedings in two cases of tomb
robbery. The defendants in both cases were accused of removing gold, silver and
other precious materials from ancient tombs. Part of the
cross-examination of the witnesses was to prove that they had recently been
overspending and therefore must have been in possession of amounts of gold and
silver beyond normal expectations. One witness Irinufer, the wife of Peinehesi one
of the robbers, is questioned about the purchase of a slave with some of the silver
from the tomb.
They said to her ‘What have you to say about this silver which your husband Peinehesi
brought away (from the great tombs).’ She said ‘I did not see it’. The Vizier said to her
‘How did you buy the servants along with him?’ She said ‘I did not see any silver: he bought
them when he was about that business on which he was engaged’.
The court said to her, ‘What is this story of the silver which Peinehesi worked for
Sebkemsaf?’ She said ‘I got it in exchange for barley in the year of the hyenas when there
was a famine’
(11.5-8)
In spite of her denials it is clear that the court thought it normal that she and her
husband should have paid out the stolen silver to buy the slave they have recently
required. They are also suspected of having passed on another amount of silver. Her
claim that she had obtained that silver by selling barley for it also indicates that such
practice was normal.
Elsewhere in this papyrus there is further evidence that such payments were
considered routine. Another defendant was accused of using silver to buy a slave and
the slave was called as witness and testifies "he gave 2 deben of silver for one".
Bukhaaf the ring leader of one gang of robbers admitted to his crime and lists how
he disposed of the loot:
The whereabouts of the herdsman Bukhaaf's share of the silver:
(to) The overseer of the field of the temple of Amun Akhenmenu: 1 deben of silver and 5 kite
of gold in exchange for land.
(to) The scribe Amenhotpe called Seret of the temple of Amun: 2 deben in exchange for land,
for 40 deben of copper and for 10 khar of barley.
(to) The servant Shedbeg in payment for the slave Begay: 2 deben of silver and 60 deben of
copper and 30 khar of spelt [i.e. grain] which I had procured in exchange for silver …"
Another witness describes the spending of some of the silver on what sounds like a
party to celebrate the success of the robbery
He said the thief, the young slave Amenkhan, son of Mutemhab, gave 5 kite of silver to
Oshefitemwes the scribe of the steward of Amun in exchange for a [illegible word for
amount] of wine: we took it to the house of the overseer of peasants and we put two hin of
honey to it and we drank it.
According to another witness the honey was also bought with the stolen silver.
The thief Amenkhan gave 1 deben 5 kite of silver to the incense roaster Penementenakht in
exchange for 1 mezekt of honey.
This by no means exhausts the incidents of payments made with silver and gold in
the text.
From this document a general impression emerges that, although the amount of
silver and gold being spent drew attention to the robbers, there was no question of
the court thinking it unusual that metal was used in payments or that it should be
measured in those payments by its weight. The silver and gold used in the
circumstances described here can, therefore, be described as money. The range and
nature of payments both in this papyrus and in the monumental inscriptions
discussed above show that the Ancient Egyptians had developed the conventions
necessary for creating money and were capable of using them.
From other records dated to the early 19th Dynasty it can be seen that the official
used silver and gold for payments strengthened the conventions which gave rise to
money. A monument of this period of the Pharaoh Seti I records the use of precious
metal to pay for the costs of work at a stone quarry at Silsileh:
The overseer Thutmosis ... gave silver and gold ... to prosecute his work ... to cut out very
much stone.
Inspite of their knowledge of money as shown in records, the Ancient Egyptians
encountered a major problem in its practical application. This was a general shortage
of the commodities chosen to be used as money. Egypt had few natural sources of
gold, silver or copper, and most of those metals had to be imported. What little there
was tended to be drawn into the official treasury, as the tomb paintings of Rekhmire
so clearly show. Once in the hands of the Pharaoh and his officials it was mostly
used to make jewellery, vessels, etc., to enrich their gods, their court, and
particularly their tombs. Gold and silver in the hands of the common people, was
unusual and as in the case of the tomb robbers, was immediately noticed. Records of
the 19-20th Dynasties (c. 1320-1085 B.C.) survive which show us how the common
people coped with this situation. Money was used by them, but only as an idea.
Most payments made among the populace were in kind. They were paid their wages
from the state in the form of their staple diet, grain -emmer a form of wheat to make
bread and barley to make beer, and occasionally they would receive luxury goods as
rewards for outstanding service. In order to acquire anything else they either had to
produce it on small holdings or obtain it through trade. Trade was conducted by
barter, but their knowledge of money gave the barter a curious aspect. The value of
the goods being bartered would be estimated in terms of money. The word they
used for "money" was silver, but the valuation could be made in terms of gold, silver
or copper by weight or even in terms of grain by volume.
Year 5 third month of the summer season day 20.
Given to Hay by the chief policeman Nebsman.
1 head of cattle makes 120 deben (of copper)
Given to Nebsmen
2 pots of fat makes 60 deben
5 shirts of smooth fabric - makes 25 deben
1 dress of Upper Egypt cloth makes 20 deben
1 hide -
makes 15 deben
[total 120 deben]
A large number of documents like this one survive from this period of the 19th and
20th Dynasties, mostly found in excavations of the homes of the workers on the
Royal tombs in the Valley of the Kings at Der el Medina. They record a variety of
exchanges, mostly like the one quoted, but some referring more explicitly to the
valuations as monetary. The goods being exchanged would be described as the “list
of the money which the buyer gave” or “the total money which the buyer gave” The
word for money was silver, even when the values were expressed in copper, as in the
following document which described the repayment of a loan:
Amount of money [literally silver] of the workman, Penné which is with Shedemdei 76
deben of copper.
(There has already) come to him (i.e. Penné) 54 deben.
His remainder (still) to be given to him 22 in order to complete the amount of money
[silver] of Shedemdei. She has brought to Penné in money [silver] 54 deben of copper. Her
remainder to complete is 22.
Although the document implies that it was copper being loaned and repaid, it is
equally likely that consumable goods of one kind were loaned and of another kind
paid back.
The picture of daily life in Der el Medina created by these documents suggests that
virtually all payments were made in kind. The workers receive their wages in the
form of food and all purchases were made by barter. Occasionally the goods
bartered were copper scraps, valued by their weight, but they ranked in the
exchanges alongside the other goods being traded. The documents were merely a
formalised record of payments in kind. Money was known to the common people
but not needed in their everyday exchanges. They did however have a need to
record, perhaps for legal purposes, the details of the exchanges. The scribes who
recorded the payments needing to define them precisely, gave the value of the goods
paid an officially recognised status, so that future disputes could be resolved fairly.
The records of an ancient court case, surviving on a papyrus in the Cairo Museum,
show why such valuations were necessary. In a dispute over the ownership of goods
used to make the purchase of a Syrian girl slave from a merchant, the defendant,
Irinofret, a townswoman, was able to describe in detail how she bought the girl and
give a precise account of what she gave.
The merchant Reia approached me with the Syrian slave Gemnihiamente, he said to me:
‘Bring this girl and give me a price for her.’ And I purchased the girl and gave him a price
for her. I will now state in front of the authorities the price I gave for her:
1 shroud of Upper Egyptian cloth makes 5 kite of silver
1 blanket of Upper Egyptian cloth makes 3 1/3 kite of silver
1 garment of Upper Egyptian cloth makes 4 kite of silver
3 garments of fine Upper Egyptian cloth makes 5 kite of silver
Bought from the woman Kafy:
1 vessel of bronze, makes [i.e. weighing] 18 deben makes [i.e. valued at] 1 2/3
kite of silver.
Bought from the head of the storehouse Pyiay:
1 vessel of bronze, makes 14 deben makes 1 1/2 kite of silver.
Bought from the priest Huy-Pinhas:
10 deben of beaten copper(?) makes 1 kite of silver.
Bought from the priest Aniy:
1 vessel of bronze, makes 16 deben makes 1 1/2 kite of silver
1 vessel of honey, makes [i.e. holding] 1 kekat makes 5 kite of silver
Bought from the woman Tjuiay:
1 cauldron of bronze, makes 20 deben makes 2 kite of silver
Bought from the steward of the house of Amun, Teti(?)
1 vessel of bronze, makes 20 deben makes 2 kite of silver
10 shirts of fine Upper Egypt clothmakes 4 kite of silver
Total 4 deben 1 kite of silver consisting of all the things.
And I gave it to the merchant Rua(?) ... he gave me this girl ...
Irinofret was asked to swear an oath that she had not used any property belonging to
a woman called Bekmut to make the purchase.
As Amun endures and the Prince endures, if witnesses establish against me that there was
any property belonging to the woman Bekmut in the silver which I gave for this servant and
I have concealed it I will be liable to 100 strokes after being deprived of her.
The end of the papyrus is missing so we do not know who won the dispute, but a
clear picture does emerge from this text of the way in which the concept of money
was used to describe what was clearly an exchange by barter.
The use of money as an idea in these documents of the second half of the second
millennium B.C. seems to represent a very sophisticated development, however
there is evidence that this practice had already been developed in Egypt a thousand
years before. On a stone monument found near the pyramids at Giza there is an
inscription which appears to be the earliest record of a monetary transaction from
Egypt. It is an agreement made before witnesses of the sale of a house.
… I have purchased this building by exchange with the scribe Tenti
and I gave for it
10 "pieces":an item of furniture made of ani wood 3 "pieces"
a bed made of first quality cedar 4 "pieces"
an item of furniture made of sycamore wood - 3 "pieces" …
… Sealed with the seal before the tribunal of the town of Khouit Khoufou and in the
presence of witnesses of the tribe of Kemaponat of Tenti ...
The word "piece" in this text seems to be an early version of the word sniw found in
later texts meaning a measurement of metal by weight equal to 1/12 deben.
The close similarity between the hieroglyph used to write this word and that used for
an Egyptian word for cake suggests that this amount of silver or gold was usually
thought of as a cake-shaped ingot, in the same way that the coiled ring shaped
hieroglyph used in writing the word deben is a pointer to the probability that a
deben of precious metal was normally thought of in the form of a ring.
This inscription therefore, expects its reader to note that the goods offered for
exchange by both parties to the argument were equal in value. The reader was also
aware that this value could be determined in relation to money which took the form
of silver (or gold) by weight. The presence at the transaction of witnesses indicates
that a socially binding convention existed to guarantee the legality of the exchange.
So, although the sale was not made with actual money, it does provide clear evidence
that the idea of money was already known in Egypt at the time it took place. This
document is not dated, but the style of its writing and language and its discovery in
an Old Kingdom context at Giza has led to it being dated to the period of the Sixth
Dynasty (c. 2345-2180 B.C.) or earlier. If this dating is credible it indicates that,
like their neighbours in Mesopotamia the ancient Egyptians were already making
use of the idea of money in the form of weighed amounts of precious metal by the
second half of the 3rd millennium B.C.
A remarkably full picture of money as it came to be used early in the history of
human society emerges from these early documents of the ancient civilisations of the
Middle East. It does not, however, do more than hint at the stages through which
its development had already gone before these records. The earlier history of money
can only be recreated from later evidence, by examining its role in the many societies
with more primitive cultures and less developed economies, which continued to
flourish alongside these great civilisations, some even surviving into modern times.
Travellers' reports of these societies, together with their own literary traditions,
provide plenty of evidence on which to build a view of money's origins. Some of the
evidence, such as the oral literatures of the Greeks takes the story back into the 2nd
millennium B.C. to a period close in time to the stages of money's development
reflected in the early written documents. Recent evidence, even when it is from
societies still flourishing today, can however, be of equal importance in achieving an
understanding of the early history and origins of money. This is particularly the case
when it has been collected by scholars who have a special interest in the study of
primitive economies.
This evidence can be put together to create an understanding of how money might
have begun and how it was brought to the stage it had reached when the ancient
peoples of the Middle East first came to record their own experiences of money.
Joe Cribb
Published in La Banca Premonetale, editor Guido Crapanzano, Milan 2004
(www.artvalley.it), pp. 79–122 (Italian translation: pp. 35–78)