Academia.eduAcademia.edu

Impact of Value of Time (VOT) on toll roads

This paper provides a brief overview of the concept of value of time (VOT), in the context of toll road schemes. VOT analysis determines the tradeoffs travelers make between time and tolls. The analysis is very important when considering the choice between tolled and un-tolled alternatives. Using travel demand model of Fresno, CA, I provide a sensitivity analysis showing how the outcomes of tolling schemes can change with varying VOT levels.

Impact of Value of Time (VOT) on toll roads Omid M. Rouhani1 1 School of Civil and Environmental Engineering, Cornell University, Hollister Hall, Ithaca, NY 14853, USA; Email: [email protected] Tel: +1 530 204 8576 Abstract This paper provides a brief overview of the concept of value of time (VOT), in the context of toll road schemes. VOT analysis determines the tradeoffs travelers make between time and tolls. The analysis is very important when considering the choice between tolled and un-tolled alternatives. Using travel demand model of Fresno, CA, I provide a sensitivity analysis showing how the outcomes of tolling schemes can change with varying VOT levels. Keyword- Value of time, Road pricing, Congestion pricing, Optimal toll, Profits, System-wide costs. Introduction and Summary Value of time (VOT) is a measure that transportation practitioners employ in order to estimate how users of toll roads (or other facilities) make choices between a cost component and a time component of each trip (Rouhani and Niemeier, 2014a,b; Rouhani et al., 2014b; Rouhani et al., 2015a,b). In fact, VOT explains the tradeoff between time and money (Brownstone and Small, 2005; Small, 2012). We can explain the application of VOT concept using a simple example. Assume that a user have to options to reach its destination: - Path 1: time: 0.5 hour, no tolls - Path 2: time: 0.3 hour, $4 of tolls The question is which path would be the choice of the user? Without any toll, all users would generally choose Path 2 since it is faster (lower travel time). However, with a toll on Path 2, some users might want to avoid Path 2 now since they have to pay money out of their pocket. Rich users or those ones that have urgent needs may want to pay more to save time. In other words, users should determine how they perceive these cost components relative to each other. Assuming a value of time measure, user can calculate a general costs instead of time cost only when roads are priced. For example, with a value of time of $10/hour, Path 1 has a general cost of $5 (0.5*10) and Path 2 has a general cost of $7 (0.3*10+4). With such calculation, users can choose their paths. VOT determines how users value time spent driving (travelling) and how they calculate a more general cost of travel (Rouhani and Niemeier, 2011; Rouhani, 2012; Rouhani et al., 2014a). For user i and each alternative mode j, GCi is the general cost of travel and can be calculated as follows: GCi = VOTi .tj (vj) + Cj (1) where tj is the travel time spent and Cj is the price or the toll paid by each user. Travel time is a function of traffic volume (vj) or congestion level. VOTi is the value of time ($/hour) which transforms time (in hours) into a monetary measure ($). Note that a more general cost could include fuel costs (Rouhani and Zarei, 2014; Rouhani and Gao, 2014), especially considering huge environmental and energy footprints of the fossil fuel burning from transportation (McCubbin and Delucchi, 1999; Lin et al., 2009; Rouhani et al., 2010; Madani et al., 2011; Mirchi et al, 2012; Rouhani, 2013). Using different VOTs, a specific time cost of tolling (VOTi .tj (vj) in Equation 1) will be translated in different monetary costs of tolls, i.e., a 10 minute–equivalent toll equals to $5 using a $30/hour VOT and equals to $10 using a $60/hour1. Under the same flow pattern, a higher average VOT will result in a higher toll rate (monetary) and consequently a higher revenue by a constant ratio. Note that to do a thorough analysis, we need to use the Multi-user concept since users have perception about their VOT’s. Users are different in the way they incur tolls. When evaluating tolling schemes, a multi-user feature (Yang and Huang, 2004; Chen and Bernstein, 2004; Rouhani and Niemeier, 2011) is necessary for any equity analysis (Levinson, 2010). VOT depend on so many factors such as income, type of trip, the quality of alternative paths/modes, etc (Hess et al., 2005). To estimate VOT, consider that traveler i chooses to maximize a random utility function (Lam and Small, 2011): Uitj ≡ θij+βiXitj+εitj (2) where X is the vector of variables affecting utility gained the time t of the choice. The vector itj include the toll C , travel-time T , and (un)reliability R , etc. Therefore, the value of travel time itj itj itj is defined as: VOT 1 i  U itj / T itj U itj / C itj The time cost of tolls is the main driver of the difference in users’ travel behavior. (3) The derivatives in the above equation allow VOT to depend not only on the individual traveler i but also on the alternative j or choice of time t. VOT is a very important measure in evaluating road pricing (Rouhani, 2009; Rouhani, 2014), congestion pricing (Prud’homme and Bocarejo, 2005; de Palma and Lindsey, 2011; Rouhani et al., 2014b), and public-private partnership tolling schemes (de Bettignies and Ross, 2004; Boardman and Vining, 2012; Rouhani et al., 2015a), and in calculating social and private costs of driving (Rouhani et al., 2013b). In this paper, I analyze the impact of VOT on several measures related to toll collection revenues and costs and their associated system-wide travel costs (system performance). The analysis is conducted using the travel demand model of the City of Fresno, California. The assumptions made for the calculation is available from Rouhani et al. (2013a), Rouhani and Gao (2014), and Rouhani and Gao (2015b). Results It is essential to run a sensitivity analysis on several key parameters of any model (Rouhani et al., 2013b; Rouhani et al., 2014b) that impact outcomes of a tolling scheme. One of the most important variables is VOT. As we discussed, Value of time (VOT) is one of the major elements in analyzing P3 projects (Rouhani et al., 2015a). Considering several base parameters, we can calculate the effects of various VOT rates on the tolling schemes’ outcomes. Note that my analysis takes into account the effects on the whole network of a metropolitan area, not only the effects on the facility of concern (Safirvoa et al., 2007). Figure 1 shows the changes in optimal profit, optimal revenue, and profit-optimal toll rate as VOT level increases. The optimal toll and profit are shown for one typical highway (Figures 1–a) and one typical arterial (Figures 1–b) and for peak (Figures 1–1) and off-peak (Figures 1–2) periods. The method used to for calculating revenues, profits, and optimal tolls can be found in Rouhani et al. (2015a). Although highly effective on the results, an average VOT (not a detailed classified VOT study) only affects the tradeoffs between money (tolls) and time. Figure 1 displays that optimal revenue is linearly related to VOT (constant ratio). However, the effects of VOT on the optimalprofit toll and optimal profit are not as simple. Even optimal toll may decrease with VOT (Figure 1–a–2) since private owners might find it more profitable to decrease tolls and attract more demand even with higher tolls. We find that this counterintuitive result has higher chances of occurrence in off-peak hours, due to a more elastic demand. However, the addition of heterogeneous users in terms of VOT could drastically impact the results. Finally, VOT sensitivity analysis should be combined with the analysis on demand risk (Chen and Subprasom, 2007), other risks associated with tolling (Jin and Zhang, 2011), operating costs (Rouhani et al., 2014c), etc. Figure 1. Sensitivity of the revenue, profit, toll with respect to average VOT for (a) a typical Highway and (b) a typical Arterial No.1 and for (1) peak vs. (2) off-peak. For Highway and in peak periods, the sensitivity of system-optimal toll rates to changes in average VOT and fuel prices is shown in Figure 2. System-optimal rates are found using a very complex optimization problem (Poorzahedy and Rouhani, 2007; Madani et al., 2014) Although system-optimal rates minimize the total system travel costs including time, fuel, and emissions costs in monetary terms (Rouhani et al., 2015a), the dominance of travel time cost relative to other travel cost components (Rouhani et al., 2013c) leads to a rate that minimizes total travel time only (Yang, 1999). Unless the VOT is very low or the fuel prices are very high, the system–optimal rate remains the same. Even when the rate changes, the change is very small ($0.25 to $0.26/mi). This result holds true for almost all other tolling systems (on all other roads). Although taking the fuel consumption and emissions costs into account have negligible effects in determining system-optimal rates, the magnitude of travel costs and the related systemwide benefits or costs could be greatly affected by taking them into account. Figure 2. Sensitivity of the system-optimal tolls to average VOT and fuel price for a typical highway in peak hours. Copyright Note The author certifies that he has the right to deposit the contribution with MPRA. References Boardman, A. E., & Vining, A. R., (2012). The political economy of public-private partnerships and analysis of their social value. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 83(2), 117–141. Brownstone, D., & Small, K. A., (2005). Valuing time and reliability: assessing the evidence from road pricing demonstrations. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, 39(4), 279-293. Chen, M., & Bernstein, D. H., (2004). Solving the toll design problem with multiple user groups. Transportation Research Part B: Methodological, 38(1), 61-79. Chen, A., & Subprasom, K., (2007). Analysis of regulation and policy of private toll roads in a buildoperate-transfer scheme under demand uncertainty. Transportation Research Part A, 41(6), 537-558. de Bettignies, J. E., & Ross, T. W., (2004).The economics of public-private partnerships. Canadian Public Policy/Analyse de Politiques, (2004), 135-154. de Palma, A., & Lindsey, R., (2011). Traffic congestion pricing methodologies and technologies. Transportation Research Part C, 19(6), 1377–1399. Hess, S., Bierlaire, M., & Polak, J. W. (2005). Estimation of value of travel-time savings using mixed logit models. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, 39(2), 221-236. Jin, X. H., & Zhang, G., (2011). Modelling optimal risk allocation in PPP Projects using artificial neural networks. International journal of project management, 29(5), 591–603. Lam, T. C., & Small, K. A. (2001). The value of time and reliability: measurement from a value pricing experiment. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 37(2), 231-251. Levinson, D., (2010). Equity effects of road pricing: A review. Transport Reviews, 30(1), 33-57. Lin, C. Y., Zhang, W., Rouhani, O., & Prince, L. (2009). The implications of an E10 ethanol-blend policy for California. California State Controller John Chiang Statement of General Fund Cash Receipts and Disbursements, 5(5), 6-7. Madani, K., Rouhani, O. M., Mirchi, A., & Gholizadeh, S., (2014). A negotiation support system for resolving an international trans-boundary natural resource conflict. Environmental Modelling & Software, 51, 240-249. Madani, K., Rouhani, O. M., Pournazeri, S., Moradi, M., & Sheikhmohammady, M. (2011, May). Can we rely on renewable energy sources to overcome global warming. In Proceedings of the 2011 World Environmental and Water Resources Congress, ASCE (pp. 3319-3326). McCubbin, D. R., & Delucchi, M. A., (1999). The health costs of motor-vehicle related air pollution. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 33(3), 253–286. Mirchi, A., Hadian, S., Madani, K., Rouhani, O. M., & Rouhani, A. M. (2012). World energy balance outlook and OPEC production capacity: implications for global oil security. Energies, 5(8), 2626-2651. Poorzahedy, H., & Rouhani, O. M., (2007). Hybrid meta-heuristic algorithms for solving transportation network design. European Journal of Operational Research, 182(2), 578–596. Prud’homme, R., & Bocarejo, J. P., (2005). The London congestion charge: A tentative economic appraisal. Transport Policy, 12(3), 279–287. Rouhani O. M., (2009). Road privatization and sustainability. MIT Journal of Planning, 6, 82-105. Rouhani, O. M., (2012). Frameworks for Public-Private Partnerships. Ph.D. dissertation, University Of California, Davis. Rouhani, O. M., (2013). Clean Development Mechanism: An appropriate Approach to reduce Greenhouse Gas Emissions from Transportation? Transportation Research Board 2013 92, No. 13-3195. Rouhani, O. M. (2014). Road pricing: An overview. http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/59662/ Rouhani, O.M., & Niemeier, D., (2011). Urban network privatization: A small network example. Transportation Research Record, 2221, 46–56. Rouhani, O. M., & Gao, H. O., (2014). An advanced traveler general information system for Fresno, California. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, 67, 254-267. Rouhani, O.M., & Niemeier, D., (2014a). Flat versus spatially variable tolling: A case study of Fresno, California. Journal of Transport Geography, 37, 10–18. Rouhani, O. M., & Niemeier, D., (2014b). Resolving the property right of transportation emissions through public–private partnerships. Transportation Research Part D, 31, 48–60. Rouhani, O. M., & Zarei, H., (2014). Gas Consumption Information: A Substitute for Congestion Pricing? Road and Transport Research 23 (3), 52. Rouhani, O. M., Madani, K., & Gholizadeh, S., (2010). Caspian Sea negotiation support system. In Proceeding of the 2010 world environmental and water resources congress, ASCE, Providence, Rhode Island (pp. 2694-2702). Rouhani, O.M., Niemeier, D., Knittel, C. R., & Madani, K., (2013a). Integrated modeling framework for leasing urban roads: A case study of Fresno, California. Transportation Research Part B, 48(1), 17–30. Rouhani, O. M., Kandel, A., & Christian, M. (2013b). The Renewable Portfolio Standard’s Impacts on the California’s Electricity Sector. International Journal of Power and Energy Systems, 33(3), 130-134. Rouhani, O.M.; Gao, O.; Beheshtian, A. (2013c). Social and Private Costs of Driving. Lecture presentation at the 2013 Annual Conference of the International Transportation Economics Association, Northwestern University, Evanston, Illinois. Rouhani, OM, Gao, HO, Geddes, R, Bel, G, & Zarei, H, (2014a). Social Welfare Analysis for Alternative Investment Public-Private Partnership Approaches. Lecture presentation in the 2014 Transportation Research Board conference, Washington D.C. Rouhani, O.M., Knittel, C., & Niemeier, D., (2014b). Road Supply in London: Addition of an Ignored Social Cost. Journal of Transportation Research Forum, 53 (1), 49–64. Rouhani, O.M., Gao, O., & Geddes, R. R., (2015a). Policy lessons for regulating public-private partnership tolling schemes in urban environments. Forthcoming in Transport Policy, DOI: doi:10.1016/j.tranpol.2015.03.006 Rouhani, O. M., Gao, H. O., Zarei, H., & Beheshtian, A. (2015b). Implications of Fuel and Emissions Externalities, Spillovers to the Outside, and Temporal Variations on Zonal Congestion Pricing Schemes. In Transportation Research Board 94th Annual Meeting (No. 15-0905). Safirova, E., Gillingham, K., & Houde, S., (2007). Measuring marginal congestion costs of urban transportation: Do networks matter? Transportation Research Part A, 41, 734–749. Small, K., (2012). Valuation of travel time. Economics of Transportation, 1(1-2), 2–14. Yang, H., (1999). System optimum, stochastic user equilibrium, and optimal link tolls. Transportation Science, 33(4), 354-360. Yang, H., & Huang, H. J., (2004). The multi-class, multi-criteria traffic network equilibrium and systems optimum problem. Transportation Research Part B, 38(1), 1–15.