Journal of Economic Integration
19(3), September 2004; 447-469
A Palestinian Growth History, 1968-2000
Sébastien Dessus
The World Bank
Abstract
The West Bank and Gaza have been occupied by Israel since 1967. As a result,
it experienced a deep integration of its factor and goods markets with the richer
economy of Israel. However, such an integration did not bring significant
“dynamic” gains. Time series analysis indeed suggest that productivity growth
hardly contributed to Palestinian GDP. Besides, the decomposition of income
convergence patterns with Israel implies a rather unusual phenomenon of
divergence in productivity. Economies of adaptation and scale that could have
been encouraged by greater integration with Israel remained scarce, or were
offset by opposite forces.
• JEL Classification: E13, F15, N15, O40
• Key words: West Bank and Gaza, Israel, total factor productivity, convergence
I. Overview
The West Bank and Gaza (WBG) have been occupied by Israel since 1967. As a
result, the Palestinian economy experienced a deep integration of its factor and
goods markets with the richer economy of Israel. Economic and population
statistics remain highly uncertain, but there is little doubt that the Palestinian
population benefited from a catch up phenomenon, whereby a small and
developing economy is taking advantage of its “integration” with a larger and
more developed one, at least in its early phase.
The nature of such an integration remains however unclear, as it might indeed
*Corresponding address: Sébastien Dessus, Sr. Economist, The World Bank UN-House, Riad El Solh P.O.
Box 118577-Beirut 1107 2270 Lebanon, Tel: (961 1) 987 800 ext. 225/Fax: (961 1) 986 800, E-mail:
[email protected]
2004-Center for International Economics, Sejong Institution, All Rights Reserved.
448
Sébastien Dessus
theoretically lead to very different patterns. Naqib (2000) distinguishes two opposite
set of theoretical effects of the integration between a large, advanced and rich economy
with a small, poor and underdeveloped economy: “A favorable repercussion is an
increased demand for the products of the small economy, a diffusion of technology
and knowledge, as well as other spread effects, resulting from the geographical
proximity to a large market leading to subcontracting, joint ventures and
coordination in tourism and other services.1 Unfavorable repercussion arises from
the disappearance of many industries in the small economy, its confinement to
producing low-skill goods and the emigration of a sizeable segment of the labor
force to the neighboring country, as well as to other countries.” In the IsraeliPalestinian case, the fact that such an integration was imposed by one party to the
other brings additional complexities, notably from an institutional point of view:
on the one hand, Israel might have pursued economic policies that were not in the
best interest of the Palestinian economy (Arnon and Weinbatt, 2000).2 On the
other hand, the imposition of economic policies by Israel might have allowed
Palestinian energies to concentrate on using market activities rather than the political
system (through rent-seeking) to generate income, as observed in comparable
cases (Schiff, 2002).
The empirical literature on the net impact of Israeli occupation remains also
scarce. Valdivieso et al. (2001) notices that Total Factor Productivity (TFP) and
capital stock growth in WBG (over the period 1973-94) compares well with Israel,
suggesting positive transfers of technologies and convergence in capital stocks.
1
Vamvakidis’s (1998) results from a cross country analysis also suggest that North-South integration can
boost GDP growth in the developing country, through economies of scale, technological spillovers, and
reduced costs of adaptation and innovation.
2
Between 1967 and 1994, the West Bank and Gaza was under the full control of the Israeli Authorities.
Following the signature of the Declaration of Principles in 1993 by the Palestinian Liberation Organization and
Israel, the Palestinian Authority (PA) was created, and granted some power on the Jericho Area and the Gaza
Strip in 1994. Further transfers of powers (on geographical areas, to eventually gain jurisdiction of zones A and
B, representing some 30 percent of the West Bank and 60 percent of the Gaza Strip) and responsibilities (in
policy-making) were progressively accomplished until end-1995. By early 1996, the PA became in charge of
education, culture, tourism, welfare, statistics, energy, labor, local governments, agriculture and postal services
among others. As far as “core” economic policy was concerned, the PA was granted on the other hand very
little autonomy: the PA was denied the right to issue its own tender, thereby limiting the mandate of the
Palestinian Monetary Authority (PMA) to the sole supervision of the banking system. Indirect taxes (VAT,
import duties, purchase and excise taxes) were collected by the PA in WBG but continued to be set by Israeli
authorities. Trade and industrial policies also continued to be largely driven by Israeli interests and political
considerations (e.g. the absence of trade relationships with Arab League Members, but Jordan and Egypt; the
creation of distribution monopolies in WBG to protect Israeli ones). The only significant leverage of economic
policy granted to the PA was the control of its own public expenditures and the setting of direct taxes.
A Palestinian Growth History, 1968-2000
449
But other authors rather suggest that the opened access of the Israeli labor market
to a large and cheap Palestinian labor force was the main driving force explaining
the observed convergence in per capita incomes since 1968 (Kleiman, 1999, Diwan
and Shaban, 1999). The two phenomenon are not necessarily exclusive, but characterize
very different models of development: in the former case, GDP growth is
encouraged by innovation, competition and the development of productive capacities,
notably for export markets; in the latter case, it is rather spurred by the demand for
non-tradable goods, fuelled by workers remittances.
This paper aims at decomposing econometrically the determinants of GDP
growth in West Bank and Gaza from 1968-2000, in order to isolate the contribution of
TFP to GDP growth in WBG, and compare it with the same measure in Israel. In
order to do so, we rely on statistics (population, employment, national accounts)
collected before 1994 by the Israeli Central Bureau of Statistics (ICBS), and
thereafter by the Palestinian Central Bureau of Statistics (PCBS) for West Bank
and Gaza.3 As far as data on Israel are concerned (population, national accounts,
total factor productivity), we rely on information provided by the Bank of Israel.
The methodology consists in estimating a neo-classical Cobb-Douglas production
function. This, within the framework of a generalized error-correction model,
which permits to test co-integration relationships and to distinguish short term
cyclical variations - believed to be significant in the Palestinian case, from longer
run GDP response to capital accumulation. Different series of capital stock are
built (using the perpetual inventory method with different initial capital/output
ratio), and a sensitivity analysis is conducted on the impact of these initial
conditions on results. Various other exogenous variables that might have
influenced GDP in the short run are introduced to check the robustness of results.
Based on econometric results, a TFP index is computed.
Results strongly suggest that TFP growth contributed only marginally to GDP
growth since 1968: TFP grew on average by less than 0.5 percent every year over
the period 1969-2000 (against 5.5 percent for GDP growth). Besides, the
decomposition of income convergence patterns with Israel suggests a rather
unusual phenomenon of divergence in productivity. In other words, Palestinian
growth under occupation was transitional rather than sustainable, as mostly driven
3
It is not entirely clear whether the two sources are strictly comparable in their coverage and respective
methodologies. Besides, real economic aggregates for the period 1994-2000 were estimated by the
World Bank, in the absence of national accounts in constant prices for this period. We nevertheless
remain fairly confident on the overall reliability of such data. Besides, the econometric analysis
restricted to the pre-1994 period gives very similar results.
450
Sébastien Dessus
by factor accumulation. Conversely, technological transfers from Israel,
economies of adaptation and innovation, and economies of scale that could have
been encouraged greater integration with Israel extremely scarce since 1967 or
were offset by opposite forces.
These results shed some interesting lights on the quality of growth in WBG
since 1968 and it is hoped that this will help policy makers in their choices
regarding future economic relations between the two parties. While the formal
determination of causal relationships between GDP growth in WBG and the
nature of integration with Israel goes beyond the scope of the paper, it nevertheless
points to an important fact the lack of convergence in productivity between Israel
and WBG−and suggests some avenues of research to better understand its causes.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section II describes briefly the
major phases of GDP growth in WBG since 1968. Section III presents and
discusses the results of the econometric estimates; Section IV proceeds to a
decomposition of income convergence patterns between Israel and the West Bank.
Section V concludes with some remarks on the possible strategies to foster
Palestinian GDP growth in the long run.
II. Growth History, 1968-2000
GDP growth in West Bank and Gaza was, first of all, characterized by its great volatility
(see Figure 1). Over the period 1968-2000, the volatility of GDP growth, measured by the
ratio of its standard deviation over its average, reaches a record of 1.4, a value comparable to
the one of the most volatile economies of Latin America (IMF, 2001).
Several factors might probably explain this high volatility, from the bi-annual
natural cycle of olive trees production to political events.4 Besides, such a high
volatility most probably lowered average GDP growth, as volatility generally
discourage savings and investment (Stiglitz, 1993). But this high volatility also
renders difficult the calculation of an average growth rate, which would properly
reflect the history of growth in West Bank and Gaza. In this regard, computing
average GDP growth rates relying only on the information given by the first and
last years of any given period is certainly not the most accurate methodology, as its
4
A simple regression of the GDP growth rate on (i) the GDP growth rate in Israel, (ii) a dummy taking
every two years the value 1 and the value 0 in between (so as to capture approximately the bi-annual
cycle of olive production) and (iii) an index of internal and external closures (source: UNSCO) allows
to explain 50 percent of GDP growth variation over the period 1969-2000.
A Palestinian Growth History, 1968-2000
451
Figure 1. Real GDP growth, 1968-2000.
outcome dramatically depends on the period chosen.5 It is therefore advisable to
use all the information contained during the period 1968-2000 to measure the
average GDP growth rate in WBG. For this purpose, we simply estimate
econometrically the following function:
Y t = Ae
βt
(1)
where Y is the real GDP, A an intercept, t a linear trend and β the average growth
rate. Transformed with logarithms and estimated over the period 1968-2000 gives
the following results (in parentheses are T-student statistics):
lnYt = −100.63 + 0.0546t
(28.2) (30.3)
(2)
Adj. R =0.966 DW=0.669
2
In other words, the average annual GDP growth rate establishes itself at 5.5
percent (See Figure 2). Unless specified, all growth rates reported thereafter are
computed econometrically.
Although the most accurate to reflect the average growth rate over the whole
period, this estimate cannot obviously reflect the fact that GDP Growth went into
several distinct episodes from 1968-2000.6 WBG experienced at first very rapid
5
A simple illustration this fact is given by the following example. If calculated for the period 1970 to
1994, the average GDP growth rate establishes itself at 6.6 percent per year. But if one decals the interval
by one year, that is, takes 1971 and 1995 as the two extremities of the new interval, then the average
GDP growth rate goes down to 6.0 percent. A 0.6 percentage points difference might look marginal, but
it is not: after 20 years, GDP levels differ by more than 10 percent with the two different growth rates.
6
The following paragraphs rely extensively upon Diwan and Shaban (1999) and Kleiman (1999).
452
Sébastien Dessus
Figure 2. Real GDP, 1968-2000.
GDP growth in the years just following the 1967 war. The opening of the Israeli
market to Palestinian labor, new trade and technological opportunities brought
rapid growth in domestic production. Integration between the two economies was
not perfect, as Israel imposed immediately barriers to the importation of
Palestinian agricultural produce, and used administrative means to hamper the
establishments of industrial firms in WBG which could compete with Israel.
However, the initial income gap between the two economies was so large that their
partial integration undoubtedly led to an income convergence phenomenon. The
opened access of the Israeli labor market to a large and cheap Palestinian labor
force was the main driving force explaining this phenomenon (Kleiman, 1999).
Although mostly confined in unskilled activities, Palestinian workers were
benefiting of larger and more modern productive capacities, hence receiving
higher remuneration than in WBG. The share of Palestinian workers in Israel grew
extremely rapidly, to reach approximately one-third in the early 70s.
Once reached this level of labor market integration, GDP growth started to
decline (from two to one-digit annual growth rates), as most of the wage gap had
been narrowed. Furthermore, the 1973 war and the Oil crisis affected Israel
negatively, and its demand for unskilled labor. But this negative shock was
compensated by increased workers’ remittances from Gulf Countries, which
fueled domestic activity in WBG. In the early 80s, the collapse of the regional Oil
boom prompted a decline in these remittances.
With the two main sources of growth (workers remittances from Israel and the
Gulf) almost exhausted, WBG started to experience a stagnation of its domestic
A Palestinian Growth History, 1968-2000
453
activity, which was operating under severe constraints. Diwan and Shaban (1999)
identify four main constraints to GDP growth during the pre-Oslo period:
• Asymmetric market relations with Israel: while imports from Israel were
unrestricted, Palestinian exports to Israel and the rest of the World were
limited by the imposition of barriers to export in Israel, practical difficulties in
trading across Israeli borders, inadequate infrastructure and the high degree of
protectionism of the Israeli economy, which hampered trade creation with the
rest of the world.
• Regulatory restrictions. Expansion of the private sector was held back by investment
approvals required by Israel and uncertainty in legal and tax frameworks.
• Fiscal compression and institutional under-development. Fiscal compression
and institutional under-development led to the under-provision of public goods.
Low tax receipts, high fiscal leakages to Israel and the inability of municipalities
to borrow limited public spending and the development of necessary
infrastructure to the development of a modern Palestinian private sector.
• Restricted access to natural resources. Administrative limitations on water use
from surface and aquifer reserves restricted the expansion of the agricultural and
industrial sector.
The mounting impact of these constraints combined with reduced external
resources probably triggered−inter alia - the first Intifada (Palestinian uprising
against the occupation forces) in 1987, which in itself affected GDP negatively, as
strikes, repression and uncertainty prevailed.7
Signed in 1994, the economic protocol of Oslo agreements−the Paris protocol−
aimed at lifting some of these constraints, by creating in WBG a political and
economic environment more conducive to private investment and growth. Through
substantial infrastructure investment, the creation of a tax revenue sharing
mechanism between Israel and WBG, the elimination of lasting trade barriers in
Israel for Palestinian agricultural products, the removal of restrictions on
economic activities, reduced political and economic uncertainty associated with
the phasing out of military occupation, the development of financial institutions,
and the creation of a legal and regulatory framework, it was hoped to boost
economic growth in the Palestinian economy.
However, the implementation of the Paris Protocol did not seem to have entailed
7
The negative effect of the Intifada was partially compensated during its final years by the housing boom
in Israel resulting from a surge in immigration, mainly from Russia. This boom was however temporary
and accompanied with strong inflation in Israel and WBG.
454
Sébastien Dessus
any structural break with respect to the pre-Oslo period, as far as GDP growth is
concerned. The average GDP growth estimated above is not altered when the
specification allows the growth rate to differ after 1994.8 Contrasting with what was
considered in 1994 as positive steps to resume growth, the policy of internal and
external closures9 imposed sporadically by Israel since 1995 certainly affected growth
negatively, by increasing transaction costs and bringing additional uncertainty, thereby
reducing incentives to invest in productive activities (Kanaan, 1998).
The period running from 1994 to 2000 is nevertheless too short to pronounce
any definitive judgment on the impact on growth of the Oslo agreements. This
period was also extremely erratic, with very distinct episodes mirroring the
volatile evolution of political relationships with Israel, and in particular the degree
of internal and external closures. In the initial post-Oslo years the economy
experienced rapid growth with the return of nationals and large inflows of public
and private capital, as the result of positive expectations on the peace process. But
two years of intermittent external closures in 1995-96 precipitated the Palestinian
economy in recession. From 1997 to September 2000, closures were less frequent,
remittances from Palestinian workers in Israel fuelled demand for domestic
products, transaction costs fell and private investment increased. The economy
also benefited from an economic boom in Israel, which enhanced opportunities for
exports of Palestinian labor and goods. The outbreak of the second Intifada in late
September 2000 finally fractured the dynamics of economic recovery and once
again demonstrated the negative impact of closure on economic growth.
As depicted in Figure 2, GDP was very close to its steady state growth path from
1997 to 1999, during which closures have been less prevalent than in 1995-96 and
2000. This might indicate that the general features of the Palestinian economy
were not significantly modified by the Oslo agreements, with the notable
exception of closures. Some suggestions can be advanced below to explain this
fact, but testing them formally is rendered difficult given the small size sample of
observations. Uncertainty (with regards to future political developments, but also
8
One simple way to test this assumption is to add to the right-hand side of Equation (2) a multiplicative
variable, t * Oslo, with Oslo taking the value 0 before 1994, and 1 from 1994 to 2000. This
multiplicative variable is not significantly different from zero at the 10 percent level, indicating no
significant change in average growth after 1994.
9
“Closure” is a term referring to the restrictions placed by Israel on the free movement of Palestinian goods
and labor across borders and within the West Bank and Gaza. The restrictions take three basic forms: internal
closure within the West Bank and Gaza, closure of the border between Israel and the West Bank and Gaza
and closure of international crossings between the West Bank and Gaza and neighboring Jordan and Egypt.
A Palestinian Growth History, 1968-2000
455
with regards to the existence and enforcement of rules and regulations) remained
high after Oslo, and the implementation of a very complex system of permits to
regulate trade did not help to reduce the already high levels of transaction costs
(Sewell, 2001). Besides, some provisions of the Paris Protocol, such as
monopolies, and the inadequacy of fiscal and trade to the best Palestinian
interests policies might have actually also affect economic growth negatively in
WBG (Arnon and Weinblatt, 2000).10 Finally, the continued high dependency on
Israeli goods and labor markets did not allow the Palestinian private sector to
diversify its risk, and entailed a significant and lasting trade diversion, whereby
consumers and producers were encouraged to buy Israeli goods, in spite of the
availability of cheaper goods on third markets. Expectations of finding a job in
Israel stayed high as well, pulling up reservation wages in WBG and hence keeping
wage-competitiveness at low levels. In turn, incentives to invest in order to expand
and modernize productive activities might have not changed dramatically. This is
illustrated by the fact that growth in capital stock (see below the discussion on capital
stocks) did not significantly accelerate after Oslo, in spite of large amounts of
official assistance provided by foreign donors. A second source of growth trade,
through imports of technologies, increased competition and economies of scale on
export markets remained also very asymmetric, with imports from Israel largely
exceeding exports to Israel, as it was already the case before the signature of Oslo.
III. Growth accounting
A growth accounting exercise is of interest to measure the different source of
long term growth in WBG. In particular, it allows to distinguish mechanically the
contribution of factor accumulation to growth from the contribution of
productivity growth (that is, a better use of existing productive capacities and the
introduction of new technologies).11 In a neoclassical analytical framework12, it
10
After 1994, most of economic policy decisions were still made in Israel, without consulting with the
Palestinian authorities nor taking into account Palestinian interests. The Paris protocol did not include
any effective mechanism to correct such an imbalance.
11
This assumption of strict independence between factor accumulation and factor productivity is imposed
for the sake of simplicity. In real life, it is nevertheless most likely that productivity affects factor
accumulation, by influencing factors rate of return. Conversely, technological progress is often
embodied in physical capital. See for instance Bradford de Long and Summers (1991), which find
strong correlation between investment equipment and TFP growth.
12
That is, assuming constant returns to scale and the remuneration of factors at their marginal productivity.
456
Sébastien Dessus
corresponds to distinguishing transitional growth from long term potential growth,
the latter being defined by the sole productivity growth, once returns to capital
accumulation have been totally exhausted. Within this framework, accounting for
growth simply consists in expressing per capita GDP growth, as the sum of (i) per
capita capital stock growth multiplied by the elasticity of GDP with respect to
capital and (ii) total factor productivity (TFP) growth, the latter being residually
determined:
·
y· ⁄ y = αk ⁄ k + x· ⁄ x
(3)
where y is real GDP per capita, k the physical capital stock per capita, and x the
total factor productivity (TFP) level. The dot on top of a variable denotes the
derivative of the variable with respect to time.
Practitioners generally face two major difficulties in the conduction of this
exercise. First, the capital stock is generally unknown, and second, the elasticity of
GDP with respect to capital is uncertain. Data on capital stock are generally obtained
using the perpetual inventory method, which consists in cumulating investments over
the years (accounting for some physical depreciation of the capital stock, generally
at an annual rate of 4 to 7 percent), but this requires inevitably the identification of
the capital stock level at one point in time.13 Different methods are used to identify
such a capital stock, from the identification of steady state paths (Harberger,
1978), to the imposition of a pre-determined value in line with what has been
estimated for other similar countries (IMF, 2001). The elasticity of GDP with
respect to capital stock, α, can theoretically be extracted from national accounts,
as one minus the share of employees compensation on total GDP at factor cost,
under the assumptions that (i) factors are remunerated at their marginal
productivity, and (ii) that labor remuneration statistics encompasses all labor
value-added. However, these two assumptions are not necessarily met, as market
imperfections on the labor market, as well as under-accounting of real labor valueadded are frequently observed (Young, 1995).
To address these shortcomings, we proceed in this paper with a sensitivity
analysis, which consists in (i) imposing arbitrary different initial values of capital
stocks, and (ii), estimating econometrically Equation (3) to determine the
elasticity of GDP with respect to the capital stock, α. Results are then scrutinized
13
The perpetual inventory method consists in writing the law of motion of capital Kt as: Kt=(1−δ)Kt-1+It,
with δ the depreciation rate (fixed in this paper at 5 percent) and It the flow of contemporaneous
investment.
A Palestinian Growth History, 1968-2000
457
Table 1. Production Function Estimates under Different Initial Capital Stocks, 1970-2000
Initial k/y
γ
β
ϕ
ϕα
Adj. R2
Durbin Watson
α
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.050 (3.78) 2.496 (3.78) 2.043 (3.82) 1.660 (3.80) 1.320 (3.47)
0.055 (0.30) 0.023 (0.10) -0.006 (0.02) -0.029 (0.09) -0.043 (0.12)
-0.686 (3.13) -0.614 (2.94) -0.555 (2.78) -0.507 (2.66) -0.467 (2.56)
0.238 (2.34) 0.241 (2.14) 0.243 (1.98) 0.247 (1.84) 0.253 (1.73)
0.334
0.315
0.297
0.280
0.266
2.249
2.316
2.376
2.432
2.484
0.347
0.393
0.438
0.487
0.542
Average Annual Growth rates, 1970-2000
GDP per capita
2.21%
2.21%
Capital per capita
5.56%
4.85%
TFP
0.28%
0.30%
Observations
31
31
2.21%
4.27%
0.34%
31
2.21%
3.78%
0.37%
31
2.21%
3.34%
0.40%
31
N.B. y is GDP per capita; k physical capital per capita. T-student statistics in absolute value are in
parentheses. The initial k/y (capital-output) ratio is computed for the year 1968. All reported growth rates
are computed econometrically. Estimates are performed using instrumental variables for capital stock
variables. The sample is restricted to the period 1970-2000 because of the use of lags.
against their economic plausibility and their econometric characteristics.
Table 1 reports the econometric estimates of a simple Cobb-Douglas function
with constant returns to scale,14 under different assumptions for initial values of
capital stock. The production function is estimated using an error correction
model, so as to distinguish the short term impact of capital accumulation on GDP
from its long term impact. It takes the form:
ln ( y t ⁄ y t – 1 ) = γ + β ln ( k t ⁄ k t – 1 ) + φ ( ln y t – 1 – α ln k t – 1 )
(4)
In Equation (4), the b coefficient gives the short term impact of capital
accumulation on GDP, while a gives its long term impact. f, the error correction
coefficient, measures at what pace the Palestinian economy corrects imbalances
between its GDP and capital stocks levels, typically after a demand shock, and g is
an intercept. Equation (4) is estimated with instrumental variables for the capital
stock in order to avoid simultaneity biases.15
14
Wald tests cannot reject at the 10 percent level the null hypothesis of constant returns to scale in all 5 cases.
15
The Hausman test of specification rejects at the 1 percent level the null hypothesis of exogeneity in all
5 cases. The instruments retained for these estimations are the World GDP, the Israeli GDP, a linear
trend, a binary variable taking the value 1 the uneven years and 0 the even years, and the number of
days of closures. The different capital stocks are regressed on these variables and their fitted values are
introduced as exogenous variables to estimate equation (4).
458
Sébastien Dessus
All parameters of interest have the expected sign, and are generally statistically
different from zero at the 10 percent level.16 The elasticity of GDP with respect to
capital, a, ranges between 1/3 and 1/2, which is in line with international standards
but lower than the ratio of capital remuneration over GDP reported by the PCBS 3/
5 in 1998. Unit root tests confirm the long-term nature of the relationship between
value added and capital.17 On pure economic grounds, an elasticity of approximately
0.4 looks plausible. Labor costs (pulled by the access to the Israeli labor market)
are high in WBG compared to capital (whose price is determined on international
markets), and this might encourage producers to adopt capital-intensive
technologies.
The lower the initial capital/GDP ratio, the better the quality of estimates, as
measured with the R2 and T-students. The higher the initial capital/GDP ratio, the
higher the elasticity of GDP with respect to capital. But whatever the assumption
on capital stock is finally retained, results strongly suggest that total factor
productivity growth contributed only marginally to GDP growth since 1970.18
Estimates are not sensitive to the initial capital/GDP ratio, and TFP growth over
the period 1969-2000 lies in the interval comprised between 0.3 and 0.4 percent,
which is a rather disappointing performance.
There are several potential explanations for slow TFP growth. First, most
capital expenditures went to construction rather than productive activities,
implying that only limited amounts of machinery and equipment were imported
by investors to modernize and upgrade their activities since 1967. Data for 1998
indicate that investment expenditures devoted to building construction represented
some four-fifths of total investment expenditures. Second, the manufacturing
sector, where most productivity gains can potentially be achieved in the development
process of a low- to middle-income economy, remained dormant. In economic
16
These results are robust to the inclusion of variables describing potential short term shocks such as
closures, business cycles in Israel, and cycles of olive trees productions. Under these alternative
specifications, the lower the initial capital/GDP ratio, the better the quality of estimates. Adding a linear
time trend to measure directly the average growth rate in TFP does not alter the results. The estimated
coefficient of this trend is not significantly different from zero, suggesting that TFP growth has not been
constant over the period of estimation.
17
The per capita GDP and per capita capital series are all integrated of order 1: I(1)+T for GDP, I(1) for
capital; and TFP series are all stationary: I(0). In other words, per capita GDP and per capita capital are
co-integrated. Using a two steps approach, whereby the long term relationship is first estimated and its
residual introduced in an error-correction model leads to the same results and conclusion.
18
TFP growth is computed residually using Equation (3).
A Palestinian Growth History, 1968-2000
459
development success stories such as Taiwan, for instance, sectoral reallocation of
resources (especially labor) from agriculture to industry accounted for about half
of the rapid total factor productivity growth (Dessus et al. 1995). In WBG, by
contrast, most of the labor force was reallocated to services with generally low
levels of labor productivity. Human capital, although rapidly accumulated by
Palestinians, was not used to modernize productive capacities. Moreover, a large
part of human capital remained unutilized due to the low labor force participation
and high unemployment rates of skilled Palestinian women. Low returns to
education pushed skilled male workers out of the Palestinian-Israeli labor market
and encouraged migration to other markets (Angrist 1995). A Dutch disease
phenomenon fueled by large inflows of income from abroad may have reduced the
need for innovation and therefore productivity growth (Shafik 1997; Dutz and
Hayri 2000; Astrup and Dessus 2002). The very low degree of Palestinian
economic integration into global markets indicates−as a cause and/or a symptom−
its weak competitiveness and productivity. Finally, this observed low productivity
growth suggests that Palestinian economic integration with Israel since 1967 has
not benefited from significant technology transfers. This last issue is discussed in
the following section.
IV. Convergence patterns
While real GDP grew by 5.5 percent on average in West Bank and Gaza from
1968 to 2000, it only grew by 4.2 percent in Israel19 . During the same time,
population grew by 2.9 percent in WBG and 2.4 percent in Israel. Therefore, per
capita income convergence was observed between WBG and Israel: per capita
GDP growth reached 2.6 percent a year in WBG, against 1.8 percent in Israel.
The observation of the evolution of the ratio of real GDP per capita in WBG
over real GDP per capita in Israel nevertheless suggests that this catch up
phenomenon was not uniform from 1968 to 2000. After a period of rapid
convergence in GDP per capita (from 1968 to the mid-eighties) during which this
ratio increased by about 50% (hence denoting a rapid narrowing in the income gap
between Israel and West Bank and Gaza), per capita GDP tended to diverge from
there onwards (See Figure 3). This figure does not indicate however the extent to
which the per capita GDP gap between Palestinian and Israeli households was
19
Data for Israel (GDP, GNP, population, total factor productivity) are from the Bank of Israel.
460
Sébastien Dessus
Figure 3. Convergence in GNI and GDP per capita between WBG and Israel.
reduced since 1967, as we use here per capita income indexes, rather than levels.
There is indeed some uncertainties regarding the difference in per capita income
levels between WBG and Israel at one point in time. This stems from the fact that,
despite their close degree of economic integration, and an extensive use of the
Israeli currency in the Palestinian economy, WBG and Israel might not necessarily
face the same price levels.20 For the sake of illustration, had the per capita income
gap (measured with per capita GDP at purchasing power parity) been of
approximately 1:10 in 1968, as suggested by Naqib (2000), it would have declined
to 1:6 in 1980 to come back to 1:8 in 2000.
Income convergence phenomena, whereas the larger the initial gap in income
(between two countries, or with respect to the steady state income of any given
county) the faster the growth in income, are generally measured using statistics of
20
Despite a close economic integration, the assumption that consumers in the WBG and Israel face the
same prices for all goods and services may be rather strong. Most likely, Israeli prices are the upper
level of prices for the WBG residents. Anecdotal evidence and theory suggest that the price level in the
WBG may be lower than in Israel for non-tradable goods. On the other hand, the parallel movement in
the price level of tradable goods in the WBG and Israel, supports the assumption that most consumer
prices in Israel and the WBG are nearly the same (World Bank, 2000).
A Palestinian Growth History, 1968-2000
461
GDP per capita (Barro and Sala-I-Martin, 1995). This, for the simple reason that
the convergence phenomenon theoretically stems from the existence of decreasing
returns in human and physical capital accumulation, as well as from the existence
of a catch up phenomenon in productivity,21 which both influence GDP, and not
GNP.22 Less attention, however, has been paid in the empirical literature on
growth to the phenomenon of income convergence through the trade in production
factors, and in particular through the export of labor services. This phenomenon
might have had a significant impact in WBG, as export of labor to Israel grew very
rapidly after 1967, and net factor incomes from abroad represent a very large share
of total Palestinian income.23
From 1968 to 2000, real GNP per capita grew annually by more than 2.5
percent in WBG, against 2.1 percent in Israel. A convergence in income, measured
with Gross National Income, might therefore be observed. But again, after a rapid
convergence in incomes from 1968 to the mid-eighties, the income gap between
WBG and Israel widened (See Figure 3).
Many factors are candidates to explain this pattern of convergence / divergence
in incomes. Although high in some markets, the degree of economic integration
between WBG and Israel has never been total, and varied over time (Naquib,
2000, Farsakh, 1998), as it will be discussed below. Besides, Palestinian and
Israeli households might not necessarily have the same economic preferences,
which for instance determine their savings rates, and the use and detention of
different currencies. In this context, external shocks and policy making might have
affected differently the income growth patterns of the two economies.
While acknowledging these differences, one striking feature of this patterns of
convergence followed by divergence lies in the fact that the catch up phenomenon
21
The theoretical principle for the convergence in productivity is similar to the one in factors
accumulation. It simply assumes diminishing returns to imitation and adaptation of foreign
technologies, which tends to generate a pattern of convergence: follower countries tend to grow faster
the greater the technological gap from the leaders.
22
The difference between GDP and GNP is given by net income from abroad, which does not directly
depend on capital stock and productivity levels in the economy.
23
In 1998, Palestinian households (excluding East Jerusalem) received some US$ 828 millions of net
income from abroad, out of which US$ 724 millions were from workers’ remittances from Israel
(Source: World Bank Staff calculations based on PCBS). This total amount represents an estimated
share of 16.4 percent of GNP, which exceeds by far averages in the region or elsewhere. In the MENA
region, this ratio did not exceed 1 percent in 1998, neither it did on average on average in the group of low
& middle income countries, nor in Egypt, Jordan or Lebanon (source: World Development Indicators).
462
Sébastien Dessus
was more pronounced in GNP than in GDP (see Figure 3). Incomes, measured with
GNP, converged, and then diverged, more rapidly than if measured with GDP.
This would tend to suggest that workers remittances from Israel – by far the most
important component of the difference between GDP and GNP, plaid a particular
role in this regard.24 A simple calculation might help assessing the magnitude of
this phenomenon. If one writes the per capita GNP, yi,t, of the country i at the
period t like:
α
i
y i, t = k i, t x i, t z i, t
(5)
with k the capital stock per capita, x the level of TFP and z the ratio of GNP over
GDP. The income ratio between to economies i and j at the period t can then be
written, in logarithm like:
α
α
i
i
ln ( y i, t ⁄ y j, t ) = ln ( k i, t ⁄ k j, t ) + ln ( x i, t ⁄ x j, t ) + ln ( z i, t ⁄ z j, t )
(6)
In turn, time-differentiating Equation (6) permits to decompose the change in
income ratio as the sum of three components: (i) the evolution of the capital ratio
between the two economies (a positive growth rate would denote a convergence in
factor endowments between the two economies if country i is initially the poorer),
(ii) the evolution of the productivity ratio between the two economies (a positive
growth rate would denote a convergence in productivity levels), and (iii) a residual
term which capture the impact of net incomes from abroad on GNP.
This decomposition is applied to study the patterns of convergence/divergence
between WBG and Israel. In order to do so, we use for WBG the results presented
in Table 1, with an initial capital stock/GDP ratio of 2 in 1968. For Israel, the TFP
series is extracted from the Bank of Israel (BoI), and the contribution of capital to
GDP is obtained by the difference between logarithms of GDP per capita and TFP.
Table 2 reports such a decomposition of the convergence patterns over different
periods. 1985 is chosen as a pivotal year, as it marks approximately the year where
incomes started to diverge (cf. Figure 3). This table first reveals that, over the
whole period, per capita GNP grew each year 0.4 percent more rapidly in WBG
than in Israel. It also permits to observe that this convergence in incomes was
24
The other mechanical explanation for the difference in convergence/divergence patterns measured with
GDP and GNP could stem from the fact that GDP and GNP growth also widely differed in Israel. But
it appears that the ratio of GNP/GDP has been much more stable in Israel than in WBG between 1968
and 2000: the volatility of this ratio, measured by the standard deviation over its average is 3.8% in
Israel and 8.1% in WBG.
A Palestinian Growth History, 1968-2000
463
Table 2. Income convergence and divergence patterns between WBG and Israel
Net Convergence effect
Capital
Productivity
Income from abroad
1968-2000
0.39%
1968-1985
3.54%
1986-2000
-2.46%
1.45%
-0.71%
-0.35%
2.63%
-0.30%
1.20%
0.19%
-0.51%
-2.15%
Source: Author’s calculation based on PCBS and BoI. Growth rates are obtained by regressing the
logarithm of the considered variable over a time trend. For that reason, growth rates of sub-periods do not
necessarily add up.
mainly due to a more rapid capital accumulation in WBG than in Israel (1.4
percent higher every year in WBG). Conversely, one can observe throughout the
period a phenomenon of divergence in productivity: on average each year, from
1968 to 2000, productivity grew by 0.7 percent more rapidly in Israel than in
WBG. Table 2 also indicates that the structural break observed in the mid-eighties
can mostly be explained by the dramatic drop in Palestinian incomes from abroad
compared to Israel. This, most likely as a result of the return of Palestinian skilled
workers from the Gulf from the 80s onwards, and the decline of the share of
Palestinian workers commuting to Israel after 1987.25
The analysis therefore suggests that the de facto economic integration of West
Bank and Gaza with Israel has not produced the positive dynamic gains - notably
in terms of productivity growth and technological transfers, that could have been
theoretically expected. Would have the net outcome of integration been better with
greater and more stable integration ? And in particular, would have the catch up in
productivity been more rapid under such conditions ? A last set of regressions
sheds some light on this issue. According to typical technological leader-follower
model, the catch-up in productivity phenomenon may be specified like:
x· i ⁄ x i = φ ( x j ⁄ x i, w ), φ ′ > 0, φ ′″ < 0, φ ( 1, 1 ) = 0
(7)
where w is an index of integration ranging from 0 to 1 between countries i and j
and x the TFP level. In non-mathematical terms, Equation (7) describes the fact
that, under assumptions of diminishing returns to education and adaptation of
foreign technologies, follower countries (in this case, West Bank and Gaza,
country i), tend to grow faster the greater the technological gap from the leaders
25
The percentage of the Palestinian labor force working in Israel grew up to 35-40 percent in the mid
eighties (with a maximum of 38 percent in 1987), before dropping to about 15-20 percent by the end
of the century (Farsakh, 1998).
464
Sébastien Dessus
(in this case, Israel, country j). However, it is most likely that being backward does
not in itself guarantee that the economy will catch up. This is probably
conditional, inter alia, on the degree and nature of exchanges between the two
countries (Pissarides, 1997). Therefore, the catch-up phenomenon will also be
conditioned by the degree of integration between the two economies.
In its simplest form, Equation (7) can be estimated like:
x· i ⁄ x i = λ ( x j ⁄ x i ) + µw
(8)
with λ the speed of convergence in productivity, once controlled for the degree of
integration between the two economies. This specification requires to know at one
point in time the gap in TFP levels between WBG and Israel, which is rendered
difficult by the fact that data on purchasing power parities are not available. To
overcome the obstacle, we write xj,0 the initial TFP level in Israel as a multiplicative
factor of the initial level of TFP in WBG:
x j, 0 = Ax i, 0
(9)
and combining (7) and (8) gives after some algebra (with gi,t the TFP growth rate
in country i at the period t):
t–1 1 + g
j, k
g i, t = λA ∏ ----------------- + µ w t
+
g
1
i, k
k=1
(10)
This equation can be directly estimated, as it only embodies TFP growth rates.
However, such estimate does not allow to separate λ from A, and therefore
identify these two parameters. Only their product can be estimated. As far as the
degree of integration between the two economies, w, is concerned, we use the
(logarithm of the) wage differential between Palestinian workers employed in
Israel and in WBG.26 The lower the differential (zero in case of wage equalization),
the higher the degree of integration. We believe that this indicator is a fair
indicator of integration between the two economies, as labor market integration is
generally perceived as a higher step of integration than goods market integration.
Results obtained estimating Equation (10) suggest that a catch up phenomenon
might have indeed been associated after 1968, as the coefficient associated with π,
the multiplicative term, is statistically different from zero and positive (T-student
26
Source: Arnon, Spivak and Weinblatt (1997) and PCBS labor force surveys, various issues. In the early
eighties, Israeli and Palestinian labor markets were highly integrated, as illustrated by wage differentials
close to zero between Palestinian workers in Israel and WBG.
A Palestinian Growth History, 1968-2000
465
statistics are in parenthesis).
g i, t = 15.568 + 0.877π t – 0.025 w t – 0.008 t
(5.95)
(5.06)
(0.42)
(6.04)
(11)
2
Adj. R =0.435 DW=2.122
But this phenomenon was not strong enough to offset some other negative factors,
here captured by a linear trend, t. Surprisingly, the degree of market integration
does not seem to have plaid a significant role.27 Or, in other words, is not a
sufficient candidate to explain the observed patterns of divergence in Total Factor
Productivity.
Some other explanation must be found, although it goes beyond the scope of
this paper. We just suggest here some possible ways of future research. One could
possibly be the lack of technological diffusion capacities (institutions) within the
West Bank; another one could be that the incentive structure in place in WBG
since 1968 did not encourage the adaptation and use of foreign technologies, in a
macro-economic context where non-tradable activities − in which the demand for
new technologies is usually lower than in tradable activities, were encouraged
(Astrup and Dessus, 2002).
But more generally, this result calls for some additional thinking on why
integration does not always promote TFP growth. We suggest here an explanation,
or at least some preliminary theoretical framework, under which this question
could be approached. The nature of integration may be characterized according to
three criteria, which all have an impact on growth and convergence patterns: (i)
the degree of trade integration; (ii) the degree of labor market integration, and (iii)
the availability of macro-economic instruments (fiscal, monetary, exchange rate
policies), to correct imbalances. Trade integration most likely promotes technological
convergence; on the other hand, labor market integration, ceteris paribus, might favor
the over-valuation of the real exchange rate in the poorest country, thereby distorting
the incentive structure and reducing the demand for foreign technologies. One way to
correct for such a negative outcome of (labor market) integration is to adjust the
exchange rate accordingly.
The European Union represents a successful case of integration: Spain, Portugal
and Ireland clearly benefited from a productivity catch-up phenomenon with the
27
Various tests were conducted to confirm this result. In particular, various lagged structure were used to
capture potential delays in adjustment to a new degree of integration; Hausman tests of exogeneity were
also conducted, using different subsets of instruments. None of these tests allowed to question the
conclusion put forward in the text.
466
Sébastien Dessus
richer economies of France and Germany. In this case, trade was liberalized, while
labor markets remained poorly integrated; and countries had some policy
autonomy to correct imbalances. Italy, where the South, despite pro-active public
policies, has been unable to catch up rapidly with the North, is an intermediate
case, whereby trade and labor markets were integrated, but no policy tools were
available to correct imbalances. Finally, the Israeli-Palestinian type of integration
possibly represents a case with all defaults: high degree of labor market
integration; low degree of trade integration; no policy tools available to correct
imbalances. Notwithstanding the fact that there was no shared will of integration,
this pattern of integration probably explains to a significant extent the poor
outcome of the Israeli occupation.
V. Conclusion
GDP growth is a complex phenomenon. It is probably driven in the long run by
supply-side conditions, i.e., the change in the level of productive capacities (labor,
human and physical capital, the technology), and in the shorter run by demand
conditions, which will affect the utilization rate of these capacities, and determine
their growth paths. In West Bank and Gaza, like everywhere else, this is a
combination of domestic and external factors and policies which determine
growth, and one should obviously not focus only on the nature of relation with
Israel to explain past growth and predict future Palestinian growth. Nevertheless,
it remains obviously a conditioning factor, as the capacity for Palestinian
authorities of making decision of economic and institutional nature depends on
their degree of autonomy in these fields. Therefore, the nature of economic
relation with Israel not only affects the environment in which the Palestinian
economy is evolving, but also the spectrum of policy instruments at the disposal of
Palestinian authorities to promote growth.
The observation of growth patterns for the period 1968-2000 suggests that
growth in WBG was mainly fuelled by factor accumulation. Conversely,
productivity growth contributed only marginally to GDP growth all over the
period of occupation, and Oslo agreements did not radically changed the situation.
This tends to indicate that the forced integration of WBG with Israel did not bring
the dynamic gains that could have been expected, notably in terms of transfers of
technology and greater access to export markets. The degree of integration
between the two economies, although highly variable during the period, cannot
A Palestinian Growth History, 1968-2000
467
simply explain this weak performance. Therefore, lifting the restrictions on the
movement of Palestinian people and goods between WBG and Israel − while certainly
helpful and necessary to restore minimum income levels28- is probably not sufficient
to foster domestic growth in a sustainable manner.
Two alternative ways of development might therefore be envisaged. A first one,
in which decision makers will try to maximize the benefits of integration which
have been observed in other parts of the world (e.g. following the creation of the
European Union). This might notably necessitates implementing measures to (i)
encourage Israeli investments (public and private) in West Bank and Gaza; (ii)
facilitate the transfer of Israeli technologies to WBG; (iii) reduce barriers to access
to higher positions for Palestinian workers in Israel; (iv) reduce transaction costs
to favor trade integration. Several measures had been initiated in this regard during
the Oslo period, like the development of industrial estates to promote Israeli −
Palestinian private joint ventures, but much remained to do in this domain as well
as in all the other above-mentioned domains.
A second way of development would consist in eliminating the current negative
aspects of integration by dis-integrating the two economies. This would at least
require to grant greater autonomy to the Palestinian authorities in their decision
making, and provide them with the physical (trade infrastructure) and legal means
(trade policies) to maximize the gains of a more direct integration into world
markets.
Acknowledgments
The author would like to thank Enisse Kharoubi, Elizabeth Ruppert-Bulmer,
Paolo Zacchia and two anonymous referees for their suggestions and comments.
The views expressed here are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect
those of the World Bank, its Executive Directors or the country they represent.
Usual disclaimers apply.
Received 7 July 2003, Accepted 10 August 2004
28
See World Bank (2002) for a detailed description of the economic and social impact of the second
Intifada.
468
Sébastien Dessus
References
Angrist, J. (1995), “The Economic Returns to Schooling in the West Bank and Gaza
Strip,”, The American Economic Review, 85: 1065-87.
Arnon, A., A. Spivak and J. Weinblatt (1997), The Palestinian Economy: Between
Imposed Integration and Voluntary Separation, Leiden, Brill.
Arnon, A. and J. Weinblatt (2000), Sovereignty and Economic Development: The Case of
Israel and Palestine, Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. Photocopied.
Astrup C. and S. Dessus (2002), Exporting Goods or Labor ? long term implications for
the Palestinian Economy, MENA Working Paper Series, 29, The World Bank,
Washington.
Barro, R.J. and X. Sala-I-Martin (1995), Economic Growth, McGraw-Hill, New York.
Bradford de Long, J. and L. Summers (1991), “How Strongly Do Developing Countries
Benefit from Equipment Investment?,” J. Bradford de Long’s Working Papers 108,
University of California, Berkeley.
Dessus, S., J.D. Shea, and M.S. Shi (1995), Chinese Taipei: The Origins of the Economic
“Miracle”, Development Centre Studies, Organisation for Economic Co-operation
and Development, Paris.
Diwan, I. and R. Shaban (1999), Development Under Adversity: The Palestinian Economy
in Transition, MAS and the World Bank, Washington D.C.
Dutz, M. and A. Hayri (2000), “Does More Intense Competition Lead to Higher
Growth?,” Policy Research Working Paper, 2320, The World Bank, Washington D.C.
Farsakh, L. (1998), Palestinian Employment in Israel: 1967-1997, A Review, Palestine
Economic Policy Research Institute (MAS), Ramallah.
Harberger, A. (1978), “Perspectives on Capital and Technology in Less-Developed
Countries,” in M.J Artis, and A.R. Nobay, (eds.), Contemporary Economic Analysis,
Croom Helm.
International Monetary Fund (2001), West Bank and Gaza: Economic Performance,
Prospects and Policies, Middle Eastern Department, Washington D.C.
Kanaan, O. 1998. “Private Investment Under Uncertainty in the West Bank and Gaza Strip,”
in The Economy of the West Bank and Gaza Strip, Middle Eastern Department,
International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Kleiman, E. (1999), “Fiscal Separation with Economic Integration: Israel and the
Palestinian Authority,” in A. Razin and E. Sadka (eds.), The Economics of
Globalization, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.
Naqib, F.M. (2000), Economic Relations Between Palestine and Israel During the
Occupation Era and the Period of Limited Self-Rule, Working Paper 2015, Economic
Research Forum for the Arab Countries, Iran and Turkey, Cairo.
Pissarides C. (1997), “Learning by Trading and the Returns to Human Capital in
Developing Countries,” World Bank Economic Review, 11(1): 17-32.
Schiff, M. (2002), Trade Policy and Labor Services: Final Status Options for the West
A Palestinian Growth History, 1968-2000
469
Bank and Gaza, Policy Research Working Paper 2824, The World Bank, Washington
D.C.
Sewell, D. 2001. “Governance and the Business Environment in West Bank/Gaza,”
MENA Working Paper Series, 23, The World Bank, Washington D.C.
Shafik, N. (1997), “Rents, Reforms and Economic Malaise in the Middle East and North
Africa,” Research in the Middle East Economics, 2: 221-45.
Stiglitz, J.E. (1993), “Endogenous Growth and Cycles,” National Bureau of Economic
Research Working Paper, 4286, March, Cambridge.
Valdivieso, R., U. Erikson von Allmen, G. Bannister, H. Davoodi, F. Fischer, E. Jenkner
and M. Said. 2001. West Bank and Gaza Economic Performance, Prospects, and
Policies: Achieving Prosperity and Confronting Demographic Challenges, Middle
Eastern Department, International Monetary Fund: Washington, D.C.
Vamvakidis, A. (1998), “Regional Integration and Economic Growth,” World Bank
Economic Review, 12(2): 251-270.
World Bank (2000), “Poverty in West Bank and Gaza,” West Bank and Gaza Update,
April, Al-Ram.
World Bank (2002), 15-month Intifada, Closures and the Palestinian Economic Crisis: an
Assessment, Washington D.C.
Young, A. (1995), “The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the
East Asian Experience,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, August, 641-679.