Real Estate & Planning
Working Papers in Real Estate & Planning 04/15
The copyright of each Working Paper remains with the author.
In some cases a more recent version of the paper may have been published elsewhere.
EU Housing Markets:
The Role of Institutional Factors
António Miguel Martins
Universidade da Madeira
Ana Paula Serra
CEF.UP and Universidade do Porto
Francisco Vitorino Martins
FEP, Universidade do Porto
Simon Stevenson*
Henley Business School, University of Reading
*Corresponding Author: Henley Business School, University of Reading, Whiteknights,
Reading, RG6 6UD, U.K. E-Mail:
[email protected]
EU Housing Markets:
The Role of Institutional Factors
Abstract
Using cluster analysis this study reveals significant heterogeneity in the institutional
characteristics of European mortgage markets. Distinct clusters are formed which can be
related to differences in the mortgage credit system, the relative importance of the
owner-occupation and the property specific fiscal system. The paper then tests for
multiple structural breaks. We find evidence that structural breaks in European housing
markets often coincide with a changes in housing market policy.
Keywords: Housing Market; European Union; Structural Breaks; Institutional
Factors
1
EU Housing Markets:
The Role of Institutional Factors
1. Introduction
The turmoil in the world’s financial system observed during the 2007-9 financial
crisis has heightened interest in housing markets and their importance both financially
and economically. Beyond the natural policy considerations that arose following the
crisis, there has been a growing awareness in the importance of assessing the effects of
changes in property prices on a variety of issues. These include consumption decisions,
given the predominance of housing in overall household wealth (Campbell & Cocco,
2007; Muellbauer & Murphy, 2008) and also the impact on the broad banking and
financial sector given the proportion of bank loan portfolios that residential mortgage
loans comprise (Martins et al. 2014).
This paper builds upon the existing literature in considering how the institutional
characteristics of national residential mortgage markets may affect house prices. A
number of studies, including Tsatsaronis & Zhu (2004), Calza et al. (2007) and Miles &
Pillonca (2008), all point to significant heterogeneity in the institutional characteristics
of national mortgage market1. Calza et al. (2007) report that “this heterogeneity is
particularly evident within the euro area, where mortgage lending remains a
predominantly domestic business activity, largely reflecting natural traditions and
cultural factors as well as the institutional settings of the local banking sector”. The
authors point out as examples of these diverging institutional features, the typical
mortgage contract duration, the required level of down-payment, degree of innovation
and development of the capital market and the type of interest-rate structure of
mortgage contracts (variable or fixed interest rate). Maclennan et al. (1998) and ECB
(2003), among others, point out the differences present in the rental market, mortgage
credit system and in transaction costs as factors that aid in explaining the differences
observed in the volatility of house prices across EU countries. Van den Noord (2003)
extends that analysis by illustrating how house price volatility within the Eurozone
appears to be related, at least in part, to differences in tax treatment of owner-occupied
housing2. The analysis contained in these papers primarily consists of surveys of
institutional differences across countries, without either a corresponding detailed
2
examination of the effects on house prices dynamics (McCrone & Stephens, 1995;
Maclennan et al., 1998 and ECB, 2003) or the study of the how a restricted set of
institutional characteristics may impact the market (Van den Noord, 2003; Tsatsaronis
& Zhu, 2004). Whilst a large number of studies have compared the behaviour of
housing markets in different countries (e.g. Holmans, 1994;, Englund & Ioannides,
1997; Iacoviello, 2000; Calza et al., 2007; Miles & Pillonca, 2008; Adams & Fuss,
2010) only Calza et al. (2007) examines the role of a restricted set of institutional
characteristics relating to the financial system and the corresponding effects of
monetary policy on consumption and housing prices. Calza et al. (2007) analyses the
effects of monetary policy shocks on consumption and housing prices, noting
significant variation in both the timing and strength of those effects across different
countries. In particular, the authors report that the size of the peak effect of a monetary
policy shock on consumption and real house prices is positively related to indicators of
development/flexibility in mortgage markets. Such indicators include the mortgages
debt to GDP ratio; the loan-to-value (LTV) ratio and the existence of equity release
products.
The contribution of this study is thus the identification of institutional
differences that exist in the housing market and financial institutions across a variety of
European countries. We base the methodological framework on cluster analysis,
showing that there are marked differences at the level of institutional characteristics. We
then consider how this heterogeneity in institutional characteristics can impact house
prices dynamics through the testing for structural breaks. Whilst there are some papers
to have considered the issue of structural breaks the literature is sparse, especially in the
context of multiple structural breaks in Europe. The issue is of relevance and
importance as institutional factors and policy changes may play an important role in any
structural breaks observed. To test for multiple structural breaks we use the Bai &
Perron (1998, 2001 and 2003) framework. We consider possible breaks in both real user
cost and real price growth. The empirical results not only confirm the presence of
structural breaks in the majority of cases, but also show that the breaks frequently
coincide, or are close to, changes in housing policy. However, many of the changes in
housing policy frequently cited in the literature do not necessarily result in structural
breaks. It is argued that this may be due to policy changes not resulting in major
3
structural changes or that their impact may have been mitigated by other events or
policies.
The paper is structured as follows. In the next section, we briefly characterise the
European housing market, with a special emphasis on the rental and house ownership
market, mortgage market and tax system. In section 3 we utilise cluster analysis to
group the markets based upon their institutional characteristics. The fourth section of
the paper contains the findings from the analysis of structural breaks. Finally, Section 5
provides concluding comments.
2. EU Housing Markets
2.1.
EU Rental Markets
Across the EU-15 the proportion of total housing stock that is rented varies quite
considerably. As displayed in Table 1 the percentage of rented stock ranges from 12%
to 58%. A variety of factors potentially influence the relative importance of the rental
sector, including the tax-subsidy system; regulation in the rental sector; the provision of
social rental accommodation and the regulation and the structure of financial markets.
In addition, preference for home ownership and expectations for capital gains from
house price appreciation may also influence the degree of rented stock, specifically in a
downward direction (ECB, 2003). The result of such factors, both supply and demand
based, has been that the role of the rental market is relatively marginal in some
European countries, such as Spain. Indeed, with the exception of Germany, across the
entire EU-15 the highest proportion of housing stock that can be categorised as privately
rented is 26% for Denmark and Luxembourg. The rental market can act as a regulating
valve, attenuating extreme house price appreciation (DiPasquale & Wheaton, 1992). In
contrast, countries such as Spain, Ireland, U.K. and Finland, with a higher percentage of
home ownership and low levels of private rental housing, may experience heightened
house price volatility.
Insert Table 1
EU governments have frequently acted in response to the reduction in the size,
and quality of the market for rented dwellings. This response has often been in the
4
context of relaxation in rent regulations. There are three fundamental aspects in rent
control systems (ECB 2003):
(i)
The existence of regulations governing how the initial rent in a multi-year
rental contract will change in the future. In many countries the rent is
indexed to CPI (Consumer Price Index). However, in countries such as
Germany there is a mechanism that allows the adjustment of rents to recent
housing market conditions.
(ii)
The existence of some type of control on the initial rent negotiated for a new
rental contract between a landlord and a tenant. If rents in new contracts
should reflect market conditions on the passage from the first to the “second
generation”
(iii) The existence of regulations governing contracts termination (eviction).
These elements are considered in the preparation of the index presented in Table
2 on the typology of property laws: pro-landlord, pro-tenant or neutral law3. The table
shows that in most EU countries the law is strongly pro-tenant. The exceptions are the
U.K. where the law is pro-landlord and Finland and Greece where property law is
neutral, i.e. the index shows a value of zero.
2.2.
EU Mortgage Markets
A wide number of papers including, Tsatsaronis & Zhu (2004), Calza et al.
(2007) and Miles & Pillonca (2008), note the existence of significant differences in
mortgage market institutional characteristics across EU-countries. Tsatsaronis & Zhu
(2004) classify countries into three groups based on institutional characteristics and
illustrate that the interaction between bank lending and house prices are affected by
these features. Key factors that can be used to differentiate markets include:
(i)
Interest-Rate Structure: In particular whether fixed or variable rate mortgage
products dominate. Variable rates may make housing prices more sensitive to
changes in short-term rates and thus to monetary policy.
(ii)
Mortgage Equity Withdrawal: The ability of liquidity-constrained agents to
take advantage of built up increased collateral value.
5
(iii)
Valuation and Leverage Practices: These elements aid in the evaluation of
risk and indicate the degree of prudence maintained in mortgage lending.
This is turn influences creditors’ appetite for exposure to the market and the
strength of the credit channel. Important parameters in this respect are the
existence and level of prudential ceilings on the loan-to-value (LTV) ratios
that determine the ability of banks to lend against real estate collateral, and
the valuation methods of property used in conjunction with these ceilings.
Methods that base lending decisions on current market value of property
would tend to increase the sensitivity of credit availability to market
conditions and could possibly help to create a positive momentum in market
demand.
(iv)
Depth of the Securitisation Market: The availability of a securitised mortgage
market facilitates the accompanying advantages and disadvantages.
(v)
Transaction Costs: Transaction costs (e.g. registration fees, agents’
commissions, legal fees and sale/transfer taxes) also contribute to differences
in house price volatility.
Insert Table 2
Papers such as Maclennan et al. (1998) argue countries with high transaction
costs, low leverage ratios, low weight of house ownership and a high proportion of
fixed-rate mortgages, tend to experience lower volatility, a lower effect of house prices
on consumption and a reduced role of housing in the transmission mechanism of interest
rate. Maclennan et al. (1998) also notes how the degree of housing finance integration
in the capital markets is an important factor in obtaining funds by financial institutions.
Warnock & Warnock (2008) highlight the importance of the mortgage market in
generating demand for housing assets. Given the relative size of the asset it follows that
factors that are associated with a well-functioning housing finance system are those that
enable the provision of long-term finance. In a cross-sectional analysis for 62 countries
between 2001 and 2005, the authors find that countries with stronger legal rights for
borrowers and lenders (through collateral and bankruptcy laws), deeper credit
information systems, and a more stable macroeconomic environment, have deeper
housing financial systems. In their study Legal Rights4 and Credit Information5
variables are obtained from the “Getting Credit” reports of the World Bank6. The
6
importance of the legal environment and investor protection are also emphasized by
Lieser & Groh (2010). The authors find that Investor Protection and Legal Framework
is only second in importance, behind Economic Activity, in their composite index of real
estate investment attractiveness7. Sorensen & Lichtenberger (2007) report that countryspecific factors such as institutional differences that are difficult to measure over time
play an important role in explaining the differences in mortgage interest rates. The
authors emphasize the importance of the national legal framework procedure to enforce
the collateral, the LTV ratios and fiscal factors, in explaining the differences in interest
rates across EU countries. The expected cost of anticipated losses depends not only on
the probability of default but also on the cost of the event itself. While the probability of
default is influenced by many factors (e.g. position in the business cycle, income
prospects, etc.), the cost of the event itself is also determined by the national legal
framework and, in particular, by the cost and duration of the procedure to enforce the
collateral. When some of these costs, such as time and resources, are borne by the
creditor, banks may include them ex ante into their lending rates.
2.3.
EU Tax Systems
The potential role that tax incentives can play, especially in the context of
stimulating demand is well documented (e.g. Van den Noord, 2003). A tax system that
contains generous incentives to house ownership may not only result in a higher steadystate level of house prices (and an associated misallocation of resources), but also in
greater volatility of house prices. Poterba (1984, 1991) argues that house price volatility
arises from the combination of the price-inelastic supply of newly built dwellings and
the preferential tax treatment of owner-occupied housing. Based on the framework
developed by Poterba, Van den Noord (2003) argues that the apparent divide between
large and small countries in the Eurozone appears to be related in part to the differences
in tax treatment in owner-occupied housing. Income tax systems in the smaller
Eurozone countries tend to be more conducive to volatile house prices and this may
have been interacting with the generally higher inflation rates (and hence lower real
interest rates) observed in these countries since the advent of the common currency.
Wolswijk (2006) analyses the effects on mortgage debt growth in the EU of
fiscal instruments. He argues that empirical research on mortgage debt has largely
7
ignored the role of fiscal instruments affecting housing markets and mortgage credit. In
particular, fiscal measures may affect housing-related decisions via the taxation of
imputed rents on own houses, the deductibility of mortgage interest payments from
income tax, and capital gains taxes on the revenue of selling house8. Sorensen &
Lichtenberger (2007) use the tax wedge computed by Van den Noord (2003) to measure
the effects of fiscal factors on mortgage interest rates and find evidence that fiscal
factors affect mortgage interest rates. Tax wedge values are presented in Table 3. The
wedge measures the difference between after-tax and pre-tax mortgage interest rates,
taking into account any deductibility of mortgage interest payments from taxable
income, tax credits, and taxation of imputed income from owner-occupied housing. As
can be seen from Table 3, in most countries a negative tax wedge is found, indicating
that the tax system provides a subsidy.
Insert Table 3
3.
Institutional Characteristics: Cluster Analysis
In this section of the paper we use cluster analysis to form groups of countries
that are broadly homogeneous with respect to the institutional characteristics of their
housing market, mortgage market and tax system. More specifically, we assign
categorical numerical variables to each of those characteristics and use a statistical
clustering algorithm, which determines the groups based on maximising the
commonality of characteristics for countries within each group and maximising the
differences between countries that belong to different groups. The selection of variables
to be included in the analysis is crucial because poor results can derive from misleading
or exclusion of important variables. The initial choice of variables determines the
institutional characteristics that will be used to identify the groups of countries. Table 4
presents the variables included in the formation of groups.
Insert Table 4
Cluster analysis is a particularly appropriate procedure when there is a suspicion
that the sample is not homogeneous. The estimations were obtained using the Ward
method, based on the square of the Euclidean distance, to the indicated variables and for
8
the EU countries9. Figure 1 and Table 5 show the dendrogram obtained based on the
Ward method and the partition of countries in different groups, respectively10. The
analysis results in five groups of countries comprised as follows:
- Group / Cluster I: Germany and Austria;
- Group / Cluster II: Italy and Greece;
- Group / Cluster III: Belgium, France, Luxembourg, Netherlands and Portugal;
- Group / Cluster IV: Denmark, Finland and Sweden;
- Group / Cluster V: Spain, Ireland and U.K.
Insert Figure 1
Insert Tables 5 & 6
In order to consider whether these characteristics relate to the dynamics of the
house prices in each market, Table 6 reports the average real rate of house price
appreciation for each of the markets. In addition, Table 7 and Figure 2 detail the
institutional characteristics across the different markets. The clusters formed by Greece
and Italy and Germany and Austria have features of outliers insofar as always appear in
single clusters. The cluster formed by Italy and Greece is characterized by the existence
of important legal and institutional barriers to the use of housing as collateral. This is
most evident in Italy, where possession proceedings by a mortgage lender to obtain the
title to the property of a borrower in default can take up to 6 years 11. These legal
difficulties appear to be associated with a general lack of competition and efficiency in
the Italian legal system, and perhaps also with lack of rationalisation in the system of
land title registration. This is corroborated by the legal rights index, which shows that it
is in these two countries where lenders are protected the least. The Austria and Germany
cluster is categorised not only by a low rate of owner-occupation but also in that
mortgage equity extraction is extremely low, transaction costs are high and banks’
lending practises (as measured by relatively low LTVs, use of fixed-rate mortgages and
the use of historical property valuation) are more conservative than in the majority of
9
countries. In addition, securitisation in its purest form when transfer of ownership is
involved is almost non-existent.
It can be seen from Table 6 that Austria and Germany are the only two countries
to have had negative real house price over the 1997-2006 period. This is consistent with
the premise that countries with large rental market, such as Austria and Germany, are
less likely to have volatile house prices (e.g. Maclennan et al., 1998). These findings are
in in stark contrast to those reported with respect to the fourth and fifth clusters. The
fourth cluster is comprised of the Scandinavian countries (Denmark, Sweden and
Finland), whilst the fifth contains Ireland, Spain and the U.K. Both of these clusters
have a number of share characteristics including; ability to extract equity, greater
development in securitisation, a generous tax system and lending practices that can be
characterised as more “aggressive”. In addition, in both groups the market value
method, high LTV ratios and floating-rate debt is most popular and the protection of
legal rights of lenders and borrowers and the information system about credit risk of
potential borrowers are well developed. The main attribute that distinguishes groups IV
and V is the weight of house ownership and rental market12. The adoption of less
conservative lending practices by banks associated with a generous tax system, may
lead to greater volatility in housing prices. For Spain, the U.K. and Ireland these factors,
linked to a small rental market, may contribute to enhanced volatility in house prices.
These institutional characteristics may aid in explaining why these three countries
display the highest rate of real house price appreciation across the EU-15 over the
decade from 1997 to 2006. The final grouping is the cluster formed by the Netherlands,
Portugal and the francophone axis (France, Belgium and Luxembourg). In contrast to
the previous group this group have more conservative bank lending practises. These
markets also have both a higher proportion of home ownership and private rented
accommodation than the EU-15 average. This offsetting effect, due to a smaller than
average public rented sector, may explain why these countries have a lower rate of real
house price appreciation in comparison to Clusters IV and V.
Insert Table 7
Insert Figure 2
10
4.
Regime Changes in EU-15 Housing Markets
The second component of this paper is to test for the presence of structural
breaks in the housing markets in the EU-15 and to consider whether any breaks
identified can be linked with changes in policy. We consider possible breaks in both the
rate of growth in real house prices (iph) and real user cost (ruc). To test for possible
breaks we adopt the Bai & Perron (1998, 2001, 2003) framework to detect multiple
structural breaks. Following the approach used in previous papers (e.g. Caporale &
Grier, 2000; Bai & Perron, 2003; Rapach & Wohar, 2005) we regress each previous
series on a constant and test for structural breaks in the constant. Consider such a
regression model with m breaks (m +1 regimes):
𝑟𝑡 = 𝛽𝑗 + 𝜀𝑡, 𝑡 = 𝑇𝑗−1 , … , 𝑇𝑗 ,
(1)
for j = 1, …, m+1, where rt are iph and ruc series in period t and βj (j=1, …,
m+1) is the mean of iph and ruc in the jth regime. The m-partition, (T1,…, Tm),
represents the breakpoints for the different regimes (by convention, T0=0 and Tm+1=T).
Bai & Perron (1998) explicitly treat these breakpoints as unknown, and estimates of the
breakpoints are obtained using the least-squares method. Consider the estimation of
Equation (1) via OLS. For each m-partition, (T1,…,Tm) the least-squares estimates of βj
are obtained by minimizing the sum of squared residuals:
𝑇
𝑗
2
𝑆𝑇 (𝑇1 , … , 𝑇𝑚 ) = ∑𝑚+1
𝑗=1 ∑𝑡=𝑇𝑗−1 +1(𝑟𝑡 − 𝛽𝑗 )
(2)
where, ST represent the sum of squared residuals in m-partition. The regression
coefficient estimates based on a given m-partition, (T1,…,Tm) are denoted by
𝛽̂ ({𝑇1 , … , 𝑇𝑚 }), where 𝛽 = (𝛽1 , … , 𝛽𝑚+1 )′ . Substituting these into Equation (2), the
estimated breakpoints are given by:
(𝑇̂1 , … , 𝑇̂𝑚 ) = arg 𝑚𝑖𝑛𝑇1 ,…,𝑇𝑀 𝑆𝑇 (𝑇1 , … , 𝑇𝑚 ),
(3)
11
The set of admissible m-partitions is subject to a set of restrictions. These
restrictions will be discussed in depth shortly. It is clear from Equation (3) that the
breakpoint estimators correspond to the global minimum of the sum of squared
residuals objective function. After estimating the breakpoint, it is straightforward to
compute the corresponding least-squares regression parameter estimates as 𝛽̂ =
𝛽̂ ({𝑇̂1 , … , 𝑇̂
𝑚 }. Bai & Perron (2001) develop an efficient algorithm for the minimisation
problem in Equation (3) based on the principle of dynamic programming.
Bai and Perron (1998) consider testing procedures aimed at identifying the
number of structural breaks (m) in Equation (1). The authors begin by describing a
statistic to test the null hypothesis of no structural breaks against the alternative
hypothesis that there are m=b breaks. Let (T1,…, Tb) be a partition such that Ti = [Tλi]
(i=1, …, b). Also, define R such that (𝑅𝛽), = (𝛽1 − 𝛽2 , … , 𝛽𝑏 − 𝛽𝑏+1 ). Bai & Perron
(1998) specify the following statistic test:
1 𝑇−(𝑏+1)2
𝐹𝑇 (𝜆1 , … , 𝜆𝑏 ) = (
𝑇
2𝑏
) 𝛽̂ , 𝑅 , [𝑅𝑉̂ (𝛽̂ )𝑅 , ]−1 𝑅𝛽̂ ,
(4)
,
̂1 , … , 𝛽
̂
where 𝛽̂ = (𝛽
𝑏+1 ) is a vector of regression coefficient estimates, and
𝑉̂ (𝛽̂) is a heteroskedastic and autocorrelation consistent estimate of the variance-
covariance matrix for 𝛽̂ . Bai & Perron (1998) next consider a type of maximum Fstatistic corresponding to Equation (4):
̂1 , … , 𝜆̂𝑏 ),
𝑆𝑢𝑝𝐹𝑇 (𝑏) = 𝐹𝑇 (𝜆
(5)
where ̂
𝜆1 , … , 𝜆̂𝑏 minimize the global sum of squared residuals, 𝑆𝑇 (𝑇𝜆1 , … , 𝑇𝜆𝑏 ),
̂1 , … , 𝜆̂𝑏 )𝜖Λ𝜉, where Λ𝜉 = {(𝜆1 , … , 𝜆𝑏 ); |𝜆𝑖+1 − 𝜆𝑖 | ≥
under the restriction that (𝜆
𝜉, 𝜆1 ≥ 𝜉, 𝜆𝑏 ≤ 1 − 𝜉} for some arbitrary positive number, ξ (the trimming parameter).
Bai & Perron (1998) develop two statistics, what they call the “double maximum”
statistics, to test the null hypothesis of no structural breaks against the alternative
12
hypothesis of an unknown number of breaks given an upper bound, M. The first “double
maximum” statistic is given by:
𝑈𝐷𝑚𝑎𝑥 = 𝑚𝑎𝑥1≤𝑚≤𝑀 𝑆𝑢𝑝𝐹𝑇 (𝑚).
(6)
The second “double maximum” statistic, WDMax, applies different weights to the
individual 𝑆𝑢𝑝𝐹𝑇 (𝑚) statistics so that the marginal p-values are equal across values of
m (see Bai & Perron, 1998, page 59 for details). Finally Bai & Perron (1998) specify
what they label the SupFT(l+1\l) statistic to test the null hypothesis of l breaks against
the alternative hypothesis of l+1 breaks. The procedure begins with the global
minimized sum of squared residuals for a model with l breaks. Each of the intervals
defined by the l breaks is then analyzed for an additional break. From all of the
intervals, the partition allowing for an additional break that results in the largest
reduction in the sum of squared residuals is treated as the model with l+1 breaks. The
SupFT(l+1\l) statistic is used to test whether the additional break leads to a significant
reduction in the sum of squared residuals. Bai & Perron (1998, 2003) derive asymptotic
distributions for the “double maximum” and SupFT(l+1\l) statistics and provide critical
values for various values of ξ and M. Although the framework can be adapted to
explicitly incorporate
specific
circumstances
such
as
heteroscedasticity and
autocorrelation in the residuals (Rapach & Wohar, 2005) we adopt the most general
specifications that allows for all of these features.
Bai & Perron (1998) discuss a sequential application of the SupFT(l+1\l)
statistics –a specific-to-general modeling strategy- as a way to determine the number of
structural breaks. While Bai & Perron (2001) find that this procedure performs well in
some settings, on the basis of Monte Carlo simulations, they recommend the following
strategy to identify the number of breaks. First, examine the “double maximum”
statistics to determine if any structural break is present. If the “double maximum”
statistics are significant, then examine the sequence of SupFT(l+1\l) statistics to decide
on the number of breaks. Bai & Perron (2001) recommend using a trimming parameter
of least 0.15 (corresponding to M=5) when allowing for heteroskedasticity and serial
correlation, and we follow this recommendation for our application.
13
The aforementioned tests are examined using both the growth rate in real house
prices (iph) and real user cost (ruc). The choice of these two variables is due to the
depth and availability of information, the degree of housing market representativeness
and the fact that they tend to capture the impacts of policy changes on the housing
market. The rationale behind considering the real user cost is that it allows for the
possibility that mortgage interest payments are tax deductible13. Hort (1998) calculates
the real user cost based on the following formula:
[(1-ti)*i-πe+th+δ]
(7)
where ti is the marginal rate of income tax, in each country, i is the interest rate
on the interbank money market, πe is the expected inflation rate, approximated by the
arithmetic mean of the current inflation rate and the previous year inflation rate, th is the
effective property tax rate and δ the property depreciation rate. The depreciation rate is
estimated as suggested by Ott (2006) as:
σt= [GFCFt – (NCSt – NCSt-1)]/NCSt-1
(8)
where GFCF and NCS refer to Gross Fixed Capital Formation and Net Fixed
Capital Stock respectively. The sample is not balanced and the depth of each individual
series depends on the information availability. The house price data was obtained from
the Bank of International Settlements. For the remaining variables used, inflation is
based on the respective Consumer Price Index, the marginal rate of income tax and
property tax details are obtained from the OECD and the GFCF and NCS series were
obtained from EUROSTAT and the European Mortgage Federation. For the interest rate
series we use the appropriate 3 month interbank rate as obtained from the ECB.
Hofmann (2001) for the Eurozone and Hofmann & Mizen (2004) for the U.K. show that
interbank rates are good proxies of loan rates14.
Tables 8 and 9 present the results of structural breaks for each of the EU-15
countries. In the case of Germany, Denmark, Italy and Luxembourg “double maximum”
statistics are not significant at conventional levels. For Spain, the Netherlands, Portugal
14
and Sweden there is only evidence of structural changes in one of the series. The F(2|1)
statistic shows statistical significance for the iph series’ of Austria and Spain and the
ruc series of both Finland and the Netherlands, whilst the F(3|2) statistic is statistically
insignificant. This therefore indicates that two structural breaks (three regimes) are
present in the series of the countries mentioned. For Belgium, Greece, Ireland and U.K.,
the F(1|0) statistic is statistical significant for both series, while the F(2|1) statistic
shows statistically insignificant. These results indicate the existence of one structural
break (two regimes) for these countries. The same conclusion is obtained for the ruc
series of Austria, Sweden and iph series of Finland and Portugal.
Insert Tables 8 & 9
Maclennan et al. (1998), ECB (2003) and Hilbers et al. (2008), among others,
illustrate how policy changes may affect the housing market. Figure 3 illustrates some
of the different channels (e.g. fiscal, prudential, monetary and structural policies)
through which these effects may flow. Based on the policy changes identified in ECB
(2003) and Wolswijk (2006), Table 10 presents a list of reforms that have taken place in
the EU-15 since the mid-eighties. In turn, Table 11 presents the dates of the structural
breaks in the two series and the 95% confidence intervals. Based on policy changes
identified in ECB (2003) and Wolswijk (2006) a number of the structural break dates
are relatively close to points in time when there were changes in policy in housing,
mortgage financing or tax. As can be seen from Table 11 a majority of the policy
changes identified can be associated structural regime changes in the housing market.
The Bai & Perron (1998, 2001 and 2003) methodology, which is based on “a purely
data-driven procedure” in the selection of structural breaks dates, seems to confirm the
existence of a linkage between policy changes and structural changes on housing market
series.
Insert Figure 3
Insert Tables 10 & 11
It should however be noted that not all policy changes have resulted in structural
breaks on housing market series. As is clear from Figure 3, the housing prices
developments is the result of a number of factors, and the effects of a particular policy
does not produce always the desired effects by the authorities because some of them are
15
mitigated by adverse effects caused by other policies. The reasons why reform measures
may not have caused a structural break can be attributed to a combination of factors: (1)
a lack of coverage in the series analysed during the emergence of these reforms, (2)
some of these reform measures may result in a lagged effect, in temporal terms, (3) the
possible existence of a mismatch between the objectives of the legislator/regulator and
the practical results of implemented policy, which can lead that final objectives pursued
by the reform measure be far short of the intended15 and (4) the authorities desired
effects may arise mitigated by adverse effects caused by other policies.
5.
Conclusion
This study contributes to the housing literature in two ways: firstly, by studying
the importance of institutional characteristics associated to rental and home ownership
market, financial mortgage market and tax system in house prices behaviour and
secondly, through the endogenous determination of structural breaks in the housing
market across the EU countries. We develop an analysis of clusters which reveals
significant differences in terms of institutional characteristics across the EU-15
countries. Five clusters emerge. The cluster formed by Spain, Ireland and the United
Kingdom, with a less conservative mortgage credit system, a sparse rental market and a
generous fiscal system. This is not particularly surprising given the high house price
appreciation observed prior to 2007 in these countries. On the other extreme, a second
cluster characterized by conservative mortgage credit system, a large rental market and
a less generous fiscal system is formed by Germany and Austria. In contrast to the
aforementioned cluster these countries have negative house prices growth.
The second key aim of this study is the determination of endogenous structural
breaks for two series relating to the EU-15 housing markets. The fact that many of the
structural breaks dates are quite close to finance mortgage market, tax system and/or
rental and house ownership market policy changes suggests that the breaks have a
policy change cause and that countries have changed policies concurrently. The results
also show that not all policy changes have resulted in structural breaks. This situation
can be explained by the fact that not all policy reforms have been structural for housing
market or have been mitigated by adverse effects caused by other policies. In this way
16
further studies on house prices determinants should take account the institutional
characteristics differences across EU countries and the regime changes in housing
markets, for there is not the risk of obtaining biased results.
17
References
[1]
Adams, Zeno e Füss, Roland, 2010, “Macroeconomic Determinants of
International Housing Markets”, Journal of Housing Economics, 19: 38-50.
[2]
Bai, Jushan and Perron, Pierre, 1998, “Estimating and Testing Linear Models
with Multiple Structural Changes”, Econometrica, 66 (1): 47-68.
[3]
Bai, Jushan and Perron, Pierre, 2001, “Multiple Structural Change Models: A
Simulation Analysis”, Econometric Theory and Practice: Frontiers of Analysis and
Applied Research, 212-237.
[4]
Bai, Jushan and Perron, Pierre, 2003, “Computation and Analysis of Multiple
Structural Change Models”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 18: 1-22.
[5]
Calza, Alessandro, Monacelli, Tommaso and Stracca, Livio, 2007, “Mortgage
Markets, Collateral Constraints, and Monetary Policy: Do Institutional Factors
Matter?”, CEPR Discussion Paper n.º DP6231, April.
[6]
Campbell, John and Cocco, João, 2007, “How Do Home Prices Affect
Consumption? Evidence From Micro Data”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 54 (3):
591-621.
[7]
Caporale, Tony and Grier, Kevin, 2000, “Political Regime Change and the Real
Interest Rate”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 32 (3): 320-334.
[8]
DiPasquale, Denise e Wheaton, William, 1992, “The Markets for Real Estate
Assets and Space: a Conceptual Framework”, American Real Estate and Urban
Association Journal, 20 (1): 161-180.
[9]
Englund, Peter e Ioannides, Yannis, 1997, “House Price Dynamics: An
International Empirical Perspective”, Journal of Housing Economics, 6: 119-136.
[10]
European Central Bank, 2003, “Structural Factors in the EU Housing Markets”,
ECB, March, 2003 (http://www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/other/euhousingmarketsen.pdf).
[11]
Giuliodori, Massimo, 2005, “The Role of House Prices in the Monetary
Transmission Mechanism Across European Countries”, Scottish Journal of Political
Economy, 52 (4): 519-543.
[12]
Guiso, Luigi, Jappelli, Tullio and Terlizzese, Daniele, 1992, “Saving and Capital
Market Imperfections: The Italian Experience”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 94
(2): 197-213.
18
[13]
Hilbers, Paul, Hoffmaister, Alexander, Banerji, Angana and Shi, Haiyan, 2008,
“House Price Developments in Europe: A Comparison”, International Monetary Fund,
wp/08/211:1-64.
[14]
Hofmann, Boris, 2001, “The Pass-Through of Money Market Rates to Loans
Rates in the Euro-Area”, ZEI, University of Bonn, mimeo.
[15]
Hofmann, Boris and Mizen, Paul, 2004, “Interest Rate Pass-Through and
Monetary Transmission: Evidence From Individual Financial Institutions’ Retail Rates”,
Economica, 71 (281): 99-123.
[16]
Holmans, Alan, 1994, “House Prices, Land Prices, the Housing Market and
House Purchase Debt in the U.K. and Other Countries”, Economic Modelling, 11(2):
157–99.
[17]
Hort, Katinka, 1998, “The Determinants of Urban House Price Fluctuations in
Sweden 1968-1994”, Journal of Housing Economics, 7: 93-120.
[18]
Iacoviello, Matteo, 2000. “House Prices and the Macroeconomy in Europe:
Results from a Structural VAR Analysis”, European Central Bank (ECB), working
paper nº. 18, April.
[19]
Lieser, Karsten and Groh, Alexander, 2010, “The Attractiveness of 66 Countries
for Institutional Real Estate Investments: A Composite Index Approach”, working
paper, July 10, 2010 (http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1638286)
[20]
Maclennan,
Duncan,
Muellbauer,
John
and
Stephens,
Mark,
1998,
“Asymmetries in Housing and Financial Market Institutions and EMU”, Oxford Review
of Economic Policy, 14 (3): 54-80.
[21]
Martins, António, Serra, Ana, Martins, Francisco and Stevenson, Simon, 2014,
“Residential Property Loans and Bank Performance during Property Price Booms:
Evidence from Europe”, working paper, School of Real Estate & Planning, University
of Reading.
[22]
McCrone, Gavin and Stephens, Mark, 1995, Housing Policy in Britain and
Europe, London, UCL Press.
[23]
Miles, David and Pillonca, Vladimir, 2008, “Financial Innovation and European
Housing and Mortgage Markets”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 24 (1): 145-175.
[24]
Muellbauer, John and Murphy, Anthony, 2008, “Housing Markets and the
Economy: the Assessment”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 24 (1): 1-33.
19
[25]
Ott, Hervé, 2007, “Are Euro Area House Prices Overvalued? An Asset Pricing
Approach”, In Three Empirical Essays on House Prices in the Euro Area (Doctoral
dissertation
at
University of
Munich)
and
available
at
(http://edoc.ub.uni-
muenchen.de/6800/1/Ott_Herve.pdf).
[26]
Poterba, James, 1984, “Tax Subsidies to Owner-Occupied Housing: An Asset-
Market Approach”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 99 (4): 729-752.
[27]
Poterba, James, 1991, “House Price Dynamics: The Role of Tax Policy and
Demography”, Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 1/1991: 143-203.
[28]
Rapach, David and Wohar, Mark, 2005, “Regime Changes in International Real
Interest Rates: Are They a Monetary Phenomenon?”, Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, 37 (5): 887-906.
[29]
Sorensen, Christoffer and Lichtenberger, Jung-Duk, 2007, “Mortgage Interest
Rate Dispersion in the Euro Area”, European Central Bank, working paper n.º 733,
February.
[30]
Tsatsaronis, Kostas and Zhu, Haibin, 2004, “What Drives Housing Price
Dynamics: Cross Country Evidence” BIS Quarterly Review, March.
[31]
Van den Noord, Paul, 2003, “Tax Incentives and House Price Volatility in the
Euro Area: Theory and Evidence”, OECD Economics Department, working paper n.º
356.
[32]
Warnock, Veronica and Warnock, Francis, 2008, “Markets and Housing
Finance”, Journal of Housing Economics, 17 (3): 239-251.
[33]
Wolswijk, Guido, 2006, “Determinants of Mortgage Debt Growth in EU
Countries”, European Journal of Housing Policy, 6, (2): 131-149.
20
Table 1: EU-15 Rental Market and House Ownership
The table shows the weight of house ownership, social rented market and private rented market and other types
of accommodation, as a percentage of the total dwelling stock, for the EU-15 countries. The values refer to 2007
and were obtained from Global Property website (www.globalpropertyguide.com) and European Mortgage
Federation (Hypostat 2008 - A Review of Europe's Mortgage and Housing Markets, November). In the last
column comes the legal rights index of landlords and tenants. This index gives the amount of control the landlord
has over his property, measured on a five-point rating scale: strongly pro-landlord = 2; pro-landlord = 1; neutral
= 0; pro-tenant = -1 and strongly pro-tenant = -2. This index is available on the website of Global Property
(Global Property Guide's Landlord and Tenant Rating System).
Landlord and
Owner
Social Rented
Private
Occupied (%)
(%)
Rented (%)
Austria
54
20
18
7
-1
Belgium
68
7
23
2
-1
Denmark
52
20
26
2
-2
Finland
57
17
16
10
0
France
54
21
17
8
-2
Germany
42
10
48
0
-1
Greece
81
0
16
3
0
Ireland
77
9
9
5
-1
Italy
68
6
18
8
-1
Luxembourg
70
0
26
4
-2
Netherlands
54
35
11
0
-1
Portugal
76
3
21
0
-1
Spain
82
2
10
6
-2
Sweden
39
22
22
17
-2
United Kingdom
67
23
10
0
1
62.8
13.0
19.4
4.8
-
Country
EU – 15
Other (%)
Tenant Rating
System
21
Table 2: Characteristics of Mortgage Markets in EU-15
The table shows five different characteristics of mortgage market: the interest rate prevailing in the
mortgage market (fixed or variable), the possibility of equity extraction (mortgage equity withdrawal), the
maximum loan-to-value (LTV) ratio, the property valuation method and the depth of the securitization
market, respectively. The values were obtained from the European Mortgage Federation.
1
F = Fixed mortgage rates (fixed mortgage rate for more than 5 years or at the end of maturity); V =
Variable mortgage rates (after one year, the mortgage rate is renegotiable) or mixed (fixed rate for more
than one year to 5 years). The classification is based on the majority of mortgage loans. 2 ML = Mortgage
Lending Value; OM = Open Market Value. 3Y = Yes and N = No. 4Securitisation was introduced at
certain stage but remained very limited. 5 N = Nonexistence of a legal limit on the LTV ratio. 6 The
maximum LTV is 80%, but tends to be reduced the loans leverage. Guiso et al. (1992) report for example,
that in Italy possession proceedings by a mortgage lender to obtain the title to the property of a borrower
in default can take up to 6 years, for what the banks tend to provide customers with a lower leverage,
which translates into reduced LTV ratios.
Country
Interest Rate
Adjustment1
Mortgage
Maximum
Equity
Withdrawal
LTV ratio
3
(%)
5
Valuation
Method2
Securitization
(Mortgagebaked)
Austria
F
N
80-100
ML
N4
Belgium
F
N
N
OM
N4
Denmark
F
Y
80
ML
N
Finland
V
Y
N
OM
N4
France
F
N
80
OM
N4
Germany
F
N
80
ML
N4
Greece
V
Y
N
OM
N4
Ireland
V
Y
N
OM
Y
Italy
F
N
80-1006
OM
Y
Luxembourg
V
N
N
OM
N4
Netherlands
F
Y
N
OM
Y
Portugal
V
N
N
OM
Y
Spain
V
Y
80
OM
Y
Sweden
V
Y
N
OM
N4
United Kingdom
V
Y
N
OM
Y
22
Table 3: Others Institutional Characteristics of Housing Market
The table presents the “typical” duration of enforcement procedure (in months); the usual length of
mortgage contracts (in years); the estimated average value of loan-to-value (LTV) ratio and the value of
the Tax Wedge (difference between after-tax and pre-tax mortgage interest rates, taking into account
deductibility of mortgage interest payments from taxable income, tax credits, and taxation of imputed
income from owner-occupied housing), respectively for the EU-15. The values were obtained from the
European Mortgage Federation, except the Tax Wedge, whose values were calculated by the authors
based on the study of Van den Noord (2003) and information collected from the International Bureau of
Fiscal Documentation (2008).
1
“Typical Duration (in months) of a forced sale procedure (without incident)” - European Mortgage
Federation (2007).
Typical Duration of a
Usual Length of
Estimated Average
forced sale
Mortgage Contracts
Value of LTV ratio
1
(years)
(%)
Country
procedure (months)
Tax Wedge
Austria
6
25
60
-0.56
Belgium
18
20
80-85
0
Denmark
6
30
80
-0.69
Finland
2-3
15-20
75-80
-0.90
France
8-18
15-20
78
0
Germany
6-12
20-30
67
0
Greece
3-24
15
55
1.58
Ireland
18-24
20
80
-0.94
Italy
60-84
5-20
55
-0.53
Luxembourg
5
20-25
80
-0.96
Netherlands
4-6
30
87
-2.03
Portugal
18-30
25-30
83
-0.23
Spain
7-9
15-20
70
-0.93
Sweden
4-6
30-45
80-95
-1.26
United Kingdom
8-12
25
69
0
23
Table 4: List of Institutional Characteristics Used in the Formation of Clusters
The following table shows the list of institutional characteristics used in the formation of clusters, divided by three areas of analysis: the rental and house ownership market, financial
mortgage market and tax system. For each different institutional feature we present the variable definition, a summary of papers highlighting its importance and its source. 1Use of
dummy variables in the formation of cluster.
Variable
Authors
Definition/Importance
Source
Rental and House Ownership Market
ECB (2003)
Maclennan et al. (1998)
Lieser and Groh (2010)
ECB (2003)
Maclennan et al. (1998)
ECB (2003)
Maclennan et al. (1998)
ECB (2003)
Maclennan et al. (1998)
Lieser and Groh (2010)
Landlord and Tenant
Rating System
Weight of Rental Market
Weight of House
Ownership Market
Transaction Costs
This index gives the amount of control the landlord has over his property, measured on a
five-point rating scale: strongly pro-landlord = 2; pro-landlord = 1; neutral = 0; protenant = -1 and strongly pro-tenant = -2.
Weight of Rental Market, as a percentage of the total dwelling stock.
Weight of House Ownership Market, as a percentage of the total dwelling stock.
Average value of house transaction costs (as a percentage of house value), including
registration costs, real estate agents’ commissions, legal fees and sale and transfer taxes.
Global Property (Global Property
Guide’s Landlord and Rating
System)
European Mortgage Federation
(Hypostat Series)
European Mortgage Federation
(Hypostat Series)
European Mortgage Federation
(Study on Cost of Housing in
Europe – Hypostat Series)
Financial Mortgage Market
Interest Rate Adjustement
1
Tsatsaronis and Zhu (2004)
Maclennan et al. (1998)
Calza et al. (2007)
Securitization1
Tsatsaronis and Zhu (2004)
Calza et al. (2007)
Mortgage Equity
Withdrawal1
Tsatsaronis and Zhu (2004)
Calza et al. (2007)
Property Valuation
Method1
Weight of Real Estate
Investment Funds
The interest rate prevailing in the mortgage market: 1 = Fixed mortgage rates (fixed
mortgage rate for more than 5 years or at the end of maturity); 0 = Variable mortgage
rates (after one year, the mortgage rate is renegotiable) or mixed (fixed rate for more
than one year to 5 years). The classification is based on the majority of mortgage loans.
Existence and depth of the securitization market. 1 = Nonexistence of securitization or
proves to be very limited, 0 = otherwise.
Possibility of Equity Extraction ("Mortgage Equity withdrawal"). If liquidity-constrained
agents could adjust their net borrowing positions or to refinance the terms of their
existing mortgages according to the changed conditions. 0 = nonused or reduced use. 1 =
used.
Tsatsaronis and Zhu (2004)
Usual Property Valuation Method: Mortgage Lending Value or Open Market Value.
0 = open market value; 1 = mortgage lending value.
Warnock and Warnock
(2008)
Weight of Real Estate Investment Funds in Investment Funds Sector.
European Mortgage Federation
(Study on Interest Rate Variability
in Europe– Hypostat Series)
European Mortgage Federation
(Study on the Efficiency of the
Mortgage Collateral in the
European Union– Hypostat
Series)
European Mortgage Federation
(The Valuation of Property for
Lending Purposes– Hypostat
Series)
EFAMA (Trends in European
Investment Funds)
Table 4: List of Institutional Characteristics Used in the Formation of Clusters (continuation)
Variable
Authors
Definition/Importance
Source
Financial Mortgage Market
LTV Ratio
Tsatsaronis and Zhu (2004)
Sorensen and
Lichtenberger (2007)
Calza et al. (2007)
Credit Info Index
Warnock and Warnock
(2008)
Lieser and Groh (2010)
Legal Rights for
Borrowers and Lenders
Index
Warnock and Warnock
(2008)
Lieser and Groh (2010)
Typical Duration of
Enforcement Procedure
Sorensen and
Lichtenberger (2007)
Lieser and Groh (2010)
Estimated average value of loan-to-value (LTV) ratio.
Credit Info index measures the depth of credit information about potential borrowers that
lenders access from standardized and informative sources of credit information. The
index ranges from 0 to 6, with higher values indicating the availability of more credit
information.
Legal Rights for Borrowers and Lenders Index measures the strength of legal rights for
borrowers and lenders. The index is composed of ten categories, seven of which pertain
to collateral law and three pertain to bankruptcy law. A score 1 is assigned if each
feature is present in the country, so that the Legal Rights index ranges from 0 to 10 with
higher scores indicating that collateral and bankruptcy laws are better designed to expand
access to credit.
Usual duration of the procedure to enforce the collateral by the lender, in the case of
borrower default.
European Mortgage Federation
(Study on Cost of Housing in
Europe – Hypostat Series)
World Bank (Doing Business
Database)
World Bank (Doing Business
Database)
European Mortgage Federation
(Typical Duration of a forced sale
procedure (without incident))
Tax System
Tax Wedge
Van den Noord (2003)
Tax wedge measures the difference between after-tax and pre-tax mortgage interest rates,
taking into account deductibility of mortgage interest payments from taxable income, tax
credits, and taxation of imputed income from owner-occupied housing. The existence of
a negative tax wedge indicates that the tax system provides a subsidy.
Tax on Imputed Rent
Maclennan et al. (1998)
Wolswijk (2006)
Existence on tax system of Tax on Imputed Rent. (1 = No; 0 = Yes)
International Bureau of Fiscal
Documentation (2008)
Deductibility of Mortgage
Interest Payments1
Maclennan et al. (1998)
Wolswijk (2006)
Possibility of deductibility of mortgage interest payments from taxable income. (1 = No;
0 = Yes)
International Bureau of Fiscal
Documentation (2008)
Tax on Capital Gains
Maclennan et al. (1998)
Wolswijk (2006)
Effective tax rate on capital gains, assuming the validity of the assumptions listed in note
14 of Table 7.
International Bureau of Fiscal
Documentation (2008)
International Bureau of Fiscal
Documentation (2008)
25
Table 5: Clusters
This table shows the clusters formed by the methods of the farthest neighbour and Ward based on 17
variables listed in Table 4, relating to the rental and house ownership market, financial mortgage market and
tax system. Based on the dendrogram obtained we classify EU-15 countries into five groups on the basis of
these characteristics. # denotes the number of countries groups/clusters.
“Farthest Neighbour” Method
Ward Method
# Clusters
# Clusters
3
4
5
6
3
4
5
6
Germany
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
Austria
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
Belgium
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
Denmark
1
3
3
3
3
3
3
3
Spain
2
3
5
3
3
3
5
4
Finland
1
3
3
3
3
3
3
3
France
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
Greece
3
4
4
6
2
4
4
5
Netherlands
2
2
2
4
2
2
2
6
Ireland
2
3
5
3
3
3
5
4
Italy
3
4
4
6
2
4
4
5
Luxembourg
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
Portugal
2
2
2
4
2
2
2
6
United
1
3
5
5
3
3
5
4
1
3
3
3
3
3
3
3
Kingdom
Sweden
Table 6: Real House Price Growth Rate (%)
This table shows the real house prices growth rate across EU-15 countries, for three different time periods: 1997
to 2001, 2002 to 2006 and from 1997 to 2006.
Country
Real House Price Growth Rate (%)
1997-2001
2002-2006
1997-2006
Austria
-18.14%
13.37%
-7.20%
Belgium
27.40%
55.47%
98.07%
Denmark
23.82%
56.03%
93.20%
Finland
19.00%
46.25%
74.04%
France
28.56%
63.57%
110.29%
Germany
-5.32%
-6.68%
-10.63%
Greece
28.33%
35.13%
73.40%
Ireland
65.41%
49.37%
147.07%
Italy
21.50%
32.02%
60.57%
Luxembourg
24.36%
39.57%
72.53%
Netherlands
58.89%
16.25%
84.71%
Portugal
15.32%
-7.06%
7.18%
Spain
27.25%
70.45%
116.90%
Sweden
38.76%
45.10%
101.33%
United Kingdom
51.62%
57.09%
138.19%
EU-15 (mean)
27.12%
37.73%
73.31
Source: Authors’ construction using data from the Bank for International Settlements (BIS).
27
Table 7: Clusters: Average Values of Variables
This table presents the average values of the 17 variables listed in Table 5, relating to the rental and house
ownership market, financial mortgage market and tax system, for each cluster formed. Cluster I: Germany
and Austria. Cluster II: Italy and Greece. Cluster III: France, Belgium, Luxembourg, Netherlands and
Portugal. Cluster IV: Sweden, Denmark and Finland. Cluster V: Ireland, United Kingdom and Spain.
Variable
Cluster I
Cluster II
Cluster III
Cluster IV
Cluster V
Financial Mortgage Market
Average Loan-to-Value Ratio (%)
Credit Information1
Legal Rights2
Interest Rate3
Mortgage Equity Withdrawal4
Securitization5
Weight of Real Estate Investment
Funds6
Valuation Method7
Enforcement Procedure8
63.50
6.00
6.50
1.00
0.00
1.00
55.00
4.50
3.00
0.50
0.50
0.50
82.10
3.40
5.60
0.60
0.20
0.60
81.66
4.33
6.67
0.33
1.00
1.00
73.00
5.66
8.00
0.00
1.00
0.00
4.18
3.07
10.12
0.00
1.83
1.00
7.50
0.00
42.75
0.00
13.00
0.33
4.50
0.00
13.00
Rental and House Ownership Market
9
Private Rent (%)
House Ownership (%)9
Landlord and Tenant Rating
System10
Transaction Costs (%)11
33.00
48.00
17.00
74.50
19.60
64.40
21.33
49.33
9.66
75.33
-1.00
-0.50
-1.40
-1.33
-0.66
11.64
16.24
14.90
7.91
8.05
Fiscal System
12
Tax Wedge
Deductibility of Mortgage Interest
Payments From Taxable Income13
Tax on Capital Gains14
Tax on Imputed Rent15
-0.28
0.53
-0.64
-0.95
-0.62
0.50
0.00
0.20
0.00
0.33
0.00
1.00
0.00
0.50
4.84
0.40
29.47
1.00
26.52
1.00
28
Table 8 – Bai and Perron (1998, 2003) Test Results: Real House Prices
Growth Rate
The table presents the Bai and Perron (1998, 2003) statistics of multiple structural breaks in the mean of
the real house prices growth rate (iph), across EU-15 countries. *, ** and *** indicate significance at the
10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. a One-sided (upper-tail) test of the null hypothesis of 0 breaks
against the alternative hypothesis of an unknown number of the breaks given an upper bound of 5. b Onesided (upper-tail) test of the null hypothesis of 0 breaks against the alternative hypothesis of an unknown
number of the breaks given an upper bound of 5. c One-sided (upper-tail) test of the null hypothesis of l
breaks against the alternative hypothesis of l+1 breaks; F(1\0), l=0; F(2\1), l=1; F(3\2), l=2. – indicates
that there was no more place to insert an additional break given the minimal length requirement.
Country
UDmaxa
WDmax (5%)b
F(1\0)c
F(2\1)c
F(3\2)c
Austria
17.18*
19.74**
17.18*
13.47**
4.36
Belgium
7.56***
11.79**
7.33***
2.37
--
Denmark
7.02
9.60
7.02
--
--
Finland
36.01*
51.83**
13.59*
6.24
--
France
5.53
9.23
5.53
--
--
Germany
6.28
9.46
6.28
--
--
Greece
9.14**
18.52**
8.80**
3.014
--
Ireland
24.62*
45.06**
8.11***
4.23
--
Italy
5.75
7.67
5.75
--
--
Luxembourg
5.50
7.41
5.50
--
--
Netherlands
6.68
9.40
6.68
--
--
Portugal
19.17*
30.36**
10.44**
7.02
--
Spain
22.90*
40.98**
22.90*
13.48**
7.20
Sweden
5.20
7.32
5.20
--
--
United
16.65*
24.11**
16.65*
4.54
--
Kingdom
29
Table 9 – Bai and Perron (1998, 2003) Test Results: Real House User Cost
Rate
The table presents the Bai and Perron (1998, 2003) statistics of multiple structural breaks in the mean of
the real house user cost rate (ruc), across EU-15 countries. *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 10%,
5% and 1% levels, respectively. a One-sided (upper-tail) test of the null hypothesis of 0 breaks against the
alternative hypothesis of an unknown number of the breaks given an upper bound of 5. b One-sided
(upper-tail) test of the null hypothesis of 0 breaks against the alternative hypothesis of an unknown
number of the breaks given an upper bound of 5. c One-sided (upper-tail) test of the null hypothesis of l
breaks against the alternative hypothesis of l+1 breaks; F(1\0), l=0; F(2\1), l=1; F(3\2), l=2. – indicates
that there was no more place to insert an additional break given the minimal length requirement.
Country
UDmaxa
WDmax (5%)b
F(1\0)c
F(2\1)c
F(3\2)c
Austria
38.14*
83.68**
7.66***
4.50
-
Belgium
30.28*
63.61**
7.99***
2.73
-
Denmark
4.16
7.66
4.16
-
-
Finland
18.71*
21.86**
18.71*
9.58***
9.57
France
3.09
4.22
4.22
-
-
Germany
4.62
9.55
4.62
-
-
Greece
24.40*
44.16**
15.03*
2.29
-
Ireland
34.55*
58.5**
21.73*
6.46
-
Italy
7.00
9.72
7.00
-
-
Luxembourg
3.76
5.86
3.76
-
-
Netherlands
36.99*
63.92**
15.33*
8.60***
8.60
Portugal
4.32
8.25
4.32
-
-
Spain
6.51
8.51
6.51
-
-
Sweden
168.62*
370.00**
20.30*
3.72
-
United
31.68*
37.65**
16.13*
2.26
-
Kingdom
30
Table 10 – Major Reforms in the EU-15 Housing Markets
The table presents major housing tax and subsidies reforms in the house ownership and rental market and
major financial deregulation measures in EU-15, starting in the 70’s, which have not resulted in a break of
the series analyzed . The list of these reforms is based ECB (2003) and Wolswijk (2006).
Country/Start
of Series
Reform Measures
Interest rate deregulation in the 1970s.
1983: Introduction of upper limit of 30% in a three-year period on rent increases for sitting
tenants; rent escalation clauses and rent contracts linked to a price index permitted.
Germany
(1975 Q4)
1987: Abolishment of tax on imputed rent, end of interest deductibility, introduction of tax
credit for redemption.
1996: Replacement of fiscal subsidies by non-fiscal subsidy.
2001: Upper limit on rent increases in a three-year period reduced to 20%. Period of
giving notice for tenants reduced to three months.
Austria
(1986 Q3)
1980: Liberalization of interest rates.
1981: Abolition of credit controls.
1994: “Indicative value rent system” introduced.
1984: Rent increases linked to CPI.
1985-1987: Indexation temporarily suspended.
Belgium
(1981 Q1)
1987: Abandoning of interest setting for deposits.
1991: Freely negotiated new rental fixed term contracts introduced.
1992: Law permitting an introduction of variable interest rate loans (“referenced loans”)
and reducing the maximum early repayment fee.
1990s: Wave of mergers and privatizations in the banking sector.
1982: Liberalization of mortgage contracts and interest rate setting.
Denmark
Early 1990s: Liberalization of mortgage contract terms and free access to withdrawal of
net equity in house and flats.
(1972 Q1)
1997: Adjustable rate loans introduced.
1998/99: Standard instead of marginal tax rate for interest deductibility. Imputed rent
substituted by a property tax.
Early 1980s: Abolition of differences in the activities permitted for different types of
banks.
Spain
1985: Freely negotiated rents in new agreements.
(1987 Q1)
1992: Securitization of mortgage loans introduced.
1995: Minimum lease of five years (at tenant’s option); CPI indexation. One-off updating
of existing contracts (to be implemented over ten years).
Finland
(1978 Q1)
1993: Substantial reduction of mortgage interest relief tax rate.
1984: Bank specialization requirements reduced.
1987: Elimination of credit controls.
France
1997: New contracts liberalised.
(1980 Q2)
1997/98: Abolishment of mortgage interest tax relief.
1999: Reform of securitization of mortgage loans.
1999: Reduced limits on early repayment fees.
31
Table 10 – Major Reforms in the EU-15 Housing Markets (continuation)
Country/Start
of Series
Greece
(1994 Q1)
Netherlands
(1976 Q4)
Ireland
(1975 Q1 and
1978 Q1)
Reform Measures
1985-1992: Gradual liberalization of quantitative constraints, interest rates and other terms
and conditions on housing loans.
1997: Freely negotiated rents in new contracts. Minimum duration of contracts of three
years.
1980: Interest rate deregulation.
1984: Formal guidelines for bank lending to private sector ended.
1985: Interest rate deregulation.
1986: Elimination of credit controls.
1991-1999: Reductions in the primary liquidity ratio from 8% to 2%.
1983: Interest rate deregulation.
1983: Credit ceilings eliminated (and temporarily re-imposed in 1986 and 1987).
1990: Abolition of administrative controls on branching.
1992: Freely negotiated rents in new agreements.
Italy
1993: Introduction of municipal property tax.
(1988 Q2)
1994: Separation of long-term and short-term credit institutions abolished.
1995: Increase of legally maximum LTV from 75% to 80% (can be raised to 100% if other
guarantees are posted).
1998: Two types of “free” contracts: freely negotiated at the individual level at the start
and contracts where yearly rent increases are collectively negotiated by landlords
and tenants.
Luxembourg
(1975 Q1)
1987: Increases in the rents of dwellings built before 10 September 1944 and clarification
of the meaning of invested capital for those built after this date.
1990s: Increase in the amount of mortgage interest deductible from income taxes;
Registration tax regime made more favourable.
1981: Freely negotiated rent contracts for new tenancies introduced (but no indexation
allowed in these contracts).
Portugal
(1988 Q1)
1983: Easing of entry restrictions in the banking and insurance sector.
1985: Mechanism of updating all rents with CPI; one-off updating of old contracts (but
still remaining very distant to rents in new contracts).
1990: Possibility of setting a limit on the duration of rental contracts.
2006: New Urban Lease Act.
United
Kingdom
1980: Removal of credit controls. Banks permitted to lend mortgages.
(1968 Q2 and
1973 Q1)
1987: Securitization introduced.
1986: Building societies allowed expanding their lending business.
1988: Assured tenancy – eviction easier and initial rent and indexation negotiated.
1983: Mortgage institutions freer to issue bonds for refinancing of old dwellings.
Sweden
(1986 Q1)
1985: Loan ceilings for banks abolished.
1986: Portfolio regulations on insurance companies dropped.
1991: Introduction of analytical income tax, reduction of tax rate for interest deduction,
abolishment of tax on imputed rent, introduction of a property tax.
32
Table 11 – EU-15 Housing Market Structural Breaks and Policies Measures
Table 11 shows the number and dates of structural breaks for the mean of real house prices growth rate (iph) and real house user cost rate (ruc), across EU-15 countries. In the determination of
regime changes is adopted the Bai and Perron (1998 and 2003) methodology. Based on this procedure are estimated the periods of breaks in house market series and their confidence intervals
for a confidence level of 95%. The institutional factors (policies measures) that explain regime changes are obtained on the website www.globalpropertyguide.com, ECB (2003) and Wolswijk
(2006). (+) And (-) indicates if on average house prices or interest rate increased (decreased) during the regime period.
Country
Germany
Austria
Belgium
Denmark
Spain
Series
Series Start
Breaks
iph
1975 Q4
No
ruc
1975 Q4
No
iph
Confidence Interval
Policies Measures
Prices in Vienna increased nearly 150% during this period, due to positive developments
in Eastern Europe, increased immigration and the expansion of home ownership.
Prudential reforms, capital requirements tightened and end of interest rate cartel.
Beginning of privatization of state-owned banks. Partial liberalization of new tenancies.
1992 Q2 (+)
[1987 Q1; 1994 Q4]
2001 Q4 (-)
[1999 Q3; 2003 Q3]
End of the immigration flow, reducing the optimism of economic agents and an oversupply in housing market.
1986 Q3
ruc
1986 Q3
1998 Q3 (-)
[1998 Q1; 2005 Q4]
Eurozone process adhesion.
iph
1981 Q1
2003 Q1 (+)
[2001 Q1; 2007 Q2]
High Growth of Housing Market caused by increased competition among banks and by
interest rate reduction.
ruc
1981 Q1
2003 Q1 (-)
[2000 Q1; 2008 Q2]
Eurozone process adhesion.
iph
1971 Q1
No
ruc
1972 Q1
No
1988 Q1 (+)
[1987 Q1; 1989 Q4]
Interest rate liberalization. Savings banks allowed opening branches outside their home
regions.
1997 Q4 (+)
[1995 Q1; 2001 Q2]
Eurozone process adhesion, high economic growth and boom in demand for second homes
in coastal areas.
1988 Q4 (+)
[1985 Q3; 1990 Q2]
Abolition of interest rate controls and government withdrew guidelines on mortgage
lending.
1988 Q4 (-)
[1985 Q3; 1990 Q2]
1996 Q2 (-)
[1995 Q4; 2006 Q4]
iph
1987 Q1
ruc
1987 Q1
iph
1978 Q1
Finland
ruc
1978 Q1
No
Abolition of interest rate controls and government withdrew guidelines on mortgage
lending.
Eurozone process adhesion and gradual liberalization of rent controls (rents are practically
free from public control).
Table 11 – EU-15 Housing Market Structural Breaks and Policies Measures (continuation)
Country
France
Series
Series Start
Breaks
iph
1980 Q2
No
ruc
1980 Q2
No
iph
1994 Q1
ruc
1994 Q1
iph
1976 Q1
Greece
Confidence Interval
Policies Measures
1999 Q1 (+)
[1998 Q4; 2002 Q4]
Eurozone process adhesion, liberalization of mortgage refinancing and expansion of nonspecialized commercial banks into mortgage lending.
1999 Q1 (-)
[1998 Q4; 2002 Q4]
Eurozone process adhesion, liberalization of mortgage refinancing and expansion of nonspecialized commercial banks into mortgage lending.
[1993 Q4; 1999 Q2]
In this period there was an increase of 78% of real house price. This is partly due to the
liberalization of the mortgage market with relaxation of the lending criteria, increasing
competition of the banks, liberalization of more expensive segment of rental market and full
deductibility of mortgages interest payments from taxable income. The proportion of loans
with LTV ratios greater than 100% increased from 15% in 1990 to a value exceeding 70% in
2001.
No
1994 Q4 (-)
Netherlands
ruc
1976 Q4
2002 Q1 (+)
[2001 Q4; 2003 Q4]
Fiscal Change: Reduced tax relief for interest payments and restricted it to principal
dwelling and expansion of the tax rate on capital gains.
iph
1975 Q1
1994 Q3 (+)
[1991 Q2; 2006 Q4]
During this period the house prices increased 179% in real terms. The liberalization of the
mortgage market with interest rate deregulation, the end of controls/regulations on rent
contracts and tax changes (favoring home ownership against the rents) help explain prices
growth in the period.
ruc
1978 Q1
1998 Q4 (-)
[1997 Q1; 2000 Q3]
Eurozone process adhesion and tax changes: abolished property tax and halved capital gains
tax.
Ireland
34
Table 11 – EU-15 Housing Market Structural Breaks and Policies Measures (continuation)
Country
Italy
Luxembourg
Portugal
United
Kingdom
Sweden
Series
Series Start
Breaks
iph
1988 Q2
No
ruc
1988 Q2
No
iph
1975 Q1
No
ruc
1975 Q1
No
Confidence Interval
Policies Measures
[1989 Q3; 1996 Q4]
Wolswijk (2006) refers the process of privatization as one of the policies measures that
explain this break that results in the liberalization of interest rates, abolition of credit
controls and credit guidelines, liberalization of investment service and legislation of entry,
branching, specialization and segmentation restrictions.
iph
1988 Q1
1992 Q1 (-)
ruc
1988 Q1
No
iph
1968 Q2
1992 Q4 (-)
[1990 Q4; 1994 Q3]
Crisis of Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM). Financial Crisis.
ruc
1973 Q1
1992 Q3 (-)
[1992 Q1; 1997 Q1]
Crisis of Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM). Financial Crisis.
iph
1986 Q1
No
ruc
1986 Q1
1996 Q1 (-)
[1992 Q4; 1998 Q2]
Measures to increase competition among mortgage finance institutions, banks and other
credit institutions in the 80's have resulted in banking crisis of 1991-93 with negative
consequences on house prices.
35
Figure 1: Dendogram: Ward Method
Figure 1 shows the dendrogram obtained from hierarchical cluster analysis for all institutional features
variables. The dendograms obtained using the "farthest neighbour" and Ward agglomeration methods,
suggest groups partition very similar, so we only present one of the agglomeration methods, the Ward
method.
Rescaled Distance Cluster Combine
CASE
Label
0
5
10
15
20
25
Num +---------+---------+---------+---------+---------+
Spain
5 ─┬─────────┐
Ireland
10 ─┘
├───────┐
United Kingdom14 ───────────┘
Finland
6 ─┬─────┐
Sweden
15 ─┘
├─────────────────────────────┐
│
│
├───────────┘
│
Denmark
4 ───────┘
│
Germany
1 ───────┬───────────────────────┐
Austria
2 ───────┘
Greece
8 ─────────────────┬─────┐
Italy
Belgium
France
│
11 ─────────────────┘
3 ─────┬───┐
│
│
│
├─────────────────┘
│
├───────┘
7 ─────┘ ├─────────┐ │
Luxembourg 12 ─────────┘
├───┘
Netherlands 9 ───────────┬───────┘
Portugal
13 ───────────┘
36
Figure 2: Hierarchical Cluster Analysis: Characterization of Clusters with
Standardized Variables
Figure 2 presents a plot with standardized values of institutional variables used on hierarchical cluster
analysis, for the five groups of countries formed. The definition of each variable appears in Table 5.
Hierarchical Cluster Analysis: Characterization of Clusters with
Standardized Variables
6
Standardized Value
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
Tax on Imputed Rent
Tax on Capital Gains
Deductibility of Mortgage Interest Payments
Tax Wedge
Transaction Costs
Landlord and Tenant Rating System
House Ownership
Rental Market
Enforcement Procedure
Valuation Method
Weight of Real Estate Funds
Securitization
Equity Withdrawal
Interest Rate
Legal Rights
Credit Information
Average LTV ratio
-3
Institutional Characteristics
Cluster I
Cluster II
Cluster III
Cluster IV
Cluster V
Note: Cluster I: Germany and Austria. Cluster II: Italy and Greece. Cluster III: France, Belgium, Luxembourg,
Netherlands and Portugal. Cluster IV: Sweden, Denmark and Finland. Cluster V: Ireland, United Kingdom and
Spain.
37
Figure 3 – Key Policy Relationship in Housing Market
FISCAL
POLICY
Rents
Demographics
Income
Taxation/Subsidies
User
Costs
DEMAND
PRUDENTIAL
POLICY
Loan
Supply
HOUSE PRICES
and TURNOVERS
Interest
Rates
POLÍTICA
MONETÁRIA
SUPPLY
STRUCTURAL
POLICY
Source: Hilbers et al. (2008)
38
Endnotes:
1
Those characteristics are related to several aspects such as the prevailing interest rate in the
mortgage market; the possibility of Equity withdrawal; the level of LTV (Loan-to-Value) ratios;
accepted property valuation methods and the availability of asset securitization.
2
McCrone & Stephens (1995) emphasise the importance of legal and institutional barriers in the
use of housing as collateral, arguing that despite convergence pressures, differences in housing and
financial market institutions across EU countries remained substantial.
3
The index is available from www.globalpropertyguide.com and takes into consideration the
following elements: (1) If rents can be freely agreed between landlord and tenant, (2) whether the
landlord collect security and rental deposits, and are the amounts limited, (3) the duration of the
contracts is freely chosen by the parties and can either the landlord or tenant terminate early, and
what are the penalties for early termination and finally does the tenant have a right to extend, (4)
whether the court system works well and how long can it take to evict a tenant for non-payment of
rent. This index gives the amount of control the landlord has over his property, measured on a fivepoint rating scale: strongly pro-landlord = 2; pro-landlord = 1; neutral = 0; pro-tenant = -1 and
strongly pro-tenant = -2.
4
Legal Rights for borrowers and lenders is composed of ten categories, seven of which pertain to
collateral law and three pertain to bankruptcy law. A score 1 is assigned if each feature is present in
the country, so that the Legal Rights index ranges from 0 to 10 with higher scores indicating that
collateral and bankruptcy laws are better designed to expand access to credit.
5
Credit Info index measures the depth of credit information about potential borrowers that lenders
access from standardized and informative sources of credit information. The index ranges from 0 to
6, with higher values indicating the availability of more credit information.
6
Available at www.doingbusiness.org. A complete description of the indexes and their components
is available in www.doingbusiness.org/MethodologySurveys/GettingCredit.aspx.
7
Global Real Estate Investment Attractiveness Index (Global REIA Index).
8
Lieser & Groh (2010) also note the importance of capital gains taxation and the deductibility of
mortgage interest on income tax in the context of their index of Real Estate Investments
Attractiveness.
9
The variables included in the analysis are standardised. When cluster analysis would have been
applied without a prior standardization, any distance measure would reflect the weight of the
variables that have higher values and greater dispersion.
10
As a robustness test we also estimated the clusters using the farthest neighbour method. The
results are do not differ from those from the Ward approach and are available from the authors on
request.
11
Guiso et al. (1992) argue that these long standing restrictions are a major reason why LTV ratios
in Italy have historically been less than 50% and why the ratio of mortgage-debt-to-GDP is so low.
39
12
Denmark is a slight outlier in some respects. Despite its high average LTVs, it shows a
preference for fixed-rate mortgages whilst historical valuations are used for collateral purposes and
there is a low weight of securitization.
13
As mentioned by Wolswijk (2006) “after-tax mortgage interest rates have an effect on mortgage
debt growth, indicating a potential role of interest deductibility as a policy instrument to influence
mortgage developments. All countries, apart from France, Germany and the U.K., in 2003 allowed
income tax deductibility of mortgage interest payment, with relevant marginal tax rates ranging
from 29 percent (Finland) to 52 per cent (the Netherlands)”.
14
As our analysis stops prior to the financial crisis the disconnect that emerged with the interbank
market does not come into play.
15
The New Urban Lease Act (Novo Regime de Arrendamento Urbano –“NRAU”) in Portugal is an
example of a legislative reform where the results fell far short of the desired effect.
40