DOI: https://doi.org/10.37075/EA.2022.2.02
Economic Alternatives, 2022, Issue 2, pp. 171-200
Dependent monetary regimes in the
Balkans
Long-term historical perspectives (1878-1989)
Received: 30.01.2022
Available online: 30.06.2022
Eric Magnin*, Nikolay Nenovsky**
Abstract
In this article, we look at the main stages
of the monetary systems in the Balkans,
representing a cyclical alternation of
dependent models, each of them effectively
serving the relationship of the Balkan
peripheral economies with their dominant
military, geopolitical and economic centre.
This centre of attraction is the anchor against
which the monetary regime of the periphery
is adjusted. We consider four periods: (i)
the building of a national monetary system
after long years of Ottoman domination, and
especially the accession to the Latin Monetary
Union, (ii) the adoption of the rules of the
League of Nations and monetary stabilizations
based on the gold exchange standard, (iii) the
inclusion in the German Lebensraum and the
system of currency control and clearings, and
finally (iv) the Soviet zone and the COMECON,
the mechanism of passive money and the
*
**
1
2
transferable ruble. In the last period we
present the Yugoslav monetary regime, which
was attached to the West.
Keywords: Balkan economies, Balkan
monetary history, dependent monetary
regime, bimetallism, monetary stabilisation,
gold exchange standard, exchange control,
clearing, transferable ruble
JEL: E42, F4, N13, N14
Introduction and theoretical
background
T
he
post-socialist
transformation
process, initiated after the fall of the
Berlin Wall, and the subsequent integration
into the European Union have prompted
social scientists to examine economic models
emerging in Central and Eastern Europe
as an outcome of these major institutional
changes1. Among the different paths explored,
the dependent capitalism hypothesis has
been given greater interest and relevance
in the context of the 2008 economic and
financial crisis2. The crisis brought to light the
LADYSS, University Paris Cité, France
LEFMI, University of Picardie Jules Verne, France
SU Higher School of Economics, Russia
RUDN, Department of Political Economy, Russia
See Chavance and Magnin (2002), Lane and Myant (2007), Bohle and Greskovits (2012).
See King (2002), Nölke and Vliegenthart (2009), Drahokoupil and Myant (2011).
171
Articles
weaknesses of East-European economies,
especially their structural dependence on
foreign capital. The concept of dependence
initially refers to the 1960s-1970s studies on
Latin America within a Marxist theoretical
framework3. Dependence is then typical of
“peripheral” economies whose growth and
accumulation depend on the decisions of
actors belonging to a hegemonic “center”
(Evans, 1979). However, the concept of
dependent capitalism, which reappeared
in the 2000s, belongs to a very different
theoretical and historical context. It moves
away from the original Marxist framework
and imperialism and now falls within the
field of comparative capitalism (May and
Nölke, 2018). Dependent capitalism displays
a number of complementary institutional
elements shared by most Central and Eastern
European countries and the Western Balkans:
FDI, cheap and skilled labour, labour market
flexibility, liberal tax regime and limited social
protection, etc4.
In recent years, we have turned the
attention of researchers of dependent
capitalism to an obvious but practically
unexplored and non-integrated leading
element of it. It is about the monetary regime
of dependent capitalism, which fits into
the above institutional configuration, and
which we have called “Dependent Monetary
Regime” (Magnin and Nenovsky, 2021, see
also the forthcoming monograph by Magnin
and Nenovsky, 2022). Here, in theoretical
terms, we note the following.
Firstly, a monetary regime can be defined
as a set of formal rules of monetary behaviour,
3
4
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
as well as mechanisms of their enforcement.
Within the monetary regime, two components
(sub-regimes) can be distinguished – internal
and external – which often conflict with each
other. The first, external component (external
rules) we can call ‘exchange rate regime’.
It covers the legal rules of exchange rate
formation (through the market or through
monetary authorities’ interventions), as
well as the mechanisms of convertibility of
national currency into foreign currency (from
full convertibility to full control). The second,
internal component of the monetary regime
(internal monetary rules), can be referred to as
‘monetary policy regime’. Monetary policy is
related to the influence on the monetary base,
and on money supply in general (this includes
domestic credit), on liquidity and generally on
GDP domestic components. Monetary policy
is associated with the interest rate policy (i.e.
with the different channels of transmission
mechanisms), and nowadays with quantitative
and qualitative easing and the active
management of the yield curve. Monetary
policy can be discretional or conducted
according to pre-set rules. Monetary regime,
i.e., the formal, codified monetary relations,
also reflect the power relationships, economic
interests, and strategies of the key political
and economic actors or groups of actors.
Broadly speaking, a country’s monetary
regime is an extension of its geopolitical
and geo-economic place in the international
system. Structurally, the political, military and
economic power hierarchy, the relationship
of dominance among individual nation-states
within the world economy, determine and
Interestingly, Latin American structuralism is strongly influenced by an economist from the Balkans, the Romanian
Mihail Manoilescu (1891-1950), whose theories of protectionism and of corporatism were extremely popular
between the two world wars (Manoilescu, 1929, 1938 [1934], Nenovsky and Torre, 2014, 2018, Nenovsky and
Penchev, 2013). In fact, this is an important “Balkan” source of modern theory of economic dependence.
See Nölke and Vliegenthart (2009), Farkas (2016).
172
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
actively interact with the hierarchy of national
money.
Second, the main feature of dependent
capitalism is dependence on foreign capital.
The need for external capital is dictated
by insufficient domestic savings, and a
generally low technological level and limited
competitive export opportunities. Peripheral
and dependent countries cannot borrow on
international markets debt denominated in
their own national currencies. They borrow
in major world currencies and become
vulnerable to currency (exchange rate)
risk. The inflow of external capital, in turn,
requires a corresponding stable institutional
and political environment. Indeed, a leading
condition for foreign capital, as well as for the
involvement of foreign financial institutions,
in addition to favourable tax conditions, is
the introduction of a monetary regime that
could ensure the return on this capital and
its predictability. This implies a low level of
risk (currency and political). It follows that
the monetary regimes of the peripheral and
catching-up countries are built in a way that
suits the political and geopolitical interests of
the leading capital centres.
The post-socialist transformation is
evidence of this; it has led to the emergence
of “dependent” monetary regimes in the
Balkans, the most extreme forms of which are
currency boards and unilateral euroization.5
However, this monetary dependence is rooted
in the long-term history of the region and
thus illustrates path dependence phenomena
highlighted by authors studying institutional
5
6
change (North, 1990; Magnin, 2002). The
monetary history of the Balkan region has
been the subject of numerous analyses, with
the emphasis mainly on individual countries
and on specific periods of financial and
monetary events. We discuss and mobilise
these analyses and achievements below
in order to provide a long-term and global
interpretation of the evolution of monetary
regimes in the region. To the best of our
knowledge, this has not been done so far,
and together with the concept of dependent
monetary regime, this represents our original
contribution.
More concretely, we look at the main
stages of the monetary systems in the
Balkans, representing a cyclical alternation of
dependent models, each of them effectively
serving the relationship of the Balkan
peripheral economies with their dominant
military, geopolitical and economic centre.6
This centre of attraction is the anchor against
which the monetary regime of the periphery is
adjusted. The anchor serves to coordinate the
expectations and, accordingly, the plans of
the participants in the economic and political
process. The change of centres of attraction,
of geo-political anchors, is disrupted by
military, political and social upheavals and
crises. In these relatively short periods of
unstable transition, not only is there a change
in the political and economic structure of the
periphery, but also new economic and social
theories and ideas, including the theory of
money and monetary policy, are emerging.
A new paradigm of economic thinking and
The emergence of dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans after 1990 is studied in more detail in Magnin and
Nenovsky (2021, 2022).
In other words, but this goes beyond the scope of the present analysis, we could speak not only of ‘dependent
capitalism’ but also of ‘dependent socialism’, ‘dependent transition/transformation’, ‘dependent Europeanism’
and so on. In Marxist literature, the monetary history of the Balkan region until the Communists came to power
was treated as a manifestation of the imperialism of the leading states, as an “appendage of imperialism”.
173
Articles
discourse takes shape (although this happens
to varying degrees in different transitional
phases)7.
Before proceeding to the exposition, we
need to make three provisos. First, the text
that follows is not a historical, but an economic
reconstruction of the past. It does not claim
to give a detailed description of historical
facts which, albeit important, remain in the
background. Neither do we aim to review the
extensive literature on the subject. Our task
is different, namely to outline the monetary
history of the region from the perspective of
the model of dependent monetary regime.
Each part gives references to other studies
(ours including), analysing each period in
more depth.
Second, the choice of historical
illustrations and highlights is dictated by our
relatively better knowledge of some of the
countries (mostly Bulgaria, Romania and
Serbia), as well as by political changes in the
region. The political and territorial dynamics in
the region largely determine the multilinearity
of history and monetary regimes (for example,
the existence of Yugoslavia, the specifics
of socialism in Albania and Romania, the
capitalist development of Greece, etc.).
Thirdly, and most importantly, the proposed
analytical reading, the proposed analytical
reconstruction of history from the viewpoint
of the dependent monetary regime, does
not claim uniqueness. It is just one of the
various possible theoretical interpretations,
each of which would enrich a theoretical
7
8
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
understanding of what is happening in the
Balkans. Our interpretation is not normative
either: it does not denounce the dependent
monetary regime (it can be useful for the
periphery) and the word “dependence” does
not necessarily carry a negative connotation8;
it only defines and analyses it.
We consider four periods of dependent
monetary regime: (i) the building of a national
monetary system after long years of Ottoman
domination, and especially the accession
to the Latin Monetary Union (LMU) (18781912/14), (ii) the adoption of the rules of the
League of Nations and monetary stabilizations
based on the gold exchange standard (1919/20
- 1931/33) (iii) the inclusion in the German
economic space and the system of currency
control and clearings (1933 -1944), and finally
- (iv) the Soviet zone and the COMECON,
the mechanism of passive money and the
transferable ruble (1945-1989). In the last
period under consideration, we also present
the Yugoslav monetary regime, which differed
significantly from other socialist countries and
was attached to the West.
I. The Building of National Currency.
Europe and the LMU. Bimetallism
and gold standard (1878 – 1912/14)
Until the Berlin Congress (1878), the
Balkan countries in various forms were part
of the Ottoman Empire and followed the
monetary practices in the Empire. Overall, the
silver standard prevailed in the Empire and
from 1844 bimetallism was officially adopted.
See the study of Marinova and Nenovsky (2019), where some reference points for long-term interpretation of the
economic thought in the Balkans are given.
In the studies on dependence in Latin America by the São Paulo School sociologists, notably Cardoso and
Faletto, development is not incompatible with the idea of dependence, and both can be associated (Cardoso
1977; Cardoso and Faletto 1979; Evans, 1979). Multinationals and foreign capital contribute to the country’s
industrialization and growth. However, dependent development does not erase the contradictions between the
center and the periphery.
174
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
The reforms initiated in 1839 (the Tanzimat),
and especially the transformation of the
Empire into a semi-colony after the Crimean
War of 1856, led to attempts to implement the
monetary institutions of developed countries.
The Ottoman Bank was established, private
and foreign in nature, which was to manage
the debt of the empire and perform the
functions of a Central Bank. Unsuccessful
attempts were also made to impose paper
currency (kaime)9. After 1865, the Ottoman
Empire sought to abide by the rules of the
LMU. The monetary practices of the Balkan
peoples followed the development of the
territorial money of the Empire.
Gaining its first political independence
in 1829, Greece became a full member of
the LMU in 1869. For their part, within their
individual degree of political subordination,
Serbia and Romania attempted to create
their own monetary systems. The actual start
of constructing national monetary regimes
was given by the Berlin Congress (1878).
Along with the formation of the nation-state,
the process of building a national monetary
and financial system began10. Below we will
note the major developments of the monetary
history before the Balkan Wars11.
After 1878, Romania, Serbia and Bulgaria
had to build a state administration and an
independent fiscal system. National producers,
basically peasants and artisans, received a
severe blow from the narrowing of markets
and the collapse of the empire’s market. The
emerging light industry suffered a similar blow
(Berov, 1990). This process was intensified
by the easy penetration of European goods
due to the inherited low import duties (8% ad
valorem duty, at the old unchanged official
prices12). There was no domestic capital in
the region and no ways to mobilise the small
savings; the postal and banking systems were
still undeveloped. Monetary chaos, legacy
from the Russo-Turkish war, reigned with
various types of coins circulating, including
silver Russian rubles (Kyoseva, 2000).
At the same time, there was a need for
investment everywhere, especially in the
development of rail and water transport –
the first conditions for the formation of
national markets. Also, the newly formed
national armies needed arms and munitions.
The only source remaining was attracting
foreign capital. It was inevitably associated
with the rich European countries, which
were at the same time military, political and
cultural powers in the region. However, these
countries were fighting for influence on the
Balkan periphery and aggressively pursuing
their interests. They wanted debt against
concessions of important businesses, mainly
railways, ports, etc., a monopoly on military
supplies, etc. The leading European countries
monopolised the export of Balkan agricultural
goods while exporting industrial goods; thus,
the entire balance of payments was controlled
by the leading countries. Specifically for
Bulgaria, A. Chakalov summarises:
The monetary history of the Ottoman Empire and Turkey can be found in the book of Pamuk (2000); for an
overview of the economic development of Turkey, see Pamuk (2018). A comprehensive analysis of the Bulgarian
literature on the subject is given in Atanasov and Nenovsky (2019).
10
See Helleiner (2003) on these processes.
11
The study of Nenovsky and Vaslin (2019) ‘Shadowing the Latin Monetary Union: Monetary Regimes and Interest
Rates in the Balkan Periphery (1867-1912)’ gives a more detailed presentation of the monetary history of that
period and reference to an extensive literature on the subject. For the economic history of the region in general,
see Palairet (1997).
12
Bulgaria, for example, was unable to build its own customs policy for 15 years.
9
175
Articles
‘The development of the state budget
and balance of payments of the country
before the Balkan War was therefore
entirely influenced by foreign capital,
mainly from foreign loans and partly from
the return on direct investments in the
economy’. (Chakalov, 1962, p.38).
The choice of monetary regime followed
logically: it had to meet the interests of the
leading countries, as well as the main national
task of the Balkan countries, namely to attract
capital, technological and industrial goods to
modernise their economies. For their part,
the Balkan countries exported agricultural
products. After Greece (which became a LMU
member for political reasons)13, Romania,
Serbia and Bulgaria also applied for full LMU
membership. This happened, however, at a
time when the LMU itself was increasingly
transformed into an alliance following the rules
of the gold standard (passing through the
limping bimetallic standard). The adoption of
the LMU institutional rules was geopolitically
determined. France was the leading force in
the LMU and had good diplomatic relations
with the liberator of the Balkans – Russia.
Russia also followed the LMU principles.
Subsequently, the centre of attraction for the
Balkans was to become Austria-Hungary, and
later Germany and England. This would lead
to attempts to introduce a gold standard (for
example, Romania in 1890).
Full membership in the LMU was refused
and the three Balkan states agreed to
follow the Union’s principles as a unilateral
commitment14. A unilateral commitment to peg
13
14
15
16
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
the exchange rate to the gold French franc
was undertaken by Romania in 1867, Serbia in
1873, and Bulgaria in 1880, i.e., 1 franc = 1 lev
= 1 leu = 1 dinar (CMI, 1890, 454)15. France
was the centre of the monetary system of the
Balkan satellites: it was their external anchor.
“The Latin Monetary Union made
France the centre of a vast system of
circulation, and by giving it satellites,
made it a sort of monetary sun. If the other
heavenly bodies that it drew into its orbit
were attracted to the gravitational force
of another monetary system, would there
not be a reason to fear that France might
lose, along with its monetary influence, a
portion of its economic importance?” (Ed.
Van der Smissen, in Chausserie-Laprée,
1911, p.218)
“By making the smaller states
dependent upon France, the Latin Union
hindered them, as we shall later see, from
actively caring for their own interest when
the fall in the value of silver began to
grow more visibly, and forced upon them
subsequently the necessity of redeeming
a mass of depreciated metal.” (Willis, 1968
[1901], p.85)
Initially, the creation of the Central
Bank and the entire monetary legislation in
Romania, Bulgaria and Serbia also copied
the practices of France. But they quickly
reoriented themselves to the experience of
Belgium as a country more appropriate in
terms of size and as a political system, i.e.,
monarchy16. Belgium was the LMU founder
See Willis (1968 [1901], 81).
As an example, this means that Union coins (mainly silver) were accepted in the Balkan countries, while Balkan
coins were not accepted in LMU countries.
That commitment ended with the wars of 1912-1914. For LMU see Willis (1968 [1901]), Einaudi (2001) and Gillard
(2017).
See for Serbia (Gnjatović et al. (2009 [2003]) and for Romania (Băicoianu, 1932, Pecorari, 2006, 2006a).
176
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
and one of the main pillars. Central Banks in
Serbia (1884) and Romania (1880) emerged
as private national joint stock companies
(in Romania with 1/3 state participation). In
Bulgaria, the Central Bank emerged entirely
as a state bank (1879)17. At first, these Central
Banks had credit functions, but very quickly
were given the right to issue currency. It is
interesting that in Bulgaria very soon two
attempts were made, first by Russian (1880)
and then by French capitalists (1882), to turn
the public Bulgarian National Bank (BNB)
into a joint-stock company with dominant
foreign influence of Russian and French
capitals, respectively18. It should be noted that
seigniorage was emerging as a significant
income with the appearance of national
territorial money. As an important source of
income for the state19, seigniorage became a
subject of conflicts.
The introduction of a dependent monetary
regime, as we know, requires conservative
public finances. During the early years, this
was simply impossible because the weight
of the budget, both in terms of revenue and
expenditure, was negligible. The lack of
mechanisms for countervailing and absorbing
shocks led to large asymmetries between the
centre and the periphery. Normally, the centre
would attract gold, with silver remaining in the
periphery or non-convertible paper money
being introduced. The net gold flow for the
Balkan countries was negative. This de facto
led to a violation of the LMU principles and
was manifested specifically in the constant
fights with the agio20. Again, about Bulgaria,
Chakalov writes:
“The more the Bulgarian governments
increased the extraordinary expenses for
various purposes, thus accumulating debts
and deficits without providing revenues to
cover them while relying on the proceeds
from external borrowing, the more foreign
financial capital took advantage of this
situation and imposed new, more difficult
conditions in negotiating each subsequent
loan.” (Chakalov, 1962, p.17).
It was not until around 1904, when, as
a result of the development of the Balkan
economies and the increased weight of the
budget, the three countries started pursuing
a conservative policy. The Balkan countries
managed to observe the principles of the
international gold standard (also practiced by
the LMU) and reduced the cost of external
financing, i.e. sovereign interest rates). It is
true that Romania adopted the gold standard
as early as 1890 in order to get closer to
Germany (on gold standard since 1871).
However, this required great effort and fiscal
restrictions. Subsequently, the gold standard
(i.e., the convertibility of paper money into
gold) was safeguarded administratively and
It should be noted that although they emerged after the Central Bank of Bulgaria, the Central Banks of Romania
and Serbia inherited significant experience in building an independent bank within the Ottoman Empire. For
Greece, which we do not consider here, see Lazaretou (1993).
18
It is interesting to note that years later, in 1928, together with the currency (monetary) stabilisation loan, the
League of Nations pushed for the idea of the BNB becoming a joint-stock bank (Chakalov, 1962, p.13).
19
Morys (2014).
20
The agio can be defined as a market premium (deviation) on gold coins over the official rate of those gold
coins (later gold-backed banknotes) with respect to silver coins (silver bank notes). The agio was one of the key
variables whose behaviour illustrated the whole range of issues related to the adoption by the Balkan economies
of the core monetary regime of the European countries. See the detailed analysis in Nenovsky and Vaslin (2020).
17
177
Articles
even by force21. In 1905/1906, joint-stock
banks of France, Germany and AustriaHungary settled in Bulgaria. Due to the high
interest rates in the country, these banks
received transfers from their parent banks
and that led to a significant increase in their
deposit base, with these deposits reaching
50-60% of their total deposits22.
Another viewpoint would be worth noting
here, concerning the asymmetry of the
dependent monetary regime, which was
repeatedly pointed out by economists of
that time. According to it, in exchanging their
goods, peripheral countries lose purchasing
power and national labour, this exchange
being not equivalent. To what extent this
statement is true from a theoretical point of
view (because it is based on the classical
theory of costs and labour as a basis for the
formation of value and prices) is irrelevant
here. What really matters is that this argument
about the lack of equivalence and exploitation
of the periphery would emerge in almost all
other periods of monetary dependence. It
would bring forth, for example, the original
protectionist theory of the Romanian scholar
Mihail Manoilescu, developed between the
two world wars and by far transcending the
ambit of Romania and the Balkans23.
The asymmetries and non-equivalence
that a dependent monetary regime can lead
to are eloquently presented in the following
two quotations (note that these are not
Marxist economists). Serbian economist M.
Bochkovitch writes:
“Exports are by far the most important
source bringing gold into the country. As
21
22
23
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
farm produce plays a predominant role
in Serbian exports, the export figures
depend chiefly on the harvest. However,
conversely, Serbian agriculture is still not
well developed. […] Borrowing is another
means of supplying the country with gold,
but these inflows of gold into the country
are only temporary, for when the debt
comes due, an equal sum, plus interest,
will go out of the country. Therefore, in
order to act as an instrument against the
agio, these borrowings must be used
productively. This is notably the case for
the borrowings that were used to build the
railways, to create the tobacco and match
monopolies. Unfortunately, the majority of
Serbian borrowings were undertaken only
to cover budget deficits or to purchase
arms and munitions, imported from
abroad in most cases. It is obvious that
instead of improving the exchange, these
borrowings contributed instead to a large
extent to worsening it.” Bochkovitch (1919,
p.145-147)
In an 1888 book on the Balkans, the great
Belgian economist, supporter of bimetallism
and defender of the Balkan peoples, Emile
de Laveleye, talks about the unbalanced
exchange they suffered by accepting the
money of the developed countries. He writes:
“All the nations of Western Europe
are wealthy countries with abundant
circulation, therefore prices are high. The
nations of Eastern Europe are, conversely,
countries with low circulation, hence
prices are low. This difference matters
little to the inhabitants of one or the other
Tenev (2014 [1938] v.1, p.344-346).
Chakalov (1962, p.50).
See the history of protectionism and protectionist theories in Romania and Bulgaria, Nenovsky and Penchev
(2013).
178
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
of these groups in their relations amongst
one another, but it is felt as soon as there
are relations between citizens of the highprice group and those of the lower-price
group. The former can easily buy from the
latter; but reciprocally, the latter cannot
buy from the former. If I sell a chicken in
London for three shillings, I can use this
money to buy three chickens in Bucharest.
A thousand francs in Paris will give me
three times as much purchasing power
in Romania or Bulgaria. The Englishman
or the Frenchman can thus take from the
poor countries everything of their liking,
because they will pay prices that nobody
could pay locally. This is why we see all
the fine and sought-after things flow to
London and Paris, to the detriment of the
countries that produce them. It is also for
this reason that such a large number of
English live abroad. Their incomes give
them a much greater purchasing and
consuming power [abroad] than at home.
Conversely, the inhabitant of Kyiv or Sofia
who would like to come to London or Paris,
to consume the equivalent of a hectolitre
of wheat, must, in order to do so, sell at
least two hectolitres of wheat at home.”
(Laveleye,1888, p.62).
The level of wages and other production
costs in the Balkan countries, an important
element in the model of dependent capitalism
and monetary regime, is about 3 to 4 times
lower than in Western Europe.
24
II. The League of Nations and
Monetary Stabilisations. Gold
exchange standard (1919/20 –
1931/33)
The Balkan Wars, and later the First World
War, led to profound structural changes in
the Balkan region. A new political community
was formed: the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats
and Slovens (from 1929 the Kingdom of
Yugoslavia24); Romania more than doubled its
territory; Albania gained independence (legally
in 1921), and Bulgaria, the only defeated
Balkan country, lost the Dobrudja granary
and had to pay reparations. The refugee
problem loomed with the displacement of
large masses of population which, too, had
to be financially supported. All countries were
in a state of inflation, depreciation of their
national currencies (gold coverage declining
to a few percent), with exchange rates sharply
declining. Their public finances were in a
deplorable state, the burden of external debts
weighing down heavily. As a defeated country,
Bulgaria was even worse off. Everything had
to be paid in gold francs, at the pre-war rate.
At the same time, during the war,
economies themselves underwent profound
structural changes: new industries emerged
and the need of rapid industrialisation
became increasingly pressing (Berov, 1990).
The leading European powers – the defeated
Germany and Austria-Hungary – also
changed, ceding their political, military and
economic leadership to France and England,
with Italy later on becoming more active. A new
“ideological” economic alternative emerged Soviet Russia. In the 1920s, an attempt was
made to restore the pre-war economic and
monetary international order. The League of
Nations (LN) became the main conduit of the
Hereinafter referred to as Yugoslavia.
179
Articles
new economic and financial order in Europe,
shaping the peripheral Balkan countries as
well.
Again, as before the wars, the Balkan
countries needed capital, foreign direct
investment and borrowing. Foreign capitals
were not late to come, primarily from the war
winning countries and under burdensome
terms, too. Not only did they control the
servicing of loans, but they also managed
the monetary and financial policy of the
Balkan countries. In Bulgaria, for example,
especially prominent was the control exerted
by the delegate of foreign debt holders who
had a strong political influence. Later on, LN
representatives joined in and also played a
decisive influence in the governance of the
BNB and public finances.
Monetary stabilisation in the region was
imperative25. It was carried out under the
influence of the LN and its experts – the
‘monetary doctors’ who were sent to the
region. Thus, the Balkan countries had the
honour of being visited and controlled by
economists, some of whom later became
famous theorists of economics and the
theory of money. We will mention two French
economists, Jacques Rueff, sent to Greece
and Bulgaria, and Charles Rist, in charge of
the stabilisation in Yugoslavia and Romania.
Stabilisations followed not only the theory
and recommendations of UN experts, but
also examples of stabilisation in the leading
countries, above all that of France.
25
26
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
Regardless of the specifics of the sources
of external financing and the technical details of
monetary stabilisation, all countries managed
to stabilise their money first de facto and
then legally. Bulgaria, for example, officially
stabilised in 1928 with the help of the Refugee
and Stabilisation loans, which supported the
Central Bank’s depleted foreign exchange
reserves26. Similar to France, a new, different
than the pre-war exchange rate level was
chosen (devaluation was in accordance with
times). The monetary reform was implemented
not without the administrative intervention
of the government and the Central Bank,
which performed significant currency control
and monopolised foreign currency flows.
Governments pursued or sought to pursue
extremely conservative policies of public
finances and deflation (despite criticism from
some academic economists). The Bulgarian
elites maintained a firmly fixed rate, which
was kept the longest compared to any other
Balkan country. Bulgaria was a debtor and
any devaluation threatened to complicate the
servicing of its debt. In his speech marking
the BNB’s 50th anniversary, Prime Minister
Andrey Lyapchev said:
‘One would be hard to find quite such
a young nation in quite such exacerbated
circumstances as ours these past fifty
years, yet one which can boast that it
has ever occupied the position of an
Elsewhere, we have presented in detail the Bulgarian stabilisation, the ensuing depression, the debates
around it and the influence of leading European economists (Nenovsky (2006, 2012). These articles contain a
comprehensive bibliography on the subject. A comparative analysis of the Bulgarian and Romanian stabilisations
was made in Nenovsky et al. (2013, part 4). For Bulgaria, see also Prost (1925) and Koszul (1932) and especially
the summary study of Danaillow (1932), for Romania, Băicoianu (1932) and Stoenescu et al. (2008), and for
Yugoslavia, Gnjatovic (2020).
According to generalised estimates of A. Chakalov, Bulgaria’s foreign loans until WWII were of low efficiency in
terms of real investment activity: only about 35% of the total amount of all loans went to develop the economy
(Chakalov 1962, p.28).
180
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
exemplary payer to its foreign creditors’
(Lyapchev, 1929, p.135)
And in his speech on the occasion of the
50th anniversary of the BNB, Governor Assen
Ivanov said that stabilisation, deflation, and
restrictive public finances go hand in hand:
‘Stabilising currency was the first and
most important task. Yet, since money
devaluation stemmed from abuse of the
privilege of issuing banknotes for the
purposes of excessive and unjustified
lending to the state after the end of the
War, initial restorative measures had to
stop further loans to the state by the
issuing authority and to limit strictly the
right to issue banknotes’ (Ivanov, 1929, pp.
140—141).
For its part, Romania significantly
expanded its territory, but at the same time it
faced the problems of political and monetary
consolidation. A new monetary space and new
territorial money had to be formed. Romania
had run up big pre-war debts, too. Being on the
side of the victors (beneficiary of reparations
from Bulgaria), however, it had some degree
of freedom in monetary stabilisation and in the
formation of its dependent monetary regime.
Romania did not take a loan guaranteed by
the LN, but directly from Western banks,
and this happened relatively late – on the
eve of the depression. Second, the fixed
exchange rate in Romania lasted a short
time (from 1929 to 1932, when exchange rate
fluctuations began), and by revaluing its gold
reserves, it practically devalued by more than
30% in 1936. Romania had more industry than
other Balkan countries, mainly oil, and this
placed the country at the centre of the fights
of Western corporations and investors, mostly
27
French and English. After the beginning of
the depression, however, similarly to Bulgaria,
it very quickly joined the German economic
area.
Yugoslavia (until 1929, the Kingdom of
Serbs, Croats and Slovenes) faced similar
problems as Romania: it expanded territorially
at the expense of Austria-Hungary and also
had to undergo a deep monetary reform27.
A new Central Bank had to be built and the
numerous foreign currencies circulating
after the war (mostly the Austrian krona),
which were flooding the country, had to be
demonetised. The second main task was
the stabilisation of currency within the LN
principles (i.e., gold-exchange standard).
Although it started early, at the same time
as those in Bulgaria and Romania, because
of the difficulties in negotiating a foreign
loan, stabilisation became legal only in 1931.
In 1928, Yugoslavia failed to obtain a loan
from private banks in London, and in 1931
negotiated a loan from France. The level of
the exchange rate was fixed at a new level,
significantly lower than the pre-war levels.
The problems with the legal delays
in monetary stabilisation in Romania and
Yugoslavia (compared to Bulgaria) reveal
the leading role of foreign loans in support
of the Central Bank’s gold reserves and
monetary stabilisation. Bulgaria received the
two loans a little earlier due to the refugee
issue and, in our opinion, due to the fact that
as a debtor country it had to service its debts.
In all three countries, however, stabilisations
were taking place with significant fiscal
restrictions, budget recovery, as well as
strict administrative quantitative restrictions
and centralisation of the foreign exchange
market. In this sense, monetary stabilisation
See for details Gnjatovic (2020).
181
Articles
was administratively rather than marketconditioned. The control over the foreign
exchange market subsequently helped all
three countries to easily fit into the German
trade clearing area.
Intellectually, there was resistance in all
three countries against the nature and methods
of monetary reform, but it was essentially weak.
According to a number of Balkan economists,
it holds back the development of national
economies. The only original protectionist
theory from the period in question is that of
the Romanian scholar Mihail Manoilescu,
published in French in 1929. Manoilescu was
a leading economic and political figure. He
confronted the “Geneva clique” (as he calls it),
which imposed models of unequal exchange
(industrial goods to the Balkans in exchange
for agricultural goods) thus exploiting Balkan
workers28. As a reaction to this theory, the
Bulgarian economist Konstantin Bobchev
presented his original theory of protectionism,
based in part on neoclassical analysis29.
Curious is the emergence of a new political
entity, Albania, which declared independence
in 1912 and was finally recognised in 192130.
As early as 1913, attempts were made at
building a Central Bank with foreign capital,
mainly Austrian and Italian. The state of the
Albanian monetary system is described in a
report to the LN by the Luxembourg economist
Albert Calmès (1922). In 1922, without legal
national money and amidst monetary chaos,
the country was practically under a gold
standard regime. The relationship between the
28
29
30
31
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
individual means of payment was determined
by private actors and the unit of measure was
the golden French franc.
“To sum up, without possessing any
legal currency Albania has the gold
standard, by which, the value of the silver
and paper money are fixed. Albania is
thus one of the few European countries
possessing a sound currency.“ (Calmès,
1922, p.20).
An Italian financial group founded the
Central Bank of Albania in 1921, and in 1925
the first Albanian money appeared, emerging
under a gold standard. This was done in
accordance with the recommendations of the
LN (where Albania was accepted in 1920 and
where its main goals were to obtain a loan
and preserve an independent status)31. The
seigniorage was distributed equally between
the Italian shareholders and the Albanian
state, and the first governors were Italians.
Thus, since its very inception, the Albanian
regime was dependent. The reason for the
establishment of the Albanian Central Bank is
interesting also because of the fact that within
the LN a significant project for the overall
organisation of the peripheral countries
emerged.
“Similarly, when Albania requested
assistance to establish a central bank in
1923, one member of the committee, Mr.
Parmentier, suggested that it might be
better to create an international bank of
Manoilescu (1929), see also Nenovsky and Torre (2015) and Basciani (2020).
See Bobchev (1933, 1937), a comparison of these theories is made in Nenovsky and Penchev (2013).
We will not dwell on Greece, where monetary stabilisation is similar, especially with that of Bulgaria. It was
realised in 1928 with a loan guaranteed by the LN. Then a new central bank was created, and the National
Bank of Greece, which had issuing and trading functions until then, was left with commercial functions only.
Montenegro and Bosnia and Herzegovina, and part of Macedonia, generally followed Yugoslavia’s monetary
system. See for Montenegro Fabris (2015). For Macedonia, see Zafiroski (2018, p.65 -71).
Hellerner (2003).
182
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
issue with a head office in Geneva, which
would issue an international currency to
Albania and other interested European
countries through branches in these
countries. “ (Helleiner, 2003, p.142)
Having barely stabilised their monetary
systems, the Balkan countries were hit by
the economic crisis that had spilled over to
Central Europe. Their agricultural sectors
were badly affected by the falling prices. Their
public finances were under strong pressure.
Capital flight began. This worsened balances
of payments and threatened exchange rates.
After some hesitation in the 1920s, economic
protectionism and monetary nationalism
settled permanently in Europe. A new phase
was looming, in which Germany was to play
a decisive role for the Balkan countries with
its markets, industry and political influence in
the region. Germany very quickly became the
new economic and monetary centre.
III. The German Lebensraum.
Clearings and currency control
(1933-1944)
The fall in prices of agricultural products
and the withdrawal of Western capital
(primarily by the WWI victors) severely
affected Balkan countries. According to the
Bulgarian banker and politician Atanas Burov:
‘Bulgaria, together with all countries
exporting grain products, is under the
burden of a long-unseen crisis, caused
by a strong, in our opinion, lasting decline
in agricultural prices. The reduced
profitability of agricultural labour caused by
this devaluation significantly reduces the
purchasing power of the rural population
and causes general stagnation in all areas
32
33
of the people’s livelihood” (foreword by A.
Burov in the introduction to Torbov, 1930,
p.III).
A number of proposals were made both
within the Agrarian Bloc and between the
leading European countries for a plan to
stabilise the region (the Danube Customs
Union, Fund for subsidising the prices of
agricultural countries, etc. projects were
launched). They did not lead to a result. Their
failures coincided with Germany’s political
and economic revival, and this was especially
evident after the National Socialists came to
power in 1933. Very quickly, the French and
British presence gave way to German and
Italian ambitions in the region. New German
banks settled in.
From that moment on, the economic and
partly political interests of Germany and the
Balkan countries began to intersect, and
this led to the complete dependence of the
Balkan countries on Germany. The Balkans
became part of the German living space
(Lebensraum). For Bulgaria, for example,
which began in 1931/1932, the final “suction”
into the German economy took place after
193632. The chronology for Germany’s other
satellites is similar33.
In the Lebensraum spirit, the aim was to
mobilise raw materials, food, etc. needed for
the already “overheating” German economy.
Germany’s interest in the Balkans can also
be explained with the devaluation of the gold
bloc currencies, which blocked Germany’s
trade with them. In short, the interest was
mutual: Germany needed the Balkans just as
the Balkans needed Germany. The Balkans
exported agricultural goods and Germany
supplied industrial goods, technology and
Christophoroff (1939, p.8-9).
Arndt (2014 [1944], p.176-206).
183
Articles
capital. According to the commissioner of the
Bulgarian military economy Petar Aladzhov:
‘The main advantage of Germany was
that its market was hungry for Bulgarian
agricultural products and they were almost
the only goods that Bulgaria could export’.
(Aladzhov, 2000, p.63).
Another Bulgarian author writes:
‘The Balkan countries would have
suffered too much economically if it was
not for the availability of the German
market for their agricultural products and
raw materials. […] First of all, this is the
economic structure of Germany, this large
Central European country, which makes
it the most natural and largest market for
Balkan countries’ (Toshev, 1934d, p.418,
421)
And according to the Bulgarian sociologist
Nikola Agansky, the geopolitical choice is
crucial:
‘In international relations, the
underlying principle is that the exchange
of goods between countries lies not only
on an economic basis, but is the result
of a particular policy, or is a prerequisite
for political orientation.’ (Agansky, 1936,
p.132).
In terms of monetary regime, three blocs
were formed in the early 1930s: the sterling
bloc (led by Great Britain, which devalued
in 1931), the gold bloc (led by France,
which devalued in 1936), and the clearing
bloc (led by Germany). The German bloc
34
35
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
brought together the countries defeated in
WWI: Germany, Hungary, Austria, as well as
countries with high foreign debts. The first
group relied on devaluation, the second one
on deflation, and yet the third – on currency
control as a form of resistance to depression.
The German group of countries sought to
overcome the constraint arising from the need
for international money (gold or convertible
currencies). National economies isolated
themselves and started interacting with other
economies on the principle of barter. The
Balkan countries fell under this third, German
group.
Technically, the “moneyless” exchange
in the clearing area, dominated by Germany,
consisted of a smooth transition from
systematic currency control, contingents of
imports (and subsequently to compensation
agreements), to bilateral, rarely tripartite,
clearings. Later, the system was expanded
to include private compensations34. Foreign
exchange flows were centralised in the CBs
of the participating countries35. We will note
that the clearing institution contains technical
elements expressing the subordination of
one of the two countries. These are: (i) the
level of the exchange rate, (ii) the prices of
goods in both countries, which are recorded
in the clearing agreements, and (iii) the
settlement of the final balances. In the case
of the clearings of the Balkan countries with
Germany, despite some technical details, they
were all designed so that even if in the short
run they were profitable for the periphery,
In clearing models, money has settlement, accounting functions. In these models, the means of measurement is
separated from that of payments.
We will not delve into this whole system of ‘monetary nationalism’, which has been the subject of detailed
analysis (Heilperin, 2010 [1960]).
184
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
in the long run they made it dependent and
deprived of choice36.
With the start of the war and the need to
mobilise more and more resources, Germany
intensified its pressure on the level of the
exchange rate and the prices of exchanged
goods in its favour. Thus, for example, from
1934 Bulgaria accumulated a positive clearing
balance with Germany (all Balkan countries
had similar positive balances), which was not
covered either by imports of machinery and
raw materials, or by capital inflows. In order to
clear the balances in the last years of WW2,
the German negotiators on the clearing lists
offered unnaturally high and “arbitrary” prices
of their machines, as well as artificially low
prices for Bulgarian goods. At times, German
agents would even act aggressively. In the
memoirs of the High Commissioner of the
Bulgarian Military Economy Petar Aladzhov,
during the negotiations, within the framework
of a series of confidential minutes in late
194337, it is noted:
“Recently, the German state has
arbitrarily increased the prices of its
exports, whereas the Bulgarian ones have
remained almost at the same level as
before. […] Germany was no longer able to
supply the requested quantities of certain
machines, and at best only supplied single
units. The German state seriously insisted
on getting the whole amount of tobacco
produced in Bulgaria. The Reich’s tobacco
agent was named Dr. Wenkel. He had an
injured leg and walked with a cane. During
the talks with our Minister of Trade Nikola
Zahariev, a point was reached where Dr.
Wenkel had reached out to hit our Minister
with a cane. It is obvious how much the
passions around the Bulgarian tobacco
had become hot.” (Aladzhov, 2000, p.121122)
For the period under review, almost all
foreign trade on the Balkans went through
clearings, and mostly through those with
Germany (Tables 1 and 2 give some
illustrations of this dynamics).
Table 1: The Balkan countries’ trade with Germany
Import
1933
Hungary
Yugoslavia
Romania
Bulgaria
Greece
Turkey
1937
19,7
13,2
18,0
38,2
10,3
25,5
Export
1938
26,2
32,6
30,8
54,8
26,1
42,0
1933
48,1
50
48,5
57,9
31,1
51,3
1937
11,2
13,9
10,6
36,0
19,7
18,9
1938
25,6
21,5
20,6
43,1
27,3
36,0
50,1
49,9
35,9
63,6
43,2
47,3
Source: Arndt (2014 [1944], p.198).
A detailed analysis of the technical elements of currency control, compensation and clearing, as well as their
micro and macroeconomic effects on the Bulgarian economy (the analysis is applicable to other Balkan countries)
is made in Nenovsky and al. (2007), and Nenovsky and Dimitrova (2007).
37
In 1943, serious clearing problems arose for Germany. It had nothing to compensate and pay with, and there was
even a plan to offer shares in German companies to trading and partner companies (Toose, 2006, p.257).
36
185
Articles
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
Table 2: Clearing and non-clearing trade of Bulgaria (1934-1939)
Export (shares, %)
Years/
shares
1934
1935
1936
1937
1938
1938a
1939a
Clearing
in total
export
78.97
77.25
69.44
65.52
77.24
71.68
72.81
Germany
in total
export
48.05
49.48
50.53
47.11
58.86
51.49
59.43
Germany
in total
clearing
Import (shares, %)
Nonclearing
in total
export
60.84
68.09
72.78
71.91
76.21
71.78
81.63
21.03
22.75
30.56
34.48
22.76
21.40
27.19
Clearing
in total
import
78.30
80.19
81.70
79.90
74.02
74.74
80.89
Germany
in total
import
48.87
59.82
66.67
58.22
51.43
54.10
61.04
Germany
in total
clearing
Nonclearing
in total
import
62.43
75.11
81.58
72.82
70.22
72.38
75.46
21.70
19.81
18.30
20.10
25.98
25.32
19.05
Source and note: a-export/import data refer to the first five/four months of the year, Christophoroff (1939)
During socialist times, and even today
in Bulgarian historiography, and above all
among historians, there is a definite opinion
that Germany plunders the Balkan countries,
including Bulgaria through the system of
clearings38. For example, according to the
leading historian Nikolay Genchev:
’In the last five pre-war years, Germany,
through the enslaving system of clearing,
established a monopoly on the exports of
the countries of the Danube basin and the
Balkans – Hungary, Romania, Yugoslavia,
Bulgaria and Greece, and partly Turkey’
(Genchev, 1998, p.16).
Finally, we will note that along with the
economic and monetary practices of the
German Lebensraum in the Balkan countries,
the economic theories of corporatism, the
managed economy and economic autarchy
permanently gain ground (see Nenovsky,
2012, Penchev, 2019).
38
IV. The Soviet area and the
COMECON. Passive money and
the transferable ruble
(1945 – 1989)
With the end of World War II (WWII) a new
centre of gravity emerged on the Balkans the Soviet Union. Greece remained in the orbit
of the winning countries (notably England and
the United States), and subsequently went
through various political regimes to reach
membership in the European Community (later
European Union). As for the rest of the Balkan
countries, the communist bloc - of the Soviet
Russia and the COMECON - became decisive.
Within this model we can talk about the
existence of ‘dependent socialism’. Romania
and Albania had their specific traits (after
1961/62), following in general the trajectory
of the socialist bloc. Yugoslavia, which had
already become socialist, (SFR Yugoslavia),
built a specific model of self-government
and conducted economic cooperation with
capitalist and developing countries. Below
we will limit ourselves to Bulgaria and SFR
More nuanced observations are given in Nenovsky and al. (2007) and Nenovsky and Dimitrova (2007).
186
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
Yugoslavia, as examples of countries where
the model of dependent monetary regime
manifests itself in various forms.
Bulgaria very quickly moved from complete
German domination to complete dependence
on the new military and geopolitical centre –
the Soviet Union and the economic bloc of
the COMECON (conceived as an alternative
to the American Marshall Plan). After the
nationalisation of banks and industry in 1947,
and later the collectivisation of agriculture
and the introduction of the foreign exchange
monopoly, Bulgaria continued its barter and
clearing practices, however this time with
new, socialist partners. Like the German
Lebensraum, the Soviet area was based on
administrative, anti-market and autarchic
principles. The internal currency circulation of
each country was closed and detached from
foreign money, from external payments (a
kind of socialist monetary nationalism).
Despite the visible similarities with the
Lebensraum, Bulgarian economists were
quick to point out the fundamental differences:
‘In accordance with the general
character of the International Economic
Relations under socialism, the foreign
exchange policy of the socialist state is
alien to the tendencies of subordinating
one currency to another, the aspiration to
place the economic and monetary policy
of the weak countries in dependence
of the strong countries […] The national
currencies of the socialist countries serve
their domestic economy. They are closed
in nature and are not freely exchanged
for foreign currencies. Therefore, they
are not used in international payments,
with the exception of some non-trade
payments within the socialist community.
[…] Retaining its form as a category of the
capitalist world economy and its foreign
exchange system, clearing in the relations
between the socialist countries radically
changed its role. Clearing is used by the
socialist countries as a means of orderly
regulating international payments and
maintaining the balance of payments
without the conversion of convertible
currencies. The clearing agreements
between the socialist states are based
on the principles of full equity and mutual
benefit’ (Tsarevski, 1976, p.8, p.178).
In the new economic and currency bloc,
payments under bilateral clearings were made
in dollars and since 1950 in Soviet rubles.
Payments in rubles released the participating
countries from the need to hold reserves in
convertible currencies. In 1957, a shift was
made to a multilateral clearing based on the
Soviet ruble; the settlement clearing centre
was located within the Soviet State Bank (the
Gosbank). In 1963/64 a serious international
payment reform was carried out. There was a
shift to a model of multilateral payments, and
the new collective settlement currency was
created – the transferable ruble. Although
payments were multilateral, the trade behind
them continued to be based on bilateral barter.
Within the framework of clearing, foreign
trade and currency planning were performed
within each country, determining mandatory
contingents for import and export, by country
and by commodity lists.
The transferable ruble had the gold parity
of the Soviet ruble. However, it was freely
transferable between socialist countries’
accounts in the newly created International
187
Articles
Bank for Economic Cooperation (IBEC)39.
Importantly, the transferable ruble was not
convertible into any socialist currency, not
even Soviet rubles40. The transition was done
through the currency ratios, which we will
mention below. IBEC performed the role of
clearing bank of the COMECON countries,
each country having an active or passive
balance towards IBEC, i.e., to other countries
taken as a whole (and not to a single country).
IBEC also provided loans within certain limits to
maintain the balance of payments of member
countries41. IBEC placed its free convertible
resources on the Eurodollar market.
Until 1973, Bulgaria had a slight positive
balance with the COMECON countries
and thereafter (more precisely until 1986)
there were strong negative balances. In the
capitalist countries, the balance throughout
the period was strongly negative, offset by
the strongly positive balance in trade with
developing countries42. Within the COMECON,
the main creditor, including of Bulgaria,
became the Soviet Union. In 1971, the
International Investment Bank (IIB) emerged,
which granted investment loans from 5 to 15
years. The Bulgarian lev was de facto pegged
to the transferable ruble, and through it to the
Soviet ruble.
39
40
41
42
43
44
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
Internationally, there were two currency
turnovers: (i) for trade and (ii) for non-trade
payments. These two turnovers, two payment
sectors, replicate the two spheres within the
individual national socialist economies (noncash and cash sectors)43. The domestic noncash sector served enterprises and institutions,
i.e., the public sector as a whole, and the
cash sector served households, cooperatives,
and the consumer sector. It preserved, within
certain limits, market relations (“commoditymoney relations”). Households had access to
limited consumer goods and services (up to
the purchase of a car and a home), which
were paid for with cash. In the cash sector,
the “balance of income and expenditure of the
population” was formed, which was controlled
by the Central Bank (the Monobank).
Consumer prices were fixed and generally low
because ‘stable low prices are the conquest
of real socialism’. In terms of volumes, the
cash sector was significantly smaller than the
non-cash sector44.
The relationship between the two cash
turnovers was actively planned – mostly the
outflows from the non-cash to the cash sector
in the form of wages, just as the reverse flow –
from the cash to the non-cash sector, in the
form of payment of taxes and fees. Cash was
also controlled by the Monobank through
“The transferable ruble is the most stable international settlement and payment instrument in the world”
(Tsarevski, 1976, p.36). In the Bulgarian clearings, at the beginning, gold and foreign exchange arrangements
were partially applied, and with Yugoslavia the clearing was always in dollars. “Currency arrangements have
never been used in Bulgaria’s clearing agreements with the socialist countries. They are irrelevant in those
clearings that are conducted in rubles, as there is no more stable currency, to which the ruble exchange rate
could be pegged.“ (Tsarevski, 1976, p.188).
In the 1980s, there were also ideas (mainly by Polish economists) for the transferable ruble to become officially
pegged and convertible into gold or dollars. See Tsarevsky (1978, p.40).
In a sense, this construction is very close to Keynes’s design. The principles and the evolution of the currency
relations within the COMECON, as well as the place of Bulgaria, are exhaustively elaborated in the extremely
useful book of N. Tsarevsky (1976).
Stoimenov (1990, p.81-87).
For details see Garvy (1977), as well as Kaser (1967), McKinnon (1982 [1979]), and Lelart (1986).
Financial markets and assets did not exist (they were “capitalist phenomena”).
188
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
the ‘cash plan’45, formulating the issue of
cash46. In order to maintain the balance of the
system and to avoid social tensions or open
inflation, one-off monetary measures were
mostly employed47. They were expressed
in raising prices, shrinking the cash supply
(deflation) or in the form of monetary reform
(currency exchange). Through the currency
exchange, the hoarded cash depreciated.
Such depreciations occurred in Bulgaria
in 194748, 1952, and 1962. These palliative
measures ended in 1989 when the planning
system exhausted the possibilities for partial
equilibria and the potential inflation became
open.
In general, this is as far as the internal
element of the monetary regime is concerned.
Let us now return to the international aspect
of the monetary regime under socialism.
Commercial payments, effected in
transferable rubles within the clearing of the
45
46
47
48
49
IBEC, were made at contract prices. These
prices were based on the average, cycleadjusted wholesale prices on capitalist
markets over a given period (five and then
one year). Contract prices were detached
from national prices, and the ratio between
contract and national prices was determined
by the famous ‘currency ratio, coefficient’,
through which national money was converted
into transferable rubles.
In
non-commercial,
non-commodity
payments, i.e., in ‘all payments made by
a country and its citizens in the territory of
other socialist countries in local currency and
at retail prices on the local market’49, mainly
for services, tourism and others – an agreed
bilateral exchange rate and real exchange
rate of currency was set. This was done
according to retail prices in both countries.
The link between both segments of payments
– commercial and non-commercial, was
It is the net balance of the implementation of the ‘cash income and expenditure of the population’ plan, as well as
the available transactions under the cooperative sector and payments abroad, etc. When the revenues are more
than the payments under the cash plan, the issuance result shows the withdrawal of money from circulation, and
vice versa, when the receipts are less than the payments under the cash plan, the net result is expressed in the
release of additional amount of cash (Kotsev, 1989, p.45-46).
Due to the internal limits of planning (“soft budget constraints”), as well as the “law on outpacing development
of the means of production sector vis-à-vis the consumer goods sector”, the cash supply inevitably grows
faster than the volume of the consumer market. This comes from wages outpacing labour productivity, as well
as the emergence of budget deficits. The outflow of purchasing power from the non-cash sector (enterprises
and institutions) to the cash sector is called by Kornai the “siphoning effect”. “Money supply overhang” and
“repressed inflation” are coupled with structural shortages in the consumer market. The specific manifestations
of these phenomena are queues, poor quality of goods, substitution of high-quality goods by poor quality goods,
forced joint sale of desired and unwanted goods, corruption and black market, privileges (specialty stores),
meaningless investment projects, artificial employments, hidden unemployment, and most of all, significant
forced savings of the population. These savings are primarily in the form of deposits in the savings bank
(sometimes saved in cash, in banknotes). These savings indicate the existence of solvent demand without a
corresponding supply.
Apart from several attempts at structural reforms aimed at business autonomy and greater arbitrariness, initially
in Hungary and Yugoslavia, and later in other countries.
In this monetary reform, the large sums presented for exchange are taxed with a progressive tax, which also
withdraws a large volume of money supply.
Ivanov (1989, p.387). See for details Daskalov and Maslarov (1990, p.160-173). Here, too, the variety of exchange
rates and premiums is reminiscent of the diversity of different types of specialised marks in the 1930s used for
payments in the German economic zone.
189
Articles
made possible by translating the balance of
non-commercial payments at a certain ratio in
order to include it in the total account of IBEC.
This conversion factor shows the deviation
of the domestic prices in the USSR from
the contract prices (according to the unified
nomenclature of goods and services). The
exchange rates of non-trade payments, and
in particular the ratios at which the balances
of non-trade transactions are included in
the balances of the IBEC, are subject to
confrontation. The country with a surplus on
non-trade transactions tends to have a lower
ratio, i.e., to receive more transferable rubles,
and the state with a passive balance strives
for this ratio to be higher in order to pay less
transferable rubles. In general, the USSR
imposed its will, and due to its active balances
sought to reduce the conversion factor. Thus,
from 3.4 domestic roubles for one transferable
ruble, in 1971 the factor became 2.3 for one
transferable ruble, and at the end of the
1970s it became 1.9. Before the collapse of
the COMECON, it was 1.7 domestic Soviet
rubles for 1 transferable ruble.
The stated anchoring of the Bulgarian
monetary regime to the Soviet ruble (‘the
most stable currency in the world’) serves
the inclusion of Bulgaria in the International
Socialist Division of Labour (launched in
1961), as well as ‘the need to catch up with
the developed socialist countries.’ This is
done both through the mechanism of trade
and through the levers of investment and
credit. Within the COMECON, the Soviet
Union is the creditor country, the rest are
debtors. The prominent Bulgarian economist
of the socialist period, E. Mateev, makes the
following summary:
“Bulgaria has embarked on the path
of its economic development with high
hidden agricultural unemployment (which
190
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
is now almost non-existent, although the
village will continue to supply workforce in
the future). In the course of industrialisation,
former unemployed peasants and their
children were able to obtain employment
in their own country (and not, for example,
through the export of labour, as in many
other countries), and not to the detriment
of efficiency dictated by proper territorial
distribution of the productive forces,
but rather in full agreement with it. This
became possible because the country
was able to supply itself with machines,
liquid fuels, metals and other raw
materials from the Soviet Union, which
was paid for by exporting products from
the specialisation of the old industries
and from the unfinished industries, i.e.,
because it gained wide access to the
Soviet markets and thereby the necessary
foreign exchange resources to pay for
imports, because in the Soviet Union it
encountered not competitive indices, as in
the capitalist markets, but, on the contrary,
fraternal assistance in quickly achieving
the necessary quality and standards.“
(Mateev, 1969, p.19).
As a result, during the first twenty-five
years of socialism:
“The strong overtaking of foreign trade
relations reflects not only absolute, but
also relative deepening of the country’s
participation in the international division of
labour. Given that nearly 4/5 of all foreign
trade of Bulgaria is with the socialist
countries, and half – with the Soviet Union,
it is concluded that it is a question of the
deepening participation of our country
not only in the International Division of
Labour in general, but in the International
Division of Labour specifically with the
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
socialist countries, and especially with the
Soviet Union […]. One third of the value of
machines and metal products produced in
the country originate directly and, above
all, indirectly, through the metal, from
imports mainly from the Soviet Union“
(Mateev, 1969, p.11, p.16)
As for Soviet investments, according
to another Bulgarian leading monetary
economist, N. Tsarevski:
“So far, our country has used a total
of more than 2 billion rubles in loans
from the USSR alone. Only in the current
five-year plan (1971-1975) Bulgaria uses
loans from the USSR in the amount of 50
million rubles. Soviet loans reach in some
periods from 20 to 25% of the value of our
capital investments. If the amount of loans
received is compared only with the active
part of capital investments, i.e., the value
of invested machines and equipment,
the relative share of credits in individual
years reaches 50%. This gave a decisive
impetus to the accelerated economic
development of the country, to socialist
transformations and industrialisation.
Our country could not possibly catch up
with economically developed socialist
countries without credit. […] The facilities
built in our country with Soviet aid provide
95% of the production of ferrous metals,
80% of the petrochemical production, 60%
of the electricity, 55% of the production
of the chemical industry, a large part
of the machine-building products, etc.“
(Tsarevski, 1976, p.195-196).
50
In general, the two types of exchange
rate factors, exchange rates and prices at
which foreign economic transactions took
place, were determined administratively (i.e.,
economically on an arbitrary principle), and
were the result of negotiations among member
states. The small countries in the COMECON
had only the power to set their domestic prices;
in all other parameters the word of the Soviet
Union overruled, as the latter considered
its strategic interests. Without going into
detail, we will mention just one eloquent
fact. During the trial of Bulgaria’s Deputy
Prime Minister Traicho Kostov (1949), who
was tried for espionage in favour of England
and Yugoslavia, one of the accusations was
that he attempted to negotiate fairer prices
in trade with the Soviet Union50. This clearly
resembles the practice of setting exchange
prices in the German clearings of the 1930s
(cf Aladzhov’s testimony from the previous
section).
Later, in the 1980s (especially after 1986),
there was a lot of talk within the COMECON
about direct links between enterprises, i.e.,
carrying integration to a micro level. It was
derived from reforms to decentralisation and
business initiative of enterprises in individual
countries. In Bulgaria, this was announced
by Decree 56 on Economic Activity as of
February 1989. In 1987, the idea of forming
a common socialist market was launched.
Enterprises were given (at least verbally) the
opportunity to choose their markets within
the COMECON (national market or Comecon
common market). This also raised the issue of
currency convertibility of the lev (internal and
external, within the COMECON), as well as
the need for a single exchange rate, foreign
See Kaser (1967, p.178). In M. Kaser’s book, as in G. Graziani’s study (1982 [1981]), analyses and facts are
presented showing the economic dependence (and alternative losses) of the small socialist countries in their
economic relations with the Soviet Union, as well as the latter’s dominant role. See Kaser (1967, p.178).
191
Articles
exchange market and currency regulation by
the Central Bank51. There were ideas for the
ruble to remain at the heart of the system and
even become convertible currency. However,
it became increasingly clear that the model of
socialist integration had no prospects given
the national isolation and central planning. As
is well known, very soon after the attempted
reforms, in 1989/1990 the COMECON ceased
to exist and payments became market-based
and in dollars.
Let us now look at Socialist Yugoslavia,
which displayed another model of monetary
dependence – dependence on the West.
Initially, it was pegged to the dollar zone and
in the 1980s also to the German mark.
Somewhat forgotten today, the Yugoslav
model of socialism, albeit within the
framework of Marxist ideology, sought to be
an alternative to Soviet central planning. It
was defined as self-management socialism,
with the characteristics of workers ownership,
decentralisation, openness to the West, etc.52.
The self-management model was introduced
with the reforms of 1952, which intensified in
1965/6653. From 1964, Yugoslavia moved to
a two-tier banking system, and the Central
Bank, without completely abandoning the
principles of planning, commenced targeting
of monetary aggregates. Without going
into details, we will note that the model of
self-management was not clarified either
conceptually or practically. It proved to be an
inefficient and disproportions-accumulating
economic system. The money supply was
51
52
53
54
55
56
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
constantly getting out of control and this led
to high inflation, balance of payments deficits
and large external debts, etc.
Externally, more than half of Yugoslavia’s
trade was with developed economies and third
world countries. Between 20% and 30% of
Yugoslav workers worked in Western Europe
at some point in their lives and transferred
significant amounts of convertible currency to
Yugoslavia54. From its inception and throughout
the years of the cold war Yugoslavia was a
member of the IMF55, followed its principles,
declared its exchange rate regime and even
received a loan (for example, in 1974). Its
representatives worked in the fund, such as
Dragolsav Avramovich, who later, in the 1990s
stabilised the dinar by pegging it to the mark.
Of particular interest is the evolution of
the exchange rate regime. Broadly speaking,
it follows three periods: (i) fixed rate regime
(1945-1973); (ii) managed floating regime
(1973 - 1989), and (iii) re-fixed rate over
a short-term horizon (1989 - 1990)56. As a
general rule, the development of the exchange
rate regime closely followed the evolution of
the international monetary system.
From the very beginning, the exchange rate
was defined within the gold-dollar standard,
and all bilateral clearings of Yugoslavia were
in dollars. In April 1945, after a monetary
reform (exchange of money, etc.), the dinar
was fixed to the dollar (and respectively to
gold) at the rate of 1 USD = 50 dinars. Several
devaluations followed, of which only two were
officially registered with the IMF (1952 and
See Stoimenov (1984, 1990).
Initially, the distinction was primarily political (anti-Stalin). Yugoslavia was not part of the Warsaw Pact and the
COMECON; it was an active participant in the Non-Aligned Movement.
In 1974, the new constitution further intensified decentralisation.
The Yugoslav passport cost 10,000 USD on the black market (Nikolic, 2018).
With a short break from 1945 to 1949.
The dynamics of the three periods is explained in the review study of Stoyanović (2007). In the text we use the
chronology of this article, as well as other sources.
192
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
1966), with two not registered (1954 and 1961).
The devaluations not registered with the IMF
were carried out by introducing premiums on
various payments on imports and exports.
The first six-fold devaluation, that of
December 1952 (1 USD became 300
dinars), coincided with the beginning of selfgovernment reforms, as well as with the
restrictive policy of Kiro Gligorov. Gligorov
stabilised public finances and convertibility
of the dinar was discussed. From 1952 to
January 1966, the official exchange rate was
maintained, but payments on imports and
exports were made with different premiums for
the dollar, which actually led to an exchange
rate between 120 and 1,200 dinars per USD.
In 1961, an accounting 150% premium was
introduced, which makes a single accounting
change rate of 750 dinars per USD57. During
these years, an attempt was made to build
a foreign exchange market (an exchange
accounting place), where the dollar reached
circa 600 dinars. On the black market they
were even higher - 2000 to 4000 dinars for
USD.
The second official devaluation of 1 January
1966 came after a price redenomination of
100 times, and the new dinar was pegged to
the dollar at the rate of 1 USD = 12.5 new
dinars (i.e., 1250 old dinars). Thus, (according
to Stojanović, 2007) officially, the devaluation
was 317%, but de facto it was 67%. The
measures can be interpreted as absorbing
the overhanging money supply, which we
mentioned when discussing Bulgaria, in order
to curb inflation and improve the state of the
balance of payments.
In 1971, two devaluations took place,
in January (up to 15 dinars for USD) and
December (17 dinars for USD). The dollar
57
crisis followed. From July 1973, the dinar
was officially switched to a regime of
managed floating against the dollar within
(+/-2.25%) corridor and steps were taken to
form a functioning foreign exchange market.
According to N. Tsarevski:
“After the devaluation of the US dollar,
Yugoslavia kept the dinar exchange rate
unchanged against the US currency and
reduced its gold content to 0.043333
fine gold, i.e., the dinar followed the two
devaluations of the US dollar. In this
way, the dinar exchange rate and parity
follow the changes in the main capitalist
currencies to which it is significantly
pegged.“ (Tsarevski, 1976, p.53).
From 1973, however, the dinar was
constantly depreciating and straying from
the specified corridor. In 1974, Yugoslavia
was forced to seek a loan from the IMF
due to difficulties in its balance of payments
and debt service. From 1977, the Yugoslav
monetary authorities intervened not only with
regard to the dollar but also as regards the
mark (Germany and the mark began to play
an increasingly important role in the country’s
external payments). Macroeconomic dynamics
was continuously deteriorating, partly due to
the decentralisation that took place during
the adoption of the new Constitution in 1974.
Expenditures and the money supply spiralled
out of control, leading to inflation and a rising
debt. The devaluation of the dinar was stopped
in the early 1990s by fixing it to the mark and
as a result of the shock therapy. However, the
reform failed, and at the end of 1990 the dinar
finally collapsed. Somewhat later, Yugoslavia
was going to experience one of the largest
hyperinflations known in monetary history.
Stojanović (2007), Tsarevski (1976).
193
Articles
Interestingly, M. Friedman visited
Yugoslavia in March 1973. This happened
at the very moment when the Yugoslav
leadership had to choose the new exchange
rate regime (in July 1973 it chose managed
floating). Clearly, Friedman was invited to
give advice58. In his speech at the Central
Bank of Yugoslavia, Friedman offered two
extreme options (Currency Board and fully
floating exchange rate), his preferred option
being fixing the exchange rate to the German
mark under a currency board arrangement
(unified currency). (Edwards, 2020, p.17)
Friedman also proposed developing the
foreign exchange market. Friedman saw the
internal contradictions of the interim regimes,
including managed floating, chosen by the
Yugoslav authorities. The problems were not
long in coming and the expansionist monetary
policy, which lacked automatic adjustment
mechanisms, became incompatible with the
controlled exchange rate. The monetary
policy is a function of the inefficient, although
at first glance different from the Soviet, model
of socialist self-management economy (Liotta,
2001, Stojanović, 2007).
Thus, both in the case of Bulgaria, which
followed the ruble and non-market payments
zone, and in the case of Yugoslavia, which
was closely tied to Western monetary
practices, we see that the monetary regime in
the Balkan periphery is dependent.
Concluding discussion
In this article we have presented a
theoretical reconstruction of the long
monetary history of different Balkan countries.
It illustrates the hypothesis of a structural
dependence of the monetary regime of Balkan
58
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
countries, passing through different political
and ideological regimes. Its cyclical nature
can be traced back to the time of the Ottoman
Empire until the present day. The monetary
regime of the Balkans is a manifestation of
a geopolitical and economic dependence, be
it imperial, capitalist, socialist, ‘transitional’
post-communist, or Europeanising, etc.
This dependence does not mean doom and
determinism. It shows the limits within which
Balkan elites can make decisions and pursue
economic and monetary policies.
The theoretical model proposed to interpret
the monetary history of the Balkan region,
that of the “dependent monetary regime”, is
only one of several possible models. We do
not claim to have exclusivity. Much remains
to be done under the proposed hypothesis,
and it is beyond the reach of individual
researchers. At least because knowledge of
the great diversity and intertwined histories
of the region must be mobilized, knowledge
accumulated in many languages and
stored
in many archives and publications. Such an
initiative can only be the product of collective
effort from representatives of all Balkan
countries.
Theoretically, it is necessary to deepen the
analysis of structural monetary dependence,
its specific and general mechanisms and
forms in different monetary systems and
monetary regimes - bimetallic, gold, goldexchange, paper (fiat), clearing, “planned”
currency, etc. Of particular importance is the
analysis of monetary dependence in the two
archetypal systems of economic coordination,
namely market and administrative-command
(planned), as well as in the two social systems
This was not his first visit, but his second one: in 1962 he was invited to Yugoslavia and the reason we can
presume was very much the same – to give advice.
194
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
– capitalist, private and socialist, collectivist59.
As we have seen, monetary dependence
is also inherent in the peripheral socialist
economy, in the case of dependence on the
USSR within or not within the COMECON.
Important in this regard is the influence of
Marxist and communist ideas about money and
monetary practice. It is also important to study
in more depth the monetary dependence on
the positions of the dialectic of the function of
money as a means of payment and as a unit
of account, of external and internal money.
In fact, the combination of these functions is
not the same in different modes (for example,
in clearing dominance the unit of account is
separated from the means of payment).
Empirically, there is even more work to
be done. There are two directions here. The
first is the presentation of individual case
studies of monetary dependence through the
analysis of the institutional configuration and
the sociology of different groups and actors,
their interests and ideology (see Nenovsky
and Rizopoulos, 2003, 2004). The second,
much more difficult, is the construction of
quantitative and qualitative indicators of
monetary dependence and their quantitative,
econometric analysis.
We repeat again, this can only happen
within the collective and international efforts
of Balkan scientists. Such analyses will be
useful in building a more realistic vision of the
prospects for Balkan monetary economies,
regarding the EU and eurozone development.
References
Aganski, N., 1936. The German market and
the Danube countries, Archive of economic
and social policy, 11 (2), pp. 132-141 (in
Bulgarian).
59
Aladzhov, P., 2000. High Commissioner. A Life
in the Service of the National Economy. Sofia:
Sofia University Kliment Ohridski, (in
Bulgarian).
Arndt, H., W., 2014[1944]. The Economic
lessons of the nineteen-thirties. London:
Routledge.
Atanasov, H., N. Nenovsky, 2019. Money and
Prices in the 18th – 19th Centuries. Bulgarian
Historiography on the Monetary History of the
Balkan Provinces of the Ottoman Empire,
Bulgarian Historical Review, (1-2), pp. 80-111.
Băicoianu C., 1932. Istoria politicii noastre
monetare şi a Băncii Naţionale. Bucureşti:
Monitorul oficial si Impremeriile Statului,
Impremeria Nationala.
Basciani, A., 2020. Growth without
Development: The Post-WWI Period in the
Lower Danube. Perspectives and Problems of
Romania and Bulgaria. The Journal of
European Economic History, (3), pp. 139-164.
Berov, L., 1990. Development of industry in
Bulgaria until the First World War. in L. Berov,
D. Dimitrov (eds), Development of industry in
Bulgaria (1834, 1947, 1989), Sofia: Nauka i
Izkustvo, 36-113 (in Bulgarian).
Berov, L., 1990а. Development of capitalist
industry in the period between the two world
wars, in L. Berov, D. Dimitrov (eds),
Development of industry in Bulgaria (1834,
1947, 1989), Sofia: Nauka i Izkustvo, 114 -238
(in Bulgarian).
Bobchev, K., 1933. Prof M. Manoilescu’s
Protectionist Theory. Journal of Bulgarian
Economic Society, 32, pp. 478-494 (in
Bulgarian).
Bobchev, K., 1937. Studies of the Theory of
International Trade. Sofia: Poligrafia, (in
Bulgarian).
The planned, socialist economy can be seen as a specific, extreme form of state capitalism. But this is another
research story.
195
Articles
Bochkovitch, M., 1919. La Banque Nationale
de Serbie. Thèse pour le doctorat, Paris:
Jouve & Cie.
Bohle, D., and Greskovits, B., 2012. Capitalist
Diversity on Europe’s Periphery. Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press.
Burg, S., 2016 [1983]. Conflict and Cohesion
in Socialist Yugoslavia: Political Decision
Making Since 1966. Princeton: Princeton
Legacy Library.
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
Compte rendu « in extenso » et documents.
Paris: Bibliothèque des annales économiques.
Colombatto, E., 1984. L’economia politica del
comercio Est-Ovest. Milano: Ed. Etas Libri,
Sonzogno.
Danaillow, G., 1932. Les effets de la guerre
en Bulgarie. Paris: Presses Universitaires de
France.
Calmès, A., 1922. The Economic and Financial
Situation of Albania. League of Nations, Report
prepared by Professor A. Calmès regarding
his mission of enquiry in Albania, Geneva.
Daskalov, P., S. Maslarov, 1990. Problems of
non-trade currency relations, in M. Stoimenov
(ed.), Currency problems of the economic
development of the People’s Republic of
Bulgaria, Sofia: Nauka i Izkustvo, pp. 160-173
(in Bulgarian).
Cardoso, F. H., 1977. The Consumption of
Dependency Theory in the United States,
Latin American Research Review, 12(3), pp.724.
Drahokoupil, J., and Myant M., 2011. Transition
Economies: Political Economy in Russia,
Eastern Europe, and Central Asia. Hoboken:
John Wiley & Sons.
Cardoso, F. H., and Faletto, E. (1979),
Dependency and Development in Latin
America. Berkeley, University of California
Press.
Edwards, S., 2020. Milton Friedman and
Exchange Rates in Developing Countries.
NBER Working Paper, No. 27975.
Chakalov, A., 1962. Forms, size and activity of
foreign capital in Bulgaria (1878-1944). Sofia:
Ed. of Bulgarians Academy of Sciences.
Einaudi, L., 2001. Money and Politics.
European Monetary Unification and the Gold
Standard (1865-1873). Oxford: Oxford
University press.
Chausserie-Laprée, P., 1911. L’Union
Monétaire Latine. Son passé, sa situation
actuelle, ses chances d’avenir et sa liquidation
éventuelle. Thèse, Université de Paris, Arthur
Rousseau, Paris.
Evans P., 1979. Dependent Development: The
Alliance of Multinational, State, and Local
Capital in Brazil. Princeton NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Chavance, B., and Magnin, E., 2002.
Emergence of path-dependent mixed
economies in Central Europe. In: G. Hodgson
(Ed.), A Modern Reader in Institutional and
Evolutionary Economics: Key Concepts,
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp.168-200.
Christophoroff, A., 1939. The Course of the
Trade Cycle in Bulgaria 1934-1939. Statistical
Institute for Economic Research, Sofia:
“Pridvorna” Printing House (in Bulgarian).
CMI (Congrès Monétaire International), 1890.
Congrès Monétaire International, 1889.
196
Fabris, N., 2015. The History of Money in
Montenegro. Journal of Central Banking
Theory and Practice, 4(1), pp. 5-18.
Farkas, B., 2016. Models of Capitalism in the
European Union. Post-crisis Perspectives.
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Genchev, N., 1998. Bulgaria’s Foreign Policy,
1938-1941. Sofia: Vector Publishing House (in
Bulgarian).
Garvy, G., 1977. Money, Financial Flows and
Credit in the Soviet Union. NBER, Ballinger
Publishing Company.
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
Gillard, L., 2017. L’Union Latine, une experience
de souverainetés monétaires partagées
(1865-1926). Paris: Classique Garnier.
Kyoseva, N., 2000. History of the monetary
crises in Bulgaria 1879-1912. Sofia: ed.
Stopanstvo (in Bulgarian).
Graziani, G., 1982 [1981]. COMECON,
domination et dépendances. Série « Économie
et socialisme », Paris: François Maspero.
Koszul, J., 1932. Les efforts de restauration
financière de la Bulgarie (1922–1931). Paris:
Félix Alcan.
Helleiner, E., 2003. The Making of National
Money: Territorial Currencies in Historical
Perspective. Ithaca and London: Cornell
University Press.
Lane, D., Myant, M., (Eds), 2007. Varieties of
Capitalism in Post-Communist Countries.
Houndmills and New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Gnjatović, D.,2020. Evolution of Economic
Thought on Monetary Reform in the Kingdom
of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes after the Great
War. Balcanica, 50(1), pp. 184-205.
Gnjatović, D., V. Dugalić, B. Stojanović, 2003.
Istorija nacionalnog novca. Belgrade: Sineks.
Iordanov, D., 1910. Bulgarian National Bank,
1879-1908 (with 7 annexes and 9 diagrams).
Sofia: Liberalen Club ed. (in Bulgarian).
Iaranov, A., 1934. Economic Policy in Bulgaria
(de 1878 à 1928). Sofia: Edition Hudojnik. (in
Bulgarian)
Iliev, I., 2004. The Economy of Bulgaria in the
Period 1949 – 2001. Sofia: Ed. “D. Bratoev ”
(in Bulgarian).
Ivanov, A., 1929. Report of the BNB Governor
Asen Ivanov at the Reception to celebrate the
fiftieth anniversary of the BNB Foundation.
The Central Public Record Office, The
Bulgarian National Bank: a Collection of
Documents, Vol. 3, 1915–1929, document No.
22, pp. 136–144 (in Bulgarian).
Kaser, M., 1967. COMECON. Integration
problems of the planned economy. London:
Oxford University Press.
King, L., 2002. Postcommunist Divergence: A
Comparative Analysis of the Transition to
Capitalism in Poland and Russia. Studies in
Comparative International Development, 37
(3), pp. 3-34.
Lazaretou, S., 1993. Monetary and iscal
Policies in Greece: 1833-1914. The Journal of
European Economic History, 22(2), pp. 285311.
Laveleye, E., 1888. La péninsule des Balkans:
Vienne, Croatie, Bosnie, Serbie, Bulgarie,
Roumélie, Turquie, Roumanie. Paris: Felix
Alcan.
Lelart, M., 1986. Le système international du
rouble et les relations monétaires Est-Ouest.
Revue d’études comparatives est-ouest, 17(1):
pp. 69-97.
Liotta, P., 2001. Paradigm Lost: Yugoslav SelfManagement and the Economics of Disaster.
Balkanologie.
Revue
d’études
pluridisciplinaires, 5(1-2), pp. 1-19.
Lyapchev, A., 1929. Welcoming speech of the
Council of Ministers’ Chairman, Andrei
Liapchev, at the reception to celebrate the
fiftieth anniversary of the BNB Foundation.
Central Public Record Office to the Council
of Ministers, The Bulgarian National Bank:
a Collection of Documents, volume 3, 1915
– 1929, document 21, pp. 134– 135 (in
Bulgarian).
Magnin, E., 2002. Path-dependence and Initial
Conditions in the Transition Process: the
Cases of Hungary and Romania. East-West
Journal of Economics and Business, 5 (1), pp.
67-87.
Magnin, E., Nenovsky, N., 2022. Diversity of
Capitalism in Central and Eastern Europe –
Dependent Economies and Monetary regimes.
197
Articles
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
Macmillan,
of European Economic History, 23(2), pp.71114.
Magnin E. and Nenovsky N., 2021. Dependent
Monetary Regimes in the Balkans: Enlarging
the “Variety of Capitalism” Hypothesis.
International Journal of Public Administration,
44(14), pp. 1216-1230.
Nenovsky, N. and Torre, D., 2018. Manoilescu’s
Approach of the “Losses of Trade”: A
Ricardian
Interpretation.
Economic
Alternatives, (1), pp. 49-54.
Basingstoke:
forthcoming.
Palgrave
Pivot
Manoilescu, M., 1938 [1934]. Le siècle du
corporatisme: Doctrine du corporatisme
intégral et pur. Paris: Félix Alcan.
Manoilescu, M.,1929. Théorie du protectionnisme et de l’échange international. Paris: Marcel Girard.
Mateev, E., 1969. Introduction, in E. Mateev et
al., The International Socialist Division of Labor
and the Economic Development of the People’s
Republic of Bulgaria, Sofia: ed. Naukla i
Izkustvo, pp. 5-24 (in Bulgarian).
Marinova, T., 2020. Bulgaria and the Great
War (1912–1919). Some Issues under
Discussion among the Bulgarian Economists
of that Time. Revue d’histoire de la pensée
économique, 10 (2), pp. 287-315.
Marinova, T. and Nenovsky, N., 2019. Towards
Understanding Balkan Economic Thought:
Preliminary Reflections. History of Economic
Thought and Policy, (1), pp. 29-50.
May, C. and Nölke, A., 2018. Dangers of
Residual Dependency in State-permeated
Capitalism: The Case of Brazil during Labor
Party Rule. Revue de la régulation [On line],
(24), 2nd semester/Autumn.
McKinnon, R., 1982 [1979]. Monnaie et finance
dans l’échange international. Paris: Bonnel.
Nenovsky, N. and Torre, D., 2015. Productivity
Based
Protectionism:
A
Marxian
Reconstruction of Mihail Manoilescu’s Theory.
Journal of Economic Issues, 49 (3), pp. 772786.
Nenovsky, N. and Penchev, P., 2013. A
historical look at protectionism in Bulgaria and
Romania. The protectionist theories of Mihail
Manoilescu (1891-1950) and Konstantin
Bobchev (1894-1976). Economic Studies,
22(2), pp. 3-44 (in Bulgarian).
Nenovsky, N., 2012. Theoretical Debates in
Bulgaria
during
the
Great
Depression. Confronting Sombart, Marx and
Keynes. Oeconomia, 2(1), pp. 67-101.
Nenovsky, N., Tochov, K. and Turcu, C., 2013.
Monetary Regime and EU Accession:
Comparing Bulgaria and Romania. Communist
and Post-Communist Studies, 46 (1), pp.13-23.
Nenovsky, N., Pavanelli, G. and Dimitrova, K.,
2007. Exchange Rate Control in Italy and
Bulgaria in the Interwar Period. History and
Perspectives, in: The Experience of Exchange
Rate Regimes in South-Eastern Europe in
a historical and comparative perspective,
Oesterreichische Nationalbank, Vienna, pp.
80-117.
Morys, M., 2014. World War I and the
Emergence of Central Banks in South-eastern
Europe. White Rose Research Papers,
University of York.
Nenovsky, N. and Dimitrova, K., 2007.
Exchange Rate Control in Bulgaria in Interwar
Period: History and Theoretical Reflections,
Bulgarian National Bank. Discussions Papers
No. 67.
Nenovsky, N., and Vaslin, J.M., 2020.
Shadowing the Latin Monetary Union:
Monetary Regimes and Interest Rates at the
Balkans Periphery (1867 - 1912). The Journal
Nenovsky, N. and Rizopoulos, Y. (2004). Peuton mesurer le changement institutionnel du
régime monétaire. Revue d’économie
financière, (75), pp. 17-36.
198
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022
Articles
Nenovsky, N. and Rizopoulos, Y., 2003.
Extreme Monetary Regime Change. Evidence
from the Currency Board Introduction in
Bulgaria. Journal of Economic Issues, 37(4),
pp. 909–941.
Nölke, A. and Vliegenthart, A., 2009. Enlarging
the Variety of Capitalism. The Emergence of
Dependent Market Economies in East Central
Europe. World Politics, 61(4), pp. 670-702.
North, D., 1990. Institutions, Institutional
Change and Economic Performance.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Palairet, M., 1997. The Balkans Economies, c.
1800 – 1914: Evolution without Development.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Pamuk, Ş., 2000. A Monetary History of the
Ottoman Empire. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Pamuk, Ş., 2018. Uneven Centuries: Economic
Development of Turkey since 1820. Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Pecorari, P., 2006. La Banca Nazionale di
Romania et il problema degli utili netti nel
1913, in: P. Pecorari, La lira debole. L’Italia,
l’Unione Monetaria Latina et il “bimetallismo
zoppo”, Padua: CEDAM, pp. 201-226.
Pecorari, P., 2006a. H.J. Frère-Orban e la
Banca Nazionale del Belgio nel 1867-69, in: P.
Pecorari, La lira debole. L’Italia, l’Unione
Monetaria Latina et il “bimetallismo zoppo”,
Padua: CEDAM, pp. 81-114.
Penchev, P., 2019. Debates over Dirigisme
during the 1930s: The Case of Bulgaria.
Journal of economic Issues, 53 (3), pp. 863878.
Prost, H., 1925. La liquidation financière de la
guerre en Bulgarie. Paris: Marcel Gard.
RIIA (Royal Institute for International Affairs),
1939. South-Eastern Europe. A Political and
Economic Survey. London: Oxford University
Press.
Roselli, A., 2014. Money and Trade Wars in
Interwar Europe. New York: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Rusinov, D., 1977. The Yugoslav Experiment
1948-1974. Berkeley: University of California
Press.
Šević, Ž. (Ed.), 2002. Banking Reforms in
South-East Europe. Cheltenham: Edward
Elgar.
Stoenescu, V., Blejan, E., Costache, B. and
Iarovici, A., 2007. Foreign Exchange Regime
in Romania between 1929 and 1939, in: P.
Mooslechner (ed.), The Experience of
Exchange Rate Regimes in South-eastern
Europe in a Historical and Comparative
Perspective, Proceedings of OeNB Workshop
SEEMHN, Vienna, pp. 243-260.
Stoimenov, M., 1984. Currency convertibility
under socialism. Problems and perspectives.
Sofia: ed. Nauka i Izkustvo (in Bulgarian).
Stoimenov, M., 1990. Problems of the
Currency Equilibrium of the Economy, in M.
Stoimenov (ed.), Currency Problems of the
Economic Development of the People’s
Republic of Bulgaria, Sofia: ed. Nauka i
Izkustvo, pp. 77-103. (in Bulgarian).
Stoimenov, M., 1990a. The participation of the
People’s Republic of Bulgaria in the currency
integration with the member countries of the
COMECON, in M. Stoimenov (ed.), Currency
Problems of the Economic Development of
the People’s Republic of Bulgaria, Sofia: ed.
Nauka i Izkustvo, pp. 104-124 (in Bulgarian).
Stojanović, B., 2007. Exchange Rate Regimes
of the Dinar 1945–1990: An Assessment of
Appropriateness and Efficiency, in P.
Mooslechner (ed.), The Experience of
Exchange Rate Regimes in South-eastern
Europe in a Historical and Comparative
Perspective, Proceedings of OeNB Workshop
SEEMHN, Vienna, pp. 198-243.
199
Articles
Tenev, M., 2014. Life and Work. (in two
volumes). Sofia: Bulgarian National Bank
Edition (in Bulgarian).
Tsarevski, N., 1983. International Monetary
Relations under Socialism. Sofia: ed. Nauka i
Izkustvo (in Bulgarian).
Tsarevski, N., 1976. Currency and Credit
Relations of the People’s Republic of Bulgaria.
Sofia: ed. Nauka i Izkustvo (in Bulgarian).
Tooze, A., 2006. The Wages of Destruction.
The Making and Breaking of Nazy Economy.
London: Allen Lane.
200
Dependent monetary regimes in the Balkans
Torbov, T., 1930. The mortgage loan in
Bulgaria. Sofia: Printing house of D.
Provadaliev & Todorov (in Bulgarian).
Willis, H.P., 1968 [1901]. A History of Latin
Monetary Union. A Study of International
Monetary Action. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Zafiroski, J., 2018. Monetary Law. Skopje:
University textbook (in Macedonian).
Economic Alternatives, Issue 2, 2022