DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS
UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS
IMMIGRATION AND INTERNATIONAL PRICES
Marios Zachariadis
Discussion Paper 2010-03
P.O. Box 20537, 1678 Nicosia, CYPRUS Tel.: ++357-2-892430, Fax: ++357-2-892432
Web site: http://www.econ.ucy.ac.cy
Immigration and International Prices∗
Marios Zachariadis†
February 2010
Abstract
This paper considers the relation between immigration and prices for a large number of cities
across the world over the period from 1990 to 2006. Aggregate immigration ratios are shown
to have a negative impact on international relative prices. The evidence is consistent with
demand-side and supply-side considerations both being relevant for the price-reducing effect of
immigration, with the latter offering a more likely explanation at annual frequencies during this
period. Our findings regarding the inverse relation of immigration and prices and the channels
via which this operates across international cities, are broadly consistent wih Lach (2007) and
Cortes (2008) who investigate the same relation within Israel and for the US respectively.
Keywords: immigration, prices, inflation, international price differences.
JEL Classification: E31, J10, J61
∗
I thank Yiannis Ioannides for first bringing this literarature to my attention, Nicos Theodoropoulos for pointing
me to the right sources for the migration data, and Nicoletta Pashourtidou for many useful discussions and insightful
comments.
†
Department of Economics, University of Cyprus, 1678 Nicosia, Cyprus. Phone #: 357-22892454, Fax#: 35722892432. E-mail:
[email protected]
Immigration and International Prices
1
1
Introduction
Immigration is an important demographic force likely to have an important role in shaping future
economic outcomes and welfare. Its effect on the labor market and domestic wages has been the
focus of a large body of work that includes a series of papers by Borjas (1994, 1995, 2003).1 By
contrast, its role in determining prices of final goods has not been considered by more than a handful
of papers. Lach (2007) utilizes Israeli data on individual product prices and immigration across
Israeli cities and finds that immigration reduces prices through a demand-side channel of increased
search and higher price elasticities for immigrants. Cortes (2008) uses prices and immigration data
across U.S. cities, to show that an increase in immigration reduces prices via a supply-side channel
by reducing wages. Finally, Frattini (2008) finds a similar negative effect of immigration on prices
in the UK.
In theory, we would expect three forces to be driving the relation between prices and immigration, two on the demand side and one on the supply side. First, there should be a positive
effect on prices after an increase in overall demand due to immigration similar to a baby boom
effect. Second, to the extent that immigrants are poorer than locals, we would expect them to have
higher search and substitutability parameters that would act to negate any positive demand-side
effects on prices. This is a “short term” effect that is likely to work when the immigration flow is
relatively large and unexpected as in Lach (2007). Third, one would expect immigrants to receive
lower wages at given productivity levels, partly because of a lower opportunity cost related also to
subjectively perceived wage comparisons relative to the typically poorer home country. Overall,
these three factors would be consistent with the presence of a negative impact of immigration on
prices depending on the relative magnitude of each of these three forces, the last two of which
have an opposing effect as compared to the first one. In addition, illegal immigration, consisting
1
Previous studies, including Borjas (2003) have typically found negative effects of immigrants on wages.
Immigration and International Prices
2
of relatively poorer individuals that are willing (due to lower opportunity cost) or have to (due to
being restricted to a smaller set of potential employer matches who face the risk of being caught)
work for less, would be expected to amplify the last two forces acting negatively upon prices.
The goal of this paper is to estimate the impact of immigration on prices for a large number
of cities across the world during the period from 1990 to 2006. Consistent with the evidence of
Lach (2007) for Israel and Cortes (2008) for the US, we show that there exists a negative impact of
immigration flows on prices of a broad number of goods and services that comprise the CPI. The
elasticity of prices with respect to immigration flows across the world is as high as 16 %. The price
impact of immigrants employed in specific occupations or sectors, appears to be lower than the
price impact of the overall number of immigrants in the local economy. This might be because the
overall price effect of immigration is small enough to begin with, so that the impact of the relatively
small number of immigrants in any one particular occupation or sector could not possibly show up
in the price of final goods and services. In addition, given that illegal immigration likely amplifies
the negative price effect of immigration and that it should be correlated with the presence of legal
immigrants (e.g. due to an existing local network for each immigrant ethnic group), then to the
extent that different measures of immigrants correlate more highly with the overall level of illegal
immigration, we should expect them to have a bigger estimated effect on prices. For example,
the overall level of illegal immigration should correlate more highly with our aggregated measure
of employed immigrants than with the number of immigrants employed in particular occupations
or sectors. Thus, we should expect the overall number of immigrants to have a higher impact on
prices than more specific immigration measures.
Moreover, the impact of the overall number of immigrants on basic food items they are more
likely to consume (such us bread, butter, rice, potatoes, bananas, tomatoes, eggs, frozen chicken,
etc) is comparable to or higher than the impact on the average good in the consumption basket.
Similarly, the impact of the overall number of immigrants on services they are more likely to produce
3
Immigration and International Prices
(such us Laundry, Dry cleaning, Domestic cleaning help, and Baby-sitting,) is comparable to or
higher than the impact on the average good in the consumption basket, depending on whether
we consider the specification in levels or in changes. From this, we infer that both demand-side
and supply-side considerations can be relevant for the adverse effect of immigration on prices we
document here.
2
Data
The price data
Microeconomic price levels are assembled by the Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU) and are
available for 304 items across 140 cities in 90 countries for the period 1990 to 2006. This includes
prices of more than one hundred distinct individual goods like “Margarine, 500g”, “Toothpaste
with fluoride, 120 g” or “aspirins, 100 tablets” typically sampled in both a supermarket and at a
“mid-priced” store, and a number of services like “man’s haircut, tips included” and “three-course
dinner for four people”.
The immigration data
We use employed migrant population Ijnt into each country n, in occupation or sector j for the
period 1990 to 2006, from the Labour Statistics Database assembled by the International Labour
Organization (ILO). We also use total employment Ejnt by occupation or sector for each country
from the same source, to construct the fraction of migrant workers in each occupation
Ijnt
Ejnt .
We
construct the total migrant employed population Int and total employment Ent for each country
by summing across all occupations. We also consider specifications that utilize data on immigrants
employed in services-related occupations and immigrants employed in the Agricultural sector.
Other data
City-specific population data are obtained for 1990 and 2000 from the Henderson revised in-
Immigration and International Prices
4
Table 1: Country availability.
Nation
Austria
Azerbaijan
Colombia
Denmark
Ecuador
Finland
France
Greece
Hungary
Indonesia
Ireland
Israel
Japan
Korea
Malaysia
Netherlands
Norway
Philippines
Poland
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
UK
US
Cities
Vienna
Baku
Bogota
Copenhagen
Quito
Helsinki
Lyon, Paris
Athens
Budapest
Jakarta
Dublin
Tel Aviv
Osaka, Tokyo
Seoul
Kuala Lumpur
Amsterdam
Oslo
Manila
Warsaw
Lisbon
Barcelona, Madrid
Stockholm
Geneva, Zurich
London, Manchester
Seventeen cities ∗
Tables
2, 3
2a , 3a
3
2a , 3a
2b , 3b
2a , 3
2, 3
2a , 3a
2a , 3a
3a
2, 3
2a , 3a
3b
2b , 3b
2, 3
3a
2a , 3
2a , 3a
2a , 3a
3b
2, 3
2a , 3a
2, 3
2, 3
2b , 3
Notes: The country-sample for Table 4 is the same as that for Tables 2 and 3 for the levels and difference specifications
respectively. The same goes for Table 5. a Country available only for agricultural sector data. b Country not available
for agricultural sector. ∗ These are: Atlanta, Boston, Chicago, Cleveland, Detroit, Honolulu, Houston, Lexington,
Los Angeles, Miami, Minneapolis, New York, Pittsburgh, San Francisco, San Juan, Seattle, Washington DC.
5
Immigration and International Prices
ternational urban database.2 Country-specific population is obtained annually for the period from
1990 to 2006 from the Word Development Indicators (WDI) database, and used to construct a
city-specific measure of population size for the period 1991 to 1999 and for the period 2001 to 2006,
based on the observed city to country population ratios of 1990 and 2000. More specifically, the
observed city to country ratio for 1990 is applied to the country population data from 1990 to 1995
and the observed city to country population ratio for 2000 is applied to the country population
data from 1996 to 2006 to obtain a city-specific measure of the population level.
We also obtained exports and imports of goods and services as a percentage of GDP from the
WDI, and used their sum as a measure of overall openness of the economy. Policies that foster
productivity growth such as deregulation and trade liberalization can lower prices and at the same
time make immigration more attractive or even feasible.3 We control for these country-level trends
by using a measure of “openness”. Finally, labor costs per hour in US dollars for each country are
also available from the EIU dataset.
We were able to assemble immigration and other data for 27 of the countries for which price
levels data exists, for 48 different cities. The country sample is shown in Table 1.
3
Estimation
The estimable regression equation takes the following form:
DEV ln pict = μc + μt + βDEV ln
Ijnt
+ γDEV ln P opct + δDEV ln Costnt
Ejnt
+ρDEV ln pict−1 + ξDEV ln Ont + uict
where DEV ln pict ≡ ln pict −
1
C
C
X
(1)
ln pict is the deviation of the log price level for product i in city
c=1
c at time t relative to the average common currency log price level across all cities for that product
and time, Ijnt is the number of immigrants into sector j in country n where city c belongs to, Ejnt is
2
3
I thank Yiannis Ioannides for providing these data.
I thank Saul Lach for pointing this out.
6
Immigration and International Prices
employment for sector j in country n where city c belongs to, P opct is the population size of city c at
time t, Costnt is the country level labor costs per hour in common currency4 , Ont captures the degree
of openness of the economy, and uict is an idiosyncratic random error. All explanatory variables are
demeaned relative to the mean across all locations for each time period, similarly to the dependent
I
I
≡ ln Ejnt
− N1
variable. That is, DEV ln Ejnt
jnt
jnt
DEV ln Costnt ≡ ln Costnt −
1
N
N
X
n=1
N
X
n=1
I
ln Ejnt
,5 DEV ln P opct ≡ ln P opct − C1
jnt
ln Costnt , and DEV ln Ont ≡ ln Ont −
1
N
N
X
C
X
ln P opct ,
c=1
ln Ont , where C is
n=1
the total number of cities and N is the total number of countries.
To control for a number of possible omitted variables, we also opt to include dummies for cities
and time, μc and μt , specific to city c or time t, respectively. The fixed effects model is desireable
here as it allows for and is therefore robust to arbitrary correlation between the effect μc or μt with
the observed explanatory variables
Ijnt
Ejnt ,
P opct , Costnt , and Ont . Finally, it should be noted that
since we have demeaned the data relative to the mean price of each good across locations, it is no
longer necessary to also include a product dummy.6 It should also be noted that the estimates we
obtain by demeaning the data as above are very close to those obtained when using instead price
levels data along with product-specific effects.7
We also estimate a regression equation in log differences between periods t and t − s as follows:
∆(DEV ln pict ) = λc + λt + η∆(DEV ln Ijnt ) + θ∆(DEV ln P opct ) + κ∆(DEV ln Costnt )
+φDEV ln pict−s + ψ∆(DEV ln Ont ) + ω∆(DEV ln Ynt ) + vict
(2)
where ∆(DEV ln Pct ) = DEV ln Pct −DEV ln Pct−s , ∆(DEV ln Ijnt ) = DEV ln Ijnt −DEV ln Ijnt−s ,
∆(DEV ln P opct ) = DEV ln P opct − DEV ln P opct−s , ∆(DEV ln Costnt ) = DEV ln Costnt −
4
This measure of labor costs is closely related to the level of income in each country, so we do not include both
income per capita and labor costs as explanatory variables.
5
We initially consider aggregate rather than sectoral immigration, Int , and employment, Ent , for each country.
6
Doing so leaves the coefficient estimates of the remaining explanatory variables largely unchanged and does not
increase the explanatory power of the estimated model leaving the adjusted R2 unchanged.
7
For instance, the estimated price impact of immigration when the data are not demeaned while including productspecific effects, compared to what is reported in columns (2), (4), (6), (8), (10) and (12) of Table 2, equal strogly
significant estimated values of -0.169, -0.132, -0.094, -0.081, -0.030, and -0.027 respectively.
Immigration and International Prices
7
DEV ln Costnt−s , ∆(DEV ln Ont ) = DEV ln Ont −DEV ln Ont−s , ∆(DEV ln Ynt ) = DEV ln Ynt −
DEV ln Ynt−s , Ynt is real GDP and s is the first available lag for each variable. That is, we consider
the change over time of the deviation of the price of each good relative to the mean across cities,
explained by changes over time for immigration, population size, labor costs, openness, and real
GDP relative to their respective means across locations. GDP growth is added here in order to
control for the well documented effect of the business cycle on inflation. The specification in log
changes considered here serves as a robustness check for the relation between local prices and the
number of immigrants, and as a check that our coefficient estimates are not the mere outcome of a
spurious regression in the presence of a non-stationary process for international price deviations.8
4
Empirical Results
Price levels
In Table 2, we present estimates based on the specification in levels described in equation (1).
That is, price deviations for each good relative to its mean across locations are being explained
by the respective deviations of immigration, population size, cost, and openness relative to the
average across all locations for the period from 1990 to 2006. The first lag of the price deviation
is included in all specifications along with city and time effects. Moreover, in order to alleviate
potential endogeneity problems, we consider the first available lag of immigration instead of its
contemporaneous value in the specifications shown in columns (3), (4), (7), (8), (11), and (12).
In the first four columns of Table 2, we consider the overall number of immigrants employed
in the local economy. The price elasticity with respect to overall immigration is about minus 12.4
% in column one. Introducing a measure of the degree of openness in column (2), the estimated
impact of immigration jumps to minus 16.3 %. Using lagged immigration reduces the estimates
in absolute terms to minus 9.9 % in column (3) without the measure of openness included, and to
8
We should not, however, that using the same set of prices, Adrade and Zachariadis (2009) show that international
relative prices are clearly stationary.
8
Immigration and International Prices
Table 2: Immigration and International price levels.
(1)
Immigration
-0.124***
(0.012)
(2)
(3)
Overall immigration
-0.163*** -0.099***
(0.013)
(0.008)
Cost
0.409***
(0.018)
0.619***
(0.029)
0.348***
(0.017)
0.560***
(0.026)
0.399***
(0.018)
0.511***
(0.026)
0.329***
(0.017)
0.439***
(0.025)
0.221***
(0.014)
0.222***
(0.014)
0.196***
(0.014)
0.193***
(0.015)
Pop size
-0.207***
(0.045)
-0.066
(0.048)
-0.255***
(0.046)
-0.107**
(0.048)
-0.137***
(0.044)
-0.040
(0.048)
-0.210***
(0.045)
-0.114**
(0.049)
0.253***
(0.032)
0.254***
(0.032)
0.199***
(0.032)
0.196***
(0.032)
Price lag
0.875***
(0.003)
0.876***
(0.003)
0.884***
(0.003)
0.885***
(0.003)
0.876***
(0.003)
0.876***
(0.003)
0.884***
(0.003)
0.885***
(0.003)
0.896***
(0.003)
0.896***
(0.003)
0.895***
(0.003)
0.895***
(0.003)
Openness
Observations
Cities (Nations)
adjusted R2
0.445***
(0.048)
47958
30 (10)
0.824
47958
30 (10)
0.825
(4)
(5)
-0.127***
(0.009)
(6)
(7)
(8)
Immigrants in Services
-0.083*** -0.089*** -0.074*** -0.078***
(0.010)
(0.010)
(0.008)
(0.008)
(10)
(11)
(12)
Immigrants in Agriculture
-0.032*** -0.032*** -0.029*** -0.029***
(0.004)
(0.005)
(0.004)
(0.004)
0.487***
(0.046)
52818
30 (10)
0.821
52818
30 (10)
0.821
0.248***
(0.044)
47958
30 (10)
0.824
47958
30 (10)
0.824
(9)
0.252***
(0.044)
52818
30 (10)
0.820
52818
30 (10)
0.821
Notes: *** p-value < 0.01, ** < 0.05, * < 0.10. In Columns (3) and (4), (7) and (8), and (11) and (12), we use the first
available lag of the immigration variable.
0.006
(0.031)
30308
16 (14)
0.877
30308
16 (14)
0.877
-0.013
(0.030)
30539
16 (14)
0.874
30539
16 (14)
0.874
Immigration and International Prices
9
minus 12.7 % in column (4).
In columns (5) to (8) of Table 2, we consider immigrants employed in the service sector. The
price elasticity with respect to immigrants employed in Services is lower than the elasticity relative
to overall immigration. This is estimated at minus 8.3 % as shown in column (5). Introducing
a measure of openness, the estimate in column (6) is equal to minus 8.9 %. Considering lags of
immigration rather than its contemporaneous values gives estimates equal to minus 7.4 % in column
(7), and minus 7.8 % in column (8) once we re-introduce a measure of openness.
Finally, in columns (9) to (12) of Table 2, we report the estimated elasticities based on immigrants employed in the agricultural sector. The estimates for the price elasticity with respect to
immigration are now at their lowest. These are equal to minus 3.2 % in columns (9) and (10), and
to minus 2.9 % in columns (11) and (12) using lagged values of immigration, remaining the same
irrespective of whether we include openness or not.
The estimated coefficients for the remaining explanatory variables in columns (1) to (12) are
as follows: The cost of production has a large positive statistically significant impact on prices
throughout as expected. The first lag of the price level has a positive significant impact on next
period’s price level deviation as expected, estimated to be just below 90 %. Population size has a
negative effect on prices in columns (1) to (8) as would be expected if it was capturing scale effects or
if it was inversely related to export markups. However, the sign of this effect is reversed in columns
(9) to (12). Moreover, the negative estimated impact of population size becomes statistically
insignificant in columns (2) and (6) once a measure of openness is included. As smaller economies
tend to be more open, the measure of openness should be expected to be highly and inversely
correlated with the measure of population size, which is consistent with the impact of the latter
becoming smaller or even insignificant when openness is allowed for in the regressions. The degree
of openness is estimated to have a significant positive impact on prices in columns (2), (4), (6),
and (8), that becomes statistically indistinguishable from zero in columns (10) and (12). This
10
Immigration and International Prices
Table 3: Immigration and International price changes.
(1)
Immigration
(2)
(3)
Overall immigration
-0.035*** -0.038*** -0.046***
(0.013)
(0.013)
(0.013)
(4)
(5)
(6)
Immigrants in Services
0.008
0.009
0.009
(0.007)
(0.007)
(0.007)
(7)
(8)
(9)
Immigrants in Agriculture
-0.014*** -0.015*** -0.012***
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
Cost
0.661***
(0.018)
0.617***
(0.021)
0.598***
(0.021)
0.628***
(0.017)
0.580***
(0.021)
0.562***
(0.021)
0.464***
(0.014)
0.458***
(0.014)
0.429***
(0.014)
Pop size
0.391***
(0.026)
0.351***
(0.027)
0.322***
(0.028)
0.412***
(0.026)
0.374***
(0.027)
0.355***
(0.027)
0.073***
(0.017)
0.072***
(0.017)
0.065***
(0.017)
Price lag
-0.107***
(0.002)
-0.107***
(0.002)
-0.107***
(0.002)
-0.107***
(0.002)
-0.107***
(0.002)
-0.107***
(0.002)
-0.125***
(0.003)
-0.125***
(0.003)
-0.125***
(0.003)
-0.151***
(0.032)
-0.151***
(0.032)
-0.147***
(0.032)
-0.146***
(0.032)
-0.014
(0.017)
-0.005
(0.017)
Openness
GDP growth
Observations
Cities (Nations)
adjusted R2
0.002***
(0.001)
74123
36 (15)
0.155
74123
36 (15)
0.156
74123
36 (15)
0.156
0.002**
(0.001)
74123
36 (15)
0.155
74123
36 (15)
0.156
74123
36 (15)
0.156
0.003***
(0.000)
57443
39 (21)
0.177
57443
39 (21)
0.177
Notes: *** p-value < 0.01, ** < 0.05, * < 0.10.
surprising positive impact might be another outcome of the inter-relation and resulting collinearity
of openness with size. Moreover, since fixed city and time dummies are included, these might be
absorbing some of the effects associated with an expected negative effect of trade liberalization on
prices to the extent that this is specific to a certain location or time period.
Inflation rates
In Table 3, we present estimates based on the specification in changes described in equation
(2). That is, for the period from 1990 to 2006, we explain changes in price deviations for each good
relative to its mean across locations by the respective deviations of immigration, population size,
cost, and openness relative to the average across all locations. A lag of the price deviation is included
in all specifications along with city-specific and time-specific effects. We also consider deviations of
each country’s GDP growth rate relative to the average across locations as an additional explanatory
57443
39 (21)
0.178
Immigration and International Prices
11
variable meant to control for the positive relation between prices and the business cycle at an annual
frequency. That is, countries at a higher point on their business cycle relative to others would be
expected to experience more rapid changes in prices.
In the first three columns of Table 3, we report results obtained using changes in the overall
number of immigrants employed in the local economy. The estimated coefficient for the impact
of immigration on relative inflation rates is minus 3.5 % in column (1). Introducing changes in
openness in column (2), the impact of immigration is now estimated at minus 3.8 %. Finally,
adding GDP growth, we obtain an impact of immigration that is now equal to minus 4.6 % in
column (3).
In columns (4) to (6) of Table 3, we report estimates when utilizing immigrants employed in
services-related occupations. The estimated impact of immigrants employed in Services is found to
be statistically indistinguishable from zero in all cases. Finally, we consider immigrants employed
in the Agricultural sector and report results in columns (7) to (9) of Table 3. In this case, the
estimated impact of immigration on price changes is equal to minus 1.4 % in columns (7), minus
1.5 % in columns (8), and minus 1.2 % in column (9), always smaller in absolute terms than the
impact of overall immigration shown in columns (1) to (3).
Turning now to the remaining explanatory variables, changes in the cost of production are
shown to be positively related to price changes. Interestingly, consistent with economic intuition,
while population levels typically have an inverse impact on price levels related to economies of
scale in distribution or an inverse relation of market size with markups, changes in population are
found to have a positive impact on prices as a proxy of higher demand resulting from an increase
in population in any given city. On the other hand, the lagged price level has a negative impact on
price changes consistent with initially low-price locations experiencing greater increases in prices.
Moreover, openness now has the expected negative effect on price changes which, however, turns
insignificant in columns (8) and (9). This inverse relation of price changes with the rate at which
12
Immigration and International Prices
Table 4: Immigration and International prices of “consumed” goods.
(1)
Immigration
-0.132***
(0.028)
levels
-0.169*** -0.091***
(0.030)
(0.019)
-0.114***
(0.020)
-0.047*
(0.027)
(6)
changes
-0.048*
(0.027)
Cost
0.392***
(0.034)
0.586***
(0.053)
0.332***
(0.033)
0.505***
(0.050)
0.658***
(0.037)
0.647***
(0.043)
0.655***
(0.045)
Pop size
-0.183**
(0.085)
-0.053
(0.089)
-0.208**
(0.085)
-0.085
(0.090)
0.364***
(0.054)
0.353***
(0.057)
0.366***
(0.059)
Price lag
0.806***
(0.006)
0.806***
(0.006)
0.816***
(0.006)
0.817***
(0.006)
-0.179***
(0.005)
-0.179***
(0.005)
-0.180***
(0.005)
-0.040
(0.065)
-0.040
(0.065)
Openness
(2)
(3)
0.412***
(0.095)
(4)
(5)
0.401***
(0.093)
GDP growth
Observations
Cities (nations)
R2 a
(7)
-0.044*
(0.027)
-0.001
(0.001)
14644
30 (10)
0.755
14644
30 (10)
0.756
16137
30 (10)
0.754
16137
30 (10)
0.755
22558
36 (15)
0.175
22558
36 (15)
0.175
22558
36 (15)
0.175
Notes: *** p-value < 0.01, ** < 0.05, * < 0.10. In Columns (4) and (5) we use the first available lag of immigration.
trade liberalization is implemented, is consistent with economic intuition regarding the increase in
product availability and resulting higher competition across differentiated products that occurs as
trade becomes more liberalized. Finally, real GDP growth has a small positive impact on prices as
expected from the relation between prices and the business cycle at an annual frequency. Overall,
the set of control variables considered here appear to capture well a number of economic factors
that are likely to be influencing prices, so that any remaining impact of immigration on inflation
rates is less likely to be due to omitted variables.
The Demand channel
In Table 4, we consider the impact of the overall number of immigrants employed in the economy,
on the prices of common food items for which lower income groups including immigrants are
more likely to constitute an important part of demand as compared to other products not deemed
13
Immigration and International Prices
as necessities. These necessities are food items such us bread, butter, rice, potatoes, bananas,
tomatoes, eggs, pork chops, and fresh or frozen chicken.
A complete list of the forty-five goods
considered here is found in the appendix Table A1. In the first four columns of Table 4, we estimate
regression equation (1) in levels for the overall number of immigrants as in columns (1) to (4) of
Table 2, restricting the set of goods as described above. For columns (5) to (7) of Table 4, we
estimate regression equation (2) in log changes for the overall number of immigrants as in columns
(1) to (3) of Table 3, again restricting the set of goods as above.
Looking in the first column of Tables 2 and 4 respectively, the impact of immigration on food
items shown in the latter table equals minus 0.132 as compared to the impact on the average good
in the consumption basket which is shown to equal minus 0.124 in the former table. Comparing
the estimates in column (2) of Tables 4 and 2 that include the full set of our explanatory variables,
the estimated impact of immigration on food items is minus 0.169 in Table 4 as compared to minus
0.163 for the impact on the average good in the consumption basket reported in Table 2. For the
specification with lagged immigration including again the full set of explanatory variables reported
in column (4) of each Table, the price impact of lagged immigration on food items is estimated
at minus 0.114 in Table 4 as compared to minus 0.127 for the impact on the average good in the
consumption basket as shown in Table 2. Overall, the impact of immigration on prices of items
likely to be consumed by immigrants is comparable to its impact on the price of the average good
in the consumption basket.
Turning to the comparison of the estimates obtained from the specification in changes for the
restricted versus the full sample of goods and services, these appear to be comparable and in
most cases higher for the impact of immigration on the restricted sample of goods. For example,
comparing the estimates in column (1) of Table 3 with those in column (5) of Table 4 the impact
on the inflation rate for food items is minus 0.047 as compared to an estimate of minus 0.035 shown
in the former table. Comparing the estimate in column (6) of Table 4 with that in column (2) of
14
Immigration and International Prices
Table 5: Immigration and International prices of “produced” services.
(1)
(4)
(5)
levels
-0.132***
-0.049
(0.050)
(0.031)
-0.084**
(0.035)
0.404***
(0.080)
0.694***
(0.120)
0.363***
(0.079)
Pop size
0.070
(0.189)
0.271
(0.190)
Price lag
0.887***
(0.013)
0.890***
(0.013)
Immigration
Cost
-0.080*
(0.044)
Openness
(2)
(3)
-0.145**
(0.066)
(6)
changes
-0.151**
(0.066)
-0.142**
(0.065)
0.628***
(0.115)
0.761***
(0.081)
0.689***
(0.095)
0.708***
(0.102)
0.066
(0.192)
0.255
(0.193)
0.165
(0.141)
0.095
(0.152)
0.126
(0.165)
0.896***
(0.012)
0.898***
(0.012)
-0.089***
(0.010)
-0.088***
(0.010)
-0.088***
(0.010)
-0.248*
(0.151)
-0.249*
(0.151)
0.606***
(0.226)
0.603***
(0.222)
GDP growth
Observations
Cities (nations)
adjusted R2
(7)
-0.002
(0.003)
1856
30 (10)
0.893
1856
30 (10)
0.894
2040
30 (10)
0.890
2040
30 (10)
0.891
2863
36 (15)
0.324
2863
36 (15)
0.325
2863
36 (15)
0.325
Notes: *** p-value < 0.01, ** < 0.05, * < 0.10. In Columns (4) and (5), we use the first available lag of immigration.
Table 3 for the specification that accounts for all explanatory variables other than GDP growth,
the impact on the inflation rate for food items is 0.048 compared to 0.038 for the full sample of
goods and services. Finally, comparing the estimates in the last column of Table 4 with those in
column (3) of Table 3 including the full set of our explanatory variables, the estimated impact of
immigration on food items is minus 0.044 in Table 4 which is comparable to the estimated value of
minus 0.046 for the impact on the average good in the consumption basket reported in column (3)
of Table 3.
The Supply channel
In Table 5, we consider the impact of the overall number of immigrants on services they are more
likely to produce such us Laundry, Dry cleaning, Domestic cleaning help, and Baby-sitting. These
categories resemble those in Cortes (2008) as typical services likely to be offered by immigrants.
Immigration and International Prices
15
Overall, we consider eleven service items for these four types of services shown in Table A2. In the
first four columns of Table 5, we estimate regression equation (1) in levels for the overall number
of immigrants9 as in columns (1) to (4) of Table 2, but restricting the set of items to the list of
services described above. For columns (5) to (7) of Table 5, we estimate regression equation (2)
in changes for the overall number of immigrants as in columns (1) to (4) of Table 3, but again
restricting the set to the services described above.
Comparing the estimates in column (2) of Tables 5 and 2 for the specifications that include all
our explanatory variables, the estimated impact of immigration on service items is minus 0.132 in
Table 5 as compared to minus 0.163 for the impact on the average good in the consumption basket
reported in Table 2. For the specification with lagged immigration including again the full set of
explanatory variables, the price impact of lagged immigration on food items is estimated at minus
0.084 in column (4) of Table 5 as compared to minus 0.127 for the impact on the average good as
shown in column (4) of Table 2.
Turning to the estimates for the specification in changes based on regression equation (2), the
estimated impact of immigration on services relative inflation rates reported in column (6) of Table
5 is 0.151 compared to 0.038 for the full sample of goods reported in column (2) of Table 3. These
estimates are based on a specification that accounts for all explanatory variables other than GDP
growth. The estimate for the impact of immigration on service items in the last column of Table
5 that accounts for the full set of our explanatory variables is minus 0.142, as compared to the
estimated value of minus 0.046 for the impact on the average good in the consumption basket
reported in column (3) of Table 3. We note that while for the specification in levels described by
9
It would be natural here to consider the impact of immigrants employed in services on the price of services. This
impact is actually estimated to be negative in all specifications corresponding to those reported in Table 5, but the
effect is significant for only one of the specifications corresponding to that in column (4) of Table 5, using lagged
immigration along with the full set of explanatory variables, where it equals -0.053. The lag of a strong significant
negative impact for immigration in services as compared to the impact of overall immigration might be related to
the fact pointed out in the introduction regarding the relation of each of these measures with illegal immigration in
conjunction with the likely strong negative impact of the latter on wages and prices.
Immigration and International Prices
16
regression equation (1), estimates of the impact of employed immigrants on prices of services they
are more likely to produce is comparable but lower than the impact on prices for the full sample
of goods, for the specification in log changes described by regression equation (2), the estimated
impact of immigration on price changes for services is estimated to be more than three times as
high as the impact on the average good in the consumption basket.
5
Conclusion
We have undertaken an investigation of the relation between immigration and prices for a number of
cities across the world. More specifically, we have considered the relation between international price
differences and the ratio of the number of immigrants present in a country relative to the overall
number of employees in that country. We have also considered the relation between the growth
rate of the number of immigrants and the rate of price changes across countries. In both cases,
we have considered the aggregated number of immigrants, the number of immigrants employed in
services, and the number of immigrants in the agricultural sector.
Our analysis suggests that aggregate immigration has a larger impact on prices for both the
levels and log changes specifications alike. In the light of this result, we have considered the impact
of aggregate immigration on the prices of basic food items immigrants are more likely to consume
and on the prices of basic services they are more likely to produce. The impact on these basic
food items is comparable to and often somewhat higher than that on the average good for both the
specification in levels and log changes.
The impact on the relative inflation for services immigrants are likely to produce is considerably
higher relative to that for the average good or service in the sample providing some evidence for
a supply-side explanation of the impact of immigration on prices, consistent with Cortes (2008).
Our finding regarding this inverse effect of the rate of immigration growth on relative inflation is
consistent with Bentolila, Dolado, and Jimeno (2008) who document an inverse relation between
Immigration and International Prices
17
immigration and inflation resulting in a shift of the Phillips curve for the Spanish economy, with
lower unemployment rates becoming consistent with lower inflation as a result of immigration flows.
18
Immigration and International Prices
References
Adrade, Philippe and Marios Zachariadis (2009) “Trends in international prices” unpublished
manuscript, Banque of France and University of Cyprus Department of Economics.
Bentolila Samuel, Juan J. Dolado, and Juan F. Jimeno (2008) “Does immigration affect the
Phillips curve? Some evidence for Spain” European Economic Review 52, 1398—1423.
Borjas, George. 1994. “The Economics of Immigration.” Journal of Economic Literature 32, 4:
1667-1717.
Borjas, George. 1995. “The Economic Benefits from Immigration.” Journal of Economics Perspectives 9, 2: 3-22.
Borjas, George. 2003. “The Labor Demand Curve is Downward Sloping: Reexamining the Impact
of Immigration on the Labor Market.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 4: 1335-1374.
Cortes, Patricia (2008) “The Effect of Low-Skilled Immigration on U.S. Prices: Evidence from
CPI Data,” Journal of Political Economy, 116(3), 381-422.
Frattini, Tommaso (2008) “Immigration and Prices in the UK,” unpublished manuscript, University College London.
Lach, Saul (2007) “Immigration and Prices,” Journal of Political Economy, 115(4), 548-587.
19
Immigration and International Prices
Table A1: Description of basic food items used in Table 4
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
White Bread (1 kg)
Butter (500 g)
Margarine (500 g)
White rice (1 kg)
Spaghetti (1 kg)
Flour, white (1 kg)
Sugar, white (1 kg)
Cheese, imported (500 g)
Cornflakes (375 g)
Yoghurt, natural (150 g)
Milk, pasteurised (1 l)
Olive oil (1 l)
Peanut or corn oil (1 l)
Potatoes (2 kg)
Onions (1 kg)
Mushrooms (1 kg)
Tomatoes (1 kg)
Carrots (1 kg)
Oranges (1 kg)
Apples (1 kg)
Lemons (1 kg)
Bananas (1 kg)
Lettuce (one)
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
Eggs (12)
Peas, canned (250 g)
Tomatoes, canned (250 g)
Peaches, canned (500 g)
Sliced pineapples, canned (500 g)
Beef: steak, entrecote (1 kg)
Beef: stewing, shoulder (1 kg)
Beef: roast (1 kg)
Beef: ground or minced (1 kg)
Veal: chops (1 kg)
Veal: fillet (1 kg)
Veal: roast (1 kg)
Lamb: leg (1 kg)
Lamb: chops (1 kg)
Lamb: Stewing (1 kg)
Pork: chops (1 kg)
Pork: loin (1 kg)
Ham: whole (1 kg)
Bacon (1 kg)
Chicken: frozen (1 kg)
Chicken: fresh (1 kg)
Frozen fish fingers (1 kg)
Table A2: Description of basic services used in Table 5
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
Laundry, one shirt in standard high-street outlet,
Laundry (one shirt) (mid-priced outlet)
Dry cleaning, man’s suit (standard high-street outlet)
Dry cleaning, man’s suit (mid-priced outlet)
Dry cleaning, woman’s dress (standard high-street outlet)
Dry cleaning, woman’s dress (mid-priced outlet)
Dry cleaning, trousers (standard high-street outlet)
Dry cleaning, trousers (mid-priced outlet)
Hourly rate for domestic cleaning help
Maid’s monthly wages (full time)
Babysitter’s rate per hour