CRE A
Discussion
Paper
2008-18
Center for Research in Economic Analysis
University of Luxembourg
Bank Secrecy, Illicit Money and
Offshore Financial Centers
available online : http://fdef.uni.lu/index.php/fdef_FR/economie/crea/discussion_papers/2008
Pierre M. Picard, CREA-University of Luxembourg
Patrice Pieretti, CREA-University of Luxembourg
:
December 1, 2008
Discussion Paper available online : http://fdef.uni.lu/index.php/fdef_FR/economie/crea
For editorial correspondence, please contact :
[email protected]
University of Luxembourg
Faculty of Law, Economics and Finance
162A, avenue de la Faïencerie
L-1511 Luxembourg
The opinions and results mentioned in this paper do not reflect the position of the Institution
Bank Secrecy, Illicit Money and
O¤shore Financial Centers
Pierre M. Picard and Patrice Pieretti1
December 1, 2008
1 Faculty
of Law, Economics and Finance, University of Luxembourg, 162a, avenue de la
Faïencerie, L-1511 Luxembourg. Tel.:+352 4666446633; fax: +352 4666446632. E-mail address:
[email protected]
Abstract
International and national institutions regularly put pressure on o¤shore …nancial centers
and their clients to enforce compliance with anti-money laundering regulations and that
in spite of the existence of bank secrecy. This paper discusses the winners and losers of
such policies. Surprisingly, aggregate pro…ts and tax revenues can increase under those
policies. In addition, we show that o¤shore banks can be encouraged to comply with
rigorous monitoring of the investor’s identity and the origin of his/her funds when the
pressure creates su¢ciently high risk of reputational harm to this investor. Nevertheless,
the e¢cient pressure policy is dichotomous in the sense that a social planner chooses zero
pressure or the pressure that just entices o¤shore banks to comply. By contrast, the implementation of those pressure policies on an onshore institution may be ine¢cient. Finally,
we show that deeper …nancial integration fosters compliance by the o¤shore center while
it also gives better incentives for delegated organizations to e¤ectively induce compliance.
Keywords: money laundering, o¤shore banking, compliance
JEL classi…cation: F21, K42
1
Introduction
O¤shore …nancial centers are often viewed as parasites that thrive by attracting tax
cheaters and money-launderers.12 In recent years, there have been concerted international
initiatives to discipline them with the result that the legal and regulatory environment
is beginning to change.3 However, sovereignty and democratic independence limit the
ability of international bodies to intervene directly in the private economy of o¤shore
…nancial centers. As noticed by Abbott and Snidal (2000), “diminution of sovereignty
makes states reluctant to accept hard legalization, especially when it includes signi…cant
levels of delegation”. This di¢culty is obviously emphasized by the fact that bank secrecy
represents an important asset of o¤shore …nancial centers.
Since the early 1990s, there have been multilateral e¤orts to address money laundering.
For example, the F.A.T.F. issued a list of recommendations “that set out the basic framework for anti-money laundering e¤orts4 and are intended to be of universal application”.
These guidelines are not as tightly constraining as hard legal commitments and are more
di¢cult to enforce. Pressure on Non-Cooperative Countries and Territories (N.C.C.T.)
may however be exercised through blacklisting and indicating that repeat o¤enders may
face counter-measures including a ban from dealing with the …nancial institutions of the
1
Like Rose and Spiegel (2006), we de…ne o¤shore …nancial centers as jurisdictions that oversee a
disproportionate level of …nancial activity by non-residents.
2
The IMF (2004) de…nes money-laundering as “a process in which assets obtained or generated by
criminal activity are moved or concealed to obscure their link with the crime”.
3
Driven by a growing political determination to …ght against money laundering, international organizations like the Financial Action Task Force (FATF) housed at the OECD, the Basel Committee
on Banking Supervision, the Commission of the European Communities, the Financial Stability Forum
(FSF) and the IMF, have focused on decreasing the opacity of operations in o¤shore …nancial centers.
4
These recommendations are especially concerned with the criminalisation of money laundering, the
requirement of banks to know their clients, and the reporting of suspicious transactions to their governments.
The IMF has now become actively involved in anti money laundering issues, in particular with the
launch in 1999 of the Financial Sector Assessment Programs. The Basel Committee (Basel 2) has extended
its traditional remit in publishing best practice standards for customer identi…cation, called the "know
your customer" rule and this principle has been implemented by European regulation.
1
O.E.C.D. countries (The Economist, 2001).
Many authors are skeptical about the e¤ectiveness of this soft law practice intended
to combat money laundering by …nancial institutions. One argument often raised is that
money laundering and bank secrecy are inextricably linked and e¢ciently …ghting against
…nancial crime can only be achieved by undermining con…dentiality laws (Antoine, 1999).
Other arguments are more speci…cally concerned with the lack of incentives to cooperate.
Focusing on national policy makers’ strategic behavior concerning the adoption of …nancial
regulations, Masciandaro (2005) notes that notwithstanding the blacklist threat, various
jurisdictions continue to be non-cooperative. According to FitzGerald (2004) compliance
with international regulations must be especially enforced on …nancial intermediaries, but
while states may face international sanctions, there is no direct means of punishing private
sector actors, as they have no status in international law.
In the following, we take the viewpoint that successfully enforcing anti-money laundering standards relies on the existence of incentives for complying with these regulations.
Mascandiaro (2005) addresses this problem by modelling national policy makers’ choice
of the optimal degree of laxity in …nancial regulation. In our paper, we rather focus on
…nancial intermediaries’ incentives to implement "know your customer" standards in order to identify and report dubious transactions. This choice is motivated by the fact that
the nature of bank secrecy does not cause automatic compliance by intermediaries even
within highly regulated institutional structures (FitzGerald, 2004).
According to Sharman (2004), public blacklisting by international organizations is an
e¤ective means of bringing about regulatory compliance by otherwise recalcitrant states.
The reason is that this type of pressure hurts tax havens’ reputations in the eyes of
governments and investors and may thus lead to capital withdrawals and other economic
damage. Zagaris (2001) notes that blacklists are not merely a way of naming and shaming
o¤shore …nancial centers, but a way to impose economic sanctions. Blum et al. (1998,
2
p.47) observe that "if a haven develops too unsavory a reputation as a home for dirty
money or a haunt of organized crime and drug tra¢ckers, then not only will legitimate
money go elsewhere as respectable companies move their businesses to avoid tarnishing
their reputations but so too will more sophisticated criminals who want to avoid any taint
by association".
The factor of loss of reputation owing to banks’ lax behavior toward anti-money laundering practices is critical for analyzing o¤shore …nancial intermediaries’ choice to comply
with controlling rules. In that context, may these costs provide enough incentives for
banks to respond appropriately? Will this occur despite the existence of bank secrecy?
To address these issues, we develop a model that endogenizes the strategic choice
of an o¤shore …nancial center between lax and scrupulous attitudes toward controlling
the origin of investments. In that context we assume that bank secrecy provided by the
o¤shore center is not only seen as a possible channel for illegal money transfers but also
as an opportunity for legal …nancial services coupled with tax advantages (Antoine,1999 ;
Desai et al. 2006). According to Blum et al. (1998, p.40), the real question “is not to issue
blanket condemnations or make e¤orts to eliminate bank secrecy and o¤shore …nancial
services, but to ensure that the legitimate uses of these facilities remain available”.
Recent papers have addressed the topic of o¤shore …nancial centers. There is one
strand of the literature, which deals with their tax haven characteristic (Rose and Spiegel,
2006 ; Slemrod and Wilson, 2006 ; Desai et al. 2006). Other papers focus exclusively on
the money-laundering aspect (Masciandaro, 2005, 2006). Our model takes into account
both features without mixing them by introducing two types of clienteles: one that has
criminal money to launder and another who seeks the most pro…table destination of licit
money.
In this paper we consider a two-country two-…nancial center model with two classes
of investors. Ordinary investors seek the best return investment opportunity but feel
3
some (preference or geographical) distance from the o¤shore …nancial center. Criminal
investors seek opaqueness and use the o¤shore banks’ secrecy policy to launder money
that is illegally obtained and that may be used for illegal purpose (e.g. terrorism). In
this paper, we conform to the standards of existing literature by endogenizing interest
rates and government taxes. Therefore, as is usual in the banking competition literature,
we assume that …nancial centers compete to attract investors and, as is usual in the tax
competition literature, we assume that governments independently set taxes on interest
payments. In addition to those actions, national or international institutions have to
decide to exert pressure on the o¤shore bank and country, for instance, by blacklisting
policies and pressure on individuals who invest o¤shore.
The …rst objective of the paper is to highlight the winners and losers of the pressure
policies. Our second objective is to establish the conditions under which the o¤shore
…nancial center is enticed to comply with scrupulous monitoring of the investor’s identity
and the origin of his/her funds. The third objective is to analyze the e¢ciency of the
decision in terms of the e¤ort exerted to blacklist the o¤shore center and to campaign
investors against o¤shore investment. Our …nal objective is to discuss the delegation of
the pressure policy to possible institutions like tax administrations.
Our main results may be summarized as follows : First, we show that o¤shore banks
and countries lose under the pressure policies. More interestingly, this conclusion also
applies for any (non-criminal) onshore investors, individually or in the aggregate. Surprisingly, the aggregate pro…t and tax revenues can increase after the implementation of
a pressure policy. This is because the pressure policy is not only likely to harm investors
but also to weaken interbank competition. Second, o¤shore banks can be enticed to comply with scrupulous monitoring of the investors’ identities and the origins of their funds
when the pressure policy gets strong enough. To be e¤ective this pressure policy should
make ordinary investors incur a reputational harm that - in monetary equivalent terms
4
- is larger than the monitoring cost of investors in banks. Third, the e¢cient pressure
policy is dichotomous in the sense that a social planner chooses only two levels of pressure: either zero pressure or the pressure that just entices o¤shore banks to comply. Since
o¤shore centers are very likely to be tax havens, anti money laundering actions exerted by
onshore institutions may also be (partially) motivated by the desire to reduce tax losses.
In that context, we show that pressure strategies decided by national or international
institutions whose objectives are biased towards tax revenue may not be e¢cient. Indeed, the resulting pressure exerted on investors may be set at a su¢ciently high level to
make them choose the onshore banks but not to large enough level to make the o¤shore
banks comply. Finally, we qualify the usual claim stating that deeper …nancial integration fosters …nancial criminality. We show in this model that deeper …nancial integration
encourages compliance by o¤shore …nancial centers whereas it also gives better incentives
for delegated organizations to use its pressure policy to e¤ectively enforce compliance. So,
deeper …nancial integration fosters the elimination of …nancial criminality.
The present paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the model. Section 3 and
4 derive the equilibrium under compliance and no compliance of o¤shore centers. Section
5 discusses the e¢cient pressure policy and the delegation to onshore institutions. Section
6 presents some extensions while Section 7 concludes.
2
Model
We consider a two-country two-…nancial center model. Let the onshore institutions be
subscripted by H (home) and the o¤shore ones by F (foreign). The timing is as follows.
First national or international institutions decide to exert pressure on the o¤shore bank
and country, for instance, by blacklisting policies and pressure on individuals who invest
o¤shore. Second, the o¤shore and onshore governments simultaneously set their tax
5
rates on deposits. Third, banks compete to attract investors by setting their interest
rates. Fourth, investors choose the bank where they deposit their cash. Finally, the
banks remunerate investors whereas investors pay their taxes on earned interests. We
now describe each side of the …nancial centers.
Each …nancial center i (i = H; F ) collects funds from investors and o¤ers a risk-free
interest rate ri . They invest those funds into risk-free assets that yield a given (world)
rate of return r and make a pro…t on the intermediation margin r
ri . We here consider
a small o¤shore …nancial center that competes with a domestic …nancial center in order
to attract investors located in the domestic jurisdiction. We thus underline the fact
that o¤shore …nancial centers often have very small populations and o¤er intermediation
services predominantly to investors residing in large foreign economies. The o¤shore
jurisdiction provides strict bank secrecy while the onshore center does not. It follows that
the o¤shore …nancial center is more vulnerable to money laundering than other market
places where …nancial transactions are more transparent. Like Rose and Spiegel (2006)
we consider that each jurisdiction contains only one bank. This allows us to focus on
international …nancial competition.5
Financial centers are also asked to scrupulously monitor investors’ identities and money
origins. Because our focus is on the e¤ect of the banks’ monitoring of investors on the
competition between …nancial centers and between governments, we simplify the monitoring technology by assuming that banks are able to discover the criminal identity and
money origin of investors at a cost c proportional to the amount of monitored deposits.
The main di¤erence between the onshore and o¤shore …nancial centers is that the onshore
…nancial center is obliged by law to comply to the monitoring of investors whereas the
o¤shore center cannot be obliged to do so. Instead, the latter should be enticed to moni5
Competition is however imperfect, since we consider an international duopoly competing in o¤ered
interest rates.
6
tor investors by onshore governments or international institutions. Therefore, the o¤shore
…nancial center has an additional decision variable s 2 fm; og, where s = m denotes a
scrupulous monitoring of the investors’ money origins and s = o a lax behavior on this
issue.
Investors lend their capital to the …nancial centers. All investors reside in the home
country H and are endowed with one unit of wealth that they deposit in the most advantageous …nancial center. The onshore economy contains S investors and the o¤shore
…nancial center is assumed to have no local investors. Investors split into an ordinary and
a criminal clientele. On the one hand we assume that there exist (1
)S (3=4 <
< 1)
criminal investors who only seek opaqueness in order to conceal the origin of money that
is illegally obtained. For simplicity we assume that those investors do not care about
interest-earning and tax-saving: their demand for opaqueness is perfectly inelastic to
the o¤ered return. Individuals having money laundering intentions are supposed to opt
exclusively for the o¤shore bank when the latter does not scrupulously monitor …nancial
transactions. If both jurisdictions do implement a scrupulous monitoring, individuals who
still seek opaqueness are supposed to look for another way of laundering money (e.g. in
underground banking like casinos, Hawalawa 6 ...). We simplify by assuming that owners
of illegal money have no such option. Finally, we assume that the social cost of each
illegal dollar invested is equal to . As a result, the social cost of the criminal activity is
equal to (1
)S when all criminal investors use the banking system. This parameter
captures the social cost of the criminality. It increases if the threat of criminality to
society rises (as it can have been perceived in the U.S. after 11/9/2001). It also increases
when substitute channels to the banking system for money laundering business become
6
Underground or ethnic banking systems are remittance systems that operate outside of (or parallel
to) traditional …nancial channels. They are becoming more and more popular today as ethnic diasporas
grow (Blum et al. 1998). The most commonly referred to informal systems are the Chinese chit or chop
system of East and Southeast Asia, the black market peso exchange system of Latin America, and the
hawala system, with its o¤shoot the hundi system in South Asia (FitzGerald, 2004) .
7
less numerous and less e¤ective. In this case, the elimination of money laundering in the
o¤shore …nancial centers brings more social bene…t. This cost is assumed to vanish when
the o¤shore …nancial centers monitor their investors.
On the other hand, the onshore country hosts S ordinary investors who invest legal
money and thus favor the …nancial center that o¤ers the highest net rate of return.
Independent of tax and return considerations, we suppose that ordinary investors incur
a cost of moving assets abroad that mainly re‡ects their home country preference. This
reluctance to invest abroad may in particular be explained by poor information about
remote areas and thus by lack of con…dence in foreign …nancial centers. We therefore
assume that ordinary investors are uniformly distributed along the unit segment according
to their preference for proximity, so that the “closer” to the border they are, the less
they will favor their home …nancial center. Consequently, the aforementioned mobility
cost of an individual located at x (x 2 [0; 1]) equals the distance x that separates him
from the border multiplied by a (constant) unit cost k. Improvements in technology that
bolster global integration by creating international links between …nancial markets and by
facilitating the access to foreign …nancial centers tend to lower transaction and information
costs. We thus will interpret the coe¢cient k as measuring the degree of international
…nancial integration. On the other hand, we consider that individuals seeking to conceal
illegal money don’t exhibit a preference for the home …nancial system.
Furthermore, according to Sharman (2004 p. 9),"it would be wrong to say that tax
havens are undi¤erentiated units o¤ering perfectly substitutable services or that customers are interested only in the bottom line." Consequently, one dollar invested in a
known place like the home country does not, other things being equal, exactly represents
the same amount invested in an o¤shore center. O¤shoring money will cause investors
to endure a premium that is likely to increase with the loss of reputation of the destination jurisdictions in which they deposit. In this vein, Sharman (2001 p.12) observes
8
that, "investors tend to avoid or leave jurisdictions with bad reputations not only out of
concern that their money will be misappropriated, but also because …rms risk harming
their own reputations, as re‡ected in their share prices. "Accordingly, to take account of
the quality of the o¤shore center’s reputation, we introduce a parameter a; which represents the disutility that the non-criminal investor incurs by o¤shoring his money to an
o¤shore …nancial center that does not scrupulously monitor the origin of his/her deposits.
This parameter encompasses various sources of utility losses that the ordinary investor
associates with a deposit in a bad …nancial center (e.g. in terms of patriotism, warm
glow, tax evasion tagging...). For the sake of convenience, we label this parameter a as
the "investor’s reputational harm" although we do not intend to model any reputation
game in this paper. Hence, the utility function of an investor located at x who deposits
in jurisdiction i (i = H; F ) is assumed to be given by
8
>
r
>
>
< H
Uis (x) =
rF
>
>
>
:
rF
tH
if i = H and s 2 fm; og
tF
k x
tF
k x
if i = F and s = m
a if i = F and s = o
In this de…nition,the …rst investor’s option is to deposit in the home country and get the
return rH and pay the tax tH per unit of deposit. The second option is to invest in the
o¤shore …nancial center, get the return rF and pay the tax tF but incur a utility loss
k x that depends on the investor’s distance from the o¤shore place. Finally, when the
o¤shore place does not monitor, it is put under pressure by international organizations.
This collective action may be achieved through campaigns in the media, new regulations,
publication of reports and statistics, categorization of tax havens and strategies of “naming
and shaming”.7 In the following we assume that investors who o¤shore their money
7
For example, the Financial Action Task Force (FATF) adopted by 1999 a ‘name, shame and punish’
strategy for countries that refused to comply with its recommendations for anti-money laundering.
9
are also stigmatized by the international pressure campaign and, in turn, incur a(n)
(individual) reputational harm a.
In this paper, the investor’s reputational harm is not an exogenous parameter. It depends on the pressure that national and/or international institutions put on the investors
and the o¤shore …nancial center. Such institutions can put pressure on the o¤shore …nancial center by blacklisting them; they can put pressure on the ordinary investors by
informing them or campaigning about the risks of investing o¤shore, by tagging and/or
pursuing o¤shore investors, etc. We assume that the cost of exerting such a pressure is
equal to C(a) = a. Finally, in accordance with standard tax competition literature, we
assume that policy makers maximize their total tax proceeds, each one taking the tax of
the other country as given.
We now derive the equilibrium deposit supplies, interest and tax rates when the o¤shore …nancial center either complies or not with the scrupulous monitoring of investors.
We then derive the incentives of the o¤shore …nancial center to monitor investors and
discuss the optimal pressure strategy.
3
Compliant o¤shore …nancial center
In this section, we derive the equilibrium of the sequential decisions of investors, banks
and governments when each …nancial center decides to monitor the origin of invested
funds and refuses to accept illicit money (s = m). In this case, deposits are supplied only
by ordinary investors who do not incur any disutility from being associated to an o¤shore
bank.
The deposit supplies are obtained as follows. If the o¤shore …nancial center monitors,
criminals are unable to use the banking system to launder money while the share of
ordinary investors lending their money in o¤shore …nancial center is determined by the
10
marginal (ordinary) investor xF who is indi¤erent between both jurisdictions. We readily
obtain that
xF =
1
(rF
k
rH
tF + tH ) and xH = 1
xF
As a result, the deposit supply functions are equal to Di = xi S (i = H; F ).
The …nancial centers i (i = H; F ) select the interest rates that maximize their pro…ts
i
by taking as given the taxes and the rival’s interest rate. That is,
max
ri
i
= (r
ri
c) Di =
(r
ri
c) xi S
where c is the monitoring cost. The unique Nash equilibrium in interest rates yields
rFm = r
c
1
(k + tH
3
tF )
and
m
rH
=r
c
1
(2k + tF
3
tH )
where the superscript m denotes the equilibrium variables in the monitoring case. Acm
cordingly, the interest rate di¤erential is rH
rFm =
1
3
[k + 2 (tF
tH )]. All taxes being
equal, the onshore …nancial center sets a lower interest rate as it can take advantage of
legal investors’ preference for their home country.
Policy-makers individually choose their tax rate ti that maximizes their total tax
proceeds Ti = ti Di (i = H; F ) taking the other country’s tax as given. The best responses
are tBR
(tj ) =
i
tj
2
+ 21 k so that taxes are strategic complements as is usual in the tax
competition literature. The tax equilibrium is uniquely determined to
4
tm
F = k > 0
3
Since tm
H
tm
F =
k
3
and
5
tm
H = k > 0
3
> 0, the onshore country always sets higher taxes. As in many
tax competition models, the o¤shore country sets a lower tax to attract a larger base of
11
taxable deposits.
At this equilibrium, the interest rates are equal to
rFm = r
c
4
k
9
m
rH
=r
and
m
The interest rate di¤erential is equal to rH
k
9
rFm =
c
5
k
9
< 0. The onshore …nancial center
o¤ers a lower interest rate to compensate for ordinary investors’ distance to it. Interest
rates are positive and investors deposit their capital if and only if
5
k
9
c<r
(1)
which we assume from now.
The equilibrium supplies are given by
DFm =
4
S
9
and
m
DH
=
5
S
9
whereas the banks’ pro…ts and tax proceeds write as
m
i
=
k
(Dim )2
Tim = 3
and
m
i
(i = H; F )
We now analyze the interesting case of a non compliant o¤shore …nancial center.
4
Lax o¤shore …nancial center
We now suppose that the o¤shore …nancial center does not monitor investors’ identity
and money origin (s = o). In this case some pressure is exerted on investors who incur
a reputational loss a. We derive the equilibrium of the sequential decision of depositors,
12
banks and governments in the following way.
When the o¤shore …nancial center is lax, criminal investors are able to launder money
in the o¤shore center. The share of legal money invested in each …nancial center is determined by the marginal (ordinary) investor xF who is indi¤erent between both jurisdictions.
We readily compute
xF =
1
(rF
k
rH
tF + tH
a)
and xH = 1
xF
The deposit supply functions are equal to
DF = ( xF + 1
)S
and
DH = xH S
Each …nancial center selects the interest rate that maximizes its own pro…t by taking
as given the rival’s rate:8
max
rF
F
= (r
rF )DF
and max
rH
H
= (r
rH
c)DH
The interest rates in this Nash equilibrium are given by
rFo = r
1
3
c
a + tF
tH +
2
k
o
and rH
=r
1
3
2c + a + tH
tF +
1+
k
Again, policy-makers determine their taxes ti by maximizing their tax proceeds Ti =
ti Di (i = H; F ) taking the other tax as a given. It follows that country F and H’s tax
8
When the o¤shore …nancial center adopts a lax behavior, it is not able to discriminate between
criminal and ordinary customers because it does not control of the investors’ identity and the origin of
their funds.
13
best responses are equal to
tBR
F (tH ) =
tH 1
+
2
2
c
2
a+
and tBR
H (tF ) =
k
tF
1
+
2
2
a
c+
1+
k
Taxes are here also strategic complement. At the Nash equilibrium of the tax game, we
get
toF =
1
3
c
a+
5
k
and toH =
1
3
a
c+
4+
k
where the superscript o denotes the equilibrium values under lax …nancial centers. This
implies the following interest rates:
rFo = r
1
9
c
a+
5
1
9
o
and rH
=r
k
1
9
Equilibrium interest rates are positive if r >
a + 8c +
4+
a + 8c +
4+
k
k , which is true for any large
enough (world) interest rate r and, which is assumed from now for the sake of simplicity.
At this equilibrium, the marginal investor who is indi¤erent between the …nancial
centers is given by
xoF =
1
9 k
[4 (2
1) k
(a
c)]
which belongs to the interval [0; 1] if and only if
4+
k<a
c<
8
4
k
(2)
When a c is set above the highest boundary of this condition, investors’ reputational loss
a is so strong that ordinary investors avoid investing in that country. By contrast, when
a
c is set below the lowest boundary, the monitoring cost is so high that the onshore
bank sets an interest rate that is unattractive for any ordinary investor. This last set of
conditions (2) determines an non empty interval and will be assumed from now for the
14
sake of simplicity. Note that both taxes are positive under conditions (2).
The equilibrium demands for deposits are then equal to
DFo =
1
[(5
9k
)k
(a
c)] S
and
o
DH
=
1
[(4 + ) k + (a
9k
c)] S
while banks’ pro…ts and tax proceeds simply write as
o
i
=
k
(Dio )2
S
and
Tio = 3
o
i
(i = H; F )
We can make the following remarks about tax and interest rate di¤erentials.
4.1
Properties of tax and interest rates
On the one hand, the interest rate di¤erential is equal to
o
rH
rFo =
2
1
2a + 7c +
9
1
k <0
So, the o¤shore bank sets higher interest rates. There are two reasons for this result.
First, the o¤shore bank must raise its interest rate to attract legal investors who feel
some moving cost (in terms of physical distance or preference). This e¤ect diminishes
however as the …nancial market becomes more integrated (lower k). Second, the o¤shore
bank must also set a higher interest rate than its competitor to attract legal investors who
su¤er some reputational harm when they are associated to a lax o¤shore bank (a > 0).
On the other hand, the tax di¤erential between the onshore and o¤shore countries can
be computed as
toH
toF =
1
2 (a
3
c) +
2
1
k
(3)
This tax di¤erential increases if investor’s reputation is more strongly harmed by institu-
15
tional pressures like blacklisting policy (larger a). The tax di¤erential also increases if the
onshore …nancial center has a smaller compliance cost (smaller c) as this change allows
the onshore center to increase its o¤ered interest rate and to attract more deposits. The
tax di¤erential increases if the number of legal money investors rises (larger ) as this
raises the demand for onshore deposits. Finally, since
> 3=4, the tax di¤erential de-
creases with …nancial integration (smaller k). Deeper …nancial integration reduces banks’
intermediation markups, which in turn limits each country’s opportunity to raise more
tax on local investments.
It is important to note that, in contrast to the monitoring case and to tax competition
literature (e.g. Kanbur and Keen, 1993), the (large) onshore country does not always set
the largest tax rate. Indeed, by (3), the onshore country sets a lower tax rate if and only
if
a<a
1=2
c
k
(4)
where a lies between the boundaries in conditions (2). The onshore country sets a lower
tax rate if the investor’s reputational harm is small enough compared to the monitoring
cost. Higher monitoring costs oblige the onshore …nancial center to decrease the o¤ered
interest, reducing its markup and its attractiveness to investors. The onshore country is
then forced to cut its tax rate. Similarly, a fall in investor’s reputational harm makes the
o¤shore center more attractive and forces the onshore country to cut its tax rate.
We now explore the e¤ect on agents of an increase in the pressure on investors.
4.2
Winners and losers
The investor’s reputational harm a impacts on the deposit supplies, interest rates and
taxes. Indeed, it can readily be shown that an increase in a entices investors to move
o
=da > 0 >
their investments from the o¤shore …nancial center to the onshore one (dDH
16
dDFo =da). To resist the out‡ow of investment, the o¤shore …nancial center raises its
interest rate. By contrast, the onshore center can take advantage of a more captive set of
o
investors and o¤ers a less advantageous interest rate (drH
=da < 0 < drFo =da). Since tax
proceeds are congruent with pro…ts, the o¤shore policy maker then reacts to the out‡ow of
investors by relaxing her tax pressure whereas the onshore policy maker takes advantage
of the repatriated investments by augmenting its tax pressure (dtoH =da > 0 > dtoF =da).
Hence, the o¤shore …nancial center and government are losers in this policy whereas the
onshore center and governments are the gainers. It is then readily understood that the
o¤shore …nancial lobbies and governments will be vividly opposed to the pressure policy
whereas the onshore …nancial lobbies will be promoting it.
It is interesting to discuss the e¤ect of investor’s reputational harm on the aggregate
surpluses of banks, governments and depositors. Note …rstly that the onshore …nancial
center and government can gain more than what the o¤shore center and government lose.
o
Indeed, it is readily shown that the aggregate pro…t
=
o
H
+
o
F
increases with larger
a if and only if
d o
2k
=
da
S
o
DH
o
dDH
dDFo
+ DFo
da
da
=
4 S
(a
81k
a) > 0
where a is de…ned in expression (4). Therefore, the aggregate pro…t increases with the
investor’s reputational harm if and only if a > a. In this case, ordinary investors who
return to the onshore …nancial center accept a lower interest rate (1) because they do
no longer feel any reputational harm and (2) because they deposit in the closer onshore.
As a consequence, the onshore center is able to realize larger intermediation markups; its
pro…t rises at a faster pace than the fall of o¤shore pro…ts. It is remarkable that, by (4),
this situation occurs when toH > toF ; that is, if the o¤shore country is a tax haven. This
allows us to conclude that the aggregate pro…t increases with the investor’s reputational
17
harm if and only if the o¤shore country is a tax haven. Because pro…ts are congruent
with taxes, the same conclusion applies to tax revenues. So, when the o¤shore country
is a tax haven, banks and governments could extract more revenues in the aggregate by
supporting pressure on investors’ reputation. Of course, their problem is that cooperation
on those issues is hard to obtain.
We now look that the aggregate welfare of ordinary investors. In contrast to banks
and governments, ordinary investors are always harmed by an increase in a. The ordinary
investors’ aggregate surplus
o
V o = (rH
o
toH ) DH + (rFo
toF ) DFo
k o
x
2 F
aDFo
2
S
includes the net return of onshore investment, the net return of o¤shore investment minus
the reputational harm a from pressure to o¤shore investors and …nally the aggregate utility
loss from distance to the foreign center. Di¤erentiating this with respect to a yields
o
dV o
d (rH
toH ) o
d (rFo toF )
DH +
=
da
da
da
{z
}
|
{z
|
+ rFo
|
toF
a
kxoF
{z
o
rH
+ toH
0
1 DFo
}
dxoF
S
da
}|{z}
where the last term is nil by the de…nition of the marginal investor xoF who is indi¤erent between the …nancial centers. We know from the above paragraphs that the return o¤ered to
o
onshore investors falls with larger reputational harm (d(rH
toH )=da) < 0), which reduces
their net utility. By contrast, the return of o¤shore investors rises (d(rFo
but this gain does not outweigh their reputational loss a (d(rFo
toF )=da) > 0)
toF )=da < 1). Indeed,
both the o¤shore …nancial center and government react to an increase in investor’s reputational harm a by raising the o¤ered interest rate rFo and decreasing the tax rate toF ;
18
however they can not o¤er to those investors a net return rFo
toF that fully compensates
for their reputational harm. In the aggregate, investors are thus negatively a¤ected by
the larger reputational harm. This is because the harm on investor’s reputation does not
only destroy the value of o¤shore deposits but it also weakens the competition that disciplines the onshore center. Hence, any lobby that representing ordinary onshore investors
or onshore investors, or both groups shall be reluctant to an increase in pressure resulting
in a higher investor’s reputational harm.
We now study the condition under which the o¤shore …nancial center is enticed to
shift from a lax behavior to a scrupulous monitoring.
5
E¢cient pressure policy and monitoring incentives
National governments and international institutions usual put e¤ort in improving the
regulatory compliance of o¤shore …nancial centers and in deterring investors to deposit
their funds in those centers. Common practices include lobbying for blacklisting of non
compliant o¤shore …nancial centers or organizing information campaigns about investors’
risks in depositing o¤shore. United States Patriot Act and several E.U. member states
explicitly rely on the O.E.C.D. (and F.A.T.F.) blacklists in drawing up their own national
blacklists of tax haven jurisdictions (Sharman, 2004).
As stated in Section 2, criminality generates a social cost (1
)S whereas exerting
pressure on o¤shore …nancial centers and investors has a cost C(a) = a. In addition
to those costs, this paper has highlighted two additional costs, namely, the investor’s
reputational harm and the related weakening of banking competition. The purpose of
this section is to discuss the balance between those costs. To be more precise, we ask the
question about the intensity of the e¢cient pressure in terms of a. Toward this end, we
…rst consider the o¤shore …nancial center’s incentives to monitor its investors. We then
19
derive and discuss the optimal policy of a benevolent planner. We …nally investigate the
cost and bene…t of delegating this policy to onshore institutions. For each case we discuss
the impact of …nancial integration on the pressure policy.
5.1
O¤shore monitoring incentives
The o¤shore …nancial center has an incentive to monitor the investor’s identity and money
origin if its pro…t is larger under monitoring than under lax behavior. That is, if
m
F
o
F
=
k
(DFm )2
(DFo )2
is positive. For any a satisfying conditions (2), this happens if DFm > DFo , or if
a > aF
c + 5k
1
;
(5)
where aF de…nes the threshold of investor’s reputational harm above which the o¤shore
…nancial center voluntarily complies and where aF satis…es condition (2). The o¤shore
center should su¤er a su¢cient demand loss (through larger a) to choose to monitor its
depositors. Note …rstly that the investor’s reputational harm a should be set higher than
the bank’s monitoring cost c. This re‡ects the fact that the o¤shore center must be
enticed to forego its pro…t on illegal money investors. If the number of illegal investors
rises, the pressure exerted on ordinary investors should be even stronger (indeed, aF
decreases with ). Note secondly that the o¤shore center is more likely to monitor its
investors for higher degree of international …nancial integration (smaller k). Indeed, the
investor’s reputational harm a hurts more the o¤shore center as its intermediation margin
falls because of the deeper …nancial integration.
20
5.2
Optimal pressure strategy
We now discuss the optimal pressure exerted by a benevolent social planner who maximizes an objective that encompasses the economic surplus and the criminality damage as
follows:
W =
X
(Vi +
i
+ Ti )
a
(1
)S
i=H;F
where a is the social cost of exerting pressure a and where
(1
) S is the social cost
attached to the use of the banking system to criminal activity. The latter cost vanishes
when the o¤shore …nancial center monitors their investors.
The economic surplus can readily be computed given that the total mass of ordinary
investors is constant and equal to S. For every unit of investment, the investor, the
bank and the government share the risk-free rate interest r. Indeed, the investor earns
ri
ti , the bank r
ri and the government ti , which all add up to r. In addition, an
o¤shore investor su¤ers from reputational losses from the pressure a and from the distance
kx to the o¤shore place. The banks incur the cost c when they monitor their investors.
Therefore, if the planner exerts a su¢cient pressure to entice the o¤shore …nancial center
to monitor (a
aF ), the above objective writes as
1
2
k (xm
F)
2
W m (a) = r
c
S
a
This function obviously decreases in a.
If the planner exerts a too low pressure a (0
a < aF ), the o¤shore center does not
monitor. The objective writes as
W o (a; ) = r
1
k (xoF )2
2
axoF
cxoH
S + (r
21
rFo ) (1
)S
a
(1
)S
The …rst term in the square bracket includes the economic bene…t induced by ordinary
investors minus the welfare loss caused by their distance from the o¤shore bank and their
reputational loss a and minus the monitoring cost in the onshore center. The second term
represents the o¤shore economic bene…t of accepting illicit money and making an earning
on it (though the earning of illicit money holders rFo is nevertheless not considered by the
planner). The third term is the cost of exerting pressure and the last term the social cost
of criminality.
Di¤erentiating this objective by a, we get
dW o
=
da
=
( kxoF
a + c)
S
[17 (a
81k
One can check that, given that
dxoF
da
c)
(55
xoF
S
drFo
S
da
23) k]
> 3=4, the …rst square bracket is negative if a < aF .
Hence, the economic surplus decreases with stronger pressure and investor’s reputational
loss a. As mentioned above, the investor’s reputational loss does not only destroy value
for o¤shore investors and it also reduces the onshore’s investor surplus through the e¤ect
of relaxing the competition for the bene…t of the onshore …nancial center.
Because both objectives decrease in a on their respective supports, the planner’s optimal pressure strategy is to set the smallest value of a on each support. As a result the
planner sets either a = 0 if W m (aF ) < W o (0; ) or a = aF if W m (aF )
that the objective W o decreases in
W o (0; ). Given
we can infer the following proposition:
Proposition 1 There exists a threshold e for the social cost of criminality such that the
social planner exerts no pressure if
< e and exerts the pressure a = aF otherwise.
In her decision, the planner balances the social cost of criminality against the cost
of reduced competition. The unexpected property of our model is the dichotomy in the
22
pressure policy. This dichotomy stems from the fact that the pressure policy reduces values
for depositors (more than it increases pro…ts and tax proceeds). The aggregate welfare
therefore falls with the pressure level until the latter triggers compliance by o¤shore
banks. At this point, welfare increases because of the sudden reduction of criminality.
The planner thus chooses the pressure level aF if the cost of criminality is high enough
and a zero pressure level if it is su¢ciently low.
We now turn to the issue of …nancial integration. How does the pressure policy change
when di¤erentiation between …nancial centers falls (smaller k)? Di¤erentiating totally the
equality W m (aF )
de
dk
=
d
dk
d
d
h
W o (0; e) = 0 we get
W m (aF )
h
W m (aF )
W o (0; e)
i
W o (0; e)
i=
17 2 c2
5
S
2 (1
) (37 + 15 ) k 2
162 (1
) k2
A fall in k has two e¤ects. On the one hand, it decreases the threshold level aF ,
which is re‡ected in the …rst (positive) term in the above expression. Indeed, a fall in k
decreases the pro…t of the o¤shore …nancial center more in the lax scenario than in the
monitoring case and therefore makes the pressure policy more e¤ective. So, the planner
needs to exert a weaker pressure on investors. On the other hand, a fall in k increases
banking competition and reduces the deadweight loss in the banking system. This e¤ect
is presented in the second term in the above expression. To sum up, a fall in k makes the
pressure policy less costly but also less needed. Which e¤ect dominates depends on the
cost of exerting pressure, . Indeed,
de
> 0 ()
dk
>b
S
17
5 162 (1
2
c2
) k2
37 +
81
The threshold b is more likely to be positive if the economy includes fewer criminals (large
).
23
Proposition 2 As …nancial markets integrate (smaller k), the social planner is more
likely to entice the o¤shore bank to monitor by exerting the pressure a = aF if and only if
> b.
This proposition quali…es the usual claim stating that …nancial globalization fosters
criminality. We have here shown that deeper …nancial integration encourages compliance
by o¤shore centers. It furthermore entices the social planner to use this pressure when
the cost of …nancial criminality is high enough compared to the cost of reducing interbank
competition. Under this condition, …nancial globalization reduces …nancial criminality.
The present analysis has relied on the existence of a social planner that aggregates
the interests of all (non-criminal) participants in the economy. In reality pressure on
o¤shore centers is implemented by international bodies which comprise various member
states.9 From that perspective it is not realistic to assume that pressure policies exerted
on o¤shore centers are exclusively driven by concerns for the global welfare. Aggregate
decisions are made through a multilateral negotiation process, which signi…cantly di¤ers
from the utilitarian aggregation of the above social planner. Accordingly, member states
may be inclined to take more or less account of national interests partly re‡ecting domestic lobbying demands. In particular, "the world’s richest and most powerful countries
have become increasingly concerned about revenue lost to tax havens, and fear that tax
competition might spark a …scal ‘race to the bottom’" (Sharman, 2006, p.143). It follows that the interests of large onshore countries could be biased towards the desire to
limit revenue losses caused by tax havens. In addition, e¤orts to curb money laundering
may also be an indirect way to combat tax competition. In that context, The Economist
(2001) wrote: "This raises the toughest question: what exactly are e¤orts against money
9
For instance, the Financial Action Task Force (FATF) is an inter-governmental organisation comprised of 34 members whose purpose is the development and promotion of national and international
policies to combat money laundering and terrorist …nancing.
24
laundering trying to achieve?... Some suspect that the O.E.C.D. would like to use the
…ght against money laundering to advance its parallel and controversial campaign against
an activity it calls “unfair” tax competition, because low rates in one place encourage tax
evasion in another".
In fact, no institution can claim to behave according to the above socioeconomic
objective. For this reason, it is important to discuss the pressure policy if the member
states’ objective is biased towards tax revenue maximization.
5.3
Delegating pressure policy to an onshore agency
We now focus on the case where an onshore agency wants to urge the o¤shore center
to comply with anti-money laundering regulations. The intensity of pressure to exert is
however biased towards onshore tax proceeds. Such a situation is likely to arise because
(1) governments are supposed to have a …scal interest in eliminating fraud, (2) they
hold representation in the international process of targeting o¤shore tax havens, and (3)
they also have audit instruments to check/threaten tax payers who possess o¤shore bank
accounts. In addition since their tax proceeds are aligned with the onshore pro…ts, they
can readily get the support of the lobby of onshore banks. We here show that such a
delegation strategy can be socially ine¢cient.
In this context, we assume that the onshore institution maximizes the tax proceed
minus the social cost of criminality net of the cost of the pressure policy, which is equal
to
o
(a; ) = THo (a)
a
(1
) S if a < aF and
m
(a) = THm
a if a
aF . We
now derive the optimal pressure policy chosen by this institution.
Let us …rst look at the case where the o¤shore …nancial center is enticed to monitor
its investors (a
aF ). Then, neither the onshore tax proceeds nor the criminality level
depend on the level of the pressure policy a. As a result, the onshore institution optimally
25
sets a = aF . Let us then consider the case where the o¤shore …nancial center is not enticed
to monitor its investors (a < aF ). As noted in Section 4.2, the onshore tax proceeds
o
o
THo (a) is an increasing and convex function of a (because THo (a) / [DH
(a)]2 and DH
(a)
is a linearly increasing function of a). So, from the onshore taxation point of view, there
always exists an incentive to raise the pressure policy and set a above zero. However, the
choice of the pressure policy also has a cost a. Since the net tax bene…t THo (a)
a is
a convex function of a, the optimal pressure policy on the interval [0; aF ) must be either
a = 0 or a = aF
", where " > 0 is in…nitely small. The second pressure policy, a = aF
";
is explained by the fact that the onshore institution (as well as the onshore banks) has
an incentive to deter ordinary depositors from o¤shoring their money. Such a deterrence
strategy increases depositors’ demand for the onshore center and raises onshore pro…ts
and taxes. In addition, the onshore institution also has an incentive to entice illegal
money depositors to go to the o¤shore bank. Indeed, because the o¤shore bank will take
advantage of this captive clientele, it will be able to lower its o¤ered interest rates so that
the demand for the onshore bank will be boosted. The following proposition presents a
full characterization of the pressure policy.
Let
=
1
=
(13
3 )k
27k
c
1k
( + 9) and
3
S
2
=
[4k(1
)
c ] [2k(2 + 3 )
27k (1
)
c ]
+
aF
(1
)S
Proposition 3 The optimal pressure policy of the onshore institution is to implement
(i) no pressure if
>
and
(ii) the pressure policy a = aF
<
2,
" if
(iii) the pressure policy a = aF if
<
and
> max f
Proof. See Appendix.
26
1;
<
2g
1
and
Insert Figure 1 here
Figure 1 illustrates the optimal pressure policy for parameters ( ; ). According to
this Figure and to Proposition 3, the onshore institution implements no pressure if the
social cost of criminality is low enough and the cost of the pressure policy is high. It
implements the pressure level aF
" if the social cost of criminality is low and the cost
of the pressure policy is low. Finally, it implements a pressure policy that eliminates
criminality through the monitoring compliance of o¤shore …nancial center if the social
cost of criminality is high enough.
The pressure policy of the onshore institution is not fully aligned with the social planner’s choice. In particular if the cost of exerting pressure and the cost of criminality are
small enough, the onshore organization exerts a pressure but never to the point where
the o¤shore …nancial center monitors. It rather uses the pressure policy to relax interbank competition and repatriate investments back to the onshore bank. This interesting
result highlights the impact of the tax repatriation motives in the …ght against moneylaundering. Such motives can indeed eliminate the incentives to have o¤shore …nancial
centers actually comply with “know-your-customer” and reporting regulations. Hence,
such a pressure policy, presented under the label of a …ght against criminality, may in
fact be diverted to the objective of tax collection, with the blessing of onshore …nancial
centers.
We …nally turn to the issue of …nancial integration. How does the pressure policy
change when di¤erentiation between …nancial centers decreases (smaller k)? It is …rstly
readily seen that
decreases to zero and becomes negative as k falls. The intuition is that
smaller di¤erentiation between …nancial markets does not only reduce pro…ts but also tax
proceeds. So, the onshore institution is less enticed to exert pressure for tax motives.
Secondly, the threshold
1
also falls to zero with smaller k. Finally, the threshold
27
2
also falls with smaller k if the mobility cost is small enough (k <
(4
12
2
p
2c
p
3
2
+2 =
+ 8)) and eventually becomes negative as k falls further. It follows that the
onshore agency will be more likelely to exert the pressure level (a = aF ) that forces the
o¤shore center to comply when …nancial integration deepens. In particular if k ! 0; we
see that max f
1;
2g
! 0. Accordingly, when …nancial markets are perfectly integrated,
the onshore agency exerts the pressure level that is exactly needed to bring into compliance
the o¤shore …nacial center.
Proposition 4 The onshore agency is more likely to exert the pressure level a = aF that
induces compliance when …nancial integration deepens.
It is generally believed that …nancial globalization enhances o¤shore …nancial centers’
attractiveness for illegal money. Our model does account for this feature by assuming
that owners of criminal funds are perfectly mobile. The last proposition however shows
that increased …nancial integration does also make the pressure policy more e¤ective and
augments o¤shore banks’ incentive to comply with international anti-money laundering
rules.
6
Conclusion
International and national institutions put pressure on o¤shore …nancial centers and their
clients to entice those centers to comply with anti-money laundering regulations. Many
observers consider such a soft law practice as ine¢cient policies to combat money laundering by …nancial institutions. They claim that money laundering and bank secrecy are
indeed inextricably linked and that e¢ciently …ghting against …nancial crime can only
be achieved by undermining con…dentiality laws. In this paper we discuss such pressure
policies and assess the impact on money laundering. Towards this aim, we consider a
28
two-country two-…nancial center model with ordinary and criminal investors. Our modelling strategy …ts with the standards of the economic literature not only by allowing
interbank competition but also by modelling the tax competition between the onshore
and o¤shore …nancial centers. This modelling strategy allows us to discuss the winners
and losers of such pressure policies in a clear-cut way. We show that the aggregate pro…t
and tax revenues can increase under the pressure policies because the pressure policy can
induce a reduction in the interbank competition and in the countries’ tax competition
on bank products. In addition, we are able to show that o¤shore banks are enticed to
comply with a scrupulous monitoring of the investors’ identities and the origin of their
funds when the pressure creates su¢cient harm to an investor’s reputation. We …nd that
the e¢cient pressure policy is dichotomous in the sense that a social planner chooses zero
pressure or the pressure that just entices o¤shore banks to comply. We also show that the
implementation of those pressure policies by an onshore tax institution may be ine¢cient
as it can be biased toward the banks’ pro…ts and can never induce the elimination of
criminality. Finally, we qualify the claim stating that deeper …nancial integration fosters
…nancial criminality. In this model, it fosters the elimination of …nancial criminality.
References
[1] Abbott , K.W., Snidal, D., 2000. Hard and Soft Law in International Governance.
International Organization 54, 421–56.
[2] Antoine, R.-M., B.,1999.The Protection of O¤shore Con…dentiality: Policy Implications and Legal Trends. Journal of Financial Crime 7, 9–25.
29
[3] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2001. Customer Due Diligence by Banks,
consultative document. Basel. Bank for International Settlements.
[4] Blum, J., Levi, M., Naylor, R., Williams, P., 1998. Banking secrecy and …nancial
havens. New York: United Nations.
[5] Desai, M. A., Foley, C. F. Hines, J. R., 2006. The demand for Tax Haven Operations.
Journal of Public Economics 90, 513–531.
[6] FitzGerald, V. , 2004. Global Financial Information, Compliance, Incentives and
Terrorist Funding. European Journal of Political Economy 20, 387–40.
[7] International Monetary Fund, 2004. The IMF and the Fight against Money Laundering and the Financing of Terrorism, A Fact sheet. September.
[8] Kanbur R., Keen M.J., 1993. Jeux Sans Frontières : Tax Competition and Tax
Coordination When Countries di¤er in Size. American Economic Review 83, 877–
892.
[9] Levi, M., 2002. Money laundering and its regulation. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 582, 181–194.
[10] Masciandaro, D., 2005. False and Reluctant Friends? National Money Laundering Regulation. International Compliance and Non-Cooperative Countries. European
Journal of Law and Economics 20, 17–30.
[11] Masciandaro, D., 2006. The International Financial War Against Terrorism: Myths
and Reality, in J.Gunning and S. Holm, Ethics, Law and Society, Vol.2, Ashgate,
Aldershot, 211–218.
30
[12] Rose, A. K. and Spiegel, M., 2006. O¤shore Financial Centers: Parasites or Symbionts? NBER Working Paper 12044.
[13] Sharman, J., 2004.International Organisations, Blacklisting and Tax Haven Regulatory Reform, paper presented at the International Studies Association 45th Annual
Convention, Montreal, March.
[14] Sharman,J., 2006. Norms, coercion and contracting in the struggle against ‘harmful’
tax competitionAustralian Journal of International A¤airs Vol. 60, No. 1,pp. 143
/169
[15] The Economist, 2001. Fighting the dirt. June 21.
[16] The Economist, 2007. O¤shore and Beyond the Pale. February 22.
[17] The Economist, 2007. Survey: O¤shore Finance. February 22.
[18] UNDCP World Drug Report, 1997. UNDCP/Oxford University Press.
[19] Zagaris, B. (2001) Issues Low Tax Regimes Should Raise when Negotiating with the
OECD, Tax Notes International, 29 January, 523-532.
7
Appendix: proof of Proposition 3
We look for the maximum of
(a) =
m
o
(a), a 2 [0; 1),where
(a; ) if a 2 [0; aF ). Note that
(a) = aF . Also, because
arg maxa2[0;aF )
o
o
m
(a) if a 2 [aF ; 1) and
(a) is decreasing in a so that arg maxa2[aF ;1)
(a; ) is a convex function of a (a 2 [0; aF )) we get that
(a; ) 2 f0; aF
us de…ne the level
arg maxa2[0;aF )
o
m
(a) =
"g where " is an in…nitely small positive number. Let
such that lim"!0
(a; ) is equal to aF
o
(aF
" if
31
"; ) =
<
o
(0; ). One readily shows that
and equal to 0 otherwise.
Consider …rst that
m
"; )
. Then, the optimal pressure is a = aF
o
" if
(aF
(aF ) and a = aF otherwise (see Figure 2). This situation arises if and
only if lim"!0 THo (aF
1
<
[THo (aF )
")
(aF
THm (aF )] = [(1
")
(1
)S
THm (aF )
aF ; that is, if
) S], which simpli…es to the expression shown in the
text. Accordingly, we get the optimal pressure a = aF
" if
<
1
and a = aF if
1.
Consider secondly that
m
>
so that the optimal pressure is a = 0 if
(aF ) and a = aF otherwise (see Figure 3). That is, if THo (0)
THm (aF )
aF . This is equivalent to
2
[THo (0)
0
o
(0; )
(1
THm (aF ) + aF ] = [(1
)S
) S],
which simpli…es to the expression shown in the text. Therefore, the pressure policy is
a = 0 if
<
2,
a = aF if
>
2.
If
=
2,
then a 2 f0; aF g. Since the latter case
has a zero measure in the set of parameters ( ; ), we omit it in the proposition.
32
γ
α* = 0
γ
α* = αF
α* = αF − ε
β1
β
Figure 1: Pressure policy under delegation to onshore agency
Ω Ho ( a , β < β1 )
Ω Hm ( a )
Ω Ho ( a , β1 )
Ω Ho ( a , β > β1 )
a
aF
0
Figure 2: Objective function of onshore agency under delegation ( γ < γ )
Ω Ho ( a , β < β 2 )
Ω Hm ( a )
Ω Ho ( a , β 2 )
Ω Ho ( a , β > β 2 )
0
aa FF
a
Figure 3: Objective function of onshore agency under delegation ( γ > γ )