Arms for education? External support
and rebel social services
Journal of Peace Research
2021, Vol. 58(4) 794–808
ª The Author(s) 2020
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0022343320940749
journals.sagepub.com/home/jpr
Reyko Huang
Bush School of Government & Public Service, Texas A&M University
Patricia L Sullivan
Department of Public Policy, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill
Abstract
How does foreign support for rebel groups affect rebel governance of civilians during armed conflict? Existing studies
primarily examine the local and domestic politics of rebel rule, leaving the effects of foreign intervention on rebel
governance underexplored. Focusing on rebel provision of social services, this study considers two competing
arguments. The first suggests that foreign sponsorship reduces rebels’ need to rely on local civilians for resources
and hence decreases rebels’ incentives to provide services. The second anticipates that by augmenting rebels’ resources
and military capabilities, foreign support increases their capacity to provide welfare services. These competing logics
suggest that different types of foreign support have divergent effects on rebel social service provision. The article tests
this theory using cross-sectional time-series data on external support for rebel groups and rebel governance for the
post-1945 period. It finds that rebel groups that receive external funding, weapons or training are significantly more
likely to provide education and health services to civilians. In contrast, direct military intervention to assist insurgent
forces has no effect on rebel service provision. This article is among the first to systematically study the impact of
external support and third-party intervention on rebel social service provision during civil war and holds implications
for civilian welfare in contested territories.
Keywords
civil war, military intervention, rebel governance, rebel support, third-party intervention
How does foreign support for rebel groups during
civil war affect rebels’ relations with local civilians?
A growing body of work examines the effects of foreign intervention on conflict duration, intensity, and
outcomes, as well as on combatants’ use of violence
against civilians (e.g. Balch-Lindsay, Enterline & Joyce,
2008; Cunningham, 2010; Salehyan, Gleditsch &
Cunningham, 2011; Sullivan & Karreth, 2015;
Sawyer, Cunningham & Reed, 2017; Fortna, Lotito
& Rubin, 2018). However, the ways in which foreign
intervention affects rebel groups’ local organization,
civilian administration, and governance has received
little scholarly attention. If external aid to the rebels
can increase their fighting capacity, how might it alter
their behavior as political actors who must engage
with civilians in their milieu?
The literature on rebel governance largely focuses on
the domestic politics of rebel rule and has not systematically examined how external sponsorship affects rebel
incentives to govern. If rebel groups seek formal state
power and control over citizens and often have strong
incentives to serve as ‘governors’ (Mampilly, 2011;
Arjona, 2016), how does the influx of foreign weapons
or troops alter their political calculus? Scholarship on
foreign interventions in civil wars and work on rebel
governance have largely developed in parallel; we have
little understanding of how external support shapes rebel
rule across conflicts.
Corresponding author:
[email protected]
Huang & Sullivan
In this article, we examine whether and how various
types of foreign support for rebel groups affect their
incentives and ability to engage in one aspect of civilian
governance: social service provision. We develop two
competing logics. The first draws on the notion of rebel
governance as a system of mutual exchange between rebel
rulers and the ruled. This logic suggests foreign support
will decrease rebels’ incentives to provide welfare services
by encouraging them to concentrate their efforts on military victory over the government and reducing their
need to rely on local civilians. The second logic focuses
on the organizational capacity that is required for rebels to
implement wartime service provision. It holds that by
increasing rebels’ resources, foreign support enhances
their capacity to deliver social services.
Which logic prevails, we argue, depends on the type of
external support rebels receive. Whereas many existing
studies examine external support in the aggregate, we
distinguish between foreign provisions of weapons, training, funding, and combat support to rebel groups. We
propose that weapons, training, and financing support
increase the capacity of rebels to provide social services
by boosting their military strength, enabling them to
allocate more of their resources and personnel towards
civilian governance and service delivery. At the same
time, receiving arms, funds, or training does not eliminate an organization’s need for local civilian support. In
contrast, when foreign combat troops intervene in support of rebels, interveners typically seek a quick military
victory so as not to be bogged down in a costly war. This
incentivizes rebels to seize the opportunity to focus on
militarily defeating the government and scale down governance work until they have achieved victory.
Understanding the factors that affect rebel governance
of civilians is important, not least because in some contexts rebel groups are the only actors providing welfare
services during conflict. While anarchy reigned in some
territories in the Syrian Civil War, for instance, in others
the Kurdish rebels or Islamic State militants became de
facto governing authorities after they wrested control
from regime forces. These armed groups implemented
their own versions of social order and service delivery to
local residents (Saleh, 2017; Robinson et al., 2017).
Rebel governance of civilians may also alter civilian loyalties, impacting conflict dynamics (Kalyvas, 2006).
Rebels’ wartime institution-building efforts can affect
post-conflict political development by providing rebel
groups with experience in civilian administration and
governance (Weinstein, 2007; Podder, 2014; Huang,
2016b; Lyons, 2016; Dresden, 2017) and shaping postwar norms of interpersonal trust (Kubota, 2018). More
795
generally, the near ubiquity of external intervention in
civil wars (Regan, 2002) reinforces the importance of
understanding how specific types of intervention affect
armed groups’ behavior. This study suggests that aid
intended as military support for a rebel group has social
ramifications concerning civilian welfare as well as political ramifications concerning rebel–civilian relations.
This has implications for policy, as external sponsors may
need to weigh any expected benefits of providing such
support against its potential repercussions on local
civilians.
Rebel governance of civilians
Building on the notion popularized by Tilly (1990) that
wars can catalyze competitive state-building, and Olson’s
(1993) concept of the stationary bandit who chooses to
provide protection to civilians in exchange for their taxes,
recent scholarship recognizes rebel governance as a central feature of many civil wars. Arjona, Kasfir & Mampilly (2015: 3) define rebel governance as ‘the set of
actions insurgents engage in to regulate the social, political, and economic life of non-combatants during war’.
To varying degrees of functionality and effectiveness,
rebel groups such as Sri Lanka’s Liberation Tigers of
Tamil Eelam (LTTE), Nepal’s Maoists, Ethiopia’s
Tigray People’s Liberation Front (TPLF), and many others established institutions such as schools, health clinics,
tax systems, radio programs, community defense forces,
local-level legislatures, courts, and laws during armed
conflict. Studies concur in conceptualizing rebel governance as a wartime system of mutual dependence – an
informal and implicit social contract – between the rebel
rulers and the ruled: rebel groups establish order and
security and provide social services to local populations
in order to present themselves as powerful and credible
alternatives to state authority; in turn, rebel groups rely
on civilians to offer their loyalty and support as well as
war-fighting resources such as funding, food, weapons,
shelter, fighters, and intelligence (Wickham-Crowley,
1993; Weinstein, 2007; Beardsley & McQuinn, 2009;
Mampilly, 2011; Arjona, 2016; Huang, 2016b; Stewart,
2018). By creating wartime order and governance, the
rebels aim to not only legitimate their political claims
against the state, but also obtain local support and
resources and motivate more voluntary civilian compliance (Arjona, 2016: 9).1
1
Civilians may have varying motives for supporting the rebels,
including grievances against the state, experiences of political
marginalization, or sympathizing with the rebels’ identity claims.
journal of PEACE RESEARCH 58(4)
796
Not all rebel organizations pursue extensive governance, however, and existing research suggests two broad
and related factors drive rebels to do so. The first is the
need for domestic and international support for their
cause. Rebel groups vary in their need to secure support
and recognition from their internal and external constituents (Stanton, 2016; Jo, 2015; Lasley & Thyne, 2015;
Fazal, 2018). Organizations that seek to signal local control, exert political authority over a population, extract
material resources from civilians, and prevent defection
often create governance and service institutions in part as
a way to meet those goals (Weinstein, 2007; Mampilly,
2011; Arjona, 2016; Huang, 2016b; Malejacq, 2017).
In particular, secessionist groups, aware that they will be
unable to achieve independent statehood without widespread international support (Coggins, 2014) and eager
to convince their domestic constituents of their political
competence, are often more compelled than nonsecessionist groups to engage in civilian governance
(Mampilly, 2011; Florea, 2017; Stewart, 2018).2
Second, rebel groups are unlikely to engage in extensive
governance unless they have attained a sufficient degree of
organizational sophistication and capacity. Wartime
‘state-building’ through the provision of alternative governance is a complex and onerous project. Indeed, studies
find that militarily stronger rebel groups are more likely to
organize popular elections, implement judicial processes,
and conduct international diplomacy, which are arguably
among the more sophisticated rebel governance activities
(Cunningham, Huang & Sawyer, 2020; Loyle, 2020;
Huang, 2016a). In tandem with military strength, robust
rebel governance reflects significant organizational coherence and capacity, since governance and social service
delivery require functional differentiation and clear lines
of command and control within the organization (Beardsley & McQuinn, 2009; Heger & Jung, 2017).
External support and rebel social service
provision: Two logics
How, then, does rebel receipt of external support affect
their incentives and ability to provide wartime social
Others may offer support due to fear of punishment for noncooperation and survival concerns (Kasfir, 2015; Arjona, 2016;
Huang, 2016b; Stewart, 2019).
2
These arguments acknowledge that rebel organizations are often
deeply embedded in local societies and arise out of genuine
grievances held by civilians. Rebel groups have diverse origins
(Braithwaite & Cunningham, 2019) while civilians have varying,
and often unobservable, motives for supporting rebels (Kalyvas,
2006).
services? In this section, we build on existing studies to
derive two competing logics.
Mutual dependence argument
The first plausible effect of foreign support to rebels is
that it reduces the rebels’ need to depend on local civilians for support. When rebels have war-fighting
resources provided to them externally, the mutuality
inherent in the logic of rebel governance weakens: civilians continue to need protection, order, and services in
their midst, but rebels are able to meet many of their
own needs without recourse to civilian inputs. This
logic is based on an understanding of rebel governance
as a system of mutual dependence between rebels and
civilians (Wickham-Crowley, 1993) – what we call the
mutual dependence argument.3 With less need to bargain
with local civilians, rebels are more likely to fulfill any
remaining need for local resources – food, shelter, and
supplies – through coercion rather than through a systematic fostering of an implicit social contract with the
population (Salehyan, Siroky & Wood, 2014). Consistent with this logic, studies suggest rebels’ income
sources have important effects on their treatment of
civilians. Groups with access to profits from natural
resources are more likely to commit violence against
civilians because such groups attract more opportunistic and less disciplined recruits (Weinstein, 2007); they
are also less beholden to local civilians and hence less
vulnerable to the legitimacy costs associated with the
use of indiscriminate violence against civilians (Fortna,
Lotito & Rubin, 2018). Studies suggest external support has an effect similar to natural resource rents – if
rebels are less dependent on civilians as a result of external support, they are more likely to victimize them
(Salehyan, Siroky & Wood 2014; Wood, 2014; Toft
& Zhukov, 2015; Fortna, Lotito & Rubin, 2018). Further, some scholars suggest rebel governance and rebel
violence against civilians can be understood as comprising two sides of the same coin (Weinstein, 2005;
Wood, 2010; Stewart & Liou, 2017): rebel groups will
govern civilians where they are not victimizing them,
and vice versa.
3
The implicit social contract argument does not assume voluntary
civilian support for rebels. Rather, the prevailing assumption
throughout the literature is a complex combination of consent and
coerced compliance and civilians often resist rebel rule (e.g. see
Arjona, 2016; Stewart, 2019).
Huang & Sullivan
Capacity argument
The second logic is that foreign sponsorship enhances
rebels’ ability to provide social services by strengthening
rebel groups’ military capability and enabling the organization to expand its realm of activity into wartime
governance. For many rebel groups, external support is
the lifeline of an otherwise weak and struggling organization (Salehyan, Gleditsch & Cunningham, 2011: 716;
Grauer & Tierney, 2018); many rebel organizations cannot survive unless they receive material support from
foreign governments (Regan, 2002). External patrons
can provide rebels with funding, weapons, training, and
personnel, significantly increasing their war-fighting capabilities. With greater strength and resources, rebel
groups are better equipped to seize and defend territory
and to establish a political presence therein (Beardsley,
Gleditsch & Lo, 2015). While territorial control is not a
prerequisite for rebel governance (Cunningham, Huang
& Sawyer 2020), it certainly facilitates it, especially for
social service provision. Further, freed of the need to
constantly seek resources or to be frequently on the
move, they are able to devote more of their efforts to
implementing political projects locally and eliciting more
voluntary civilian support (Olson, 1993; Wood, 2010;
Wood, Kathman & Gent, 2012). Additionally, rebel
groups that receive external support may pursue ‘statelike’ projects such as social service provision in order to
showcase their organizational sophistication to their foreign sponsors so that the latter is enticed to continue
supplying the group with aid. Weaker groups, in contrast, must orient more of their efforts toward procuring
resources, concealing their locations, and maintaining
mobility to evade state security forces. These demands
are likely to leave them without the capacity to undertake
activities aimed at establishing local political authority.
This logic is thus based on an understanding of rebel
governance as a reflection of rebel strength and organizational capacity – what we call the capacity argument.
To sum the two logics, rebel groups with external
support are less beholden to civilians and thus may be
less willing to provide services, but they also have more
resources and hence are more able to do so. Rebel receipt
of external support thus introduces a tension between
the incentives and the opportunities for social service
provision.
The two logics and types of external support
Which of these competing logics prevails, we argue,
depends on the type of external support provided to rebel
groups. Different types of support affect rebel behavior
797
differently because they bear on distinct aspects of rebel
motives. We focus our analysis on the distinctions
between material support and direct military
intervention.
When external sponsors provide material support –
financing, weapons, or training – to rebel groups, the
logic of rebel behavior as described in the capacity argument comes into play; greater military capacity not only
facilitates territorial gain through battlefield victories, but
also enables political organization and engagement in
governance (Wood, 2010; Malejacq, 2017; Heger &
Jung, 2017; Cunningham, Huang & Sawyer, 2020).
Beardsley, Gleditsch & Lo (2015) find that relatively
weak rebels tend to fight in more geographically dispersed locations; they must stay on the move to survive
and are therefore unable to establish deep roots in local
communities. Material support from a foreign sponsor
can increase a rebel group’s military capacity to the point
that they are able to establish a more stationary presence
and provide local social services.
Importantly, the receipt of foreign funds, weapons, or
training does not supplant the rebels’ need for other
wartime inputs such as intelligence, recruits, and civilian
compliance. Weapons, money, and training are thus not
substitutes for civilian support, but rather are complements to it. For instance, the FMLN’s ability to obtain
food, fighters, and especially intelligence about Salvadoran government forces from local civilians was critical
to the group’s military successes, its receipt of weapons
support from Cuba and Nicaragua notwithstanding
(Wood, 2003: 121). Likewise, despite significant provisions of weapons and training from the Indian military
(Bose, 2002: 633), Sri Lanka’s Tamil Tigers ‘have realized that the people will be beholden to those that take
care of them. In an effort to capture that community
support, the Tamil Tigers have ensured that the communities in LTTE-controlled provinces perceive health
and social services as coming from the LTTE itself’ (Flanigan, 2008: 504). Angola’s UNITA rebels, for their
part, made sure that their external patrons witnessed
first-hand their local governance accomplishments so
that they would continue to provide the rebels with
weapons. UNITA would take US officials on tours of
its rebel capital, impressing them with ‘a well-supplied
bush hospital, schools, a stadium, traffic lights and an
airport with UNITA immigration facilities’ (Brittain,
1998: 11). If the type of external support is such that
rebels still have to rely on civilians, it should not weaken
the implicit social contract. Instead, the support should
help reinforce the social contract by enhancing the
rebels’ overall capacity.
journal of PEACE RESEARCH 58(4)
798
In contrast, and consistent with the mutual dependence argument, we propose that direct combat support
weakens rebels’ incentives to provide social services. The
direct intervention of foreign forces is often a gamechanger that greatly increases the odds of rebel military
victory over the regime, with or without popular support
(Akcinaroglu, 2012; Balch-Lindsay, Enterline & Joyce,
2008; Gent, 2008; Sullivan & Karreth, 2015; Acosta,
2014; Grauer & Tierney, 2018). External states that
intervene with their own military forces do so to pursue
their own agendas; they are often motivated by enmity
toward the sitting government rather than by any real
affinity for the rebel cause (Salehyan, Gleditsch & Cunningham, 2011: 712; Maoz & San-Akca, 2012). Regardless of their motives, they seek to minimize their costs.4
This means foreign interveners typically seek a quick
military victory in order to avoid getting mired in an
intractable war. Although some foreign sponsors may
have long-term interests in promoting local governance,
they will rarely have the patience, cost-tolerance, or foresight to invest in rebel governance while their troops are
engaged in combat with the incumbent regime (Sullivan,
2012). For example, when the United States partnered
with the Northern Alliance (the United Islamic Front for
Salvation of Afghanistan) to topple the Taliban regime in
Afghanistan in 2001, it used air strikes and special forces
troops to support indigenous opposition forces on the
ground and accomplished the mission within a matter of
weeks. In a pattern typical of foreign interventions in
support of armed opposition movements, it largely
ignored governance issues (Sullivan, 2012). US forces
turned their attention to local governance only after the
resurgence of al Qaeda and Taliban forces compelled it
to develop a counterinsurgency strategy to sustain the
new Karzai government (Jones, 2008).
For rebel groups, direct foreign intervention presents
a major opportunity to make battlefield gains and drive
the war toward rebel victory. While foreign troop support can boost rebel capacity for governance, the rare
prospect of swift military gains should galvanize the
rebels to focus on defeating government forces, thus
shortening their time horizons and making social service
provision less pressing, even burdensome (Reno, 2011:
122; Arjona, 2016: ch. 3; Stewart, 2019).
Indeed, large-scale direct military intervention may
even make local inputs largely superfluous, as it did from
the outset of the ADFL rebellion in the First Congo
War, where rebel leader Laurent-Désiré Kabila ‘relied
more on his foreign backers than he did on domestic
support’ (Dunn, 2002: 60). If the rebels have remaining
needs for civilian inputs, they may find it more efficient
to acquire them through coercion (Salehyan, Siroky &
Wood, 2014: 637). Coercive means can backfire if the
rebels have a need to elicit greater civilian support, but
the infusion of foreign combat forces can minimize such
needs in the short term. For example, in the Sierra Leonean civil war against the RUF, Charles Taylor was a
major sponsor of the rebel group, contributing ‘some of
his toughest troops’ from the National Patriotic Front of
Liberia (NPFL) to fight alongside the RUF and continuing his support for the RUF once he became Liberian
president (Keen, 2005: 37, 253). Although RUF forces
appear to have built some rudimentary educational and
health services, they largely focused on hit-and-run
attacks rather than on setting down roots in a community; they ‘were “mobile” rather than “stationary” bandits, with relatively little incentive to care for a
geographical constituency’ (Keen, 2005: 43). Consequently, and consistent with our theory’s expectations,
the organization relied heavily on coercion to gain supporters and perpetrated rampant abuses, including
extreme atrocities, against the very civilians it claimed
to represent (Keen, 2005: 40–43).
To sum, we expect financing, weapons, and training to
complement rather than substitute for local civilian support.
When external actors provide material support or training
to rebel groups, it strengthens their ability to engage in
governance projects as well as their fighting capacity.
4
External states back armed groups for a range of reasons, including
securing access to natural resources, aiding coethnics, and
destabilizing the incumbent regime (Cunningham, 2010: 117;
Salehyan, Gleditsch & Cunningham, 2011).
Research design
H1: Rebel groups that receive foreign funding, weapons or training are more likely to provide civilian
social services than those without such support.
In contrast, we expect combat support to weaken
rebels’ implicit social contract with civilians, leading to
decreased incentives to provide social services.
H2: Rebel groups that receive direct combat support
from foreign forces are less likely to provide civilian
social services than those that do not receive such
support.
We test our hypotheses using cross-sectional time-series
data on external aid to rebel groups and rebel group
Huang & Sullivan
social service provision in civil wars that began between
1946 and 2004. The unit of analysis is the rebel group in
each year of a conflict (group-year). We use the Rebel
Governance Dataset (RGD) (Huang, 2016b) for data on
social service provision by rebel groups. Data on external
assistance provided to rebel groups are from the StateNonState Armed Groups Cooperation (NAGs) dataset
(San-Akca, 2015). Because these two data sources have
different units of analysis and somewhat different inclusion criteria for armed groups, we collected additional
data to combine the two datasets as detailed below.
The primary threat to our ability to identify a causal
effect of external support is that foreign support is not
randomly assigned to opposition groups. The groups
that receive external assistance are likely to be systematically different from the groups that do not receive any
assistance. If these differences are also determinants of
social service provision, it will be difficult to determine
whether any observed differences between rebel groups
are due to the external support they received or to preexisting differences. In addition, we are concerned about
the possibility of reverse causality. It could be that rebel
service provision attracts (or repels) external support,
rather than support enabling (or deterring) service provision as our hypotheses anticipate.
We adopt several strategies to mitigate these threats.
First, we use coarsened exact matching (CEM) to reduce
the imbalance between treatment (supported rebels) and
control (unsupported rebels) groups before analysis
(Iacus, King & Porro, 2017). Our matching equation
includes variables that (1) have been identified in previous research as possible determinants of external support
for rebel groups, (2) are plausibly related to rebel service
provision, and (3) are not themselves consequences of
external support (King, 2010; Stuart, 2010). The aim is
to use the matching variables – ethnic conflict, communist ideology, and Cold War conflict year – to create
treatment and control groups that are as similar as possible on potentially confounding variables so that our
estimates of the effects of external support are unbiased.
Although matching on observables cannot eliminate the
possibility of selection bias, matching on observed variables also matches on unobserved factors to the extent
that those variables are correlated with observed covariates (Stuart, 2010: 3). If there are, for example, unobserved characteristics of rebel groups that affect both
external support and service provision, omitting them
from the model will not bias the coefficient estimates
on external support unless those characteristics are
uncorrelated with all of the matching variables.
799
To address concerns about the endogeneity of external support, we estimate all models with measures of
external support prior to the measure of social service
provision. As an additional step, we replicate the analyses with a sample restricted to observations in which a
rebel group was not providing social services in the
prior year. These models allow us to test whether support provided by foreign states increases the odds that a
rebel group will begin providing social services after
receiving the assistance.
Dependent variable: Rebel service provision
Our measure of rebel social service provision comes from
the Rebel Governance Dataset (RGD) (Huang, 2016b),
which contains conflict-level data on governance institutions formed by armed opposition groups in all major
civil wars that ended between 1950 and 2006. We create
a binary variable for rebel social service provision that
takes the value of 1 if the rebel organization maintained
its own education or healthcare services in a given year by
expanding the RGD in two ways.
First, we extend the coding of education and
healthcare provision to the primary rebel group in
armed conflicts that appear in the UCDP/PRIO
Armed Conflict Database (ACD), but not in the
RGD dataset, to match the source of our key independent variables. The RGD is based on the Doyle
& Sambanis (2006) list of conflicts in which there
were 1,000 total deaths within three years of conflict
onset. Our independent variables on external support
are drawn from the State-Nonstate Armed Group
Cooperation (NAG) dataset, based on the UCDP/
PRIO ACD (v 4-2014a), which identifies conflicts
that resulted in at least 25 battle-deaths a year (Gleditsch et al., 2002; Themnér & Wallensteen, 2014).
To avoid the possibility of bias introduced by including many observations for conflicts with multiple
rebel groups, and to make coding of the dependent
variable more tractable, we include annual observations for just one government–opposition dyad per
conflict.5
Second, for every group coded as providing social
services, we conducted additional research to determine
5
We identify the primary rebel group as the group that has the
greatest military strength relative to the government according to
the Non-State Actor (NSA) dataset (Cunningham, Gleditsch &
Salehyan, 2013). If two groups are in the same relative military
strength category, we choose the larger group using the NSA
dataset’s best estimate of rebel size.
journal of PEACE RESEARCH 58(4)
800
60
0.8
50
0.7
0.6
40
0.5
30
0.4
0.3
20
0.2
Number of active armed groups
Proportion of groups providing social services
0.9
10
0.1
0
Active armed groups
2003
2000
1997
1994
1991
1988
1985
1982
1979
1976
1973
1970
1967
1964
1961
1958
1955
1952
1949
1946
0
Social service provision
Figure 1. Armed groups and social service provision, 1946–2003
when the group began providing these services.6 As anticipated, this was often difficult to determine. Because we are
testing hypotheses about the effects of external assistance
on service provision, we were most concerned about coding the initiation of services too late, creating the impression that receipt of external assistance preceded social
service provision when in reality the temporal order was
the reverse. Consequently, when there is ambiguity about
the year a group began to provide services, we erred on the
side of the earliest date. Table A.1 in the Online appendix
lists each of the rebel groups that established services with
the year service provision began and the year external
assistance (if any) was first provided.
Figure 1 displays the number of armed groups
engaged in an active conflict and the proportion of those
groups that provided civilian social services across time.
6
We explored using annual data on rebel social service provision
from Stewart (2018) but found that there was very little year-toyear variation in the data. Of the 128 insurgent groups coded as
providing some level of social services during a conflict, 110 are
coded as providing them from the first through the last year of the
conflict. As a result, the value of the rebel service provision indicator
in year t is equal to its value in year t–1 in 99% of the dataset’s
observation years.
The cast of rebel groups that provided social services is
diverse. UNITA claimed to have established 22 secondary schools and built six central hospitals in southern
Angola, in addition to regional hospitals and clinics in
its operational areas (James, 1992: 98). The Darul Islam
movement in Indonesia established schools and hospitals
as well as ‘an academy of literacy science’. To stock the
latter, rebel troops ‘ransacked the library of Jajene, where
2,500 titles were reported to have disappeared’ (Van
Dijk, 1981: 194). The Fretilin of East Timor built health
clinics, in addition to manufacturing pills from medicinal plants (Taylor, 1999: 81).
Key independent variables: Financing,
weapons, training, troops
We use the NAGs dataset (San-Akca, 2015) for measures
of external support to rebel groups between 1940 and
2010. The NAG-year dataset contains information on
external state provision of nine specific types of aid in each
year that a rebel group was active.7 We use these data to
7
External states can also provide other types of support to rebel
groups, including sanctuary in their territory. We do not expect
sanctuary to change a rebel group’s need for civilian support or
Huang & Sullivan
create several different measures of external support. Our
first set of variables consists of dichotomous indicators
that the rebel group received training, weapons and logistics, financing, or troop support. To address endogeneity
concerns, we measure external support in the year prior to
the observation of our dependent variable.
A second set of measures attempts to incorporate information about the level of support the rebel group received.
We expect the effects of aid to be cumulative and to persist
for some time even after support is withdrawn. Arms transferred to an opposition group will continue to function,
and rebel fighters that receive training can continue to use
the skills they develop, for years after the sponsor has ceased
providing support. Ideally, we would have data on the value
of weapons transferred to a group over time, or the number
of rebel fighters trained by foreign troops. As these data are
not available, we use the number of years that a group has
been receiving support and the number of states providing
assistance as proxies for the scale of aid a group has received.
First, we create variables that range from 0 to 2 based on the
number of providers of each type of assistance. Because
there are two or fewer providers in 97% of our observation
years, we record a 2 if the opposition received assistance
from two or more foreign states. We then create backwardmoving averages by summing the number of foreign governments that provided each type of support in each of the
three years prior to our observation year and dividing by
three. The variable is 0 when there were no external providers of a particular type of assistance in the preceding
three years. If two or more states assisted the group in each
of the preceding three years, the variable is coded as 2. If
only one state provided weapons for one year of this period,
the variable would equal 0.33.8
We use this ordinal measure as a way to capture the
magnitude and consistency of external support. If financing, weapons, combat support, or training increase an
armed group’s capacity to provide social services, the
effects should be cumulative and increasing in the duration of that support. Likewise, larger-scale support
capacity to provide social services, but we do control for this type of
support in robustness checks.
8
One major advantage of San-Akca’s data is that rebel groups and
their supporters are coded from the first year the group declares a
name, even if the group did not conduct any violent attacks until
years later (San-Akca, 2016: 47). This allows us to include support
received prior to the initiation of an armed conflict in our measures of
external assistance. Our backward-moving averages capture prewar
support for the first three years of a conflict. In the second year of
a conflict, for example, the three-year backward-moving average
includes support provided in the two years before conflict initiation
and the first year of the conflict.
801
should correspondingly diminish rebels’ need to draw
on civilian inputs. To ensure our results are not driven
by a particular measure, we test models with dichotomous measures of support and discrete variables that
separate years of support (consistency) from number of
supporters in the Online appendix.
Potentially confounding variables
Several characteristics of rebel groups are likely to influence both the support they receive from foreign governments and their propensity to provide social services. As
discussed above, current literature suggests that territorial control and secessionist aims increase a group’s ability
and motivation to engage in public goods provision
(Mampilly, 2011; Stewart, 2018; Florea, 2017; Wood,
2010). We estimate models with dichotomous variables
indicating whether the armed group controlled territory
(territory) or had secessionist aims (secessionist). Both variables are from the Non-State Actor (NSA) dataset (Cunningham, Gleditsch & Salehyan, 2013). Potential
sponsors are unlikely to see rebel organizations as a good
investment unless they are able to pose a credible threat
to the government (Gent, 2008; Salehyan, Gleditsch &
Cunningham, 2011). We use a categorical measure of
rebel troop strength from the Strategies and Tactics in
Armed Conflict (STAC) dataset (Sullivan & Karreth,
2019). The rebeltrpcat variable has four categories and
varies from 1, for groups with fewer than 3,000 troops,
to 4, for armed groups with more than 30,000 troops.
Groups that are reliant on mobilizing ethnic kin to
support their operations may be more likely to provide
social services as a means to establish local control and
gain legitimacy (Beardsley, Gleditsch & Lo, 2015). And
ethnic ties often motivate states to sponsor armed groups
that mobilize coethnics in other countries (Salehyan,
2009; Salehyan, Gleditsch & Cunningham, 2011). We
include the dichotomous variable ethnic conflict from the
NSA Dataset to indicate armed groups that mobilize
support from among a population that identifies with a
distinct ethnic or cultural heritage. Several studies suggest that armed groups with Marxist or Maoist ideologies
are more likely to engage in civilian governance due to a
strategic emphasis on the population as a critical base of
support (Kalyvas & Balcells, 2011; Mampilly, 2011;
Huang, 2016b; Stewart, 2018). Further, these groups
could often draw support from communist regimes in
other states, particularly during the Cold War. We create
a dichotomous variable (communist) indicating a rebel
group with a Marxist, Maoist, communist, or socialist
ideological orientation with data from NSA dataset and
journal of PEACE RESEARCH 58(4)
802
Table I. Descriptive statistics
Variable
Rebel service provision in year
Funding provided in year
Number of finance providers in year
Finance providers (mean, prior 3 yrs)
Arms provided in year
Number of arms providers in year
Arms providers (mean, prior 3 yrs)
Training provided in year
Number of training providers in year
Training providers (mean, prior 3 yrs)
Combat troops provided in year
Number of troop providers in year
Troop providers (mean, prior 3 yrs)
Communist ideology
Secessionist aims
Ethnic conflict
Rebel troops (categorical)
Rebel territorial control
Year of conflict
Cold War year
Foreign sanctuary in year
Conflict spread
Population (logged)
Pro-government intervention
Government troops (categorical)
Rough terrain
Democratic government
Number of rebel groups in country
N
Mean
Std dev.
Min.
Max.
1,183
1,183
1,154
1,024
1,183
1,161
1,096
1,183
1,142
1,077
1,183
1,158
1,098
1,053
1,183
1,050
960
1,160
1,079
1,183
1,158
985
914
1,025
943
1,051
939
1,052
0.52
0.26
0.34
0.35
0.52
0.68
0.65
0.31
0.39
0.39
0.08
0.09
0.09
0.37
0.42
0.42
2.69
0.47
8.27
0.62
0.45
2.36
16.66
0.22
3.68
2.64
0.32
2.34
0.50
0.44
0.61
0.60
0.50
0.72
0.68
0.46
0.61
0.59
0.27
0.31
0.28
0.48
0.49
0.49
0.98
0.50
9.17
0.49
0.50
1.20
1.39
0.41
0.69
1.21
0.47
1.92
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
1
11.4
0
1
0
0
1
1
1
2
2
1
2
2
1
2
2
1
2
2
1
1
1
4
1
54
1
1
4
20.8
1
4
4.41
1
12
Table II. Coarsened exact matching results
Finance
Weapons
Training
Troops
Treatment
Data
Raw
Matched
Raw
Matched
Raw
Matched
Raw
Matched
Global L1 distance
Observations
0.24
852
9.04e–16
906
0.21
972
1.6e–15
939
0.31
923
1.1e–15
899
0.34
1,109
6.3e–16
936
generate a Cold War dummy variable for observation
years between 1947 and 1989.
Several additional control variables are included in
models estimated to assess the robustness of our results.
Table A5 in the Online appendix displays results from
models estimated with controls for rebels’ access to sanctuary on foreign territory (sanctuary from NAGs dataset),
the number of armed groups active in a country in a
given year (from NSA dataset), the logged population
of the conflict country from Penn World Tables (Heston, Summers & Aten, 2012), direct intervention on
behalf of the government (STAC dataset), the
proportion of the country affected by significant armed
conflict (STAC dataset), rough terrain (NSA dataset),
and democratic governance in the conflict country (Marshall, Jaggers & Gurr, 2011). Table I reports descriptive
statistics for all of our variables.
Results
Table II reports results from implementing the coarsened
exact matching (CEM) method (Blackwell et al., 2009;
Iacus, King & Porro, 2017) to reduce the imbalance
between our treatment and control groups. We execute
Huang & Sullivan
803
Table III. External assistance and rebel service provision
Model 3.1
Financing (prior 3 yrs)
Model 3.2
Model 3.3
Model 3.4
0.690**
(0.26)
Weapons (prior 3 yrs)
0.926***
(0.26)
Training (prior 3 yrs)
0.787*
(0.31)
Troops (prior 3 yrs)
Communist ideology
Secessionist aims
Ethnic conflict
Territorial control
Size of rebel forces
Cold War
Conflict year
Conflict year2
Conflict year3
Constant
N (group-years)
n (armed groups)
chi2
Model 3.5
1.102**
(0.40)
–0.063
(0.40)
–0.554
(0.36)
0.857**
(0.30)
0.526**
(0.16)
0.327
(0.33)
–0.034
(0.06)
0.011
(0.01)
–0.000
(0.00)
–2.452***
(0.59)
698
87
48.0
1.324*
(0.52)
–0.071
(0.43)
–0.897*
(0.39)
1.185***
(0.32)
0.573**
(0.20)
0.405
(0.35)
–0.089
(0.09)
0.015
(0.01)
–0.000
(0.00)
–3.064***
(0.76)
673
84
61.0
1.473**
(0.50)
0.266
(0.44)
–0.487
(0.38)
0.793*
(0.31)
0.590**
(0.19)
0.267
(0.33)
–0.250*
(0.10)
0.025**
(0.01)
–0.000*
(0.00)
–3.098***
(0.64)
698
87
50.6
1.241**
(0.46)
0.333
(0.48)
–0.457
(0.41)
1.050**
(0.36)
0.534**
(0.20)
0.171
(0.37)
–0.113
(0.09)
0.015*
(0.01)
–0.000
(0.00)
–2.845***
(0.76)
685
87
56.3
0.375
(0.58)
1.288**
(0.45)
0.268
(0.54)
–0.647
(0.48)
0.809*
(0.39)
0.784***
(0.21)
0.410
(0.46)
–0.110
(0.08)
0.019*
(0.01)
–0.000*
(0.00)
–3.423***
(0.94)
635
85
63.9
Probit regression models with CEM matched data. Robust standard errors clustered by armed group in parentheses. *p < .05, **p < .01, ***p <
.001 (two-tailed tests).
the CEM procedure for each type of external assistance
separately using the same set of pretreatment observables: ethnic conflict, communist ideology, and Cold
War. The global L1 statistic measures overall (joint distribution) imbalance in pretreatment covariates between
the treated and untreated groups. The statistic varies
between 0 and 1, with 0 indicating perfect balance
(Blackwell et al., 2009). In the table, we report this
measure for the raw data and for each of the matched
samples. In all cases, the matching procedure greatly
reduces imbalance between the treatment and control
groups. We also report the number of group-year observations in the raw data and the number of matched
observations.
Model 3.1 in Table III is a baseline model of rebel
service provision with unmatched data. Models 3.2
through 3.4 use CEM matched samples to estimate the
effects of external sponsorship on the likelihood that a
rebel group will provide social services to civilians. The
key independent variables are moving averages of the
number of foreign governments that supplied financing,
weapons, training, or direct troop support over the past
three years. The effect of each type of assistance is estimated in a separate model because we are only able to
match on one treatment variable at a time and because
forms of assistance are highly correlated. In the Online
appendix, we report results from models estimating the
effects of arms transfers while controlling for the direct
intervention of combat troops. All standard error estimates are clustered on the armed group and we include a
cubic polynomial temporal approximation of conflict
duration to account for temporal dependence.
The coefficients on financing, weapons, and training
are all positive and statistically significant, suggesting
804
that rebel groups are significantly more likely to provide
social services if an external sponsor has provided them
with one of these types of support. In contrast, direct
intervention by another state has no effect on service
provision. To get a better sense of the substantive effects
of foreign assistance we generate predicted probabilities
holding all but our variables of interest constant at their
mean values. For the ‘average’ armed group-year, the
probability that a rebel group will provide social services
increases from approximately 45% if it receives no external funding, to 70% with one consistent foreign funder,
and over 85% if at least two states provided consistent
funding over the prior three years.9 The substantive
effect of arming a rebel group is even more pronounced.
Only 18% of groups that do not receive weapons from
external sponsors are expected to provide welfare services. The likelihood of rebel service provision increases
to 49% if the group receives arms from one state in each
of the preceding three years. If the rebels receive arms
from two or more states in each of the preceding three
years, the probability of service provision jumps to 81%.
The effect of training is similar to that of external financing. If a group receives training from one sponsor for
three years, the predicted probability of service provision
in the following year is 76%, compared to just 47% for a
group that does not receive any training assistance from a
foreign military.
In the Online appendix, we explore the robustness of
these results to different measures of our key independent variables. In Tables A2 and A3, we report the results
of models estimated with a dichotomous indicator that
the rebel group received weapons or training from a
foreign state in the prior year; a categorical measure of
the consistency of material support provided over the
past three years; and a categorical measure of the number
of external states providing either weapons or training.
All of these measures have a positive, statistically significant effect on rebel service provision. Of note, both the
number of providers and the consistency of support condition the impact of arms transfers, while only consistency appears to affect the impact of training.
The effects of the control variables in our model are
largely as expected. Larger rebel groups and groups that
control territory are significantly more likely to provide
education or healthcare services. To illustrate the combined impact of territorial control and external arms
9
Rebels were financed by two or more states in 9% of group-years,
armed by two or more states in 20% of group-years, and trained by
two or more states in 10% of group-years.
journal of PEACE RESEARCH 58(4)
Figure 2. Probability of social service provision
Capped spikes indicate 95% confidence intervals around point estimates of the probability of service provision. Controls are held at their
respective means.
supplies, Figure 2 plots the probability of service provision by both rebel territorial control and arms providers.
Armed groups that control territory are significantly
more likely to deliver health or educational services
across the range of weapons providers. The predicted
probability of service provision varies from under 7% for
a group that is not armed by an external actor and does
not have a territorial base to over 94% for a group with
territorial control and at least two state sponsors funneling weapons to it over the prior three years.
Opposition groups that espouse a communist or
Marxist ideology are also significantly more likely to
provide social services to the civilian populations. In fact,
communist ideology is one of the strongest predictors of
service provision even after controlling for Cold War
years. Contrary to our expectations, there is no evidence
that rebel groups mobilized on the basis of ethnic identity or groups with secessionist aims are any more likely
to provide social services to civilian populations. While
several studies maintain that rebels with secessionist
ambitions are more motivated to provide governance
(Mampilly, 2011; Florea, 2017; Stewart, 2018), in our
data, secessionist and non-secessionist groups provide
health and education services at roughly the same rate.
The link between secessionist groups and rebel governance is a relatively new area of research; it is possible that
the effect depends on the type of rebel governance
Huang & Sullivan
examined or other contextual factors. We hope to
explore these issues in future research.
As noted above, the most significant threat to the
internal validity of our results is endogeneity – the possibility that rebel service provision attracts external providers of material support, rather than this support
enabling service provision as Hypothesis 1 anticipates.
To address this threat, we have used measures of external
support in years prior to the observation of our dependent variable. As an additional step, we replicate our
analyses using Markov transition models to estimate the
effect of receiving aid on the onset of service provision.10
We do this by restricting the sample to observations in
which the rebels were not delivering social services in the
prior year. Table A4 in the Online appendix reports the
results.
Although we lose almost two-thirds of our cases by
restricting the sample to rebel groups that were not
engaged in social service provision at t–1, the models
in Table A4 increase our confidence in the effects of
external assistance. Receiving weapons or military training from external states significantly increases the likelihood that a rebel group that has not been providing
social services will begin to deliver these public goods (p
< .001). Financing is also positively correlated with the
onset of social service provision, but the estimate is only
significant at the p < .1 level. As in the previous analyses,
direct intervention has no effect on rebel service
provision.
In the Online appendix, we report the results of additional robustness checks including models estimated
with additional control variables (e.g. pro-government
intervention, rebel sanctuary, and conflict with multiple
rebel groups). None of the results cause us to question
our core findings.
Conclusion
This article examined how different forms of external
support to rebel groups affect rebel service provision.
Our results show that direct military intervention on
behalf of an armed opposition group has no effect on a
group’s propensity to create welfare institutions. However, when external states increase a rebel group’s capacity by providing funding, weapons, or training, the
group is significantly more likely to invest in social service provision. This finding challenges the notion that
rebel groups that have access to external resources
10
Ruggeri, Dorussen & Gizelis (2017) use this approach to estimate
the effects of UN peacekeeping on conflict onset.
805
become less reliant on local civilians for support and
therefore have less incentive to cultivate a reciprocal relationship with them. While receiving funds, arms, and
training can increase a group’s fighting capacity, rebels
still need civilians to provide them with shelter, intelligence, protection, and recruits. In fact, receiving weapons, capital, or military training may actually increase
rebels’ demand for recruits. Although increased firepower and combat skill could encourage rebel groups
to fulfill their remaining needs through violent coercion,
our results suggest that increased military capacity may
instead translate into increased capacity to bolster civilian
governance and provide social services.
Considered in conjunction with existing research, our
findings have complex but important implications about
external interventions in civil wars. Studies suggest that
militarily strong rebel organizations are less likely to
inflict violence on civilians, more likely to engage in
wartime state-building, and better prepared for postwar
politics (e.g. Wood, 2010; Wood, Kathman & Gent,
2012; Weinstein, 2005; Lyons, 2016). External states,
by providing resources such as weapons and training, can
significantly boost rebel military capabilities and thereby
contribute to the generation of these ostensibly positive
outcomes. However, studies also show that external
intervention can prolong civil wars by propping up otherwise weak rebel groups, make war termination more
elusive by increasing the number of actors that must be
placated at the negotiating table, create moral hazards for
aspiring rebel groups, and potentially corrode rebel
groups’ interest in local governance if interveners engage
in direct combat on the rebels’ behalf (Elbadawi & Sambanis, 2000; Cunningham, 2010; Kuperman, 2008).
These multifarious impacts can be readily observed in
the ongoing war in Syria, where the survival and internal
operations of various rebel groups could not be explained
apart from the foreign military interventions that have
artificially sustained them in the face of massive military
onslaughts by regime security forces, and where military
support by various foreign powers for both the state and
the rebels have ensured a protracted war with extremely
high civilian casualties. Studies thus collectively illuminate the difficult tensions that inherently underlie foreign interventions in civil wars. This study brings the
study of external support and its effects to a more granular level by developing different causal logics for different types of military support. Future research should
further examine the impacts of different types of external
support, as well as seek to explain whether and why
different sources of rebels’ material inputs – civilian
806
taxes, natural resources, foreign support, and others –
generate different local-level effects.
Replication data
The dataset, codebook, and do-files for the empirical
analysis in this article, as well as the Online appendix,
can be found at http://www.prio.org/jpr/datasets.
Acknowledgments
We are grateful for research assistance from Ghazal
Dezfuli, Frances Duffy, and Lara Handelsman. We
thank participants in the Lethal Aid and Human
Security workshop at the University of North Carolina and the 2018 Peace Science Society Meeting at
the University of Texas for early feedback on the
project. Joey Huddleston, Reed Wood, and the
reviewers and editors at JPR provided invaluable comments on the article.
Funding
Data collection for this project was supported by the
Carnegie Corporation of New York (D 15126). All statements made are solely the responsibility of the authors.
ORCID iD
Reyko Huang
https://orcid.org/0000-0003-21462012
https://orcid.org/0000-0002Patricia L Sullivan
0028-9452
References
Acosta, Benjamin (2014) Live to win another day: Why many
militant organizations survive yet few succeed. Studies in
Conflict & Terrorism 37(2): 135–161.
Akcinaroglu, Seden (2012) Rebel interdependencies and civil
war outcomes. Journal of Conflict Resolution 56(5):
879–903.
Arjona, Ana (2016) Rebelocracy: Social Order in the Colombian
Civil War. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Arjona, Ana; Nelson Kasfir & Zachariah Mampilly, eds
(2015) Rebel Governance in Civil War. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Balch-Lindsay, Dylan; Andrew J Enterline & Kyle A Joyce
(2008) Third-party intervention and the civil war process.
Journal of Peace Research 45(3): 345–363.
Beardsley, Kyle & Brian McQuinn (2009) Rebel groups as
predatory organizations: The political effects of the 2004
tsunami in Indonesia and Sri Lanka. Journal of Conflict
Resolution 53(4): 624–645.
journal of PEACE RESEARCH 58(4)
Beardsley, Kyle; Kristian Skrede Gleditsch & Nigel Lo (2015)
Roving bandits? The geographical evolution of African
armed conflicts. International Studies Quarterly 59(3):
503–516.
Blackwell, Matthew; Stefano Iacus, Gary King & Giuseppe
Porro (2009) CEM: Coarsened exact matching in Stata.
Stata Journal 9(4): 524–546.
Bose, Sumantra (2002) Flawed mediation, chaotic implementation: The 1987 Indo-Sri Lanka peace agreement.
In: Stephen John Stedman, Donald Rothchild & Elizabeth M Cousens (eds) Ending Civil Wars: The Implementation of Peace Agreements. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner,
631–659.
Braithwaite, Jessica Maves & Kathleen Gallagher Cunningham (2019) When organizations rebel: Introducing the
Foundations of Rebel Group Emergence (FORGE) dataset. International Studies Quarterly 64(1): 183–193.
Brittain, Victoria (1998) Death of Dignity: Angola’s Civil War.
Trenton, NJ: Africa World.
Coggins, Bridget (2014) Power Politics and State Formation in
the Twentieth Century: The Dynamics of Recognition. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
Cunningham, David E (2010) Blocking resolution: How
external states can prolong civil wars. Journal of Peace
Research 47(2): 115–127.
Cunningham, David E; Kristian Skrede Gleditsch & Idean
Salehyan (2013) Non-state actors in civil wars: A new
dataset. Conflict Management and Peace Science 30(5):
516–531.
Cunningham, Kathleen Gallagher; Reyko Huang & Katherine
Sawyer (2020) Voting for militants: Rebel elections in civil
war. Journal of Conflict Resolution. (https://doi.org/10.
1177/0022002720937750).
Doyle, Michael W & Nicholas Sambanis (2006) Making War
and Building Peace: United Nations Peace Operations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Dresden, Jennifer Raymond (2017) From combatant to candidates: Electoral competition and the legacy of armed
conflict. Conflict Management and Peace Science 34(3):
240–263.
Dunn, Kevin C (2002) A survival guide to Kinshasa. In: John
F Clark (ed.) The African Stakes of the Congo War. New
York: Palgrave Macmillan, 53–74.
Elbadawi, Ibrahim A & Nicholas Sambanis (2000) External
interventions and the duration of civil wars. Policy
Research Working Paper 2433. Washington, DC: World
Bank.
Fazal, Tanisha M (2018) Wars of Law: Unintended Consequences in the Regulation of Armed Conflict. Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press.
Flanigan, Shawn Teresa (2008) Nonprofit service provision by
insurgent organizations: The cases of Hizballah and the
Tamil Tigers. Studies in Conflict & Terrorism 31(6):
499–519.
Huang & Sullivan
Florea, Adrian (2017) De facto states: Survival and disappearance (1945–2011). International Studies Quarterly 61(2):
337–351.
Fortna, Virginia Page; Nicholas J Lotito & Michael A Rubin
(2018) Don’t bite the hand that feeds: Rebel funding
sources and the use of terrorism in civil wars. International
Studies Quarterly 62(4): 782–794.
Gent, Stephen E (2008) Going in when it counts: Military
intervention and the outcome of civil conflicts. International Studies Quarterly 52(4): 713–735.
Gleditsch, Nils Petter; Peter Wallensteen, Mikael Eriksson,
Margareta Sollenberg & Håvard Strand (2002) Armed
Conflict 1946–2001: A new dataset. Journal of Peace
Research 39(5): 615–637.
Grauer, Ryan & Domonic Tierney (2018) The arsenal of
insurrection: Explaining rising support for rebels. Security
Studies 27(2): 263–295.
Heger, Lindsay L & Danielle F Jung (2017) Negotiating with
rebels: The effect of rebel service provision on conflict
negotiations. Journal of Conflict Resolution 61(6):
1203–1229.
Heston, Alan; Robert Summers & Bettina Aten (2012) Penn
World Table Version 7.1. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University
of Pennsylvania (July).
Huang, Reyko (2016a) Rebel diplomacy in civil war. International Security 40(4): 89–126.
Huang, Reyko (2016b) The Wartime Origins of Democratization: Civil War, Rebel Governance, and Political Regimes.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Iacus, Stefano M; Gary King & Giuseppe Porro (2017) Causal
inference without balance checking: Coarsened exact
matching. Political Analysis 20(1): 1–24.
James, W Martin III (2011) A Political History of the Civil War
in Angola, 1974–1990. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction.
Jo, Hyeran (2015) Compliant Rebels: Rebel Groups and International Law in World Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Jones, Seth (2008) Counterinsurgency in Afghanistan. Santa
Monica, CA: RAND.
Kalyvas, Stathis N (2006) The Logic of Violence in Civil War.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Kalyvas, Stathis N & Laia Balcells (2011) International system
and technologies of rebellion: How the end of the Cold
War shaped internal conflict. American Political Science
Review 104(3): 415–429.
Kasfir, Nelson (2015) Rebel governance – constructing a field
of inquiry: Definitions, scope, patterns, order, causes. In:
Ana Arjona, Nelson Kasfir & Zachariah Mampilly (eds)
Rebel Governance in Civil War. New York: Cambridge
University Press, 21–46.
Keen, David (2005) Conflict and Collusion in Sierra Leone.
Oxford & New York: James Currey.
King, Gary (2010) A hard unsolved problem? Post-treatment
bias in big social science questions. Presented at the Hard
807
Problems in Social Science Symposium, 10 April, Cambridge, MA.
Kubota, Yuichi (2018) Nonviolent interference in civic life
during civil war: Rebel service provision and postwar norms
of interpersonal trustworthiness in Sri Lanka. Security Studies 27(3): 511–530.
Kuperman, Alan J (2008) The moral hazard of humanitarian
intervention: Lessons from the Balkans. International Studies Quarterly 51(1): 49–80.
Lasley, Trace & Clayton Thyne (2015) Secession, legitimacy,
and the use of child soldiers. Conflict Management and
Peace Science 32(3): 289–308.
Loyle, Cyanne (2020) Rebel justice during armed conflict.
Journal of Conflict Resolution. (https://doi.org/10.1177/
0022002720939299).
Lyons, Terrence (2016) From victorious rebels to strong
authoritarian parties: Prospects for post-war democratization. Democratization 23(6): 1026–1041.
Malejacq, Romain (2017) From rebel to quasi-state: Governance, diplomacy and legitimacy in the midst of Afghanistan’s wars (1979–2001). Small Wars & Insurgencies 28(4–
5): 867–886.
Mampilly, Zachariah Cherian (2011) Rebel Rulers: Insurgent
Governance and Civilian Life During War. Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press.
Maoz, Zeev & Belgin San-Akca (2012) Rivalry and state support of non-state armed groups (NAGs), 1946–2001.
International Studies Quarterly 56(4): 720–734.
Marshall, Monty G; Keith Jaggers & Ted Robert Gurr (2011)
Polity IV project: Political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2010. Dataset users’ manual. Center for Systemic Peace.
Olson, Mancur (1993) Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review 87(3): 567–576.
Podder, Sukanya (2014) Mainstreaming the non-state in
bottom-up state-building: Linkages between rebel governance and post-conflict legitimacy. Conflict, Security &
Development 14(2): 213–243.
Regan, Patrick (2002) Civil Wars and Foreign Powers: Outside
Intervention in Intrastate Conflict. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
Reno, William (2011) Warfare in Independent Africa. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
Robinson, Eri; Daniel Egel, Patrick Johnston, Sean Mann,
Alexander Rothenberg & David Stebbins (2017) When the
Islamic State Comes to Town: The Economic Impact of Islamic
State Governance in Iraq and Syria. Santa Monica, CA:
RAND.
Ruggeri, Andrea; Han Dorussen & Theodora-Ismene Gizelis (2017) Winning the peace locally: UN peacekeeping
and local conflict. International Organization 71(1):
163–185.
Saleh, Yassin Al-Haj (2017) The Impossible Revolution: Making
Sense of the Syrian Tragedy. Chicago, IL: Haymarket.
808
Salehyan, Idean (2009) Rebels without Borders: Transnational
Insurgencies in World Politics. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Salehyan, Idean; Kristian Skrede Gleditsch & David E Cunningham (2011) Explaining external support for insurgent
groups. International Organization 65(4): 709–744.
Salehyan, Idean; David Siroky & Reed M Wood (2014) External rebel sponsorship and civilian abuse: A principal–agent
analysis of wartime atrocities. International Organization
68(3): 633–661.
San-Akca, Belgin (2015) Dangerous Companions: Cooperation
between States and Nonstate Armed Groups (NAGs). v.04/
2015 (retrieved from nonstatearmedgroups.ku.edu.tr).
San-Akca, Belgin (2016) States in Disguise: Causes of State
Support for Rebel Groups. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Sawyer, Katherine; Kathleen Gallagher Cunningham & William Reed (2017) The role of external support in civil war
termination. Journal of Conflict Resolution 61(6):
1174–1202.
Stanton, Jessica (2016) Violence and Restraint in Civil War:
Civilian Targeting in the Shadow of International Law. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
Stewart, Megan A (2018) Civil war as state-making: Strategic
governance in civil war. International Organization 72(1):
205–226.
Stewart, Megan A (2019) Rebel governance: Military boon or
military bust? Conflict Management and Peace Science 37(1):
16–38.
Stewart, Megan A & Yu-Ming Liou (2017) Do good borders
make good rebels? Territorial control and civilian casualties.
Journal of Politics 79(1): 284–301.
Stuart, Elizabeth A (2010) Matching methods for causal inference: A review and a look forward. Statistical Science 25(1):
1–21.
Sullivan, Patricia (2012) Who Wins? Predicting Strategic Success
and Failure in Armed Conflict. New York: Oxford University Press.
Sullivan, Patricia L & Johannes Karreth (2015) The conditional impact of military intervention on internal armed
conflict outcomes. Conflict Management and Peace Science
32(3): 269–288.
Sullivan, Patricia L & Johannes Karreth (2019) Strategies and
tactics in armed conflict: How governments and foreign
interveners respond to insurgent threats. Journal of Conflict
Resolution 63(9): 2207–2232.
Taylor, John G (1999) East Timor: The Price of Freedom. New
York: Zed.
journal of PEACE RESEARCH 58(4)
Themnér, Lotta & Peter Wallensteen (2014) Armed Conflicts, 1946–2013. Journal of Peace Research 51(4):
541–554.
Tilly, Charles (1990) Coercion, Capital, and European States,
AD 990–1990. Cambridge: Basil Blackwell.
Toft, Monica Duffy & Yuri M Zhukov (2015) Islamists and
nationalists: Rebel motivation and counterinsurgency in
Russia’s North Caucus. American Political Science Review
109(2): 222–238.
Van Dijk, Cornelius (1981) Rebellion Under the Banner of
Islam: The Darul Islam in Indonesia (Verhandelingen Van
Het Koninklijk Instituut Voor Taal-, Land- en
Volken-Kunde, number 94). The Hague: Martinus
Nijhoff.
Weinstein, Jeremy M (2005) Autonomous Recovery and International Intervention in Comparative Perspective. Washington, DC: Center for Global Development.
Weinstein, Jeremy M (2007) Inside Rebellion: The Politics of
Insurgent Violence. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Wickham-Crowley, Timothy P (1993) Guerrillas and Revolutions in Latin America: A Comparative Study of Insurgents
and Regimes since 1956. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Wood, Elisabeth Jean (2003) Insurgent Collective Action and
Civil War in El Salvador. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Wood, Reed M (2010) Rebel capability and strategic violence
against civilians. Journal of Peace Research 47(5): 601–614.
Wood, Reed M (2014) Opportunities to kill or incentives for
restraint? Rebel capabilities, the origins of support, and
civilian victimization in civil war. Conflict Management and
Peace Science 31(5): 461–480.
Wood, Reed M; Jacob D Kathman & Stephen E Gent (2012)
Armed intervention and civilian victimization in intrastate
conflicts. Journal of Peace Research 49(5): 647–660.
REYKO HUANG, PhD in Political Science (Columbia
University, 2012); Associate Professor, Texas A&M
University (2012– ); primary interests: rebel governance,
rebel diplomacy, and rebel social networks.
PATRICIA L SULLIVAN, PhD in Political Science
(University of California, Davis, 2004); Associate Professor,
University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill (2011– ) and
Director, Triangle Institute for Security Studies (2020– );
current interests: military intervention, military aid, and
human security.