Chapter 10
Development of Water Rights
in Indonesia
Suharto Sarwan, Tjoek Walujo Subijanto, and Charles Rodgers
— One objective of Indonesia’s 2004 Water Law is to establish a uniform
system of water use rights.The law distinguishes between water usage for
basic needs and noncommercial purposes, including domestic uses and
small-scale “people’s” agriculture; and exploitation, including industrial,
municipal, hydropower, and commercial agriculture. The former uses are
entitlements requiring no formal permit, and the latter require formal
licensing for specific uses of water. This chapter outlines the legal and
conceptual framework for water use rights in Indonesia; describes key
aspects of rights enacted in the new water law, including differences
between usage and exploitation rights and prohibition of transfers of water
use rights; presents an illustrative example of water allocation management in the Brantas Basin; and then looks at water use rights as property
rights and human rights.
R
ecent social and economic developments in Indonesia have induced a paradigm shift in water resources management. Historically regarded as a social
good, water has been transformed into an economic good with a social and
environmental function. These developments have also affected the roles and
management strategies of the law concerning water: from provider toward enabler,
from centralized toward decentralized authority, from single purpose toward a
multisector approach, and from narrow toward broader stakeholder participation
(DGWR 2003).
238
SUHARTO SARWAN, TJOEK WALUJO SUBIJANTO, AND CHARLES RODGERS
Table 10.1 Indonesian total availability of surface water and groundwater
Island(s)
Java
Lesser Sunda Islands
Sulawesi
Sumatra
Borneo
Mollucas + Papua
Indonesia
Area
(million km2 )
Population
(million)
Water
potential
(MCM/yr)
0.133
0.071
0.186
0.475
0.536
0.493
1.894
121.4
11.1
15.0
43.3
11.3
4.2
206.3
187,000
60,000
247,000
738,000
1,008,000
981,000
3,221,000
Water potential
Water
demand
(MCM/yr )
Per km2
(MCM/yr)
Per capita
(1,000 m3/yr)
83,378
13,827
25,555
25,298
8,204
589
156,850
1.411
0.839
1.327
1.553
1.881
1.991
1.700
1.54
5.40
16.53
17.04
88.96
232.93
15.62
Source: Machbub (2000); WRI (2003).
Adequacy of water availability, both in quantity and in quality, greatly influences many aspects of social well-being and prosperity, including health, food security, industrial development, and environmental sustainability. Industrialization
and population growth in Indonesia have caused significant impacts, and place
increasing pressure on available water resources, which leads to further competition
between beneficiaries and between uses. Industrialization and population growth
have also caused declines in water quality and decreases in dependable flow as a result
of the degradation of catchment areas. These pressures are responsible for a relative
decrease in water availability over time, leading ultimately to water scarcity.
Indonesia is a tropical archipelago of more than 17,500 islands, with a total
land area of 19.2 million square kilometers. Rainfall variability reflects the extreme
geographical diversity, which is further reflected in surface and groundwater potentials (LRI 1990; WRI 2003). Table 10.1 summarizes statistics on Indonesia’s water
resources situation. World average water availability is close to 7,600 cubic meters
per capita; Asia has the smallest continental average at 4,000. Indonesia as a whole
has 15,600 cubic meters per person but this masks great differences within the
archipelago (Machbub 2000; WRI 2003). Java, which contains 121 million of Indonesia’s 206 million inhabitants, has the lowest availability, 1,500 cubic meters
per capita, extremely low relative to West Papua and the Mollucas at 233,000.
The extent of water scarcity in Indonesia can be appreciated by considering
the ratio of potential water availability to demand. It is predicted that by the year
2015, on some islands, this ratio will be less than one during many periods. A
study conducted by the Ministry of Public Works and the Ministry of Forestry
in 1995 identified a number of critical basins, including Cisedane, Ciliwung,
Citarum, Cimanuk, Citanduy, Jratunseluna, Bengawan Solo, and Brantas. In these
DEVELOPMENT OF WATER RIGHTS IN INDONESIA
239
basins, the water use potential index, the ratio of demand to dependable flow generally equals or exceeds 0.5.
Water resources are a national resource that must be managed wisely and
sustainably to secure the greatest benefit for the welfare of existing and future generations. However, water scarcity has the potential to create conflict among beneficiaries and between communities of users. Therefore, sustainable water management
is considered a strategic task, essential in sustaining national development and
requiring a national commitment. In the past, water resource development strategies tended to emphasize the supply side. Water was treated as a free good, and
stakeholder participation was quite limited. In many basins, the current strategy
for the development and management of water resources is now focusing on the
demand side. To achieve efficient water allocation, it is understood that it is now
necessary to establish a water use rights system.
Water allocation is perhaps the most important element of water resources
management. Allocation must be implemented to achieve national objectives, as
guided by clear principles of rights and priorities, of which the water use rights
system is of central importance. Effective management policies require a system for
water allocation and water rights administration that recognizes the legitimate
private uses of a public resource. As demand increases relative to an essentially
fixed, limited supply, leading to intersectoral competition, public regulation based
on recognized water rights will be required to achieve societal goals.
In light of a series of factors including the natural characteristics of water;
increasing demand; the paradigm shift from water as a social good to water as
an economic good with social function; and the tide of opinion within the water
resources community, a consensus has emerged among stakeholders and policymakers that the substance of water rights in Indonesia must be clarified. Determination of water rights in this context includes rights, duties, impacts on allocation,
affected parties, jurisdiction (boundary), and responsibilities to the environment.
The process of developing a water rights system was included in the Water Resources
Reform Program that began in 1999.
In this chapter, we first present the legal and conceptual framework for water
resources management in Indonesia. We next discuss water rights reform as part
of Indonesia’s ambitious water sector reform agenda, including some key aspects
of the 2004 Water Law, brief descriptions of the planned program of pilot implementation, and anticipated outcomes of water rights reform. A description of the
Brantas Basin in East Java illustrates the context of water allocation reform. We
then discuss some aspects of water use rights in Indonesia as property rights and
human rights.
240
SUHARTO SARWAN, TJOEK WALUJO SUBIJANTO, AND CHARLES RODGERS
Legal and Conceptual Framework for Water Rights
Legal Framework for Water Management
The Constitution of 1945 established the fundamental principles of water resources
management in Indonesia. Article 33 of the constitution states that the earth,
water, and any wealth therein are governed by the state and utilized as far as possible for the welfare of the people. The basic national law governing water resources
management has been Law No. 11 of 1974 on Water Resources, supported by
Government Regulation No. 22 of 1982 on Water Resources Management, Government Regulation No. 23 of 1982 on Irrigation and Drainage, and the Basic Agrarian Law No. 5 of 1960. According to Law No. 11 (1974) article 5 paragraph (1),
intersectoral water uses were to be coordinated by the minister responsible for water
resources. Government Regulation No. 22 of 1982 provided detail on the basis for
management at the river basin level, including planning and coordination activities.
A 1989 Decree of the Minister of Public Works on the Determination of 90
River Territories in Indonesia divided Indonesia into 90 river territories (Wilayah
Sungai) that in turn encompass 5,590 river basins. Most river basins are small,
about 87 percent cover less than 500 square kilometers (Amron 1998). River
basins in Indonesia, and particularly in Java, are usually short, steep, and rainfed,
with 94 percent of rivers less than 50 kilometers long. Only 15 rivers are longer
than 400 kilometers. According to the 1989 decree, and a related 1990 Decree on
Management of Water Resources in River Territories, regional governments manage
72 river basins, with responsibilities delegated under the concept of comanagement.
Fifteen river basins are managed directly by the Minister of Public Works, because
their boundaries cross provincial boundaries. Public corporations currently manage
three basins: Jasa Tirta I (PJT-I) manages the Brantas river basin in East Java and
the Bengawan Solo river basin in East and Central Java, and Jasa Tirta II (PJT-II)
manages the Citarum river basin in West Java. Some other river basins on Java,
Sulawesi, and Sumatra have already begun developing public river basin management institutions. Under the current reform agenda, new public corporations or
branches of Jasa Tirta I will manage the basins of Jratunseluna, Serayu-Bogowonto,
and Jeneberang.
Water distribution within each basin is supposed to be based on a water allocation plan. The plan should be agreed on by the representatives of the water users
and the water manager in a coordination forum called the Water Resources Management Committee, or Panitia Tata Pengaturan Air for the provincial level and
Panitia Pelaksana Tata Pengaturan Air for the basin level.
The kernel of Indonesian water use rights is found in the Basic Constitution
of 1945, stipulating that water resources, although governed by the state, must be
DEVELOPMENT OF WATER RIGHTS IN INDONESIA
241
utilized for the welfare of the people. Water use rights per se were first mentioned in
the Basic Agrarian Law No. 5/1960. Water was identified as a gift of the Almighty
and everyone has a right to its use, although certain uses require permission and
others do not. The 1974 Water Law required corporations, associations, and individuals to obtain government approval (a license) and assigned the primary responsibility to the central and local governments to ensure that water and water
resources are used beneficially. The water law also required that water allocation be
subject to established priorities.
Government Regulation No. 22/1982 established the principles and the basis
for water management. In water management regulations, the principles of public
utility, harmony, and conservation should be applied. A water right was interpreted
as water use right. Moreover, the regulation stated that everyone has a right to use
water for their basic needs in daily life, for domestic purposes, and for domestic
livestock. This government regulation established the basis for water use permits,
but did not address the process by which water rights are formally established.
Indonesia has had a water licensing system applied to some specific economic
uses, including urban water supply, hydropower, industry, mining, and commercial
agriculture. Licensing was intended primarily as a strategic planning instrument, a
guide to the allocation of water use for the purposes of meeting development goals,
as distinct from short-term operational decisionmaking. In contrast to commercial
uses, users could obtain water for domestic, household, and other basic, noncommercial uses without prior permission from the designated authority, subject
to certain limitations. The earlier licensing was applied selectively to help regulate
water use to meet development goals, but this partial system fell short of fulfilling the
basic principles of fair and effective water allocation. To illustrate, during drought,
water supplied for irrigation and river maintenance flow, which were not governed
by licenses, might be reduced in order to secure the required quantities of water for
those other beneficiaries who did have licenses to use the water.
Conceptual Principles
Ideally, in terms of economic theory, a structure of property rights in water that
would facilitate the efficient allocation of water should include several characteristics.
Universality means that all water resources are subject to some claim status, and property rights claims to water resources, including the nature and contents of these
rights, are clearly identified, consistently applied, and universally respected. With
exclusivity, all benefits and costs (setting aside externalities) arising from the rights
are exclusively owned; and exclusively borne, respectively, by the rights-holder.
Transferability allows specific components of the right to be transferred through
freely negotiated, legally transparent transactions. Enforceability secures all rights
242
SUHARTO SARWAN, TJOEK WALUJO SUBIJANTO, AND CHARLES RODGERS
from unlawful takeover or violation, via a well-defined process of grievances and
remedies.
In establishing the structure of water rights, a clear justification must be provided for the initial distribution of claims. On this matter, there is no universal
consensus along either historical or ethical lines. Muslim water law establishes a
fundamental right of human access to water, as a gift from God, and imposes an
equally fundamental duty to conserve, and to share based on priority of need
(chafa: the right of thirst) beginning with water for domestic uses, followed by
water for animals, then water for irrigation. Water is viewed, together with pasture
and fire (fuel) as a common entitlement (waqf, usufruct or collective property) (see
Faruqui, Biswas, and Bino 2001).
Other systems of water rights based on notions of community or common
property are also prevalent in Indonesia. An often-cited example of a communitybased water rights system in Indonesia is the Balinese subak (e.g., see Sutawan 2000).
Such common property water rights systems are often characterized by relatively
clear boundaries and flexible rules. However, this flexibility, potentially valuable
during changing or uncertain conditions, is often difficult to realize through formal
or statutory law.
Broadly speaking, the evolved legal structures of property rights in water in the
West tend to follow either riparian doctrine, appropriation doctrine, or some combination. Under the riparian doctrine, the landowners have the right to divert (but
typically not to store) a portion of the natural flow of water through or adjacent to
their land, for reasonable and beneficial use. Under an appropriation doctrine, a
person may acquire a right to divert, store, and use water simply by being the first
to develop a previously unallocated source of water. In some places, this right is
sometimes not tied to land ownership, and may be transferred, even outside of the
watershed. In contemporary Indonesian water resources management systems, many
farmers (and others) typically share water that is often stored at and delivered from
remote locations via public infrastructure, and use it for a wide variety of purposes.
Adoption of undiluted versions of either riparian or prior appropriation-type doctrines is neither practical nor appropriate, particularly when fairness and efficiency
are paramount objectives. Indonesian farmers, who traditionally were more likely
to use water for basic needs and subsistence farming than for commercial purposes,
typically receive water allocations that reflect the outcome of discussion and agreement with others. This suggests that allocation and issuance of water rights must
apply principles of justice and fairness. Ideally, the water right will guarantee the
rights-holder access to water of the proper volume and at the proper time, and as
appropriate to their investment.
DEVELOPMENT OF WATER RIGHTS IN INDONESIA
243
There are three basic principles guiding Indonesia’s efforts to implement water
use rights. These are general use, efficiency, and sustainable supply. General use refers
to an understanding that a clear, complete, and detailed water right arrangement
will secure the right of parties to use the water as appropriate to their basic needs,
received on time in sufficient quantity. Efficiency refers to an understanding that
a clear, complete, and detailed water right arrangement will create an obligation of
the water user to use the water (1) for beneficial purposes; (2) as efficiently as possible; (3) without endangering the environment, the water resources quantity and
quality; and (4) without unnecessarily impairing or disturbing other users’ ability
to use water. A sustainable supply refers to an understanding that a clear, complete,
and detailed water right arrangement will reflect conditions specific to each basin
and locality in the resulting water allocation system, including both long-term and
real-time aspects of water allocation, as well as the national social and economic
perspective on water resources.
Reforming the Indonesian Water Rights System
The Government of Indonesia is currently undertaking a program of broad reform
of water resources policy to improve the national institutional framework for water
resources development and management; the organizational and financial framework for river basin management; regional water quality management, regulatory
institutions, and implementation; and national irrigation management policy, institutions, and regulations (DGWR 2003). Water rights play an important role in
these reforms. An essential first phase of this process is the revision of the enabling
legal framework for water resources management.
To secure equitable and efficient water allocation, the government will establish
a national framework for an enforceable water rights system for surface and groundwater. Indicators of progress toward this goal are issuance of a new Government
Regulation for Water Rights and issuance of guidelines for the revised provincial
water licensing regulations and allocation of water use rights. Water rights for irrigation schemes will be explicitly addressed, and prevailing customary water right
concepts will be considered. The water user rights system will be supported by
appropriate national regulations as well as a uniform provincial framework of water
licensing for abstraction and discharges that covers all water sectors.
A formal water use rights system is also essential in order to document and to
protect the historical claims of existing water users within a basin, as well as to accommodate new users. Three broad roles emerge for water use rights. They should
enable the government to manage the nation’s water resources more effectively and
244
SUHARTO SARWAN, TJOEK WALUJO SUBIJANTO, AND CHARLES RODGERS
efficiently. Water use rights provide the community, and individuals within the
community, a degree of certainty concerning the availability of the water resource,
so that they can invest with confidence. Rights serve as a basis for resource accounting, which is necessary both for long-term planning and for real-time water allocation decisionmaking in the basin. A formal water use rights system is currently
intended as a tool for effective basin-wide bulk water allocation at all times and,
in particular, during times of water scarcity, especially in the dry season.
A water use rights system is a formal procedure to confer, from public ownership as managed by the government to the user, the right to use surface or groundwater in a particular basin or location. It carries out specific policy objectives of the
government with regard to water use. In this process, historical water diversion and
use are documented, users and uses are identified, water use is quantified, water
available for allocation is determined (quantified), and the water that has been allocated is monitored with respect to its use(s). When the system is in place, clear legal
and administrative procedures establish the priorities of respective rights, providing
for transparent water allocation and water administration. The system also helps
identify those users and uses that would be affected by proposed actions or activities that would alter or modify the quantity and quality of the water resources in
the basin.
Usage and Commercial Rights in the 2004 Water Law
In February 2004, a new National Water Law, intended to replace Law No. 11 of
1974 on Water Resources, was passed by the Indonesian House of Representatives.
The law defines a water use right as “the right to get and use or exploit water for
various purposes.” The law then defines more specific categories of use rights, Hak
Guna Pakai Air (usage for basic needs and noncommercial uses) and Hak Guna
Usaha Air (commercial exploitation).
Usage rights are “acquired without permit to fulfill daily basic needs for individuals and people’s agriculture located in irrigation systems.” Daily basic needs
encompass what is required “to achieve healthy, clean and productive life” and
include water used in religious services, drinking, cooking, bathing, and washing.
Irrigated agriculture requires a permit if it involves changing the condition of the
water resource, takes large volumes of water, or occurs outside of existing irrigation
systems. The Elucidation to the water law states that permits are required if water
use exceeds 2 liters per second per household head, and that pumping requires a
permit even if for people’s agriculture.
Throughout much of Java, 2 liters per second of continuous flow would service
an irrigated area of one hectare or more, assuming wet transplanted paddy as is commonly grown during the first dry season. A single volumetric standard may not be
DEVELOPMENT OF WATER RIGHTS IN INDONESIA
245
appropriate for all regions, as conditions governing evapotranspiration and soil percolation vary extensively throughout the archipelago. Although this is certainly the
case, it is clearly possible to regionalize this standard based on soils and climatic data.
Moreover, a rule based on flow volume, as distinct from cultivated area, appears
preferable for many reasons, not the least of which is the incentive it provides for
water conservation. In establishing this threshold, the government has taken an
important step toward protecting smallholder and subsistence agriculturalists’ priority right of access to irrigation water.
Commercial rights can be granted to individuals or corporations via permit,
and are provisional rights to exploit water resources for specified commercial purposes. These purposes include, among others, electric power generation, municipal
water supply, industrial production, and agribusiness. Licenses are highly restrictive
with respect to the type of use permitted—they are not broad volumetric commercial abstraction licenses.
As in the previous water law, water rights of traditional legal communities are
to be accepted, as long as they are not in conflict with national interests, laws, and
regulations, and as long as they actually continue to exist. The new law also states
that customary rights must have been confirmed by regional government regulations. The means of resolving conflicts between traditional users and/or laws and
“national interests and laws and regulations” are not made clear, however, and this
suggests an interesting arena in which many issues raised in the new water law may
be tested.
Subsequent government regulations will specify explicit details of the implementation of water use rights, which may include the duration of rights, conditions for terminating rights, and procedures for dealing with droughts or other
extreme situations.
Prohibition of Transfers
The question as to whether or not water user rights as specified in the new National
Water Law could be transferable generated considerable debate. In the course of
preparing the reform program, a right to transfer water under the framework of
established use rights was envisioned. This would have enabled the transfer of water
use rights from the original permit holder to a third party on the basis of a legitimate agreement that could be endorsed by responsible authorities. A transfer of a
water use right might apply to all, or to only a part of the original owner’s water use
rights. In case of a temporary transfer, the formal “splitting” of the water use right
would not be necessary. Transfers of water rights might have occurred through private trading, or through regulated transactions established by agreement between
water users in which the appropriate government authority would play a central role.
246
SUHARTO SARWAN, TJOEK WALUJO SUBIJANTO, AND CHARLES RODGERS
There was concern that the permissibility of water use rights transfer would
introduce a potential for abuse. A negative impact of such arrangements could
occur in the event that a water right were (temporarily) transferred to, and subsequently not relinquished by a pengusaha kuat (literally “strong company”) resulting
in the original right holder (presumably less powerful) being deprived of their right
to water.
In the Water Law passed by the Parliament in February 2004, no allowance is
made for the transfer of water use rights. The Law states “Water utilization right . . .
cannot be leased out or transferred, partially or wholly.” The Elucidation adds: “If
water utilization right is not used by the holder of water utilization right, Government or regional government can revoke the related water utilization right.” The law
prohibits transfers and specifies penalties, fines, and imprisonment for violators.
This would appear to settle the issue for the time being, at least with respect to
private transactions. Key to understanding the proscription on water markets is the
fact that under the new law, water use rights and commercial licenses are purposespecific. In Western water law, rights typically adhere either to individuals (doctrine
of appropriation) or to land (riparian doctrine), each framework providing a basis
for transfers as private transactions. According to the new Indonesian Water Law,
however, a farmer (irrigator) is not free to transfer his water use right, for example,
to an industry, since his right was derived from the use of the water in irrigation
and not from his ownership of the land, riparian or otherwise.
If water rights were transferable, then a clear water rights arrangement could
improve the efficiency of water resources allocation by directly facilitating water
right transfers. An example is the transfer of water out of irrigation to industrial
and domestic uses. A transferable water right would provide farmers with an incentive to use water more efficiently, if the water saved could be transferred (sold or
leased). It would provide one more alternative solution to the problem of increasing water scarcity, at a time when the construction of new dams is increasingly
expensive and attended by many serious problems including resettlement and land
compensation. Within the framework of the new water law, arrangements by
which government reallocates water, with compensation for those whose rights are
reduced (e.g., a functional equivalent of water banking, or coordinated agreements
for retirement of an existing right and issuance of a new right) might be developed,
but processes for reallocation are not explicitly specified.
Preliminary Implementation of Water Use Rights
The Government of Indonesia intends to conduct an exploratory, pilot program
introducing water use rights to specific regions. The pilot program will be implemented in three locations, the Citarum River Basin in West Java, the Jratunseluna
DEVELOPMENT OF WATER RIGHTS IN INDONESIA
247
River Basin in Central Java, and the Brantas River Basin in East Java. These river
basins have been chosen because their water resources have been extensively developed over long periods, each contains various categories of water users, and each
possesses the potential for intersectoral conflict. The decision to conduct a pilot
implementation program is motivated by the fact that the Government of Indonesia’s experience in implementing water use rights is limited to commercial licensing, so the information gathered during these trial programs will be invaluable in
improving the legal framework for water use rights.
The preliminary programs will focus on groups that use water primarily for
commercial and irrigation purposes. The number and composition of these groups
will be chosen to be representative, so that results from pilot programs can be generalized to regions outside the target basins. The experience gained through the
pilot basin programs will be used to strengthen implementation of water use rights.
This should be the starting point for Indonesia to adopt a uniform licensing system
procedure within the framework of a national water use rights system. In consideration of the macrocharacteristics of water availability, of increasing demand due to
growing population, and the increasing variety of competing water uses, and of
forces of economic globalization and the liberalization of trade, all of which impact
on the management of water resources, the rapid implementation of effective water
use rights in Indonesia is a high priority.
Anticipated Outcomes from Water Use Rights Reforms
The intended outcomes include assignment of rights, improvements in water use
security and efficiency, and increases in the level of responsibility of water users.
The implementation of water use rights could be evaluated as successful on the basis
of consistency of water rights implementation and all related laws and regulations
at all stages, and improved allocation and productive efficiency achieved through
the implementation of water use rights.
The creation of water use rights creates a legal channel by which rights-holders
can fulfill all basic needs with respect to water, while fulfilling all responsibilities
corresponding with these rights. This could help avoid some conflicts related to
water use, since each rights-holder will acquire an understanding of both the extent
and limits to their rights. In the process, the government will have a control instrument for determining policies and decisions. Water rights-holders who understand
their rights should also understand the demarcation of their rights, so that they will
make efficient use of water, making more water available for use by others in support of their rights and interests.
Water availability depends on many other elements beyond the structure of
rights, such as the presence of reservoirs, other water resources infrastructure, and
248
SUHARTO SARWAN, TJOEK WALUJO SUBIJANTO, AND CHARLES RODGERS
the requirements of the environment. Water rights-holders, while exercising their
rights, should also assume greater responsibilities for safeguarding and protecting
the water resources system to which they are connected in order to sustain the
integrity of the system. If rights-holders fail to meet these duties, they will be subject to claims by any other users harmed by their action.
Case Study in the Brantas River Basin
The Brantas River Basin is located in the Province of East Java. The watershed covers
11,800 square kilometers and the main channel stretches 320 kilometers from its
source on Mount Arjuna to New Lengkong, where it branches into two rivers,
Surabaya River and Porong River, each of which discharges into the Madura Strait.
Along its main stem, many tributaries join the Brantas, including the Lesti,
Ngrowo, Konto, and Widas rivers. Figure 10.1 depicts the Brantas Basin, including important water resources management features.
Average precipitation in the basin is close to 2,000 millimeters/year, about 80
percent of which occurs during the rainy season from December to May. Annual
surface discharge is around 12,000 million cubic meters (MCM) on average. About
3,000 MCM is subject to regulation by storage dams, a quantity constrained primarily by the limited surface storage, which currently totals only 297 MCM.
Beginning in 1961, the Brantas River Basin Development Project carried out
river basin development, under the authority of the Directorate General of Water
Resources Development. In that year, the first Master Plan was established, with
primary emphasis on flood control. Large reservoirs constructed in the upper
reaches for flood control also provided water supply for irrigation and hydropower
generation.
In 1973, the Master Plan was reviewed and Master Plan II prepared, with a
primary orientation toward supplying water for irrigation, in line with government
policy that emphasized self-sufficiency in rice production. During this period,
some additional reservoirs and barrages were built. Work on flood control projects
continued.
Having achieved relative success with rice production, the government then
turned to strengthening the industrial sector in the 1980s. Consequently, the river
basin development plan was reviewed again in 1985. Master Plan III emerged with
the main purpose of supplying water for industry and municipalities. The need was
later felt to review the master plan, to improve water resources conservation and management. The Master Plan IV, reflecting these priorities, was completed in 1998.
The benefits of development under the Master Plans can be summarized as
follows:
DEVELOPMENT OF WATER RIGHTS IN INDONESIA
249
• flood control for events up to a 50-year return period;
• water supply for 83,000 hectares of paddy fields that directly abstract water
from Brantas main stem (out of a total 345,000 hectares of irrigated area
within the basin) supplying up to 2,500 million cubic meters of irrigation
water per year;
• energy production of about 1,000 million kilowatt-hours per year;
• bulk water supply for industries and municipal drinking water of about
380 MCM/year;
• maintenance flow of 204 MCM/year; and
• flows supporting fisheries of 41 MCM/year (PJT-I 2002).
During preparation of the fourth Master Plan, it was anticipated that the Brantas
River Basin would face diverse problems due to population growth and industrial
development. Water demand is projected to increase significantly, while the supply
will remain limited. Previous assessments of water balance in the growing urban
areas of Gresik, Bangkalan, Mojokerto, Surabaya, and Sidoarjo highlighted the
importance of developing new sources of surface water (such as the proposed Genteng, Kedungwarak, and Beng dams) to cope with the growing demand. Although
these dams are classified as “promising” projects based on benefit-cost analysis, the
unit water costs are still considered too expensive given current abilities to recover
costs. The costs for the proposed Genteng, Kedungwarak, and Beng dams were
1,119; 1,090; and 889 Rp/cubic meter (US$1 = 11,300 Rp in June 2001), respectively: by comparison, the unit water cost of Wonorejo Dam (2001) was only
520 Rp/cubic meter (JICA 1998:V-32). These projects (or their equivalent) will
almost certainly be required in the near future.
However, water supply and demand projections within the Brantas to the year
2020 under a range of assumptions concerning supply indicate that supply augmentation alone will not provide a comprehensive solution to the pending water
shortage. Demand management therefore will also be important. Supply augmentation together with improvements in irrigation efficiency, water reuse, and recycling
are currently anticipated to allow the basin to accommodate growing urban demand
up to the year 2020. Based on these projections and assumptions, implementation
of water use rights, and possibly water right transfers, might make an important
contribution toward coping with future water deficits.
Figure 10.1 The Brantas Basin
LOCATION MAP
Y
Kalimantan
E
23
F
Z
4
U
C
B
5
9
ra
26
8
2
G
H
7
6
Str
ait
11
LEGEND
Mt. Kelud
W
X
13
Boundary of
catchment area for
Brantas River Basin
Mt. Kawi
12
Railway
T
S
J
19
K
14
15
17
Indo Project Area
n esia
n Oc
ean
Mt.Arjuno
Mt.Wilis
L
Surabaya
U
10
I
16
Java
Sea
Jakarta
25
A
3
27
du
Ma
D
1
Sumatra
24
18
M
R
21
Source: Based on map provided by Jasa Tirta I Public Corporation.
Mt. Semeru
23
22
20
N
Indonesian Ocean
Dam site
O
Q
P
Completed projects
1. Bening Dam
2. Glatik Dam
3.Widas irrigation 3200 HA
4. Mentupus rubber dam
5. Jatimlerek rubber dam
6.Warujayeng irrigation area
7. Middle Reach River improvement
8. Paparpeterongan irrigation area
9.Turi Tunggorono irrigation area
10. Mrican Barrage
11. Selorejo multipurpose dam
12. Mt. Kelud debris control
13.Tulungagung Gate
14. Lodoyo Tulungagung irrigation area
15. Parit Agung Canal
16. South Tulungagung Tunnel
17. Gulungagung Hepp
18. Lodoyo Aftgerbay
19.Wlingi multipurpose dam
20. Sutami multipurpose dam
21. Lahor Dam
22. Sengguruh Dam
23. Kepanjen Dam
24. Brantas Delta irrigation area
25. New Lengkong Dam
26. Kaliporong River improvement
27. Karangpilang Treatments Work
Proposed projects
A.Widas extension area 3200 HA
B. Beng Dam
C. Kedungwarak Dam
D. Semantok Dam
E. Beng irrigation area 3200 HA
F. Gottan Losare irrigation area 4300 HA
G.Widas South irrigation area 5500 HA
H. Kuncir Dam
I. Babadan Dam
J.Wonorejo irrigation area
K.Trenggalek irrigation area
L.Tugu Dam
M. Flood diversion
N. Lestileft irrigation area 2300 HA
O. Lesti Dam
P. Genteng Dam
Q. Upper West watershed management
R. Sutami multipurpose dam
S. Lumbangsari Dam
T. Upper Brantas watershed management
U. Umbulan Spring
Under-construction projects
W. Segawe Weir
X.Wonorejo Dam
Y. Suragaya Urban Development Project
Z. Karangpilang Treatments Work
252
SUHARTO SARWAN, TJOEK WALUJO SUBIJANTO, AND CHARLES RODGERS
Industrial water recycling, such as recirculation of cooling water, can be a major
source of water savings. Domestic water use can be made more efficient by steps
ranging from repairing leaks in municipal systems to installing low-flow showerheads. Efficiency in irrigation water use can be enhanced by technologies including
drip irrigation and microsprinklers; management changes such as the adoption of
demand-based irrigation scheduling systems and conjunctive use of surface and
groundwater; and institutional improvements including the creation of effective
water users’ associations.
Water allocation in the Brantas Basin is based on a water allocation plan,
which is discussed and agreed on by representatives of various categories of water
users, as well as by Jasa Tirta I Public Corporation (PJT-I), in a coordinated forum
called the Provincial Water Resources Management Committee. The water allocation system currently practiced in the Brantas Basin is based on decrees issued
by the governor of East Java. As described earlier, the water licensing is a form of
acknowledging water use rights as well as an instrument for regulating use. The
content of the water licensing system can be summarized as follows:
1. All water users shall have a license from the governor of East Java.
2. PJT-I (the river basin authority) will guarantee the supply of water, to the
extent feasible considering available discharge.
3. The license will be issued following issuance of technical recommendations
from PJT-I, a recommendation from chief of regency as chief of the Irrigation
Committee and consideration from the Consideration Group on Surface
Water Licensing.
4. Other relevant rules and regulations are fulfilled.
5. The beneficiaries shall pay a fee for operation and maintenance of water
resources infrastructure.
Regulation of the implementation of licenses is the responsibility of the agencies
involved, including the East Java Provincial Government, Provincial Water Resources Services, PJT-I, and others. Control over the implementation of licenses is
by designated agencies, which in the Brantas Basin include the Government of East
Java, Water Resources Services, and PJT-I.
Modeling Transferable Rights
To illustrate the potential of trading of licensed water to improve the economic
productivity of water resources, we present some results from modeling studies
DEVELOPMENT OF WATER RIGHTS IN INDONESIA
253
Figure 10.2 Allocation scenarios with and without transfers
Basin net profit (Bn. IDR)
840
830
820
810
800
790
780
770
760
750
740
Baseline
WR-NT
WR-B
Rights Scenario
WR-M
Source: Rodgers and Zaafrano 2002.
recently conducted in the Brantas Basin, East Java. An integrated economic-hydrologic basin simulation model (Rodgers and Zaafrano 2002) was used to compare
four water rights scenarios.
The first, economically idealized, scenario allocated water purely according
to its highest economic return, without regard to water use rights and subject only
to hydrologic and infrastructure constraints and minimum supply constraints for
domestic uses and environmental flows. In the second scenario (WR-NT), with
water rights and no trading, each irrigation system was assigned a volumetric right,
by period, which corresponded to efficient cultivation along historical cropping
patterns. In this scenario, any water not used productively at a site is simply forfeited, and flows downstream. In the third scenario (WR-B), irrigation systems could
either buy additional water from or sell unused water to the river basin management authority (“the broker”) at a flat price per cubic meter, subject only to supply
constraints. (This constitutes a form of water banking, in which so long as the
basin authority has water to sell, it must sell it, and it must purchase whatever is
offered without regard for whether or not it can be resold.) The fourth scenario
(WR-M), water rights market clearing, was similar to the third, but industries and
water utilities were excluded from water trading, and sales were private transactions
—a buyer had to be found for every unit sold.
Figure 10.2 shows that the use of a simple system of volumetric rights, based
on historical cropping patterns, with no trading, has lower aggregate basin output
254
SUHARTO SARWAN, TJOEK WALUJO SUBIJANTO, AND CHARLES RODGERS
by comparison with the first scenario where economic returns were optimized. This
occurs because at least some water resources do not move to the locations and uses
where marginal net value is highest. However, if a simple water brokerage system is
present (scenario three), virtually the same level of output (and implied water economic productivity) is achieved as under the first scenario. In the fourth scenario,
allocation efficiency is also improved as compared to the fixed right (second) scenario, although not to the same extent as in scenario three because the rules governing transfers are more restrictive. In the third and fourth scenarios, the welfare
of irrigators at any particular location would be improved through such voluntary
trades, if we assume that they would never agree to trade unless trading made them
better off.
Models and scenarios such as these provide one tool for evaluating the impact
of different rules for water use rights on the economic efficiency of water allocation. They indicate the potential economic gains from institutional arrangements
that would facilitate reallocation between water uses, such as transferable water use
rights, or, under the current law, arrangements that would compensate users for
giving up rights that the government could then reallocate to others.
Human Rights and Property Rights
In moving from principle to statute and on to implementation, it is necessary to
acknowledge that the intentions behind efforts to establish or to strengthen water
rights simultaneously reflect two distinct sets of social objectives. On one hand,
water rights may be promoted as the legal manifestation of the concept of basic
human rights, in the sense of natural entitlements, as defined in documents such as
the United Nations Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights (UNESCO
2002). From this perspective of distributive justice, embedded in sources as diverse
as the arguments of Rawls (1971) and Moslem water law, one essentially views
water rights as desirable and necessary in order to protect the interests (and perhaps
the survival) of society’s least powerful against coercion and dispossession by the
strong or the wealthy. On the other hand, water rights may be understood explicitly as property rights in water, reflecting a utilitarian perspective. Water rights are
desirable in this context for reducing the friction in economic transactions and for
reducing the risks associated with investments that enhance water productivity.
Ownership is often described as a “bundle” of distinct rights. Table 10.2 compares usage and commercial rights in the new law with the framework of property
rights proposed by Honore (1961). It is somewhat difficult to characterize water
rights within this framework, since, among other factors, water has no stable boundaries. Honore’s system also strongly reflects Western European concepts of ownership.
DEVELOPMENT OF WATER RIGHTS IN INDONESIA
255
Table 10.2 Comparison of water use rights as property rights
Basic water
usage rights
Commercial water
use rights
The right to exclusive physical
control of the thing owned
(includes right to exclude)
Yes, within confines
of use allotment
Yes, within confines of licensed
quantities
(2) Right to use
The right to personal enjoyment
and use of the thing (as distinct
from 3 and 4)
Yes, although qualified
by type of use
Yes, although qualified by license
conditions
(3) Right to manage
The right to decide how and by
whom a thing shall be used
Unclear (limited)
Yes, although qualified by license
conditions
(4) Right to income
The right to the benefits derived
from forgoing personal use of a
thing and allowing others to use it
No (formally prohibited)
From products; but not through
transfer of water use rights
(5) Right to capital
The right to alienate the thing and
to consume, waste, modify, or
destroy it. To alienate is to convey
or transfer as a matter of an owner’s
choice and not in the course of the
state’s legal activities
Right to consume,
obligation to conserve
Right to consume as specified in
license, obligation to conserve
(6) Right to security
Immunity from expropriation
Yes, subject to priorities
Subject to allocation plans and
priorities
(7) Power of
transmissibility
The power to devise or bequeath
the thing
Implicit
No, transfers prohibited
(8) Absence of term
Indeterminate length of one’s
ownership right
Yes, for uses not
requiring license
No, may be limited by term of
license and renewal conditions
(9) Prohibition of
harmful use
Duty to forbear from using the thing
in certain ways harmful to others
Yes
Yes
10) Liability to
execution
Liability to having the thing taken
away for repayment of debt
No
Unclear, but (probably) effectively
yes
11) Residuary
character
The existence of rules governing the
reversion of lapsed ownership rights.
Reversion is the right of succession
or future possession or enjoyment.
Government holds
Government holds
Characteristic
Description
(1) Right to possess
Source: Characteristics and descriptions of rights are from Honore (1961).
256
SUHARTO SARWAN, TJOEK WALUJO SUBIJANTO, AND CHARLES RODGERS
In many societies, an absolute “right to exclude” others would be viewed as an
intolerable defect in the framework of rights, especially with respect to resources
essential for life, or commonly shared or managed resources. It is thus important to
recognize that a rights framework that is “incomplete” with respect to full ownership does not indicate a deficiency or flaw in that framework.
Neither usage rights nor commercial rights fulfill the requirements of full
ownership. This follows primarily (but not exclusively) from the “right to capital,”
which corresponds most closely to the core concept of ownership, at least in the
Western tradition (Becker 1977:20). To grant individuals, groups, or other institutions this right would undermine the intent of Indonesia’s constitution, which
clearly establishes the state’s authority to govern water resources.1 In both categories
of water use right, specific rights characteristics are qualified, sometimes heavily.
Usage rights are categorically qualified in terms of what meets the definition of a
basic use. Specific conditions of the license qualify commercial rights.
Usage rights lie closer to the root concept of “rights” as widely understood.
This follows from the conditions under which water user rights can be denied: for
basic uses, the right is presumed, and such water use is assigned a high priority by
law, except under unusual intervening circumstances. By contrast, the state is (evidently) not compelled to issue commercial use licenses upon request, but retains an
element of discretion beyond the statutory requirements. There is clear merit in
both arguments, for water rights as human rights and property rights, as well as the
potential for conflicting objectives. The ambitious task faced by Indonesian lawmakers and regulators is simultaneously to protect the legitimate historical claims
of current water users, to make explicit the hierarchy of claims on scarce water,
and to permit and facilitate investment and the economic transactions that lead to
greater efficiency in water use. In addition, the process of specifying and formalizing water use rights presents Indonesian policymakers with a unique opportunity
to address longstanding problems associated with the maldistribution of wealth and
productive resources. The process of allocating claims to increasingly scarce water
could be employed as a tool for promoting the health and economic welfare of the
nation’s poorest citizens. Legislation implicitly acknowledges these distinct objectives through the conceptual, as well as legal distinctions provided between basic or
noncommercial users and uses (addressing arguments from natural rights and religious duty) and commercial uses (addressing arguments for economic efficiency).
Some uses of water, however, do not fall neatly into either category. The irrigation of small family-owned plots, typically for paddy and polowijo (irrigated, dryfooted crop) production, is seldom either purely subsistence, or purely commercial.
To illustrate, in a recent field study conducted in the Brantas Basin, East Java, where
irrigated plots are on average less than 0.4 hectare, it was found that an average of
DEVELOPMENT OF WATER RIGHTS IN INDONESIA
257
around 40 percent of paddy produced was consumed within the producer’s household. Much of the income derived from marketed paddy paid for basic necessities
(Rodgers and Zaafrano 2002). The importance of this category of water use in
Indonesia cannot be overemphasized. Surface irrigation schemes divert more than
70 percent of current water abstractions in the Brantas, the majority to large gravity schemes serving numerous smallholders (most of whom would be well below
the threshold of 2 liters per second for which permits would not be required).
It has been persuasively argued (e.g., Gleick 1999) that rights of access to and
use of water for basic purposes are clearly and fully implicit in internationally recognized human rights to life, and to adequate food, clothing, and shelter. Indeed,
it is hard to imagine how these baseline conditions could possibly be guaranteed
absent a corresponding and no-less-fundamental right to water, particularly if we
interpret these rights as including an acceptable level of human dignity. The case
for derived rights for irrigation water use is, unfortunately, less self-evident. The
U.N. Economic and Social Council (UNESCO 2002) is prepared to argue for a
derived water right for food production (irrigation implicit) through “right to adequate food,” “right to health,” and “right to gain a living by work.” However, they
acknowledge a distinction based on priority of right: “(Nevertheless) priority in the
allocation of water must be given to the right to water for personal and domestic
uses. Priority should also be given to the water resources required to prevent starvation and disease, as well as water required to meet the core obligations of each of
the Covenant rights” (UNESCO 2002:2). In a similar vein, Gleick (1999) argues
for the existence of derived rights to water arising from provisions of basic human
rights covenants, but notes that rights to adequate health and nutrition can, technically, be satisfied through the direct provision of food. This argument is possibly
more problematic when applied to rights to livelihood by work.
But note that none of these technicalities preclude arguments for establishing
formal priorities of allocation that favor irrigation over, for example, industrial use,
particularly where irrigation is clearly not a purely commercial enterprise, but
rather enables the primary means to livelihood for established communities of smallholders. Under Indonesia’s water law, basic uses, including noncommercial irrigation, are granted highest priority, but priorities in allocation of water for commercial
uses are established at the discretion of government at the appropriate level.
Conclusions
As an important component of Indonesia’s comprehensive water sector reforms, the
government passed a new National Water Law in February 2004. One objective
is to establish a uniform system of water use rights. The law distinguishes between
258
SUHARTO SARWAN, TJOEK WALUJO SUBIJANTO, AND CHARLES RODGERS
basic usage rights (Hak Guna Pakai Air) and commercial or exploitation use rights
(Hak Guna Usaha Air). Basic usage rights are entitlements requiring no formal permit, while exploitation rights require formal licensing for specific uses of water. The
law specifically precludes transfers of water rights. Experience from the pilot basin
programs will be used to strengthen national implementation of water use rights.
The Brantas Basin offers an example of relatively effective institutions for river
basin management, which have been developed over many decades. However, analysis using a hydrologic–economic model indicates that transfers could yield substantial additional benefits, compared to establishing only nontradable rights.
Under the new law, transfers between sectors could occur, but only through
the agency of the government, which would reacquire water use rights when, for
example, land is converted out of irrigated agriculture, commercial permits expire,
license conditions are violated, or if the right is not exercised. The government
would then be able to reallocate this water to different parties or sectors, subject to
priority and availability. Given the interest of numerous international institutions
in seeing water use rights made transferable, it is likely that the issue of water use
transfers will be revisited in Indonesia’s future.
It is entirely reasonable, however, to insist that the basic framework of use
rights be established, clarified, and legally secure before allowing market-type
transfers. The government will necessarily have an ongoing role in supervising water
sector transactions whatever the form they ultimately take, in order to perform its
constitutionally mandated functions, to ensure that water allocation decisions are
consistent with local custom and regional development goals, and to protect the
welfare and economic security of all of Indonesian citizens, particularly the weak
and vulnerable.
Notes
1. The equivalence of “to govern” and “to own” is not completely self-evident, although the
state’s power to alienate is an important aspect of the right to capital. State ownership is qualified,
however, by its duty to utilize water resources for the welfare of the people, thus negating rights to
waste or destroy, which Honore included (1961) under the right to capital.
References
Amron, M. 1998. Basin water resources management policy in Indonesia. Jakarta: Directorate General of Water Resources Development, Ministry of Settlements and Regional Infrastructure.
Becker, L. 1977. Property rights: Philosophic foundations. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
DGWR (Directorate General of Water Resources, Ministry of Settlements and Regional Infrastructure, Republic of Indonesia). 2003. Republic of Indonesia: Water resources management—
DEVELOPMENT OF WATER RIGHTS IN INDONESIA
259
Toward enhancement of effective water governance in Indonesia. Country report prepared for
the Third World Water Forum. March 2003, Kyoto, Japan.
Faruqui, N. I., A. K. Biswas, and M. J. Bino, eds. 2001. Water management in Islam. Tokyo: United
Nations University Press, International Development Research Centre.
Gleick, P. 1999. The human right to water. Water Policy 1 (15): 487–503.
Government of Indonesia, Minister of State for Public Planning, Chairman of National Development
Planning Agency. Letter to Mr. James D. Wolfensohn, President, The World Bank, April 29,
1999 concerning water resources and irrigation sector: Policy, institutional legislative and regulatory reform program.
Government of Indonesia. 2002. Draft Law of the Republic of Indonesia about water resources,
October 24, 2002, version, English translation.
———. 2004a. Draft of Law of the Republic of Indonesia about water resources, March 2004
version. English translation by N. Arifin, No. 05/03/04—Jakarta, March 17, 2004.
———. 2004b. Explanation (Elucidation) of Draft of Law of the Republic of Indonesia about
water resources, March 2004 version. English translation by N. Arifin, No. 05/03/04—
Jakarta, March 17, 2004.
Honore, A. M. 1961. Ownership. In Oxford essays in jurisprudence, ed. A.G. Guest. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Quoted in Becker, Lawrence. 1977. Property rights: Philosophic foundations. London:
Routledge and Kegan Paul.
JICA ( Japanese International Cooperation Agency). 1998. The study on comprehensive management plan for the water resources of the Brantas River Basin in the Republic of Indonesia.
Final report, Main report. Jakarta: Indonesia, Ministry of Public Works, Directorate General
of Water Resources Development.
LRI (Land Resources of Indonesia). 1990. The land resources of Indonesia: A national overview.
Regional Physical Planning Programme for Transmigration. London: Overseas Development
Administration. Jakarta: Departemen Transmigrasi.
Machbub, D. 2000. Pengelolaan sumberdaya air berwawasan lingkungan pada pengembangan wilayah.
Jakarta: Badan Penelitian dan Pengembangan Departemen Permukiman dan Pengembangan
Wilayah.
PJT-I (Perusahaan Jasa Tirta I). 2002. Company profile. Malang, East Java: PJT I.
Rawls, J. 1971. A theory of justice. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Rodgers, C., and R. Zaafrano. 2002. A water resources management policy simulation model of the
Brantas Basin, East Java, Indonesia. Paper prepared for the final policy workshop “Irrigation
Investment, Fiscal Policy and Water Resources Allocation in Indonesia and Vietnam,” November 21–23, 2002, Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam.
260
SUHARTO SARWAN, TJOEK WALUJO SUBIJANTO, AND CHARLES RODGERS
Sutawan, N. 2000. Negotiation of water allocation among irrigators’ associations in Bali, Indonesia.
In Negotiating water rights, eds. B. R. Bruns and R. S. Meinzen-Dick. London: Intermediate
Technology Publications.
UNESCO (United Nations Economic and Social Council). 2002. Substantive issues arising in the
implementation of the international covenant on economic, social and cultural rights. General
comment No. 15: The right to water (Articles 11 and 12 of the international covenant on
economic, social and cultural rights.) Committee on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights,
Twenty-ninth Session, November 11–29, 2002, Geneva.
WRI (World Resources Institute). 2003. Water resources and freshwater ecosystems—Indonesia. Washington, D.C.: WRI.