CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC HISTORY
THE AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY
DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES
ALWAYS EGALITARIAN: AUSTRALIAN EARNINGS INEQUALITY 1870-19101
LAURA PANZA
UNIVERSITY MELBOURNE
JEFFREY G. WILLIAMSON
HARVARD UNIVERSITY & UNIVERSITY WISCONSIM
DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 2019-08
JULY 2019
THE AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY
ACTON ACT 0200 AUSTRALIA
T 61 2 6125 3590
F 61 2 6125 5124
E
[email protected]
http://rse.anu.edu.au/CEH
Always Egalitarian: Australian Earnings Inequality 1870-19101
Laura Panza (Melbourne)*
Jeffrey G. Williamson (Harvard and Wisconsin)**
Abstract
Trends in Australian inequality across the twentieth century are now well documented and they
closely replicate trends in every other advanced economy: from WWI to the 1970s, inequality fell
steeply everywhere, and from the 1970s to the present, it rose just as steeply. Despite following a
similar trajectory, Australia remained more egalitarian throughout. Why has it been exceptional
and what are its origins? Our previous work has found plenty of evidence documenting a steep fall
in Australian income and earnings inequality from 1820 to 1870 (Panza and Williamson 2019a).
This paper answers two additional questions. First, what was the level of inequality around 1870
after the fall? While we cannot speak to income inequality in 1870, we do find that earnings
inequality was much lower in Australia than in the United States, the United Kingdom, and
presumably the rest of Europe. Second, we find that there was no rise in Australian earnings
inequality over the half century 1870-1910, but rather a modest fall. These findings rely on the use
of an array of primary sources – especially the underutilized government Blue Books reporting
annual earnings of an impressive range of white collar occupations – as well as better known
secondary sources reporting the earnings of manual workers and farm labor. These occupational
(average) earnings data are merged with occupational employment data taken from the censuses
to construct social tables for Australia’s 1870 earnings distribution. We do the same for postfederation 1910 Australia. This exercise establishes that the source of modern Australia’s relative
egalitarianism is the middle third of the colonial nineteenth century. We also apply Goldin-Katz
(2008) analysis to the half century 1870-1910 thus to identify the sources of slow skill demand
and fast skill supply growth. Australia missed a rise up some Kuznets Curve before World War I,
a rise so common in Europe and most of its offshoots.
*
[email protected]
1
**
[email protected]
We are grateful for the useful comments on a previous draft by Jeff Borland and Tim Hatton.
1
1. Twentieth Century Inequality: Australia versus the Rest
Thanks to the impressive work of Anthony Atkinson, Thomas Piketty and many other
economists, trends in earnings, income and wealth inequality across the twentieth century are now
well established (Atkinson 2008; Atkinson and Bourgingnon 2015; Atkinson and Piketty 2007,
2010; Atkinson, Piketty and Saez 2011; Bengtsson and Waldenstrom 2018; Piketty 2005, 2014).
All countries in the OECD experienced a great levelling from World War 1 to the 1970s and almost
all experienced a big rise from the 1970s to the present. The timing of the inequality-trend turning
point is also very similar across countries. While some underwent more dramatic changes than
others, almost all countries for which we have the data exhibit the same trends. Figure 1 illustrates
the evolution of the top 1 percent income shares for the US, the UK and Australia between 1913
and 2006.1 With very few exceptions, all advanced economies exhibited much the same decadal
trend-related turning-points. This commonality suggests that twentieth century inequality was
driven by the same exogenous forces pretty much everywhere: by the switch from Great
Depression to post-war prosperity; from two World Wars to relative world peace; from deglobalization to re-globalization; from anti-immigration to pro-immigration; from baby bust to
baby boom; from liberal to conservative tax policies; from regulated to deregulated domestic
financial markets; and from closed domestic capital markets to an integrated world capital market.
All of these big shocks were shared, and all of them had the same predictable impact on inequality,
first lowering it, and then raising it.2
The Australian experience followed a very similar path, with income inequality declining
over the first three-quarters of the twentieth century before increasing thereafter. Using tax data,
Anthony Atkinson and Andrew Leigh show that the income share of the top 1 percent fell from
around 11 percent in 1921 to under 5 percent by 1980 and then rose again to around 9 percent in
the early 2000s (Atkinson and Leigh 2007b Table 7.1, pp. 315-6; Atkinson and Leigh 2007a,
Figure 1, p. 253).3 Earlier studies portray an analogous story of income inequality decline from the
1
Our empirical analysis refers only to non indigenous Australians. While the Aboriginal population became a
relatively important source of labor in the settler economy from the mid nineteenth century (Lloyd 2010), there are no
available statistics on the Aboriginal labor market to allow us to include them into the analysis.
2
See the summary in Lindert and Williamson (2016: Chapter 8).
3
See also Saunders (1993) on the decline and rise of inequality with the 1970s as turning point.
2
pre-World War 1 decade to the post-World War 2 decades, despite using different data and
different inequality measures. For example: Noel Butlin (1983) found a fall in the skilled to
unskilled wage ratio between 1901 and 1968, an earnings inequality correlate; Jones (1975)
documented an income inequality fall between 1914/15 and 1968/9; and McLean and Richardson
(1986) reported a considerable leveling in the distribution of per capita family income between
1933 and 1979. The Australian income inequality rise since the 1970s is even better documented
(Travers and Richardson 1993; Boehm 1994; World Bank 2019).
Despite the similarities between country-specific inequality trends, it is important to stress
that Australia remained much more egalitarian throughout. Table 1 reports top 1 percent income
shares for twentieth century Australia, the United States and the United Kingdom. Across the
1920s, when inequality was at a secular peak, the Australian share was only 62 percent of the US
and UK average. Following the great leveling, and having reached an inequality trough in the
1970s, Australia again recorded lower figures than the average of the US and the UK, 66 percent.
And after the steep rise to the inequality peak in the 2000s, once again Australia recorded much
lower figures, only 61 percent of the US and UK average. It is also notable how stable the ratio of
Australia to the other two stayed across the twentieth century, while exhibiting the same inequality
trends. Why were Australian inequality levels so modest across the twentieth century – at least
relatively -- and what are their nineteenth century origins? This paper asks whether this relative
egalitarianism is rooted in its colonial past well before the 1901 Federation, and well before a set
of policies to reduce perceived inequalities were implemented (McLean and Richardson 1986, p.
67) and during decades recording a growth slow down (McLean 2013) and very modest
industrialization.
To our knowledge, we are the first to provide an estimate of Australian inequality in the
nineteenth century.4 True, our previous work found plenty of evidence documenting a fall in
earnings and income inequality from 1820 to 1870, a period of exceptional growth in GDP and
living standards (Panza and Williamson 2019b). So much for mid-nineteenth century trends. What
about the level of inequality around 1870 and how did it compare with the rest of the world? Was
it always more egalitarian than other New World countries and Europe?
4
See Maddock and Olekalns (1984) for a review of the available studies on income inequality in Australia between
1914 and 1980.
3
We overcome the constraints imposed by the lack of income and wealth data before the 1933
census and the tax data reported from the 1920s onwards, by constructing social tables for earnings.
Specifically, we build from scratch labor earnings social tables for Victoria, New South Wales and
South Australia (the latter using only urban males), which covered about 87 percent of Australian
1870 GDP, in order to estimate its earnings distribution. To this end, we use the colonial censuses
to document the occupational structure of the labor force (that is, employment by occupation,
gender and location); and two key primary sources for their average earnings by category: the
Sessional Papers for working class occupations, and the Blue Books for white collar jobs, since it
lists the annual earnings of all public employees by occupation.
We find that Australia was exceptional in 1870: the distribution of earnings was far more
equal than in the United States in the same year (Lindert and Williamson 2016), and even more so
compared with the United Kingdom in 1867 (Baxter 1868) and the rest of Europe. Next, we ask
whether Australia maintained that exceptionalism over the four decades between 1870 and 1910
by constructing another social table for the latter year, and the answer is yes. Indeed, earnings
inequality actually fell over that half century, while it rose in most advanced economies
2. On Building Australian Social Tables
2.1 What’s a Social Table?
Social tables were first used to document national income and its distribution across social
classes more than four centuries ago by the English political arithmeticians William Petty and
Gregory King, writing in the seventeenth century. They were followed in the eighteenth and
nineteenth centuries by Patrick Colquhoun, Dudley Baxter and others (for a summary see Lindert
and Williamson 1982). Their idea was to rank income earners by various occupations or social
classes from the richest to the poorest with their estimated number of income earners and their
estimated average incomes. Petty, King, Colquhoun and Baxter used their social tables to derive
national income estimates, but in the absence of modern income surveys and tax records, they can
also be used to measure inequality. Social tables are especially useful in evaluating pre-industrial
societies where classes were clearly delineated, and the differences in mean incomes between them
were clear without any fuzzy edges between classes. As such, the social table is a matrix,
sometimes with separate columns by gender and location. Most recent uses dealing with inequality
4
are: Milanovic, Lindert and Williamson (2011) using a large sample of 29 countries from Rome
14 to India 1948 (recently and modestly updated in Milanovic 2018); Lindert and Williamson
(2016) for the United States for the years 1774, 1800, 1850, 1860, and 1870; and Burnard, Panza,
and Williamson (2018) for 1774 Jamaica.
As we suggested above, in the absence of modern survey data or even tax data to construct
Atkinson’s top shares, we think social tables offer the best way to estimate earnings or income
distributions. While relying on social tables to estimate Australian earnings inequality around 1870
and 1910 has its weaknesses (see section 2.3), it is important to bear in mind that the same
weaknesses are shared by our comparators, a US social table for 1870 (Lindert and Williamson
2016: Chapter 6) and a United Kingdom social table for 1867 (our revision of Baxter 1868). While
all the above mentioned studies report income distributions (the US and UK document earnings,
income and wealth distributions), we are only able (thus far) to estimate annual income
distributions for Australia. This is because we have not found data on average property income by
occupation. Do earnings distributions typically understate income inequality? Apparently not for
one of the three nations being considered here: Lindert and Williamson (2016: Chapter 6) show
that for 1870 United States earnings inequality was slightly higher, not lower, than income
inequality.5 The observation year 1870 is unlikely to characterize 1867 UK: in both newly-settled
economies – compared with Europe – had their wealth and property income distribution still
dominated by small owner-operated family farms and firms, implying less income inequality than
earnings inequality. In any case, modern evidence shows a very high correlation between income
and earnings inequality trends.
2.2 Constructing Social Tables for 1870 and 1910 Australia
All six of Australia’s colonies (New South Wales, Queensland, South Australia, Tasmania,
Victoria, Western Australia) published occupational employment censuses for a date around 1870,
but only two have roughly the same occupational earnings detail in their official documents – New
South Wales and Victoria – where aggregation between them is possible. South Australia also has
some earnings data, but they are limited mostly to urban males. As was true for all British colonies,
5
One piece of evidence supporting this assumption is the extensive overlap between occupational hires in the two
sectors including clerks, lawyers, porters, messengers, teachers, bakers, cooks, printers, lithographers, compositors,
clergy, pharmacists, surgeons, physicians, accountants, bankers, store managers common labor and others.
5
the six Australian colonies also published what were called Blue Books which, among other details,
report the annual incomes of all public employees by department, occupation, location and gender
(e.g. male clerks, matrons, female domestics, porters, police, judges, surgeons, surveyors,
engineers, urban common labor, gardeners, stable keepers, carters, cooks, nurses, some artisans,
teachers, laundresses, and so on). However, the occupational earnings detail around 1870 is only
adequate for the same three colonies – New South Wales, South Australia, and Victoria. According
to available GDP estimates (Sinclair 2009), New South Wales and Victoria accounted for 75
percent of Australia’s 1870 GDP (87 percent with the addition of South Australia), thus providing
validity to the representativeness of our sample.
The social tables for New South Wales and Victoria are reported in the Appendix. As
indicated above, while white collar earnings are taken from the Blue Books, some urban unskilled,
some artisans, most skilled in the building trades, and all farm labor earnings are missing from the
Blue Books; these are derived from other sources, mainly Coghlan (1918: v. ii) and the Sessional
Papers from the House of Commons (1868-1873).
All of these comments on the 1870 data apply to the 1910 data as well, although the latter
are much more detailed by occupation. The occupational earnings and employment for both years
are described in much greater detail in the Appendix.
2.3 Potential Weaknesses as Australian Earnings Inequality Measures
The colonial and post-federation Blue Books report annual earnings for all public employees,
but not for private sector employees. In effect, therefore, we assume that public and private sector
labor markets were competitive, and that there was no selectivity regarding employee quality. This
assumption seems reasonable to us given the relatively small size of the government sector at that
time, implying that private sector labor market conditions drove public sector occupational
earnings, not the other way around. In addition, public employees almost always had annual work
contracts. The same was true of private sector white collar workers, farm labor and domestics.
However, it was not true of skilled, semi-skilled and unskilled manual workers: in the private
sector, manual labor was hired by the day or week while all white collar workers and most other
6
public employees were usually paid by the year.6 Thus, we assume that the security of annual
contracts were offset by higher daily and weekly wages in the more volatile private sector (with
high unemployment risk). In any case, the same assumptions are made for the construction of the
1870 social table for the United States and the 1867 social table for the United Kingdom with
which comparisons will be made.
In addition, while we can take account of earnings variation within some occupations – e.g.
inspectors, clerks and police by grade, domestics by gender – we cannot do so for most unskilled
and semi-skilled occupations, and even some artisanal occupations, except when their earnings are
reported separately. Thus, each occupation cell in our social tables reports average earnings,
calculated from all employees who had their annual earnings listed in that occupation, and that
weighted average is then multiplied by the numbers so employed economy-wide as reported in the
censuses. In short, while the social tables certainly measure the variance of earnings between
detailed occupations, and thus reflect schooling and skills, they do not include all the variance
within those detailed occupation. However, we are not convinced that this is a serious shortcoming
of the social tables. After all, most of the earnings variance within occupations (controlling for
location) is driven by age, health and luck. To the extent that the occupation-specific distributions
of age, health and luck vary little across time and location, the social tables should be effective in
gauging differences in earnings inequality across time and space.
3. Australian Earnings Distributions in 1870
Table 2 converts our social table for Australia7 -- merging those for Victoria (Table A1) and
New South Wales (Table A2) – into a size distribution which yields various inequality summary
statistics: top 10 percent earnings share, top 1 percent earnings share, the ratio of the top 10
percent’s average earnings to the bottom 10 percent’s average earnings, the ratio of white collar
6
While the Blue Books report annual earnings by occupation, the other sources typically report only daily or weekly
wages that must be converted to annual earnings by days worked per year assumptions. For the latter, we use Panza
and Williamson (2018b), which also tells us how in-kind income is added to the earnings estimates for farm labor and
domestics.
7
For the 1870 analysis, the label Australia refers to the aggregation of our social tables for New South Wales and
Victoria, roughly three quarters of the total colonial economy.
7
average earnings to common labor’s average earnings, and the gini coefficient.8 In the discussion
that follows, we will rely on the top 1 percent share as our inequality indicator,9 but note that these
five inequality statistics are highly correlated. The subsequent discussion would hardly be changed
if we used any of the remaining four inequality indicators. Table 3 reports the same statistics
(except for the white collar to common labor earnings ratio) for the United States in 1870 (using
Lindert and Williamson 2016), and the United Kingdom in 1867 (using Baxter 1868). We should
stress here, however, that some limitations to Baxter’s social table (see Appendix 5, Table A5)
suggests that our UK earnings inequality figures are probably biased upwards. Still, we know that
income inequality was higher in the United Kingdom than in the United States at that time (Figure
1; Lindert and Williamson 2016: Figure 5-3, p. 119). Indeed, the top 5 percent received an amazing
46 percent of total income in 1867 England and Wales (Lindert and Williamson 1982: p. 96), so
there is reason to expect a similar earnings inequality gap between the two.
Before considering what Table 2 tells us about Australian earnings inequality across space,
note that the data for South Australia are only adequate for estimating urban male earnings
inequality (see Appendix 4). Having said so, our estimates show that older, slightly richer (per
capita GDP 2.3 percent higher: Sinclair 2009), more industrial (manufacturing value added 9
percent of GDP versus 5.5 percent: Sinclair 2009) and much more urbanized10 New South Wales
recorded higher inequality than Victoria (top 1 percent share 7.37 versus 4.17 percent), but still
much lower than the United States (top 1 percent share 9.7). While the South Australian data are
not available to speak to colony-wide issues, we can see clearly that urban inequality was lower
there (top 1 percent share 4.6 percent) than in New South Wales (top 1 percent shares are 6.9
percent versus 4.6 percent). Table 2 also repeats what is almost always found for every country
and time: namely, rural earnings inequality was far less than urban inequality in both New South
Wales and Victoria but more so in New South Wales (top 1 percent share 7.63 percent versus 5.04
percent) than in Victoria (4.33 versus 3.66 percent).
8
In addition, Appendix Table A4b reports the “Australian” size distribution by decile.
9
Appendix Table A4b reports 1870 earnings shares for all ten deciles.
10
The urban employment share of total employment in New South Wales was double that of Victoria. But note that
this figure relates to employees not to the working population. Recall that our earnings social tables document
employees and omit self-employed workers on family farms and in family firms.
8
Next, consider the role of gender. Not surprisingly, women were paid considerably less
than men, even when doing the same work: in towns, female common labor received only 55
percent of their male co-worker’s pay in both colonies (Tables A1 and A2).11 But female labor
participation in paid work was so low that their inclusion in the distribution calculations raises the
inequality statistics very little. For Australia as a whole, the top 1 percent received 5.48 percent
when females are excluded, but 5.83 percent when they are included. To repeat, the difference is
modest simply because female participation in the paid labor market was modest.
Finally, consider the central question that motivates this section: Was 1870 Australia a
relatively egalitarian place compared with the United States and the United Kingdom? In this
paper, the comparison will be limited to the United States and the United Kingdom primarily
because very few other countries supply such earnings data. The comparison reported in Table 3
is unambiguous: Australia was a far more egalitarian place in 1870. The top 1 percent share was
5.8 in Australia, 9.7 percent in the United States and 16.8 percent in the United Kingdom. Thus,
earnings inequality was only 60 percent of the US, 35 percent of the UK (but an upward bias for
UK inequality contributing to a downward bias to the relative Australia estimate), and about 50
percent of the average of the two. This is a remarkable finding: given that the same figure for
income inequality was 62 percent in the 1920s and 61 percent in the 2000s. It appears that
Australia’s relative egalitarianism has persisted for a century and a half, although that leadership
may have eroded a bit between the 1870s and the 1920s. Was the erosion in Australian distribution
leadership due to rising inequality there or a fall in the UK, the US or both? Available evidence
on income inequality trends suggests that it was likely to have been the latter since Figure 1 points
to a fall in British income inequality between 1870 and 1920; and the next section will show that
Australian earnings inequality actually fell between 1870 and 1910.
4. Did Australian Earnings Inequality Rise or Fall from 1870 to 1910?
4.1
11
Assessing the 1910 Earnings Distribution
As we shall see, the figure was higher in 1910, 66.7 percent, so that there was some reduction in the gender pay gap
over those five decades.
9
Tables 4 and 5 summarize our estimates of Australian earnings inequality in 1910.12
Consider gender issues first. Table 4 shows that the distribution of earnings among females was
much more equal than among males, simply because women were rarely employed in high-skilled
and high-paying jobs. In New South Wales, the gini coefficient was 0.304 for males and 0.249 for
females, while the top 10 percent shares were 26.35 and 23.83 percent. The same was true for
Australia as a whole, the ginis being 0.378 and 0.282. Male experience clearly dominated the total
earnings distributions: the male gini in New South Wales was 0.304 while the gini for the two
combined was 0.306. When aggregating across gender, the pay gaps between them certainly raised
the gini above that of males, but it did not do so by much, from 0.304 to 0.305. As in 1870, female
participation in the labor market was still too modest in 1910 to have a significant impact on total
inequality. However, not only did women face job discrimination in high skilled occupations, they
also faced wage discrimination within almost every occupation. This was especially true of white
collar jobs where women earned only 68 percent of men, but even for lower skilled jobs – like
domestic servants, farm labor and urban common labor -- where they earned 71-78 percent of men
(Table 5).
Next, consider the impact of job distributions across Australian states. Using Australian
employment weights, the gini was much higher, 0.373, than in New South Wales. 0.306, simply
because there were many more low-paying jobs – farm labor and non-farm unskilled labor – in the
more newly settled, less urban and less industrial states like Queensland, Tasmania, South
Australia and Western Australia.
4.2
Did Earnings Inequality Rise or Fall? Still Egalitarian in 1910?
Did Australia remain egalitarian between 1870 and 1910? Did a relatively equal
distribution of earnings persist over the half century? Table 6 supplies the answers. The first fact
12
We simplify by referring to the year 1910, while the social tables and these summary tables actually refer to the
1910 Blue Book and the 1911 Census. In addition, and to repeat table notes and text, 1910 “Australia” refers to the
Commonwealth’s total occupational employment figures but to New South Wales for the occupational earnings.
Resources permitting, we plan in future versions of this paper first to exploit the earnings data in Victoria’s Blue Book
and next, if time permits, that of the other four states. Tables titled by New South Wales use both the earnings and
employment data of that state. The 1870 tables use the earnings data from both Victoria and New South Wales (section
3 and Appendix 4), not just the latter. However, as we can see in Appendix 4, the earnings structure was quite similar
in the two 1870 colonies, and we expect the same for those two states.
10
to note there is how little average white collar earnings changed over those fifty years, a fall of 17
percent in New South Wales and a rise of 16 percent for Australia as a whole. In contrast, unskilled
urban worker’s earnings more than doubled in both New South Wales (up by 2.16 times) and all
Australia (up by 2.51 times). Thus, the ratio of white-collar average earnings at the top to that of
urban common labor at the bottom fell steeply from 7.11 to 2.74 in New South Wales. However,
farm labor’s earnings remained relatively stable. Thus, the rural-urban earning gap rose over the
half century.
Although farm wage trends must have produced a partial offset, the non-farm earnings
trends certainly are consistent with a fall in earnings inequality between 1870 and 1910. And so it
did. The gini coefficient fell from 0.399 to 0.306 in New South Wales and from 0.411 to 0.373 in
all Australia. To take another example, the top 1 percent share fell from 7.37 to 5.31 percent in
New South Wales and from 5.48 to 5.44 percent in all Australia. Appendix Table A6c shows that
the earnings compression took place everywhere up and down the decile ladder.
While there was a fall in earnings inequality from the beginning to the end of the half
century, our evidence does not speak to the possibility that it first rose and then fell. Perhaps it did.
A recent paper by Mike Pottenger and Andrew Leigh used executive earnings data from the BHP
Billiton company to document the ratio of high executive salaries to average Australian earnings
from 1887 to 2012. Although their evidence is only for one company and covers only about half
of our period, their results might still be suggestive. The series for directors shows a steep rise
1887-1892, and then an equally steep fall thereafter (Pottenger and Leigh 2018: Figure 1, p. 5)
while the one for the CEOs shows volatility 1887-1902 followed by a steep fall (Figure 2, p. 7).
This somewhat limited earnings inequality evidence does suggest that our half century may have
undergone an early rise and then a later fall, with a modest net decline overall. As far as we know,
there is no other published evidence that speaks to these issues in the half century before the Great
War.
4.3 Searching for Explanations
Trends in earnings inequality can best be understood by explaining the skill premium, or
the earnings gap between high-skilled white-collar employees and that of low-skilled manual
labor. And as Claudia Goldin and Lawrence Katz (2008) have shown for the United States across
the twentieth century, earnings inequality fell when the demand for skills grew slower than the
11
supply, and rose when skill supply grew slower than demand. They dubbed it as a race between
schooling and technology. Did schooling and skills grow faster than demand in Australia between
1870 and 1910? Available statistics generally suggest that it was the case: despite sustained GDP
growth, the industries relying more heavily on white collar and skilled labor grew a bit slower than
GDP. At the same time, the skilled labor supply bottlenecks which characterized Australia during
early settlement (Panza and Williamson, 2019a) were overcome by rapidly growing native born
skilled and schooled labor augmented by relatively skilled and schooled immigrants from the
United Kingdom (Hatton 2019).
As a proxy for relative demand growth for skills, we use the performance of manufacturing
and modern service sector GDP shares, given that these industries were more white collar-cumskill-intensive than farming, mining or the pastoral sector. Between 1870 and 1910 total output in
New South Wales manufacturing and services both grew slower than agriculture: an average yearly
growth rate of 4.4 percent for manufacturing, 3.9 percent for services and 4.9 percent for the
primary sector (Sinclair 2009). This modest structural change is in sharp contrast with
industrialization events in North America and Europe, a performance that came to be called their
“second industrial revolution”. More to the point, the Australian output trends lagged behind the
increase in Australian skill supply, as documented by available schooling data: indeed, the
Australian colonies were among the international leaders in the provision of primary education
(Seltzer 2015: p. 93). Free and compulsory primary schooling was introduced in the late 1860s in
all colonies. By the late nineteenth and early twentieth century about 98 percent of the New South
Wales population could read and write (Pope 1989). School enrolment rates grew fast over time
and by 1880, they surpassed all European countries for which data are available (Lindert 2004).
Another key contributor to the supply of skilled workers came from immigration, as shown by
Glen Withers (1989) some time ago, between 1877 and 1910 most immigrants belonged to skilled
and semi-skilled occupations, and more so than the native born. More recently, Timothy Hatton
(2019) has shown that this was more true of Australia and New Zealand than Canada and,
especially, the United States. Based on the occupations of UK emigrants, the skilled shares
between 1877 and 1913 averaged 51.3 percent for Australian immigrants, 37.2 percent for
American immigrants, and 30.8 percent for Canadian immigrants (Hatton 2019: p. 14).
Furthermore, the share of Australian immigrants that were Irish – the poorest source region of the
12
UK emigrants – was huge in the 1850s and 1860s but then dropped steeply to 10.5 percent between
1877 and 1913 (Hatton 2019: pp. 8 and 17).
Late in the period, labor policies also played a role in lowering skill premia by legislation,
which served to regulate wages in favor of low skilled manufacturing workers.13 That Australia
remained a “workers’ paradise” at the turn of the twentieth century has also been noted by
Australian historians: for example, Peter Macarthy (1971) points to the existence of extremely high
wages especially for unskilled workers.
Finally, while the key driver of the egalitarian earning distribution in the 1870-1910 period
was the urban leveling forces listed above, it was partially offset by a big rise in the urban-rural
earnings gap. The shift towards a more urban-based economy is illustrated by New South Wales
in Table 7. The labor force in the primary sector declined, and the reasons are not hard to find.
Figure 2 plots a decline in land acreage per capita, a trend matched by an increase in land values
per acre, particularly of rural land (Taylor 1992). Relative export prices showed no fall over the
period (data underlying Williamson 2008), so increasing land scarcity must have put downward
pressure on labor productivity growth and thus rural wages relative to urban.
5. Road Map for Future Research
Australian earnings inequality was already very low in 1870, lower than the United States,
and much lower than the United Kingdom. And it was even lower in 1910 than 1870, although
similar earnings distribution data are not yet available for the US and the UK thus to know whether
Australian relative egalitarianism persisted over the half century (although it was certainly true of
income inequality in the 1920s: see Atkinson and Leigh 2007a, 2007b). Our new evidence is also
consistent with the Goldin-Katz model: in the Australian case, schooling and skill growth over the
half century 1870-1910 exceeded demand growth.
What remains to be done? While this paper has been able to use Australian occupational
employment data to construct our earnings social tables for 1870 and 1910, our 1910 occupational
earnings data are for New South Wales only. It is certainly possible to augment the earnings
13
Australia and New Zealand were the first two countries to pass minimum wage legislation. Furthermore, a set of
laws were enacted prohibiting child labor, women’s work at night and setting maximum working hours (Huberman
and Meissner 2010).
13
evidence to include the other five colonies/states. The evidence is easy to gather for the manual
trades, but it is very hard to extract the white collar occupational earnings evidence from the Blue
Books. A still more difficult task would be to uncover property incomes by occupation thus to
speak to income inequality. In addition, we need an earnings social table for the 1920s thus to hook
up with the Atkinson-Leigh twentieth century income inequality series and also to compare our
early twentieth century earnings inequality estimates with already available late twentieth century
estimates. And can we identify which was doing most of the work creating such an egalitarian
place by 1910? Was it the macro labor market forces elaborated above, or was it the rise in literacy
and numeracy generated by public schooling, or was it the influx of skilled and schooled
immigrants (perhaps induced by agents’ preferring skilled for steerage subsidies), or was it wage
regulations introduced late in the half century? One way to find out is to build another earnings
social table for 1890, before that legislation was introduced.
So, while the sources of Australian egalitarianism can be found as far back as 1870, we do
not yet know which were the main driving forces, a slow conversion from primary product
specialization to urban-industrial activities, a big policy commitment to schooling, the attraction
of high skilled immigrants, or wage regulation. To the extent that schooling, immigration and wage
policies mattered greatly, then perhaps economics should yield to political economy. That is, why
were these policies followed so aggressively in Australia, so much more than elsewhere?
Persistence matters: the egalitarian distribution of 1870 established a norm which became a
powerful driver for the 150 years that followed.14
14
There are other historical cases where this persistence has been stressed, the most important being Latin America
where its extensive modern inequality is thought to have its roots in Iberian colonialism five centuries ago (Engerman
and Sokoloff 2012; Williamson 2015).
14
References
Atkinson, Anthony B. 2008. The Changing Distribution of Earnings in OECD Countries. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Atkinson, Anthony B. and François Bourgingnon (eds.) 2015. Handbook in Income Distribution.
Amsterdam: North Holland.
Atkinson, Anthony B. and Andrew Leigh 2007a. “The Distribution of Top Incomes in Australia,”
The Economic Record 83, 262: 247-61.
Atkinson, Anthony B. and Andrew Leigh 2007b.“The Distribution of Top Incomes in Australia”,
in Atkinson, Anthony B. and Thomas Piketty (eds.). Top incomes over the Twentieth
Century: a Contrast between Continental European and English-speaking Countries. New
York: Oxford University Press, pp. 309-332.
Atkinson, Anthony B. and Thomas Piketty (eds.). 2007. Top incomes over the Twentieth Century:
a Contrast between Continental European and English-speaking Countries. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Atkinson, Anthony B. and Thomas Piketty (eds.). 2010. Top incomes: A Global Perspective.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Atkinson, Anthony B., Thomas Piketty, and Emmanuel Saez. 2011. “Top Incomes in the Long
Run of History,” Journal of Economic Literature 49, 1 (March): 3-71.
Baxter, R. D. 1868. National Income: The United Kingdom. London: Macmillan.
Bengtsson, Erik and Daniel Waldenstrom 2018. “Capital Shares and Income Inequality: Evidence
from the Long Run,” Journal of Economic History 78 (3): 712-43.
Boehm, E. 1994. “A Review of Income Inequality in Australia,” Institute of Applied Economics.
Burnard, Trevor, Laura Panza and Jeffrey G. Williamson 2019. ” Living Costs, Real Incomes, and
Inequality in Jamaica c1774,”Explorations in Economic History 71 (January): 55-71.
Butlin, Noel G. 1983. ‘Trends in Australian Income Distribution: A First Glance’. Working Paper
No 17, Department of Economic History, Australian National University
15
Engerman, Stanley L. and Kenneth L. Sokoloff 2012. Economic Development in the Americas
since 1500: Endowments and Institutions. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Goldin, Claudia and Lawrence Katz 2008. The Race Between Education and Technology.
Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.
Greasley, David and Jakob B. Madsen 2016. “The Rise and Fall of Exceptional Australian
Incomes Since 1800,” Australian Economic History Review 57, 3: 264-90.
Hatton, Timothy J. 2019. “Emigration from the UK 1870-1913: Quantity and Quality,”
unpublished (June).
Huberman, Michael and Christopher M. Meissner 2010. “Riding the wave of trade: the rise of
labor regulation in the Golden Age of Globalization”, The Journal of Economic History, 10
(3).
Jones, F. L. 1975. The Changing Shape of the Australian Income Distribution, 19114/15-1968/69
Lindert, Peter H. 2004., Growing Public: Social Spending and Economic Growth since the
Eighteenth Century (New York : Cambridge University Press).
Lindert, Peter H. 2015. “Three Centuries of Inequality in Britain and America,” in A. B. Atkinson
and F.Bourgingnon (eds). Handbook in Income Distribution. Amsterdam: North Holland,
pp. 167-216.
Lindert, Peter H. and Jeffrey G. Williamson 1982. “Revising England's Social Tables, 1688-1812,”
Explorations in Economic History 19, 4 (October): 385-408.
Lindert, Peter H. and Jeffrey G. Williamson 2016. Unequal Gains: American Growth and
Inequality since 1700 .Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Macarthy, P. G. 1971. “Wages in Australia, 1891–1915”, Australian Economic History Review,
10 (1).
Maddock, R., Olekalns, N., Ryan, J., and Vickers, M. 1984. The distribution of income and wealth
in Australia 1914–80: An introduction and bibliography. Source Papers in Economic
History (1).
McLean, Ian W. 2013. Why Australia Prospered: The Shifting Economic Sources of Economic
Growth. (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
16
McLean, Ian W. and Richardson, S. (1986). More or less equal? Australian income distribution in
1933 and 1980. Economic Record, 62(1), 67-81.
Milanovic, Branko 2018. “Towards an explanation of inequality in premodern societies: the role
of colonies, urbanization, and high population density,” Economic History Review 71, 4:
1029-47.
Milanovic, Branko, Peter H. Lindert, and Jeffrey G. Williamson 2011.”Pre-Industrial Inequality,”
Economic Journal 121 (March): 255-72.
Panza, Laura and Jeffrey G. Williamson 2019a. ”Squatters, Convicts, and Capitalists: : Dividing
Up a Fast-Growing Frontier Pie, 1821-1871” Economic History Review 72, 1 (May): 568594.
Panza, Laura and Jeffrey G. Williamson 2019b. ”Living Costs and Living Standards: Australian
Development 1820s-1870s,” European Review of Economic History (forthcoming).
Pottenger, Mike and Andrew Leigh 2018. “Long-Run Trends in Australian Executive
Renumeration: BHP, 1887-2012,” Australian Economic History Review 56 (1): 2-19.
Piketty, Thomas. 2005. “Top Income Shares in the Long Run: An Overview,” Journal of the
European Economic Association 3(2-3): 1-11.
Piketty, Thomas. 2014. Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap Press.
Pope, D. 1989. “The relevance of human capital”, in D. Pope and L. Alston (eds), Australia’s
Greatest Asset: Human Resources in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries (Sydney:
Federation Press).
Saunders, P. 1993. “Longer run changes in the distribution of income in Australia”. Economic
Record, 69(4), 353-366.
Seltzer, A. (2015). “Labour, skills and migration.” In S. Ville and G. Withers (eds.), The
Cambridge Economic History of Australia (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), pp.
178-201.
Sinclair, W. A. 2009. Annual Estimates of Gross Domestic Product: Australian Colonies/States
1861-1976/77, Working Paper, Department of Economics, Monash University (September).
17
Taylor, A. D. (1992), The Value of Land in Australia before 1913, ANU Source Paper in Economic
History (Canberra: ANU).
Travers, P. and S. Richardson 1993. Living Decently: Material Well-being in Australia, Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Vamplew, W. (1987) (ed.), Australians: Historical Statistics (Broadway: Fairfax, Syme and
Weldon).
Williamson, Jeffrey G. 2015. “Latin American Inequality: Colonial Origins, Commodity Booms,
or a Missed 20th Century Leveling? Journal of Human Development and Capabilities
(special issue) 16 (August): 324-41.
Withers, Glen 1989. “The immigration contribution to human capital formation’, in D. Pope and
L. Alston (eds), Australia’s Greatest Asset: Human Resources in the Nineteenth and
Twentieth Centuries (Sydney: Federation Press).
World Bank 2019. Webpage https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/si.pov.gini accessed May 2019.
18
Figure 1: Top 1% income shares in Australia, UK and US, 1913-2006
20
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
1913 1918 1923 1928 1933 1938 1943 1948 1953 1958 1963 1968 1973 1978 1983 1988 1993 1998 2003
Australia
US
UK
Source: Atkinson and Piketty (2007).
Figure 2: Acreage per capita in NSW, 1870-1910
400
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
1870
1875
Acreage per capita
1880
1885
1890
1895
Land value per acre (Crown sales)
1900
1905
1910
Land value per acre (rural land)
Source: Acreage per capita, left axis: Vamplew (1987). Land value per acre in £, right axis:
Taylor (1992).
19
Table 1. Income Shares of Top 1%, 1920s-2000s, Australia, the UK and the US
Australia United Kingdom United States Average (UK &US) Australia/Average
1920s
11.37
19.59
16.98
18.29
0.62
1970s
5.35
8.37
7.9
8.14
0.66
2000s
8.71
12.67
15.69
14.18
0.61
Sources: Australia, the UK and US are from Atkinson and Piketty (2007: Tables 4.1, 5A.1, 7.1).
Table 2. Comparative Earnings Inequality across the Australian Colonies 1870
A. Using both Male and Female
Total
New South Wales
Top 10% vs bottom 10%
31.45
Top 10% share (%)
34.40
Top 1% share (%)
7.37
Top 10% mean income (£)
813.79
Gini coefficient
0.399
Victoria
Top 10% vs bottom 10%
16.15
Top 10% share (%)
27.46
Top 1% share (%)
4.17
Top 10% mean income (£)
689.38
Gini coefficient
0.353
Australia (VIC + NSW)
Top 10% vs bottom 10%
26.90
Top 10% share (%)
33.53
Top 1% share (%)
5.83
Top 10% mean income (£)
706.14
Gini coefficient
0.426
Urban
Rural
31.36
39.00
7.63
827.02
0.480
19.01
22.27
5.04
466.43
0.273
16.07
29.38
4.33
685.47
0.377
15.72
21.64
3.66
623.58
0.271
26.17
33.05
5.54
703.36
0.438
23.57
30.89
5.81
621.37
0.369
20
B. Using only male labor force
New South Wales
Top 10% vs bottom 10%
Top 10% share (%)
Top 1% share (%)
Top 10% mean income (£)
Gini coefficient
Victoria
Top 10% vs bottom 10%
Top 10% share (%)
Top 1% share (%)
Top 10% mean income (£)
Gini coefficient
South Australia
Top 10% vs bottom 10%
Top 10% share (%)
Top 1% share (%)
Top 10% mean income (£)
Gini coefficient
Australia (VIC + NSW)
Top 10% vs bottom 10%
Top 10% share (%)
Top 1% share (%)
Top 10% mean income (£)
Gini coefficient
Sources: Appendices 1, 2, and 3.
Total
Urban
Rural
22.16
32.72
6.75
813.79
0.377
24.27
36.22
6.90
907.49
0.455
9.80
21.27
4.99
323.38
0.274
11.73
27.35
4.18
689.38
0.343
10.18
28.89
4.22
685.47
0.367
11.79
21.47
3.61
623.58
0.263
13.42
27.26
4.57
624.26
0.361
16.60
32.12
5.48
742.98
0.411
17.49
31.27
5.15
774.50
0.409
15.65
30.09
5.64
651.14
0.356
Table 3. Earnings Inequality around 1870: the US and the UK
Top 10% share (%)
Top 1% share (%)
Gini coefficient
United States
44.5
9.7
0.546
United Kingdom
47.5
16.8
0.625
Sources: The US figures are from Lindert and Williamson (2016, Table 6.5, p.156). The UK
figures are derived from Baxter (1868) and see Appendix 5.
21
Table 4. Earnings Inequality in Australia, 1910
Top 10% vs bottom 10%
Top 10% share (%)
Top 1% share (%)
Top 10% mean income (£)
Gini coefficient
Using NSW employment
weights
Total
Male
Female
11.05
10.58
8.45
25.93
26.35
23.83
5.31
5.04
3.31
625.67
632.77
409.22
0.306
0.304
0.249
Using AUS employment
weights
Total
Male
Female
10.27
10.60
6.04
31.11
31.52
24.91
5.44
5.19
4.74
604.89 617.61
420.34
0.373
0.378
0.282
Table 5: Earning Ratios in New South Wales, 1910
Occupation
Mean
N.
Mean earnings Mean earnings Female/
category
earnings (£)
occs
Male (£)
Female (£)
Male
White collar
316.14
73
330.90
225.11
0.68
Urban common
108.19
10
108.40
79.56
0.73
labor
Domestic/servant
80.92
11
103.31
80.92
0.78
Farm
86.43
16
86.7
61.48
0.71
All categories
198.65
197
206.70
144.01
0.696
Notes: This Table is based on NSW labor weights. White collar includes Officials (High, Legal),
Officers (Military, Penal, Police, Church, Charity, Health, Scientific Dept., Education Dept.,
Telephone, Ferry, Harbor), Judges, Clerks, Magistrates, Bailiffs, Barristers/Solicitors, Clergy,
Sanitary Inspectors, Medical Practitioners, Medical and Hospital Attendants, Dentists,
Pharmacists, Nurses, Midwives, Veterinarians, Chemists, Assayers, Geologists,
Biologists/Botanists, Civil Engineers, Engineers, Surveyors, Architects, Draftsmen, University
Professors, Teachers (Grammar/High School, State, Church, Private, Music, and Language
Schools, Technical Colleges), Tutors, Photographers, Musicians, Bankers/Brokers,
Accountants/Auditors, Actuaries, Underwriters, Auctioneers, Storekeepers, Managers
(Government Store, Factory, Farm, Station, Store), Undertakers, Postmasters/Sorters, Letter
Carriers, Mailmen, Stationmasters (Telegraph, Railway), Electricians/Linemen, Barristers, and
Station Agents. Urban common labor includes: Stevedores/Wharf Labor, Watermen, Laborer,
Street Cleaners/Chimneysweepers, Deliverymen, Draymen/Carters/Teamsters, Road labor
(navvy), Messengers, Railroad Labor, Wood choppers. Farm labor includes: Laborer (Farm, Fruit,
Vineyard, Sugar, Pastoral, Dairy, Poultry Farm, Pig farm), Market gardener, Nurseryman, Station
Agent, Horsekeeper, Fisherman, Forestry worker, Stablekeeper, Woolwasher.
22
Table 6: Australian Earnings Inequality Trends 1870 - 1910
Using NSW labor weights
Ratio
1910
1870
1910/1870
275.60 331.21
0.83
100.47
46.56
2.16
71.85
68.46
1.05
Using AUS labor weights
Ratio
1910
1870
1910/1870
348.84
300.24
1.16
111.65
44.54
2.51
61.80
73.51
0.84
Weighted
earnings (£)
White collar
Urban labor
Farm labor
Earnings ratios
White collar/ urban
2.74
7.11
0.38
3.12
6.74
0.46
common labor
White collar/ farm
3.84
4.84
0.79
5.64
4.08
1.38
Labor
Inequality indicators
Gini index
0.306
0.399
0.77
0.336
0.411
0.91
Top 10% share (%)
25.93
34.40
0.75
31.11
32.12
0.97
Top 1% share (%)
5.31
7.37
0.72
5.44
5.48
0.99
Note: Earnings weights are based on occupational’ employment shares within each category. The
white collar, urban common and farm labor categories are defined in Table 5. white collar in 1870
include: Assistants, Accountants, Auctioneers, Bankers, Brokers, Architects, Artists, Authors,
Editors, Reporters, Civil engineers, Clergy, Dispensing Chemists, Dentists, Chiropractors, Harbor
pilots, Lighthouse keepers, High government Officials, Judges, Lawyers, Barristers/Solicitors,
Clerks, Physicians, Surgeons, Policemen, Jailers, Professors, Schoolmasters, Teachers. Urban
labor refers to labor employed in towns. Farm labor refers to all farm types and pastoral labor. For
1870, Australian labor force weights include employment in New South Wales, South Australia
(males only) and Victoria.
Table 7: Labor force shares by sector, 1870-1910
Sector
1870 1910
Farm labor
0.25 0.16
Manufacturing (skilled/semi-skilled)
0.16 0.28
Mining
0.10 0.07
Service (non-white collar)
0.21 0.22
Service (white collar)
0.09 0.16
Common labor (unskilled)
0.19 0.11
Source: Authors calculations based on census data: New South Wales Census of 1871 and The First
Commonwealth Census (1912).
23
Appendix 1: Victoria 1870
Appendix Table A1 reports our social table for earnings in Victoria around 1870. To fit in
the table cells reported here, the occupations listed in the table are selective, but the complete list
can be found at the end of Appendix 4. The employment figures are from the Census of Victoria,
1871: General Report and Appendices (John Ferres, Government Printer, Melbourne, 1871-1874).
All white collar and some working class and artisan earnings data are taken from the Blue Book of
the colony of Victoria for the year 1867 (John Ferres, Government Printer, Melbourne, 1868).
Urban working class and farm earnings (e, g. farm labor, building trade workers, blacksmiths,
cooks, grooms, stable keepers, gardeners, female domestics, housemaids, nursemaids, laundresses,
common labor, and seamen) are all constructed from Timothy A. Coghlan, Labour and Industry
in Australia, v. II, chap. 2 (Melbourne: Oxford University Press, 1918) and the House of
Commons, Sessional Papers: Statistical Tables relating to the Colonial and other Possessions of
the United Kingdom, Parts XIV-XV (1868- 1875). We also constructed and include estimates of
in-kind income for farm labor, seamen and domestics as well as converting daily and weekly wages
in to annual earnings as explained in Panza and Williamson (2018b). Teacher salaries are from
Parliamentary Paper (Victoria. Parliament), no. 66: Education Act .1872.—Regulations
(Melbourne : Robt. S. Brain, Government Printer, 1889). All earnings in Table A1 are in Australian
an pounds.
Table A1. Earnings Social Table for Victoria 1870
Occupation
Accountants, auctioneers,
brokers
Architects, Surveyors,
Scientific persons
Artist, actor, musician
Assistants clerks
Authors, editors, reporters
Barber, hair dresser
Blacksmith, locksmith
Butcher, baker, brewer
Civil engineers
Clergy
Commissioner, agent
Common labor
Dealers, agents, contractors
Domestic
Dressmaker, seamstress
Gender
Urban
employees
Rural
employees
Urban
earnings
Rural
earnings
M
1,293
463
517.93
473.06
M
M
M
M
M
M
M
M
M
M
M
M
M
F
2,386
740
31
90
470
2,240
5104
132
508
475
19,346
3,988
18,068
6,186
780
222
6
24
50
1,770
2396
54
287
90
12,725
1,378
10,181
1,396
365.99
225
200
472.50
159.06
126
212.08
341.59
393.26
537
58.66
525.50
67.98
62.50
362.49
210
189.39
472.50
159.06
94.12
212.08
341.59
393.26
537
58.66
386.32
67.98
46.69
24
Farm laborer
Farm overseer
Fishmonger, milkman
Goldsmith, jeweler, engraver
Government clerks
Harbour pilot, light house
keeper
Hawkers, peddlers, dealers,
shopkeeper
Hawkers, peddlers, dealers,
shopkeeper
High government officials
Hotel & lodging operator
Hotel & lodging operator
Judges, lawyers, solicitors
Law clerks
Machine and tool maker
Manager
Midwife
Miner
Nurse
Pharmacists, dentist
Physicians, surgeons
Police, jailers
Private sector clerks
Professors, Schoolmasters
Seaman, boatman
Skilled workers (textiles,
paint, tailor, wood)
Skilled with leather
Skilled with stone and metal
M
M
M
M
M
2,867
89
825
970
982
19,096
975
868
104
414
90.64
244.79
212.08
297.20
294.95
90.64
244.79
212.08
269.57
286.55
M
154
60
398.85
328.78
F
730
72
40
40
M
M
F
M
M
M
M
M
F
M
F
M
M
M
M
M
M
5,599
324
57
2,809
575
425
1,228
721
88
7,596
602
480
516
997
3,216
10
1,176
3,176
189
61
1,540
132
37
167
88
42
24,881
162
95
201
406
442
3
1,187
203.40
820.16
113.57
183.84
732.79
391.51
168
525.50
36
177.80
36
200
399.83
123.78
294.95
971.88
110
203.40
596
113.57
183.84
691.69
369.55
125.50
386.32
36
177.80
36
189.39
376.85
123.78
286.55
820.16
110
M
M
M
17,479
5,301
3,631
1,372
1,682
1,013
129.5
126
147
96.735
94.12
109.81
25
Appendix 2: New South Wales 1870
Appendix Table A2 reports our social table for earnings in New South Wales around 1870.
To fit in the cells here in the paper, the occupations listed in the table are selective, but the complete
list can be found at the end of Appendix 3. The employment figures are from the New South Wales
Census of 1871, Consisting of Report, Summary Tables, and Appendix, and Detailed Tables
(Sydney: Thomas Richards, Government Printer. 1873). All white collar and some working class
and artisan earnings data are taken from the New South Wales Blue Book for the year 1867
(Sydney: Government Printer, 1868). Urban working class and farm earnings (e, g. farm labor,
building trade workers, blacksmiths, cooks, grooms, stable keepers, gardeners, female domestics,
housemaids, nursemaids, laundresses, common labor, and seamen) are all constructed from
Timothy A. Coghlan, Labour and Industry in Australia, v. II (Melbourne: Oxford University Press,
1918) and House of Commons, Sessional Papers: Statistical Tables relating to the Colonial and
other Possessions of the United Kingdom, Parts XIV-XV (1868- 1875). We constructed estimates
of in-kind income for farm labor and domestics as well as converting daily and weekly wages in
to annual earnings as explained in Panza and Williamson (2018b). We were not able to find
common school teacher salaries for New South Wales, so we assumed that Victorian earnings
applied. All earnings figures in Table A2 are in Australian pounds.
Table A2. Earnings Social Table for New South Wales 1870
Occupation
Butchers, bakers
Butchers, bakers
Fishmongers, fruiterers
Fishmongers, fruiterers
Hawkers, peddlers
Hawkers, peddlers
Hotel, lodging operator
Hotel, lodging operator
Barber, hairdresser
Blacksmith, farrier,
Locksmith
Dressmaker, seamstress
Goldsmith, jeweler, watch
maker
Printer, compositor,
Lithographer
Skilled with leather
Skilled with stone
Skilled worker casual
Gender
F
M
F
M
F
M
F
M
M
M
Urban
employees
70
1,495
322
2,862
587
3,,181
385
304
2,488
614
Rural
employees
63
461
12
699
43
1,131
101
706
325
205
Urban
earnings
26
102.86
26
102.86
41.42
218
26
102.86
49.72
192
Rural
earnings
26
102.86
26
102.86
36.04
19
26
102.86
39.6
144
F
M
3,815
276
419
30
75.33
186.25
55.75
137.83
M
633
46
150
120
M
M
M
864
4,142
8,148
218
823
3,267
151
100.19
56.93
120
79.8
45.77
26
Wheelwright, coachmaker
Common labor
Common labor
Domestic
Domestic
Farm laborer
Farm laborer
Miners
Seaman, boatman
Stevedore, lumper, stoker
Accountant, banker,
Merchant
Architect, surveyor
Assistants
Authors, editors, reporters
M
F
M
F
M
F
M
M
M
M
M
770
2,369
12,551
10,891
3,901
65
4,038
1,836
1,431
200
1,543
247
263
15,092
5,127
2,810
1,455
36,565
14,530
418
177.50
27.50
56.10
28.00
66.00
65.71
71.20
150.00
120.00
100.31
407.27
154
27.50
56.1
20.16
48
65.71
71.20
150
100.31
M
M
M
69
65
547
177
6
150
70
505.15
144.99
70
Civil engineers
Clergy
Dispensing chemists,
Dentists
Harbor pilot and masterr
High government officials
M
M
M
1,998
400
225
415
104
22
582
237.88
270
582
160
270
M
M
245
8
70
250
1,050
175
Judges, lawyers, solicitors
Law clerks
Physicians, surgeons
Police, jailers
Private sector clerks
Private sector clerks
Teachers, common school
Teachers, common school
M
M
M
M
F
M
F
M
273
257
252
706
527
3,651
1,342
3,114
37
22
72
132
103
590
499
772
1,472.22
403.13
270.00
225.00
49.86
262.45
75.00
525.74
950
260.13
270
225
43.38
228.33
65
150.9
179
200
27
Appendix 3. South Australia 1870
Appendix Table A3 only reports employment and earnings of urban males since our sources do
not document enough female and rural occupational earnings to include inequality statistics for
anything other than urban males. Most earnings data come from the Blue Book of South Australia
for the year 1867 (Government Printer, Adelaide, 1868) with the exception of the following
occupations which are derived from the Sessional Papers: Statistical Tables relating to the
Colonial and other Possessions of the United Kingdom, Parts XIV-XV (1868- 1875): butcher;
locksmith; tailor; cabinet maker; skilled with leather; mason, bricklayer; wheelwright; domestic,
stevedore; carriage maker; engineer; and lithographer. In addition, barber and hairdresser earnings
are from Frederick Sinnett, An account of the colony of south Australia (Adelaide, Government
Printer, 1863), and teacher earnings are from Kay Whitehead, “Women's life-work: teachers in
South Australia, 1836-1906,” Phd thesis, June1996, Department of Education and Women's
Studies, University of Adelaide. The employment data come from the 1876 South Australian
Census.
Table A3. Earnings Social Table for South Australia 1870
Occupation
Accountants, bankers, merchants
Architects, surveyors, scientific persons
Artist, actor, musician
Assistants, clerks
Authors, editors, reporters
Barber, hair dresser
Blacksmith, farrier, locksmith
Butchers, bakers, brewers
Civil engineers
Clergy
Commissioner, agent
Common labor
Dispensing chemists, Dentists
Domestic
Dressmaker, seamstress, tailoress
Farm laborer
Fishmongers, fruiterers
Goldsmith, jeweler, watch maker
Government clerks
Hawkers, peddlers, pawnbroker
High government officials
Urban
employment
Urban
Earnings
351
257
113
44
37
30
630
1,073
15
103
274
5,217
99
407
234
1,145
1,144
142
305
358
55
250
408.95
225
76.25
300
52
125
70
187.5
300
300
45.71
124.78
48
125
40.33
115
313.75
165.35
127.5
749.55
28
Hotel & lodging operator
Judges, lawyers, barristers
Law clerks
Machine and tool maker
Midwife, nurse
Miners
Overseer
Pharmacists, dentist
Physicians, surgeons
Police, jailers
Printer, compositor, lithographer
Private sector clerks
Professor
Seaman, boatman
Skilled with leather (boot, shoe, and
saddle maker; tanner)
Skilled with stone (mason, bricklayer)
and metal
Skilled with textiles and wood
Stevedore, wharf labor
Teachers, common school
Tobacconist
Wheelwright, coachmaker
20
75
70
313
12
284
35
16
59
133
350
938
3
454
970
150
540.91
224.23
135
93.53
90
310
71.18
450
324.63
313.75
277.67
971.88
120
116.81
2,485
143.33
1,515
22
162
34
535
122.5
92.5
120
150
130
29
Appendix 4: Australia 1870
The Australian earnings social table (Table A4a) simply merges those for Victoria (Table A1) and
New South Wales (Table A2). South Australia is excluded since both rural and female
occupational earnings data are inadequate for that colony. All earnings data are in Australian
pounds.
In the text tables, the gini coefficients derived from Tables A1-A5 use the following algorithm:
where the W are weights based on employment figures and the X are annual earnings (ordered in
ascending order).
Following Table A4a, we also report the complete list of occupations which are abbreviated in
Tables A1, A2 and A3. Finally, the size distribution underlying Table A4a are reported as decile
shares in Table A4b.
Table A4a. Earnings Social Table for Australia 1870
Employment
Occupation
Accountants, auctioneers, brokers
Architects, surveyors, scientific
persons
Artist, actor, musician
Assistants clerks
Authors, editors, reporters
Barber, hair dresser
Blacksmith, farrier, locksmith
Butcher, baker, brewer, miller
Butcher, baker, brewer, miller
Civil engineers
Clergy
Commissioner, agent
Common labor
Common labor
Dealers, agents, contractors
Domestic
Domestic
Earnings
Gender
Urban
Rural
Urban
Rural
M
2,836
642
457.72
396.92
M
M
M
M
M
M
M
F
M
M
M
M
F
M
M
F
2,455
740
96
637
2,958
2,854
6,599
70
2,130
908
475
31,897
2,369
3,988
21,969
10,891
957
222
12
24
375
1,975
2,857
63
469
391
90
27,817
263
1,378
12,991
5,127
359.92
225.00
111.98
500.54
67.09
140.20
187.34
26.00
567.10
324.81
537.00
57.66
27.50
525.50
67.63
28.00
322.26
210.00
129.70
472.50
55.53
99.30
194.46
26.00
554.32
331.22
537.00
30.44
27.5
386.32
63.66
20.16
30
Dressmaker, seamstress, tailoress
Farm laborer
Farm overseer
Fishmonger, milkman
Fishmonger, milkman
Goldsmith, jeweler, engraver,
Government clerks
Harbour pilot
Hawkers, peddlers, shopkeeper
Hawkers, peddlers, shopkeeper
High government officials
Hotel & lodging operator
Hotel & lodging operator
Judges, lawyers, solicitors
Law clerks
Machine and tool maker,
millwright
Manager
Midwife
Miner
Nurse
Pharmacists, dentist
Physicians, surgeons
Police, jailers
Printer, compositor
Private sector clerks
Private sector clerks
Professors, Schoolmasters
Seaman, boatman
Skiled workers
Skilled with leather
Skilled with stone and metal
Stevedore, wharf labor
Teachers, common school
Teachers, common school
Telegrapher, stenographer
Tobacconist
Wheelwright, coachmaker
F
M
M
M
F
M
M
M
F
M
M
F
M
M
M
10,001
6,905
89
3,687
322
1,246
982
399
1,317
8,780
332
442
3,113
848
682
1,815
55,661
975
1,567
12
134
414
130
115
4,307
189
162
2,246
169
59
67.39
41.64
244.79
127.30
26.00
272.62
294.95
307.45
40.63
208.68
825.70
37.29
175.94
970.84
395.89
48.78
77.87
244.79
163.36
26.00
240.08
286.55
245.98
38.52
154.98
596.00
58.97
158.39
748.24
328.75
M
M
F
M
F
M
M
M
M
M
F
M
M
M
M
M
M
M
F
M
M
M
1,228
721
88
9,432
602
705
768
1,703
3,064
6,867
527
10
2,607
25,627
6,165
7,773
417
5,514
1,342
160
394
1,994
167
88
42
39,411
162
117
273
538
476
1,032
103
3
1,605
4,639
1,900
1,836
81
2,235
499
70
20
553
168.00
525.50
36.00
172.39
36.00
222.34
357.23
165.74
211.52
277.67
49.86
971.88
115.49
106.43
129.50
122.06
90.33
394.28
75.00
132.00
212.08
145.89
125.50
386.32
36.00
167.55
36.00
204.55
348.67
148.61
202.81
253.27
43.38
820.16
107.48
60.84
97.09
96.36
90.33
198.56
65.00
132.00
212.08
120.87
31
Table A4b: Australian Earnings Distribution by Decile (NSW+VIC) 1870
Decile
Total (%)
Urban (%)
Rural (%)
1st
2.84
2.25
3.04
2nd
3.82
3.89
3.53
3rd
4.42
4.11
4.98
4th
5.46
4.63
7.31
5th
5.94
4.88
8.55
6th
6.12
8.32
8.55
7th
9.04
9.22
8.55
8th
11.51
12.41
8.88
9th
17.32
17.25
15.74
33.05
30.89
top
33.53
32
Appendix 5: The United Kingdom 1867
The social, table for the United Kingdom 1867 comes from R. Dudley Baxter, National Income:
The United Kingdom (London: Macmillan, 1868), Appendix IV and V. There are three limitations
to Baxter’s 1867 social table, in rising order of seriousness. First, he does not break down the three
manual classes -- skilled, semi-skilled and unskilled -- in to occupations, gender, or urban/rural
(although the occupations within these three groups are listed). Second, the top income groups are
not identified by occupation, but we eliminate them since these high-income recipients were
unlikely to have been employed. Third, his three white collar “middle class” groups do not identify
occupation or distinguish between labor earnings and property income. We assume that these
“middle class” incomes were overwhelmingly labor income, not property income. To the extent
that this was not true, our estimates of UK earnings inequality are upward biased. However, the
text offers a defense of their use in comparisons with the US and Australia.
All income figures in Table A5 are in pounds sterling.
Table A5. A Social Table for Earnings in the UK 1867
Total
Total
Average
Recipients
Income
Income
Middle incomes 300-1000
178,300 87,723,000
492.00
Small incomes 100-300
1,026,400 110,950,000
108.10
Lower incomes < 100
1,497,000 81,320,000
54.32
Manual, High Skilled
1,345,000 66,353,000
49.33
Manual, Lower Skilled
5,087,000 160,652,000
31.58
Agriculture and Unskilled
4,529,000 97,640,000
21.56
Total
13,662,700 604,638,000
44.25
33
Appendix 6: Australian Social Tables 1910
Appendix Table A6a reports our social table for earnings in New South Wales around 1910.
Table A6b does the same for Australia as a whole using employment figures for all of Australia,
but the earnins structure of NSW (also embodied in Table 6A1). In the future, we hope to revise
the earenings estimates by including Victoria (data already collected) and perhaps the other four.
The employment figures are from the The First Commonwealth Census (Melbourne:
Bureau of Census and Statistics, 1912). The earnings data are taken from the following three
sources: New South Wales Statistical Returns of the Colony (Blue Book), Sydney: Government
Printer, 1911 (BB in Tables A6a and A6b); The Official Yearbook of New South Wales, 1910-11,
Sydney: W. A. Gullick, Government Printer, 1911 (YB in Tables A6a and A6b); Peter Macarthy
(1967) “The Harvester Judgment: An Historical Assessment”, Unpublished PhD dissertation,
ANU (MC in Tables A6a and A6b).
We constructed estimates of in-kind income for farm labor, house servants (domestics),
farm station clerks and the clergy, based on detailed board and lodging data contained in the Blue
Books. Specifically, we augmented annual earning by 18% to account for in-kind income. All
earnings are based on annual averages reported in the original sources, with the exception of:
a) bricklayer, brick maker, founder, molder, house painter, mason, plasterer and silversmith, which
were converted from daily earnings, based on 250 working days.15
b) clothing maker, farm labor (including poultry farm, dairy farm, sugar farm, pig farm) and
leathergoods maker, which were converted from weekly earnings.
We were not able to find barbers and hairdressers earnings, so we assumed a 16.7% wage premium
over servants, inferred from NSW earnings in 1870. Managers earnings are inferred from directors
earnings as reported in the Blue Books for the following occupations: Director of Labour, Secretary
to Department of Public Instruction and Director of Education; Director of the Botanic Gardens,
Director of the Forests Dept.; Director of the Immigration and Tourist Bureau; Director of the
Microbiology Institute. Clergy earnings are based on 19 observations of clergymen in gaols
reported in the Blue Book, belonging to the following denominations: Church of England, Roman
Catholic, Presbyterian, Methodist, Jewish. When female earnings were not reported, we assigned
them an average of 66.4% of male earnings, based on data where both wages were available (28
occupations). We did not find earnings data for the following occupations: artists, chemical
makers, editor/journalist, irregular clergy, irregular medical practitioner, undertaker,
cigar/cigarettes makers, glass maker, confectioner, iceman, lime cutter, miller, paper maker,
pottery maker, and stone cutter, all of which representing 10,355 workers. Since these missing
observations represent only 1.8% of the total labor force, their omission should not generate a large
bias to our inequality estimates. All earnings figures in Table A1 are in Australian pounds.
15
The 250 figure is commonly assumed in living standard calculations for other regions and times, assuring
comparability with Australian estimates in this study, (See Panza and Williamson forthcoming).
34
Appendix Table A6b reports Australian employment figures from the The First Commonwealth
Census (Melbourne: Bureau of Census and Statistics, 1912) and annual earnings by occupation
based on New South Wales experience around 1910 (as in Table A6a, with the same sources).
Table A6a: New South Wales Earnings Social Table, 1910
Occupation
Accountant, auditor
Actuary, underwrite, auctioneer
Architect
Arms maker
Assayer
Bailiff
Baker
Banker, broker
Barge master, lighterman
Barrister
Biologist, botanist
Blacksmith
Boiler maker
Bookbinder
Boot maker (craftsmen)
Boot maker (factory)
Brick layer
Brick maker
Butcher
Meat, fish curer
Carpenters
Carriage maker
Charity officer
Charwomen, cleaner
Chemist
Church officer
Civil engineer
Clergyman
Clothing maker (craftsman)
Clothing maker (factory)
Coachman, groom
Coke burner
Compositor
Cooper
Cordial Maker
Dairy farm laborer
Deliveryman
Dentists
Labor force
Male
Female
827
73
3,939
416
613
22
62
2
113
0
107
0
6,373
2,813
4,637
20
90
0
1,185
0
36
3
5,487
0
1,877
0
628
1,037
2917
0
2,854
1606
4,021
0
3,238
0
7,553
170
2,518
113
12,374
0
5,333
43
93
147
133
703
48
1
27
12
441
1
1,674
162
1,774
14,107
2,890
7,175
1,329
705
358
0
2,933
60
255
0
1,188
87
8,694
167
261
2
1,339
250
Earnings (£)
Male
Female
346.7
230.2
346.7
230.2
452.6
300.5
210
139.4
260
259.1
143.2
95.1
660
438.2
149.6
560
483.8
321.2
125
210
164.3
136.8
107.7
71.5
137.5
137.5
72
47.8
72
47.8
139.8
210
139.4
187
124.2
79
52.7
483.8
321.2
187
124.2
399.2
265.1
220.7
146.5
159.8
106.1
125.8
83.5
126
83.7
130
164.8
109.4
137
75
50
61.4
40.7
158.2
105
650
431.6
Source
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
YB
BB
BB
MC
MC
YB
YB
YB
YB
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
YB
BB
YB
MC
MC
BB
YB
BB
MC
YB
MC
BB
BB
35
Die/type maker
Domestic nurse
Draftsman
Drayman, carterman, teamster
Electrical apparatus maker
Electrician
Lineman
Engine driver (farm)
Engine driver (fireman)
Mechanical engineer
Engineer
Stoker
Engraver
Factory manager
Farm laborer
Farm manager
Ferry officer
Fisherman
Fishmonger
Florist
Forestry worker
Founder
Fruit grower laborer
Furniture maker (craftsman)
Furniture maker (factory)
Gardener
Gas supply worker
Geologist
Grocer, fruiter
Guard, signalman
Hairdresser, barber
Harbour officer
Hat, bonnet maker
Hatter, milliner
Health officer
High officials
Horse keeper
Hospital attendant
Hospital nurse
Hotel servant
House painter
House servants
Joiner
Judges
Laborer
Laundryman
81
1
408
10,493
7
1,790
983
3,268
1,742
6,971
63
2,196
117
219
26,797
246
577
1,524
561
142
6,358
3,140
3,729
1,411
2,589
1,583
1.808
14
10,323
3,709
2,906
932
451
1,871
113
1,198
159
836
14
7,057
5,340
1,965
1,165
20
23632
546
14
896
2
35
0
0
0
0
0
0
4
0
2
0
4
3
0
1
25
117
6
0
0
0
257
0
0
0
1,371
1
221
3
579
682
7
34
0
664
1,938
7,526
7
34,462
3
3
0
3,158
168.9
122.6
257.8
126
210
130
130
158.2
158.2
210
399.2
183.2
240
680.8
61.36
303.1
225.8
119.6
171.4
171.4
79
125
61.36
132.1
104
101.5
130
483.8
171.4
146.4
122.8
390
75
75
620
906.9
120
122.6
122.6
89.2
125
105.3
156
906.9
86.3
125
112.1
90.4
171.2
83.7
265.1
159.4
40.74
201.3
79.4
113.8
113.8
52.46
69.1
113.8
97.2
81.7
326.1
50
50
411.7
602.2
69.5
90.4
50
83
69.9
103.6
602.2
49.2
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
YB
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
MC
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
YB
YB
MC
MC
MC
BB
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
YB
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
36
Law Clerks
Leathergoods maker (artisan)
Leathergoods maker (factory)
Legal officials
Letter carrier
Lighthouse keeper
Lithographer
Locksmith
Lodging house servant
Machinist
Magistrates
Mailman
Maltster, brewer
Market gardener
Mason
Medical attendant
Medical practitioner
Messenger
Midwife
Military officers
Milkman
1,267
2,223
274
171
718
56
362
53
968
148
20
362
1,403
4,758
1,268
113
1,333
882
0
3,096
2,348
520
76
48
7
0
0
17
0
3,412
0
0
0
6
39
0
0
83
3
1,569
0
125
498.5
136.8
107.7
721.1
202.5
225.7
208.5
137.5
89.2
148.6
432.5
202.5
137
145
137.5
122.6
650
106.4
Millwright
Miner
Motorman, cab driver
Moulder
Music teacher
Musical instrument maker
Nursery man
Officer, Scientific Dept.
Officer, Education Dept
Omnibus driver
Optician
Ornament makers
Pastoral laborer
Penal officer (skilled)
Penal officer (regular)
Pharmacist
Photographer
Pig farm laborer
Pilot
Plasterer
Plumber
Police officers (skilled)
Police officers (regular)
Porter, gate keeper
Postmaster, sorter
2,629
39,551
432
3,140
274
555
1,701
73
141
1,145
224
741
28,189
17
296
1,443
716
109
111
1,681
3,599
73
2,563
556
2,131
0
23
3
0
2,333
29
3
2
7
13
26
718
10
9
40
134
399
0
0
0
0
0
0
5
690
210
131.9
93.7
131.2
252.1
210
101.5
587.5
587.5
154.7
210
210
61.36
304.8
128.6
122.6
250
61.36
275.3
125
130
450
162.5
86.7
364.6
304.8
171.4
202.5
90.8
72.9
481
138.4
50
91
96.3
163.3
70.6
137.5
113.8
87.6
62.2
211.8
139.4
67.4
390.1
305.2
102.7
139.4
139.4
40.74
120
92
90.4
166
60
242.1
BB
MC
MC
BB
BB
BB
BB
YB
YB
BB
BB
BB
MC
BB
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
YB
YB
BB
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
MC
BB
BB
BB
BB
MC
BB
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
37
Poulterer
Poultry farm laborer
Printer
Quarry man
Railroad labor
Railway station master
Restaurant servant
Road laborer (navvy)
Rope/canvas maker
Sail maker
Sanitary inspector
Sawmill worker
Scientific instruments maker
Ship master, seaman
Shipwright
Shirt maker
Sick nurse
Silversmith
Slater, shingler
Smelter
Sports equipment maker
Stable keeper
Station agent
Station manager
Stevedore, wharf labor
Steward
Store manager
Storekeeper
Street cleaner, chimney sweeper
Sugar laborer
Surgical instrument maker
Surveyor
Tanner, soap maker
Tea/coffee seller
Teachers
Telegraph- Stationmaster
Telegraph/telephone maker
Telephone officer
Textile worker
Tinsmith
Tobacconist
Tramway driver
Tutor
Typist
Umbrella maker
Professor
142
1,191
682
952
6,921
3,016
1,478
10,873
78
119
209
1,335
21
4,742
1,809
90
17
977
272
1,261
74
532
1,399
2,860
5,643
1,351
226
6,900
1,967
288
41
1499
8016
698
3,878
697
12
840
525
876
606
4,870
438
1,230
70
93
8
0
116
0
243
12
2,706
1
0
3
2
7
0
0
0
867
1,353
115
0
0
37
8
31
0
0
82
2
2,963
0
7
5
8
154
89
5,430
0
0
0
460
0
69
0
964
161
197
6
171.4
61.36
184.1
94
121
202.5
89.2
87.5
85.4
137
281.1
89
210
114
210
93.7
122.6
137.5
125
125
210
121
202.5
202.5
121
131
171.4
171.4
79
61.4
210
382
81
171.4
257.1
202.5
210
202.5
75
115
171.4
158.2
257.1
150
90
587.5
113.81
122.2
80.3
134.5
50
58.1
91
186.6
59.1
62.2
90.4
91.3
139.4
80.3
134.5
87
113.8
113.8
40.7
139.4
253.6
53.7
113.8
211.8
49.8
113.8
211.8
99.6
59.8
390.1
YB
MC
BB
YB
YB
BB
BB
YB
YB
MC
BB
YB
BB
BB
BB
YB
BB
YB
YB
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
MC
BB
BB
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
YB
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
YB
BB
38
Veterinarian
Vineyard laborer
Watch maker
Waterman
Wheelwright
Wine seller
Wood chopper
Wool washer
Investment societies clerks
Bank clerks
Railway, tramway, shipping, telegraph clerks
Station clerk
161
383
662
266
595
708
1,284
1,064
47
3,215
5,415
2860
5
5
6
0
0
78
0
29
6
20
72
0
300
61.4
210
119.6
210
171.4
79
52
190
174
209
224.2
199.2
40.7
139.4
113.8
34.5
126.2
115.5
138.78
BB
MC
BB
BB
BB
BB
BB
YB
BB
BB
BB
BB
Table A6b: Australian Earnings Social Table, 1910
Occupation
Accountant, auditor
Actuary, underwrite, auctioneer
Architect
Arms maker
Assayer
Bailiff
Baker
Banker, broker
Barge master, lighterman
Barrister
Biologist, botanist
Blacksmith
Boiler maker
Bookbinder
Boot maker (craftsmen)
Boot maker (factory)
Brick layer
Brick maker
Butcher
Meat/fish curer
Carpenters
Carriage maker
Charity officer
Charwomen, cleaner
Chemist
Church officer
Civil engineer
Clergyman
Clothing maker (craftsman)
Employment
Male
Female
1,943
178
10,649
904
1,515
53
285
202
451
1
184
0
17,314
3,834
13,770
45
226
0
2,949
0
64
3
17,157
11
3,845
1
1,671
2,689
8,749
0
8,560
4,626
8,031
0
5,976
34
21,252
653
465
147
33,885
3
14,610
272
227
171
259
1,228
5,211
4,373
101
431
2,115
5
61
11
629
44,033
Earnings (£)
Male
Female
346.7
230.21
346.7
230.21
452.6
300.53
210
139.44
260
259.1
143.2
95.08
660
438.24
149.6
560
483.8
321.24
125
210
164.3
137
108
71.5
137.5
137.5
72
47.81
72
47.81
139.8
92.83
210
139.4
187
124.2
79
52.7
483.8
321.2
187
124.3
399.2
265.1
220.7
146.5
159.8
106.1
39
Clothing maker (factory)
Coachman, groom
Coke burner
Compositor
Cooper
Cordial Maker
Dairy farm laborer
Deliveryman
Dentists
Die/type maker
Domestic nurse
Draftsman
Drayman, carterman, teamster
Electrical apparatus maker
Electrician
Lineman
Engine driver (farm)
Engine driver (fireman)
Engineer
Mechanical engineer (stoker)
Engraver
Factory manager
Farm laborer
Farm manager
Ferry officer
Fisherman
Fishmonger
Florist
Forestry worker
Founder
Fruit grower laborer
Furniture maker (craftsman)
Furniture maker (factory)
Gardener
Gas supply worker
Geologist
Grocer, fruiter
Guard, signalman
Hairdresser, barber
Harbor officer
Hat, bonnet maker
Hatter, milliner
Health officer
High officials
Hospital attendant
Hospital nurse
7,124
3,307
378
7,540
701
3,388
17,216
569
2,979
156
3
1,033
25,493
19
4,645
2,676
9,187
4,535
123
5,730
323
718
92,104
1,206
618
7,795
1,411
326
24,393
10,667
14,185
3,743
6,867
4,162
4,003
30
28,330
10,219
6,807
2,362
1,257
4,387
296
11,771
2,169
17
22,396
2,115
0
140
2
181
523
7
668
15
2,683
8
79
0
100
0
0
0
12
0
14
0
102
7
9
1
68
309
12
62
438
0
559
0
18
0
3,887
22
509
6
1,654
1,526
18
730
1,875
5,001
125.8
126
130
164.8
137
75
52
158.2
650
168.9
122.6
257.8
126
210
130
130
158.2
158.2
399.2
183.2
240
680.83
52
303.12
225.8
119.6
171.4
171.4
79
125
52
132.08
104
101.5
130
483.8
171.4
146.4
122.83
390
75
75
620
906.9
122.6
122.6
83.5
83.7
109.43
50
34.5
105.04
431.6
112.15
90.4
171.18
83.66
265.07
159.36
34.53
201.28
79.41
113.81
113.81
52.46
83
34.53
69.06
113.81
97.21
81.69
326.1
50
50
411.68
602.18
69.5
90.4
40
Hotel servant
House painter
House servants
Joiner
Judges
Laborer
Laundryman
Law Clerks
Leather goods maker (artisan)
Leather goods maker (factory)
Legal officials
Letter carrier
Lighthouse keeper
Lithographer
Locksmith
Lodging house servant
Machinist
Magistrates
Mailman
Market gardener
Mason
Medical attendant
Medical practitioner
Messenger
Midwife
Military officers
Milkman
28,970
13,912
22,280
21
4,795
97,163
3,270
54
60,634
1,771
3,344
313
7,027
414
1,729
338
976
153
2,583
16,218
155
744
15,488
4,185
204
3,630
2,441
0
5,261
5,611
6
0
0
7,122
1,300
650
432
16
0
0
40
0
9,695
0
0
0
147
0
0
275
4
4,487
0
439
Millwright
Miner
Motorman, cab driver
Music teacher
Musical instrument maker
Nursery man
Officer, Scientific Dept.
Officer, Education Dept.
Omnibus driver
Optician
Ornament makers
Pastoral laborer
Penal officer (skilled)
Penal officer (regular)
Pharmacist
Photographer
Pilot
Plasterer
Plumber
8,526
103,475
0
735
10
6,044
54
48
18
30
30
58
2,032
43
13
105
377
1092
0
0
0
905
735
1,162
6,725
246
368
2,649
525
292
57,843
52
755
3,810
1,923
262
3956
9440
89.2
125
105.26
156
906.9
86.3
125
498.5
136.76
107.68
721.1
202.5
225.7
208.5
137.5
89.2
148.6
432.5
202.5
145
137.5
122.6
650
106.4
50
83
69.89
103.58
49.2
202.5
90.81
72.9
480.97
138.44
50
96.28
163.3
70.65
137.5
304.8
171.4
113.81
210
131.9
93.7
87.58
62.22
252.1
211.8
210
101.5
587.5
587.5
154.7
210
210
52
304.8
128.6
122.6
250
275.3
125
130
139.44
67.4
390.1
305.2
102.72
139.44
139.44
34.5
120
92
90.4
166
41
Police officers (skilled)
Police officers (regular)
Porter, gate keeper
Postmaster, sorter
Poulterer
Printer
Quarry man
Railroad labor
Railway station master
Restaurant servant
Road laborer (navvy)
Rope/canvas maker
Sail maker
Sanitary inspector
Sawmill worker
Scientific instruments maker
Ship Master/Seaman
Shipwright
Shirt maker
Sick nurse
Silversmith
Slater, shingle
Smelter
Sports equipment maker
Stable keeper
Station agent
Stevedore, wharf labor
Steward
Store manager
Storekeeper
Street cleaner, chimney sweeper
Sugar laborer
Surgical instrument maker
Surveyor
Tanner, soap maker
Tea/coffee seller
Teachers
Telegraph- Stationmaster
Telephone officer
Textile worker
Tinsmith
Tobacconist
Tramway driver
Tutor
Typist
Umbrella maker
178
6,369
1,369
5,054
316
1,578
3,253
21594
8,789
3,480
27,026
161
375
367
4,450
57
11,621
2,774
259
23
2,610
486
5,271
169
1,580
3535
13,564
3,701
1,193
15,770
5,107
5,031
102
3,856
3,536
1,668
9,500
1943
2676
1,712
2,669
1,278
8738
998
3,346
182
0
0
17
2016
31
345
0
625
217
7,210
6
0
20
6
18
0
0
0
2,322
4,008
232
0
0
44
25
87
0
243
4
6,759
0
77
16
14
25
231
15,206
0
0
1,882
39
233
55
1,985
606
296
450
162.5
86.7
364.6
171.4
184.1
94
121
202.5
89.2
87.5
85.4
137
281.1
89
210
114
210
93.7
122.6
137.5
125
125
210
121
202.5
121
131
171.4
171.4
79
52
210
382
81
171.4
257.1
202.5
210
75
115
171.4
158.2
257.1
150
90
60
242.09
113.81
122.24
80.34
134.46
50
58.1
90.97
186.65
59.1
62.22
90.4
91.3
139.44
80.34
134.46
86.98
113.81
113.81
34.5
139.44
253.65
53.78
113.81
211.8
49.8
76.36
113.81
105.04
211.8
99.6
59.76
42
Professor
Veterinarian
Vineyard laborer
Watch maker
Waterman
Wheelwright
Wine seller
Wood chopper
Wool washer
Investment societies clerks
Bank clerks
Railway, tramway, shipping, telegraph clerks
Station clerk
233
406
2,121
1,830
479
2026
1,969
4,171
1809
111
8803
15006
1098
34
6
88
17
0
0
209
271
30
2
51
185
0
587.5
300
61.4
210
119.6
210
171.4
79
52
190
174
209
224.2
390.1
199.2
40.7
139.4
113.8
34.5
126.2
115.5
138.78
43
Table A6c: Australian earnings distribution by decile, 1910 (%)
Decile NSW LF weights AUS LF weights
1st
3.88
3.03
2nd
4.65
4.58
3rd
5.51
5.40
4th
6.57
6.07
5th
8.30
7.28
6th
9.49
7.65
7th
9.96
8.42
8th
11.26
11.16
9th
14.19
15.29
Top
26.16
31.11
44