Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
8784
Why Do Fiscal Multipliers Depend
on Fiscal Positions?
Raju Huidrom
M. Ayhan Kose
Jamus J. Lim
Franziska L. Ohnsorge
Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
Policy Research Working Paper
Macroeconomics, Trade and Investment Global Practice
March 2019
Policy Research Working Paper 8784
Abstract
The fiscal position can affect fiscal multipliers through two
channels. Through the Ricardian channel, households
reduce consumption in anticipation of future fiscal adjustments when fiscal stimulus is implemented from a weak
fiscal position. Through the interest rate channel, fiscal
stimulus from a weak fiscal position heightens investors’
concerns about sovereign credit risk, raises economy-wide
borrowing cost, and reduces private domestic demand. The
paper documents empirically the relevance of these two
channels using an Interactive Panel Vector Auto Regression
model. It finds that fiscal multipliers tend to be smaller
when fiscal positions are weak than strong.
This paper is a product of the Macroeconomics, Trade and Investment Global Practice. It is part of a larger effort by the
World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the
world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://www.worldbank.org/research. The authors
may be contacted at
[email protected],
[email protected],
[email protected], and
[email protected].
The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development
issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the
names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those
of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and
its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent.
Produced by the Research Support Team
Why Do Fiscal Multipliers Depend on Fiscal Positions? ∗
Raju Huidrom, M. Ayhan Kose, Jamus J. Lim, and Franziska L. Ohnsorge
Key Words: Fiscal multipliers, fiscal position, state-dependency, Ricardian channel, interest rate
channel, business cycle.
JEL Codes: E62, H50, H60
∗
Huidrom: International Monetary Fund;
[email protected]. Kose: World Bank, Prospects Group; Brookings
Institution; CEPR; and CAMA;
[email protected]. Lim: Essec Business School;
[email protected]. Ohnsorge:
World Bank, Prospects Group; and CAMA;
[email protected]. We greatly appreciate Ricardo Reis (editor) for
his detailed comments that significantly improved the paper. We also would like to thank referees for many useful
suggestions. Earlier drafts benefited from comments by S. Amer Ahmed, Jean-Louis Arcand, Raphael Espinoza,
Alejandro Izquierdo, Aart Kraay, Sergio Kurlat, Jaime Marquez, Rahul Mukherjee, Ugo Panizza, Assaf Razin, Naotaka
Sugawara, Luis Serven, Cedric Tille, Carlos Vegh, Guillermo Vuletin, Sebastian Weber, Kei-Mu Yi, Hakan
Yilmazkuday, Charles Wyplosz, and seminar participants at the Graduate Institute-Geneva, the 2015 Midwest Macro
Conference, and the 2016 Conference on Fiscal Policy and the Macroeconomy at Johns Hopkins SAIS. We thank Kiwako
Sakamoto for excellent research assistance. Ethan Ilzetski kindly shared data. The findings, interpretations, and
conclusions expressed in this paper are those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the
institutions they are affiliated with.
1. Introduction
During the Great Recession of 2008-09, many countries deployed fiscal policy to support activity.
As a result, government debt increased in a number of countries, and it remains elevated (Kose
et al., 2017). There is mounting empirical evidence that weak fiscal positions erode the
effectiveness of fiscal policy in stimulating the economy, although the channels through which this
mechanism operates have not yet been systematically explored. The objective of this paper is to
fill this gap in the literature by answering the question: why do fiscal multipliers depend on fiscal
positions?
In theory, the fiscal position can affect the size of fiscal multipliers through two specific channels.
First, a Ricardian channel: when a government with a weak fiscal position implements fiscal
stimulus, households expect tax increases sooner than in an economy with a strong fiscal position
(Blanchard 1990a and 1990b; Sutherland 1997). The perceived negative wealth effect leads
households to cut consumption and save more, thereby weakening the impact of the stimulus on
output. Thus, the net effect of fiscal policy on output—the size of the fiscal multiplier—may be
smaller in an economy with a weaker fiscal position. Second, an interest rate channel: when the
fiscal position is weak, fiscal stimulus can increase lenders’ concerns about sovereign credit risk.
This raises sovereign bond yields and hence, borrowing costs across the whole economy (Corsetti
et al. 2013). This, in turn, crowds out private investment and consumption, reducing the size of
the fiscal multiplier. Therefore, in theory, both channels imply that fiscal policy is less effective
when fiscal stimulus is implemented from a weak initial fiscal position. 1
To analyze the relevance of the channels through which the fiscal position affects fiscal multipliers,
we use an Interacted Panel Vector Autoregressive (IPVAR) model. The model is essentially an
extension of an otherwise standard panel structural VAR (SVAR), with the distinction that the
VAR coefficients interact with (observable) state variables. Consequently, these coefficients
become time-varying, and evolve endogenously according to these states. This results in a
framework where the VAR dynamics and hence, the fiscal multipliers are conditional on the state
variables which we take to be the fiscal position. 2 Since the state-dependency is captured by
making use of the full sample, the model allows us to maintain sufficient degrees of freedom to
draw sharp inferences. It also allows us to trace out the fiscal multipliers as a function of a
continuum of government debt, rather than relative to ad hoc debt thresholds. In addition, our
framework extends the suite of models – from Smooth Transition Regressions (Auerbach and
Gorodnichenko 2012) or local projections (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2013, Riera-Crichton,
Vegh and Vuletin 2015) – that are used in the literature to estimate state-dependent multipliers.
Applying our empirical methodology to a large dataset that covers 34 countries (19 advanced and
15 developing), at the quarterly frequency over the period 1980:1 to 2014:1, we first establish that
the fiscal position helps determine the size of the fiscal multipliers: estimated multipliers are
systematically smaller when the fiscal position is weak (i.e. government debt is high). We then
In a theoretical model, Sutherland (1997) formalizes the Ricardian channel by postulating that there exists a debt
threshold at which the government makes fiscal adjustments, via increasing taxes, to remain solvent. Thus, households
expect higher taxes to be more imminent when the government conducts an expansionary fiscal policy from a high
initial level of debt. In Perotti (1999), such expectations of higher taxes can also result in increased tax distortions
which are an additional source of negative wealth effects. With regard to the interest rate channel, Bi, Shen, and Yang
(2014) theoretically establish that sovereign risk premia can increase nonlinearly as government indebtedness rises.
Corsetti et al. (2013) highlight that the interest rate is particularly relevant for the effectiveness of fiscal policy when
monetary policy is constrained, for instance during a zero lower bound episode.
2
The model was originally used to estimate the impact of exchange rate fluctuations on output conditioning on foreign
currency debt and import structure (Towbin and Weber 2013) or to estimate the impact of capital flows on OECD
housing markets conditioning on mortgage market characteristics (Sa, Towbin, and Wieladek 2014).
1
1
employ a model that includes both the Ricardian and interest rate channels to provide evidence
that such state-dependent effects operate through these two channels. In particular, we show that
when a government with weak public finances conducts expansionary fiscal policy, the private
sector scales back on consumption in anticipation of future tax pressures (Ricardian channel) and
risk premia rise on mounting concerns about sovereign risk (interest rate channel).
Our paper presents the first systematic empirical study on the relevance of the two theoretical
channels through which the fiscal position affects the size of fiscal multipliers. It builds on two
interrelated branches of the literature. The first branch focuses on the importance of fiscal
positions for fiscal multipliers. Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), Nickel and Tudyka (2014),
and Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012 and 2013) estimate multipliers that depend on the fiscal
position and find that weaker fiscal positions are associated with smaller fiscal multipliers.
However, none of these studies examines jointly the two channels through which the fiscal position
affects multipliers.
The other branch of the literature considers the relevance of the two channels. Blanchard (1990a)
sketches out a theoretical model of Ricardian consumers who, after a fiscal stimulus, cut back
consumption in anticipation of future tax hikes. Others document empirically that the effect of
government spending shocks on private consumption depends on government debt (Perotti 1999,
Giavazzi and Pagano 1990 and 1996). However, none of these studies present a systematic
empirical assessment of implications for the channels as well as output.
Our paper extends the limited set of studies on the Ricardian channel in several dimensions. First,
the IPVAR, unlike panel regressions, is a multivariate model that allows us to trace the dynamic
effects of fiscal shocks not only on private consumption—as a mechanism for a government’s fiscal
position to matter for multipliers—but also on output. Second, we employ a model that allows us
to examine the relevance of the Ricardian and interest rate channels together in a much larger
sample of countries and longer series.
A couple of recent studies examine the interest rate channel. Corsetti et al. (2013) model the role
of investor perceptions of sovereign risks and, calibrating their dynamic stochastic general
equilibrium model to the United States, illustrate smaller fiscal multipliers when government debt
is high. Bocola (2016), using a structural model, estimates that a higher probability of sovereign
default raised risk premia for corporate lending and reduced credit to firms in Italy during the
sovereign debt crisis. These studies illustrate the workings of the interest rate channel, i.e. how
output effects of fiscal stimulus could be eroded during times of high debt. Our reduced-form
approach contributes to this literature by providing an empirical assessment of the interest rate
channel for a wide range of countries in a model that also includes the Ricardian channel.
Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2017) take the first step towards exploring the interest rate channel
by estimating the impact of fiscal policy shocks on activity and credit default swap spreads (not
on private consumption) in a local projections model for a sample of 20 OECD countries. They
report no statistically significant difference between fiscal multipliers depending on government
debt. Nor do they find a statistically significant effect of fiscal stimulus on credit risk premia but
rather a statistically significant decline in short-term interest rates. They interpret this as evidence
that fiscal stimulus remains an effective tool for boosting growth and that the penalty from rising
borrowing cost is small. The divergence in the results of Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2017)
from those in Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013) may reflect two factors. First, Auerbach and
Gorodnichenko (2017) add a number of control variables, such as interest rates, that may reduce
degrees of freedom, introduce multicollinearity with credit spreads and lower the statistical
significance of the estimated response of credit spreads. Second, they redefine the conditioning
2
variable as demeaned government debt (instead of government debt) and, thus, remove all crosscountry variation from a variable that, to begin with, has limited across-time variation.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the econometric methodology,
identification strategy, and database. We present estimates of state-dependent multipliers in
Section 3.1 and analyze the roles of the Ricardian and the interest rate channels in Section 3.2.
Section 4 discusses a rich menu of robustness exercises. Section 5 concludes.
2. Empirical Methodology and Database
Our empirical approach requires several choices that may affect the results. These are explained
in this section, together with a discussion of our database.
2.1. Econometric Model: We use an Interacted Panel Vector Autoregressive (IPVAR) model where
the main innovation, with respect to a standard panel SVAR, is that the model coefficients vary
deterministically according to conditioning (state) variables. By choosing the conditioning variable
to be a measure of fiscal position in the IPVAR, we estimate multipliers that depend on the fiscal
position. The IPVAR model, in its structural form, is represented by:
1
⎡𝛼𝛼 21
⎢ 0,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
31
⎢𝛼𝛼0,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
⎢ 41
⎣𝛼𝛼0,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
0
1
32
𝛼𝛼0,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
42
𝛼𝛼0,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
0
0
1
43
𝛼𝛼0,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
11
𝛼𝛼𝑙𝑙,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
0 𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
⎡
0⎤ 𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔
𝛼𝛼 21
⎥
𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
𝐿𝐿 ⎢ 𝑙𝑙,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
∑
�
�
=
𝑙𝑙=1 ⎢
0⎥ 𝑔𝑔𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
⋮
⎥ 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟
⎢
41
𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
1⎦
⎣𝛼𝛼𝑙𝑙,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
12
𝛼𝛼𝑙𝑙,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
22
𝛼𝛼𝑙𝑙,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
⋮
42
𝛼𝛼𝑙𝑙,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
⋯
⋯
⋱
⋯
14
𝛼𝛼𝑙𝑙,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
⎤ 𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−𝑙𝑙
24
𝛼𝛼𝑙𝑙,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
⎥ 𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−𝑙𝑙
34 ⎥ � 𝑔𝑔𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−𝑙𝑙 � + 𝑋𝑋𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝐹𝐹 + 𝑈𝑈𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ,
𝛼𝛼𝑙𝑙,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
⎥ 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟
44
𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−𝑙𝑙
𝛼𝛼𝑙𝑙,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
⎦
(1)
where for a given country i in period t, gc represents real government consumption, gdp real gross
domestic product (GDP), reer the real effective exchange rate, and ca the current account balance
(as a share of GDP).
We take government consumption as the fiscal instrument and track the effects of fiscal policy in
terms of GDP. The real effective exchange rate and the current account are also included in the
model to account for open-economy features that characterize most of the countries in our sample.
The matrix X captures additional controls, which include time-invariant country fixed effects, and
U is a vector of uncorrelated, i.i.d. (structural) shocks. The shock corresponding to government
consumption is the fiscal shock. We set the lag length as L = 4 which is standard for VAR models
with quarterly data but we also test for robustness to different lag lengths in Section 4.
The impact matrix 𝐴𝐴0 (matrix of coefficients on the left-hand side of Equation (1)) is lower
triangular. This, along with the ordering of the variables in the VAR, is related to our
identification scheme (discussed below). Both the impact matrix 𝐴𝐴0 and the coefficient matrices
𝐴𝐴𝑙𝑙 , 𝑙𝑙 = 1, … , 𝐿𝐿 (on the right-hand side of Equation (1)) comprise time-varying model coefficients
that, for any given entry in row 𝑗𝑗 and column 𝑘𝑘 , evolve deterministically according to:
𝑗𝑗𝑗𝑗
𝑗𝑗𝑗𝑗
𝑗𝑗𝑗𝑗
𝛼𝛼𝑙𝑙,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 = 𝛽𝛽1,𝑙𝑙 + 𝛽𝛽2,𝑙𝑙 𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ,
3
(2)
𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 refers to the fiscal position. 3 Our measure of the fiscal position is the government debt-to-GDP
ratio. While the literature has used a variety of measures, our choice is in line with theoretical
models, where government debt is the modal state variable (as discussed below). 4 Since measures
of the fiscal position are endogenous and move in tandem with the business cycle, we take lagged
moving averages of our fiscal measures to control for business cycle effects. 5
The matrices 𝐴𝐴𝑙𝑙 , 𝑙𝑙 = 1, … , 𝐿𝐿 determine the effects of structural shocks on the dynamics of
endogenous variables in the VAR system. By conditioning the law of motion of the coefficients in
these matrices on the fiscal position, as in Equation (2), we are allowing those effects to depend
on the fiscal position. This scheme allows us to calculate impulse responses and hence estimates
of fiscal multipliers conditional on a specific fiscal position.
As standard in the literature, we compute the cumulative fiscal multiplier at horizon T as the
discounted cumulative change in output until horizon 𝑇𝑇, as the discounted cumulative government
consumption increases by one unit. That is,
𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑙𝑙𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑔𝑔𝑙𝑙𝑀𝑀𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 (𝑇𝑇) =
−𝑡𝑡
∑𝑇𝑇
𝑡𝑡=0(1+𝑟𝑟) ∆𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡
−𝑡𝑡
∑𝑇𝑇
𝑡𝑡=0(1+𝑟𝑟) ∆𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡
,
(3)
where 𝑟𝑟 denotes the interest rate. We utilize the median short-term rate in the sample.
From (3), the impact multiplier is obtained by setting 𝑇𝑇 = 0 and the long-run multiplier by setting
T at an arbitrarily large number, which is taken to be 𝑇𝑇 = 20 (5 years). To calculate the fiscal
multiplier using the coefficient estimates from the IPVAR, we first cumulate the discounted
impulses of output and government consumption at different horizons and compute the ratio of
the two impulses. That ratio is then multiplied by the average government consumption-to-GDP
ratio in the sample to yield multipliers. Since the conditional multipliers are estimated from the
panel of countries, they reflect an average estimate across those countries included in the panel.
Thus, we use the average government consumption-to-GDP ratio in the sample to calculate the
multipliers rather than country-specific government consumption-to-GDP ratios.
Equations (1) and (2) jointly denote the IPVAR system that is estimated with ordinary least
squares (OLS) applied separately to each equation. 6 This yields model coefficients that depend on
the fiscal position such that a given level of the fiscal position maps out to a set of model
coefficients. For presenting the results, we evaluate model coefficients at specific values of the
fiscal position which are mostly taken to be the 10th and 90th percentiles within the sample.
Confidence bands are calculated by bootstrapping over 300 iterations. We report median
estimates, along with the 16 - 84 percent confidence bands.
3
Including the fiscal position in the law of motion in Equation (2) is tantamount to having interaction terms with the
fiscal position in the regressors of Equation (1). For this reason, we do not separately include the fiscal position as an
endogenous variable in the IPVAR.
4
For instance, while Riera-Crichton, Vegh, and Vuletin (2015) condition multipliers on fiscal balances, Auerbach and
Gorodnichenko (2013), Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), and Nickel and Tudyka (2014) condition on government
debt.
5
In particular, we take the 5-quarter moving average of the fiscal position, and then lag it by 2 quarters. Given the
average length of the business cycle, this effectively allows us to abstract from changes in the fiscal state that may
potentially be contaminated by cyclical movements. We allay any residual endogeneity concerns by jointly conditioning
on the fiscal position and the phase of the business cycle below.
6
Because the error terms are uncorrelated across equations by construction, estimating the IPVAR equation by equation
does not result in loss of efficiency. See Towbin and Weber (2013) for a discussion.
4
2.2. Choice of Fiscal Instrument and Fiscal Position: Our selection of government consumption as
the fiscal instrument reflects several considerations. Government consumption is a subset of the
much broader measure of government spending that strips out the automatic stabilizers
component, and hence represents discretionary fiscal policy. We recognize, however, that
government consumption plays a modest role in large discretionary fiscal stimulus programs, such
as those implemented in 2008-10, or discretionary consolidation packages. Such large packages,
on the spending side, are often predominantly based on government investment and transfers
(OECD 2009). Government investment could be an ideal fiscal instrument, in principle, to model
large discretionary policies but, in practice, available quarterly data is insufficient to establish
robust results. In addition, in our sample, government investment is relatively small, averaging
only about one-quarter of government consumption. Hence, we choose government consumption
as a fiscal instrument that is quantitatively large over the full sample period and available for
many economies. 7 On the tax side, the ideal measure to represent discretionary fiscal policy would
be tax rates. However, consistent measures of tax rates across countries are not readily available.
Tax revenues, even though they are easily available, are highly procyclical and less suitable for
our study.
Our selection of government debt as the conditioning state of fiscal position is motivated by the
fact that in theoretical dynamic models that feature a fiscal sector, government debt is a state
variable that enters as a lagged variable due to the flow budget constraint of the government
(Galí, López-Salido, and Vallés 2007; Forni, Monteforte, and Sessa 2009; Davig and Leeper 2011).
Moreover, in these models, nonlinear dynamics would depend on the initial state of government
debt (and other state variables in the model). By conditioning on debt, our empirical approach
attempts to match this theoretical aspect, and measures the effects of fiscal shocks conditional on
the initial level of government debt.
The IPVAR model does not allow for endogenous feedback loops after the fiscal shock. Such
feedback loops could be an important consideration because debt dynamics can feed into
government spending, especially during times of unstable debt (Favero and Giavazzi 2007). Thus,
the omission of such endogenous feedback loops could bias multipliers, even though the direction
and the size of the bias is hard to pin down since multipliers are a function of both government
spending and output. That said, any bias is likely to be larger over longer time horizons because
debt stocks move slowly. Hence, we focus our analysis on shorter-run multipliers, i.e. multipliers
up to two years. We also conduct a robustness exercise in Section 4 to analyze the impact of debt
dynamics on our findings.
2.3. Identification: Given the challenges associated with identification of fiscal shocks, we consider
a multi-pronged approach to identification. First, we carefully motivate our baseline identification
that follows the standard Blanchard-Perotti scheme. Second, we consider an alternative
identification following Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013) to check the robustness of our
headline findings. Third, we consider alternative identifications and explain why we are unable to
employ them in our exercise.
Baseline identification. Our baseline estimation relies on the standard recursive identification
scheme of Blanchard and Perotti (2002). The key timing assumption in this scheme is that
discretionary fiscal policy does not respond to macroeconomic conditions within the same quarter.
Such a timing assumption can be motivated by implementation lags typically associated with
Government consumption is also chosen by Ilzetzki, Mendoza and Vegh (2013), Nickell and Tudyka (2014), and
Corsetti et al. (2012) whereas Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013 and 2017) use the sum of government consumption
and investment, but for a smaller sample of countries.
7
5
discretionary fiscal policy. In the VAR model, this timing assumption is achieved by ordering
government consumption first in Equation (1), before GDP.
Since the IPVAR model conditions its dynamics on government debt, it is important to
understand how debt dynamics could perturb the identifying assumption for government
consumption and output. There are two key issues in this context. First, we are implicitly
assuming that the lagged response of government consumption to macroeconomic conditions does
not depend on the initial level of government debt. 8 Second, debt dynamics, as mentioned earlier,
can feed into government consumption and output and hence can affect the timing assumption.
However, given the slow-moving nature of debt and given that Blanchard and Perotti (2002) is
essentially a short-run identification, concerns about misidentification due to the absence of
feedback loops are limited, at least in the short run.
The timing assumption for the remaining variables is the following. Output is assumed to be,
contemporaneously, independent from real exchange rates and current account balances in the
same quarter. We assume that the output impact of current account balances and real effective
exchange rates takes at least one quarter to occur. We order current account balances before
exchange rates but the relative ordering of these two is immaterial for the results as we show in
Section 4.
To assess the relevance of the Ricardian and the interest rate channels, we augment the baseline
model with private consumption and CDS spreads. In the augmented model, we order private
consumption between government consumption and output, and CDS spreads last. This ordering
scheme preserves the lagged response of government consumption to output which is the key
identifying assumption of Blanchard-Perotti scheme. Ordering private consumption before output
assumes that private consumption contemporaneously affects output, while output affects private
consumption only with a lag of one quarter. The former is consistent with simple national account
identities, and the latter may be justified in terms of households adjusting their consumption
gradually to changes in incomes. Regarding CDS spreads, it is standard in the literature to order
interest rates and spreads last since they typically respond fastest (e.g. Gilchrist and Zakrajšek
2012).
One caveat of the recursive identification scheme is that the fiscal shocks identified using the
Blanchard-Perotti scheme may be predicted by private forecasts (Ramey 2011). Born, Juessen,
and Muller (2013), in the context of OECD countries, investigate this aspect formally by explicitly
controlling for anticipated changes in government spending using a panel VAR identified with a
similar timing assumption. While their model does not include interaction terms with government
debt, they find that explicitly controlling for anticipation effects has little bearing on fiscal
multipliers. Arguably, fiscal policy is particularly erratic in developing economies, which are
heavily represented in our sample; hence, our identified fiscal shocks are less likely to be affected
by anticipation issues (Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh 2013).
An alternative identification scheme. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012 and 2013) proxy
exogenous fiscal shocks by forecast errors of government consumption for OECD countries. This
alternative identification circumvents some of the caveats associated with recursive identification
and one that is available for a broad sample of OECD countries. As a robustness check in Section
4, we use the same approach and find broadly consistent results.
Auerbach and Gorodnochenko (2012) make a similar assumption: the lagged response of fiscal policy to macroeconomic
conditions, i.e. Blanchard-Perotti identification, holds irrespective of the phase of the business cycle.
8
6
Other possible identification approaches. For example, Favero and Giavazzi (2010) note that
impact estimates of fiscal policy are larger when fiscal shocks are identified in a narrative approach
than when they are identified in a VAR framework. Romer and Romer (2010) use a narrative
approach to identify exogenous fiscal shocks for the United States. For a broader set of countries,
Guajardo, Leigh, and Pescatori (2014) and Gupta et al. (2017) have compiled data for fiscal
consolidation episodes. However, we would not necessarily expect the interest rate channel,
especially, to operate during a fiscal consolidation if investors remain cautiously risk averse during
consolidations, whereas their risk aversion may lead them to respond sharply to fiscal stimulus.
Hence, a dataset of fiscal consolidations is less useful for our purposes.
2.4 Database: Our main database comprises an unbalanced panel that covers 34 countries (19
advanced and 15 developing), at the quarterly frequency over the period 1980:1 to 2014:1. Real
government consumption and real GDP are based on the quarterly database in Ilzetzki, Mendoza,
and Vegh (2013) which are extended to 2014:1 by splicing data from the OECD and Haver
Analytics. Real effective exchange rates are from the narrow (wherever available) and broad
indices of the BIS, and current account balances are from Haver Analytics. The short-term rate
used for discounting the multiplier is drawn mainly from the IMF-IFS database. We obtain
quarterly real private consumption and private investment series from the OECD, Haver
Analytics, and Eurostat. CDS spreads are in basis points and taken from Kose et al. (2017). We
draw the conditioning variable (government debt as percentage of GDP) from the IMF-WEO
database. 9 The government consumption, private consumption and GDP series are converted into
logarithmic form, and detrended using a linear quadratic trend. The exchange rate is transformed
into quarter-on-quarter growth rates, and the current account series is seasonally-adjusted using
the X11 routine. All these series are detrended and demeaned on a country-by-country basis,
which effectively controls for country fixed effects in the regressions.
3. Results
This section presents the results of our empirical exercise. We first document our evidence for the
presence of the Ricardian and interest rate channels. We also discuss the implications of these
channels for fiscal multipliers that are contingent on the initial fiscal position.
3.1 Fiscal Position-Dependent Multipliers: We first briefly present the set of estimated fiscal
multipliers that depend on government debt—our measure of the fiscal position. 10 Figure 1 shows
that there is a systematic link between the size of the multiplier and the fiscal position: the median
value of the multiplier decreases monotonically in debt, for all horizons reported. That is, the
estimated multipliers for all the horizons are positive and significant for low levels of debt, but
turn negative or insignificant when debt levels are high. For instance, the two-year multiplier is
about 0.6 when debt is low (10th percentile in the sample, i.e. a “strong” fiscal position) and nearzero when debt is high (90th percentile in the sample, i.e. “weak” fiscal position). The difference
in the estimated multipliers for low and high levels of debt remains significant at longer horizons.
Our empirical results therefore lend support to the theoretical insights of earlier studies which
show that a weak fiscal position can result in stronger crowding-out effects, blunting the
Details on the sample are provided in Table 1. The sources and definitions of our data are provided in the
Supplementary Appendix (Table A.1).
10
We also examine the unconditional multipliers using a standard panel SVAR. We provide details of these results in
the Supplementary Appendix Figure A.1 and A.2. The estimates suggest that unconditional multipliers are, on average,
insignificantly different from zero.
9
7
stimulative effects of fiscal policy (Sutherland 1997; Perotti 1999; Corsetti et al. 2013; Bi, Shen,
and Yang 2014).
We next examine the conditional impulse responses associated with expansionary fiscal policy in
Figure 2 to get a better understanding of the intuition behind these results. For the purpose of
illustration, we consider impulse responses conditional on two levels of debt: one corresponding to
the strong fiscal position and the other corresponds to the weak fiscal position. 11 For
comparability, the shock size in each case is normalized such that government consumption rises
by 1 percentage point on impact. While output increases on impact and remains significantly
positive for around 2 years when the fiscal position is strong, such stimulative effects dissipate
after about a year when the fiscal position is weak. In the case of government consumption, the
conditional impulses for both strong and weak fiscal positions exhibit some persistence in response
to the positive fiscal shock. However, fiscal expansion is more quickly unwound when the fiscal
position is strong than weak. In other words, relative to the strong fiscal position, the government
in fact spends more, especially initially, when the fiscal position is weak. Despite this, output falls
more when the fiscal position is weak. These results are consistent with findings of several other
empirical studies. For example, Ilzetzki, Mendoza and Vegh (2013) find that fiscal multipliers are
lower in countries with debt levels above 60 percent of GDP. Nickell and Tudyka (2014), using a
similar methodology to ours but with annual data, find that fiscal multipliers are larger in
advanced economies with lower debt. Using a local projections model for OECD countries,
Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013) also find that, pre-crisis, fiscal multipliers from aggregate
government consumption and investment shocks diminished, even in deep recessions, when
government debt rose. 12 While these studies document the importance of fiscal positions for fiscal
multipliers, they are silent about the empirical relevance of the theoretical channels through which
the fiscal position affects multipliers. In the next section, we extend our model to study the
relevance of the two channels in a unified framework.
3.2 Why Does The Fiscal Position Matter? Ricardian Channel and Interest Rate Channel
We explore the empirical relevance of the two channels through which fiscal positions may impact
fiscal multipliers: a Ricardian channel and an interest rate channel. The Ricardian channel has
been explored in an older literature on the impact of fiscal policy on private consumption (Giavazzi
and Pagano 1990, Blanchard 1990a and 1990b, Bertola and Drazen 1993, Perotti 1999). For
example, Giavazzi and Pagano (1990) argue that unexpectedly high consumption in Ireland and
Denmark in the late 1980s can partially be attributed to households’ response to government
spending cuts that signaled lower future tax burdens. Conversely, the decline in private
consumption following the large fiscal expansion in Sweden in the early 1990s may reflect similar
Ricardian considerations (Giavazzi and Pagano 1996). Perotti (1999), using a single-equation
framework with measures of fiscal position as interaction terms, estimates the impact of
government expenditures on private consumption in OECD countries during the three decades
ending in the mid-1990s, and finds that the impact varies with the initial level of government
debt. Compared to his work, the multivariate framework of the IPVAR allows us to evaluate how
fiscal position determines not only the fiscal impact on private consumption but also on output.
11
Figure A.3 in the Supplementary Appendix provides the distribution of government debt-to-GDP ratio in our sample.
Table A.2 provides the specific percentile values from the sample.
12
As noted earlier, Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2017) report no statistically significant difference between fiscal
multipliers depending on government debt in their sample of OECD countries. Similarly, using annual data, Corsetti,
Meier, and Muller (2012) find only statistically insignificant differences between fiscal multipliers depending on different
levels of debt (and a number of other conditioning variables). Their generally weak results may reflect the challenges
of using the timing assumption of Blanchard and Perotti (2002) for identifying fiscal shocks in annual data as discussed
in Perotti (2008).
8
We use the framework to bridge the response of consumption and output to fiscal shocks, thereby
explicitly establishing the relevance of Ricardian considerations (i.e. private consumption effects)
as a mechanism for a government’s fiscal position to matter for fiscal multipliers (i.e. output
effects). Moreover, we use a much broader sample of countries and cover more recent data than
Perotti (1999).
In theory, the interest rate channel operates through risk premia charged by risk averse investors.
For example, Corsetti et al. (2013) employ a DSGE model in which sovereign risk premia rise (i.e.
rising CDS spreads), in response to a deteriorating fiscal outlook of an economy (i.e. rising
government debt) which then raises the economy’s overall borrowing costs. The closer to sovereign
default, the greater the likelihood of tax increases and expenditure cuts that will erode firms’
profitability and households’ incomes. The resulting decline in private sector aggregate demand
reduces the size of the multiplier. Given these theoretical insights, our main contribution is to
provide an empirical assessment of the interest rate channel. 13
To show the relevance of the Ricardian and interest rate channels, we augment the baseline model
with private consumption and CDS spreads. As discussed in Section 2, we order private
consumption between government consumption and output, and CDS spreads last in the model.
Including both variables allows us to assess the relevance of the two channels together in a “joint”
model. However, the inclusion of CDS spreads significantly limits the sample: it removes
observations before 2003 and those for 5 countries. To assess the relevance of the Ricardian
channel, which can be studied using a larger sample, we also estimate the model with each channel
separately. In fact, the model with only the Ricardian channel results in about twice the number
of observations from the joint model that includes both channels. For these “separate” models,
we retain the respective ordering of private consumption and CDS spreads as in the joint model.
We find statistically significant evidence that both channels operate in our sample. The upper two
panels of Figure 3 show the impulse responses of private consumption and CDS spreads in response
to a positive government consumption shock. Again, economies with weak fiscal positions are
those with government debt in the 90th percentile in the sample; those with strong fiscal positions
are economies with government debt in the 10th percentile. A fiscal stimulus in an economy with
weak fiscal positions is associated with significantly lower private consumption for up to four years
whereas a stimulus in an economy with strong fiscal positions significantly lifts private
consumption for up to two years. The difference in the responses of private consumption is
statistically significant, in the second and third year after the fiscal stimulus. A fiscal stimulus
also raises CDS spreads significantly in an economy with weak fiscal positions for several years
after the stimulus. In contrast, in economies with strong fiscal positions, CDS spreads typically
do not respond statistically significantly to fiscal stimulus. Again, the difference between the
responses of CDS spreads across two fiscal positions is statistically significant.
The lower two panels of Figure 3 illustrate fiscal multipliers, on impact and after two years,
conditional on government debt. Impact fiscal multipliers range from about 0.2 for low government
debt to virtually nil when government debt is high. Over time, after two years, these multipliers
rise to 0.9 when government debt is low (in the 10th percentile) but about half as large (0.5) when
debt is high (in the 90th percentile). Allowing for feedback loops with government consumption
and CDS spreads has resulted in slightly larger fiscal multipliers when debt is low compared to
the model that does not include them (Figure 1). This reflects the boost to private consumption
that fiscal stimulus provides: when debt is low, there is limited need for precautionary household
There is a rich literature on the link between sovereign defaults and fiscal position, i.e. the level of debt (e.g. Arellano
2008; Mendoza and Yue 2012). Our paper studies how such linkages matter for the transmission of fiscal policy.
13
9
savings (the Ricardian channel) and for rising sovereign risk premia (the interest rate channel).
The differential impulse responses of private consumption and CDS spreads during times of high
and low debt, and the corresponding multiplier estimates together highlight the relevance of the
Ricardian and interest rate channels in explaining why government debt matters for the
magnitude of fiscal multipliers.
We then analyze the relevance of the Ricardian and the interest rate channels in models that are
separately estimated. The left panel of Figure 4 shows the impulse responses of private
consumption to a positive fiscal shock in a model that only includes private consumption (in
addition to the baseline variables). The right panel shows the corresponding impact on CDS
spreads in the model that only includes CDS spreads (in addition to the baseline variables). The
responses of private consumption and CDS spreads from separate models are strikingly similar to
those from the joint model (Figure 3). Private consumption falls when fiscal stimulus is
implemented amid weak fiscal positions and rises otherwise; CDS spreads rise following stimulus
amid weak fiscal positions and remain broadly constant otherwise. Compared with the response
from the joint model (in Figure 3), the response of CDS spreads to a fiscal shock is almost identical
in the separate model that excludes private consumption. In the broader sample that is
unconstrained by data requirements for CDS spreads, the responses of private consumption are
somewhat more muted but still statistically significantly different between strong and weak fiscal
positions. 14
4. Robustness Exercises
We consider a number of exercises to check the robustness of our headline findings about the
empirical relevance of the Ricardian and the interest rate channels: (i) alternative samples of
countries and time periods; (ii) changes in lag length; (iii) alternative ordering of some variables
in the IPVAR; (iv) alternative definition of fiscal position; (v) alternative identification scheme;
(vi) controlling for the phases of business cycles, financial crises, and exchange rate regimes; and
(vii) controlling for debt dynamics. As mentioned earlier, data for CDS spreads are sparse and
inclusion of CDS spreads in the joint model results in a significant loss of degrees of freedom. For
the subsamples, we employ the joint model but restrict our analysis to the advanced economies
and the post-crisis period. In some other robustness exercises, we employ the model with only the
Ricardian channel because of data limitations.
4.1. Alternative samples and changes in lag length: Figure 5 present the impulse responses of
private consumption and CDS spreads for weak and strong fiscal positions in different samples
and lag structures using the joint model that includes both private consumption and CDS
spreads. 15 Like before, weak and strong fiscal positions are taken to be government debt
corresponding to the 10th (strong) and 90th (weak) percentiles from the sample. 16 By and large,
our baseline results are qualitatively similar when the sample is restricted to advanced economies,
the post-crisis years from 2009 onwards, and when shorter or longer lags are considered. That is,
The corresponding impacts on output, i.e. fiscal multipliers, as estimated separately from the Ricardian model and
the interest rate model are also quite similar to the ones estimated from the joint model (Figure 3, panel (B)). More
importantly, fiscal multipliers remain dependent on government debt. See Figure A.4 in the Supplementary Appendix.
15
Figure A.5 in the Supplementary Appendix present additional findings.
16
To ensure that we are not reporting outliers, we also present results (in Figure A.5 in the Supplementary Appendix)
for alternative cut-offs: 25th percentile for low debt and 75th percentile for high debt.
14
10
impulse responses of private consumption are systematically weaker and those of CDS spreads
stronger for weak fiscal positions than for strong fiscal positions. 17
4.2. Alternative ordering of variables and definition of fiscal position: The ordering of government
consumption before output is key to the Blanchard and Perotti (2002) identification we used in
Section 3. Ordering CDS spreads last in VAR models is standard as well. Keeping these orderings
intact, we report results for alternative orderings among the rest of the model variables: ordering
private consumption after output, and current accounts after exchange rates. In addition, we
redefine the fiscal position of a country as the deviation of its government debt from the respective
group-specific or country-specific average which reflects a notion of fiscal position that is relative
to its peers or its historical average. The headline results hold for alternative orderings of model
variables or when the alternative measure of fiscal position is used. That said, in some instances
(except when restricting the sample to advanced economies and focusing on the post-crisis period),
the statistical significance of the difference between fiscal multipliers across different fiscal
positions naturally diminishes as degrees of freedom shrink. 18
4.3. Alternative identification scheme: We consider an alternative identification scheme based on
forecast errors as in Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013) and using the local projections model
to trace the effects of fiscal shocks. Fiscal shocks are based on the one-year ahead forecast errors
from the OECD’s semi-annual Economic Outlook, available for 19 advanced and emerging market
economies at semi-annual frequency during 2004H1-2011H2. We then trace the effects of these
shocks on key model variables using the local projections framework as in Jorda (2005).
Specifically, we estimate a single-equation model, using ordinary least squares, each for output,
private consumption, and CDS spreads. The model for output is:
Yi,t+h = αih + Πh(L) Yi,t-1 + Ψh(L) Gi,t-1 + Φ h(L) FEitG + Ηh (L)FEitG Qit-1 + µh Qit-1 + Ωh(L) Ci,t-1 +
Θh(L) CDSi,t-1 + uit
(5)
where Y is log real output, G is log real government consumption, C is real private consumption,
CDS is CDS spreads, FE is the unpredicted forecast error from OECD, and Q is government debt.
The model includes 2 lags (i.e. one year, since the data is semi-annual). The coefficients
(Φ + Ξ ∗ Q) represents an impulse response that traces out the impact of fiscal shocks on output
over the horizon h, conditional on government debt. As in Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013),
the forecast errors are defined as the unpredicted portion of the actual OECD forecast errors, i.e.
the residuals from a regression of OECD forecast errors on the other independent variables of
equation (5).
Figure 6 shows the impact of fiscal shocks on fiscal multipliers and on private consumption
conditional on fiscal positions, when fiscal shocks are identified as forecast errors of government
consumption. A weak fiscal position is defined as government debt in the 90th percentile of the
sample while a strong fiscal position is defined as government debt in the 10th percentile. As before,
the output response of fiscal shocks is smaller when fiscal positions are weaker. This is partly
attributable to a contraction in private consumption when a fiscal shock is implemented in a
country with a weak fiscal position. Our results also indicate that impulse responses of CDS
spreads are not meaningfully different when fiscal positions are weak or strong.
Figure A.6 in the Supplementary Appendix summarizes the estimates of fiscal multipliers that correspond to Figure
5 and Figure A.5 of the Supplementary Appendix. Again, the multipliers are systematically larger for low government
debt (strong fiscal position) than high government debt (weak fiscal position).
18
Results are shown in Figure A.7 of the Supplementary Appendix.
17
11
4.4. Business cycle phases, financial crises, and exchange rate regimes: Given theoretical and
empirical grounds that multipliers can be different across the phases of business cycles, during
financial crises, and across exchange rate regimes, we conduct additional exercises to check
whether our results are robust to controlling for these aspects. The fiscal position could be
systematically weaker during recessions than expansions. In that case, the effects we attribute to
the fiscal position would merely reflect well-established effects of business cycles on fiscal
multipliers (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2012 and 2013). For financial crises, specifically,
previous studies suggest that the correlation between financial crises and high debt episodes could
strengthen or weaken our results. The presence of credit constrained households and firms, caused
by disruptions in access to credit during crises, could be expected to raise fiscal multipliers. 19 In
this case, prima facie, financial crisis episodes should be episodes of large fiscal multipliers. On the
other hand, the presence of highly risk averse households that build precautionary savings in
financial crises could reduce fiscal multipliers (de Paoli and Zabcyk 2013). This would argue for
financial crises episodes being episodes of smaller fiscal multipliers. In flexible exchange rate
regimes, the exchange rate may act as a buffer to dampen output effects of fiscal shocks compared
with fixed exchange rate regimes.
The sparse data for CDS spreads—delaying the sample’s start to around 2003 (a period during
which exchange rate regimes were largely unchanged), and the recessions and financial crises to
the financial crisis and global recession of 2008-09—restricts our ability to conduct these additional
robustness exercises using the joint model. To relieve these degrees-of-freedom constraints, the
additional robustness tests were carried out by dropping CDS spreads from the model and
including only private consumption—i.e. we focus only on the Ricardian channel.
To estimate fiscal multipliers conditional on the fiscal position while controlling for business cycle
effects, we replace Equation (2) by the following expression that jointly conditions the model
coefficients on both the fiscal position and the business cycle state as follows:
𝑗𝑗𝑗𝑗
𝑗𝑗𝑗𝑗
𝑗𝑗𝑗𝑗
𝑗𝑗𝑗𝑗
𝛼𝛼𝑙𝑙,𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 = 𝛽𝛽1,𝑙𝑙 + 𝛽𝛽2,𝑙𝑙 𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝛽𝛽3,𝑙𝑙 𝑏𝑏𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ,
(6)
where bc is an indicator variable that equals 1 for recessions and 0 for expansions as determined
by the Harding-Pagan (2002) dating algorithm. 20 We undertake a similar approach to control for
financial crises and exchange rate regimes, and include the respective dummies in the equation
above. Financial crises are defined as in Laeven and Valencia (2013). The fixed exchange rate
regime is defined as in Ilzetzki, Mendoza and Vegh (2013), extended using the IMF’s de facto
exchange rate classification.
Figure 7 shows the impulse responses of private consumption in response to fiscal shocks in these
exercises. Private consumption responds more negatively to positive fiscal shocks when fiscal
positions are weak than when they are strong. The difference in private consumption response
between strong and weak fiscal positions is statistically significant at some intermediate horizons.
This suggests that the fiscal position genuinely represents a different conditioning state that
determines fiscal multipliers rather than capturing other correlates such as business cycle effects,
See Spilimbergo, Symanski, and Schindler (2009); Zubairy (2014); and Eggertsson and Krugman (2012).
In our sample, there is little overlap between recessions and high debt episodes. Recessions and weak fiscal positions
coincide in only 2 percent of observations (Table A.3 of Supplementary Appendix). On average, debt ratios also do not
differ meaningfully between economic expansions and recessions: The average debt-to-GDP ratio during economic
expansion is 52 percent, compared to 54 percent during recessions.
19
20
12
financial crises, and exchange rate regimes. 21 We also study the corresponding fiscal multipliers
on impact and after two years, depending on fiscal positions, in these exercises. 22 Fiscal multipliers,
especially at the two-year horizon, are larger in recessions than expansions, in crises than in noncrises, and in flexible exchange rate regimes than in fixed exchange rate regimes. These findings
are consistent with others in the literature (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2013; Bachmann and
Sims 2012; Candelon and Lieb 2013; Ilzetzki, Mendoza and Vegh 2013). The main takeaway from
these exercises is that fiscal multipliers remain debt-dependent: they are larger when fiscal
positions are strong, although sometimes not statistically significantly so.
4.5. Debt dynamics: As discussed in Section 2, our IPVAR framework considers the statedependent effects of initial level of government debt, but it does not allow for endogenous feedback
loops from government debt to model variables which could then result in biased estimates of
multipliers. Such feedback loops are, however, expected to play a significant role during times of
unstable debt. Thus, one way to guard against this potential bias is to estimate the model using
a sample that exhibits relatively stable debt dynamics. Accordingly, we present estimates for a
sub-sample of advanced economies during 1980-2006. 23 Our results indicate that, mitigating
concerns about potential biases caused by endogenous debt, multipliers are also larger when fiscal
positions are strong in a sample of advanced economies with low and stable debt. 24 In addition,
to check for potential nonlinearities in the role of government debt, we also estimate the joint
model by including quadratic debt (in place of linear debt) in the law of motion of the coefficients
(in Equation 6). Our headline result remains intact: fiscal multipliers are higher when fiscal
positions are strong than when positions are weak.
5. Comparison with previously estimated fiscal multipliers
Our results from the benchmark model suggest that two-year fiscal multipliers can range from nil
when government debt is high (in the 90th percentile, i.e. above 92 percent of GDP) to 0.6 when
government debt is low (in the 10th percentile, i.e. below 17 percent of GDP). When controlling
for both transmission channels, these multipliers rise somewhat to range from 0.5 when debt is
high to 0.9 when debt is low. During recessions, two-year fiscal multipliers in low-debt countries
can reach 1.5.
The magnitude of our estimated multipliers conditional on government debt is higher than
previous estimates, which are typically negative, when government debt is high and somewhat
lower when government debt is low (Table 2). Nickell and Tudyka (2014) estimate an impact
multiplier around 1.2 that fades gradually to near-zero if government debt remains below 60
percent of GDP. In contrast, at higher levels of government debt, the impact of stimulus on detrended GDP turns statistically significantly negative over the longer-term. Ilzetzki, Mendoza and
Vegh (2013) similarly estimate a negative cumulative longrun multiplier (of -3) when government
debt exceeds 60 percent of GDP and insignificantly different from zero when government debt is
lower. The findings of Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2017) contrast with these earlier studies
that find significantly negative fiscal multipliers if government debt is high. Auerbach and
Gorodnichenko (2017), while not providing explicit multiplier estimates, find that a 1 percent
When the model with the Ricardian channel only is estimated with the restricted sample of the joint model in section
3,2 and Figure 3, the results are broadly robust (see Supplementary Appendix Figure A.4).
22
We present these results in Supplementary Appendix Figures A.8 and A.9. As a benchmark, the first two columns
of Figure A.8 show the fiscal multipliers in the full sample, allowing only for Ricardian effects and disregarding the
interest rate channel (as in the left chart of Figure 4).
23
During 1980-2006, government debt in most advanced economies was on a broadly low and stable path. We remove
we remove Canada, Italy and Belgium that exhibited high debt levels throughout the sample period.
24
We present these results in Figure A.8 in the Supplementary Appendix.
21
13
increase in government spending raises real GDP statistically significantly over the long term
when government debt is at its (country-specific) minimum and has only insignificant effects when
government debt is at its (country-specific) maximum.
In general, these conditional multipliers suggested by our results as well as previous studies
conditioning on government debt are somewhat smaller than those estimated in studies that
condition on other factors (Table 2). Especially recent studies that condition on recessions have
found at times very large multipliers in advanced economies. Several have estimated peak fiscal
multipliers during recessions in the range of 3-4 (Bachmann and Sims 2012, Auerbach and
Gorodnichenko 2012 and 2013, Candelon and Lieb 2013). In a literature survey of earlier U.S.
evidence, Ramey (2011) puts multipliers during a severe recession “at the upper bound of this
[0.8-1.5] range,” notwithstanding considerable uncertainty about the estimates. Much of this
evidence rests on U.S. data. However, in Europe as well, during the 2009-11 recessions in the wake
of the global financial crisis, fiscal stimulus packages have been attributed with multipliers above
1 (Blanchard and Leigh 2014). 25 When we condition our multiplier estimates on recessions as well
as government debt, we also find that multipliers can be above 1, at least for countries in the
bottom quintile of government debt. 26
6. Conclusion
A growing literature has documented how weaker government finances reduce the effectiveness of
fiscal policy, i.e. fiscal multipliers. In this paper, we complement this literature by analyzing the
empirical relevance of the two theoretical channels through which the fiscal position impacts the
size of fiscal multipliers. Specifically, we study the Ricardian channel where households reduce
consumption in anticipation of future fiscal adjustments during times of high debt; and the interest
rate channel where increased investors’ perception of credit risks, raises sovereign credit risk and
economy-wide borrowing cost, thereby weakening private domestic demand. We deploy an
empirical model that allows us to trace the effects of fiscal shocks not only on private consumption
and CDS spreads (as a measure of risk premia) but also on output. By bridging the response of
consumption, CDS spreads and output to fiscal shocks, we explicitly establish the relevance of
Ricardian and interest rate considerations (i.e. private consumption and borrowing cost effects)
as the two channels for a government’s fiscal position to matter for fiscal multipliers (i.e. output
effects). We also undertake a wide range of exercises to show the robustness of our findings with
respect to the relevance of these channels.
Future research can usefully focus on three issues. First, while some earlier theoretical studies
considered each channel separately, there has been no study exploring how the two channels
operate jointly in a general equilibrium framework. This type of work could provide insights about
the relative strength of each channel in response to different types of shocks. Second, one could
study whether the two channels function differently in open economies in the context of a multicountry DSGE model. Finally, it would be useful to study the relevance of the two channels in a
framework that allows fiscal-monetary policy interactions. In particular, one can assess how the
use of monetary policy affects the roles of the two channels during periods of weak fiscal position.
Conversely, OECD fiscal consolidation packages have been estimated to have long-term multipliers close to 2
(Favero, Giavazzi and Perego 2011).
26
Four EU countries in the sample entered the 2008-09 recession with general government debt in the bottom quintile
of the sample.
25
14
References
Alesina, A., C. Favero and F. Giavazzi. 2015. “The Output Effect of Fiscal Consolidation Plans.”
Journal of International Economics 96: S19-S42.
Arellano, C. 2008. “Default Risk and Income Fluctuations in Emerging Economies.” American
Economic Review 98(3): 690–712.
Auerbach, A. J., and Y. Gorodnichenko. 2012. “Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal
Policy.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4(2): 1–27.
Auerbach, A. J., and Y. Gorodnichenko. 2013. “Fiscal Multipliers in Recession and Expansion.”
In Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis, edited by A. Alesina and F. Giavazzi, 63–98. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Auerbach, A. J., and Y. Gorodnichenko. 2017. “Fiscal Stimulus and Fiscal Sustainability.” NBER
Working Paper 23789, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge.
Bachmann, R., and E. R. Sims. 2012. “Confidence and the Transmission of Government Spending
Shocks.” Journal of Monetary Economics 59(3): 235–249.
Bertola, G., and A. Drazen. 1993. “Trigger Points and Budget Cuts: Explaining the Effects of
Fiscal Austerity.” American Economic Review 83(1): 11–26
Bi, H., W. Shen, and S.-C. S. Yang. 2014. “Fiscal Limits, External Debt, and Fiscal Policy in
Developing Countries.” IMF Working Paper 14/49, International Monetary Fund, Washington,
DC.
Blanchard, O. J. 1990a. “Comment: Can Severe Fiscal Contractions Be Expansionary? Tales of
Two Small European Countries.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1990, Volume 5, edited by
O. J. Blanchard and S. Fischer, 111–116. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Blanchard, O. J. 1990b. “Suggestions for a New Set of Fiscal Indicators.” OECD Economics
Department Working Paper 79, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.
Blanchard, O.J. and D. Leigh. 2013. “Growth Forecast Errors and Fiscal Multipliers.” American
Economic Review 103(3): 117-20.
Blanchard, O., and R. Perotti. 2002. “An Empirical Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of
Changes in Government Spending and Taxes on Output.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4):
1329–1368.
Bocola, L. 2016. “The Pass-Through of Sovereign Risks.” Journal of Political Economy 124(4):
879–926.
Born, B., F. Juessen, and G. J. Müller. 2013. “Exchange Rate Regimes and Fiscal Multipliers.”
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37(2): 446–465.
Candelon, B., and L. Lieb. 2013. “Fiscal Policy in Good and Bad Times.” Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control 37(12): 2679–2694.
Corsetti, G., K. Kuester, A. Meier, and G. J. Müller. 2013. “Sovereign Risk, Fiscal Policy, and
Macroeconomic Stability.” Economic Journal 123(566): F99–F132.
Corsetti, G., A. Meier, and G. J. Müller. 2012. “Fiscal Stimulus with Spending Reversals.” Review
of Economics and Statistics 94(4): 878–895.
Davig, T., and E. M. Leeper. 2011. “Monetary–Fiscal Policy Interactions and Fiscal Stimulus.”
European Economic Review 55(2): 211–227.
15
De Paoli, B., and P. Zabczyk. 2013. “Cyclical Risk Aversion, Precautionary Saving, and Monetary
Policy.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 45(1): 1–36.
Eggertsson, G. B., and P. Krugman. 2012. “Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A FisherMinsky-Koo Approach.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 127(3): 1469–1513.
Fatás, A. and I. Mihov. 2009. “Why Fiscal Stimulus is Likely to Work.” International Finance
12(1): 57-73.
Favero, C., and F. Giavazzi. 2007. “Debt and the Effects of Fiscal Policy.” NBER Working Paper
12822, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge.
Favero, C. A., and F. Giavazzi. 2010. “Reconciling VAR-Based and Narrative Measures of the
Tax-Multiplier.” CEPR Discussion Paper 7769, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.
Favero, C., F. Giavazzi and J. Perego. 2011. “Country Heterogeneity and the International
Evidence on the Effects of Fiscal Policy.” IMF Economic Review 59(4): 652-682.
Forni, L., L. Monteforte, and L. Sessa. 2009. “The General Equilibrium Effects of Fiscal Policy:
Estimates for the Euro Area.” Journal of Public Economics 93(3–4): 559–585.
Galí, J., J. D. López-Salido, and J. Vallés. 2007. “Understanding the Effects of Government
Spending on Consumption.” Journal of the European Economic Association 5(1): 227–270.
Giavazzi, F., and M. Pagano. 1990. “Can Severe Fiscal Contractions Be Expansionary? Tales of
Two Small European Countries.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1990, Volume 5, edited by
O. J. Blanchard and S. Fischer, 75–111. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Giavazzi, F., and M. Pagano. 1996. “Non-Keynesian Effects of Fiscal Policy Changes:
International Evidence and the Swedish Experience.” Swedish Economic Policy Review 3(1): 67–
103.
Gilchrist, S., and E. Zakrajšek. 2012. “Credit Spreads and Business Cycle Fluctuations.” American
Economic Review 102(4): 1692–1720.
Guajardo, J., D. Leigh, and A. Pescatori. 2014. “Expansionary Austerity? International
Evidence.” Journal of the European Economic Association 12(4): 949–968.
Gupta, S., J. T. Jalles, C. Mulas-Granados, and M. Schena. 2017. “Governments and Promised
Fiscal Consolidations: Do They Mean What They Say?” IMF Working Paper 17/39, International
Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Harding, D., and A. Pagan. 2002. “Dissecting the Cycle: A Methodological Investigation.” Journal
of Monetary Economics 49(2): 365–381.
Ilzetzki, E., E. G. Mendoza, and C. A. Végh. 2013. “How Big (Small?) are Fiscal Multipliers?”
Journal of Monetary Economics 60(2): 239–254.
Jordà, Ò. 2005. “Estimation and Inference of Impulse Responses by Local Projections.” American
Economic Review 95(1): 161–182.
Kose, M. A., S. Kurlat, F. Ohnsorge, and N. Sugawara. 2017. “A Cross-Country Database of
Fiscal Space.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 8157, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Laeven, L., and F. Valencia. 2013. “Systemic Banking Crises Database.” IMF Economic Review
61(2): 225–270.
Mendoza, E. G., and V. Z. Yue. 2012. “A General Equilibrium Model of Sovereign Default and
Business Cycles.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 127(2): 889–946.
16
Mountford, A. and H. Uhlig. 2009. “What Are The Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks?” Journal of
Applied Econometrics 24(6): 960-992.
Nickel, C., and A. Tudyka. 2014. “Fiscal Stimulus in Times of High Debt: Reconsidering
Multipliers and Twin Deficits.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 46(7): 1313–1344.
OECD. 2009. OECD Economic Outlook: Interim Report. March. Paris: Organisation for Economic
Co-operation and Development.
Perotti, R. 1999. “Fiscal Policy in Good Times and Bad.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(4):
1399–1436.
Perotti, R. 2008. “In Search of the Transmission Mechanism of Fiscal Policy.” In NBER
Macroeconomics Annual 2007, Volume 22, edited by D. Acemoglu, K. Rogoff, and M. Woodford,
169–226. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Perotti, R. 2011. “Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation.” IGIER Working
Paper 429, Bocconi University, Milan, Italy.
Ramey, V. A. 2011. “Identifying Government Spending Shocks: It’s All in the Timing.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 126(1): 1–50.
Riera-Crichton, D., C. A. Vegh, and G. Vuletin. 2015. “Procyclical and Countercyclical Fiscal
Multipliers: Evidence from OECD Countries.” Journal of International Money and Finance 52:
15–31.
Romer, C. D., and D. H. Romer. 2010. “The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: Estimates
Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks.” American Economic Review 100(3): 763–801.
Sá, F., P. Towbin, and T. Wieladek. 2014. “Capital Inflows, Financial Structure and Housing
Booms.” Journal of the European Economic Association 12(2): 522–546.
Spilimbergo, A., S. Symansky, and M. Schindler. 2009. “Fiscal Multipliers.” IMF Staff Position
Note 09/11, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Sutherland, A. 1997. “Fiscal Crises and Aggregate Demand: Can High Public Debt Reverse the
Effects of Fiscal Policy?” Journal of Public Economics 65(2): 147–162.
Towbin, P., and S. Weber. 2013. “Limits of Floating Exchange Rates: The Role of Foreign
Currency Debt and Import Structure.” Journal of Development Economics 101: 179–194.
Zubairy, S. 2014. “On Fiscal Multipliers: Estimates from a Medium Scale DSGE Model.”
International Economic Review 55(1): 169–195.
17
Figure 1: Fiscal Position-Dependent Multipliers
A. On Impact
B. 1 Year
0.3
0.6
0.2
0.4
0.1
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.1
24.8
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
65.5
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
24.8
80.5
32.2
C. 2 Years
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
65.5
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
80.5
D. Long Run
0.9
1.6
0.6
0.8
0.3
0.0
0.0
-0.8
-0.3
-1.6
-0.6
-2.4
24.8
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
65.5
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
80.5
24.8
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
65.5
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
80.5
Note: The graphs show the conditional fiscal multipliers for different levels of fiscal position at select horizons. Fiscal multipliers are defined as
cumulative change in output relative to cumulative change in government consumption in response to a 1 unit government consumption shock.
They are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. Government debt as a
percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position and the values shown on the x-axis correspond to the 10th to 90th percentiles from the sample.
Fiscal position is strong (weak) when government debt is low (high). Solid lines represent the median, and dotted bands are the 16-84 percent
confidence bands.
18
Figure 2: Conditional Impulse Responses
A. Government Consumption
B. GDP
0.2
1.2
1.0
0.1
Weak fiscal position
0.8
Strong fiscal position
0.0
0.6
0.4
-0.1
0.2
-0.2
0.0
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
-0.2
-0.3
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
Note: The graphs show the conditional impulse responses (deviation from baseline in percentage points) for strong (blue) and weak (red) fiscal
positions. These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. Government
debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP
ratio from the sample, while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Solid lines represent the median, and dotted bands are
the 16-84 percent confidence bands.
19
Figure 3: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Joint Model
Private Consumption
A. Impulse Responses
0.3
70
0.2
60
CDS
50
0.1
40
0.0
30
-0.1
20
10
-0.2
0
-0.3
-10
-0.4
Weak fiscal position
-20
Strong fiscal position
Weak fiscal position
-30
-0.5
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Strong fiscal position
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
B. Multipliers
On Impact
2 Years
0.6
1.6
0.4
1.2
0.2
0.8
0.0
0.4
-0.2
0.0
-0.4
-0.4
23.1
32.0
38.5
42.8
47.4
54.6
63.8
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
23.1
76.7
32.0
38.5
42.8
47.4
54.6
63.8
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
76.7
Note: The upper graphs show the conditional impulse responses (deviation from baseline in percentage points) for strong (blue) and weak (red)
fiscal positions. The lower graphs show the fiscal multipliers on impact and after two years (cumulative change in output relative to cumulative
change in government consumption after a fiscal shock) by government debt, ranging from the 10th to the 90th percentile of government debt in
the sample. These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. Government
debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio
from the sample, while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Solid lines represent the median, and dotted bands are the 1684 percent confidence bands.
20
Figure 4: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Impulse Responses in Separate Models
A. Private Consumption
B. CDS
80
0.2
60
0.1
40
0.0
20
-0.1
0
-0.2
-20
Weak fiscal position
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Strong fiscal position
-40
-0.3
1
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
Note: The graphs show the conditional impulse responses (deviation from baseline in percentage points) for strong (blue) and weak (red) fiscal positions.
These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. Government debt as a percentage
of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample, while the
weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Solid lines represent the median, and dotted bands are the 16-84 percent confidence bands.
Multipliers can be found in the supplementary annex.
21
Figure 5: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Impulses Responses
A. Sub-sample: Post-Crisis (2009-14)
Private Consumption
CDS
150
0.5
0.4
100
0.3
50
0.2
0
0.1
0.0
-50
-0.1
-100
-0.2
Weak fiscal position
-0.3
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Strong fiscal position
Private Consumption
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
B. Lag Structure: 3 Quarters
0.2
100
0.1
80
0.0
60
-0.1
40
-0.2
20
-0.3
0
-0.4
-20
Weak fiscal position
Weak fiscal position
-150
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
Strong fiscal position
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
CDS
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
-40
-0.5
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
Private Consumption
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
C. Government Debt Gap
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
CDS
60
0.3
0.2
40
0.1
20
0.0
-0.1
0
-0.2
-20
-0.3
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
Weak fiscal position
-0.4
Strong fiscal position
-40
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
Note: The panel C is based on government debt gap (deviation from group mean) as conditioning variable. Strong
fiscal positions are defined as government debt in the 10th percentile and weak fiscal positions are defined as
government debt in the 90th percentile in the sample. These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where
model coefficients are conditioned on fiscal position, with government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure
of fiscal position.
22
Figure 6: Conditional Impulse Responses Based on Local Projections Model
A. Output
B. Private Consumption
1.0
0.5
0.5
0.0
0.0
-0.5
-0.5
-1.0
Strong position
-1.0
Strong position
Weak position
Weak position
-1.5
-1.5
0
1
2
3
4
0
1
2
3
4
Half-Years
Half-Years
Note: The graphs show the impulse responses for strong (blue) and weak (red) fiscal positions, as a cumulative
percent change. These are defined as the coefficient estimates from a regression of h-period-ahead real output and
real private consumption on lagged output, private consumption, CDS spreads, and unpredicted OECD forecast
errors, in which all coefficients are interacted with government debt in percent of GDP. The strong fiscal position
corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample, while the weak fiscal position corresponds
to the 90th percentile. Solid lines represent the coefficient estimates, and dotted bands are the 85 percent confidence
bands.
23
Figure 7: Ricardian Channel Only: Impulse Responses of Private Consumption
A. Recessions
B. Financial Crises
0.2
2.0
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
Weak fiscal position
1.5
0.0
Strong fiscal position
1.0
-0.2
0.5
-0.4
0.0
-0.6
-0.5
-0.8
-1.0
-1.5
-1.0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
2
3
4
5
C. Countries with Stable Debt
6
7
8
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
D. Nonlinear Debt
0.6
0.2
0.4
0.1
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.1
-0.4
-0.2
-0.6
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
Weak fiscal position
-0.8
Strong fiscal position
-0.3
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
1
2
3
E. Fixed Exchange Rate
4
5
6
7
8
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
F. Flexible Exchange Rate
0.1
0.3
0.2
0.0
0.1
-0.1
0.0
-0.2
-0.1
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
-0.3
-0.2
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
Note: The graphs show the impulse responses of private consumption over time by fiscal position. These are based
on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned on fiscal position for the samples of
recessions (defined as in Harding and Pagan 2002), expansions, financial crises (defined as in Laeven and Valencia
2013), non-crises, countries with stable debt (advanced economies excluding Belgium, Canada, and Italy during 19802006), and nonlinear debt. “Nonlinear debt” are coefficients conditioned on a linear and a quadratic terms of
government debt. Coefficients are jointly conditioned for fiscal position and recession, financial crises, and fixed
exchange rates. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample,
while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Dotted bands represent the 16-84 percent confidence
bands.
24
Table 1: Country Coverage
Advanced
Country
Australia
Belgium
Canada
Germany
Denmark
Spain
Finland
France
United Kingdom
Iceland
Italy
Lithuania
Netherlands
Norway
Portugal
Slovenia
Sweden
United States
Developing
Period
1980:Q1-2013:Q4
1991:Q1-2013:Q4
1980:Q1-2013:Q4
1991:Q1-2013:Q4
1999:Q1-2013:Q4
1995:Q1-2013:Q4
1998:Q1-2013:Q4
1980:Q1-2013:Q4
1980:Q1-2013:Q4
1997:Q1-2013:Q4
1999:Q1-2013:Q4
1995:Q1-2013:Q4
1988:Q1-2013:Q4
1996:Q1-2013:Q4
1980:Q1-2013:Q4
1995:Q1-2013:Q4
1993:Q1-2013:Q4
1980:Q1-2013:Q4
Country
Argentina
Bulgaria
Brazil
Chile
Colombia
Czech Republic
Croatia
Hungary
Israel
Mexico
Poland
Romania
Slovak Republic
South Africa
Turkey
Period
1993:Q1-2013:Q4
1999:Q1-2013:Q4
1995:Q1-2013:Q4
1989:Q1-2013:Q4
2000:Q1-2013:Q4
1999:Q1-2013:Q4
2000:Q1-2013:Q4
1995:Q1-2013:Q4
1999:Q1-2013:Q4
1991:Q1-2013:Q4
1999:Q1-2013:Q4
1998:Q1-2013:Q4
1999:Q1-2013:Q4
1993:Q1-2013:Q4
1998:Q1-2013:Q4
Note: The table shows the list of countries in the sample. Coverage corresponds to maximum temporal coverage for
each country in the baseline specification of the IPVAR model. Coverage may differ for specifications used in the
robustness exercises. The list of countries is presented in the Appendix. Our developing-country coverage comprises
primarily emerging and frontier market economies that have some ability to tap into international financial markets,
which renders the fiscal solvency risks that underpin our nonlinear crowding-out mechanisms relevant. We exclude lowincome countries not only because of data reliability issues, but also because they primarily rely on concessional finance
for government expenditure, which would not reflect the crowding-out mechanisms.
25
Table 2. Fiscal Multiplier Estimates
Conditioning on government debt
Study
Our results 1/
Ilzetzki, Mendoza, Vegh (2013) 2/
Nickell and Tudyka (2014) 2/
Auerbach and Gorodnichenko
(2017) 3/
Conditioning on business cycles 4/
Study
Favero, Giavazzi and Perego (2011)
5/
Bachmann and Sims (2012)
Auerbach and Gorodnichenko
(2012)
Auerbach and Gorodnichenko
(2013)
Blanchard and Leigh (2013) 6/
Candelon and Lieb (2013)
Unconditional 7/
Study
Blanchard and Perotti (2002)
Gali, Lopez-Salido and Valles (2007)
Perotti (2008)
Fatas and Mihov (2009)
Mountford and Uhlig (2009)
Perotti (2011)
Ramey (2011)
Auerbach and Gorodnichenko
(2012)
Bachmann and Sims (2012)
Alesina, Favero and Giavazzi (2015)
Sample
Methodology
33 countries,
1980-2014
44 countries,
1960-2007
17 EU countries,
1970-2010
IPVAR
Government debt
High
Low
0-0.5
0.6-0.9
SVAR
-3
insignificant
IPVAR
<0
1.2
25 OECD
countries, 200317
LPM
<0
>0
Sample
US, 1980-2009
Methodology
GVAR
Recession
"close to 2"
Expansion
US, 1960-2011
US, 1947-2008
VAR
LPM
2.13-3.35
1.12-3.85
1.04-1.1
0.17-3.02
OECD, 19852008
26 European
countries, 200912
US, 1968-2010
LPM
3.5
0
Panel
regression
"Substantially
above 1"
…
TVAR
1-2.4
0.5
Sample
US, 1947-97
US, 1954-2003
US, AUS, CAN,
UK, 1926-2003
Methodology
VAR
DSGE
VAR
Average
0.9-2.67
1.74-3.5
0 (UK, Canada) -3.1 (US)
Not applicable
US, 1955-2000
US 1939-2008
US
US, 1947-2008
Survey
VAR
SVAR, EVAR
Survey
LPM
>1
0.65
"in the neighbourhood of 1"
0.6-1.8
1-2.12
US, 1960-2011
16 OECD
countries, 19782009
VAR
SUR
0.89-0.88
negative to positive
Note: IPVAR stands for interacted panel vector autoregression, SVAR for structural vector autoregression,VAR
for structural vector autoregression, TVAR for threshold vector autoregression, LPM for local projections model,
EVAR stands for expectations-augmented vector autoregression.
1/ High government debt is defined as government debt above 60 percent of GDP, low government debt is the
remainder. Fiscal instrument is government consumption
2/ High government debt is defined as debt in the 90th percentile of the sample (92 percent of GDP). High
government debt is defined as debt in the 10th percentile of the sample (17 percent of GDP). Fiscal instrument is
government consumption.
3/ Explicit multiplier estimates not available. Table shows longterm impulse response of real GDP. Fiscal
instrument is government spending (consumption and investment).
4/ Fiscal instrument is government spending, except for Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) who use a wide
range of fiscal instruments.
26
5/ Fiscal shocks are consolidation episodes (tax and spending) as identified in
Devries et al. (2011).
6/ Fiscal shocks are structural fiscal balance changes during
2009-10.
7/ Fiscal instrument is government spending, except when otherwise specified. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko
(2012), Blanchard and Perotti (1999), Ramey (2011), and Gali, Lopez-Salido and Valles (2007) discuss a range of
fiscal instruments.
27
Supplementary Appendix
Why Do Fiscal Multipliers Depend on Fiscal Positions? ∗
Raju Huidrom, M. Ayhan Kose, Jamus J. Lim, and Franziska L. Ohnsorge
This appendix presents some additional results.
IT IS NOT FOR PUBLICATION.
Figure
Figure
Figure
Figure
A.1
A.2
A.3
A.4
Figure A.8
Figure A.9
Unconditional Fiscal Multipliers
Unconditional Impulse Responses
Distribution of Fiscal Positions
Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels in Separate Models: Fiscal
Multipliers
Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Impulse Responses
Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Fiscal Multipliers
Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Impulse Reponses and Fiscal
Multipliers
Ricardian Channel Only: Fiscal Multipliers
Baseline Model: Robustness
Table A.1
Table A.2
Table A.3
Data Sources
Distribution of Fiscal Positions
Comparison of Fiscal and Business Cycle States
Figure A.5
Figure A.6
Figure A.7
∗
Huidrom: International Monetary Fund;
[email protected]. Kose: World Bank, Prospects Group; Brookings
Institution; CEPR; and CAMA;
[email protected]. Lim: Essec Business School;
[email protected]. Ohnsorge:
World Bank, Prospects Group; and CAMA;
[email protected].
28
Figure A.1: Unconditional Fiscal Multipliers
0.4
0.2
0.0
-0.2
-0.4
-0.6
-0.8
On Impact
1 Year
2 Years
Long Run
Note: The graph shows the unconditional fiscal multipliers for select horizons.
Bars represent the median, and the error bands are the 16-84 percent
confidence bands. These are based on estimates from the SVAR model of
Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013) that features with no interaction terms.
Figure A.2: Unconditional Impulse Responses
A. Government Consumption
B. GDP
0.08
1.2
1.0
0.04
0.8
0.6
0.00
0.4
0.2
-0.04
0.0
-0.08
-0.2
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
Note: The graphs show the unconditional impulse responses (percentage points) to a positive shock to government
consumption. Solid lines represent the median, and dotted lines are the 16-84 percent confidence bands. These are
based on estimates from the SVAR model of Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013) that features with no interaction
terms.
Figure A.3: Distribution of Fiscal Positions
25
20
15
10
5
0
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
100
110
120
130
Note: The graph shows the distribution of fiscal position (in percent),
taken to be the annual government debt-to-GDP ratio, from the sample
of advanced and developing economies during the period 1980-2014.
29
Figure A.4: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels in Separate Models: Fiscal Multipliers
A. Ricardian Channel Only
On Impact
2 Years
0.9
0.3
0.2
0.6
0.1
0.3
0.0
-0.1
24.8
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
65.5
0.0
80.5
24.8
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
65.5
80.5
63.8
76.7
B. Ricardian Channel Only with CDS Sample
On Impact
2 Years
0.6
1.6
0.4
1.2
0.2
0.8
0.0
0.4
-0.2
0.0
-0.4
-0.4
23.1
32.0
38.5
42.8
47.4
54.6
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
63.8
23.1
76.7
32.0
38.5
42.8
47.4
54.6
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
C. Interest Rate Channel
On Impact
2 Years
1.6
0.4
1.2
0.2
0.8
0.0
0.4
-0.2
0.0
-0.4
-0.4
23.1
32.0
38.5
42.8
47.4
54.6
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
63.8
23.1
76.7
32.0
38.5
42.8
47.4
54.6
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
63.8
76.7
Note: The graphs show the fiscal multipliers on impact and after two years (cumulative change in output relative to
cumulative change in government consumption after a fiscal shock) by government debt, ranging from the 10th to
the 90th percentile of government debt in the sample. These are based on estimates from two IPVAR models, where
model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position, that separately include, first, private consumption to proxy
the Ricardian channel (top two rows) and, second, CDS spreads to proxy the interest rate channel (bottom row).
The second row shows the fiscal multipliers from the model including only the Ricardian channel, but with the
sample restricted to the sample of the joint model of Figure 3. Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the
measure of fiscal position. Solid lines represent the median, and dotted bands are the 16-84 percent confidence bands.
Multipliers can be found in the supplementary annex.
30
Figure A.5: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Impulse Responses
A. Sub-sample: Advanced Economies Only
Private Consumption
0.9
CDS
150
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
100
0.6
50
0.3
0
0.0
-50
-0.3
-100
-0.6
-150
Weak fiscal position
-200
-0.9
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Strong fiscal position
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
B. Alternative thresholds for weak and strong fiscal positions
Private Consumption
CDS
0.2
30
0.1
20
0.0
10
-0.1
0
-0.2
-10
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
-20
-0.3
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
Private Consumption
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
C. Lag Structure: 5 Quarters
0.3
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
CDS
60
0.2
0.1
30
0.0
-0.1
0
-0.2
-0.3
Weak fiscal position
-0.4
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Strong fiscal position
Weak fiscal position
-30
1
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Strong fiscal position
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
D. Deviation of government debt in percent of GDP from country-specific average
Private Consumption
CDS
40
0.2
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
30
0.1
Weak fiscal position
20
0.0
Strong fiscal position
10
0
-0.1
-10
-0.2
-20
-0.3
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
-30
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
Note: Impulse responses are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned
only on fiscal positions, with government debt in percent of GDP as the conditioning variable (except for the fourth
row, where the fiscal position is defined as deviation of government debt in percent of GDP from the country-specific
31
average). Weak fiscal positions are defined as government debt in the 90th percentile and strong fiscal positions are
defined as government debt in the 10th percentile in the sample (except for charts in the second row, where weak
fiscal positions are defined as government debt in the 75th percentile and strong fiscal positions are defined as
government debt in the 25th percentile in the sample).
32
Figure A.6: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Fiscal Multipliers
B. 2 Years
Weak position
Debt gap
(country)
Strong position
Baseline
(Figure 3)
Debt gap
(country)
Debt gap
(group)
Five
lags
Three
lags
2009-14
Advanced
economies
Baseline
(Figure 3)
-2
Five
lags
-1
Three
lags
0
2009-14
Weak position
1
Advanced
economies
Strong position
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3
Debt gap
(group)
A. On Impact
2
Note: The graphs show the fiscal multipliers on impact and after two years (cumulative change in output relative to
cumulative change in government consumption after a fiscal shock) by government debt, for the 10th to the 90th
percentile of government debt in the sample. These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model
coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. (The exception are the last two sets of multipliers which condition
on the deviation of government debt from the group-specific mean, “Debt gap (group-mean)”, and country-specific
mean, “Debt gap (country-mean)”.) Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. The
strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample, while the weak fiscal
position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Vertical error bars represent the 16-84 percent confidence bands. The
upper row uses a model that allows for both Ricardian and interest rate channels. The bottom row uses a model that
allows only for Ricardian channels, to preserve degrees of freedom.
33
Figure A.7: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Impulse Reponses and Multipliers
Output
before Private Consumption
Real Effective Exchange Rate
before Current Account Balances
A. Impulse Responses
Private Consumption
Private Consumption
0.4
0.3
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
0.2
0.2
0.1
0.0
0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.4
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
CDS
CDS
80
80
Weak fiscal position
Strong fiscal position
Weak fiscal position
60
60
40
40
20
20
0
0
-20
-20
Strong fiscal position
-40
-40
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
2
3
4
5
B. Multipliers
On Impact
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
-0.4
6
7
8
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Q uarters
On Impact
-0.4
23.1
32.0
38.5
42.8
47.4
54.6
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
63.8
76.7
23.1
32.0
38.5
42.8
47.4
54.6
63.8
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
2 Years
76.7
2 Years
1.8
1.8
1.5
1.5
1.2
1.2
0.9
0.9
0.6
0.6
0.3
0.3
0.0
0.0
-0.3
-0.3
23.1
32.0
38.5
42.8
47.4
54.6
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
63.8
23.1
76.7
32.0
38.5
42.8
47.4
54.6
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
34
63.8
76.7
Note: The left column shows results from a model in which the Cholesky ordering of output and private consumption
is reversed to order output first. The right column shows results from a model in which the Cholesky ordering of real
exchange rates and current account balances is reversed to order real exchange rates first. The results are based on
estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. Government debt
as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile
of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample, while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Solid lines
represent the median, and dotted bands are the 16-84 percent confidence bands.
The top two rows of the Figure show the conditional impulse responses (deviation from baseline in percentage points)
for strong (blue) and weak (red) fiscal positions. The bottom two rows show the conditional fiscal multipliers for
different fiscal positions at select horizons. Fiscal multipliers are defined as cumulative change in output relative to
cumulative change in government consumption in response to a 1 unit government consumption shock.
35
Figure A.8: Ricardian Channel Only: Fiscal Multipliers
A. On Impact
B. 2 Years
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
Nonlinear
debt
Stable debt
Non-Crises
Crises
Baseline
Nonlinear
debt
Stable debt
Flexible
exchange rate
Fixed
exchange rate
Non-Crises
Crises
Expansions
Recessions
Baseline
-1
Expansions
0
Strong position
Weak position
Recessions
Strong position
Weak position
1
Flexible
exchange rate
Fixed
exchange rate
2
Note: The graphs show the fiscal multipliers on impact and after two years (cumulative change in output relative to
cumulative change in government consumption after a fiscal shock) by government debt, for the 10th to the 90th
percentile of government debt in the sample. These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model
coefficients are conditioned on fiscal position for the sample samples of recessions (defined as in Harding and Pagan
2002), expansions, crises (defined as in Laeven and Valencia 2013), non-crises, advanced economies with stable debt
(advanced economies excl. Belgium during 1980-2006), and nonlinear debt. “Nonlinear debt” are coefficients
conditioned on a linear and a quadratic terms of government debt. Coefficients are jointly conditioned for fiscal
position and fixed exchange rates (defined as in Ilzetzki, Mendoza and Vegh 2013). “Baseline” are the fiscal
multipliers corresponding to the left chart of Figure 4. Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of
fiscal position. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample,
while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Vertical error bars represent the 16-84 percent
confidence bands. The upper row uses a model that allows for both Ricardian and interest rate channels. The bottom
row uses a model that allows only for Ricardian channels, to preserve degrees of freedom.
36
Figure A.9: Baseline Model: Robustness
A. During Recessions
On Impact
0.6
2 Years
2.5
2.0
0.4
1.5
1.0
0.2
0.5
0.0
0.0
-0.5
12.4
24.8
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
65.5
80.5
107.4
12.4
24.8
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
On Impact
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
65.5
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
B. Nonlinear Government Debt
0.4
80.5
107.4
80.5
107.4
2 Years
0.9
0.6
0.3
0.3
0.2
0.0
0.1
-0.3
0.0
-0.6
-0.9
-0.1
12.4
24.8
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
65.5
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
On Impact
80.5
12.4
107.4
24.8
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
65.5
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
C. Fixed Exchange Rate Regimes
2 Years
0.8
0.3
0.2
0.6
0.2
0.4
0.1
0.1
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.1
-0.1
-0.2
12.4
24.8
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
65.5
80.5
12.4
24.8
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
On Impact
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
D. Flexible Exchange Rate Regimes
0.7
65.5
80.5
2 Years
3
0.6
2
0.5
0.4
1
0.3
0.2
0
24.8
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
65.5
80.5
24.8
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
32.2
38.5
42.9
47.9
56.1
Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP)
37
65.5
80.5
Note: The graphs show the conditional fiscal multipliers for different levels of fiscal position at select horizons. Fiscal
multipliers are defined as cumulative change in output relative to cumulative change in government consumption in
response to a 1 unit government consumption shock. They are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where
model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure
of fiscal position and the values shown on the x-axis correspond to the 10th to 90th percentiles from the sample.
Fiscal position is strong (weak) when government debt is low (high). Solid lines represent the median, and dotted
bands are the 16-84 percent confidence bands.
38
Table A.1: Data Sources
Variable
Output
Private consumption
Private investment
Definition
Real gross domestic product (GDP)
Real personal consumption expenditure
Real private gross fixed capital formation
Government consumption
Real government consumption expenditurea
Government investment
Frequency
Source
Quarterly Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), OECD, Haver Analytics
Quarterly Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), OECD, Haver Analytics
Quarterly
a
Real government gross fixed capital formation
b
Quarterly
Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), OECD, Haver Analytics
Quarterly
OECD, Haver Analytics, Eurostat
Real effective exchange rate
Real effective exchange rate
Quarterly
Current account
Current account as percent of GDP
Quarterly
Government debt
General government debt as percent of GDP
Annual
Fiscal balance
Overall fiscal balance as percent of GDP
Annual
Government consumption-to-GDP ratio Government consumption as percent of GDP
Annual
Government investment-to-GDP ratio Government investment as percent of GDP
Annual
Interest rate
Short term nominal interest rate
Quarterly
Note: The main source for the quarterly series is Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013). This database
Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), BIS
Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), WEO
WEO
WEO
WDI
WDI
Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013)
which ends around 2008 is extended by splicing from
different sources as mentioned in the table.
a
This refers to general government for most countries while for a few countries central government is taken. See Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013).
b
The narrow index wherever available is taken while the remainder uses the broad index. Details are available upon request.
Table A.2: Distribution of Fiscal Positions
Percentile
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95
Debt-GDP Ratio 12.4 17.3 24.8 28.7 32.2 35.9 38.5 40.7 42.9 45.1 47.9 51.4 56.1 60.1 65.5 71.3 80.5 92.4 107.4
Note: The table shows the percentile values of fiscal position, taken to be annual government debt-to-GDP ratio, from the sample of advanced
and developing economies during the period 1980-2014.
39
Table A.3: Comparison of Fiscal and Business Cycle States
Full Sample Advanced Developing
a
Relative frequency
Strong fiscal and recessionary state
2.2
2.4
1.8
Weak fiscal and recessionary state
2.1
2.4
3.0
Test of differences
b
[52.3, 54.0] [57.3, 57.9] [43.4, 44.6]
In means
0.25
0.76
0.55
Note: The table shows the association (or lack thereof) between different fiscal positions and
the recessionary state.
a
The top panel shows the relative frequency (percent of observations) of the strong fiscal
position and the recessionary state, and that of weak fiscal position and the recessionary state.
The frequencies are reported for the full sample and also for specific country groups: advanced
and developing economies. The strong (weak) fiscal position corresponds to the 10th (90th)
percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio in each sample. The bottom panel reports results that show the
statistical significance of the difference of those relative frequencies. The recessionary state is
determined by the Harding-Pagan (2002) business cycle dating algorithm.
b
The top entry shows the average debt-to-GDP ratio (in percent) during expansions (left) and
recessions (right). The bottom entry shows the p-values of two-group t-test of difference in
means with unequal variances.
40