Journal of Agrarian Change, Vol. 10 No. 1, January 2010, pp. 98–106.
The Food Crisis, Industrialized Farming
and the Imperial Regime
JAN DOUWE VAN DER PLOEG
This paper argues that the food crisis cannot solely be equated with abrupt food
price increases or seen as merely market induced. The unprecedented price
increases of the first half of 2008, and the extremely low prices that followed,
are expressions of a far wider and far more persistent underlying crisis, which
has been germinating for more than a decade. It is the complex outcome of
several combined processes, including the industrialization of agriculture, the
liberalization of food and agricultural markets and the rise of food empires.
The interaction of these processes has created a global agrarian crisis that has
provoked the multifaceted food crisis. Both these crises are being accelerated
through their interactions with the wider economic and financial crisis.
_JOAC
98..106
Keywords: agrarian crisis, food crisis, liberalization, imperial food
regime
INTRODUCTION: THE SPECIFIC AND THE GENERAL
At the beginning of 2008 the world was confronted with abrupt and huge increases
in food prices, a crisis that considerably extended the proportion of the world’s
population suffering from hunger, even into developed countries. It suddenly
became clear that affordable food could no longer be taken for granted. Initially it
was argued that the price increases were the expression of temporary disequilibria
in the relevant commodity markets, although other analyses suggested that the
world is likely to face long-term scarcities. Banse et al. (2008) argued that growth in
agricultural productivity would have difficulties in keeping up with demographic
growth, the rapidly increasing demand for biofuels, expected changes in consumption patterns in China and India, and the effects of climate change. These pressures
were all discussed in the 2008 World Development Report (World Bank 2007), the
first to focus on agriculture in 20 years, which diagnosed a ‘decade’s long neglect
of agriculture’.1 Yet the responses that the report prescribed were startlingly familiar:
more investment, especially in biotechnological research, more market freedom and
the avoidance of any temptation to return to protectionism. This last point was
mostly meant to emphasize that any public governance of, or intervention into, the
agricultural and food markets should remain an absolute taboo.2 Instead, the market
Jan Douwe van der Ploeg, Professor of Transition Studies, Wageningen University, Hollandseweg 1,
6706 KN Wageningen, The Netherlands. e-mail:
[email protected]
1
For an assessment of the World Development Report, see Oya (2009).
2
It is, though, extremely naive to assume that, for example, Argentina would not impose export
taxes on some of its main agricultural commodities in order to avoid high world market prices
© 2010 The Author – Journal compilation © 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
The Food Crisis, Industrialized Farming and the Imperial Regime 99
should be actively brought to smallholders, a recommendation reiterated by the
2008 G8 summit on agriculture.
The inflated prices of early 2008 had specific causes. These include speculation,
extremely low levels of world grain reserves (actively run down as part of the
neoliberal project), extreme weather conditions in major grain producing countries
and the impact of biofuels. However, these specific causes could only trigger a food
crisis because they occurred in a dramatically changed context. The new ‘imperial’
or ‘corporate food regime’ (Ploeg 2008, 256; McMichael 2009, 237), which increasingly governs the production, processing, distribution and consumption of food,
implies that relatively small disequilibria in the markets translate into huge fluctuations in prices. It is not only material disequilibria that can cause such fluctuations,
but also symbolic disequilibria; that is, those solely related to expectations.The mere
assumption that there could be a scarcity (and the possibility of turning this fear into
profit through dealing in futures) was, within this new imperial regime, a major
factor in triggering the sharp price increases (see also Ghosh 2010, this issue). In the
same way, changing expectations (partly related to material changes in supply–
demand relations) also triggered the extremely low price levels that followed the
peak of mid-2008, which translated into a widespread slump in agricultural production, especially in Europe and the United States. This, in turn, may provoke
yet another wave of upward pressure on prices. Thus, turbulence is becoming a
permanent feature of the new food regime, to the detriment of both farmers and
consumers.Today we face the frightening combination of an evolving agrarian crisis
and a highly differentiated, but increasingly generalized, food crisis.
THE ORIGINS OF THE CURRENT AGRARIAN AND FOOD CRISES
The current agrarian crisis emerges out of the interaction of: (1) a partial but
constantly ongoing industrialization of agriculture; (2) the emergence of the world
market as the ordering principle for agricultural production and marketing; and (3)
the restructuring of processing industries, large trading companies and supermarket
chains into ‘food empires’ that increasingly exert a monopolistic power over the
entire food supply chain. These three processes meld together in the creation of a
new, worldwide, food regime that is deeply affecting the nature of farming, the
ecosystems on which farming is grounded, and the quality and distribution of
food. The resulting constellation is extremely sensitive to external shocks, which is
precisely what occurred at the interface of the current agrarian and food crises, on
the one hand, and the general economic and financial crisis on the other.
The first process – that is, the industrialization of agriculture – is well documented and analyzed (see, e.g., McMichael 1994). Several dimensions of this have
a critical bearing on the current crisis. Industrial agriculture involves an, often
extreme, disconnectedness between farming and nature and locality: with natural
growth factors (such as soil fertility, high-quality manure, carefully selected varieties and locally adapted breeds) increasingly being replaced by artificial growth
benefiting just a small segment of large landowners. It is equally naive to assume that India would
not introduce a prohibition on exports of food in order to avoid major socio-political turmoil due
to food scarcities.
© 2010 The Author – Journal compilation © 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
100 Jan Douwe van der Ploeg
factors entailed in external inputs and new technological devices. Instead of being
built on ecological capital, farming has become dependent upon industrial and
financial capital. This has led variable costs to become a relatively high and rigid
part of total production costs and has sharply reduced the surplus (or margin) per
unit of end product. Thus another indispensable ingredient of industrialization
emerged: ongoing scale increase of farming became an intrinsic need. Together,
the decreasing margins and the scale increases constitute a ‘race to the bottom’
(Marsden 2003).
The need for permanent scale increases has triggered another, and currently
decisive, feature: a heightened dependency of farming upon capital markets. In order
to expand, industrializing farms have had to take out considerable loans. Their
indebtedness has grown exponentially. The strategies operated by the farmers
involved in these processes have also changed considerably: moving from peasant-like
styles to an entrepreneurial logic. While the former centre on autonomy, family
labour and a self-controlled resource base, the latter focuses on market integration and
competiveness.The entrepreneurial logic also allows for the deactivation of farming:
when margins become too low, capital shifts towards more profitable activities and
agricultural activities diminish. As a consequence, agriculture is becoming far more
sensitive to economic trends and fluctuations than it ever has been before. Its very
foundations have started to follow ‘the logic of the market’ (Friedmann 1993).
Through this multidimensional process of industrialization, a new agricultural
segment has emerged: a growth pole of highly intensive, specialized and large-scale
farms that require a specific market environment in order to continue their needed
expansion. There is a paradox here, for these farms require resources, such as land,
labour, production quotas, environmental space and access to markets, to be freely
available commodities; they also require market stability for long-term planning,
investment decisions and the repayment of debts.Yet these requirements (which are
intrinsic to the industrialization of farming) run counter to the reality of the new,
global, liberalized markets, which have introduced turbulence where stability is
needed. At the same time it is important to note that, while there has been
considerable productivity growth within these industrializing farm enterprises, the
process of industrialization has also decreased the rhythm of growth in the farming
sector as a whole. The growth of expanding farm enterprises has occurred through
takeovers of other farms and also led to large agricultural areas where the industrialization model could not be implemented, whether for ecological and/or social
reasons, becoming marginalized.
The centrality of short-term financial results has also provoked a long-term decay
in biophysical productivity within the industrializing poles. The longevity of
milking cows, for instance, has been reduced from some seven or eight lactation
periods (or more) to only three, while the overall efficiency of nitrogen use has
decreased from some 60 per cent in the 1950s to less than 20 per cent in the 1990s.
The use of energy and irrigation water has increased considerably, although the
efficiency of their use has decreased (Ventura 1995; Dries 2002). Consequently,
industrial farming has become a major contributor to environmental problems,
including greenhouse gas emissions. There have been many attempts to transfer the
model of industrialized farming to developing countries (the ‘Green Revolution’
being the major one). Yet these attempts often ran aground, as there was a lack of
© 2010 The Author – Journal compilation © 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
The Food Crisis, Industrialized Farming and the Imperial Regime 101
resources to provide the required long term security (through, for example, market
regulation, price subsidies and financial support for on-farm investments). Such
attempts also ran counter to the complexities of ecosystems and the ‘uncapturedness’ of the peasant populations.
The second process is the restructuring of markets under the aegis of the
neoliberal project. The World Trade Organization’s Agreement on Agriculture is, in
this respect, an important landmark (Weis 2007). Although only some 15 per cent
of the world’s total agricultural production crosses borders (thus de facto becoming
part of a world market), the remaining 85 per cent (which circulates within
national, regional and/or local markets) is now being aligned with the price levels,
trends and ratios that govern the world market (EC 2006). The previous differentiation of interconnected, locally or regionally centred markets, that to a degree
reflected the specificity of relative factor prices at the regional or local level, is being
restructured into one global market, increasingly characterized by the same set of
price levels and price ratios. This global market also allows for enormous flows of
commodities between different parts of the globe.This possibility, together with the
extensive commoditization of all the main resources (e.g. land, water, seeds), has
induced a completely new feature into the world agricultural and food market: the
complete exchangeability of large agricultural systems. For example, asparagus production was once completely unknown in Peru, but in recent years the country has
become the world’s largest exporter of asparagus.The ‘asparagus system’ is currently
travelling to China, where even ‘better’ conditions are available.This exchangeability
now applies to all fresh products, introducing considerable insecurity and turbulence. Polanyi once wrote that ‘leaving the fate of soil and people to the market
would be tantamount to annihilating them’ (1957, 131). These words clearly apply
to the actively ‘globalized’ food and agricultural markets.This turbulence is not only
reflected in sharp price fluctuations, but is globalizing insecurity and threatening the
very continuity of many agricultural systems.
The liberalization of food and agricultural markets is intimately interwoven with
the third process: the rise of food empires. Liberalized markets have become an
arena in which agribusiness groups are striving for hegemony. Through a series of
accelerated takeovers, facilitated by the nearly unlimited availability of credit, food
empires have been constructed that increasingly control large segments of the global
food supply chain. These include well established empires such as Nestlé, Unilever
and Monsanto, which are continuing to expand, together with new food empires
that emerged over the last 20 years, including Ahold, Parmalat and Vion, the recently
created north-west European meat empire (for a review of these trends, see ETC
Group 2008). These food empires exert considerable monopoly power:3 it is
becoming difficult, if not often impossible, for farmers to sell food ingredients or for
consumers to buy food outside of the circuits that they control. Food empires
increasingly represent a ‘visible hand’ that governs a range of markets, by exerting
control over important linkages within, and especially between, different markets,
and in so doing have constructed new linkages between spaces of poverty and
spaces of wealth. High-value products such as asparagus, vegetables, chicken, pork,
3
Although they themselves are particularly vulnerable, Ahold nearly went bankrupt in 2002 and
later on in the same year Parmalat did collapse, leaving a total debt of 14 billion euro.
© 2010 The Author – Journal compilation © 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
102 Jan Douwe van der Ploeg
beef, dairy products and flowers are now being produced in Peru, Kenya, Thailand,
Brazil, Argentine, Poland and Colombia, respectively (although tomorrow this might
shift to countries such as China, Ukraine and Madagascar) and transported, often
by air, to the north-west of Europe and the metropolises of the US.4 These new
linkages allow for an enormous accumulation of wealth (Friedmann 2004) and at
the same time introduce huge downward pressures in other spaces.
Mainly financed by credit (and partly consolidated through shares), the food
empires have contributed considerably to the making of (what we now know as) the
financial crisis. The dependency on credit (and the requirement to enlarge stockholder value) introduces the need to generate a large enough cash flow to pay
redemption and interest rates as well as to co-finance further expansion.Thus, these
structures that link the production and consumption of food have a strong inbuilt
need to ‘squeeze out’ as much value as possible, by exerting a permanent downward
pressure on the prices received by primary producers and an upward pressure on food
prices paid by consumers, allowing for considerable accumulation.This explains why
massive levels of chronic undernutrition coexist with persistent trends towards
de-activation of primary production. The latter might be triggered by (farm-gate)
prices being too low, while the former is partly due to (consumer) prices being too
high. For example, in the period from 1980 to 2003, most industrial subsectors in Italy
witnessed only a small increase in total value added (from an index of 100 in 1980 to
112 in 2003 for the chemical industry; 109 for wood processing, 106 for mineral
processing) or even a considerable decrease (to 79 for textiles, 84 for the automobile
industry, 91 for the chemical industry and 92 for the mechanical industry). The only
exception was the food industry, where the index for total value added increased from
100 in 1980 to 148 in 2003.The same occurred in The Netherlands, where the Gross
Value Added of the food industry grew from 22.5 billion euro in 1985 to 33.0 billion
euro in 1997 – a growth of 46 per cent in only 12 years.These exceptional levels of
growth also explain why large chemical industries (such as DSM) have increasingly
started to invest in the food industry (Ploeg 2008).
The other side of this accumulation is a large-scale draining of wealth out of
agricultural sectors. This reduces the capacity for autonomous growth and simultaneously reduces to redundancy large, potentially productive, areas and large
numbers of people who have little alternative apart from earning a living in
farming. ‘Wasted lives’ (Bauman 2004) and wasted land have thus become a chronic
feature of many rural areas5 – just as Polanyi anticipated many years ago. The same
draining also affects food quality. Impoverished farmers facing a continuing squeeze
can hardly afford to provide the care that is required for the production of healthy
and high-quality food. But this is not the only threat to food quality.
4
The crisis of the 1880s was partly resolved, at least in Europe, through a massive change from the
production of basic grains to the production of high-value products such as meat, vegetables and
cheeses. Such a response is now impossible: high-value products are now being imported, through
channels controlled by different food empires, from spaces of poverty. Typically, the response that
helped to overcome the agrarian crisis of the 1930s – that is, the introduction of a well-tuned
agrarian policy – is now equally impossible, as it is excluded by the reigning free trade regime.
5
This phenomenon is exemplified by the millions of smallholders, especially in Africa, Latin
America and parts of Asia, who experience hunger in their homes while their fields are lying fallow.
They lack the means to initiate agricultural production or, if such means are available, the marketing
channels to sell their products.
© 2010 The Author – Journal compilation © 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
The Food Crisis, Industrialized Farming and the Imperial Regime 103
Parmalat was one of several food empires created through aggressive takeovers,
which resulted in very large debts.To generate the cash flow needed to deal with this
situation, a major project was designed that later became known as the latte fresco blu
project (fresh blue milk).6 This project involved the deconstruction of milk into its
constituent elements, a range of technological interventions (micro-filtration and
repeated pasteurizations) and then a subsequent recombination of the different (and
differently treated) elements into ‘fresh milk’ (Benvenuti et al. 2004). The strategic
advantage of this technology lay in that it allowed the bridging of huge distances in
both time and space. It allowed for milk produced, say, one month ago in, for example,
Poland or Ukraine to be transported, re-fabricated and sold as ‘fresh milk’ in Italy. For
Parmalat, which controlled the UHT segment of the milk market, the ability to
construct a linkage between places of poverty and the Italian food market (where
prices of up to 1.50 euro are paid for one litre of milk) would have allowed them to
conquer the market for fresh milk, controlled by the Granorolo group and regional
co-operatives, and, consequently, the accumulation of enormous wealth. However, the
success of the ‘fresh blue milk’ project would have implied an abrupt marginalization
of Italian dairy farmers. Their ‘market’ would have been completely taken over. For
Italian consumers it would have implied an undeniable degradation of food: from real
fresh milk to a look-alike product. Food empires need (and therefore introduce) food
engineering to make ‘high-value’ products out of cheap ingredients.There is a clear
link between this need and the qualitative side of the food crisis. Additives (such as
sweeteners, colorants, softeners, preservatives and boosters) are systematically added
(even when there is little knowledge of their long-term and cumulative effects on
human health) as the range of ‘look-alike’ food products constantly expands. Due
to its enormous debts, Parmalat imploded before the ‘latte fresco blu’ project had
generated enough returns. Nonetheless, the case clearly shows how an abrupt
acceleration of the agrarian crisis and a widening of the food crisis can go hand in
hand – each being a prerequisite for, and a result of, the other.
The interface of the industrialization of agriculture, the liberalization of food
markets and the rise of food empires has seen the creation of a persistent and
worldwide agrarian crisis. Liberalization and the emergence of food empires have
induced an unprecedented tightening of the squeeze on agriculture. Beyond this,
food empires have considerably widened the gap between farm-gate prices and those
paid by consumers. Finally, the liberalization of markets, and especially the worldwide
operations of food empires, have provoked high levels of turbulence that now
characterize not only the ‘world market’ sensu stricto, but also the many national and
regional food markets that materially link the production and consumption of food.
Yet these effects run counter to the intrinsic requirements of industrialized farming,
which needs predictability (as opposed to turbulence), prices that cover both the
higher financial obligations and costs related to the increased use of inputs (as opposed
to the squeeze), and consumer prices that allow for an increase in demand (as opposed
to consumer prices that reduce demand and produce considerable exclusion).
In synthesis: food empires require industrial farming (for its capacity to deliver
large amounts of standardized and cheap raw materials for further processing and
6
The adjective ‘blu’ was added in order to avoid problems with the Italian law that very strictly
specified the characteristics of fresh milk.
© 2010 The Author – Journal compilation © 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
104 Jan Douwe van der Ploeg
trading) while, at the same time, they tend to destroy it.This particular contradiction
(which has intensified due to liberalization) has led to a range of new and
permanent phenomena: poverty (especially among large farmers), less room for
manoeuvre due to asphyxiating regulatory schemes (partly imposed by food
empires, partly by state agencies), an ongoing degradation of ecological capital, and
a substantial increase in the quantity and intensity of frictions between farmers and
society at large.The sharply increased number of ‘food scares’ is just one of the many
expressions of such frictions (in the US, the number of publicly admitted food
scandals has tripled over the last 10 years).
THE FOOD CRISIS UNDER CLOSE SCRUTINY
It is ironic that the world only started to discuss the food crisis when the price
shock of 2008 provoked discomfort and fears (notably over restrictions on the free
trade of food) in the spaces of wealth – the chronic hunger elsewhere has largely
been neglected for two decades. Currently, the distortions of the food market are
extending into a global, albeit highly differentiated phenomenon, with the sudden
price increases for food having led to food riots, export restrictions and reductions
in import-tariffs. However, these problems cannot be explained by the food market
only. They are strongly rooted in the agrarian crisis. What we witnessed in the first
half of 2008 is that the agrarian crisis is now translating into a persistent and
worldwide food crisis.7 The two cannot be discussed in isolation – they are
intimately intertwined. Firstly, the agro-food complex, as it is currently ordered,
introduces massive and chronic levels of undernutrition, mainly, though far from
exclusively, in the South. From the mid-1980s onwards, some 850 million people
have been chronically suffering from undernutrition. Regardless of all the rhetoric
associated with millennium goals and the like, the world has not been able to reduce
this shameful phenomenon. During the past two years, this figure has risen to more
than 1,000 million people.
Secondly, the agro-food complex is also creating an epidemic of obesity. It is
estimated that a further 1,000 million people in the world are obese (see also Lang
2010, this issue). This is strongly related to both food engineering (of the latte fresco
blu type) and the orientation towards short-run profitability that drives food
empires, the same combination that also provokes the ongoing flow of food scandals
(Lang and Heasman 2004).
Thirdly, the ‘world market’ is an intrinsically unstable organizing principle. It
constantly produces disequilibria, insecurity and turbulence (just as it is unable to
create the required coordination between the production of biofuels and food).This
both sharpens the agrarian crisis and makes the food crisis more widespread.
THE ACCELERATION
The economic and financial crises are currently accelerating the agrarian and food
crisis, through two principal mechanisms. These are the overall reduction in
7
The nearly unavoidable pressure to introduce forms of protectionism is probably is the biggest
menace that the food crisis presents for the free trade ordering of the world.
© 2010 The Author – Journal compilation © 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
The Food Crisis, Industrialized Farming and the Imperial Regime 105
purchasing power, which will negatively translate into the volume and value of
food consumption (and in farmers being paid even lower prices) and the impossibility of refinancing all existing debts. Together, these two effects produce a
third, and so far hardly recognized, effect: the impossibility of reproducing industrialized farming.
Food empires are highly dependent upon credit, as is industrialized agriculture.
Both these sectors have expanded through the principle of leverage. Earlier, more
limited, crises in the US showed how large farms and rural banks are interwoven.
When large farms entered the risk zone, rural banks went bankrupt – and this
affects all the farms in the area.
In 2007 the total debts of Dutch agriculture as a whole were equal to 38.8 billion
euro (family capital excluded), a 33 per cent increase compared to 2002 (Berkhout
and van Bruchem 2008). The average farm owed 550,000 euro to banks and other
institutions, although this figure masks large variations. Some farms tend to be ‘free’,
as the expression in the countryside goes; others – especially in the industrialized
segment – have levels of indebtedness that far exceed the average.The magnitude of
the total debts becomes clear when they are related to other parameters: the gross
value of agricultural production in 2007 was 22.9 billion euro, net value added was
6.6 billion euro and total agrarian income equalled 3.0 billion euro.Thus, total debts
were six times higher than the net value added per year and more than twelve times
as high as the annual agrarian income.While there are huge international variations
in these debt/earnings ratios, Dutch agriculture is far from unique in this respect.
Considerable segments of the agricultural sectors in the US, Latin America, South
Africa, some parts of Asia, Eastern Europe and the rest of the European Union are
showing (albeit sometimes for different reasons) similar or even higher levels. The
high levels of indebtedness imply that, if banks became less willing to, or less capable
of, refinancing debts this could trigger a forced selling of animals (as occurred in the
second half of 2008 and the first half of 2009 throughout the United States), a
complete closure of farms and/or a temporary reduction of production (the EU dairy
sector has seen a remarkable de-activation since the middle of 2008). Reduced
imports of feed and fodder (that follow from the slaughtering of cattle in the US and
de-activation in the EU) will then create havoc in large areas elsewhere that
specialized in the production of soybeans, groundnuts and cassava.
Together, the current difficulty of refinancing highly indebted industrial farms
and the low price levels paid by food empires will set a trend that is likely to
characterize the coming years. It is now the, apparently impressive, industrialized
farms that are de-activating production or even going out of business: their negative
cash flows (resulting from low prices and high costs, including financial duties) do
not allow for any other alternative. This tendency was latent for several years. This
somewhat hidden Achilles heel of industrialized farming is now growing and
becoming more visible as result of the general economic and financial crisis.
Considerable parts of the industrialized farming segment will go broke; and of those
that do not, many will increasingly run counter to socio-political pressures. As a
consequence, more peasant-like forms of farming may well be reactivated and come
to the fore. History shows that this is exactly what has happened during and after
earlier agrarian crises. The difference now is that urban people may well be
supportive of such a change, as they start to understand some aspects of how the
© 2010 The Author – Journal compilation © 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
106 Jan Douwe van der Ploeg
agrarian and the food crises are linked to each other and to the availability and
quality of the food they consume.
REFERENCES
Banse, M., P. Nowicki and H. van Meijl, 2008. Why are Current World Food Prices So High?
LEI, Report 2008-040. The Hague: LEI.
Bauman, Z., 2004. Vite di Scarto [Wasted Lives: Modernity and its Outcasts]. Rome: Edizione
Laterza.
Benvenuti, B, E. Bussi, G. Losi, C. Pignagnoli, C. Petrini, J.D. van der Ploeg and C. de
Roest, 2004. Latte vivo. Il lungo viaggio del latte dai campi alla tavola. Prospettive dopo il
Parmacrack. Reggio Emilia: Edizione Diabasis.
Berkhout, P. and C. van Bruchem, 2008. Agricultural Economic Report of The Netherlands, LEI,
Rapport 2008-030. Den Haag: LEI.
Dries, A. van den, 2002. The Art of Irrigation: the Development, Stagnation and Redesign of
Farmer-Managed Irrigation Systems in Northern Portugal. Wageningen: Circle for Rural
European Studies, Wageningen University.
EC (European Commission) Directorate-General for Agriculture and Rural Development,
G5, 2006. Agricultural Trade Policy Analysis: Agricultural Commodity Markets – Past Developments and Outlook. Brussels: EC, G5.
ETC Group, 2008. Who Owns Nature? Corporate Power and the Final Frontier in the Commodification of Life. Leusden: ETC Group.
Friedmann, H., 1993.‘The Political Economy of Food: A Global Crisis’. New Left Review, no.
197: 29–57.
Friedmann, H., 2004. ‘Feeding the empire: the pathologies of globalized agriculture’. In The
Socialist Register 2005:The Empire Reloaded, eds. L. Panitch and C. Leys, 124–43. London:
Merlin Press.
Ghosh, J., 2010. ‘The Unnatural Coupling: Food and Global Finance’. Journal of Agrarian
Change, 10 (1): 72–86.
Lang, T. and M. Heasman, 2004. Food Wars: The Global Battle for Mouths, Minds and Markets.
London: Earthscan.
Lang, T., 2010. ‘Crisis? What Crisis? The Normality of the Current Food Crisis’. Journal of
Agrarian Change, 10 (1): 87–97.
Marsden, T., 2003. The Condition of Rural Sustainability. Assen: Van Gorcum.
McMichael, P., 1994. The Global Restructuring of Agro-Food Systems. Ithaca, NY: Cornell
University Press.
McMichael, P., 2009. ‘Banking on Agriculture: A Review of the World Development Report
2008’. Journal of Agrarian Change, 9 (2): 235–46.
Oya, C., 2009. ‘Introduction to a Symposium on the World Development Report 2008’. Journal
of Agrarian Change, 9 (2): 231–4.
Ploeg, J.D. van der, 2008. The New Peasantries: Struggles for Autonomy and Sustainability in an
Era of Empire and Globalization. London: Earthscan.
Polanyi, K., 1957. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time.
Boston: Beacon Press.
Ventura, F., 1995. ‘Styles of Beef Cattle Breeding and Resource Use Efficiency in Umbria’.
In Beyond Modernization, the Impact of Endogenous Rural Development, eds. J.D. van der
Ploeg and G. van Dijk, 219–32. Assen: Van Gorcum.
Weis, T., 2007. The Global Food Economy: The Battle for the Future of Farming. London: Zed
Books.
World Bank, 2007. World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for Development. Washington,
DC: The World Bank.
© 2010 The Author – Journal compilation © 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd