Academia.eduAcademia.edu

Trade Deficit And Currency Devaluation: Testing The J-Curve

2022, International Journal of Business & Management Studies

This paper is testing empirically the effect of a devaluation of a currency on the trade account of the country, the Jcurve effect, by using the trade between the U.S. and seven countries (Euro-zone, Mexico, Canada, United Kingdom, Switzerland, Japan, and Australia). A devaluation (depreciation) of the U.S. dollar is increasing the spot exchange rate ($/FC) and increases the price of imports and reduces the price of exports. Then, imports are falling and exports are increasing and the trade account is improved in the long-run. In the short-run, the trade account is deteriorated because the international trade transactions are prearranged and the invoices are in foreign currency, so it cannot be adjusted. This J-curve hypothesis is tested by using a regression equation and a VAR model, where the volatility of the real exchange rate (TOT) is specified with a GARCH-M process. Also, different stationary tests are taking place, like, unit root and cointegration ones. The empirical results mostly are supporting the J-curve effect.

IPRPD International Journal of Business & Management Studies ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) Volume 03; Issue no 12: December, 2022 DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 TRADE DEFICIT AND CURRENCY DEVALUATION: TESTING THE J-CURVE Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis1, Dr. Iordanis Petsas2 1 2 Economics/Finance Department, The Arthur J. Kania School of Management, University of Scranton, USA Professor & Chair, Department of Economics and Finance, Kania School of Management, University of Scranton, USA Abstract This paper is testing empirically the effect of a devaluation of a currency on the trade account of the country, the Jcurve effect, by using the trade between the U.S. and seven countries (Euro-zone, Mexico, Canada, United Kingdom, Switzerland, Japan, and Australia). A devaluation (depreciation) of the U.S. dollar is increasing the spot exchange rate ($/FC) and increases the price of imports and reduces the price of exports. Then, imports are falling and exports are increasing and the trade account is improved in the long-run. In the short-run, the trade account is deteriorated because the international trade transactions are pre-arranged and the invoices are in foreign currency, so it cannot be adjusted. This J-curve hypothesis is tested by using a regression equation and a VAR model, where the volatility of the real exchange rate (TOT) is specified with a GARCH-M process. Also, different stationary tests are taking place, like, unit root and cointegration ones. The empirical results mostly are supporting the J-curve effect. Keywords Demand for Money and Exchange Rate, Foreign Exchange, Current Account Adjustment, Forecasting and Simulation, Information and Market Efficiency, International Financial Markets JEL (Classification): «Πονηροί δέ ἄνθρφποι καί γόηηες προκόυοσζιν ἐπί ηό τείρον, πλανῶνηες καί πλανώμενοι.» - E4, F31, F32, F47, G14, G15 Β΄ Τιμ. γ΄ 13 I. Introduction A continuing U.S. trade deficit after 1980 is a proof of a major structural problem of the country. This situation is detrimental to the nation’s economy and to citizens’ wellbeing because it affects negatively production, employment, income, competitiveness, independence, and causes reductions of foreign assets of the Fed, because are used in financing the trade deficits, which are foreign currencies, SDRs, gold or debt. A country can buy more goods from abroad than it makes domestically by borrowing from its trading partners. This can only continue as long as the lending country trusts the borrowing one to repay the loan. One day, the lending countries could decide to ask the borrower to repay not only the interest, but the entire debt, which could generate serious effects in the domestic economy.1 However, this is not likely to happen because it would have adverse effects (depreciation) on those borrowing countries’ currencies and imports will fall and trade will be reduced, which will deteriorate lender’s economy. Another concern regarding the trade deficit is about the competitiveness of the deficit country’s economy itself. By purchasing goods overseas for a long enough period, the companies of the country lose their expertise and even the factories2 to make those products. As a nation loses its competitiveness, it outsources more jobs, more companies, and more income, which reduce its standard of living. Countries must be self-sufficient and 1 It might make its debt unsustainable. See, Kallianiotis (2018, p. 164). See, Niko J. Kallianiotis, America in a Trance. https://www.nikokallianiotis.com/book , where this problem is depicted in photos. 2 1| International Journal of Business & Management Studies ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) in an autarky situation and this depends on the competence of domestic leadership and its public (monetary, fiscal, and trade) policies. Countries can use trade policies (devaluation of their currencies) to reduce the trade account deficits, given that the Marshall-Lerner condition holds (elastic domestic and foreign demands for imports). Devaluation increases the price of imports and reduces the price of exports and due to the law of demand, imports are falling and exports are increasing and the trade account is improved. Let us start with a country that has a trade account deficit and decides to devaluate (depreciate) its currency to reduce the deficit, as it appears in Figure 1. At time t1 , the depreciation of the domestic currency takes place and a further deterioration in the trade balance occurs and gradually the trade balance improves, after time t 2 ; this path of adjustment takes the shape of a ―j‖ and for this reason it called the J-Curve adjustment. There is a theoretical rational behind this hypothesis, but in Finance and mostly in its mother Economics (Οἰθολοκηθός), everything must be proved beyond mathematics and assumptions with actual data from the trading partners. A sudden unexpected depreciation of the domestic currency has the following impact, in the current period ( t1 ), due to the contracts for exports (in $) and imports (in €), which are already in effect. All or most of the imports are priced in foreign currencies. Thus, a sudden depreciation of the U.S. dollar will cause an increase in the trade deficit after time t1 because the cost of imports will be higher in dollars, due to its depreciation, while the revenue from exports will remain unchanged because of the already existing export contracts. As the time is passing, the price of imports is increasing and imports are falling, but the price of exports might fall (the price of imported raw material or other inputs for their production will increase) and we will Figure 1. The J- Curve (TA Adjustment) reach period t 2 , where the trade account is Note: t1 = depreciation of the domestic currency improving, due to reduction of imports and increase period and t2 = TA improvement period. to exports. After time t 2 , the trade account becomes positive (in surplus). S  ($ )  ( M  and X ) S  R  TAS  R  (int ernational trade transactio ns are pre  arranged and cannot adjust )  ( M  and X ) L R  TAL R  ( M d and M s are more inelastic in the short  run than in the long  run ) where, S = spot exchange rate ($/FC), M = imports, X = exports, and TA = trade account. The adjustment of the trade account takes place over a prolonged period of time. In some industrial countries the total time elapsing between the time of the depreciation of the currency and the improvement of the trade account varies between 3 to 12 months (depending on the payments grace period). For example, a depreciation of the U.S. dollar will have the following effects on its trade account: TAt1  0  S  ($ )  X  M  ( PX$ Q X )  ( S $ / euro  PMeuro QM )  TA  where, PX = price of exports, QX = quantity of goods exported, PM = price of imports, and QM = quantity of goods imported. With the passing of time the current contracts will mature and the new contracts will be written with the new prices, which will reflect the changes of cost, due to the depreciation of the currency and the trade account3will be improved because imports will fall, due to higher cost and exports will increase because of the lower cost (lower prices in foreign currency) of the U.S. products. The objective of this study is to test the J-curve hypothesis by using a regression and a vector autoregression (VAR) model based on the trade account variables and the exchange rate volatility by applying a GARCH-M specification. 3 The U.S. Current and Trade Account Deficits 2 | Trade Deficit and Currency Devaluation- Testing the J-Curve: Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis et al. Vol. 03 - Issue: 12/December_2022 ©Institute for Promoting Research & Policy Development DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 II. A Theoretical Model of the Trade Account Specification of Currency Volatility As it was mentioned, countries can use trade policies (the traditional, like, tariffs, import taxes, and quota or the less reactionary one, devaluation of their currencies) to reduce the current account and the trade account deficits. The trade account can be presented with eq. (1), as following,     TA  X  M  f 1 ( p, Y )  f 2 ( p, Y ) * (1) where, Y = domestic income, Y * = foreign income, and p = the relative price level ( TOT ) or real exchange rate. The terms of trade ( TOT ) are: P S P* (2) p  TOT  M  PX P where, p = terms of trade or real exchange rate, PM = price of imports, PX = price of exports, S = spot exchange rate ($/€), P = domestic price level, and P * = foreign price level. By presenting the natural logarithm of a variable with its lower-case letter ( ln X t  x t ), eq. (2) becomes: p  tot t  st  pt*  pt (3) We will test the J-curve hypothesis by using, first, a regression analysis and a GARCH-M model for the exchange rate fluctuation by writing eq. (1) as follows: (4) Now, by taking the logarithms of the variables (the lower case letters are the ln of the capital counterpart), we have from eqs. (4) and (3) the following eq. (5): (5) A Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity (GARCH)4 model can be used, here, to model and forecast the conditional variance of the spot exchange rate. The variance of the dependent variable ( ) is modeled as a function of exogenous or predetermined macro-variables ( ) from both countries and of the conditional variance ( ) of the ( ), which are included in the mean eq. (6) and give the GARCH-in-Mean (GARCH-M) model: (6) Graph 1. Current Acount and Trade Balance Note: -----Blue line: Balance of CA (goods and services) and ----- Red line: Trade balance (goods). Source:https://fredblog.stlouisfed.org/2017/02/demystifying-the-tradebalance/?utm_source=series_page&utm_medium=related_content&utm_term=related_resources&utm_campaign=fredblog 4 See, Bollerslev (1986). 3 | www.ijbms.net International Journal of Business & Management Studies ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) The GARCH-M (q, p) variance is: ∑ ∑ (7) We can determine the volatility of the exchange rate ( ) in eq. (7) if it is statistically significant by using the multivariate GARCH-M model.5 We can begin with the simplest GARCH (1, 1) specification or a higher order GARCH model, GARCH (q, p) to test the significant of its lagged values on ( ), where q is the order of the autoregressive GARCH terms and p is the order of the moving average ARCH terms, eq. (7). Then, we combine eq. (5) the trade account and eq. (7) the conditional variance or volatility of the spot exchange rate ( ). This volatility can show the significant effect of past exchange rates movements on our trade account. We care for the periods of time that the spot rate has caused a positive adjustment on the trade balance. (8) or ( ) (9) Now, eq. (1), domestic exports ( x t ) or foreign imports ( mt* ) and domestic imports ( m t ) or foreign exports ( xt* ) can be written with the following linear functions: mt*  x t   0  1 ( st  pt*  pt )   2 y t*   1t x t*  mt   0   1 ( s t  pt* (10)  p t )   2 y t   2t (11) 6 If the Marshall-Lerner condition (price elasticity of supply of exports and demand for imports), eq. (12), holds (elastic domestic and foreign demands for imports), a devaluation of the dollar can improve the trade account. Devaluation increases the price of imports and reduces the price of exports; and due to the law of demand, imports are falling and exports are increasing and the trade account is improved. The Marshall-Lerner condition holds when, 1  1  1 (12) In addition, a vector autoregression (VAR) model is used based on exports, eq. (10) and imports, eq. (11) to test the effects of the lagged ( ) on and , which is the following VAR system, eqs. (13): 5 6 See, Engle, Lilien, and Robins (1987). Also, Smith, Soresen, and Wickens (2003). The empirical results (regressions) are as following for the logarithm of the U.S. imports ( m t ) from U.K., x t*  mt  4.418  0.060 ( s t  p t*  p t )  1.276 ** y t  0.996 *** AR(1)  0.643 *** MA(1) (4.939) (0.116) (0.535) (0.004) (0.30) R 2  0.981, SER  0.110, F  5,891.758, D  W  1.875, N  569, RMSE  0.109208 and the U.S. exports ( x t ) to U.K., mt*  x t  8.077 ***  0.122 ( s t  p t*  p t )  1.268 *** y t*  0.904 *** AR(1)  0.421*** MA(1) (1.564) (0.138) (0.124) (0.030) (0.067) R 2  0.899, SER  0.097, F  652.166, D  W  1.886, N  372, RMSE  0.096649 The empirical results show that the price elasticity of demand for imports has correct sign (-0.060), but it is statistically insignificant. The income elasticity is not very high (+1.276) and statistically significant at 5% level. The price elasticity of supply of exports is (+0.122), but insignificant and the British income elasticity for demand for U.S. exports is (+1.268), statistically significant at 1% level. Thus, the Marshall-Lerner condition, eq. (12), does not hold: 0.060  0.122  0.182  1 (inelastic demand and supply; thus, a depreciation of the U.S. dollar cannot improve the trade account). Only, it can cause an increase in prices (inflation), due to excess supply of money, as the following correlation and causality statistics show: , ); ; also, ; , . Thus, the zero federal funds rate since 2008 has caused this enormous inflation (official π = 9.1% in June 2022 and 7.7% in October 2022) in the country; but, (SGS π = 17%) and other independent studies insist that it is over 30%. 4 | Trade Deficit and Currency Devaluation- Testing the J-Curve: Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis et al. Vol. 03 - Issue: 12/December_2022 ©Institute for Promoting Research & Policy Development ( ( DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 ) ) (13) The interrelated objective variables and of the trade account ( ) are the endogenous variables of the VAR as a function of the lagged values of these two endogenous variables plus the lag and the two income ( and ) variables to test the real exchange rate volatility and its effects on trade. III. Some Empirical Results The data are monthly and are coming from Economagic.com, Eurostat, and Bloomberg. For the Euro-zone (€), the data are from 2004:12 to 2020:12; for Mexico (MP), they are from 1994:08 to 2021:02; for Canada (C$), they are from 1981:03 to 2020:12; for U.K. (£), the data are from 1990:01 to 2018:05; for Switzerland (SF), the data are from 2001:11 to 2021:02; for Japan (¥), they are from 1990:01 to 2021:02; and lastly, for Australia (A$), the data are from 1986:10 to 2021:02. The variables are U.S. exports to (usxfc) and imports from (usmfc) these foreign countries, trade accounts (ustafc), incomes ( and ), exchange rates (st) quoted in American terms ($/FC), price levels ( and ), terms of trades (tott), and the exchange rates volatilities ( ). We start estimating eq. (9) by using the GARCH-M model of eq. (7). The results appeared in Table 1. We see that the sum of the ARCH and GARCH coefficients (α+β) are very close to one (1) for Mexico, Canada, U.K., Switzerland, Japan, and Australia, indicating that volatility shocks are quite persistent for these countries. The only exception is the Euro-zone. These results are often observed in high frequency financial data. The J-curve hypothesis is that the trade account deteriorates in the S-R and improves in the L-R.7 Table 1 shows that a devaluation of the dollar has significant effects in period ( tot t  3 ) by reducing the ustaeu and improves it later in ( ). The residual (ARCH)  t21 has a significant positive effect at the 5% level and the variances (GARCH) are highly positive significant at  t21 (5% level) and negative at  t2 2 (1% level). The devaluation of the dollar has no significant effects on ustam. The residual (ARCH) and have significant positive effects at 1% level and a significant negative effect at 1% level; the variance (GARCH) is positive and significant at (5% level). Also, a devaluation of the dollar has a positive significant effect on ustac at (1% (at 1% level). The ARCH has a significant negative effect at  t22 (at 5% level) and a positive at level) and the GARCH a significant negative effect at  t2 2 (at 1% level). Then, in  t23 the effect becomes positive at 1% level. With U.K., a devaluation of the dollar has a significant negative effect on ustauk at tot t  7 (1% level) and another negative one at tot t  9 (at 10% level). The ARCH has positive effect at  t21 (at 1% level) and the GARCH has a significant negative effect at  t23 (at 1% level) and two positive effects at  t21 (10% level) and at  t2 2 (5% level). Now, with respect the ustasw, the results are: The devaluation of the dollar has a significant negative effect at tot t 8 (at 5% level) and a positive at tot t (at 5% level). The ARCH has a positive significant effect at  t21 (at 1% level). The depreciation of the dollar has a significant positive effect on ustaj at tot t  7 (at 10% level). The ARCH has a significant positive effect at  t21 (at 1% level) and a GARCH significant negative effect at  t2 2 (at 5% level). Lastly, the devaluation of the dollar has a significant negative effect on ustaa at tot t 8 (at 5% level) and a positive at tot t  9 (at 1% level). The ARCH has significant negative effect at  t22 (at 10% level) and a positive at  t21 (at 5% level) and at  t23 (at 10% level). The GARCH has significant negative effect at  t25 (at 1% level) and positive at  t21 (at 1% level) and at  t2 4 (at 1% level). There are some S-R negative effects and some L-R positive ones that prove the J-curve effect, as Figure 1 shows. The income effects ( y t ) is negative, except with Australia and the ( y t* ) is positive except with Japan and Australia. Further, the long run estimates of the U.S. exports ( ) and U.S. imports ( ) from foreign countries, eq. (13), are taking place by using a VAR model and are presented in Tables 2a and 2b. The VAR model is estimated by using lags of terms of trade ( ) up to nine lags (j = 0, 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9). The usxeu and usmeu are positively affected by the U.S. income ( y t ) at the 1% level of significant. The devaluation of the dollar increases x t and m t at tot t and reduces imports at tot t 1 (at 5% level). The usxm and usmm have significant positive effects from (at 1% level) and usmm has a positive effect from (at 10% level). The devaluation of the dollar has significant positive effects on and at (1% level) and significant negative effect at 7 The J-curve hypothesis: (M↑ and X↓) => TA↓ (S-R) => (M↓ and X↑) => TA↑ (L-R). 5 | www.ijbms.net International Journal of Business & Management Studies ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) (1% level). The usxc and usmc have significant positive effects from y t (at 1% level) and negative from y t* (at 5% level and 1% level respectively). The devaluation of the dollar has significant positive effects on x t and m t at tot t 1 period (at 10% and 5% level respectively). The devaluation of the dollar has negative effects on x t at tot t  2 (at 5% level). The usxuk and usmuk have significantly been affected by y t (at 10% and 1% level) and negatively the m t by y t* at 1% level. The devaluation has a positive effect on x t at tot t (at 5% level) at tot t  3 (at 1% level) and at tot t 8 (at 10% level); it has a negative effect at tot t 1 (at 1% level) and tot t  7 (at 1% level). No significant effects on U.S. m t from U.K. The usxsw are positively affected and significant by Swiss income y t* at 1% level, by tot t (at 1% level), and negatively by tot t 1 (at 1% level). The usmsw are positively affected by U.S. income ( y t ) at the 10% level and negatively by tot t 8 at 1% level. Now, the usxj are positively affected by y t and y t* at 1% level. The devaluation of the dollar has positive effects at tot t (at 1% level) and tot t -5 (at 10% level); it has a negative effect at tot t 1 (at 10% level). The usmj have positive significant effects from y t and y t* (at 1% level). The devaluation of the dollar increases imports at tot t (at 10% level), at tot t -5 (at 5% level) and at tot t -9 (at 5% level). The devaluation of the dollar reduces usmj at period tot t  3 at 5% level. Lastly, the uuxa are affected positively by y t (at 1% level) and negatively by y t* (at 10% level). The devaluation of the dollar increases exports to Australia at tot t period (1% level of significant). The usma have a positive significant effect from y t (at 5% level). The devaluation of the dollar increases imports from Australia at tot t  3 (at 5% level) and decreases imports at tot t  2 (at 5% level). The results for these seven countries trading with U.S. show that there are some J-curve effects. The Graphs A1a, A2a, A3a, A4a, A5a, A6a, and A7a, in the Appendix, show the ustafcf (U.S. trade forecasting with the seven different foreign countries) and their variances. Graphs A1b, A2b, A3b, A4b, A5b, A6b, and A7b give the responses to Cholesky innovations, where imports are increasing up to 5 months and then, they decline. The exports are declining in the S-R and then, they stay constant (flat lines). Consequently, the J-curve has been tested by examining the pattern of distributed effects of the (real exchange rate) on exports and imports, which make up the trade account ( ). These coefficients of the lag real exchange rate depreciation (tot) show that the depreciation of the dollar leads to deterioration of trade in the short-run and to an improvement in the trade account after some periods. (Tables 1, 2a, and 2b and the Graphs in the Appendix). These tables are giving some mixed results; but overall, the devaluation of the dollar improves the trade with a delay for all the countries (J-curve) with Euro-zone, Mexico, Canada, U.K., Switzerland, Japan, and Australia. Table 3 gives the results by testing the stationarity of our variables used in our regression and VAR models, with a unit root test (Augmented Dickey-Fuller test). Some variables are stationary series, I(0); but their difference stationary series are all integrated as I(1) that there is one unit root; except LSWCPI, which is I(2), a second order integration (two unit roots). Table 4 reports the Johansen cointegration test of the VAR estimates. Trace and Max-Eigenvalue tests indicate cointegration at the 1% level. IV. Policy Implications of Trade Balance The J-curve hypothesis says that after the depreciation of a currency ($) or increase of the spot exchange rate ($/€), in American terms, the balance of trade worsens in the short-run, but improves in the long-run, (Figure 1). The trade balance ( ) is very important for a country and shows its competitiveness, production, employment,8 «Μέ ηήλ ἐργαζία θεύγεη ηὀ ἄγτος, ἡ ἀγφλία, ἡ ἀλία, ἡ θαηάζιηυε θαί ηό θελό ηῆς υστῆς θαί δεῖ ὁ ἄλζρφπος εὐηστηζκέλα, ποιηηηζκέλα θαί ἰδαληθά, ἀθοῦ κέ ηήλ ἀκοηβή ηῆς ἐργαζίας ηοσ ἀποιακβάλεη ηά ἀγαζά θαί γίλεηαη θοηλφληθός θαί δεκηοσργηθός.» Παῦιος Ἀζ. Παιούθας. 6 | Trade Deficit and Currency Devaluation- Testing the J-Curve: Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis et al. 8 Vol. 03 - Issue: 12/December_2022 ©Institute for Promoting Research & Policy Development DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 resources, self-sufficiency, autarky, public policy effectiveness, leadership, independence, etc. The U.S. trade deficit after 1980 is enormous,9 showing and proving the inefficiency of the public policies and the aggravation of the structural problems of our economy. Two important events that have contributed to deterioration of the U.S. trade account, Graph 2, were: First, the NAFTA agreement in 1994, signed by President Clinton10 and second, the 9 The U.S. trade deficit increased from $676.7 billion in 2020 to $1,076.8 billion in 2021. The trade deficit in January 2022 was $107.571 billion and up to June 2022, it was $647.7 billion. See, ―Trade in Goods with World, Seasonally Adjusted‖, https://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/balance/c0004.html .The U.S. current account the last 60 years is as follows (Graph 2). See, Petros C. Mavroidis, André Sapir, ―China and the WTO: An uneasy relationship‖, April 29, 2021. https://voxeu.org/article/china-and-wto-uneasy-relationship Graph 2: U.S. Current Account Note: In 1994, the free trade agreement (NAFTA) takes place and the CA deficit increased. In 2002 China joins the WTO and the CA deficit increased enormously. The current account was in balance until late 1970s and it had the highest deficit during the years 2005-2008. The current account gap in the U.S. widened to $214.8 billion or 3.7% of the GDP in the third quarter of 2021 from an upwardly revised $198.3 billion in the prior period and compared to forecasts of a $205 billion shortfall. It was the largest current account deficit since Q3 2006 as imports surged to a record and companies were trying to fill up inventories. Reduced surplus on services and expanded deficits on secondary income and on goods were partly offset by an expanded surplus on primary income. The services surplus shrank to $49.9 billion from $62.6 billion in Q2, the goods (TA) deficit rose to $274.8 billion in Q3 of 2021from $269.6 billion in Q2 of 2021, it became $291.4 billion in Q2 of 2022, led by imports of industrial supplies and materials, mainly petroleum products and metals and nonmetallic products, and the secondary income shortfall advanced to $38 billion from $30 billion. In 2021, the U.S. had a $915.0 billion deficit with its top ten trading partners. With China, it was $355.3 billion, with Mexico $108.2 billion, with Vietnam $91 billion, with Germany $70.1 billion, with Japan $60.2 billion, with Ireland $60.2 billion, with Canada $49.5 billion, with Malaysia $41 billion, with Taiwan $40.2 billion, and with Italy $39.3 billion. https://www.thebalance.com/u-s-trade-deficit-causes-effects-trade-partners-3306276 Source: U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis and https://tradingeconomics.com/united-states/current-account Also, Foreign Trade. https://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/balance/c0004.html Further, See, Foreign Trade. https://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/balance/c0004.html 10 ―NAFTA is over 1,700 pages long--741 pages for the treaty itself, 348 pages for annexes, and 619 pages for footnotes and explanations. It is difficult to see how 1,700 pages of government rules and regulations can free trade. By definition, free trade is the removal of government from the trading process, not its expansion.‖ See, Joe Ogrinc, ―The NAFTA Analysis: Not Free Trade‖, Saturday, May 1, 1993. https://fee.org/articles/the-nafta-analysis-not-free-trade/?gclid=EAIaIQobChMItPzezp CC9QIVArjICh1dPwHqEAAYAiAAEgJEsfD_BwE . Unfortunately, no one from the Senators is reading these long bills or laws; they just vote ―Yea‖ or ―Nay‖ going with the party’s will and against their citizens’ and voters’ will. (Sic). Joseph Stiglitz, Clinton’s economic advisor, had insisted to the president to avoid to sign the NAFTA agreement because, it will be disastrous for the U.S. economy. But, he signed NAFTA ignoring his advisor’s suggestion. The problem is just a leadership problem. Who is controlling these pseudo-leaders? On September 30, 2018, an agreement was reached during re-negotiations on changes to NAFTA. The next day, a re-negotiated version of the agreement was published, and referred to as the United States-MexicoCanada Agreement (USMCA). In November of 2018, at the G20 summit, the USMCA was signed by President Donald Trump, Canadian Prime Minister Justin Trudeau and then-Mexican President Enrique Peña Nieto. See, Anne Sraders, ―What Is NAFTA? History, Purpose and What It Means in 2019‖. https://www.thestreet.com /politics/nafta-north-american-free-tradeagreement-14651970 . ―Since NAFTA was ratified, U.S.-Mexico trade—excluding services and petroleum, which are not addressed by NAFTA—has grown three and a half times faster than U.S. GDP. The United States ran a small trade surplus with Mexico in 1993; today, the U.S.-Mexico trade deficit is America’s second largest. If NAFTA were solely responsible for all that trade, it might appear that renegotiating it to obtain more favorable terms for the United States would have big payoffs, and that repealing it might improve the U.S. deficit.‖ See, Russell A. Green and Tony Payan, ―WAS NAFTA GOOD FOR THE UNITED STATES?‖ June 2017. file:///C:/Users/JK/AppData/Local/Microsoft/Windows/Temporary%20Internet%20Files/Content.IE5/51F9Y8AK/BI-pubNAFTA-062317.pdf . See also, Kallianiotis, Niko J. ―America in a Trance‖ Damiani. https://www.amazon.com/Niko-J-Kallianiotis-America-Trance/dp/8862085958 7 | www.ijbms.net International Journal of Business & Management Studies ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) entrance of China to the World Trade Organization (WTO) on December 11, 2001.11 Now, China has become the number one producer and net exporter of the world (―everything is Chinese‖). This dependence on Chinese products will destroy domestic production, existing industries, employment, incomes, and social welfare in U.S. and EU, too. The U.S. and the entire world will be very soon in big trouble with Chinese aggression.12 It is another culture and has nothing in common with the traditional (Christian) West. The country to recover must satisfy the following equation: (14) where, Y = GDP or national income, E = expenditures (absorption = C+I+G), T = taxes, G = government spending, S = saving, I = investment, X = exports, and M = imports. But, because , which shows that the national production is less than the domestic spending. Also, the government budget is in deficit, due to enormous spending, inefficiencies, corruption, wastes, and businesses (corporations) do not pay taxes.13 Further, because the cost of living is enormous (high inflation) and the real return on savings is negative ( ); thus savings are declining.14 Lastly, because the country does not produce the goods needed for domestic consumption, investment, and government spending. The real GDP growth was negative (-1.6%) for the 1st quarter of 2022 and (-0.6%) for the 2nd quarter of 2022.15 The economy is in a stagflation, (Fedflation and Bidenflation), Figure 2. The monetary policy has some small significant effects on the value of the dollar and the trade account,16 but this easy monetary policy since 2008 has caused an enormous inflation and much other harm to people 11 On 11 December 2001, China officially joined the WTO. Its achievements since then have been truly remarkable. In 2001, China was the sixth largest exporter of goods in the world (fourth, if the European Union is counted as one unit). Since 2009, it has been the world’s largest goods exporter, surpassing even the EU bloc from 2014 onwards. See, Petros C. Mavroidis, André Sapir, “China and the WTO: An uneasy relationship”, April 29, 2021. https://voxeu.org/article/china-and-wto-uneasyrelationship 12 The neo-pagan (―economic elites‖) forced the pseudo-leaders to go against Russia, which is a European Christian Orthodox nation, with the highest moral and ethical values in the world. The principal accessory (aider abettor) of the war in Ukraine is the U.S. and NATO. Actually, it is a U.S. war against Russia in the land of poor Ukrainians. 13 In U.S., 55 companies with pre-tax income $40.482 billion, paid in 2020, zero taxes and received a tax refund of $3.49 billion; thus, their effective tax rate was -8.6%. See, ―55 Corporations Paid $0 in Federal Taxes on 2020 Profits‖. https://itep.org/55-profitable-corporations-zero-corporate-tax/ . So, the budget deficit ($1.986 trillion) and the national debt ($31.281 trillion) are going up daily. The Treasury Secretary, Janet Yellen, said that ―deficits do not matter‖. (Sic) or Sick? See, https://www.usdebtclock.org/ 14 See, Personal Saving Rate. https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/PSAVERT . See, also, Personal saving as a percentage of disposable personal income. https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/A072RC1Q156SBEA . Further, Gross saving as a percentage of gross national income, https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/W206RC1Q156SBEA . The U.S. official inflation rate (July 2022) was: and the SGS inflation was: . Then, . 15 See, BEA, ―Gross Domestic Product‖, https://www.bea.gov/data/gdp/gross-domestic-product 16 See, Table A2: Measuring the correlation (  ) and testing the causality (  ) between the instruments ( i FFt , MB , and M s ) and the objective variables ( TA and e ) --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- (1) The Previous Zero Interest Rate Regime, ZIRR (2008:12-2015:11): iFF , ta  0.358 iFF  ta and ta  iFF ( F  6.068*** ) iFF , e  0.073 iFF  e ( F  2.877* ) and e  iFF mb , ta  0.663 mb  ta ( F  2.726* ) and ta  mb ( F  3.747** ) mb , e  0.501 mb  e ( F  4.433** ) and e  mb m, ta  0.697 m  ta ( F  3.371** ) and ta  m ( F  4.519** )  m, e  0.625 m  e ( F  3.416** ) and e  m  iFF ,  0.015   i FF ( F  2.891* ) iFF , p  0.614 iFF  p and p  iFF ( F  4.743** ) mb, p  0.973 mb  p and p  mb ( F  4.617** ) 8 | Trade Deficit and Currency Devaluation- Testing the J-Curve: Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis et al. Vol. 03 - Issue: 12/December_2022 ©Institute for Promoting Research & Policy Development DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 (enormous social cost, bail out cost to taxpayers and bail in cost to depositors),17 by paying IOR, IONRRP, and forcing a . Then, a combination of monetary and trade policy is necessary to increase the terms of trade ( ) and improve the TA. This policy can be more effective through a pure trade one, like, a tariff or a quota or anything else that can affect positively the terms of trade and improve the trade account and consequently, competitiveness, production and employment in the country and reduction of outsourcing. The trade among countries must be fair and satisfy the social welfare of the country’s citizens. The latest expansionary monetary policy (zero interest rate from December 16, 2008 until December 16, 2015, and then again from March 16, 2020 until March 16, 2022: )18 and the similar fiscal one with the stimulus money plus the unemployment insurance and the questionable ―infrastructure‖ bill and lately, the ―inflation reduction act‖ have increase aggregate demand (AD). The COVID-19 ―innovation‖, the irrational vaccine mandates, the other inhumane restrictions, the lockdowns, the layoffs and the resignations of people from their Figure 2 U.S. Current Aggregate Demand and Supply Note: The quantitative easing (QE) moved the AD0 to AD1 from point E0 to E1. The jobs because they were continue increases in money supply and the COVID-19 stimulus increase the AD to unvaccinated, the supply chain AD2 ; Biden’s regulations and businesses’ lockdowns shifted the AS 0 to AS1 and the problems, the traveling equilibrium output (Q2) and employment (u2) to point E2 . Then, the new money supply and the ―infrastructure‖ bill moved the AD to AD3 and the vaccine mandates, resignations, layoffs, supply chain problems, ―protection of the environment‖ by going ** .971 fuels, magainst ( FAS p ASmto 994*the  82 .and ) equilibrium to E4 , which cause m  p and the etc, reduce , p  0fossil reduction in output (Q4 ) and high unemployment (u4 ) and at the same time an (2)enormous Theinflation Current in New Regime, NRIf(2015:12-2020:12): P4 (stagflation). the AS had been at AS0 and the AD at AD3 , *** the economy almost at full employment and the output would have been to E , with 5 iFF , ta  0.111 iFF  ta ( F  6.286 ) and ta  iFF moderate inflation at P5. Then, moderation is the only solution, but our policy makers values iFFhistoric  e traditions, iFF and virtues. i do, enot  follow 0.139these and e  FF mb, ta  0.279 mb  ta and ta  mb mb, e  0.297 mb  e ( F  5.393*** ) and e  mb m, ta  0.314 m  ta ( F  8.792*** ) and ta  m ( F  3.180** ) m, e  0.281 m  e  iFF ,  0.125   i FF ( F  7.570 *** ) iFF , p  0.320 iFF  p ( F  2.929* ) and p  iFF mb , p  0.146 mb  p and p  mb m, p  0.871 m  p and e  m and p  m ( F  5.208 ) *** Note: iFF = federal funds rate, ta = trade account, e = exchange rate, mb = monetary base, m = money supply, p=ln of price level, π = inflation rate,  m, c = correlation coefficients between m and e , mb  e (F ) ) = causality test between mb and e mb causes e and F-statistic in parenthesis), mb  ta = no causality between mb and ta , a lower-case letter (mb) is the logarithm of the capital one (MB), i.e., mb = ln MB. Source: Kallianiotis (2021a, Table A2, pp. 107-108). 17 See, Kallianiotis (2022). 18 See, ―Open Market Operations‖, https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/openmarket.htm 9 | www.ijbms.net International Journal of Business & Management Studies ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) restrictions, the tough regulations, the reduction of use of coal, oil and natural gas in production (―green fraud‖), etc. have reduced aggregate supply (AS), Figure 2. Then, U.S. prices went up (huge inflation)19 and a reduction in production has increased imports and reduced exports; and consequently, the trade account has deteriorated (TA<0), Graph 2. The Trade Account deficit was $1,076.8 billion in 2021 and up to June 2022, it was $647.7 billion.20 The enormous money supply (M2 = $22.072 trillion in April 2022 and fell to $21.338 trillion with September 2022)21 has also generated a very dangerous bubble in the stock market.22 In March 17, 2022, the Fed started to increase the federal funds target to and from November 2, 2022, it became .23 But, prices continue to grow. Thus, our public policies are inefficient, ineffective, and anti-social. The country cannot be dependent on foreign production (Chinese goods), but we have to increase domestic production (agricultural and manufacturing) to satisfy domestic demand and export also these products to other nations. The reduction in oil production will cause serious economic and social problems in U.S., the gasoline prices have increased by 50%. The price of fertilizers is skyrocketing and together with the price of fuel, gas, the cost of agricultural products continues to go up, which increases their prices. The uncontrolled outsourcing, the unfair trade, the oligopolist high tech censorship and propaganda, the corruption of our politicians and institutions, and the anti-social globalization have destroyed the country’s social welfare, its independence, its freedoms, its value system, its national income, and its citizens’ wellbeing. The risk of the stock market bubble has to be controlled. Monetary policy must increase the federal funds rate to reduce inflation and make American products less expensive domestically and for our exports. Real interest rate must be positive ( )24 and the growth in the stock market enough to cover only the historic risk premium ( ). A 36% growth in the financial market is just a dangerous deception to the poor citizens (investors), who will lose their wealth and their retirement income (IRA). V. Concluding Remarks The official inflation was 9.1% (June 2022), the SGS inflation was 18%, but the average consumer’s inflation (cost of living) exceeds 30%. See, https://tradingeconomics.com/united-states/inflation-cpi. See also, http://www.shadowstats. com/alternate_ data/inflation-charts 20 See, ―Foreign Trade‖, https://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/balance/c0004.html . See also, https://www.bea.gov/news/2022 /us-international-trade-goods-and-services-january-2022 . Also, https://tradingeconomics.com/united-states/balance-of-trade . Further,https://tcf.org/content/report/true-state-u-s-economy/?gclid=EAIaIQobChMIxLTQ3tL49gIVpQiICR0Teg9nEAA YBCAAEgK61fD_BwE 21 See, https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/WM2NS. 22 The money supply (M2) was in March 2009: $8,438.3 billion and in March 2022: $21,768.8 billion, a small reduction; in January 2022 it was $21,844.7 billion, an annual growth of 12.12%, and continues to grow; in April 2022 reached $22,072.1 billion and in October 2022 fell to $21,409.7 billion. See, https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/WM2NS The DJIA was on 3/9/2009: 6,547.05 and on 1/4/2022 reached 36,799.65 a growth of 36.242% p.a. This enormous liquidity was not necessary and it causes this colossal bubble in the stock market, which will burst and will generate a new global crisis even worse than the coronavirus one. See, Macrotrends. https://www.macrotrends.net/1319/dow-jones-100-year-historicalchart . The bubble has started losing air with the Ukrainian crisis that we have created. The DJIA from 36,799.65 (1/4/2022) has fallen to 28,725.51 (9/30/2022), a decline by 8,074.14 points or -21.941%. 23 See, https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/DFEDTARU 24 The Fisher equation gives: , where r = 0.5%, πε = 8.5%; then, an i = 9% is fair for the entire economy and it can reduce the bubble in the financial market. Kallianiotis (2019b) rule is an expansion of Taylor’s rule by using an extra term, the growth of the financial market ( g DJIA ), as follows: 19 t i FFt   t  rt*   ( t   t* )   u (ut  utN )   DJIA ( g DJIAt  g *DJIAt ) * = the optimal (the bubble prevention) growth of the DJIA ( where, g DJIA = the actual growth of the DJIA index, g DJIA t t * g DJIA  7%  i10YTB  5% t or HRP  8.7% ), and   0.25 ,  u  0.50 ,  DJIA  0.25 . Kallianiotis rule with June 2021 gives: (1) With official data, the target federal funds rate ( iFF ) must have been: i FF  5.4%  1%  0.25(5.4%  2%)  0.50(5.9%  4%)  0.25 (18.22%  8.7%)  8.68% , but it was close to zero. (2) With SGS data, the iFF should have been: i FF  13%  1%  0.25(13%  2%)  0.50(25.8%  4%)  0.25 (18.22%  8.7%)  8.23% (3)With February 2022, iFF = 7.5%+1%+0.25 (7.5%-2%)-0.50 (4%-4%)+0.25 (18.73%-8.7%) = 12.383% (with official data) and with SGS data (u=24.5%), iFF = 2.075% and it was very low, 0.00 ̅ 0.25%. 10 | Trade Deficit and Currency Devaluation- Testing the J-Curve: Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis et al. Vol. 03 - Issue: 12/December_2022 ©Institute for Promoting Research & Policy Development DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 The current paper examines the short-run (up to nine months) relationship between the trade account and changes in real exchange rates (TOT) of seven countries with respect the U.S. dollar ($/FC). It was found that real exchange rate changes have a significant impact on the U.S. trade balance. The empirical results show that there exists a long-run relationship between the trade account (TA) and the income (domestic, Y and foreign, Y*), the terms of trade (TOT), and volatility of the exchange rate, the residual ε2 (ARCH) and the variance ζ2 (GARCH) have a significant effect on the TAs, Table 1. The VAR estimations give similar results of the same independent variables on exports (X) and imports (M) between the U.S. and the other seven countries (Euro-zone, Mexico, Canada, U.K., Switzerland, Japan, and Australia), Tables 2a and 2b. A unit root and a cointegration test are given in Tables 3 and 4, too. The results of this analysis could be relevant regarding the impact of exchange rate changes on trade account (mostly, U.S. trade deficits). While the short-run effects of changes in the exchange rate on the balance of trade of a county may be perverse (J-curve), in the long-run the impact of exchange rate changes on trade volumes are expected to be sufficiently large, so a depreciation of the domestic currency will improve the country’s trade account. Number of factors may explain the persistence of the J-curve effect. In the short-run, a combination of price and volume effects, following a currency depreciation may increase a country’s spending on imports by more than it increases its export earnings, thus accounting for the observed J-curve effect; then a devaluation will likely result in an initial deterioration of the trade balance. Furthermore, differences in the degree of the restrictiveness of devaluing countries trade regimes also may affect the duration of the J-curve effect. The graphs in the Appendix support our argument of existing J-curves between the U.S. and the seven partners in trade countries. Finally, as far as policy implications are concerned, it is important for the country to use public policies (monetary, fiscal, and trade) to improve the domestic economy and the social welfare of its citizens. The economy has some structural problems and must be considered as soon as possible, otherwise the country will lose completely its competitiveness, as it has already lost its manufacturing output and the agricultural one follows, compared with China.25 The liberal views of globalization, the new monetary and fiscal policies, which have caused inflation and high risk, the ―protection‖ of the environment by going against fossil furls, and the disregard of people, and of ―nothing matters‖ are going to lead the country to a permanent negative trend. The trade must be fair among the nations and in favor of the domestic economy and not ―the allies first‖ policy that the U.S. is using since 1980. It seems (it is obvious by now) that there is a serious political (―leadership‖) problem in the western ―democracies‖ the last fifty years. Acknowledgments We would like to acknowledge the assistance provided by Julia Betti, Meshari A. Albakhat, and Janice Mecadon. Financial support (professional travel expenses, submission fees, etc.) are provided by Provost’s Office (Faculty Travel Funds, Henry George Fund, and Faculty Development Funds). The usual disclaimer applies. Then, all remaining errors are of the authors. Works Citation Amaded, Kimberly (2022), ―What Is the Current U.S. Trade Deficit?‖. https://www.thebalance.com/u-s-tradedeficit-causes-effects-trade-partners-3306276 Backus, D.K., Kehoe, P.J., Kydland, F.E. (1994), ―Dynamics of the trade balance and the terms of trade: The Jcurve?‖ The American Economic Review, March, 84(1):84–103 Bahmani-Oskooee, M. (1991), ―Is there a long-run relation between the trade balance and the real effective exchange rate of LDCs?‖, Economics Letters 36: 403–407 Bera, A.K., Higgins, M.L. (1993), ―ARCH models: Properties, estimation and testing‖, Journal of Economic Surveys , December. 7(4): 305–366 Bollerslev, T. (1986), ―Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity‖, Journal of Econometrics , 31: 307–327 Bollerslev, T. (1987), ―A conditional heteroskedastic time series model for speculative prices and rates of return‖, The Review of Economics and Statistics, August, 69(3): 542–547 Campbell, J.Y., Shiller, R.J. (1987), ―Cointegration and tests of present value models‖, Journal of Political Economy, October, 95(5): 1062–1088 Chou, R. (1988), ―Volatility persistence and stock valuation: Some empirical evidence using GARCH‖, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 3: 279–294 See, Mark J. Perry, ―Chart of the day: China is now world’s No. 1 manufacturer‖. https://www.aei.org/carpe-diem/chart-ofthe-day-china-is-now-worlds-no-1-manufacturer/ 25 11 | www.ijbms.net International Journal of Business & Management Studies ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) Engle, Robert F., David M. Lilien, and Russell P. Robins, (1987), ―Estimating Time Varying Risk Premia in the Term Structure: The ARCH-M Model‖, Econometrica, 55, 391-407. Himarios, D. (1989), ―Do devaluations improve the trade balance? The evidence revisited‖, Economic Inquiry, 27: 143–168 Kallianiotis, I.N. (2022), ―The Inadmissible Social Cost of the Modern Monetary Policy and the Liberal Fiscal Policy‖, International Journal of Economics, Business and management Research, Volume 6, Issue 8, August 2022, pp. 274-333. https://ijebmr.com/link/1019 ,Archive issue: https://ijebmr.com/archive Published Issue Link: https://ijebmr.com/view/8/2022 Kallianiotis, John N. (2021a), ―The New Monetary Policy: Its Social Cost and Benefits‖, Chapter 1, in Progress in Economics Research, Volume 46, Albert Tavidze (Editor), pp. 1-111, Hauppauge, N.Y.: Nova Science Publishers, May, ISBN: 978-1-53619-704-4 (eBook) and ISBN: 1549-1552. https://novapublishers.com/shop/progress-in-economics-research-volume-46/ Kallianiotis, I. N. (2021b), ―Ethics in Finance, Public Policies, and Institutions: The Latest Financial and Social Crises‖, International Journal of Managerial Studies and Research (IJMSR), Volume 9, Issue 1, pp. 13-41. https://arcjournals.org/international-journal-of-managerial-studies-and-research/volume-9-issue1/,https://arcjournals.org/pdfs/ijmsr/v9-i1/3.pdf , file:///C:/Users/R97719842/Downloads/02200133%20(2).pdf Kallianiotis, J. N. (2019a), Foreign Exchange Rates and International Finance, Hauppauge,N.Y.: Nova Science Publishers, October, ISBN: 978-1-53616-550-0. https://novapublishers.com/shop/foreign-exchange-ratesand-international-finance/ Kallianiotis, I.N. (2019b), ―Monetary Policy, Real Cost of Capital, Financial Markets, and the Real Economic Growth‖, Journal of Applied Finance & Banking, Vol. 9, No. 1, pp. 75-118. http://www.scienpress.com/journal_focus.asp?main_id=56&Sub_id=IV&Issue=810815 http://www.scienpress.com/Upload/JAFB/Vol%209_1_4.pdf Kallianiotis, John N. (2018), The European Union and its Debt Crises: The Deception of the Greeks, Hauppauge, N.Y.: Nova Science Publishers, August, ISBN: 978-1-53614-067-5. https://novapublishers.com/shop/theeuropean-union-and-its-debt-crises-the-deception-of-the-greeks/ Kallianiotis I. N. (2016), ―Factors Affecting the Exchange Rate Risk Premium‖, Journal of Applied Finance & Banking, Vol. 6, No. 6, November, pp. 33-55. http://www.scienpress.com/journal_focus.asp?main_id =56&Sub_id=IV&Issue=1945 and http://www.scienpress.com/Upload/JAFB/Vol%206_6_3.pdf Kallianiotis, J. N. (2013a), International Financial Transactions and Exchange Rates: Trade, Investment, and Parities, Theories, and Practices, Palgrave Macmillan, December, pages 332, ISBN: 978-1-137-35815-8. http://us.macmillan.com/internationalfinancialtransactionsandexchangerates/JohnNKallianiotis Kallianiotis, J. N. (2013b), Exchange Rates and International Financial Economics: History,Theories, and Practices, Palgrave Macmillan, October, pages 312, ISBN: 978-1-137-28322-1. http://us.macmillan.com/exchangeratesandinternationalfinancialeconomics/JohnNKallianiotis Marquez, J. (1991), ―The dynamics of uncertainty or the uncertainty of dynamics: Stochastic J-curves‖, The Review of Economics and Statistics, February, LXXIII(1): 125–133 Marwah, K., Klein, L.R. (1996), ―Estimation of J-curves: United States and Canada‖, Canadian Journal of Economics, August, XXIX(3):523–539 Pozo, S. (1992), ―Conditional exchange-rate volatility and the volume of international trade: Evidence from the early 1900s‖, The Review of Economics and Statistics, May, LXXIV(2): 325–329 Rose, A.K., Yellen, J.L. (1989), ―Is there a J-curve?‖, Journal of Monetary Economics, July, 24(1): 53–68 Rose, A.K. (1991), ―The role of exchange rate in a popular model of international trade: Does the Marshall-Lerner condition hold?‖, Journal of International Economics, May, 30(3/4): 301–316 Schwaiger, W.S.A. (1995), ―A note on GARCH predictable variances and stock market efficiency’, Journal of Banking and Finance, August, 19: 949–953 Singh, Tarlok (2004), ―Testing J-curve hypotheses and analyzing the effect of exchange rate volatility on the balance of trade in India‖, Empirical Economics, pp. 227-245. Smith, P., S. Soresen, and M. Wickens (2003), ―Macroeconomic Sources of Equity Risk‖, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 4070. 12 | Trade Deficit and Currency Devaluation- Testing the J-Curve: Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis et al. Vol. 03 - Issue: 12/December_2022 ©Institute for Promoting Research & Policy Development DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Variables 𝑒 𝑘 𝑤 𝑗 -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------0.487 -11.400*** 5.298*** -6.293*** 22.683*** 3.122** -1.742*** C (0.934) (0.430) (0.198) (0.684) (1.135) (1.220) (0.609) -0.065 -2.416*** -0.753*** -1.293*** -4.194*** 0.062 1.041*** (0.107) (0.074) (0.030) (0.117) (0.346 (0.040) (0.144) 0.110*** 2.279*** 0.249*** 1.447*** 1.834*** -0.313*** -0.525*** (0.037) (0.073) (0.014) (0.118) (0.291) (0.082) (0.068) 0.002 0.668*** 0.970** 0.744** (0.064) (0.197) (0.409) (0.295) -0.223 -0.758*** -0.597 -0.351 1 (0.104) (0.104) (0.410) (0.324) 0.540*** 0.174 -0.272 2 (0.071) (0.120) (0.215) -0.375** 0.014 0.306 0.279 3 (0.179) (0.151) (0.274) (0.253) 0.198* -0.045 4 (0.119) (0.158) 0.026 0.732* -0.307 5 (0.141) (0.387) (0.230) 0.126 -0.847** 0.344* 6 (0.129) (0.388) (0.207) -0.191 0.574 -0.328** -0.226** 7 (0.125) (0.475) (0.137) (0.103) *** * 0.075 0.249 -0.604 0.581*** 8 (0.104) (0.020) (0.345) (0.108) 0.062 9 (0.076) Variance Equation C  t21 2 2 2 3 2 0.006*** (0.001) 0.204** (0.100) 0.064 (0.140) - 4 - 5 - 2  t21 2 2 2 3 0.553** (0.227) -0.674*** (0.152) - 0.001 (0.001) 0.503*** (0.136) -0.373 (0.311) -0.379*** (0.187) 0.333*** (0.176) - 0.001** (0.001) 0.461*** (0.112) -0.414** (0.182) 0.201 (0.145) - 0.673 (0.604) 0.734** (0.347) -0.430 (0.387) 1.111*** (0.226) -0.772*** (0.296) 0.378*** (0.124) - 0.003 (0.005) 0.398*** (0.116) -0.193 (0.172) -0.047 (0.207) 0.534* (0.296) 0.600** (0.255) -0.407*** (0.148) Appendix 13 | www.ijbms.net 0.010 (0.007) 0.667*** (0.157) -0.058 (0.389) 0.218 (0.449) -0.016 (0.551) -0.269 (0.595) 0.151 (0.167) 0.004** (0.002) 0.397*** (0.120) -0.053 (0.239) 0.525 (0.393) -0.192** (0.086) - 0.003 (0.002) 0.259** (0.109) -0.286* (0.159) 0.295* (0.161) -0.029 (0.157) -0.046 (0.109) 1.013*** (0.266) -0.316 (0.269) -0.171 (0.244) International Journal of Business & Management Studies 2 -0.108 4 (0.193) 2 5 ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) 0.625*** (0.240) -0.412*** (0.109) 2 R 0.409 0.607 0.565 0.064 0.469 0.006 0.121 0.081 0.056 0.082 0.181 0.233 0.124 0.225 D  W 1.106 0.889 0.614 0.641 0.487 0.586 0.730 N 193 319 478 341 224 367 404 RMSE 0.079504 0.054466 0.081895 0.178658 0.229648 0.122846 0.223410 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- - Table 1: Estimation of Eq. (9) with the use of GARCH-M Model, Eq. (7): Trade Account and Real Exchange Rate Note: 𝑒 = ln of U.S. Trade Account with EU, = ln of U.S. Trade Account with Mexico, = ln of U.S. Trade Account with Canada, 𝑘 = ln of U.S. Trade Account with U.K., 𝑤 = ln of U.S. Trade Account with Switzerland, , 𝑗 = ln of U.S. Trade Account with Japan, , = U.S. Trade Account with Australia, = ln of U.S. Income (GDP), = ln of foreign Income (GDP), = ln of Terms of Trade (Real Exchange Rate), = lag of Residual R 2 = R-squared, = S.E. of regression, D  W = Durbin-Watson statistic, F = F statistic, N = number of observations, RMSE = Root Mean Squared Error, *** significant at the 1% level, ** significant at (ARCH), = lag of Variance (GARCH), the 5% level, and * significant at the 10% level. Source: Economagic.com, Bloomberg, and Eurostat. 14 | Trade Deficit and Currency Devaluation- Testing the J-Curve: Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis et al. Vol. 03 - Issue: 12/December_2022 ©Institute for Promoting Research & Policy Development DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- ----------------------------Variables 𝑒 𝑒 𝑘 𝑘 -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- ------------------------------0.375*** 0.450*** 0.077 0.023 0.121** 0.139 0.594*** -0.284*** 1 (0.084) (0.092) (0.110) (0.119) (0.079) (0.068) (0.056) (0.059) 0.078 0.344*** 0.241** 0.005 0.057 0.142** 0.314*** -0.125* 2 (0.088) (0.096) (0.116) (0.125) (0.085) (0.073) (0.063) (0.067) 0.031 0.218** -0.052 0.114 -0508*** -0.085 0.063 -0.156*** 3 (0.079) (0.086) (0.106) (0.114) (0.077) (0.066) (0.055) (0.059) *** 0.343*** 0.748*** 0.194** 0.285*** 0.005 0.542*** 0.439*** 1 -0.191 (0.069) (0.076) (0.101) (0.109) (0.091) (0.079) (0.051) (0.055) -0.191*** 0.120** -0.026 -0.096 -0.243*** -0.185 0.197*** 2 -0.080 (0.076) (0.083) (0.112) (0.121) (0.097) (0.083) (0.056) (0.059) 0.148*** 0.128** 0.442*** -0.072 0.217*** 0.110 -0.083 0.181*** 3 (0.070) (0.077) (0.098) (0.105) (0.091) (0.078) (0.051) (0.055) C -2.898*** -9.182*** -10.348*** -11.930*** -14.070*** -2.871*** 0.178 2.142** (1.973) (2.154) (2.011) (2.164) (0.680) (0.585) (0.970) (1.032) 1.462*** -0.250 0.696*** 0.625*** 0.410* 0.743*** 2.151*** 0.508* (0.280) (0.306) (0.268) (0.289) (0.130) (0.112) (0.229) (0.244) 0.759*** -0.054** -0.070*** -0.168 -0.015 -0.006 -0.590*** 1.023*** (0.036) (0.040) (0.271) (0.292) (0.027) (0.023) (0.221) (0.236) 0.382** 0.096 0.273* -0.212 0.009 -0.176 -0.180 0.444** (0.173) (0.189) (0.116) (0.125) (0.211) (0.181) (0.215) (0.229) 0.646*** 0.565* -0.122 -0.092 -0.790*** 0.548** -0.500** 0.493*** 1 (0.246) (0.269) (0.178) (0.192) (0.308) (0.265) (0.334) (0.355) 0.197 0.050 -0.480*** -0.710*** -0.586** -0.383 -0.366 0.083 2 (0.246) (0.268) (0.184) (0.198) (0.310) (0.267) (0.336) (0.357) -0.016 0.447* 0.197 0.212 0.126 0.163 1.018*** 0.208 3 (0.244) (0.267) (0.187) (0.201) (0.311) (0.267) (0.332) (0.353) -0.223 -0.364 -0.145 0.039 0.289 0.137 -0.403 0.085 4 (0.244) (0.267) (0.186) (0.200) (0.309) (0.266) (0.335) (0.357) 0.432* 0.063 -0.210 -0.259 -0.448 -0.307 0.204 -0.185 5 (0.245) (0.267) (0.181) (0.195) (0.308) (0.265) (0.338) (0.356) -0.178 0.266 0.376** 0.303 0.239 0.020 0.294 0.243 6 (0.248) (0.271) (0.180) (0.194) (0.309) (0.266) (0.330) (0.351) 0.127 0.124 -0.317* -0.068 0.003 0.018 -0.844*** -0.183 7 (0.250) (0.273) (0.181) (0.195) (0.309) (0.266) (0.326) (0.347) 0.017 -0.096 0.107 -0.044 -0.088 0.002 0.551* 0.030 8 (0.249) (0.272) (0.181) (0.195) (0.308) (0.265) (0.325) (0.346) 0.007 -0.154 -0.065 -0.026 0.162 0.015 -0.210 -0.041 9 (0.178) (0.194) (0.118) (0.128) (0.211) (0.181) (0.211) (0.224) R2 0.860 0.897 0.982 0.980 0.972 0.985 0.904 0.889 0.060 0.066 0.070 0.076 0.093 0.080 0.092 0.097 58.178 82.413 896.547 823.612 896.769 1644.213 169.298 143.474 N 190 190 319 319 478 478 341 341 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Table 2a VAR Estimates of Eq. (13): Effects of Terms of Trade on Exports and Imports Note: See, Table 1. 𝑒 = ln of U.S. exports to EU, 𝑒 = ln of U.S. imports from EU, = ln of U.S. exports to foreign country, = ln of U.S. imports from foreign country, = S.E. of equation. Source: See, Table 1. 15 | www.ijbms.net International Journal of Business & Management Studies ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Variables 𝑤 𝑤 𝑗 𝑗 --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------*** 0.372 -0.136** 0.085 0.285*** 0.244*** 1 0.855 (0.070) (0.337) (0.058) (0.065) (0.050) (0.066) -0.064 -0.104* -0.505 0.138*** 0.394*** 2 0.013 (0.093) (0.447) (0.056) (0.062) (0.051) (0.068) * ** *** -0.119 0.432 -0.066 0.027 0.113 0.274 3 (0.070) (0.336) (0.058) (0.065) (0.049) (0.065) 0.402*** 0.069 -0.103*** 0.593*** 0.580*** 1 -0.118 (0.014) (0.070) (0.052) (0.058) (0.038) (0.051) -0.085 -0.200*** 0.159** 0.060 0.096* 2 0.013 (0.017) (0.080) (0.058) (0.064) (0.042) (0.056) 0.255*** -0.062* 0.198*** 0.039 0.146*** 3 -0.007 (0.015) (0.072) (0.050) (0.056) (0.039) (0.052) C -3.090*** -4.339*** -7.824*** -3.379*** -4.497*** -3.888*** (0.898) (4.331) (1.645) (1.827) (0.865) (1.149) 0.153*** 0.224*** 0.607** 0.886*** 0.093 0.905* (0.097) (0.469) (0.041) (0.046) (0.219) (0.291) 0.568*** -0.580 0.447*** 0.822*** -0.148* -0.001 (0.134) (0.646) (0.145) (0.161) (0.087) (0.116) 0.986*** -0.178 0.653*** 0.320* 0.710*** -0.040 (0.095) (0.460) (0.159) (0.178) (0.218) (0.290) -0.883*** 0.369 -0.413* -0.099 -0.335 0.262 1 (0.159) (0.767) (0.256) (0.285) (0.358) (0.475) 0.225 0.364 -0.257 0.186 -0.277 -0.922** 2 (0.172) (0.830) (0.257) (0.286) (0.369) (0.491) 0.019 -1.009 0.010 -0.567** 0.120 1.020** 3 (0.158) (0.761) (0.257) (0.286) (0.371) (0.492) 0.025 0.679 -0.103 0.031 -0.013 -0.298 4 (0.137) (0.662) (0.253) (0.282) (0.372) (0.494) 0.068 0.102 0.427* 0.551** 0.428 0.233 5 (0.136) (0.655) (0.252) (0.280) (0.372) (0.494) -0.066 -0.818 -0.230 -0.225 -0.457 0.049 6 (0.136) (0.653) (0.253) (0.281) (0.370) (0.491) -0.107 0.691 0.090 -0.065 0.026 -0.026 7 (0.137) (0.660) (0.253) (0.281) (0.368) (0.488) 0.082 -1.032* -0.225 -0.232 0.055 0.290 8 (0.137) (0.659) (0.250) (0.277) (0.355) (0.471) -0.016 0.578 0.233 0.349** 0.060 -0.363 9 (0.092) (0.442) (0.156) (0.173) (0.217) (0.288) R2 0.993 0.936 0.755 0.728 0.930 0.895 0.030 0.144 0.070 0.078 0.107 0.143 1,728.493 166.034 59.269 51.543 285.422 182.242 N 223 223 365 365 404 404 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Table 2b: VAR Estimates of Eq. (13): Effects of Terms of Trade on Exports and Imports Note: See, Tables 1 and 2a. 𝑤 = ln of U.S. exports to Switzerland, 𝑤 = ln of U.S. imports from Switzerland, 𝑗= ln of U.S. exports to Japan, , 𝑗 = ln of U.S. imports from Japan, = ln of U.S. exports to Australia, = ln of U.S. imports from Australia. Source: See, Table 1. 16 | Trade Deficit and Currency Devaluation- Testing the J-Curve: Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis et al. Vol. 03 - Issue: 12/December_2022 ©Institute for Promoting Research & Policy Development DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Variables Level (y), I(0) 1st Difference [Δ(y)], I(1) 2nd Difference [Δ2(y)], I(2) ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------LUSXEU -3.162041** LUSMEU -0.792457 -3.978001*** USTAEU -0.368738 -6.092984*** LUSRGDP -1.640910 -8.998455*** LEUGDP -1.179551 -19.40762*** LEUHICP -1.904826 -17.22646*** LUSCPI -6.418572*** LEUS -1.777332 -13.57573*** TOTEU -1.080653 -14.11127*** LUSXM LUSMM USTAM LMGDP LMCPI LMS TOTM -2.322441 -1.768286 -2.435575 -1.433629 -2.780290* -3.344312** -2.419574 -6.206835*** -7.132625*** -23.69309*** -18.77435*** LUSXC LUSMC USTAC LCGDP LCCPI LCS1 TOTC -1.946904 -2.684839* -1.590967 0.014997 -5.805180*** -2.001353 -0.909630 -5.867487*** LUSXUK LUSMUK USTAUK LUKGDP LUKCPI LUKS TOTUK -2.243627 -3.555911*** -3.150286** -0.193334 -4.177993*** -2.595632* -2.768019* LUSXSW1 LUSMSW USTASW LSWGDP LSWCPI LSWS1 TOTSW -0.473440 -0.067195 -0.052968 -2.553187 -1.973128 -2.461943 -2.867018* -21.59019*** -8.564824*** -8.949051*** -4.847784*** -2.481234 -18.79962*** LUSXJ LUSMJ USTAJ LJGDP1 LJCPI LJS1 TOTJ -2.472834 -4.129341*** -3.926427*** -4.526552*** -4.305581*** -2.137365 -1.499921 -6.908138*** -12.25298*** -8.307771*** -22.15808*** -20.55438*** -22.28565*** -5.865940*** -19.70102*** -15.55943*** -17.69212*** -14.12346*** LUSXA -2.791847* LUSMA -1.653819 -13.85459*** *** USTAA -5.031164 LAGDP -3.569385*** LACPI -1.853885 -4.057147*** LAS -1950877 -17.77384*** TOTA -2.239219 -13.78797*** ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Table 3: Unit Root Tests Augmented Dickey-Fuller Note: See Tables 1, 2a, and 2b. Source: See, Table 1. 17 | www.ijbms.net International Journal of Business & Management Studies ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Hypothesized Trace 5% Critical Maximum Max-Eig 5% Critical No. of CEs Eigenvalue Statistic Value Eigenvalue Statistic Value ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Series: LUSXEU and LUSMEU ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------0 0.265 66.682 15.495 0.265 57.936 14.265 1 0.045 8.746 3.841 0.045 8.746 3.841 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Series: LUSXM and LUSMM ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------0 0.210 98.721 15.495 0.210 75.391 14.265 1 0.071 23.330 3.841 0.071 23.330 3.841 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Series: LUSXC and LUSMC ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------0 0.124 83.541 15.495 0.124 63.315 14.265 1 0.041 20.226 3.841 0.041 20.226 3.841 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Series: LUSXUK and LUSMUK ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------0 0.076 48.669 15.495 0.076 26.932 14.265 1 0.062 21.738 3.841 0.062 21.738 3.841 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Series: LUSXSW1 and LUSMSW ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------0 0.139 48.938 15.495 0.139 33.245 14.265 1 0.068 15.694 3.841 0.068 15.694 3.841 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Series: LUSXJ and LUSMJ ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------0 0.127 72.793 15.495 0.127 49.465 14.265 1 0.062 23.328 3.841 0.062 23.328 3.841 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Series: LUSXA and LUSMA ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------0 0.114 72.273 15.495 0.114 48.853 14.265 1 0.056 23.420 3.841 0.056 23.420 3.841 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Table 4: Johansen Cointegration Test for the VAR Estimates of Eq. (13): Effects of Terms of Trade on Exports and Imports Note: Trace tests indicate 2 cointegrating eigenvalues at the 1% level. Max-Eigenvalue tests indicate 2 cointegrating eigenvalues at the 1% level. Source: See, Table 1. -.1 -.2 -.3 -.4 -.5 -.6 -.7 -.8 2006 2008 2010 2012 USTAEUF 2014 2016 2018 2020 2018 2020 ± 2 S.E. Fore ca s t: USTAEUF Actua l : USTAEU Fore ca s t s a mpl e : 1970M01 2021M12 Adjus te d s a mpl e : 2004M12 2020M12 I ncl ude d obs e rva ti ons : 193 Root Me a n Squa re d Error 0.079504 Me a n Abs ol ute Error 0.063818 Me a n Abs . Pe rce nt Error 16.66371 The i l Ine qua l i ty Coe f. 0.089520 Bi a s Proporti on 0.000042 Va ri a nce Proporti on 0.182043 Cova ri a nce Proporti on 0.817915 The i l U2 Coe ffi ci e nt 0.959980 Symme tri c MAPE 15.44461 .016 .012 .008 .004 .000 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Foreca s t of Va ri a nce 18 | Trade Deficit and Currency Devaluation- Testing the J-Curve: Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis et al. Vol. 03 - Issue: 12/December_2022 ©Institute for Promoting Research & Policy Development DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 Graph A1a: Forecasting of U.S. Trade with EU and its Variance [Eq. (9)] Response to Cholesky One S.D. (d.f. adjusted) Innovations Response of LUSXEU to Innovations .08 .06 .04 .02 .00 -.02 1 2 3 4 5 6 LUSXEU 7 8 9 10 LUSMEU Response of LUSMEU to Innovations .06 .05 .04 .03 .02 .01 .00 -.01 1 2 3 4 5 6 LUSXEU 7 8 9 10 LUSMEU Graph A1b: Response of Trade with EU to Cholesky Innovations Eq. (13) Note: Imports are increasing until the 4th month and exports are falling; then, TA in the S-R and it improved TA after the 5th month. .4 .2 .0 -.2 -.4 -.6 -.8 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 USTAMXF 10 12 14 16 18 20 14 16 18 20 ± 2 S.E. Fore ca s t: USTAMXF Actua l : USTAMX Fore ca s t s a mpl e : 1970M01 2022M12 Adjus te d s a mpl e : 1994M08 2021M02 I ncl ude d obs e rva ti ons : 319 Root Me a n Squa re d Error 0.078442 Me a n Abs ol ute Error 0.065058 Me a n Abs . Pe rce nt Error 279.0898 The i l I ne qua l i ty Coe f. 0.130340 Bi a s Proporti on 0.042989 Va ri a nce Proporti on 0.314878 Cova ri a nce Proporti on 0.642133 The i l U2 Coe ffi ci e nt 0.334571 Symme tri c MAPE 24.74582 .05 .04 .03 .02 .01 .00 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 Fore ca s t of Va ri a nce Graph A2a: Forecasting of U.S. Trade with Mexico and its Variance [Eq. (9)] 19 | www.ijbms.net International Journal of Business & Management Studies ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) Response to Cholesky One S.D. (d.f. adjusted) Innovations Response of LUSXMX to Innovations .08 .06 .04 .02 .00 -.02 1 2 3 4 5 6 LUSXMX 7 8 9 10 LUSMMX Response of LUSMMX to Innovations .08 .06 .04 .02 .00 -.02 1 2 3 4 5 6 LUSXMX 7 8 9 10 LUSMMX Graph A2b: Response of Trade with Mexico to Cholesky Innovations Eq. (13) Note: Imports are increasing until the 2th month and exports are falling; then, TA in the S-R and it improved TA after the 4th month. 0.4 0.2 0.0 -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -0.8 -1.0 1985 1990 1995 2000 USTACF 2005 2010 2015 2020 2015 2020 ± 2 S.E. Foreca s t: USTACF Actua l : USTAC Foreca s t s a mpl e: 1970M01 2021M12 Adjus ted s a mpl e: 1981M03 2020M12 Incl uded obs erva ti ons : 478 Root Mea n Squa re d Error 0.081895 Mea n Abs ol ute Error 0.063303 Mea n Abs . Percent Error 76.89202 The i l Inequa l i ty Coe f. 0.156415 Bi a s Proporti on 0.013396 Va ri a nce Proporti on 0.112070 Cova ri a nce Proporti on 0.874534 The i l U2 Coe ffi ci e nt 2.312241 Symme tri c MAPE 34.87563 .05 .04 .03 .02 .01 .00 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Foreca s t of Vari ance Graph A3a: Forecasting of U.S. Trade with Canada and its Variance [Eq. (9)] 20 | Trade Deficit and Currency Devaluation- Testing the J-Curve: Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis et al. Vol. 03 - Issue: 12/December_2022 ©Institute for Promoting Research & Policy Development DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 Response to Cholesky One S.D. (d.f. adjusted) Innovations Response of LUSXC to Innovations .10 .08 .06 .04 .02 .00 1 2 3 4 5 6 LUSXC 7 8 9 10 9 10 LUSMC Response of LUSMC to Innovations .07 .06 .05 .04 .03 .02 .01 .00 1 2 3 4 5 6 LUSXC 7 8 LUSMC Graph A3b: Response of Trade with Canada to Cholesky Innovations Eq. (13) Note: Imports are increasing until the 4th month and exports are falling; then, TA and it improved TA after the 5th month. 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 -1.5 1990 1995 2000 2005 USTAUKF 2010 2015 2020 2015 2020 ± 2 S.E. .25 .20 .15 .10 .05 .00 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Foreca s t of Vari ance 21 | www.ijbms.net Foreca s t: USTAUKF Actua l : USTAUK Foreca s t s a mpl e: 1970M01 2021M12 Adjus ted s a mpl e: 1990M01 2020M12 Incl uded obs erva ti ons : 372 Root Mea n Squa re d Error 0.178658 Mea n Abs ol ute Error 0.142901 Mea n Abs . Percent Error 400.0042 The i l Inequa l i ty Coe f. 0.568043 Bi a s Proporti on 0.003260 Va ri a nce Proporti on 0.562733 Cova ri a nce Proporti on 0.434007 The i l U2 Coe ffi ci e nt 0.389606 Symme tri c MAPE 113.3731 International Journal of Business & Management Studies ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) Graph A4a: Forecasting of U.S. Trade with U.K. and its Variance [Eq. (9)] Response to Cholesky One S.D. (d.f. adjusted) Innovations Response of LUSXUK to Innovations .10 .08 .06 .04 .02 .00 -.02 1 2 3 4 5 6 LUSXUK 7 8 9 10 LUSMUK Response of LUSMUK to Innovations .10 .08 .06 .04 .02 .00 1 2 3 4 5 LUSXUK 6 7 8 9 10 LUSMUK Graph A4b: Response of Trade with U.K. to Cholesky Innovations Eq. (13) Note: Imports are increasing until the 4th month and exports are falling; then, TA and it improved TA after the 5th month. 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 20 16 18 20 ± 2 S.E. USTASWF Foreca s t: USTASWF Actua l : USTASW Foreca s t s a mpl e: 1970M01 2021M12 Adjus ted s a mpl e: 2002M07 2021M02 Incl uded obs erva ti ons : 224 Root Mea n Squa red Error 0.229648 Mea n Abs ol ute Error 0.138710 Mea n Abs . Percent Error 3.981089 Thei l Inequa l i ty Coef. 0.029612 Bi a s Proporti on 0.052476 Va ri a nce Proporti on 0.195942 Cova ri a nce Proporti on 0.751582 Thei l U2 Coeffi ci ent 1.741872 Symmetri c MAPE 3.744889 2.0 1.6 1.2 0.8 0.4 0.0 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 Forecas t of Variance Graph A5a: Forecasting of U.S. Trade with Switzerland and its Variance [Eq. (9)] 22 | Trade Deficit and Currency Devaluation- Testing the J-Curve: Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis et al. Vol. 03 - Issue: 12/December_2022 ©Institute for Promoting Research & Policy Development DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 Response to Cholesky One S.D. (d.f. adjusted) Innovations Response of LUSXSW1 to Innovations .04 .03 .02 .01 .00 -.01 1 2 3 4 5 6 LUSXSW1 7 8 9 10 LUSMSW Response of LUSMSW to Innovations .150 .125 .100 .075 .050 .025 .000 1 2 3 4 5 LUSXSW1 6 7 8 9 10 LUSMSW Graph A5b: Response of Trade with Switzerland to Cholesky Innovations Eq. (13) Note: Imports are flat and exports are falling; then, TA and it improved TA after the 9th month. 0.4 0.0 -0.4 -0.8 -1.2 -1.6 1995 2000 2005 USTAJF 2010 2015 2020 2015 2020 ± 2 S.E. .14 .12 .10 .08 .06 .04 .02 .00 1995 2000 2005 2010 Foreca s t of Vari ance 23 | www.ijbms.net Foreca s t: USTAJF Actua l : USTAJ Foreca s t s a mpl e: 1970M01 2021M12 Adjus ted s a mpl e: 1990M08 2021M02 Incl uded obs erva ti ons : 367 Root Mea n Squa re d Error 0.122846 Mea n Abs ol ute Error 0.096594 Mea n Abs . Percent Error 18.66876 The i l Inequa l i ty Coe f. 0.096303 Bi a s Proporti on 0.015434 Va ri a nce Proporti on 0.762221 Cova ri a nce Proporti on 0.222344 The i l U2 Coe ffi ci e nt 1.441667 Symme tri c MAPE 16.12030 International Journal of Business & Management Studies ISSN 2694-1430 (Print), 2694-1449 (Online) Graph A6a: Forecasting of U.S. Trade with Japan and its Variance [Eq. (9)] Response to Cholesky One S.D. (d.f. adjusted) Innovations Response of LUSXJ to Innovations .08 .06 .04 .02 .00 -.02 1 2 3 4 5 6 LUSXJ 7 8 9 10 9 10 LUSMJ Response of LUSMJ to Innovations .08 .06 .04 .02 .00 -.02 1 2 3 4 5 LUSXJ 6 7 8 LUSMJ Graph A6b: Response of Trade with Japan to Cholesky Innovations Eq. (13) Note: Imports are increasing until the 4th month and exports are falling; then, TA and it improved TA after the 5th month. 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 1990 1995 2000 2005 USTAAF 2010 2015 2020 2015 2020 ± 2 S.E. Foreca s t: USTAAF Actua l : USTAA Foreca s t s a mpl e: 1970M01 2021M12 Adjus ted s a mpl e: 1987M07 2021M02 Incl uded obs erva ti ons : 404 Root Mea n Squa re d Error 0.223410 Mea n Abs ol ute Error 0.167498 Mea n Abs . Percent Error 24.93902 The i l Inequa l i ty Coe f. 0.124275 Bi a s Proporti on 0.038833 Va ri a nce Proporti on 0.450409 Cova ri a nce Proporti on 0.510758 The i l U2 Coe ffi ci e nt 0.427426 Symme tri c MAPE 19.40256 .30 .25 .20 .15 .10 .05 .00 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Foreca s t of Vari ance Graph A7a: Forecasting of U.S. Trade with Australia and its Variance [Eq. (9)] 24 | Trade Deficit and Currency Devaluation- Testing the J-Curve: Dr. Ioannis N. Kallianiotis et al. Vol. 03 - Issue: 12/December_2022 ©Institute for Promoting Research & Policy Development DOI: 10.56734/ijbms.v3n12a1 Response to Cholesky One S.D. (d.f. adjusted) Innovations Response of LUSXA to Innovations .12 .10 .08 .06 .04 .02 .00 -.02 1 2 3 4 5 6 LUSXA 7 8 9 10 9 10 LUSMA Response of LUSMA to Innovations .16 .12 .08 .04 .00 -.04 1 2 3 4 5 LUSXA 6 7 8 LUSMA Graph A7b: Response of Trade with Australia to Cholesky Innovations Eq. (13) Note: Imports are increasing until the 4th month and exports are falling; then, TA and it improved TA after the 5th month. 25 | www.ijbms.net