investment-law-module-highlighted
investment-law-module-highlighted
investment-law-module-highlighted
Discuss the main issues which are the object of arbitral awards
concerning direct or de facto expropriation.
1.1 Defining
investment .................................................................................................
.................................. 5
1.1.1 Foreign Direct
Investment ...............................................................................................
....................... 5
1.1.2 Portfolio
investment ...............................................................................................
................................. 6
1.2 Economic theories on foreign
investment ............................................................................................... 6
1.2.1 Classical
theory ........................................................................................................
................................ 7
1.2.2 Dependency
theory ........................................................................................................
......................... 7
1.2.3 Middle path
theory ........................................................................................................
......................... 7
1.3 Benefits of foreign
investment..................................................................................................
............... 7
1.4 Factors that can potentially deter FDI
inflow ..................................................................................... 10
1.5 Exercises ....................................................................................................
............................................... 10
UNIT 2 LEGAL FRAMEWORK ON
INVESTMENT .............................................................................. 11
2.0 Introduction ................................................................................................
.............................................. 11
2.1 Legislative
framework ..................................................................................................
......................... 11 2.2 Institutional
framework ..................................................................................................
........................ 11
2.3 Permitted sectors for
investment .................................................................................................
......... 12
2.4 Investment
incentives ...................................................................................................
........................... 12
2.4.1 Types of
incentives ..................................................................................................
............................. 13
2.4.2 Legal regime for
incentives ..................................................................................................
.............. 13
3
5.3 Structure of a
Treaty .........................................................................................................
.................... 28
5.4 Emerging Issues in Bilateral Investment
Treaties .............................................................................. 36
5.4.1 Human
Rights ...................................................................................................
............................... 36
5.4.2 Economic
Development ........................................................................................
......................... 36
5.4.3 Environment
Concerns ..............................................................................................
..................... 37
5.5 SADC Model
BIT ..............................................................................................................
......................... 37
5.6 Exercises ....................................................................................................
............................................... 38
UNIT 6 POLITICAL RISK IN FOREIGN
INVESTMENT ........................................................................ 39
6.2 Investor Motivation for
Investment ......................................................................................................
39
6.2.1 Market
Seeking ................................................................................................
............................. 39
6.2.2 Resource
Seeking ................................................................................................
.......................... 39
6.2.3 Efficiency
Seeking ................................................................................................
......................... 39
6.2.4 Strategic asset-
seeking..................................................................................................
............... 39
6.3 Political Risks in foreign
investment .....................................................................................................
40
6.3.1 Nationalization .....................................................................................
......................................... 41
6.3.2 Expropriation ........................................................................................
................................................. 41
6.4 Legality of
Expropriation ....................................................................................................
................. 45
6.4.1 Measure must serve a Public
Purpose ....................................................................................... 45
5
UNIT 1
1.0 Introduction
The term ‘Foreign Direct Investment’ has defied a singular definition but
many of the definitions share common characteristics. The International
Monetary Fund Balance of Payments Manual which defines it as an
investment made to acquire lasting interest in enterprises operating
outside of the economy of the investor.
1. Greenfield Investments
1 Section 3
2 Section 3
3 http://www.investmentsandincome.com/investments/foreign-direct-investments.html (accessed 25 June 2012)
7
2. Brownfield Investments
4. Joint ventures
instability and the second is that the risks in portfolio investments are
manageable whereas asset management is not. The factors that affect
international portfolio investment are: (i) tax rates on interest or dividends
(investors will normally prefer countries where the tax rates are relatively
low); and (ii) interest rates (money tends to flow to countries with high
interest rates).
There are three (3) main theories of foreign investment. These are:
This theory takes the view that FDI benefits the host economy fully.
According to the theory, the fact that foreign capital is brought in by the
MNC that capital may be used for a number of developmental projects.
The investor also brings with him into the host economy technology that is
absent in the host country which ultimately leads to the diffusion of that
technology within the economy. Furthermore, there is employment
created with the added advantage of acquisition of new skills that are
associated with the foreign investor’s technology. A number of other
benefits flow from the foreign investors entry and these include
infrastructure and upgrading of transport, health or education sectors.
Accordingly, all restrictions on FDI should be eliminated so as to increase
global wealth with regard to the comparative advantage theory. A number
of other benefits flow from the foreign investors entry and these include
infrastructure and upgrading of transport, health or education sectors.
This traces its roots from the Marxist theory and economic theory. It
basically considers FDI to as a tool for imperialist domination that should
he completely forbidden since it entails no advantages for host countries.
It therefore, views these multinational corporations as tools for exploiting
host countries to the exclusive benefit of their capitalist imperialist home
countries.
This theory does not accept the possibility of any sort of development in
the periphery but only the development of underdevelopment. This theory
affirms that what is decisive is that the economic development of under
developed states is inimical to the interests of the advanced capitalist
countries. In ensuring that development does not trickle down to the
developing nations, the more advanced developed states form alliances
with the pre capitalist domestic elites with the intention of inhibiting any
such form of transformation.
This presents a shift away from ideological tendencies towards FIs. While
supporting the view that FI through MNCs could have harmful results in
certain circumstances, properly harnessed MNCs could be engines that
fuel the growth of the developing world.
The host countries view foreign investment in terms of its costs and its
benefits, its risks and its rewards. In other, words host countries perceive
FI largely in terms of benefits such jobs that the foreign investment will
bring to their countries. Host country governments believe that the
establishment of foreign investment projects within their territories offers
them numerous benefits. Under proper conditions, investors expect it to
bring to the host countries a combination of resources, skills, and
activities that will result in a surplus of output and real income beyond
that which goes directly to the investor as profit. The opportunities that
host countries look for from fi include the following:
1. Capital formation
8 Section 5(3)(a)
10
2. Transfer of Technologies
3. Employment creation
This takes place when investors set up new plants, acquire companies or
outsource to local subcontractors.
9 Section 69(e)
10 Section 69(b); 5(3)(f)
11
7. Linkages
8. Competition
The entry by MNCs into local markets may reduce the concentration of
firms in a market with the result that there is an increase in competition.
The ultimate benefit of this to consumers is lower prices, perhaps a wider
choice of goods and reduction in organizational inefficiencies.
Foreign Direct Investment has the effect, where it generates and expands
businesses, of stimulating employment, raise wages and replace declining
market sectors. These investments may be helpful in assisting the host
countries to set up mass educational programs which in the long run may
help them educate the disadvantaged sections of the society.
There are certain factors that can deter the inflow of FDI to a country e.g.
inadequate infrastructure, inadequate number of trained human
11 Section 5(3)(g)
12
1.5 Exercises
UNIT 2
2.0 Introduction
12 Kenneth Mwenda Legal Aspects of Foreign Direct Investment (1999) (Vol. 6 No. 4)
13
Some of the stated objectives are to: (a) foster economic growth and
development by promoting trade and investment in Zambia through an
efficient, effective and coordinated private sector led economic
development strategy; (b) attract and facilitate inward and after care
investment; (c) promote Greenfield investments through joint ventures
and partnerships between local and foreign investors. 13
The Zambia Development Agency (ZDA) is the body that deals with
investments. It main function as stated in section 5(1) is to further the
economic development of Zambia by promoting efficiency, investment
and competitiveness in business and promoting exports from Zambia. The
specific functions are inter alia to: (a) give advice to the Minister; (b) study
market access; (c) formulate investment promotion strategies; (d)
promote and coordinate Government policies on investment; (e)
undertake economic and sector studies and market surveys so as to
identify investment opportunities; (f) control the privatisation of State
Owned Enterprises; (g) develop or facilitate the development of multi-
facility economic zones by investors; and (h) encourage and promote the
transfer of appropriate technology.14
In promoting investment, the ZDA shall have regard to the need to: (a)
improve the overall economic performance of the economy; (b) reduce
regulation of industry where this is consistent with the social and
economic goals of the Government; (c) encourage the development and
growth of Zambian industries; (d) facilitate adjustment to structural
changes in the economy; (e) protect the interests of industries,
employees, consumers and the community; (f) increase employment in
Zambia; (g) promote regional development, cooperation and integration;
(h) monitor the progress made by Zambia’s trading partners in reducing
both tariff and non-tariff barriers; (i) ensure that industry develops in a
way that is ecologically sustainable; (j) ensure that Zambia meets its
international obligations and commitments; and (k) maintain regular,
13 The Preamble
14 Section 5 (2)
14
productive and effective dialogue and cooperation with the public and
private sector and encourage public-public dialogue, private-private
dialogue and private-public dialogue.15
The areas in which foreign investment is not permitted are provided for in
section 2(1)(2) of the First Schedule. These are: (i) an industry
manufacturing arms and ammunition, explosives, military vehicles and
equipment, aircraft and any other military hardware; (ii) an industry
manufacturing poisons, narcotics, dangerous drugs and toxic, hazardous
and carcinogenic materials; and (iii) an industry producing currency, coins
and security documents.
Incentives can be used for attracting new FDI to a particular host country
or for making foreign affiliates in a country undertake functions regarded
as desirable such as training, local sourcing, research and development or
exporting.
1. Regulatory
2. Financial
3. Fiscal
4. Non-fiscal
5. Indirect incentives
An incentive offered under the ZDA Act is valid for a period of five years
from the grant of the licence, permit or certificate. 24 In order to qualify, an
investor investing not less than $500,000 or the equivalent in convertible
currency is entitled to incentives as specified by or under the Income Tax
Act or Customs and Excise Act.25
An incentive can be conditioned upon an undertaking to employ a certain
number of persons.26An investor is only entitled to an incentive unless the
investor holds a licence, permit or certificate of registration. 27 Relief or
exemption from any tax or duty to which an investor is eligible can only
be effected by the Commissioner-General upon the Board certifying that
the investor has complied fully with the ZDA Act and any condition
prescribed.28
23 Section 54
24 Section 55
25 Section 56
26 Section 17(2), and 69(2)
27 Section 59
28 Section 60
29 Section 61. Double taxation occurs when the same transaction or income source is subject to two or more
taxing authorities. This can occur within a single country, when independent governmental units have the power
to tax a single transaction or source of income, or may result when different sovereign states impose separate
taxes, in which case it is called international double taxation. The consequence of double taxation is to tax
certain activities at a higher rate than similar activity that is located solely within a taxing jurisdiction. This leads to
unnecessary relocation of economic activity in order to lower the incidence of taxation, or other, more
objectionable forms of tax avoidance- available:
http://legal-dictionary.thefreedictionary.com/Double+Taxation+Agreements (accessed 26 June 2012) 30 Section
69
17
30 Section 71
31 Section 72
32 Section 73
33 Section 74
34 Section 75
35 Section 77
18
2.6 Exercises
19
UNIT 3
3.1 Introduction
The idea of MFEZ came into Zambia in 2001 following the enactment of
the Export Processing Zone Act No. 7 of 2001. This Act established the
Zambia Export Processing Zone Authority (ZEPZA) as the body mandated
to address promotion of investment in EPZ. However, by 2004, ZEPZA had
not become operational.
Following a number of policy changes, which also led to repeal of the EPZ
Act and replacing with the ZDA Act in 2006, the government came up with
Multifacility Economic Zone (MFEZ) program. The MFEZ program falls
under the auspices of the Triangle of Hope (ToH) initiative which is aimed
at creating the platform for Zambia to achieve economic development by
attracting significant domestic and foreign direct investment (FDI) through
a strengthened policy and legislative environment. 36 The implementation
of MFEZs is designed to make Zambia competitive through increased
activity in the trade and manufacturing sectors, which have numerous
positive spill over effects in other sectors such as utilities, transport,
agriculture and services. The MFEZs are for both export-oriented and
domestic-oriented industries and blend the best features of the free trade
zones (FTZs), export processing zones (EPZs) and the industrial
parks/zones concept and create the administrative infrastructure, rules,
regulations etc. that benchmark among the best dynamic economies. 37
The blending of physical infrastructure with an efficient and effective
36 The Triangle of Hope (ToH) was introduced to Zambia in 2005 by the Japanese Government through Japan
International Corporation Agency (JICA). It emphasises on political will and integrity, private sector dynamism
and integrity and civil service efficiency and integrity as key forces that enable the economy to attain accelerated
economic development.
37 Free trade zones (FTZs) are fenced-in, duty-free areas, offering warehousing, storage, and
distribution facilities for trade, transhipment, and re-export operations. Export Processing
Zones are industrial estates aimed primarily at foreign markets. Hybrid EPZs are typically sub-
divided into a general zone open to all industries and a separate EPZ area reserved for export-
oriented, EPZ-registered enterprises.
20
The key priority sectors for MFEZ are: Information and Communication
Technology (ICT); Health; Education and skills training; Manufacturing;
Tourism; and Processing of products.
The creation of a MFEZ is regulated by Act No. 11 of 2006 and the Zambia
Development Agency (ZDA) is responsible for this. Section 5 (2) of the
ZDA Act provides that, the role of ZDA, inter alia, are: (i) develop multi-
facility economic zones or facilitate the development of multifacility
economic zones by investors; (ii) administer, control and regulate MFEZs;
(iii) monitor and evaluate the activities, performance and development of
enterprises operating in MFEZs; and (iv) promote and market multi-facility
economic zones among investors.
In accordance with section 18 (1) of the ZDA Act, the Minister can declare
an area, premises or building to be a multi-facility economic zone and also
prescribe the terms and conditions under which such goods produced and
services provided in a multi-facility economic zone may be sold, exported
or disposed of. Section 18 (2) enables the minister to prescribe the: (a)
limits of the area, premises or building declared as a multi-facility
economic zone; (b) facilities to be provided and maintained within a multi-
facility economic zone; (c) terms and conditions under which such goods
produced and services provided in a multi-facility economic zone may be
sold, exported or otherwise disposed of; (d) activities which are prohibited
within a multi-facility economic zone; (e) conditions under which goods
may be removed from a multi-facility economic zone; (f) the powers and
obligations of an investor in a multi-facility economic zone; and (g) such
other matters that are necessary for the effective and efficient operations
of multi-facility economic zones.
38 http://www.mcti.gov.zm/index.php/investing-in-zambia/multifacility-economic-zones/85-multi-facility-economic-
zones (accessed 5 June 2012)
21
The LS-MFEZ is a public sector led commercial project through which the
government is providing hard and soft infrastructures to support the
development of the private sector. It is planned and established with a
strong public sector participation involving ZESCO Limited, Zamtel, Lusaka
Water and Sewerage Company (LWSC), Road Development Agency (RDA)
and Industrial
Development Corporation (IDC). The LS-MFEZ is the SPV established in
June 2012 by the Ministry of Finance to manage, operate and develop the
zone. As of August 2015, IDC has taken over the shareholding in LSMFEZ
Ltd on behalf of the Ministry.
The key priority sectors for MFEZ are: Information and Communication
Technology (ICT); Health; Education and skills training; Manufacturing;
Tourism; and Processing of products.
The significance of the MFEZ lies in its ability to promote more export and
thereby enhancing the inflow of foreign currency. Its efficacy largely
depends on the ability and the will of a government to distribute the
proceeds of growth from these areas outwards. To a great extent, the fate
of zone initiatives has been determined from the outset, by choices made
in the establishment of policy frameworks, incentive packages, and
various other provisions and bureaucratic procedures. As Yue-man Yeung
et al opined “…the combination of favorable policies and the right mix of
production factors in the SEZs resulted in high rates of economic growth
unprecedented in China.”42
41 Section 69 (a)
42 Yue-man Yeung, Joanna Lee and Gordon Kee “China’s Special Economic Zones at 30” Eurasian Geography
and Economics (2009) (Vol. 50 No. 2) pp. 222–240 at 224
23
The ZDA is the main government entity responsible for the MFEZ program.
Given the lack of expertise and experience of most officials in the agency
in terms of SEZ development, they are not able to provide the right
incentives and efficient services that are demanded by the private sector.
2. Inadequate infrastructures
Many firms in the zones show interests in sourcing locally, especially those
in agribusiness, which will help them to reduce the logistics and
transaction costs. However, they also feel most local SMEs cannot meet
their requirements in terms of stable volume, quality and standards, etc.
This involves many local products, such as barley, cassava, mushroom,
fruits and livestock, etc. If local firms’ productivity, quality and standards
can be improved, it will greatly help with the zonelocal firm linkages. In
addition, some investors in the zones also feel it’s difficult to find suitable
labors from the local market.
The following are the possible Interventions that could be taken to support
the growth of MFEZs: (1) Institutional and capacity building; (2)
Infrastructure support e.g. power shortage; and (3) Support for the SEZ –
local economy linkages.
3.7 Exercises
24
UNIT 4
4.0 Introduction
In the mid-1980s, there were further attempts for policy support to the
sector. This was made in the Fourth National Development Plan (1988 to
1993) whose objectives were:
1. Identify and promote SMEs that have potential for output expansion
and employment generation in a manner that structurally integrates
such activities to complement the largescale enterprises sector;
44 Section 3
26
5. Government will set out to review and harmonize all existing laws
and regulations with a view to identifying and removing
impediments to the operations of the sector.
27
1. Exemption from payment of tax on income for the first three to five
years;
In 2006, there were further reforms which resulted into the repeal of the
SED Act, which was replaced by the ZDA Act of 2006.
Micro, Small and Medium Enterprises are the engine of every nation’s
economy as they occupy a prominent position in the development of
many countries in the world. Contributions of SMEs can be well noted in a
number of aspects including labour absorption, creation of entrepreneurial
spirit and innovation, promotion of linkages and complementary role to
large companies, wealth creation, among others. The SMEs have a greater
flexibility and ability to change and respond quickly to changing market
28
Promotion of MSMEs is provided for under Part V of the ZDA Act. Section
22 mandates the Board to promote and facilitate the development of
MSMEs by —
45 Section 23(1)
46 Section 23(2)
29
4.6 Exercises
47 Section 48(1)
48 Section 48(2), and 49
49 Section 48(3)
50 Section 48(4)
51 Section 48(5). “Fronting” includes holding out as being the de facto director, shareholder or partner of a business
enterprise in order to hide the true identity of the director, shareholder or partner of that business.
30
UNIT 5
6.0 Introduction
The definition of investment has always been a moot issue and countries
have debated whether the definition of investment should be broad or
narrow. These differences imply that there is no common definition of
investment and every BIT may have different definitions depending on
many factors. For instance, one of the contentious points in the definition
of investment is whether the definition of investment should be limited to
foreign direct investment (FDI) or should be broad to include other types
of investments, such as portfolio investment, as well. 52
52 Prabhash Ranjan “Definition of Investment in Bilateral Investment Treaties of South Asian countries and
Regulatory Discretion” Journal of International Arbitration (2009) (Vol. 26 No. 2) 219-243 at 219
53 http://www.unctadxi.org/templates/Page1006.aspx (accessed 23 January 2012)
54 http://financial-dictionary.thefreedictionary.com/Bilateral+investment+treaties (accessed 23 January.2012)
31
Every BIT begins with a title which gives an indication of the nature of the
treaty. An example can be drawn from the Finland – Zambia BIT which
states:
55 https://www.wits.ac.za/news/latest-news/in-their-own-words/2016/2016-03/why-developingcountries-are-
dumping-investment-treaties.html#sthash.yzkx6VU9.dpuf (accessed 8 August 2016)
33
2. Definitions
All treaties define some of the terms that are used in the treaty (e.g.
investments, limitation on the definition of investments, portfolio
investments, corporate nationality and protection of shareholders). They
also indicate the understanding that the states have on issues such as
corporate nationality.
3. Preamble
4. Promotion of Investments
56 Article 2(2)
34
a. National Treatment
b. Most-Favoured-Nation Treatment
35
1) Each Contracting Party shall ensure fair and equitable treatment of the
investments of nationals of the other Contracting Party and shall not
impair, by unreasonable or discriminatory measures, the operation,
management, maintenance, use, enjoyment or disposal thereof by those
nationals. Each Contracting Party shall accord to such investments, full
physical security and protection.
7. Expropriation
a) the measures are taken in the public interest and under due process of
law;
Nationals of the one Contracting Party who suffer losses in respect of their
investments in the territory of the other Contracting Party owing to war or
other armed conflict, revolution, a state of national emergency, revolt,
insurrection or riot shall be accorded by the latter Contracting Party
treatment, as regards restitution, indemnification, compensation or other
settlement, no less favourable than that which that Contracting Party
accords to its own nationals or to nationals of any third State who are in
37
9. Free Transfer
e) royalties or fees;
10. Transparency
This provision has historically been drafted to enable the investor and its
home State to become acquainted with the host State’s regulatory
framework and the process of domestic rulemaking affecting investments.
Article 15 of Finland – Zambia BIT provides:
39
Each Contracting Party shall observe any obligation it may have entered
into with regard to investments of nationals of the other Contracting Party.
This clause brings to the fore two controversial issues: (a) whether an
investment treaty-based international arbitral tribunal can exercise
jurisdiction over claims of breach of state contract between an FI and a
state; and (b) whether an umbrella clause in a BIT transforms all foreign
investment (contractual) breaches into treaty breaches.
13. Subrogation
The treaty permits parties to derogate from their obligations where doing
so in the security interest of the party in times of war or armed conflict.
Such measures should not be discriminatory and should be adopted to
protect public order, health and safety, and environment. Article 14 of
Finland – Zambia BIT says:
There are two broad approaches: (1) the “minimalist” (and more
traditional) approach which is characterized by few procedural
specifications, leaving most procedural matters to the applicable
arbitration rules and arbitrators’ discretion; and (2) the “detailed”
approach which features much more sophisticated procedural regulation
63 See Article 14(3)
42
This denotes the day when the treaty would come into effect, its duration,
and the requirements for its termination. Article 17(2)(3) of the Finland –
Zambia BIT states:
2. This Agreement shall remain in force for a period of twenty (20) years and
shall thereafter remain in force on the same terms until either Contracting
Party notifies the other in writing of its intention to terminate the
Agreement in twelve (12) months.
This treaty requires in sub article 3 that, in the event of termination, the
obligations undertaken would continue for a further period of 20 years.
Other treaties, such as the Belgo-Luxembourg, and Egypt - Zambia BITs,
are for a period less than 20 years – 10 years. The Germany – Zambia BIT
was for a period of 5 years and thereafter in perpetuity unless denounced
by either party.65
There are issues that have either been omitted from BITs or have been
inadequately addressed. These are called “emerging issues”. They are
numerous, but some of them are:
Human rights are per essence focused on individual human beings. While
investors can be individuals, international investments law deals mostly
with investors envisaged as legal persons, not individuals, the investor
This explains in part why human rights are still rarely invoked in
international arbitrations dealing with international investments, be it by
the investor or by the State hosting the investment. It is also stated that
human rights has no relationship with investment. In Siemens v
Argentina, the tribunal concluded that the reference made by Argentina
to international human rights law ranking at the level of the Constitution
after the 1994 constitutional reform and implying that property rights
claimed in this arbitration, if upheld, would constitute a breach of
international human rights law [ … ] has not been developed by
Argentina. The Tribunal considered that, ‘without the benefit of further
elaboration and substantiation by the parties, it is not an argument that,
prima facie, bears any relationship to the merits of this case.’
44
The SADC Model BIT, completed in June 2012, has been developed due to
the recognition of the important contribution investment can make to the
sustainable development of the State Parties, including the reduction of
poverty, increase of productive capacity, economic growth, the transfer of
technology, and the furtherance of human rights and human
development.68 The Model BIT is intended as a guide for Member States’
The Model BIT encompasses clauses that are excluded in BITs that Zambia
has concluded – issues of environmental and social impact assessment 70 ,
environmental management and improvement 69, minimum standards for
human rights70, right to regulate71, and the right to pursue development
goals.72
5.6 Exercises
UNIT 6
7.1 Introduction
The Unit examine the concept of political risk in foreign investment and
the nature thereof. It also underscores the interpretation of political risk
from international tribunal’s view point.
69 Article 14
70 Article 15
71 Article 20
72 Article 21
46
its risks to the investor. The decision to invest abroad depends essentially
on the business strategy of the firm in question. The basic aim of
undertaking any investment is to increase or at least preserve the
profitability of the firm. Put simply, the purpose of making investment is to
make a profit on that investment.
These are investments which firms hope will increase their efficiency by
exploiting the benefits of economies of scale and scope, and also those of
common ownership. It is suggested that this kind of FDI comes after either
resource or market seeking investments have been realized, with the
expectation that it further increases the profitability of the firm. 73
FI faces political risks because the foreign investor must submit its assets
and property rights to the sovereign jurisdiction of a foreign state, thereby
creating the possibility that the foreign sovereign may exercise its political
power so as to interfere with the investor’s use of those assets and
property rights.
For the purposes of the MIGA Political Risk Survey, the definition of
political risk includes the following:
This is the risk of losses arising from an investor’s inability to convert local
currency into foreign exchange for transfer outside the host country.
2. Expropriation
3. Breach of contract
6.3.1 Nationalization
6.3.2 Expropriation
This could take many forms: gradual increases in tax rates on profits
which eventually make a business unprofitable to operate; instituting
ever‐increasing barriers to removing profits or dividends from the country;
gradually increasing property tax rates for foreign companies; changing
the percentage of ownership which must be held locally; as well as many
other actions.
The State may adopt certain measures in order to regulate. This is what is
known as ‘police powers’ or ‘power of imminent domain’. It stems from
the realization that, generally, under international law, a State can adopt
certain measures and these should not constitute indirect expropriation or
be seen as ‘tantamount to expropriations’. The use of the term
‘‘tantamount to expropriations’ has often been narrowly construed to
avoid expanding the definition of expropriation; rather, it is simply meant
to include expropriations that occur in substance but not in form. In fact,
some arbitral tribunals have treated “measures tantamount to
expropriation” as the functional equivalent of expropriation.
79 Peter Leon ‘Creeping Expropriation of Mining Investments: an African Perspective’ Journal of Energy &
Natural Resources Law (2009) (Vol. 27 No. 4) pp. 597-644 at 598; August Reinisch, ‘Expropriation’, in Peter
Muchlinski, Federico Ortino and Christoph Schreuer (eds.) The Oxford Handbook of International Investment
Law (2008) 427
80 S.D. Myers, Inc. v. Government of Canada, UNCITRAL/NAFTA, First Partial Award, paragraph 285 (Nov.
13, 2000), 40 I.L.M. 1408 84 Pope & Talbot v. Canada, Interim Award, 26 June 2000, para. 102
51
1. Decrease in value
6.5 Exercises
57
58
UNIT 7
7.0 Introduction
The Convention’s drafting took place from 1961 to 1965. The main bodies
involved were the World Bank’s legal department, the World Bank’s
Executive Directors and a series of regional meetings in which experts
from 86 States participated. The text of the Convention together with a
short explanatory report was adopted by the Executive Directors of the
World Bank on 18 March 1965. Its official designation is Convention on the
Settlement of Investment Disputes between States and Nationals of Other
States.1 It created the International Centre for Settlement of Investment
Disputes (ICSID). This is why the Convention is commonly referred to as
the ICSID Convention.
60
Thus, the Convention is aimed to protect, to the same extent and with
the same vigour the investor and the host State, not forgetting that to
protect investments is to protect the general interest of development
and of developing countries.98
Jurisdiction means the power, right, or authority to interpret and apply the
law. The jurisdiction of ICSID is established by Article 25(1) which provides
that:
The jurisdiction of the Centre shall extend to any legal dispute arising
directly out of an investment, between a Contracting State and a national of
another Contracting State, which the parties to the dispute consent in
writing to submit to the Centre. When the parties have given their consent,
no party may withdraw its consent unilaterally.
The ICSID arbitrator or tribunal can only arbitrate 'a legal dispute arising
directly out of an investment.' A definition of the terms 'legal dispute' and
'investment' were not included in the Convention. The ICSID Convention
does not define what is obviously the most important term of the
Convention – investment. Therefore a broad discretion is given to the
parties in defining this term. This definition, however, must be in
accordance with “the need for international cooperation for economic
development and the role of private international investment therein”, as
stated in the Preamble of the Convention.
the term directly in Article 25 of the ICSID Convention related to the fact
that the dispute should arise directly out of the investment, and did not
apply to the definition of the investment itself. Accordingly, the tribunal in
Fedax held that jurisdiction could exist even with respect to investments
that are not made directly into the host state’s economy, as long as the
dispute arises directly from the investment in question.
100 Consortium RFCC v. Morocco, Award, ICSID Case No ARB/00/6, IIC 76 (2003), (2005) 20 ICSID Rev. - FILJ
391
101 Salini Costruttori S.p.A. and Italstrade S.p.A. v. Jordan, Award, ICSID Case No ARB/02/13, IIC 208 (2006)
102 ICSID Case No ARB/00/4; 42 ILM 609 (2003), 23 July 2001, at para 53
103 Joy Mining Machinery Ltd v. Egypt, Award on jurisdiction, ICSID Case No ARB/03/11; IIC 147 (2004); 19
ICSID Rev—Foreign Investment L J 486 (2004); (2005) 132 Journal du droit international 163
63
The Phoenix tribunal took issue with the fourth criterion in the Salini test—
contribution to the host state’s development— on the premise that
determining an investment’s contribution to development is “impossible
to ascertain.” Instead, the tribunal favoured “a less ambitious approach,”
and proceeded to consider if there had been a contribution to the
economy of the host state. The Phoenix tribunal unanimously rejected the
notion that a contribution to development should be criteria of an ICSID
investment. The tribunal also added two further criteria to the Salini test,
104 Saipem S.p.A. v. The People’s Republic of Bangladesh, ICSID Case No. ARB/05/07. The Salini
criteria was: (i) duration; (ii) regularity of profit and return; (iii) assumption of risk; (iv) substantial
commitment; and (v) significance for the host state’s development
105 Phoenix Action Limited v. Czech Republic, Award, ICSID Case No ARB/06/5, IIC 367
(2009), 9 April 2009 111 Para 114, Ibid
64
that is, whether the assets were invested in accordance with the laws of
the host state and whether there was a bona fide investment of those
assets. Phoenix Action’s claim failed to meet the tribunal’s benchmark for
of bona fide investment as the investment. The tribunal stated:
Other tribunals have explicitly rejected the objective test, which requires
the definition of investment to meet an independent criterion under the
ICSID Convention, and have followed the so-called subjective approach.
The subjective approach focuses on the state parties’ definition of
investment in the IIA, and does not enforce an independent requirement
to be met for the purposes of the ICSID Convention. For example, in
M.C.I. Power Group L.C. v Ecuador,107 which concerned a power plant
investment in Ecuador, the tribunal concluded that the dispute at hand
indeed arose out of an “investment” as defined by Article 25 of the ICSID
Convention. The tribunal held:
From a simple reading of Article 25(1), the Tribunal recognizes that the
ICSID Convention does not define the term “investments”. The Tribunal
notes that numerous arbitral precedents confirm the statement in the
Report of the Executive Directors of the World Bank that the Convention
does not define the term “investments” because it wants to leave the
parties free to decide what class of disputes they would submit to the
ICSID [. . .] The BIT indicates in its Article 1 which investments are to be
protected under it. Thus, the BIT complements Article 25 of the ICSID
Convention, for purposes of defining the Competence of the Tribunal with
respect to any legal dispute arising directly out of an investment.
106 Para 144, Phoenix Action Limited v Czech Republic, Award, ICSID Case No ARB/06/5, IIC 367 (2009), 9
April 2009
107 MCI Power Group LC and New Turbine Incorporated v Ecuador, Award, ICSID Case No ARB/03/6, IIC 296
(2007), 26 July 2007
65
While this Committee’s majority has every respect for the authors of the
Salini v. Morocco Award and those that have followed it, such as the Award in
Joy Mining v. Egypt, and for commentators who have adopted a like stance—
and, it need hardly add, for its distinguished co-arbitrator who attaches an
acute Dissent to this Decision—it gives precedence to awards and analyses
that are consistent with its approach, which it finds consonant with the
intentions of the Parties to the ICSID Convention.
The Criteria for an ‘Investment’: An initial point arises as to the relevant test
to be applied. In advancing submissions on Article 25 of the ICSID
Convention, parties not infrequently begin with the proposition that the term
‘investment’ is not defined in the ICSID Convention, and then proceed to
apply each of the five criteria, or benchmarks, that were originally suggested
by the arbitral tribunal in Fedax v. Venezuela, and re-stated (notably) in Salini
v. Morocco, namely (i) duration; (ii) regularity of profit and return; (iii)
assumption of risk; (iv) substantial commitment; and (v) significance for the
host State’s development [citations omitted].
In the Tribunal’s view, there is no basis for a rote, or overly strict, application
of the five Salini criteria in every case. These criteria are not fixed or
mandatory as a matter of law. They do not appear in the ICSID Convention.
On the contrary, it is clear from the travaux préparatoires of the Convention
that several attempts to incorporate a definition of ‘investment’ were made,
but ultimately did not succeed. In the end, the term was left intentionally
undefined, with the expectation (inter alia) that a definition could be the
subject of agreement as between Contracting States. Hence the following oft-
quoted passage in the Report of the Executive Directors: [. . .] [citations
omitted].
Given that the Convention was not drafted with a strict, objective, definition
of ‘investment’, it is doubtful that arbitral tribunals sitting in individual cases
should impose one such definition which would be applicable in all cases and
for all purposes…
Further, the Salini Test itself is problematic if, as some tribunals have found,
the ‘typical characteristics’ of an investment as identified in that decision are
elevated into a fixed and inflexible test, and if transactions are to be
presumed excluded from the ICSID Convention unless each of the five criteria
are satisfied. This risks the arbitrary exclusion of certain types of transaction
from the scope of the Convention. It also leads to a definition that may
contradict individual agreements (as here), as well as a developing consensus
in parts of the world as to the meaning of ‘investment’ (as expressed, e.g., in
108 Biwater Gauff (Tanzania) Ltd v Tanzania, Award and Concurring & Dissenting Opinion, ICSID Case No
ARB/05/22; IIC 330 (2008)
66
The Arbitral Tribunal therefore considers that a more flexible and pragmatic
approach to the meaning of ‘investment’ is appropriate, which takes into
account the features identified in Salini, but along with all the circumstances
of the case, including the nature of the instrument containing the relevant
consent to ICSID.
The Arbitral Tribunal notes in this regard that, over the years, many tribunals
have approached the issue of the meaning of ‘investment’ by reference to
the parties’ agreement, rather than imposing a strict autonomous definition
as per the Salini Test [citation omitted].
The personal jurisdiction of ICSID restricts the parties eligible for dispute
resolution to a Contracting State and a foreign investor. Article 25(2)
defines a National of another Contracting State as:
(a) any natural person who had the nationality of a Contracting State other
than the State party to the;
(b) any juridical person which had the nationality of a Contracting State
other than the State party to the dispute and any juridical person
which had the nationality of the Contracting State party to the dispute
on that date and which, because of foreign control, the parties have
agreed should be treated as a national of another Contracting State.
requirement, investors must not have the nationality of the host State.
Juridical persons will qualify as nationals of Contracting States through
their place of incorporation or seat of business. A juridical person may,
however, possess the host State’s nationality and still qualify as a national
of another Contracting State under an exception contained in Article 25(2)
(b).
a. Natural person
68
b. Juridical person
69
requirement has been fulfilled. Such an agreement will carry much weight,
but it cannot create a nationality that does not exist. Therefore, the
existence of such an agreement will not preclude the tribunal from
examining the compliance with this requirement.
109 ARB/81/1
110 ARB/83/2
70
In Amco Asia v Indonesia115, in this case the ICSID clause was contained
in an investment licence application. The government argued: (i) its
approval of the application containing the clause did not constitute
consent for the purpose of the ICSID Convention; (ii) that consent to ICSID
arbitration by a state should be construed restrictively since it constitutes
a limitation of the state's sovereignty. The Tribunal disagreed, declaring
that an arbitration agreement 'is not to be construed restrictively, nor as a
matter of fact, broadly or liberally. It is to be construed in a way which
leads to find out and to respect the common will of the parties...'
Consent can also be construed from the provisions of a BIT. In Aguas del
Tunari SA v Republic of Bolivia 119, AdT, under the “Contract for
Concession of Use of Water and for the Public Potable Water and Sewer
Service for the City of Cochabamba” concluded in 1999, received the right
to provide water and sewage services for the city of Cochabamba, Bolivia.
AdT claimed that Bolivia through various acts and omissions breached
various provisions of a BIT. AdT initiated this proceeding against Bolivia
before the ICSID invoking the BIT as the basis of jurisdiction. Bolivia raised
a number of objections to the jurisdiction of the Tribunal including
arguments that it did not consent to ICSID jurisdiction and that AdT is not
a Dutch national as defined by the BIT. The tribunal concluded that the
dispute is within the jurisdiction of the Centre and the competence of the
Tribunal.
Based on case law, the consent to the ICSID arbitration does not need to
be expressed in a single instrument. It could be expressed: (a) in the
domestic legislation of the host state (a unilateral act of the contracting
state); (b) in an investment agreement between parties to the dispute;
and (c) in an international treaty (bilateral or multilateral). The most
important requirement for consent to ICSID arbitration is for the consent
to be in writing.
The Tribunal is, however, not convinced that it is correct to interpret the
BIT to mean that litigation is always an essential precondition to unilateral
reference of a dispute to arbitration, and does not decide the point or rest
its decision upon the rejection of this interpretation and the existence of
an implied right of unilateral reference to arbitration…The Tribunal thus
proceeds on the assumption, and without deciding the point, that Article
10 of the Argentina-Germany BIT imposes a mandatory 18-month
submission to the national courts as a precondition of unilateral recourse
to arbitration under the BIT.121
However, recourse to local remedies does not preclude the Centre from
having jurisdiction. In Enron Corporation and Ponderosa Assets v
Argentine Republic122, the Claimants sought to protect investments
made in the important gas industry of Argentina, the privatization of
which was carried out under the terms of the Gas Law and related
instruments. The Argentine Republic made a jurisdictional objection on
the ground that TGS had applied to various courts of the Argentine
Republic seeking remedies in respect of the tax measures affecting it. It
affirmed that this amounts to the choice of local courts under the Treaty
and hence the jurisdiction of an ICSID tribunal would thus be precluded.
The Tribunal held that the dispute was within the jurisdiction of the Centre
and the competence of the Tribunal. In its own words “…even if there was
recourse to local courts for breach of contract this would not prevent
resorting to ICSID arbitration for violation of treaty right….”
In Tradex v Albania, the consent clause in the Albanian Law was subject
to the condition that the dispute “cannot be settled amicably”. The
Tribunal noted that Tradex had sent five letters over four months to the
competent Albanian Ministry but that none of these was answered or
resulted in any relevant action. The Tribunal found these letters to be a
sufficient good faith effort to reach an amicable settlement.
3. Diplomatic immunity
According to article 27, States are not allowed to give diplomatic immunity
where one of its nationals and another Contracting party has consented to
submit to arbitration. In Lucchetti v Peru123, the investor had initiated
arbitration against the host State under a BIT. Thereupon the respondent
State initiated inter-State proceedings under the BIT against Chile, the
investor’s home State, and sought a suspension of the investor-State
proceedings. Peru argued that interpretative priority should be given to
the State-State proceedings. The Tribunal in the investor-State
proceedings rejected the request for the suspension of proceedings
without giving reasons.
121 Page 15
122 ICSID CASE No. ARB/01/3
123 ICSID Case No. ARB/03/4
74
When the parties have given their consent, no party may withdraw its
consent unilaterally.
The irrevocability of consent operates only after the consent has been
perfected. A mere offer of consent to ICSID’s jurisdiction may be
withdrawn at any time unless, of course, it is irrevocable by its own terms.
In the case of national legislation and treaty clauses providing for ICSID
jurisdiction, the investor must have accepted the consent in writing to
make it irrevocable. Therefore, it is inadvisable for an investor, to rely on
an ICSID consent clause contained in the host State’s domestic law or in a
treaty without making a reciprocal declaration of consent. This may be
done by a simple letter addressed to the host State. Alternatively, the
investor may accept the offer of consent simply by instituting proceedings
before the Centre but in doing so runs the risk that the offer may be
withdrawn at any time before then.
75
The parties are free to subject their consent to limitations and conditions.
However, once consent has been given, its irrevocability extends to the
introduction of new limitations and conditions. In other words, the
prohibition of withdrawal covers the full extent of the consent to
jurisdiction.
The SADC was established by the SADC Treaty which was signed on 17
August 1992. Article 4 of the Treaty confirms that “SADC and its Member
States shall act in accordance with certain principles, including “the rule of
law” and the “peaceful settlement of disputes”. To these ends, the Treaty
created a permanent tribunal, the SADC Tribunal, whose mandate is:
The Tribunal shall consist of not less than ten (10) Members, appointed
from nationals of States who possess the qualifications required for
appointment to the highest judicial offices in their respective States or
who are jurists of recognised competence.
The Tribunal shall have jurisdiction over all disputes and all applications
referred to it in accordance with the Treaty and this Protocol which relate
to:
(c) all matters specifically provided for in any other agreements that
States may conclude among themselves or within the community and
which confer jurisdiction on the Tribunal.
1. The Tribunal shall have jurisdiction over disputes between States, and
between natural or legal persons and States.
The jurisdiction of the Tribunal is twofold: (1) between States; and (2)
between the State and a person. Under the Protocol, the Tribunal has
“exclusive jurisdiction over all disputes between the States and the
Community” and “disputes between natural or legal persons and the
Community”. Such disputes may be referred to the Tribunal either by the
State concerned or by the competent institution or organ of the
Community.128
[…] investors have the right of access to the courts, judicial and
administrative tribunals, and other authorities competent under the laws
of the Host State for redress of their grievances in relation to any matter
concerning any investment […].”
deprived of their lands without having had the right of access to the courts
and the right to a fair hearing, which are essential elements of the rule of
law, and […] consequently […] that the Respondent has acted in breach of
Article 4(c) of the Treaty.
The Tribunal went on to hold that, since the implementation of the land
reform legislation “affects white farmers only and consequently
constitutes indirect discrimination or de facto or substantive inequality”;
Zimbabwe had “discriminated against the Applicants on the basis of race
and thereby violated its obligation under Article 6(2) of the Treaty.” The
Tribunal further held that the applicants were entitled to “fair
compensation,” although such compensation was not quantified in the
judgment. Mike Campbell attempted to enforce the judgment in
Zimbabwe, but was denied. He then proceeded to enforce it in South
Africa following the grant of leave to do so by the Constitutional Court.
79
Article 7(c) of the Treaty establishes, as one of the organs of the COMESA,
the Court of Justice. The Court is composed of seven Judges who are
chosen from among persons of impartiality and
7.3.1.1 Jurisdiction
The Court has jurisdiction to adjudicate upon all matters which may be
referred to it pursuant to the Treaty. 131 The reference can be made
threefold by: (1) a Member State which considers that another Member
State or the Council has failed to fulfil an obligation under the Treaty 132;
(2) the Secretary-General who considers that a Member State has failed to
fulfil an obligation under the Treaty or has infringed its provision 133; and
(3) any person who is resident in a Member State requesting the court’
determination of the legality of any act, regulation, directive, or decision
of the Council or of a Member State. 134 The Treaty also gives the Court
jurisdiction over matters arising from a contract that has an arbitration
clause. Article 28 provides:
The Court shall have jurisdiction to hear and determine any matter:
(b) arising from a dispute between the Member States regarding this
Treaty if the dispute is submitted to it under a special agreement
between the Member States concerned.
7.4 Exercises
82