SSRN 3516096
SSRN 3516096
SSRN 3516096
Amnon Lehavi
Dean and Atara Kaufman Professor of Real Estate
Harry Radzyner Law School
Academic Director, Gazit-Globe Real Estate Institute,
Interdisciplinary Center (IDC) Herzliya
8 University Street, Herzliya 4610101, Israel
Email: [email protected]
Abstract. Digital technology can open new frontiers in the formation, registration, and
enforcement of property rights in land. This chapter explores the prospects - but also the limits -
of digital technology in streamlining efficient land use and land markets. In particular, it asks
whether the digital production and dissemination of information can enhance a more optimal use
of land, such as by the three-dimensional (3D) delineation of real estate into distinct segments
and specific rights thereto, including for subsurface infrastructure, or by the digital pooling of
non-adjacent assets for purposes such as creating collective security interests in them. This
chapter shows that while aligning the digital production of information with a corresponding
system of “legal volumes” and 3D zoning regulation can innovate land markets, the growing
multiplicity of property rights in multi-layered tracts faces a genuine collective action problem,
having both commons and anticommons features. Digital technology should thus be matched
with a legal reform on the institutional governance of multiple uses and interests in and across
tracts, somewhat like in the case of condominiums and other current forms of strata title.
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
I. Introduction
The Fourth Industrial Revolution, embedded in the rapid development of digital technology
and other technological/scientific advances, purports to transform all walks of life, such that “the
real opportunity is to look beyond technology, and find ways to give the greatest number of
people the ability to positively impact their families, organisations and communities” (World
Economic Forum, 2020). Land use and land markets are definitely instrumental for the future of
families and communities. Yet at first glance, land seems to be a less natural candidate for
outright revolution, given its finite supply and physical traits, unlike other forms of economic
activities.
This chapter looks at how digital technology can be utilized to advance a more extensive and
efficient use of land, primarily by the 3D digital slicing or pooling of land, dissemination of this
information to all relevant actors, and matching of such geographical and technological data with
a more flexible multi-use approach to land-use regulation (and zoning in particular) and a multi-
layered allocation of property rights. Such a legal development could extend beyond the current
closed list (numerus clausus) of types of property rights to meet this changing landscape.
At the same time, the growing sophistication of digital technology and its application to land-
use regulation and to legal aspects of property rights do not inherently solve genuine collective
action problems that typify intensive, multi-use, multi-party land developments. In fact, the
growing intensity of use and multiplicity of stakeholders enabled by digital technology can also
increase potential frictions among such stakeholders: from neighboring (vertical or horizontal)
users of land, to multiple financiers holding competing or overlapping security interests in land.
Such collective action problems can implicate both issues of commons (Hardin, 1968), in which
multiple stakeholders in the same asset will tend to over-exploit and under-invest in it - and ones
of anticommons (Heller, 1998; Contreras, 2018), in which over-fragmentation of private property
rights in legally separate but practically interdependent assets can lead to inefficient results or
outright deadlocks, by preventing coordination or integrative use of such assets. These collective
action problems can result from either strategic behavior, such as holdouts or free riding, or from
genuine heterogeneity among stakeholders about their preferences and priorities.
While digital technology can provide better information to all parties about the spatial features
of land, and a corresponding reform in zoning regulation and the composition of property rights
can potentially give them more flexibility in exploiting physical space, such developments do not
in themselves offer a mechanism for resolving potential frictions and deadlocks among parties.
What is therefore needed is a dynamic decision-making framework that would accompany
various types of multi-use, multi-layered land developments, facilitating institutional governance
that draws inspiration from the legal design of condominiums and other forms of strata title.
The rest of this chapter is structured as follows. Part II discusses the traditional allocation of
property rights in land, which is based largely on a two-dimensional identification of a single
tract’s surface, with certain particular exceptions that still fall short of a flexible spatial approach.
Part III shows how different forms of strata title, including condominiums, have been able to
create an institutional and legal framework for the governance of multi-party, multi-layered use
of land, mostly in the residential context, despite their reliance on a static, pre-digital delineation.
Part IV demonstrates recent experiments with the digital production of 3D spatial data and a
corresponding adaptation of zoning regulation and 3D land registration of “legal volumes.” Part
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
V suggests that, in addition to innovative 3D slicing, digital technology can also facilitate the
pooling of non-adjacent properties for purposes such as cross-asset collective security interests.
Part VI shows that while digital technology can facilitate a more dynamic and intensive use of
land, it cannot in itself resolve potential collective action problems that persist or may be even
exacerbated by the growing multiplicity of property rights and numbers of stakeholders. Any
such innovation must be matched with the legal design of multi-party institutions of governance.
Prior to discussing how current digital technology can transform the spatial allocation of
property rights in land, this part briefly identifies the piecemeal development of legal and
regulatory doctrine on multi-layered property in the face of previous generations of economic,
social, and technological changes. In principle, such exogenous changes may implicate demand
and (to a lesser extent) supply of physical space, as well as the relative costs and benefits of
following a certain system of property rights, thus leading to potential changes in legal and
regulatory policy (Demsetz, 1967). While such changes have indeed occurred for land, especially
over the past two centuries, it would be fair to say that longstanding principles of property in
land have not been entirely disrupted, but were rather gradually adjusted and fine-tuned.
Moreover, this development has often been unsystematic, leaving much room for ambiguity,
such that the overall spatial system of allocating property rights in land is presently suboptimal.
The starting point is that of the ad coelum rule. Under the Latin maxim, which dates back to
the times of Gaius and Justinian: “Cuius est solum eius est esque ad coelom et usque ad inferos”
(“Whoever owns the land owns the property all the way to heaven and all the way to the center
of the earth”). While exceptions to this rule have already been introduced during Roman times
through the actio de superficie, allowing for the creation of horizontal surface rights owned by
subjects other than the owner of the estate, it has proven resilient over centuries (Parisi, 2002).
In the common law system, the ad coelum rule became influential after it was cited by Edward
Coke in the seventeenth century and William Blackstone in the eighteenth century (Rule, 2011).
At its core, while referring to a three-dimensional space, the ad coelum rule is in fact
dominated by the two-dimensional delineation of the land’s surface for establishing property
rights. The identification of a two-dimensional space and title thereto automatically governs
rights over open space above and below the surface. Moreover, such delineation controls rights
to other valuable objects: from subterranean minerals and other materials, to above surface
human-made structures through the principle of accession, or ‘fixtures’ in Anglo-American legal
terminology, mostly in a landlord-tenant context (van Erp & Akkermans, 2012).
In Continental Europe, nineteenth-century civil codes, including the 1804 Code Napoléon,
adhered to the ad coelum rule by disallowing the horizontal severance of land into multiple
surface and subsurface estates. But property owners occasionally continued to do so. While such
agreements on the partition of land into multiple surface and subsurface estates could not
formally commit to conveying real title to the various land strata, parties to such transactions
sought to bypass this impediment by agreeing not to invoke accession rules for any structures
(such as buildings) erected on the land. With time, civil courts developed a more accommodating
approach and allowed such atypical forms of property fragmentation to survive in the shadow of
the law. Subsequently, twentieth-century civil codes, including the 1900 German BGB, moved
away from applying the strict principle of physical unity, allowing in effect for limited forms of
fragmentation, involving typically not more than two layers: surface and subsoil (Parisi, 2012).
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
A more systematic legal challenge to the ad coelum rule began in regard to airspace with the
start of aviation in the early twentieth century. In the seminal case of United States v. Causby
(1946), the US Supreme Court moved away from a strict application of the ad coelum rule -
reasoning this doctrine “has no place in the modern world” (p. 261). It distinguished between an
upper altitude that serves as a “public highway” for air travel, and the lower layer of airspace
above the land’s surface that may be practically usable, such that the “landowner owns at least as
much of the space above the ground as he can occupy or use in connection with the land” (pp.
264-65).
That said, the ad coelum rule, and the underlying dominance of the two-dimensional
delineation of the land’s surface for establishing property rights and legal control, are far from
abolished. For both airspace and subsurface, the ad coelum rule has been occasionally adjusted to
accommodate economic, social, and technological changes, but it otherwise maintains the control
of the surface owner over usable spaces or those in which invasions might otherwise impact such
use and enjoyment. Thus, regarding unauthorized invasions to the lower airspace and immediate
subsurface, courts generally adhere to a strict version of the ad coelum rule (Smith, 2015).
The complexity of managing a multiplicity of layers in the face of the ad coelum rule, and not
less importantly, in a system of property rights and land registries that still generally follows a
two-dimensional approach, manifests itself even more vividly in the case of subsurface rights.
Subsurface rights are created most frequently through the voluntary creation of easements on
relevant routes across/in the subsurface or materials located in the subsurface. Easements -
defined generally as an irrevocable license to enter and use land owned by or in possession of
another person - are recognized as property rights in the various legal systems and can be
registered accordingly in the land registry. In the case of the right to enter the surface and/or the
subsurface in order to remove materials such as timber, minerals, oil, and gas, such an easement
is traditionally referred to as a profit à prendre, or simply as a profit (Restatement, 2000). In
particular, the law governing easements relating to subsurface oil, gas, and minerals has
developed into a separate and complex branch of doctrine, with unique rules applying to such
subsurface interests (Dukeminier et al., 2018; Kostrub & Christenson, 2012). The multi-layered
structure of a subsurface right of easement is further challenged in light of recent technological
developments, such as horizontal drillings or hydraulic fracturing (Wilkerson, 2015).
In addition to transaction-based easements, the need for surface or subsurface public
infrastructure, such as roads and railways, electricity lines, water pipes, fiber-optic cables, etc.,
may require the government to use its power of eminent domain to obtain an easement or right of
way in the surface or subsurface (Morriss, Brandys & Barron, 2014). Some legal systems -
including those of many US states - may also grant private entities, such as oil and gas
companies, the right to use the power of eminent domain to obtain such easements or rights of
way (Klass, 2008; Righetti, 2016). That said, the ad coelum rule continues to play a major role,
such that any form of permanent physical invasion of the surface or subsurface requires either
the consent of the landowner or exercising the power of eminent domain for public use against
the payment of due compensation. This may be so even if such a physical invasion is very
limited in scope and does not practically deny current use and enjoyment of the land by the
owner, as famously articulated by the US Supreme Court in the case of Loretto v. Teleprompter
Manhattan CATV Corp. (1982).
Another type of multi-layered fragmentation of property rights in land, which emerged as an
exception to the ad coelum rule, concerns the ability to separate ownership of a building or
another structure from the ownership of the land. In Roman law, it is known as a superficies.
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
While as a general rule, civil law systems adhere to the maxim of sepreficies solo cedit (adopting
the rule of accession for any such building or another structure), civil codes were amended and
other pieces of legislation or regulation were introduced to recognize a self-standing right of
superficies. That said, the exact content of the right of superficies (for example, in regard to
future construction rights, or the right to enter the land to access the building) are often not set by
law, but should be specifically determined between the parties (van Erp & Akkermans, 2012).
The separation of land ownership from property rights in structures or buildings has also been
gradually introduced in Anglo-American systems. However, such fragmentation is done in
specific contexts, when the practical need for this manifests, often with little or no statutory or
regulatory provisions linking such exceptions to the ad coelum rule or to the law on fixtures.
One such setting, introduced in the United States, is that of the Community Land Trust (CLT).
The CLT is a community-based, non-profit organization that acquires land for the purpose of
retaining perpetual ownership in it to facilitate affordable housing. An eligible buyer leases the
land for a long period of time (typically 99 years) and becomes owner of the building erected on
it. The lease agreement on the land divides the bundle of rights between the individual and the
CLT during the tenancy and upon its transfer by inheritance or resale. In the latter case, to keep
the land available for affordable housing in perpetuity, the CLT repurchases the property itself or
monitors its direct transfer from seller to buyer, while ensuring that the resale price is restricted
to a set formula. This is done to allow the exiting homeowner to receive a reasonable return on
investment, while granting income-eligible buyers affordable access to the housing unit. Most
US states allow for the legal fragmentation of rights between the land and the housing unit,
whereas in a couple of states (Ohio and North Carolina) there is a gray area in the law,
suggesting that such a separation of title is not permitted. In such cases, the CLT leases out to the
buyer both the land and the building (Davis, 2010; Lehavi, 2013; Miller, 2013). The CLT model,
with its division of property title, is now becoming familiar also in Britain (Chadwick, 2018).
Finally, another limited and often incomplete feature of multi-layered entitlements in land,
which exceeds the paradigm of two-dimensional property rights over a single tract, concerns
transferrable development rights (TDRs), also referred to colloquially as “air rights.” TDRs are a
regulatory mechanism that allows landowners to buy unused development rights from owners of
other lots, under specific terms set out in statutory law or local zoning provisions, and to add
such development rights to their own lots. The mechanism was originally introduced in New
York City, prominently as in-kind compensation for owners of designated landmark buildings
restricted from altering the building or building on top of it, by allowing them to sell such unused
development rights to owners of other, non-restricted lots in the area (Ellickson et al., 2013).
Gradually, TDRs have come to be employed in a broader fashion, such that in New York
City and elsewhere today developers can acquire unused development rights from owners of
properties, whenever the two lots share a physical boundary, but the developers can then go on to
assemble more development rights from consecutive lots (Guardian, 2019). While TDRs start to
have a substantial impact on land use and land markets, it should be noted, first, that the term
“air rights” is misleading in the sense that landowners do not actually acquire the property rights
in the physical unbuilt spaces in other lots, and secondly, that unlike property rights, unused
development rights are typically not registered as such in land registries. In these and other
respects, TDRs are limited in their ability to create a comprehensive and transparent system of
efficiently allocating property rights, horizontally or vertically, across different tracts of land.
The large picture that emerges from the current legal landscape of multi-layered property in
land is one of piecemeal, often ad-hoc solutions to address the growing complexity and intensity
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
of land use and land markets in light of social, economic, and technological changes. The two-
dimensional approach to land ownership, expressed in the ad coelum rule, but also pertinent in
traditional land registries and land use regulation, continues to serve as the default rule for the
allocation and control of property rights in land.
Exceptions are carved out specifically and gradually, looking to solve particular problems
with airspace, surface rights of way and subsurface exploitation of oil, gas, and minerals, etc. -
but lacking a systematic approach to transform the two-dimensional tradition into a flexible,
transparent, and accessible system of multi-layered property. Accordingly, easements (whether
voluntary or compulsory), superficies, and other types of limited proprietary rights allowing for
the use of - or the taking of profit from - certain subsurface, surface, or above-surface parts of a
tract of land are subject to many intricacies and ambiguities, and are often not featured clearly
and comprehensively in traditional land registries.
Moreover, to the extent that a certain legal system currently wishes to avoid ambiguities in
defining a certain multi-level property right, it must often engage in excessive subdivision of
parcels given the features of two-dimensional land registries. Thus, for example, in many
countries, in the case of a right of superficies for a building that is constructed under, on, or over
a part of a tract of land, the said object would be projected on a two-dimensional parcel map, and
the parcel would be further subdivided into smaller parcels, to be able to register such a property
right. Such a subdivision would often make little sense for the principal use of the land (Stoter et
al., 2017). This means that the division or aggregation of pieces of land and rights thereto might
not be driven by efficiency or other normative considerations, but rather by technical constraints,
obsolete doctrine, or other varieties of path-dependency (Fennell, 2019).
The traditional system of multi-level allocation of property rights is thus often suboptimal. As
the next parts will show, what is required is a systematic transformation into a three-dimensional
model, which not only enables efficient spatial allocation of property rights, but also sets up an
institutional mechanism for a long-term governance of multi-layered interests and stakeholders.
Similar steps should be taken to enable the virtual and legal pooling of non-adjacent assets, such
as for creating cross-asset security interests, to promote land markets and real-estate financing.
This part identifies the most important exception to the above-surveyed systematic deficiency
in multi-layered property rights. In the context of residential land use, basically all legal systems
have introduced over the past few decades common interest developments (CIDs). The term CID
refers here to various types of shared-interest residential developments, such as condominiums,
planned unit developments, stock cooperatives (co-ops), and community apartment projects. Not
all forms exist in all countries, and the organizational and legal structure of each type of CID, as
well as the terminology used, somewhat diverge among different legal systems (Lehavi, 2016).
Thus, for example, the vertical (but also horizontal) division of property rights in apartment
buildings, which is typically governed by the legal institution of condominiums in the United
States, is referred to as strata title in Australia. It is the most prevalent form of CID in the world.
Horizontal subdivisions - under which a real estate development is comprised of detached homes
or housing units, with other areas serving as common facilities - are generally known as “planned
unit developments” in the United States and as “community title” in Australia (Sherry, 2017).
This part focuses on condominiums or strata title as legal institutions for multi-layered
property rights. It shows how such a volumetric allocation of space - while still relying on paper-
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
based or static techniques for 3D allocation - is effectively intertwined with mechanisms for
collective governance of both the common amenities and at least some aspects of the individual
units. This part then presents the emergence of the “stratum subdivision” in Australia, which
governs mixed-use developments, including structures having diverse types of commercial uses.
The condominium consists of an “undivided interest in common in a portion of real property
with a separate interest in [a] space called a unit” (California Civil Code, 2014). The basic legal
structure is one by which the housing units are individually owned, whereas the hallways,
staircases, elevators, etc. of the structure (or complex of structures), alongside exterior spaces
and amenities, such as yards, lawns, inner streets, or sports facilities, are owned in common by
the group of unit owners. Condominiums developed at different stages and a diverging pace
across the world. In Western Europe, early forms of condominiums have been in existence for a
few hundred years, but the major push toward comprehensive legislation came in the aftermath
of the world wars, which caused an acute housing shortage alongside growing popular demand
for homeownership (van der Merwe, 2015). Emerging economies in Southeast Asia followed
mostly Australian legislation during the 1960s and 1970s to meet growing local and foreign
demand for condominium-type dense developments (Rabenhorst & Ignatova, 2009).
Condominiums were introduced in the United States only during the later 1950s and early 1960s,
but have since been burgeoning rapidly (McKenzie, 1994; Schill et al., 2007). Transitional
economies have more recently seen the need for the legal design of condominiums mostly in
their urban cores, as demonstrated in the case of China or that of Russia (Chen & Kielsgard
2014; Lehavi, 2015).
As suggested above, the key institutional feature allowing condominiums to function
effectively over time in governing multi-owned, multi-layered properties is the establishment of
decision-making bodies with broad powers. Thus, for example, under the Australian model
(introduced in New South Wales in 1961 and essentially followed in all other Australian states),
a body corporate, constituted by all owners, is automatically created by the registration of the
subdivision plan of the strata title. This body corporate is granted by statute the power to raise
levies for maintenance, insurance, and administration, as well as the power to enforce bylaws.
While the statute provides for default bylaws, the body corporate can alter such bylaws (for
some provisions unanimously, for others by special majority), and subsequently engage in
creating new bylaws, typically by special, non-unanimous resolution. Importantly, such bylaws
may govern not only the use and enjoyment of the shared property, but also the physical features
and use of the privately owned apartments. Such bespoke bylaws, particularly for large schemes,
can include provisions about paint colors, mailbox style, plant type, pet type and weight, etc.
There are some limits imposed by statute on the power of the body corporate, such that most
Australian states ban bylaws that restrict transferring, leasing, or mortgaging lots (Sherry, 2017).
The organization and scope of power of internal bodies that govern multi-owned properties
are similar in other countries, such as in the United States. The core of the collective action
among homeowners in condominiums lies in the governing documents, comprised of
“declarations” containing a set of conditions, covenants, and restrictions (CC&Rs), which are
recorded with the land registrar. Though based on contractual provisions, the governing
documents and subsequent amendments, rules, and regulations adopted by the association go
well beyond the law of contracts, awarding these rules a more credible and reciprocal nature.
This is so because under enabling legislation, individually owned lots or units are “burdened by a
servitude that imposes an obligation that cannot be avoided by nonuse or withdrawal”
(Restatement, 2000).
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
As the California Supreme Court reasoned in its decision in Pinnacle Museum Tower
Association v. Pinnacle Market Development (2012), having a single set of recorded covenants
and restrictions that applies to an entire residential association “protects the intent, expectations,
and wishes of those buying into the development and the community as a whole by ensuring that
promises concerning the character and operation of the development are kept” (p. 524). The fact
that such provisions are enforced as servitudes and not merely as contractual provisions - which
might otherwise allow an infringing homeowner to avoid specific performance and instead pay
compensatory damages - secures the endurance of collective action.
As is the case in Australia, rule-making powers of condominium associations extend beyond
the establishment and management of common facilities, and may also control cross-apartment
externalities resulting from the use of privately owned units, with such types of private ordering
coming in addition to - and not in lieu of - public regulation, such as zoning or nuisance law.
Elected directors and officers of the association have broad authority to “exercise all the
powers of the community except those reserved to the members.” This authority also regularly
includes the power to adopt “reasonable” rules that govern the use of the common property and
the use of individually owned property when this is required to protect the common property. In
reviewing the board’s actions, courts regularly adopt either a “reasonableness rule” or corporate
law’s “business judgment rule” - both bearing a similar deferential content (Restatement, 2000).
As for decisions taken by the general body corporate of homeowners, unless expressly limited by
law or the association’s declarations, simple majority is effective to amend the declarations or to
otherwise adopt rules. Unanimous consent is required for restrictions on individual uses that
cannot be grounded in common interest; changes made to the basis for allocating voting rights or
assessments among homeowners; or rules that do not apply uniformly to similar units/lots.
In practice, however, US courts tend to broadly construe enabling legislation and declarations
so as to settle for simple majority to amend the declaration or to promulgate new rules in nearly
all instances. In Villa De Las Palmas Homeowners Association v. Terifaj (2004), the California
Supreme Court upheld a majority-approved amendment to the condominium’s declarations
imposing a no-pet restriction, by viewing such a use restriction as “crucial to the stable, planned
environment of any shared ownership arrangement” and holding that all homeowners, including
those who purchased their units prior to the amendment, are bound by it. The court read Section
1355(b) of California’s Civil Code on declaration amendments as settling for simple majority,
reasoning that it is designed to prevent a “small number of holdouts from blocking changes
regarded by the majority to be necessary to adapt to changing circumstances and thereby permit
the community to retain its vitality over time” (p. 1228). Amendments made by simple majority
thus generally enjoy a presumption of reasonableness, shifting the burden to the challenging
party, who must show that these restrictions are “wholly arbitrary, violate a fundamental public
policy, or impose a burden on the use of affected land that far outweighs any benefit” (p. 1231).
While these broad powers may at times seem controversial, especially when they have a
practical effect of singling out certain homeowners, or when they otherwise infringe on what
may be considered to be fundamental individual rights, there is no doubt that, generally
speaking, the governance mechanism that is attached to the proprietary setup of condominiums
or strata title is essential for the effective allocation and control of multi-owner, multi-layered
properties. As such, it allows for a more intensive use of urban land in an age of increasing
density and demand.
A recent development in Australia, which seeks to offer an institutional solution to multi-
owned, multi-layered properties beyond residential buildings, is that of ‘stratum’ or ‘volumetric’
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
subdivisions. Realizing that strata title legislation was not adequate for mixed-use developments
with residential and commercial owners, or with diverse commercial owners, such that a single
body corporate may find it difficult to make decisions, Australian legislation was amended to
allow for the subdivision of a building by a deposited plan into separate stratum lots, limited by
height or depth by reference to the Australian Height Datum. Such stratum lots can be further
divided by a strata plan, creating a residential or commercial strata scheme within that stratum
lot, which becomes a ‘stratum parcel.’ Each such stratum lot or parcel could be then governed by
its own set of bylaws. To address the vertical and lateral interdependencies between the different
stratum lots, such stratum subdivisions require the introduction of easements intended to grant
separate stratum owners access to shared property, which is partly or entirely located in another
stratum owner’s lot or parcel. Further, in order to deal with maintenance costs and other issues
that require ongoing coordination across the different stratum lots or parcels, owners must
register Building Management Statements (BMS) and Strata Management Statements (SMS).
Such documents must include provisions on insurance, damages, and disputes, but may also and
typically do include many other issues. In addition, the BMS must establish a Building
Management Committee, which includes all stratum lot or parcel owners (Sherry, 2017). This
committee is discussed further in Part VI, by illustrating how it facilitates collective governance.
Digital technology and other types of innovations are being increasingly employed by both
governmental agencies and private entities across the world in the context of land use and land
markets. This includes the use of advanced technologies and professional standards, such as
interactive graphic visualization, geographic information systems (GIS), building information
modelling (BIM), and the land administration domain model (LADM) (Lemmen et al., 2015).
The key challenge for efficiently implementing such new technologies lies to a large extent
in the ability to integrate them across different professional and governmental platforms that are
relevant to land use and land markets, and particularly in land registries and cadastral systems.
Optimally, such geographical, technical, and legal tools should be formalized and accessible to
all parties concerned, and governed by a unified system of registration (Yu et al., 2017).
Such techniques are being increasingly used in an attempt to gradually switch cadasters and
land registries from two-dimensional systems to three-dimensional ones, with diverging degrees
of success in introducing 3D systems and in synchronizing industry and governmental platforms.
Accordingly, there is a growing body of literature on the recent experiences with 3D cadasters
and/or land registries worldwide (Paasch et al., 2016), with numerous works focusing on case
studies in countries such as Australia (Atazadeh et al., 2017), Croatia (Vučić et al., 2017), Korea
(Kim & Heo, 2019), India (Hamid et al. 2016), and Slovenia (Drobež et al., 2017).
In 2016, The Netherlands experimented with the first registration of an interactive 3D
visualization of “legal volumes” – i.e., 3D physical spaces identified each as a distinctive unit -
in the cadaster and the land registry (Stoter et al., 2016). As shown below, by legally validating
and providing access to such a new type of physical identification and registration of rights in
regard thereto, this regulatory and legal innovation seeks to serve not only current stakeholders,
but even more so future transferees and other stakeholders of these multi-level property rights.
As such, the introduction of legal volumes not only facilitates a more flexible approach to the
division or aggregation of space over time in the face of social, economic, and technological
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
changes, but may also enable the development of new types of property rights, outside of the
current closed list (numerus clausus) – thus better serving future organizational and legal design.
The program was run for the Delft Railway Zone Project. The project covers an area of 24
hectares, but the 3D cadaster was introduced for a smaller part, consisting of the combined new
Railway Station and City Hall, together with the underground platforms and railway tunnel,
several technical installations, and underground bicycle parking (Stoter et al., 2016). This multi-
layered construction combined the property rights of three parties: Municipality of Delft, which
is the owner of the land and the City Hall; the Dutch railroad company for passenger
transportation (“NS Real Estate” or “NS Vastgoed”), which is the owner of the Station Hall,
shops, and technical installations; and the Dutch railroad infrastructure company (“ProRail” or
“Railinfratrust B.V.”), which owns the travelers’ area, the tunnel, and the platforms. To address
this multi-level setup, six legal volumes and property rights thereto have been established:
1. Residual legal volume, not covered by the other five legal volumes (represented as
“Index 1” in Figure 1 below) – under a right of ownership of the Municipality of Delft.
2. Tunnels (“Index 2” in Fig. 1) – right of superficies, Railinfratrust B.V.
3. Travelers’ area (“Index 3” in Fig. 1) - right of superficies, Railinfratrust B.V.
4. Station Hall (“Index 4” in Fig. 1) - right of superficies, NS Vastgoed.
5. Elevators and stairs (“Index 5” in Fig. 1) - right of superficies, NS Vastgoed.
6. Technical installations (“Index 6” in Fig. 1) - right of superficies, NS Vastgoed.
Because of the experimental nature of the 3D registration process, in order to avoid the
economic risks of delay in doing so, the property rights were initially recorded in the land
registry through traditional 2D registration. In the deed, the six legal volumes were described
textually, and were accompanied by 2D maps, illustrating the various cross sections. For this
initial registration process, new ground parcels were formed by the cadaster - such that the
original parcels were consolidated and subsequently subdivided to specify the different
accumulation of rights of the new complex (Stoter et al., 2016).
Then, for the 3D registration, the architect of the building complex converted the 3D data of
the construction itself, using BIM technology, into 3D geometries representing the six legal
volumes, based on the design data of the complex, the already registered deed with 2D maps of
the complex, and the input of all stakeholders collected via four work sessions. Next, the 3D
representations of the property rights were converted into a 3D PDF. This also included a legend
of the rights, the 2D cadastral map in which the parcels were identified, and the x, y, and z
coordinates of the national reference system. Subsequently, a notary firm issued a certificate for
the deposit of the 3D PDF in the land registry as an official deed (Stoter et al., 2016).
In the cadastral registration, a 3D complex ID was generated and the different rights were
assigned unique indices (numbered 1 to 6, as shown in Fig. 1 below). Additionally, a reference
was made in the cadastral registration to the interactive 3D visualization of property rights. The
3D data itself was stored by the cadaster to accommodate future needs, which may require the
adjustment of the legal situation. The 3D data is stored and maintained by the public registries.
The 3D PDF is publicly viewable not only from the public registries, but also from the
cadaster, and can be viewed in any PDF viewer that supports 3D. In the viewer, the 3D setup can
be interactively viewed, such that one sees the relationship between the different legal volumes.
Each volume is visible for further inspection, such that by clicking on each one of the objects,
one sees the 3D indices and identity of the property owner of the legal volume (Kadaster, 2016).
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
Figure 1: Frame taken from the interactive 3D PDF of the Delft Railway Zone Project, as
deposited in The Netherlands’ national cadaster and the land registry (Source: Kadaster, 2016).
Without going into further technical details and addressing other intricacies that may be the
result of the transition from a 2D registration system of property rights to a 3D system, a few
comments are in order about the prospects - but also the limits - of this technological and legal
innovation.
First, the transition into 3D interactive registration has clear benefits for facilitating more
efficient land use and land markets. The inefficiency of relying on 2D maps and accompanying
textual descriptions is especially significant in cases of multi-level property rights, wherever
boundaries are not exactly on top of each other when projected on a 2D plane (Stoter et al.,
2016). Under 2D systems, there is often a need to artificially create tiny parcels to accommodate
potential mismatches between the location of 2D cadastral boundaries and the projection of the
3D construction. Moreover, future division or aggregation of current legal volumes may also not
conform to purely vertical or horizontal divisions. It may employ geometrically irregular - but
economically efficient - 3D shapes. A system of 3D surveying of the land for cadastral purposes,
followed by a system of 3D land-use regulation and the 3D creation of legal volumes allows for
more flexibility for both the initial stage of developing the project and any future redevelopment.
Second, while the benefits are clear, the regulatory and technical challenges in synchronizing
the different industry and governmental platforms are still prevalent and not merely the result of
conservatism or other path-dependency. Thus, for example, BIM systems and cadastral
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
surveying methods often have a different level of accuracy, which may result in physically small
but important implications for questions of property rights, use, and future development of lands.
As shown in the case of the Delft Railway Zone Project, this may also call for an active input by
all stakeholders in setting up the multi-layered property scheme to resolve any such ambiguities.
Third, and relatedly, the potential for dynamic reconfiguration of legal volumes and property
rights thereto, embedded in an interactive 3D system, may require that the relevant stakeholders
be involved in any processes of change in real time to mitigate the potential for disputes or
ambiguities for any such future reconfigurations. This may strengthen the need for intertwining
the development of systems for the 3D planning, allocation, and registration of property rights,
with the establishment of institutional governance mechanisms for the various stakeholders that
hold multi-layered property rights. This point is discussed further in Part VI below.
Finally, the switch to a more flexible, transparent, and dynamic system of allocating and
reallocating property rights across subsurface, surface, or above-surface spaces may provide an
opportunity for creating new types of property rights - ones that may better accommodate up-to-
date needs coming from developers, financiers, tenants, and so forth, and that may be supported
by digital technology and legal innovation.
As noted, in the case of the Delft Railway Zone Project, the Dutch railroad company for
passenger transportation and the Dutch railroad infrastructure company, which together own five
out of the six legal volumes, were granted a superficies right - and not an ownership right - in
view of traditional legal constraints, whereas the Municipality of Delft retains its ownership of
the complex and rights to the residual legal volume. While such a division may make sense, there
is no reason to a-priori rule out a different type of allocation of rights, including by setting up a
new kind of property right that may be particularly appropriate for complex settings of multi-
layered property rights. This could have implications not only for increasing legal certainty, but
also for the ability to finance the acquisition and development of a certain legal volume by
pledging such a new type of right, in light of current constraints that often apply to limited
proprietary rights, such as the superficie. In considering the list of recognized property rights as
embedding “optimal standardization” that balances between increasing the efficiency of land use
and land markets and the social costs of introducing new types of rights (Merrill and Smith,
2001), the innovation of 3D registration and legal volumes might create a new optimal standard
in determining the number and variety of property rights in land.
Digital technology, big data analytics, interactive graphic visualization, and other innovative
tools can push forward land use and land markets in various other ways. Thus, alongside the
ability to more effectively slice tracts through the integration of three-dimensional visualization,
land use, and land registration systems, new technologies can also be utilized to pool together
non-adjacent assets. Such interactive pooling, which could also carry legal consequences in
bundling property rights to non-adjacent assets, could serve current and future economic needs,
especially in the context of real-estate financing and real-estate-backed investment securities.
To understand why current forms of real-estate financing challenge traditional boundaries
(literally speaking), consider the observation by which “loans secured on real estate today are
amended, redeemed, subjected to both initial and subsequent syndication, assigned, certified,
secured by charges against more than one property, divided up and sold in part” (Stöcker, 2012).
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
What this new reality means is that individuals, business corporations, and financial
institutions increasingly engage in practices that move away from the single loan/single asset
model for a secured transaction in real estate. These practices include securitization of real-
estate-based credit, which includes both pooling of multiple loans and the reslicing of such
agglomerated debts into different tranches of bonds, and their consequent trade in stock-
exchange markets (Basel Committee, 2014). Modern credit instruments may also involve
portfolio financing, by which multiple real-estate properties collectively serve as security for
large-scale financing schemes. Portfolio financing is currently more prevalent for movable goods
and intangible assets, especially in the context of receivables financing, by which a financial
institution that extends credit to a business corporation acquires a proprietary interest in the
monetary claims (receivables) that the corporation has vis-à-vis its own debtors (Lehavi, 2019).
In fact, the ability to increase the usage of portfolio financing for real estate may hinge to a
large extent on improving the ability to consolidate information and to link proprietary rights -
and particularly security interests - in non-adjacent assets in a flexible and efficient manner.
In the case of movable goods or intangible assets, the constant replacement of assets that
serve as part of the package of the collateralized assets can be generally done in a flexible way.
This is so because the financier and/or debtor do not need to register a distinct security interest in
each specific movable or intangible asset, but can generally rely on a “floating lien” and related
legal instruments to provide general priority to the financier over other, non-secured creditors.
The floating lien is thus premised on placing a “charge on assets both present and future,” with
such assets “expected to change in the normal course of business,” thus allowing the corporation
to sell such assets - including its commercial inventory - to buyers in the ordinary course of
business, while subjecting new/future assets to the floating charge, and so forth (Sheehan, 2017).
Differently, under the current dominant approach across various legal systems, placing a
security interest over a tract of land or a standalone unit in a subdivision (such as a condominium
unit) requires the registration of a specific security interest on each tract/unit. Accordingly, any
change in the security interest or its termination requires a specific process of registration. When
security interests are placed on various tracts/units for the purpose of portfolio financing, the
different tracts/units are neither visually nor legally interrelated. Current land registries do not
agglomerate the different locations of the charged assets in a single map, registration deed, or
other instrument. Unlike the floating lien, a legal action taken in regard to one tract/unit does not
have direct effect on other assets that are allegedly under the same portfolio financing scheme.
This means that bundling, slicing, or otherwise updating such a scheme requires a relatively
cumbersome analogical process, and that the overall picture of the composition and status of the
securitized assets is not readily and digitally accessible to right-holders and other stakeholders.
Enabling portfolio financing for real estate thus requires, first, the employment of digital
technology that would identify in real time the various assets placed under a security interest -
thus pooling visual and textual information on such multiple, non-adjacent properties. In so
doing, this technology can rely, at least to some extent, on existing platforms related to security
interests, such as information made available for mortgages under the US Home Mortgage
Disclosure Act (HMDA) of 1975, which grants access to much of the raw data - modified to
protect applicant and borrower privacy - and accordingly enables cross-asset visual and textual
analysis (Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, 2019). Thus, in 2016, almost 7,000 institutions
released over 16 million records, making HMDA an invaluable administrative dataset on housing
and homeownership for policymakers, regulators, and researchers, and this data is increasingly
used for digital, publicly available cross-asset analysis, such as interactive boom and bust maps
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
(Urban Institute, 2019). Presenting such pooled information on non-adjacent assets could prove
essential for land use and land markets in many other contexts. One could think, for example –
especially considering the gloomy history of the 2007 subprime crisis - about requiring issuers of
real-estate-based securitized bonds to make available to investors real-time cross-asset visual and
textual data. This would allow investors to better understand the tranches of securitized loans,
including local and regional risks of default, foreclosure, and realization of real-estate assets. The
degree of diversification of the bond portfolio could be better understood by digital technology.
In addition to employing digital technology to link together non-adjacent assets through the
provision and dissemination of cross-asset information, portfolio financing or real-estate-backed
security investments could be further facilitated by legal innovation. One could think about a
new type of security interest in land, located somewhere between the traditional fixed mortgage
and the floating lien (for movables and intangible assets), which would allow for a swift
replacement of real-estate assets that are used as a collective collateral by a certain borrower.
To facilitate a streamlined legal process of replacing charged assets, parties holding a security
interest, other creditors, and additional stakeholders would have access to a digital platform,
which presents at any given time the current assets placed under security interests and the overall
value of the security vis-à-vis the debt - based also on third-party evaluations of the land in
question, such as those done for purposes of property taxation. To accommodate potential
conflicts in the transition of security interests across different real-estate assets, such a new type
of charge should set rules on the date that would apply as the starting date of the charge on a
replacement asset (such as the filing date of the charge on the preceding land) and any other rules
that would establish the priority of such a replacement charge vis-à-vis other rights. While the
details of such a legal reform should be tailored more specifically to meet the changing needs of
real-estate finance, there is no doubt that such legal innovation would prove effective only if it
relies on interactive digital visualization and registration platforms that link non-adjacent lands.
As the previous parts have shown, digital technology and other innovations can provide better
information to all parties about the spatial features of tracts of land. A corresponding reform in
zoning regulation and the composition of property rights can potentially give them more
flexibility in exploiting physical space. That said, the potential for coming up with new or more
sophisticated forms of multi-layer property rights or the pooling of non-adjacent assets does not
in itself create a mechanism for resolving potential frictions and deadlocks among multiple
holders of property rights and other legal interests. In fact, any such type of digital or legal
innovation intended to facilitate more intense land use or more sophisticated land markets may
also generate new types of collective action problems.
Such coordination challenges can implicate the ‘tragic’ dynamics of commons (Hardin, 1968),
in which multiple stakeholders that simultaneously occupy and use the same physical space
might tend to over-exploit it and under-invest in it. Correspondingly, the allocation of a certain
physical space among multiple parties can implicate the mirror-image problem of anticommons
(Heller, 1998; Contreras, 2018), under which over-fragmentation of private property rights in
legally separate but practically interdependent spaces can lead to inefficient results or outright
deadlocks, by preventing coordination or integrative use of such assets. These collective action
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
problems can result from either strategic behavior, such as holdouts or free riding, information
asymmetries, or genuine heterogeneity among stakeholders about their preferences and priorities.
Examples for collective action problems resulting from multi-layered, multi-party uses of
lands abound. One such instance, prevalent in the United States, concerns conflicts among
landowners and utility companies, when the latter are granted the power of eminent domain to
create involuntary easements in their favor for the construction and the laying-out of power lines,
pipelines, communication lines, and other utilities in and across privately owned lands. Unlike
cases of eminent domain in which the fee simple estate (ownership) is condemned, such that the
utility company becomes the owner of the entire land, the creation of an involuntary easement
results in the division of property rights and use of space. Also, unlike the case of a voluntary
easement, where parties not only negotiate the initial allocation of rights, but also address future
contingencies to alleviate frictions resulting from the existence of simultaneous rights, the parties
in the case of such involuntary easements find themselves entangled in long-term governance
problems with basically no tools to address them efficiently and fairly (Morriss et al., 2014).
In particular, despite the fact that the creation of multi-layered, multi-party property rights
embedded in such infrastructure projects require repeated interactions on a variety of issues,
there is no institutional arrangement that accompanies such projects and practically no default
legal rules against which parties would be able to act collaboratively over time. This is a type of
problem that no digital technology can solve. As a pure governance problem, it requires a legal
solution that sets up a mechanism for long-term institutional governance of such properties.
What is therefore required to facilitate new forms of land uses and land markets, which are
otherwise made possible by digital technology and other innovations, is a systematic legal reform
that establishes dynamic decision-making frameworks tailored to accommodate such
innovations. Just as condominiums and other forms of residential strata title have been able to
develop and create real innovation in land use and land markets, so do other new forms of multi-
layered, multi-party interests in land depend on the ability of property owners and other
stakeholders to engage in long-term institutional governance. To ensure coordination, order, and
a reasonable balance between predictability and flexibility in the on-going governance of such
new types of land uses and markets, such institutions should be supported by default legal rules
that establish the various issues that are relevant for such types of real-estate schemes. Such rules
should address issues such as voting rights, required majorities for decisions, mechanisms for
assessment of fees, maintenance and improvement, or rights-of-way and other easements.
To illustrate how the future of land use and land markets can and should be complemented by
setting up rules and institutions for long-term collective governance, tailored to the specific
intricacies of such innovations, consider again ‘stratum’ or ‘volumetric’ subdivisions, which seek
to offer an institutional solution to multi-owned, multi-layered properties beyond residential
buildings, as mentioned in Part IV above. In order to deal with various issues relating to the
vertical and lateral interdependencies between the different stratum lots, such as establishing
easements intended to grant separate stratum owners access to shared property that is partly or
entirely located in another stratum owner’s lot or parcel, or dealing with maintenance costs, lot
owners must register Building Management Statements (BMS) and Strata Management
Statements (SMS) that address such issues. Beyond the initial rule-setting for the allocation of
rights and responsibilities to private and common spaces, the BMS must establish a Building
Management Committee, which includes all stratum lot or parcel owners, although owners may
be excluded from the Building Management Committee with their consent (Sherry, 2017). The
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
Committee is intended to deal with the ongoing governance of the ‘stratum’ subdivision,
considering also the unique features of each type of stakeholder in such mixed-use projects.
While still underdeveloped legislatively and regulatory, and not often analyzed by Australian
courts, stratum subdivisions have a significant potential in furthering new types of developments.
As such, they can also serve as a source of inspiration for other kinds of multi-layered, multi-use
developments, including those involving large surface or subsurface infrastructure utilities. The
same can also hold true for the governance of portfolio financing or other proprietary interests
that implicate non-adjacent assets, as discussed in Part V above. At its core, every type of
intensive, interconnected land-use or land-market novelty calls for such collective governance.
VII. Conclusion
Digital technology has enormous - but not unlimited - potential to promote efficient land use
and land markets. Thus, three-dimensional surveying, visualization, registration, and planning
are increasingly being introduced around the world, fostering legal innovation in the form of
“legal volumes” and rights thereto, and opportunities for more intensive, sophisticated land uses.
In addition, the interactive pooling of non-adjacent real-estate assets through digital technology
may push forward current market practices, such as portfolio financing, and in turn encourage
legal innovation in the form of new types of property rights, providing a more flexible approach
to security interests as a means to broaden financing opportunities and expand land markets.
That said, while digital technology and other innovations open up new opportunities, and
allow for broad dissemination of data in real time, they cannot solve in themselves what are
largely interpersonal challenges of governance and decision-making. Collective action problems
resulting from strategic behavior or genuine heterogeneity require dynamic institutions of
governance and a system of substantive and procedural rules that supports collective action.
On a final note, the analysis in this chapter might echo the voluminous discussion about
blockchain as an alternative, decentralized, and verified recording system for transfers of asset
ownership - one that allows for validating and registering various transactions by bypassing
traditional centralized channels such as banks on the one hand, while alleviating problems of
conflicting transactions or unauthorized transfers of rights on the other (Koch & Pieters, 2017).
However, to truly replace current systems of market transfers and registration of property rights
in the context of land, the blockchain technology must be supported by legal innovation. Thus,
blockchain-based transactions should be broadened in scope to include other types of proprietary
rights, such as security interests and easements, alongside the right of ownership. Accordingly,
blockchain ledgers and protocols should also be governed by priority rules and governance
bodies that settle potential conflicts between different types of property rights in the same asset.
It is a challenge that can be met, but it cannot rely merely on digital technology. It requires legal
innovation and mechanisms for multi-party governance institutions relying on human judgment.
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
Bibliography
Atazadeh B. et al. (2017). Building information modelling for high-rise land administration.
Transactions in GIS, 21(1), 91.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2014). Basel III document: revisions to the
securitisation framework. Available at: https://www.bis.org/bcbs/publ/d303.htm.
Chadwick, H. (2018). Community land trust solutions to local housing issues. AMPS Conference
10: Cities, Communities and Homes: Is the Urban Future Livable? P164. University of Derby.
Chen, L., Kielsgard, M.D. (2014). Evolving property rights in China: patterns and dynamics in
condominium governance. Chinese Journal of Comparative Law, 2(1), 21.
Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (2019). Mortgage data (HDMA). Available at:
https://www.consumerfinance.gov/data-research/hmda/.
Contreras, J.L. (2018). The anticommons at 20: concerns for research continue. Science, 361, 335.
Davis, J.E. (Ed.) (2010). The community land trust reader. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of
Land Policy.
Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. American Economic Review Papers &
Proceedings, 57, 347.
Drobež, P. et al. (2017). Transition from 2D to 3D real property cadaster: the case of the
Slovenian cadaster. Computers, Environment and Urban Systems, 62, 125.
Ellickson, R.C. et al. (2013). Land use controls: cases and materials. Fourth edition. New York:
Wolters Kluwer.
Guardian (2019). Super-tall, super-skinny, super-expensive: the ‘pencil towers’ of New York’s
super rich. Feb. 5, 2019.
Fennell, L.A. (2019). Slices and lumps: division and aggregation in law and life. Chicago &
London: The University of Chicago Press.
Hamid, Q. et al. (2016). Arc GIS and 3D visualization of land records: a case study of urban
areas in Punjab. National Academy of Sciences Letters (India), 39(4), 277.
Heller, M.A. (1998). The tragedy of the anticommons: property in the transition from Marx to
markets. Harvard Law Review, 111, 621.
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
Kim S., Hoe J. (2019). Registration of 3D underground parcel in Korean cadastral system. Cities,
89, 105.
Klass, A.B. (2008). The frontier of eminent domain. University of Colorado Law Review, 79,
651.
Koch, C. & Pieters, G.C. (2017). Blockchain technology disrupting records systems. Financial
Insights, (Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas), 6(2), 1. Available at
www.dallasfed.org/outreach/insights/fi1702.
Kostrub, D.B. & Christenson II, R.S. Canons of construction for the interpretation of mineral
conveyances, severances, exceptions, and reservations in producing states. North Dakota Law
Review, 88, 649.
Lehavi, A. (2015). Law, collective action, and culture: condominium governance in comparative
perspective. Asia Pacific Law Review, 23(2), 5.
Lehavi, A. (2019). Property law in a globalizing world. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
Press.
Lehavi, A. (2013). The construction of property: norms, institutions, challenges. Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Lehavi, A. (2016). The culture of private law. Real Estate Law Journal, 45(1), 35.
Lemmen, C., van Oosterom, P., Bennett, R. (2015). The land administration domain model. Land
Use Policy, 49, 535.
McKenzie, E. (1994). Privatopia: homeowner association and the rise of the residential private
government. New Haven & London: Yale University Press.
Merill, T.W., Smith H.E. (2001). Optimal standardization in the law of property: the numerus
clausus principle. Yale Law Journal, 110, 1.
Miller, S. (2013). Community land trusts: why now is the time to integrate this housing activists’
tool into local government affordable housing policies. Zoning and Planning Law Report, 36(9),
1.
Morriss, A.P., Brandys, R. & Barron M.M. (2014). Involuntary cotenants: eminent domain and
energy and communications infrastructure growth. LSU Journal of Energy Law & Resources, 3,
29.
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
Paasch, J.M. et al. (2016). Building a modern cadastre: legal issues in describing real property in
3D. GEODETSKI VESTNIK, 60, 256.
Parisi, F. (2002). Entropy in Property. American Journal of Comparative Law, 50, 595.
Rabenhorst, C.S., Ignatova S.I. (2009). Condominium housing and mortgage lending in
emerging markets--constraints and opportunities. Urban Institute Center on International
Development and Governance. Available at: www.urban.org/publications/411921.html.
Righetti, T. (2016). The private pore space: condemnation got subsurface ways of necessity.
Wyoming Law Review, 16, 77.
Rule, T.A. (2011). Airspace in a green economy. UCLA Law Review, 59, 270.
Schill, M.H., Voicu, I., Miller, J. (2007). The condominium versus cooperative puzzle: an
empirical analysis of housing in New York City. Journal of Legal Studies, 36, 277.
Sheehan, D. (2017). The principles of personal property law. Oxford: Hart Publishing.
Sherry. C. (2017). Strata title property rights: private governance of multi-owned properties.
London and New York: Routledge.
Smith, H.E. (2015). The persistence of system in property law. University of Pennsylvania law
Review, 163, 2055.
Stöcker, O. (2012). The Eurohypothec. In. B. Akkermans, A.F. Salomons, and J.H.M. van Erp
(Eds.), The Future of European Property Law (pp. 65-77). Munich: Sellier.
Stoter, J. et al. (2017). Registration of multi-level property rights in 3D in The Netherlands: two
cases and next steps in further implementation. International Journal of Geo-Information, 6, 158.
Urban Institute (2019). Home mortgage disclosure act data. Available at:
https://www.urban.org/policy-centers/housing-finance-policy-center/projects/home-mortgage-
disclosure-act-data.
Van der Merwe, C.G. (2015). Introduction and content. In C.G. van der Merwe (Ed.), European
Condominium Law (pp. 1-24). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Van Erp. S. & Akkermans, B. (2012). Cases, materials and text on property law. Oxford &
Portland, OR: Hart Publishing.
Vučić, N. et al. (2017). Overview of the Croatian land administration system and the possibilities
for its upgrade to 3D by existing data. International Journal of Geo-Information, 6, 223.
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)
Yu C., et al. (2017). LADM-based modeling of the unified registration of immovable property in
China. Land Use Policy, 64, 292.
Legislation:
California Civil Code (as amended, 2014). West’s Annotated California Civil Code, § 4125.
Cases:
Pinnacle Museum Tower Association v. Pinnacle Market Development, 145 Cal.Rptr.3d 514
(2012).
Villa De Las Palmas Homeowners Association v. Terifaj, 90 P.3d 1223 (Cal. 2004).
Amnon Lehavi, The Future of Property Rights: Digital Technology in the Real World (2020)