Stock Prices and Fundamentals: January 2000
Stock Prices and Fundamentals: January 2000
Stock Prices and Fundamentals: January 2000
net/publication/5033933
CITATIONS READS
180 8,647
2 authors, including:
Deborah J. Lucas
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
76 PUBLICATIONS 6,490 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
All content following this page was uploaded by Deborah J. Lucas on 21 July 2014.
1. Introduction
While stock returns in the United States this past century have exceeded
Treasury returns by an average of about 6% annually, in the last few years
they have done so by more than 12% annually. Commentators have sug-
gested a variety of explanations for the dramatic stock-market run-up that
accompanied these high returns. The baby boom is entering peak savings
years, productivity has escalated worldwide due to technological im-
provements and political change, and stock-market participation rates are
on the rise. The growth of mutual funds has lowered transaction costs and
made diversification feasible. Public awareness of the benefits of stock-
market investing is high. On the other hand, irrational exuberance could
be fueling the price rise, with inexperienced investors expecting double-
digit returns to continue indefinitely or at least long enough to reap a
substantial gain.
Whether the price rise is due primarily to fundamentals or whether it
is the result of a bubble is important to policymakers concerned with
avoiding the real disruption a sharp stock-market decline could precipi-
tate. It is also important to the academic debate over the determinants of
stock valuations. Because this paper is about the relations between stock
prices and fundamentals, we emphasize three broad categories of expla-
nations for the recent price rise: changes in corporate earnings growth,
changes in consumer preferences, and changes in stock-market participa-
tion patterns. The goal in qualifying the importance of fundamental
effects is to better understand whether a combination of fundamentals
and statistical fluctuation can plausibly explain the observed magni-
tudes, or whether a bubble is the likely cause of the price rise.
The paper has benefited from the comments of John Campbell, Annette Vissing-
J0rgensen, and participants of the 1999 NBER Macroeconomics Annual Conference. We
thank the National Science Foundation for financial support.
214 *HEATON& LUCAS
Facts
2. Empirical
Historically stocks have returned a substantial premium over bonds. Over
the period 1871 to 1998, the average annual (log) real return on a broad-
based index of U.S. stocks was 7.3%, compared to an average (log) real
return on bonds of about 3%.1The return on stocks over the last few years
has exceeded this historical average. For example, since 1991, the average
real return on stocks was 17% per year. This has led many observers to
question whether expected returns looking forward are lower than they
have been in the past.
A related issue is the composition of recent returns, which have been
mostly the result of capital gains rather than increased dividend pay-
ments. To illustrate this, Figure 1 plots the ratios of prices to dividends
and prices to earnings for aggregate U.S. stocks. (For the years since
1926 this is based on the S&P 500 index.) Notice that the price-dividend
ratio for this index has increased to an unprecedented level since about
1995. The increase in this ratio is significant because in a discounted-
cash-flow model of stock valuation, it indicates a reduction in the ex-
pected rate of return or an increase in the dividend growth rate (see
Section 3). Because dividends are discretionary and only one of the ways
in which corporations distribute cash to shareholders, it may be more
informative to look at price-earnings ratios. Figure 1 also shows the ratio
of prices to earnings. This ratio is also at a relatively high level, but the
change has not been as dramatic as for dividends.
A notable aspect of the rise in the price-dividend ratio is that there is
substantial evidence that a large value of the price-dividend ratio pre-
dicts lower stock returns in the future. For example, Table 1 reports the
results of regressing annual (log) stock returns on a constant and the log
of the price-dividend ratio lagged one year for the period 1887 to 1998.
Notice that the coefficient on the dividend-price ratio is negative. This is
consistent with a large body of evidence (e.g., Campbell and Shiller,
1988; Hodrick, 1992; Lamont, 1998). At the current high level of the
1. Source: Robert Shiller's data, available at http://www.econ.yale.edu/shiller/chapt26.html.
216 *HEATON& LUCAS
2000
Table 1 REGRESSION
OF ONE-
YEARSTOCKRETURNS
ON LAGGEDP/D OVER
THEPERIOD1871TO 1998
a 0.28 0.02
/3 -0.07 0.05
logRS+1 = a + ,3log(Pt/D,) + Et.
aCorrectedfor conditional heteroskedasticity
and autocorrelation using the procedure of
Newey and West (1987)and two years of lags.
*217
StockPricesandFundamentals
3. PossibleExplanations
In this section, we discuss some of the potential explanations that have
been offered for the stock price run-up, and begin to evaluate their likely
quantitative importance in the context of a simple discounted-cash-flow
model. We also present some evidence on changes in market participa-
tion patterns that may be influencing required returns.
3.1. GORDONGROWTHMODEL
The Gordon growth model is perhaps the simplest fundamentals-based
approach to predicting stock prices.2 In this model, stock prices are
based on the discounted present value of future expected dividend pay-
ments. It is assumed that dividends grow, on average, at a constant rate,
g, and investors discount dividends at a constant rate, r. Dividends,
earnings, and growth are connected by two equations: DIV = (1 - p)E
and g = p(ROE), where DIV is dividends, E is earnings, p is the propor-
tion of earnings reinvested, and ROE is the marginal physical product of
capital. If the marginal physical product of capital is constant, and if the
fraction of reinvested earnings is constant, then, all else equal, dividend
growth is constant. Then the price-dividend ratio equals 1/(r - g).
The model highlights two of the fundamental reasons that the price-
dividend ratio can change. The first is due to changes in dividend
growth, reflected in the choice of g. The second is due to changes in
preferences that affect the subjective rate of time preference or the pre-
mium demanded for risk, reflected in the choice of r.
Expectations of g may be higher than in the past for several reasons. A
major determinant of dividend growth is the availability of profitable
investment projects. The potential for sustained economic growth in
excess of historical precedent has been attributed to the opening and
Whichof the statementson this page comesclosest to the amount offinancial risk
that you (and your husband/wife) are willing to take when you save or make
investments? If more than one box checked,code smallest category #.
3. See Blanchard (1993) for an analysis of historical trends in the equity premium and risk-
free rate.
*219
StockPricesandFundamentals
Table 2 reports the average response by age and survey year. The implied
population standard deviation across responses is reported in parenthe-
ses. Since the population represented by the survey totals approximately
90 million households, the standard errors of the estimates of the means
are quite small. Consistent with the idea that risk tolerance has in-
creased, the average reported aversion to risk has decreased slightly for
each age category over time. Older households own significantly more
stock than younger households, and reported risk aversion increases
with age in each survey year. When a similar tabulation (not reported
here) is done conditional on households that own at least $500 in stocks,
the same patterns emerge with respect to age and time. The average
reported level of risk tolerance, however, is higher when we condition on
stockholders. For instance, in 1995 the average risk attitude for stockhold-
ers over age 65 was 3.17, as compared to 3.58 for all households over 65.
This suggests that those who already own stocks are more risk-tolerant
as a group than nonparticipants. Hence, the entry of new stockholders
may slightly decrease the average level of risk tolerance. One would
expect this to mitigate the effect of wider participation in reducing the
equity premium.
There are objective reasons why the underlying subjective rate of time
preference also may be changing. Increases in life expectancy beyond
retirement would likely increase the incentive to save and thereby re-
duce required returns. Mortality, for example, has declined at an average
annual rate of 3.3% over the period 1900 to 1988 (Social Security Adminis-
tration). Past improvements in health and life expectancy might under-
state expected improvements in these factors that are premised on con-
tinued medical progress.4 As with the other explanations considered for
the stock price run-up, however, it is hard to point to events that would
4. In fact, there is a lively debate in the demographic literature on these questions, with
some authors claiming that a life expectancy at birth of 100 years will be realized early in
the next century.
220 *HEATON& LUCAS
5. While stock prices depend on the long-run behavior of dividends, properly measured,
in the short run dividends can vary due to temporary changes in payout policy (for
instance, in response to changes in the tax law). Therefore, it is common to focus on the
price-earnings ratio, adjusted for reinvestment rates, to approximate long-run price-
dividend ratios.
*221
StockPricesandFundamentals
Table 3 GROWTHRATESIMPLIEDBYTHEGORDONGROWTHMODEL
Ten-Yearg to
Long-Rung to Long-Rung to Match1998P/E
rs MatchHistoricalP/E Match1998P/E with2%Tail
0.05 0.014 0.029 0.064
0.07 0.034 0.049 0.134
0.09 0.054 0.069 0.189
0.11 0.074 0.089 0.236
0.13 0.094 0.109 0.280
0.15 0.114 0.129 0.320
3.2 STOCK-MARKET
PARTICIPATION
PATTERNS
It is well documented that a large fraction of the U.S. population holds
little or no stocks (Bertaut and Haliassos, 1995; Blume and Zeldes, 1993)
222 *HEATON& LUCAS
.g
5)
0
U-
40 50 60 100
Income Percentile
I 1111
vv
I
I 1 i i 1 I i I 'Jf
90
80
70
e)
0
0
60
c
50
"o
0
40
LL
30
I
20
10
J KS)'
~ ' ]I'-,I I
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Wealth Percentile
*225
StockPricesandFundamentals
Ideally, one would like to measure the net investment in the stock
market in recent years on behalf of households. If net inflows were large,
one could perhaps conclude that the demand for stocks had significantly
increased. The fact that aggregate savings rates are low is indirect evi-
dence that these net inflows cannot be large. Still, there could be substitu-
tion out of money and bonds into stocks, increasing the net flow into
stocks. According to the flow-of-funds accounts, U.S. Treasury securities
are the only category of fixed-income investment that had a large net
outflow from the household sector in recent years. Calculating flows into
stocks directly is tricky because there have been large changes in the
institutional structure of the investment industry. Table 5, using data
from the Investment Company Institute, shows net purchases of stocks,
purchases made through mutual funds, and purchases made outside
mutual funds, by households, from 1995 to 1997. While purchases made
through mutual funds increased significantly over the period, net pur-
chases of equities by households were actually negative in each year.
This is because households were net sellers of equities to institutions.
Changes in foreign participation in the U.S. market may also affect
expected returns. Assuming that foreign participants are similar to U.S.
stockholders in their attitude towards risk and their ex ante risk expo-
sure, an increase in foreign participation should lower expected returns
by increasing opportunities for diversification. Net foreign purchases of
stock have spiked sharply in recent years (see Figure 4), and these in-
flows, over the period January 1988 to February 1999, have a correlation
of 0.13 with monthly returns on the S&P 500. The average monthly net
inflow between January 1996 and February 1999 is $3.8 billion, compared
to only $349 million from the period January 1988 to December 1995.
Although the inflows have increased significantly, they still represent a
small fraction of total market transactions, which totaled approximately
$479 billion per month in 1997 on the New York Stock Exchange alone.7
7. Data on foreign purchasesand sales of U.S. stocks are from the U.S. Departmentof the
Treasury'stable "TICCapital Movements, U.S. Transactionswith Foreignersin Long
TermSecurities."S&P 500 monthly returns data are from RobertShiller.Totaltrading
volume is from the NYSE 1997 Fact Book.
226 - HEATON& LUCAS
tc
a:
a
c
CO
a)
Date
4. An Overlapping-Generations
Model
In this section, we ask whether changing stock-market participation pat-
terns and increased diversification can have a quantitatively important
effect on stock prices in an equilibrium model. We calibrate an overlap-
ping-generations (OLG) model in which agents face both aggregate and
idiosyncratic income risk, and a variable subset of agents has limited
access to financial markets.
The effects of limited participation in financial markets has been con-
sidered by a number of authors, including Basak and Cuoco (1998),
Saito (1995), and Vissing-Jorgensen (1997). In these papers, aggregate
consumption is completely traded in financial markets in the form of
dividends. Only a limited number of agents can trade claims on this
dividend flow directly. The other agents participate in financial markets
only by trading claims to risk-free bonds. The result is incomplete
sharing of aggregate risk, with stockholders often taking leveraged posi-
*227
StockPricesandFundamentals
4.1 STRUCTURE
OF THEMODEL
At each time period, t, a generation of J "young" agents are born and live
for two periods.8 Let C(j,t) be the consumption of agent j when young,
8. Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (1998) consider an OLG model in which the agents face
nontradable idiosyncratic risk and live for a large number of periods. We limit ourselves
to a smaller number of periods to make numerical solution of the model easier.
228 *HEATON& LUCAS
where 3j> 0 and aj > 0. Here ;(t) is the information available at time t and
is assumed to be common across agents. As discussed by Epstein and Zin
(1989), the parameter aj is the coefficient of relative risk aversion. The
elasticity of intertemporal substitution equals one. In the experiments
considered below, changes in participation affect the equilibrium volatil-
ity of individual consumption in the second period. In general, this affects
both the level of interest rates and the equity premium. By distinguishing
between risk aversion and the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, the
effect of the income process on the equity premium is to some extent
separated from its effect on the risk-free rate.
Each agent j(j = 1,2, . . ., J) is endowed with random nonmarketed
income Y(j,t) at time t and random nonmarketed income Y?(j,t + 1)
when old at time t + 1. The details of the individual income processes
are described below. The agents trade in financial markets in an attempt
to smooth consumption over time. There are two securities that can be
traded: a stock and a risk-free bond. At time t the stock represents a
claim to future dividends {D(t + r): r = 1,2, . . . }. The total supply of
stock is normalized to one. The bond is assumed to be in zero net supply.
Each agent is exposed to nonmarketed income risk that has both an
aggregate component and an idiosyncratic component. Aggregate non-
marketed income at time t is denoted by Ya(t),where
J J
ya(t) = Y(j,t) + E Y(j,t). (2)
j=l j=1
that depends on the agent's access to financial markets. Let PS(t)be the
price of the stock at time t, and Pb(t) be the price of a bond that pays one
unit of consumption at time t + 1 for sure. If agent j has access to both
financial markets, then the agent's flow wealth constraints are
where S(j,t) gives the stockholdings of agent j, and B(j,t) gives the
bondholdings of agent j. A subset of the agents is assumed to have only
limited access to financial markets and can trade only in bonds. In this
case the constraints (3) are replaced by
S*(j,t) = 1, (5a)
j=l
B*(j,t) = 0, (5b)
j=l
where {S*(j,t),B*(j,t)} maximizes (1) subject to (3) if the agent can trade in
both markets, or subject to (4) if the agent can trade only in the bond
market.
We assume that nonmarketed income {Ya(t): t = 0,1, . . . } and divi-
dend income grow over time in such a way that the growth rate of
aggregate income is a stationary process. Consistent with this, we as-
sume that at time t we have Y(j,t) = y(j,t)Ya(t) and D(t) = d(t)Ya(t),where
y(j,t) denotes the share of individual j's income in aggregate income,
and d(t) the dividend relative to aggregate nonmarketed income. Simi-
larly we assume that Y?(j,t) = y?(j,t)Ya(t).This implies that one can look
for an equilibrium in which the stock price also scales with aggregate
income, so that PS(t) = ps(t)Ya(t).Finally, we assume that the face value of
a bond purchased at time t is given by Ya(t), so that B(j,t) = b(j,t)Y'(t),
where b(j,t) gives the quantity of these "rescaled" bonds purchased by
agent j.
230 *HEATON& LUCAS
4.2 CALIBRATION
In this subsection, we calibrate the model in order to revisit quantita-
tively some of the questions discussed in Section 3. How much do as-
sumed changes in participation rates affect the predicted equity pre-
mium and expected returns (and hence prices)? How does the degree of
portfolio diversification affect required returns? Can small changes in
preference parameters, reflecting changes in patience or risk aversion,
result in large changes in required returns? How important is hetero-
geneity in income risk? To answer these questions, the model is solved
numerically using standard techniques. Although we assume consider-
able heterogeneity in the cross section, the fact that agents only live for
two periods makes the problem numerically tractable.9
We begin by describing the parameterization of the income processes
and preferences. Parameters are chosen to reflect limited stock-market
participation, and to try to match gross features of the data with respect
to stock returns, the risk-free rate, and the driving processes for non-
marketed income and dividends.
As in most exercises of this type, the equity-premium puzzle remains
a serious problem. For income and dividend processes and participation
rates based on historical data, the model predicts an unrealistically small
equity premium. We have increased the assumed volatility of aggregate
income to increase the predicted premium, but want to emphasize that
this may not be a neutral adjustment with respect to the other quantities
of interest.10
where
J J
E(j,t) = 1 and f(k,t) =1. (8)
j=1 k=l
Under this normalization, r(t) gives the share of old individuals' non-
marketed income in total nonmarketed income. The analysis is sensitive
to this parameter because the amount of nonmarketed income influ-
ences agents' attitude towards the risk of investment income. For the
basic analyis we assume that r1= 0.2 for all t, reflecting the observation
that noninvestment wealth is relatively small for retirees. In the sensitiv-
ity analysis, this parameter is varied to a maximum of 0.3.
The process for E(j,t) and E?(k,t)captures idiosyncratic income risk
across agents. We know from earlier work (e.g., Constantinides and
Duffie, 1996) that asset returns are potentially sensitive to the persis-
tence of idiosyncratic income shocks and to the correlation and condi-
tional covariance of idiosyncratic and aggregate shocks. We assume a
process for individual income risk based in part on the estimations re-
11. In constructing the total dividend series, we always normalize the level of dividends so
that they average 15% of GDP.
232 - HEATON& LUCAS
ported in Deaton (1992) and adjusted for the assumed 25-year period
length. Deaton reports a standard deviation of shocks for an MA(1)
specification of individual income growth of 15%, and an MA coefficient
of -0.4. Based on this, the idiosyncratic income shocks for both the
young and the old are assumed to have a standard deviation of 45% over
each 25-year period. The shock when young is assumed to be completely
persistent, so that
gate income and dividend risk alone are not sufficient to generate a
sizable equity premium. This is true even under the assumption of ex-
tremely limited participation, inflated aggregate risk, and nonmarketed
income risk. Still, the premium predicted here is higher than in Mehra
and Prescott (1985) by about 1%. Experiments not reported here indicate
that this difference is due primarily to the assumption that aggregate risk
is higher than that observed in the data, rather than to limited participa-
tion or exposure to idiosyncratic income risk.
In the experiments that follow, we examine other stochastic steady
states based on different degrees of diversification, risk aversion, etc.
Although looking across steady states does not allow one to watch re-
turns gradually changing over time as parameters gradually change, it
does provide an upper bound on the size of these effects. Thus, one can
give a temporal interpretation to some of the experiments. For instance,
we will compare the stylized historical past, with low diversification and
low participation rates, to the stylized present, with greater diversifica-
tion, more complete participation, and greater patience.
No.of
No. of StandardDeviation(%)
Stocks Monthly Annual
1 16.0 55.4
2 11.7 40.4
3 9.8 33.9
4 8.7 30.2
5 8.0 27.7
10 6.3 21.9
20 5.3 18.3
100 4.3 14.9
500 4.1 14.1
tions reported in the table assume equal value weights on each stock.
Monthly returns are annualized under the assumption that they are
independent. These calculations show that holding a one-stock portfolio
results in an annual standard deviation of 55%, while increasing hold-
ings to five stocks decreases the standard deviation to 28%, and holding
500 stocks brings it down to 14%.
The above statistics on portfolio returns do not translate directly into
parameter values, since the inputs into the model are income and divi-
dend processes, whereas returns are endogenous. One assumption
about dividends that produces returns consistent with those observed in
CRSP data is that d(t) is variable over time, taking on the values 0.11 and
0.25 with equal probability. This level of variation essentially brackets the
variation in dividends' share in total income, based on the S&P 500
dividend flow and U.S. gross domestic product since 1947. We call this
the case of high dividend volatility. It implies variation that is approxi-
mately consistent with a three-stock portfolio under the parametriza-
tions we focus on.
Second, we consider a situation referred to as correlatedhigh dividend
volatility. Here the aggregate dividend is assumed to be correlated with
nonmarketed income, taking on the value 0.11 in the low-nonmarketed-
income state and 0.25 in the high-nonmarketed-income state. These first
two cases bracket two views of the relation between dividend growth
and income growth. The first is that there is very little correlation be-
tween income growth and dividend growth on an annual basis. The
second is that over longet time periods, such as the 25-year periods
StockPricesandFundamentals
?235
AND
Table8 AVERAGERETURNSAS A FUNCTIONOF PARTICIPATION
THEDIVIDENDPROCESS
Returns
Returns(%)
of
Percentage
Stockholders E(rb) E(rs) E(rs - rb)
A. LowDividendVolatility
100 4.42 5.47 1.05
50 4.33 5.52 1.19
B. HighDividendVolatility
100 3.81 5.57 1.76
50 3.51 5.67 2.16
HighDividendVolatility
C. Correlated
100 3.38 5.87 2.49
50 3.36 5.95 2.59
D. SkewedDividends
100 1.54 6.17 4.63
50 0.47 6.93 6.46
this risk to new participants with no initial exposure to market risk. For
correlated high dividend volatility, however, changes in participation
have a smaller effect on the equity premium than for uncorrelated high
dividend volatility. This is because the new entrants are less willing to
bear stock-market risk when it is correlated with their nonmarketed risk.
Finally, the much more dramatic results in the skewed-dividend case
are shown in panel D. The small risk of a catastrophic outcome reduces
the risk-free rate to 0.47% and increases the equity premium to 6.46%
with 50% participation. With 100% participation, the risk-free rate equals
1.54% and the equity premium is 4.63%. This assumption therefore
allows one to match the historical equity premium. It also suggests that
in this region of parameter space the premium is more sensitive to
changes in participation rates. This points to changes in diversification
as a potentially large factor in explaining changes in expected returns.
is endogenous. For simplicity, and to put an upper bound on this effect, we assume
that participation is completely exogenous.
14. These parameter assumptions are consistent with the estimates reported by Heaton
and Lucas (1998).
*239
StockPricesandFundamentals
5. Conclusions
In this paper, we have looked at a number of potential fundamentals-
based explanations for the recent stock price run-up. In particular, we
focused on whether changes in market participation patterns or changes
in portfolio diversification are likely to account for a substantial fraction
of the rise in stock prices. We conclude that the changes in participation
that have occurred over this decade are unlikely to be a major part of the
explanation. This conclusion is based both on the data, which suggest
only small changes in participation for wealthy households, and the
model, which implies that participation changes have to be quite ex-
treme to substantially affect expected returns. Increased portfolio diversi-
fication, however, is likely to have had a larger effect. There is empirical
evidence that households have significantly diversified their portfolios,
selling individual stocks and buying mutual funds. An important differ-
240 * HEATON & LUCAS
REFERENCES
Allen, E, and D. Gale. (1994).Limitedmarketparticipationand volatility of asset
prices. AmericanEconomicReview84:933-955.
Bakshi, G., and Z. Chen. (1994). Baby boom, population aging, and capital
markets.Journalof Business67:165-202.
Basak, S., and D. Cuoco. (1998). An equilibrium model with restricted stock
marketparticipation.Reviewof FinancialStudies11:309-341.
Bertaut,C., and M. Haliassos. (1995).Why do so few hold stocks? TheEconomic
Journal, 105:1110-1129.
Blanchard, 0. (1993). Movements in the equity premium. Brookings Papers on
Activity2:75-138.
Economic
Blume, M., and S. Zeldes (1993). The structure of stockownership in the U.S.
Wharton.Manuscript.
Bodie, Z., R. Merton, and W. Samuelson (1992). Labor supply flexibility and
portfolio choice in a life-cycle model. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research. NBER Working Paper 6.
Brealey, R., and S. Myers (1996). Principles of CorporateFinance, 5th ed. New York:
McGraw-Hill.
Campbell, J., and J. Cochrane (1998). By force of habit: A consumption-based
explanation of aggregate stock market behavior. Journalof PoliticalEconomy
107:205-251.
Stock Prices and Fundamentals*241
Cochrane, J. (1997). Where is the market going? Uncertain facts and novel theo-
ries. FederalReserveBankof ChicagoEconomicPerspectivesXXI(6):3-37.
Campbell, J., and R. Shiller. (1988). Stock prices, earnings, and expected divi-
dends. Journalof Finance 43:661-676.
Constantinides, G., J. Donaldson, and R. Mehra. (1998). Junior can't borrow: A
new perspective on the equity premium puzzle. University of Chicago. Manu-
script.
, and D. Duffie. (1996). Asset pricing with heterogeneous consumers.
Journalof Political Economy104(2):219-240.
Davis, S., and P. Willen. (1998). Using financial assets to hedge labor income
risks: Estimating the benefits. Princeton University. Manuscript.
Deaton, A. (1992). Savings and liquidity constraints. Econometrica59:1221-1248.
Epstein, L., and S. Zin (1989). Substitution, risk aversion and the temporal
behavior of consumption and asset returns: A theoretical framework. Econo-
metrica57:937-969.
Friend, I., and M. Blume. (1975). The demand for risky assets. AmericanEconomic
Review 65:900-922.
Gentry, W. M., and R. G. Hubbard. (1998). Why do the wealthy save so much?
Columbia University. Manuscript.
Heaton, J., and D. Lucas (1998). Asset pricing and portfolio choice: The impor-
tance of entrepreneurial risk. Northwestern University. Manuscript.
Hodrick, R. (1992). Dividend yields and expected stock returns: Alternative pro-
cedures for inference and measurement. Review of Financial Studies 5:357-386.
King, M., and J. Leape (1984). Asset accumulation, information, and the life
cycle. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Work-
ing Paper 2392.
Lamont, 0. (1998). Earnings and expected returns. Journal of Finance 53:1563-
1587.
Lee, Charles M. C., and B. Swaminathan. (1999). Valuing the Dow: A bottom-up
approach. Cornell University. Manuscript.
Mankiw, N. G., and S. Zeldes (1991). The consumption of stockholders and non-
stockholders. Journalof Financial Economics29:97-112.
Mehra, R., and E. Prescott (1985). The equity premium: A puzzle. Journal of
Monetary Economics15:145-161.
Newey, W, and K. West (1987). A simple positive semi-definite heteroskedasti-
city and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix estimator. Econometrica
55:703-708.
Polkovnichenko, V. (1988). Heterogeneity and proprietary income risk: Implica-
tions for stock market participation and asset prices. Kellogg Graduate School
of Management. Manuscript.
Poterba, J. (1993). Who owns corporate stock?: A report to the New York Stock
Exchange. MIT. Manuscript.
. (1998). Population age structure and asset returns: An empirical investi-
gation. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Work-
ing Paper 6774.
, and A. Samwick. (1997). Household portfolio allocation over the life
cycle. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Work-
ing Paper 6185.
Saito, M. (1995). Limited market participation and asset pricing. Department of
Economics, University of British Columbia. Manuscript.
242 *J0RGENSEN
Comment
ANNETTE VISSING-J0RGENSEN
Universityof Chicago
1. Introduction
During the period 1995-1998 the U.S. stock market experienced four
consecutive years with real stock returns above 20%. Suppose as a rough
approximation that annual real log gross stock returns are normally dis-
tributed and independent over time. With a mean and variance of this
distribution equal to the historical values for the period 1871-1994, the
probability of observing four years of above 20% returns is 0.4%.1 The
high returns have come primarily from capital gains driving price-
dividend and price-earnings ratios to historical highs (the latest num-
bers from August 9 for the S&P 500 are P/D = 78.5 and P/E = 31.9). Thus,
even taking into account statistical fluctuation, it is becoming increas-
ingly unlikely that nothing has changed. The only period since 1871 with
as impressive returns was 1924-1928, with five years of above 20% real
stock returns. Over the three-year period following that event, real stock
returns averaged -15.4% annually.
In the present paper Heaton and Lucas ask whether the recent stock-
market boom can be explained by changes in economic fundamentals.
Three candidates are considered: changes in corporate earnings growth,
changes in consumer preferences, and changes in stock-market participa-
tion patterns. Participation is defined broadly as concerning both the
level of stock-market participation and the amount of diversification
among participants. Poor diversification is found to have large effects on
equilibrium returns in an overlapping generations exchange economy.
The main conclusion of the paper is that increased diversification by
itself can explain at least half of the increase in the adjusted P/D ratio.
This is an interesting finding, not only for interpreting the recent past
but also seen in the context of the literature on the equity premium
1. Using the data from Robert Shiller's home page, the 1871-1994 mean and standard
deviation of log(l + rt?ck'real)
are 0.067 and 0.17.
Comment 243
2. Is theIncreasein Diversification
Largeand
RecentEnough?
In the overlapping-generations model calibrated by Heaton and Lucas a
shift from a three-stock portfolio to full diversification generates a decline
in the mean real stock return of 1.41 percentage points for participation
fixed at 50% (compare cases D and A in Table 8). This is in fact more than
needed to explain current valuation ratios according to my calculations
in Section 4 below. Should we conclude from this that increased diversifi-
cation is the main reason behind the stock-market boom? From an empiri-
cal perspective it would need to be established that diversification has in
fact increased from something close to the level of a three-stock portfolio
to close to full diversification and that the timing of the increase coincides
to a reasonable extent with the stock-market boom. The evidence pre-
sented below shows that the trend in diversification started long before
the recent stock-market boom. Thus if diversification is as important as
suggested, valuation ratios should have reached historical highs long
before the 1990s. P/D and P/E ratios have trended upward since the early
1980s, but much of this was a return to normal levels from very low values
in the beginning of the 1980s.2
0.90
0.80 -
Househods and nonpaf
0.70 organatns
0.60 Bankpersonatmusts
C and estates
a) R_, ofthevworld
0.50 -
Insu[ance ompanies
Q.
040 itepensionfuds,
-Prtiv defied benefit
Private pensionfunds,
0.30 d-e ned contruton
eand bcatgovemrnnet
0.20 - emr_ ,byee rret ent ds
0.10 - Muttjalfunds
0.00 - - r . .
1950 1955 1960- 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000
Year
The values shown are for the end of the first quarterof the year, except for the last data point for the
split of privatepension plans between defined contributionand definedbenefits,which is forthe end of
1998.The dataarenot seasonallyadjusted.Mutualfunds include closed-endfunds. The category"bank
personaltrusts and estates"was added in 1969.Beforethis it was lumped togetherwith directowner-
ship by households and nonprofitorganizations.Four small categoriessumming to less than 1.5%of
the totalfor all yearsare left out of the graphfor simplicity,but areincludedin the numbersgiven in the
text. These are state and local governments, commercialbanking, savings institutions, and security
brokersand dealers.The measureof equityin the Flow of FundsAccountsis the totalU.S. stock-market
capitalizationincludingclosely held companies.
nonlinear, with a bigger effect of a given increase in participation at initially low partici-
pation levels. It seems more plausible that changes in participation have contributed to a
gradual trend in returns than that they are responsible for the recent boom.
Comment 245
Number
of stocks 1971 1983 1989 1995
In sum, the empirical evidence raises two concerns for the theory
that the recent stock-market boom is due to increased diversification:
firstly, that the trend in diversification started much earlier than 1995;
secondly, that although diversification has improved, the share of eq-
uity owned through mutual funds is still only 16.5% and a substantial
share of the stock market remains owned by poorly diversified house-
holds. It would be interesting to see how large effects on returns
Heaton and Lucas's model generate for changes in diversification more
in line with this.
3. Robustness ResultsfromtheOLGModel
of Theoretical
I was surprised by the way the authors calibrate the poor-diversification
cases (cases B-D). They first use firm-level return data to determine the
effects of holding a larger number of stocks on the standard deviation of
a portfolio (Table 7). The amount of idiosyncratic dividend risk (and for
case D bankruptcy risk) is then chosen such that the model generates a
stock return volatility equal to that observed for a typical three-stock
portfolio. For this amount of volatility the expected stock return and the
equity premium are much higher than in the full-diversification case
(case A). But how do we know whether this is a reasonable amount of
idiosyncratic dividend and bankruptcy risk? This could be checked
against the firm-level data. In fact, a more standard approach would be
to first use the firm-level data to determine the dividend risk and the
bankruptcy probability for a typical firm, then assume that a portfolio of
three such stocks was bought, and determine if the model generates a
stock return (a return to such a portfolio) which is much higher than the
one for full diversification.
It should also be emphasized that the assumption of risk aversion
equal to 5 may be crucial for the large effects of diversification on the
mean stock return. If risk aversion were set to 1, there would most likely
be little or no effect on the mean stock return of either diversification or
participation. To see this, consider the following special case of the
model for which a simple closed-form solution for the stock price is
available. Suppose there is no idiosyncratic labor income risk and no
labor income when old. With risk aversion set to one (and thus equal to
the assumed elasticity of intertemporal substitution), Epstein-Zin prefer-
ences specialize to CRRA preferences. Then each young agent consumes
the constant fraction a = P3/(1+ ,3) of wages, independent of asset re-
turns. Let A denote the proportion who are stockholders, wt their portfo-
lio share for stocks at time t, and P,t the stock price at t. The equilibrium
conditions for the stock and the bond market at t are then as follows.
Comment 249
Equation (2) implies Awt= 1. Inserting this in (1) gives Pst = (1 - a)(l -
dt)Yt.Thus in this special case the stock price is unaffected by the level of
stock-market participation. Furthermore, the stock price is affected by
diversification only because this is modeled by a stochastic aggregate
dividend share (causing the wage share to be stochastic) rather than
using several different stocks. In other words, for this special case in-
creased participation [diversification] affects the equity premium only
[mainly] via the bond rate, with no [little] effect on stock price and the
stock return. Given this, I would expect much smaller effects of diversifi-
cation on the mean stock return if risk aversion were set equal to 2 or 3
rather than 5 (in the end the right number may turn out to be 5 or higher,
but given that we do not have precise knowledge about this parameter,
sensitivity analysis is relevant).
The underlying reason that the stock price is unaffected by participa-
tion or diversification in the log utility case is that the model is an
exchange economy. With log utility the propensity to save is the same for
all households. The bond market therefore requires that stockholders in
equilibrium be willing to lend to the nonstockholders as much as stock-
holders wish to save. This implies Awt = 1 and thus, along with a con-
stant, leaves the stock price to be determined by the wage income of the
young. In an exchange economy wages are exogenous to both participa-
tion and diversification. This suggests that an alternative way of generat-
ing a higher stock price upon entry or diversification, even in the log
utility case, is to change the model to one in which the resources of the
young can be affected by increased participation or diversification. In
Vissing-Jorgensen (1998) I analyze an OLG model with production to
study the general equilibrium effects of limited participation. In that
model (for the log utility case) the riskless rate is unaffected by participa-
tion, and the full effect on the equity premium is due to a lower mean
stock return. Wages, the capital stock, and the stock price are higher for
higher levels of participation. I recalibrated the model to have similar
amounts of output risk to Heaton and Lucas's low-dividend-volatility
case. Increasing participation from 10% to 60% then decreases the mean
stock return by around 0.5 percentage point.4
4. The model is fairly standard. The results are not sensitive to whether the production
function is assumed to exhibit constant or decreasing returns to scale. One assumption
which is central for the results is that in each period, factor input levels and wages are
set before the realization of uncertainty. Factors are paid after output is realized. Thus
the labor share of output is countercyclical, since workers do not take any of the output
risk. Countercyclical labor shares are well documented in the business-cycle literature.
250 *J0RGENSEN
4. TheGordonGrowthModel
Although I agree that a decrease in the required return is needed to
explain recent valuation ratios, the authors' calculation based on the
Gordon growth model to some extent overstates the necessary change.
The required stock return in the formula P/E = l/(r - g) is net of transac-
tion costs, and these have declined significantly. While it is hard to evalu-
ate costs of direct investment, Bogle (1991) finds that equity mutual funds
underperformed the S&P 500 by an average of 2.1 percentage points over
the period 1969-1989. Rea and Reid (1998) find that the sales-weighted
average of total shareholder costs for equity mutual funds has decreased
from 2.25% in 1980 to 1.49% in 1997. Indeed, declining transaction costs
both for direct investment and for investment via mutual funds are likely
to have been a key factor behind the increases in diversification and
participation (the issue of lower transaction costs does not arise in the
overlapping-generations model, since diversification or participation is
changed exogenously). Assuming a 0.75-percentage-point decline in
transaction costs, the change in r - g needed to imply a movement in the
adjusted P/D ratio from 28 historically to 48 at the end of the authors'
sample is not 2 - 1 = 0.015 but 0.0075, or 0.75 percentage points. It is
worth pointing out in this context that without transaction costs it is very
difficult to reconcile the Gordon growth model with the historical-mean-
adjusted P/D ratio. With a historical value of g around 2% the model
implies a historical required real stock return of 2 + 0.02 = 0.056. The
actual real stock return was much higher at 8.5% (arithmetic average) for
1871-1994, and 9.1% if we include the recent period up to 1998.
The authors' calibration of the Gordon growth model furthermore
assumes that the riskless rate has increased by 2 percentage points.
Therefore an increase in g of 3.5 percentage points (or a g of 13.4% for 10
years and 2% thereafter) is required to explain an adjusted P/D of 48 with
a constant equity premium. The most relevant interest rate in this con-
text is the real interest rate on long-term bonds. These rates are currently
high (around 4% for long-term inflation-indexed U.S. Treasury bonds),
but it may be premature to conclude that they are as much as 2 percent-
age points higher than their historical mean. Blanchard (1993) and the
discussion of it by Siegel show that fluctuations in long-term real bond
rates have historically been quite dramatic.
As for the dividend growth g, it has in fact been higher than its histori-
cal average lately. The geometric and arithmetic averages were 1.5% and
2.4%, respectively, for 1871-1994, but 3.9% and 4.0%, respectively, for
1995-1998.5 An alternative to considering the recent past is to look at
5. The Gordon growth model assumes that g is nonstochastic and thus does not recom-
mend whether to use geometric or arithmetic means. The numbers for real earnings
Comment*251
EARNINGSGROWTHFORECASTS,
Figure2 I/B/E/STWO-YEAR-AHEAD
1982-1999
40.00
P/E
30.00
20.00
Anayst forecast of
10.00
^~~--^
/y/~
^\ ~I^~ J
/~
e/
\ \\ real earnings groth,
e/ p ye
000
-20.00
-30.00 1 . .
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000
Year
growth are as follows. Geometric means: 1.9% for 1871-1994, 4.0% for 1995-1998.
Arithmetic means: 5.0% for 1871-1994, 4.1% for 1995-1998.
252 *J0RGENSEN
Several points are worth noticing. First, analyst earnings growth fore-
casts are quite good. The R2 from a regression of the realized earnings
growth rates on the forecasts is 0.59 for the real-earnings growth rates
and 0.52 for the nominal-earnings growth rates. Second, until 1995 the
correlation between the P/E ratio and the two-year-ahead real-earnings
growth forecast is surprisingly high, 0.87. But third, this correlation
breaks down after 1995. Earnings growth forecasts have stayed essen-
tially constant while the P/E ratio has increased sharply. Thus, if the
expectations of the analysts asked by I/B/E/Sare representative of current
market expectations, it looks like the stock market boom since 1995 ei-
ther is driven by a sudden decrease in required returns or is a bubble.
In sum, the required change in r - g to explain an increase in the
adjusted P/Dfrom 28 historically to 48 recently is around 0.75 percentage
points. Dividend growth and (geometric) earnings growth has been
higher since 1995 and thus might warrant an increase in the expected
dividend growth rate. However, at least according to one source, market
participants have not increased their dividend growth expectations. If,
therefore, a change in the required real stock return is left as the sole
factor explaining the increase in valuation ratios, the necessary change is
around 0.75 percentage points. For given long-term real bond rates the
necessary change in the equity premium is of the same size. If we believe
long-term real bond rates will be higher in the future, the required de-
crease in the equity premium is correspondingly larger.6
5. Conclusion
Heaton and Lucas address an important but difficult question: What
caused the recent stock-market boom? They focus on changes in stock-
market participation and diversification. Having worked on limited
stock-market participation, I found the analysis of the related issue of
diversification very interesting. The references given by the authors and
the numbers in Table 1 above indicate that poor diversification is in fact a
pervasive phenomenon which should be considered seriously in general
equilibrium asset pricing models. Understanding why many households
concentrate large amounts of wealth in own-company stock seems cru-
cial in this respect.
More work is needed to determine exactly how large the effects on
6. The latest P/D ratio of 78.5 is higher than the value 48 used by Heaton and Lucas,
suggesting that larger changes in r -g are needed. This depends on how the P/D ratio is
adjusted. Campbell and Shiller (1998) refer to studies suggesting adjustments to D/P of
80 basis points for 1996 and 1997. This would make the latest adjusted P/Dequal to 48.2,
close to the value 48 used in Heaton and Lucas's calibration.
Comment 253
REFERENCES
Blanchard,O. J. (1993). Movements in the equity premium. BrookingsPaperson
Economic Activity1993(2):75-118,137-138.
Blume, M. E., and I. Friend. (1978). TheChangingRoleof theIndividualInvestor:A
TwentiethCenturyFundReport.New York:Wiley.
Blume, M. E., J. Crockett,and I. Friend. (1974). Stock ownership in the United
States:Characteristicsand trends. Surveyof CurrentBusiness54(11):16-40.
Bogle, J. C. (1991).Investing in the 1990s.JournalofPortfolioManagement,17(3):5-
14.
Campbell,J. Y, and R. J. Shiller. (1998).Valuationrates and the long-run stock
marketoutlook. Journalof PortfolioManagement, 24(2):11-26.
Poterba, J. M., and A. A. Samwick. (1995). Stock ownership patterns, stock
market fluctuations, and consumption. BrookingsPaperson EconomicActivity
1995(2):295-357,368-372.
Rea, J. D., and B. K. Reid. (1998).Trendsin the ownership cost of equity mutual
funds. InvestmentCompanyInstitutePerspective 4(3).
Vissing-J0rgensen,A. (1998).Limitedstock marketparticipation.Departmentof
Economics,MIT.Ph.D. Thesis.
Comment
JOHN Y. CAMPBELL
Harvard University
1. Introduction
The dramatic bull market of the late 1990s has challenged economists to
explain why stock prices are so high relative to historical valuation lev-
els. John Heaton and Deborah Lucas begin their interesting paper by
254 *CAMPBELL
reviewing some facts and then using theory to interpret them; I shall
organize my discussion in a similar fashion.
2. HowHighIs theStockMarket?
Popular commentary often uses the Dow Jones Industrial Average index
(around 11,000 as I write) or the Standard and Poor 500 index (around
1,300) to track the level of stock prices. Of course, index levels can
increase because of general price inflation, or growth in the real econ-
omy, or changes in the size of the publicly traded corporate sector rela-
tive to the economy, or changes in the size of index-included firms rela-
tive to other publicly traded firms. Intelligent analysis of stock index
levels must begin by scaling them in some way.
Recognizing this point, Heaton and Lucas discuss price-dividend and
price-earnings ratios for the S&P 500 index. Both ratios are high relative
to historic norms, but the price-dividend ratio is far more extreme; it is
almost two-thirds higher than its previous peak in the early 1970s,
whereas the price-earnings ratio is close to levels reached earlier in this
decade and in several previous decades.
Heaton and Lucas focus on the price-earnings ratio (scaled by the
historical average payout ratio of dividends to earnings) rather than
the price-dividend ratio. They claim that "earnings are likely to be a
more stable proxy for long-run payments to shareholders" (Section 3.1)
and that "in the short run dividends can vary due to temporary
changes in payout policy (for instance, in response to changes in the
tax law). Therefore, it is common to focus on the price-earnings ratio,
adjusted for reinvestment rates, to approximate long-run price-
dividend ratios" (footnote 5).
It is certainly true that changes in corporate financial policy can affect
the price-dividend ratio. Most notably, a shift from paying dividends to
repurchasing shares can permanently increase the price-dividend ratio.
The Gordon growth model, discussed in the paper, says that the price-
dividend ratio is the reciprocal of the difference between the discount
rate and the growth rate of dividends per share. A share repurchase
program causes the number of outstanding shares to shrink over time;
this increases the growth rate of dividends per share and increases the
price-dividend ratio. Share repurchases account for some of the increase
in the price-dividend ratio over the last decade, although direct esti-
mates of the effect are fairly modest. Cole, Helwege, and Laster (1996),
for example, suggest that net repurchases have increased the growth
rate of dividends per share by about 0.8%. Their calculation assumes
that shares are issued and repurchased at the market price; to the extent
Comment 255
1. One factor that can produce higher long-run earnings growth is a reduction in the
payout ratio. As Heaton and Lucas point out, the earnings growth rate should be the
fraction of earnings that is retained (one minus the payout ratio) times the return on
equity. If the payout ratio falls, earnings growth should be expected to increase. Unfortu-
nately this effect also increases Heaton and Lucas's adjusted price-earnings ratio, so it
does not make it easier to account for the level of stock prices.
256 *CAMPBELL
3. ModelingDecliningDiscountRates
While reasonable people can disagree about the prospects for future
earnings growth, it is almost impossible to rationalize the current level of
stock prices without some decline in the discount rate applied to inves-
tors to future earnings. Heaton and Lucas devote most of their paper to
an exploration of alternative mechanisms that could produce such a
decline. They rightly concentrate on effects that could reduce the equity
premium (the expected excess return on equities over short-term debt),
since real interest rates have not historically moved closely with the
stock market.
Heaton and Lucas first consider an increase in the stock-market partici-
pation rate. Intuitively, if aggregate equity risk is now shared more
broadly, then the amount of risk borne by any single investor has de-
clined, justifying a decline in the equity premium. In thinking about this
effect, it is important to keep in mind that investors should be weighted
by their wealth. The right measure of the participation rate is not the
fraction of individuals who invest in stocks, but the fraction of wealth
controlled by individuals who invest in stocks. As Heaton and Lucas
admit, wealthy individuals have always tended to participate in the
Comment*257
Equilibrium requires that the total supply of the output claim (normal-
ized to one) be held. When all agents participate in the financial market,
this requires a = 1, or
0- (4)
E[- P)' (k ( k) )]
1
- 1= - 1 y, (6)
P 1 - y~[1 + y(y + 1)2/2]
9 - yo2
1- . (7)
P k
REFERENCES
Barberis,N., M. Huang, and T. Santos. (1999).Prospect theory and asset prices.
Cambridge,MA: National Bureauof EconomicResearch. NBERWorkingPa-
per 7220.
Campbell,J. Y. (1999).Asset prices, consumption, and the business cycle. Forth-
coming in Handbookof Macroeconomics, J. B. Taylorand M. Woodford (eds.).
Amsterdam:North-Holland.
, and J. H. Cochrane. (1999). By force of habit: A consumption-based
explanation of aggregate stock market behavior. Journalof PoliticalEconomy
107:205-251.
262 *DISCUSSION
Discussion