CampbellGrossmanWang93 TRADING VOLUME
CampbellGrossmanWang93 TRADING VOLUME
CampbellGrossmanWang93 TRADING VOLUME
STOCK RETURNS*
*We thank J. Harold Mulherin and Mason Gerety for providing data on daily
NYSE volume, G. William Schwert for providing daily stock return data, Martin
Lettau for correcting an error in the theoretical model, Ludger Hentschel for able
research assistance throughout this project, and four anonymous referees and
seminar articipants a t Princeton University and the 1991 NBER Summer
Institute for helpful comments. Campbell acknowledges financial support from the
National Science Foundation and the Sloan Foundation. Wang acknowledges
support from the Nanyang Technological University Career Development Assistant
Professorship a t the Sloan School of Management.
1. See also Campbell and Kyle 119931; De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and
Waldmann 11989, 19901;Shiller 119841;Wang [1993a, 1993131;and others.
o 1993 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of
Technology.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 1993
906 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
A. Measurement Issues
The main return series used in this paper is the daily return on
a value-weighted index of stocks traded on the New York Stock
Exchange and American Stock Exchange, measured by the Center
for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) at the University of
Chicago over the period 7/3/62 through 12/30/88. Results with
daily data over this period are likely to be dominated by a few
observations around the stock market crash of October 19, 1987.
For this reason, the main sample period we use in this paper is a
shorter period running from 7/3/62 through 9130187 (1962-1987
for short, or sample A). We break this period into two subsamples:
7/3/62 through 12/31/74 (1962-1974 for short, or sample B),
which is the first half of the shorter sample and which excludes the
3. Some other papers have come to our attention since the first draft of this
paper was written. Duffee [I9921 studies the relation between serial correlation and
tradingvolume in aggregate monthly data, while LeBaron [1992bl uses nonparamet-
ric methods to characterize the aggregate daily relation more accurately. Conrad,
Hameed, and Niden [I9921 study the relation between individual stocks' return
autocorrelations and the tradingvolume in those stocks.
908 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
Date
FIGUREI
D e v i a t i o n s f r o m 1 y r MA of Log T u r n o v e r
.--.
'4
I
Date
FIGUREI1
still about 0.5. The standard deviation of the series is close to 0.25;
all these moments are stable across subsamples.
We also need a measure of stock return volatility. We take the
conditional variance series estimated by Campbell and Hentschel
[I9921 using daily return data over the period 1926-1988. Camp-
bell and Hentschel used a quadratic generalized autoregressive
heteroskedasticity (QGARCH) model with one autoregressive term,
two moving average terms, and a mean return assumed to change
in proportion to volatility. The QGARCH model is very similar to
the standard GARCH model of changing volatility, but it allows
negative returns to increase volatility more than positive returns
do.
B. Forecasting Returns from Lagged Returns, Volatility, a n d
Volume
Table I summarizes the evidence on the first daily autocorrela-
tion of the value-weighted index return. For each of our four
sample periods, the table reports the autocorrelation with a
heteroskedasticity-consistent standard error, and the R2 statistic
for a regression of the one-day-ahead return on a constant and the
return. This statistic, which we write as R2(1) in the table, is just
the square of the autocorrelation. The remarkable fact is that the
VOLUME AND SERIAL CORRELATION IN STOCK RETURNS 911
TABLE I
THE FIRSTAUTOCORRELATION OF STOCKRETURNS
(1) rt+l = cu + Prt
(2) rt+l = a + (Z:=l P,Di)rt
Sample period
TABLE I1
VOLUME, VOLATILITY, AND THE FIRSTAUTOCORRELATION
r t + l = cu + ( I L 1 PiDi + ylVt + y z ~ f +
2 y3(1000uf2))rt
- -
Volatility
B: 713162-12131174
Volume
Volatility
C: 112175-9130187
Volume
Volatility
D: 713162-12130188
Volume
Volatility
TABLE I11
THE SECOND
AUTOCORRELATION OF STOCKRETURNS
(1) rt+z = cu + prt
(2) rt+z = a + (Zf=l PiDi)rt
P
Sample period (s.e.1 R2(1) R2(2)
TABLE IV
VOLUME, VOLATILITY, AND THE SECOND
AUTOCORRELATION
rt+z = a + (ZL1 PiDi + ylVt + yzV; + y3(1000u;))rt
Sample period YI Yz Y3
and specification (s.e.1 (s.e.1 (s.e.1 R2
A:713162-9130187
Volume -0.028
(0.060)
Volatility
TABLE V
VOLUME,VOLATILITY,AND THE FIRST AUTOCORRELATION:
ALTERNATIVE VOLUMEMEASURES
r t + ~= + (2:=1P,Di + y~Vt+ yzMAVt + ys(Vt + MAVt))rt
A: 713162-9130187
Detrended volume -0.328 0.065
(0.060)
Total volume -0.156 0.064
(0.028)
Detrended and -0.313 -0.090 0.066
trend volume (0.061) (0.037)
B:713162-12131174
Detrended volume -0.445 0.095
(0.114)
Total volume -0.227 0.087
(0.081)
Detrended and -0.417 0.292
trend volume (0.108) (0.141)
C: 112175-9130187
Detrended volume -0.214
(0.073)
Total volume -0.132 0.047
(0.040)
Detrended and -0.218 -0.090
trend volume (0.073) (0.046)
D:713162-12130188
Detrended volume -0.169 0.062
(0.080)
Total volume -0.091 0.063
(0.050)
Detrended and -0.134 -0.065 0.064
trend volume (0.066) (0.059)
5. LeBaron [I992131 builds on the work of this paper to explore the relation
between autocorrelation and high-frequency volume movements more thoroughly.
6. Grossman and Miller [I9881 model the long-run determination of market-
making capacity and show that in steady state the constant negative autocorrelation
of stock price changes is determined by the cost of maintaining a market presence
and the risk aversion of market makers. We believe that market-making capacity
adjusts slowly to the steady state, and this is consistent with our empirical results.
For simplicity, our theoretical model assumes that market-making capacity is fixed;
it is a short-run counterpart to Grossman and Miller's long-run model.
918 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
TABLE VI
THEFIRSTAUTOCORRELATION
OF STOCK RETURNS: ALTERNATIVE
SAMPLE
PERIODS
(1) rt+l = a + Prt
(2) rt+l = a + (Z:=, PiDiIrt
P
Sample period (s.e.1 R2(1) R2(2)
TABLE VII
VOLUME, VOLATILITY,
Volatility
F: 112126-12130139
Volume
Volatility
G:1/2140-12/31/49
Volume
Volatility
H: 113150-6129162
Volume
Volatility
I: 112126-9130187
Volume
Volatility
TABLE VIII
THE FIRSTAUTOCORRELATION OF STOCKRETURNS:
THE DOWJONES INDUSTRIAL AVERAGE
( 1 )rt+l = a + Prt
( 2 )rt+l = a + (Zf=l PLDi)rt
P
Sample period be.) R2(1) R2(2)
TABLE IX
VOLUME, VOLATILITY, AND THE FIRSTAUTOCORRELATION:
THE DOWJONES INDUSTRIAL AVERAGE
rt+l = a + (Zf=, PiDi + ylVt + yzV; + y3(1000u;))rt
A: 713162-9130187
Volume -0.257 0.032
(0.061)
Volatility
TABLE X
VOLUME
AND THE FIRSTAUTOCORRELATION:
INDMDUAL
STOCK
RETURNS
Equal-weighted index regression:
~ E W , ~ +=I LYEw + (C;=lP~w,iDi+ Y E W ~ ~ ) ~ E W , L
Pooled regression:
rj,t+l + clp + (C5=1 Pp,iDi + ypVt)rjjt, j = 1, . . . , 32
Individual stock regressions:
rj,t+1= aj + (CL1 Pj,iDi + yjVt)rj,t, j = 1, . . . , 32
7 = (1132) C g l yj, f., = (1132) ZE1t,j
-
YEW YP Y a,
Sample period be.) (s.e.1 (# < 0) (# < -1.64)
tion of each stock return is smaller than the volume effect on the
index return, but the statistical significance of the effect is not
much reduced.
The third column of Table X shows the average effect of
volume on the first autocorrelation across 32 separate OLS regres-
sions, one for each individual stock. Not surprisingly the cross-
sectional average effect is close to the effect in the pooled regres-
sion. The number of negative individual coefficients is also reported;
at least 25 of these coefficients are negative in every sample period.
Finally, the fourth column of Table X shows the cross-sectional
average t-statistic for the effect of volume on the autocorrelation,
and the number of individual t-statistics that are less than - 1.64
(the 5 percent level for a one-tailed test, or the 10 percent level for a
two-tailed test). The cross-sectional average t-statistic is less than
- 1in every period except 1975-1987, and as many as a third of the
individual t-statistics are less than - 1.64.
We interpret these results as strong evidence that nonsynchro-
nous trading is not solely responsible for the phenomena we have
described.
A. The Economy
Our model further specifies the economy as follows. The
risk-free asset, which is in elastic supply, guarantees a rate of
+
return R = 1 r with r > 0. We assume that there is a fixed supply
of stock shares per capita, which is normalized to 1. Shares are
traded in a competitive market. Each share pays a dividend in
period t of D, = D + D,. D > 0 is the mean dividend, while D, is
the zero-mean stochastic component of the dividend. (We use
similar notational conventions for other variables below.) D,
follows the process:
subject to
where W, is wealth, X,is the holding of the risky asset, and Pt is the
ex dividend share price of the stock, all measured at time t. E, is the
expectation operator conditioned on investors' information set Yt
at time t.
The set Y ,contains the stock price P, and the dividend D,. It
also contains a signal, St,which all investors receive at time t about
the future dividend shock UD,,+I:
where K = p Z l u ~Equation
. (8) states that the unexpected excess
stock return per share has two components: innovations in ex-
pected excess returns per share and innovations in expected future
VOLUME AND SERIAL CORRELATION IN STOCK RETURNS 927
cash flows per share. Given the return process (9), the serial
correlation in returns can be easily calculated:
IV. IMPLICATIONS
OF THE MODELFOR VOLUME
AND SERIAL
CORRELATION
Investors in the economy have perfect information about the
current level of 2,. They can use Zt to predict future excess returns
as shown by equation (7).When Zt is high, the type B investors are
highly risk averse and less willing to hold the stock. The price of the
stock has to adjust to increase the expected future excess return so
that the type A investors are induced to hold more of the stock.
We, as econometricians, do not directly observe Zt or St. We
observe only realized excess returns and trading volume.1° How-
ever, these variables do provide some information about the
10. We could actually use a finer information set containing dividends, prices,
and volume. This would improve our inferences about 2,.For simplicity, however,
we use only excess returns and volume in this paper.
928 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
current level of Zt and can help predict future returns. A low return
due to a drop in the price could be caused either by an increase in Zt
or by a low realization of St,i.e., bad news about future cash flow.
However, changes in Zt will generate trading among investors,
while public news about future cash flows will not. Therefore, low
returns accompanied by high trading volume are more likely due to
increases in Zt while those accompanied by low trading volume are
more likely due to low realizations of St.In the case of an increase
in Z,, the expected excess return for next period will be high, while
for the case of low St,it will not. Thus, the autocorrelation of the
stock return should decline with trading volume.
A. Analytical Results
In this subsection we use analytical methods to develop this
intuition more formally. In the next subsection we use simulation
methods to a similar end.
We want to calculate the predictable component in the excess
return based on the current return and volume: EIQt+lI Qt,Vtl =
ui E [ZtI Qt,Vtl.The following theorem holds.
THEOREM 2. Under the assumptions we have made about the
structure of the economy and the distribution of shocks, we
have
B. Simulation Results
Although the analysis of the previous subsection makes our
basic point, that volume and serial correlation should be negatively
related in our heterogeneous-agent model, it is not clear whether
this effect is quantitatively important for plausible parameter
values. In this subsection we run some simple simulations to
address this question. The model of Section 111, with normal
driving processes, is straightforward to simulate because it is a
linear model conditional on investors' information. It only becomes
nonlinear when we condition on the smaller information set
containing volume and returns alone. The key question is how to
calibrate the parameters of the model.
We begin by describing the riskless and risky assets in the
economy. We set the riskless interest rate R equal to 1.01 at an
annual rate, or 1.00004 at a daily rate assuming that there are 250
trading days in a year. We set the autoregressive parameter for the
stock dividend, aD,equal to one. This makes the dividend a random
walk. In daily data any plausible dividend process will have CYDvery
close to one, and the model is simplified by setting it equal to one.
Next we normalize the stock price so that it equals one when all the
stochastic terms equal zero, and set stochastic terms to zero at the
beginning of our simulations. This normalization means that the
average stock price should not be too far from one during our
simulation periods, although the stock price process has a unit root
so there is no fixed mean. The normalization makes absolute price
variability close to percentage price variability, and it ensures that
the coefficient of absolute risk aversion and the coefficient of
relative risk aversion are similar if initial riskless asset holdings are
small.l1
The next step is to pick a plausible value for the innovation
variance u i of the stock's fundamental value F,. We choose ug =
(0.0U2,so that the standard deviation of the daily stock return (in
the absence of shifting risk aversion) is 1 percent. This is a little
higher than the average in postwar data. Equation (4) gives the
implications of this choice for the variances of the dividend signal
St and the contemporaneous dividend innovation E,. If there is no
dividend signal, then a : = 0, and the implied variance of the
dividend innovation E, is uf = (R - ~ ) ~ u i l R If ~all. dividend
11. Note that riskless asset holdings of the agents are not identified by the
model. With exponential utility, these holdings do not affect demand for the risky
asset.
VOLUME AND SERIAL CORRELATION IN STOCK RETURNS 931
TABLE XI
SIMULATIONS
OF VOLUME AND THE FIRSTAUTOCORRELATION
rt+l = a + (P + ylVt)rt
Specification
Volume
B:a,= 0.25
AR(1)
Volume
C:a,= 0.5
AR(1) -0.005 0.000
(0.261)
Volume 0.024 - 14.07 0.001
(0.840) (1.26)
Under the condition that a; Iuj2,we have two real roots forpz:
For Q < 1,both roots are negative. We choose the root that gives
the right limit when a: goes to zero. In the case that u -+ 0,pz :
should go to zero. This leads to the solution forpz which is the root
with the positive sign. po is then given bypo = (1 - %)pZElr.
and
VOLUME AND SERIAL CORRELATION IN STOCK RETURNS 937
--o (1 + R ) P Z U ~
uQt+l,At - a 1+ % a
Hence,
REFERENCES
Brock, William A,, Josef Lakonishok, and Blake LeBaron, "Simp,l,e Technical
Trading Rules and the Stochastic Properties of Stock Returns, Journal of
Finance, XLVII (19921,1731-64.
Campbell, John Y., and Ludger Hentschel, "No News Is Gvyd News: An Asymmet-
ric Model of Changing Volatility in Stock Returns, Journal of Financial
Economics, XXXI (19921,281-318,
Campbell, John Y., and Albert S. Kyle, "Smart Money, Noise Trading, and Stock
Price Behavior," Review of Economic Studies, LX (19931, 1-34.
Conrad, Jennifer, Allaudeen Hameed, and Cathy M. Niden, "Volume and Autoco-
variances in Short-Horizon Individual Security Returns," unpublished paper,
University
* nn"
of North Carolina at Chapel Hill and University of Notre Dame,
IYYL.
Conrad, Jennifer, and Gautam Kaul, "Time-Variation in Expected Returns,"
Journal of Business, LXI (19881,409-25.
De Long, J. Bradford, Andrei Shleifer, Lawrence H. Summers, and Robert J.
Waldmann, "The Size and Incidence of the Losses from Noise Trading,"
Journal ofFinance, XLIV (19891,681-96.
De Long, J. Bra;$ford, Andrei Shleifer, Lawrence H. Summers, and Robert J.
Waldmann, Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets," Journal of Political
Economy, XCVIII (19901,703-38.
Duffee, Gregory, "Trading Volume and Return Reversals," Finance and Economics
Discussion Series No. 192, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
1992.
Friend.
- .-
. .. Irwin. and
., -- ---> Marshall
.- - .
- -- ~- - - - -
-- - E. Blume. "The Demand for Riskv Assets." American
- - ~ ~ - - -
Nelson, Daniel B., "Filtering and Forecasting with Misspecified ARCH Models I:
Getting the Right Variance with the Wrong Model," Journal of Econometrics,
LII (1992). 61-90.
Schwert, G. ~ i l l i a m ,"Why Does Stock Market Volatility Change Over Time?"
J t u r n a l of Finance, XLIV (1989),1115-53.
, Indexes of U. S. Stock Prices from 1802 to 1987," Journal of Business, LXIII
(1990), 399-426.
Sentana, Enrique, and Sushi1 Wadhwani, "Feedback Traders and Stock Return
Autocorrelations: Evidence from a Century of Daily Data," Economic Journal,
CII (1992), 415-25.
Shiller, Robert J . , "Stock Prices and Social Dynamics," Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity (19841,457-98.
Tauchen, George E., and Mark Pitts, "The Price Variability-Volume Relationship
on Speculative Markets," Econometrics, LI (1983), 485-505.
Wan ,Jiang, "A Model of Competitive Stock Trading Volume," unpublished paper,
h o a n School, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1993a.
Wang, Jiang, "A Model of Intertemporal Asset Prices Under Asymmetric
Information," Review of Economic Studies, LX (1993b1, forthcoming.
White, Halbert, Asymptotic Theory for Econometricians (Orlando, FL: Academic
Press, 1984).