1NC Shell Patents
1NC Shell Patents
1NC Shell Patents
T-STRENGTHEN
Our interpretation is that topical affirmatives must increase
the penalties for violations of intellectual property. That’s
supported by the resolution:
1. Strengthen means “increasing.”
Yamamoto et al. 4, Inventor at Osaka, along with Katsutoshi Yamamoto, Jun
Asano, Shinichi Chaen, and Tomohisa Knoishi (Seigo Yamamoto, 2004, “NON-
WOVEN FABRIC AND, A LAMINATE AND BRAIDED MATERIAL USING THE SAME,” Pub.
No.: US 2004/0198127 Al, Appl. No.: 10/481,127, University of Kansas Libraries,
Lexis)
[0047] The term "strengthen" here is defined as increasing the tensile strength and/or
the strength in the thickness direction.
The ‘ great transformation ’ and the making of IP law The IP regime as we know it today took much of
its shape, in so-called industrialised countries , in the second half of 19th Century. It is the result of a law-governed
process of enabling market forces to extract value from instances that are not even ‘things’ , let
alone commodities : actions like writing a book, composing a melody, inventing a new device,
designing the shape of an object, indicating the source of origin of goods – all these actions and more,
abstracted from the respective intellectual commons to which they belong, could be transformed into
tradeable commodities by operation of law.Footnote4 Such commodification is the result of a process that
coincides, historically, with the rise of industrial capitalism and the market economy . To be sure, patents ,
copyright , and trademarks have been around at least since the 16th Century, when the market economy did not yet exist, let
alone a capitalist market economy. In fact, not only can the actions mentioned above be protected by law while remaining an
integral part of their respective intellectual commons and without being abstracted from those commons
and commodified,Footnote5 but also even markets in products resulting from those actions can subsist
and thrive in the absence of capitalist forms of production.Footnote6 So capitalism did not ‘invent’ patents,
copyright and trademarks: rather, it took them from the existing arsenal of legal tools and transformed them
gradually into forms of property over tradeable commodities – and into commodities themselves to be exchanged in
the marketplace. These commodities are not less ‘fictitious’ than the three factors of production – land, labour, and capital – described as such
by Karl Polanyi in his seminal work on the ‘great transformation’.Footnote7 Historically, the symbolic landmark of this first transformation is
represented by the international treaties signed at the height of the age of classic liberalism and free trade, namely the Paris Convention on
industrial property of 1883 and the Berne Convention on literary and artistic property of 1886.Footnote8 The success of the resulting IP regime
– which was destined to remain in force, essentially unaltered in its structural elements, for a good century – depended on the tacit assumption
that legitimate competing interests over intangible commodities created by law – works, inventions, badges of origin etc – can be defined and
balanced ex ante by the law itself. Such ex ante determination operated in various ways, for example by establishing that exclusive rights over
certain protected subject matter have limited duration, limited scope (eg expressions and not ideas) and are subject to exceptions (eg fair use in
copyright, government’s use in patent law, etc) or to other provisions that temper the exclusionary nature of property rights (eg compulsory
licensing). By defining de jure the dividing line between what can be claimed as private property and what should remain in the commons, the
law enacted a commodification of intangibles that was strictly functional to the correct operation of the market. From a Polanyian perspective,
thelimits embedded in IP law can be interpreted as part of the ‘ protective counter-movement ’ that arises in
response to unrestrained marketisation and the degradation resulting from treating human life and nature
activities as mere commodities. Such counter-movement does not just protect society and nature from the destructive forces of the market,
but is also required for the continued existence of the market structures themselves vis-à-vis the threat of self-destruction. In Polanyi’s words:
For a century the dynamics of modern society were governed by a double movement: the market expanded continuously but this movement
was met by a countermovement checking the expansion in definite directions. [This countermovement] was more than the usual defensive
behaviour of a society faced with change; it was a reaction against a dislocation which would have destroyed the very organization of
production that the market had called into being.Footnote9 The double movement results from the action of two opposing organising
principles, namely economic liberalism and laissez-faire on the one side, pushing towards the establishment of a self-regulating market for the
factors of production (land, labour and capital), and the ‘principle of social protection’ on the other side, aiming at the ‘conservation of man and
nature as well as productive organization’ by means of protective legislation and other regulatory techniques.Footnote10 Commodification of
intangibles followed a similar pattern, with market forces on the one side pressing for the complete alienation of creative actions from their
original collective meaning and their fixation into mere exchange values, and societal forces on the other side seeking to protect universal
freedom to access intellectual commons through regulation, legislation and resistance.Footnote11 The
IP regime that took shape in the
second half of 19th Century can be seen as the outcome of the double movement consisting of capitalism’s seizure of
economy and society’s regulative reaction. In this way, the resulting IP system operated a commodification
of certain intangibles while at the same time defining the boundaries of such commodification – and all this
by keeping a neutral stance and leaving entirely to the market the task of determining the exchange value of the thus created
commodities. Otherwise put, IP law established itself as an integral component of the rule-set of the
capitalism game – a component whose relevance grew exponentially, without changing qualitatively its nature, in the course of the
20th Century. 3. The second transformation and the age of IP expansionism The institutional structures that, within the IP regime, made
possible a defence of the freedom to access intellectual commons against unlimited propertisation remained relatively unchallenged for a good
part of the 20th Century up to post-World War II ‘regulated capitalism’.Footnote12 These structures started shaking at the end of the 1970s
with the transition to a new phase of capitalism dominated by a medley of political, economic and intellectual approaches which is now
commonly referred to as ‘neoliberalism’.Footnote13 At
the heart of neoliberalism is the basic idea that human well-
being can be best advanced by liberating individual, instead of collective, entrepreneurial forces, and that
the precondition to achieve this is an institutional framework characterised by strong private property rights
and weak regulatory barriers. Neoliberalism does not necessarily imply a weakened role of the state vis-à-vis the ‘market forces’ – as per the
hegemonic narrative that began to take shape in those years – but rather a new and different role of the state in the capitalist system. As far as
IP law is concerned, the most visible consequence of the transition from regulated to neoliberal capitalism was that the interests of the owners
of the means of production – which in the classic IP regime represented only one of the competing interests in intangible commodities – were
now taken directly onboard by the state. In other words, the neoliberal state diverted the IP regime from its neutral,
rule-setting role and converted it to a pure instrument of capital accumulation . Indeed, according to the new
hegemonic ideology of IP law-making, inspired by neoliberal economic theories, strong property rights over intangible
commodities are the necessary incentives to release individual entrepreneurial forces which in turn
ensure expansion , growth and market competitiveness . The ideology triggered a legislative process starting in
the 1980s and 1990s in USA and in EuropeFootnote14 as an erosion of the limits to commodification imposed under the classic IP regime,
which paved the way to the expansion of exclusive rights into every corner of the society and of the globe
– a process whose symbolic landmark is represented by the TRIPs Agreement 1994.Footnote15 Legislations of states under the
influence of neo-liberal ideology assisted informational capitalism in bringing commodification of intangibles to a
new level , both quantitatively and qualitatively. Examples of IP expansionism abound: broadening of the scope of patent
subject matter,Footnote16 extension of copyright duration,Footnote17 extended protection for pharmaceutical patents,Footnote18
world-wide enforceability of patents and copyrights (with increasingly high standards of protection imposed on low-income
countries),Footnote19 extended trademark protection for ‘famous’ brands,Footnote20 introduction of new IP rights (semiconductor
chips,Footnote21 sui generis database right),Footnote22 establishment of stronger and more effective enforcement measures and
remedies.Footnote23 Seen from the angle of the distinction between private property and the public domain, as established within the
traditional IP regime, the process of IP expansionism appears as the latest frontier of a law-driven plunder of the
commons .Footnote24 This was not just a quantitative empowerment of existing rights, but a transformation of the very raison d’être of
those rights. In fact, the process of plunder is consistent with the changing nature of IP law in the hands of neoliberal states, which loses its
original neutral rule-setting character to become a mere instrument of value extraction and capital accumulation. It can be observed that,
within the logic of never-ending capital accumulation, no boundaries can be set to the expansion
of instruments that make accumulation possible.Footnote25 This inherent indefinability of limits to IP expansion is
captured implicitly in the language of legislators and courts alike. A case in point is the proclamation of ensuring ‘a high level of protection’ that
features in key EU directives and is regularly reiterated in the judgements of the European Court.Footnote26 The judiciary has interpreted the
expression as requiring generally a ‘broad’ interpretation of the property rights harmonised by the EU legislator.Footnote27 Yet, in the absence
of a defined yardstick, the concept of ‘highness’, as referred to the quantum of protection to be ensured by property rights, cannot function as
a meaningful hermeneutic principle. It is rather a blunt assertion of an imperative: that of ensuring that the interests protected by IP rights are
given default priority over any other competing interests. The quantum of protection is at liberty of expanding indefinitely to ensure that such
priority is met. In its abstractness, the language of the legislator seconds the logic of capital accumulation in that, by definition, no ‘high level’ is
ever high enough.Footnote28 Within the legal framework inspired by neoliberal ideology, commodification of intangibles loses
the character of a legal fiction strictly functional to the operation of markets in works, inventions and other
intellectual instances and turns into a never-ending task that law is permanently summoned to achieve
(and is never good enough at achieving) on behalf of capital accumulation .
Vote neg for global syndicalism---pressures towards socialist state action are building,
forces the hand of monopolies.
Cecilia Rikap 21. Professor of Economics and Coordinator of YSI States and Markets Working Group,
Institute for New Economic Thinking. “Tilting the Scale Against Intellectual Monopoly Capitalism.”
Capitalism, Power and Innovation Intellectual Monopoly Capitalism Uncovered. Routledge. 2021. 287-
289
Capitalism is a system based on asymmetries and inequalities (of income, wealth, between classes, genders, races,
countries and more). Quite striking for a system born from the motto “Liberté, égalité, fraternité”. As time passes by, this broken
promise of modernity becomes all the more apparent. Inequalities deepen as knowledge is
monopolized, digital surveillance reinforces firms and states control capacities over workers and citizens,
and political conflicts never cease – with the US-China tech cold war at the current epicentre. Social
disrupts are an expected recurring outcome, and we have seen them everywhere in the 21st century. The
specific motives differed, but there is a common root: people are fed up with capitalism’s growing inequalities, with a
stagnant or even declining “middle class” in developed countries for several decades already and the
highest gains accumulating at the global level for those in the richest 5% (Milanovic, 2016). There is another shared feature;
demonstrations are increasingly being organized online. The same technology that is used for surveillance, for
broadcasting extreme right and even fascist ideas, and that drives the USChina world hegemony conflict, is also being used as a
counterbalancing weapon. Internet, particularly social networks, is a powerful tool for the organization
of grassroots movements. Workers’ unions can also learn from each other’s experiences online. The
absence or weakness of unions and social movements in some parts of the world has benefited
intellectual monopolies rentiership and predation. For instance, hiring workers with a vendor contract not
only hides the working relation (see Chapter 10) but also impedes unionization as it currently stands. Still,
unions are adapting and workers organizing. In 2018, Google employees managed to stop the company
from renewing an artificial intelligence contract with the Pentagon and to cancel its plans for a censored search engine
for China. And, in 2020, 2,000 employees urged the company to cease selling technology to the US police after
George Floyd’s killing. These initiatives should be taken by workers in other companies and contribute to
unionization. Unions should be reconceived as a political actor capable of exercising their influence beyond
wage claims. Workers’ organization is indispensable to counterbalance the power of intellectual
monopolies, given both their global reach and states’ internal contradictions and limitations. Peripheral
countries should cease competing to attract outsourcing and offshoring by allowing worse wages and
working conditions. As mentioned above in this chapter, world cooperation agreements to establish minimum labour regulations,
forbidding new and old forms of informality and granting minimum working conditions are urgent.
However, these agreements require great social pressures to take place. When it comes to transforming
capitalism, social disrupts, grassroots social movements and unions play a crucial role. To illustrate their
paramount importance, let us briefly consider taxes. It is crystal clear that the global taxing system has failed. As pointed out in Chapters 7 and
10, global intellectual monopolies declare profits and IPRs in tax havens and use tax loopholes to minimize
paid taxes. Global tax reform should consider the separation between ownership and control. Intellectual monopolies control production
and innovation networks beyond their legal ownership and have the capacity to trickle down the burden of taxes. However, the
intertwined relationship between global intellectual monopolies and their home (core) states renders
highly unlikely to accomplish such global tax reform without intense social pressure. Even the recent US
corporate tax reform was not – at least so far – successful in this respect (Clausing, 2020). Then, as far as tax havens are not eliminated, there
will still be room for tax avoidance and evasion (Zucman, 2015). Countries
acting as tax havens will not comply with a
global reform unless huge social disrupt forces them to do so. Additionally, workers’ protests must be
coordinated at the level of the global production network because the production unit is no longer the
factory but the network. The same applies to global innovation networks. Intellectual monopolies’
recognized employees have greater bargaining power than workers in subordinate firms , which are precisely
those that generally need a more urgent improvement in their salaries and working conditions. “Workers of the world unite, you have nothing
to lose but your chains” (Marx & Engels, 1848) can and must become an everyday reality for the French Revolution motto to be more than
aspirational.
OFF---1NC
CHEVRON CP
The United States [USPTO] ought to significantly enforce [Aff
plan] based on agency interpretation of current intellectual
property rights protection
of cases and, most of the time, they have the final say. That is why, along with
the Supreme Court’s justices, the judges who sit on the nation’s federal district and circuit courts
are so important. At any given time, there are vacancies on U.S. federal courts that need to be filled. If
they are not filled, federal caseloads get backlogged, and as a result, Americans’
access to justice is limited. As of March 9, 2015, there were 50 current vacancies on U.S. federal courts. These seats have
been vacant for a total of 22,222 days, resulting in a backlog of 29,892 cases. The Administrative Office of the United States Courts has designated 23 of
these pending vacancies as judicial emergencies, meaning that filling them is a critical task. As the Center for American Progress has noted, “in practical
significantly delayed for the American public. The Constitution dictates that the president appoints federal judges while the
Senate advises and consents on these appointments. The result is a delicate balance between the desires of the White House, deference to home-state
senators, and the power of the party that controls the Senate. Recently, politics has played a big role in the pace at which judicial nominees are
confirmed. In an attempt to slow President Barack Obama’s effect on the federal courts, Senate Republicans have obstructed the president’s judicial
nominees at unprecedented levels by attempting to prevent or delay a vote through filibustering a record number of nominees and making them await
confirmation for long periods of time. The reason many Senate Republicans have played politics with President Obama’s judicial nominees is because
they know the dramatic impact the judiciary can have on policies, including marriage equality and reproductive choice. The fewer judges that President
Obama appoints to fill federal judicial vacancies, the greater leverage the next president will have in deciding the make-up of these courts. Yet in the face
of unprecedented obstruction, President Obama has made great strides to fill vacancies and to ensure that federal judges meaningfully reflect the
dynamic diversity of the nation. A diverse federal bench improves the quality of justice and instills confidence that judges understand the
real-world implications of their decisions. Americans have different backgrounds, as well as an assorted set of professional, educational, and life
experiences. It is important that the federal courts reflect the diversity of the public they serve. As Supreme Court Justice Sonia Sotomayor once
wrote, “The dynamism of any diverse community depends not only on the diversity itself but on promoting a sense of belonging among those who
formerly would have been considered and felt themselves outsiders.”Furthermore, scholars have found that judges often change their minds during the
deliberative process. In one study, researchers concluded that having a woman on the panel affected “elements of both deliberation and bargaining—
alternative perspectives, persuasive argument, and horse trading.” Not only do the federal courts play a vital role
in preserving democracy, but who sits on the courts has an effect too.
not contemplate, and it’s a dark world in which Trump, Putin, Xi, Erdogan,
and others construct regimes that are authoritarian and nationalist.
Fascism is possible in the United States and elsewhere if big business can be
seduced by promises of riches in return for the institutional keys to democracy.
Perhaps Foreign Affairs editors are right to leave this dark world out, for it would
be very dark: nationalist wars with risks of escalation into global nuclear
conflict, further digital militarization (even Terminator-style scenarios of
smart military robots), and unchecked climate disasters.
OFF---1NC
DEVOLUTION CP
The United States federal government should:
---devolve authority over intellectual property rights to the states,
---the states should strengthen IPR protection by aff plan minus strengthen
protections.
This Article compares the patent legislative power allocation models in China and the U.S. In terms of evolutionary paths, the U.S.
transitioned from a decentralized model where patent legislative power resided with the states, to a
centralized model which consolidated this power at the federal level. Within the realm of patent
legislation, there is no collaboration between the federal and state government s. Conversely, China moved
from a centralized model, where patent legislative power was concentrated in the central government,
to a semi-decentralized model, with coexistence between the patent legislative power of the central and
local governments.
Compared to the current centralized patent legislation model in the U.S., this Article suggests that the
intricate structure of a semi-decentralized patent legislation model might be better equipped to cater to
the diverse needs of local industries and inventor communities, and to spur local competition and
institutional innovation. It can do this while complying with international treaty requirements, given
that national patent laws maintain a level of protection no lower than these treaties necessitate and
that local patent laws do not decrease the protection level of the national laws. However, the model also faces
challenges regarding potential inconsistency, rent-seeking behaviors, and local protectionism.
[*304] The examination of this semi-decentralized patent legislation model opens new avenues for
understanding legislative diversity, stimulating further scholarly discourse. Beyond introducing a novel case study in intellectual
property law within a particular national context, it also offers fresh perspectives on the institutional designs of federal and unitary
governments in addressing innovation issues.
OFF---1NC
Farm Bill DA
The Farm Bill is heading towards passage now, but it will require a bipartisan
compromise.
David Sivak 5-26. Manages the Congress and campaigns team at the Washington Examiner, where he
previously led the copy desk for three years. "Debbie Stabenow fights for Senate legacy with farm bill
standoff". Colorado Springs Gazette. 5-26-2024. https://gazette.com/news/wex/debbie-stabenow-
fights-for-senate-legacy-with-farm-bill-standoff/article_e65ad08b-ffe3-5b0b-843a-48520597ca42.html
Sen. Debbie Stabenow (D-MI) risks leaving the Senate at the end of the year with a big question mark hanging over her almost three-
decade career in Washington. As the top Democrat on the Agriculture Committee, she is waging her third and final fight over
the farm bill, which sets agriculture and nutrition policy every five years, yet she may retire with the latest package stuck in limbo. The
central holdup is hardly new. Republicans, who control the House, have sought to restrict the growth of the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance
Program, also known as food stamps, after the farm bill ballooned to $1.5 trillion in recent years. The entitlement makes up 82% of the total
bill. Meanwhile,
fights over “climate-smart” conservation funding and price supports for certain
commodities have also delayed the legislation. Stabenow said she would dedicate herself to passing the current farm bill in
announcing her retirement from the Senate a year ago. But the impasse means she may not be at the negotiating table when the full, five-year
reauthorization is finally approved. Congress has already punted on the bill once, passing a one-year extension last fall, and could do so again
later this year. Stabenow, 74, has broken a series of barriers in her career, including her election as the first woman to represent Michigan in
the Senate. She will end her tenure as the No. 3 Democrat in leadership in her capacity as chairwoman of the Democratic Policy and
The plan kills any chance of passage – The process of the plan
is time consuming – last time Congress attempted this is
dragged committee members into weeks of back and forth
debates – that would doom any attempt a trying to pass Farm
Bill
Molteni 6/5/2019
Megan Molteni is a science writer at STAT News. Previously, she was a staff writer at
WIRED,, “Congress Is Debating—Again—Whether Genes Can Be Patented”,
https://www.wired.com/story/congress-is-debating-again-whether-genes-can-be-
patented/ --- ECM
THE Supreme Court unanimously struck down patents on two human genes—BRCA1 and
IN 2013,
BRCA2—associated with breast and ovarian cancers. Justice Clarence Thomas wrote for the court at the time that isolated
DNA “is a product of nature and not patent eligible.” The historic decision invalidated patents held by Myriad Genetics, the
defendant in a 2009 lawsuit brought by dozens of patients and researchers represented by the American Civil Liberties Union, breaking the company’s
virtual monopoly on predictive cancer testing and unleashing a torrent of competition. Today, more than a dozen companies, including mail-order spit-kit
operations like 23andMe and Color, can tell you what your BRCA genes say about your risk of getting cancer.
Nowlawmakers in Washington, DC, are weighing a new proposal that would upend
that landmark decision and other recent rulings that created judicial exceptions
to federal patent law. Under debate are the notions that natural phenomena, observations of
laws of nature, and abstract ideas are unpatentable. That legal precedent includes a major
victory for the software industry against a plague of patent trolls. If successful, some worry this bill could
carve up the world’s genetic resources into commercial fiefdoms, forcing
scientists to perform basic research under constant threat of legal action.
The bipartisan draft bill, released last month by Senators Thom Tillis (R-North Carolina) and Chris Coons (D-Delaware), makes changes to several
sections of the statutes covering patent law and adds a provision that would nullify the Supreme Court’s
exceptions to it. Critics of those decisions say they’ve left the US with incoherent and overly stringent patent eligibility rules that are hurting
innovation, at a time when technological rivals, in particular China, are speeding ahead. Proponents of the current legal
doctrine fear reform will send the US back to a time when you could slap intellectual
property rights on almost anything —from a DNA sequence to the act of scanning and sending a file with a single click.
The proposed patent bill now pits the pro-reformers, which include the biomedical and pharmaceutical industries,
against the internet giants of Silicon Valley. That clash is on display in a series
of three public hearings that began this week in the Judiciary Subcommittee on Intellectual Property,
which Tillis chairs and of which Coons is ranking member.
The goal, Tillis said in his opening remarks on Tuesday, was to hear concerns from both sides and move toward compromise in the form of a final bill they
could introduce in the Senate later this summer. “If I was a CEO of a company in [the tech and software] industries, I would want to maintain the status
quo because it provides certainty,” said Tillis. “Unfortunately it does so for only a portion of our current innovation economy. I’m concerned about the US
economy as a whole.”
Forty-five witnesses are expected to testify, among them law professors, retired judges, former heads of the US Patent
and Trademark Office, pharmaceutical and medical diagnostic testing executives, and trade associations representing Big Tech, including Amazon,
Facebook, Google, and Microsoft. Joining the bill’s opponents is the ACLU, which is testifying this afternoon. On Monday, the organization sent a letter to
lawmakers signed by 169 scientific societies, research institutes, and patient advocacy groups arguing that the proposed changes would suffocate
potentially life-saving biomedical research and impede patients from accessing affordable diagnostic testing.
But the lawmakers say that their bill doesn’t in fact revive companies’ power to patent human genes or other basic research discoveries. “I want to be
clear on one thing,” Coons said Tuesday. “Our proposal would not change the law to allow a company to patent a gene as it exists in the human body.”
The confusion is understandable though. Even witnesses at Tuesday’s hearings had differing interpretations of the
bill’s language. Charles Duan, a patent policy researcher at the R Street Institute in Washington, DC, said he was encouraged by Coons’ words
but that his assertion is inconsistent with the proposed text. “The result of the legislation as it’s been drafted right now could make it possible to obtain
patents on pure scientific research,” he said. “I don’t think that’s the intent, but I think that’s what the language does.”
Sherry Knowles, an intellectual property attorney in Atlanta, celebrated the proposed bill precisely because she believes it would overturn Supreme Court
decisions like the Myriad case. Since that decision, she said during her testimony Tuesday, “there’s been a dead stop in research in the United States on
isolated natural products.” She cited as an example the drug adriamycin, which was first discovered in bacteria and which helped her survive a bout with
breast cancer. If the Myriad case had happened earlier, she argued, she wouldn’t have had access to the drug.
exceptions to subject matter eligibility, including ‘abstract ideas,’ ‘laws of nature,’ or ‘natural phenomena,’ shall be used to
determine patent eligibility under section 101, and all cases establishing or interpreting those exceptions
to eligibility are hereby abrogated.”
As with many legal fights, meaning can turn on the interpretation of a single
word. In this case, that word is abrogation. By most legal dictionary definitions, it means the formal nullification of a law through an act of Congress—
as in, Congress overruling the outcomes of the Supreme Court. Its more common usage, though, basically says that whatever legal approach the courts
used in the past isn’t going to be used anymore, says David O. Taylor, a legal scholar who specializes in patent eligibility at Southern Methodist University.
“They’re not saying, ‘OK, now you can patent natural phenomena,’" Taylor says. "They’re saying it can be hard to figure out what is an abstract idea, what
is a law of nature, what do we mean when we say ‘natural phenomena’?” This bill creates a clarified legal test for how patent evaluators should determine
those things in place of Supreme Court precedence.
The new legal test includes an updated definition of the term “useful.” To be eligible for a patent, a discovery or invention would now have to have an
identifiable benefit made possible only through human intervention. And it would have to be in a “field of technology,” which Taylor believes is meant to
create a safe zone for pure scientific research. He agrees with the senators that these new stipulations should keep human genes and other laws of nature
off-limits to patent-seekers.
Arti Rai, a patent law scholar at Duke University, finds more comfort in the parts of the statute the new bill leaves unchanged, namely the novelty
requirement. If the draft bill passed, she believes it could still allow patents on versions of genes “isolated” by human scientists, the defense Myriad used
in its case. “But the novelty requirement would make patenting individual human genes no longer a possibility,” she wrote in an email to WIRED, because
those genes are no longer new. Two decades of research into how human DNA at the single-gene level codes for traits and diseases has already put most
of that information in the public domain. But the proposed law could affect situations where multiple genes are being assessed for their role in certain
conditions. This would encompass the emerging field of polygenic risk scores. People are already seeking patents for some of the methods for calculating
them, says Rai.
All these conflicts and more are on display today and next Tuesday, when the third hearing takes place.
No one expects to resolve the issues in a week. But, as Coons said in his opening statement, the
point of the hearings is to expose any weaknesses in their solution, to test whether it’s
workable, and determine if such changes are even necessary at all.
Humans have fought over food and the means of producing it for 20,000 years, as rock art in Australia
shows. Food, water and land scarcity are primary drivers in two thirds of modern conflicts today. Indeed, many
people seem to have forgotten that the primary German war aim in World War II was to take farmland
from the Soviets and put German farmers on it. It is very likely that controlling the Ukraine’s bountiful and
reliable food bowl is among Putin’s main aims also. In the short run this is imposing hunger and even starvation on hundreds
of millions of people far beyond Europe. Spreading hunger in turn snowballs into government failures, civil wars
and refugee tsunamis around the world – as it did in 2008 when a shortfall in Ukrainian grain exports led to revolutions in three
Arab countries. Already, a third of a billion people – equal to the entire population of Europe – leave their homes each year, either as refugees
or economic migrants, to seek better lives in countries which seem more stable and food secure. War will add to the flood. Thus, in developing
a new food system for the world of the 21st Century, we also have to find a way to curb the human appetite for war. In Food or War, I trace the
links between food and conflict through human history, explore the role of food in recent conflicts and examine nine
regions of the
world which are at high risk of food failure and conflict in the foreseeable future – conflicts ranging from
riots and government failure to nuclear war. My aim is to show that the link between food and war is
inexorable – but that it can be broken. And that having enough good food is the most under-rated, under-
recognised and precious ‘weapon of peace’ in the world today.
OFF---1NC
HORSE-TRADING DA
Big tech hates stronger IP---they’ll retaliate with lobbying tactics
Barnett 21 (director of University of Southern California’s law school’s Media, Entertainment and Technology Law Program, professor at
USC law, with a focus on innovation policy and strategy in technology markets., “Why Big Tech Likes Weak IP”,
https://www.cato.org/regulation/spring-2021/why-big-tech-likes-weak-ip?fbclid=IwAR0nD2gHEYNiVmzImumMx3sLILLwTa-
1aHGmfao8ilRsQDbR5mr__ySLV5E, CATO, Spring 2021---gm)
https://www.cato.org/regulation/spring-2021/why-big-tech-likes-weak-ip?
fbclid=IwAR0nD2gHEYNiVmzImumMx3sLILLwTa-1aHGmfao8ilRsQDbR5mr__ySLV5E
Specifically, weak‐IP environments are hospitable for large, integrated firms that maintain internal
markets for financing and conducting R&D and then embed the resulting intellectual output in goods
and services for the end‐user market. By contrast, strong‐IP environments enable entry by smaller firms
that specialize in R&D and monetize the resulting intellectual outputs through external relationships
with third parties. This organizational distortion matters because larger firms tend to excel in incremental and process‐related
innovation that refines existing technologies while smaller firms tend to excel in product innovation that challenges existing technologies.
The most striking examples are found in the biotechnology and semiconductor industries, in which patent‐
dependent business models have facilitated significant entry by R&D-specialist firms and a vertical disintegration of the market supply chain.
Counterintuitively, a
strong‐IP environment can lower entry costs by relieving firms from having to assemble
a production and distribution infrastructure in order to earn returns on R&D investments. This may explain
why in 1966 (during the postwar weak‐IP regime) small firms accounted for only about 5% of business R&D spending, but they accounted for
almost 24% in 2006 (during the strong‐IP regime starting in the early 1980s).
Lessons from Political Economy
As an empirical matter, it
is notoriously difficult to establish definitively the extent to which patents are
necessary to support innovation by particular firms or industries. I adopt an alternative approach that assesses the
value that firms themselves place on patents as indicated by firms’ advocacy and lobbying actions. If it is true that patent protection facilitates
entry by smaller and less integrated firms that specialize in R&D, we should expect to observe those firms expressing policy preferences
favoring stronger IP rights. If
it is true that larger and more integrated firms do not rely heavily on patents or
can even derive competitive advantages through non‐IP‐dependent production and distribution
capacities, we should expect to observe that those firms express policy preferences favoring weaker IP
rights.
Lobbying behavior/ To test this hypothesis, I reviewed and gathered evidence on the lobbying behavior of various technology‐intensive
industries. Historical examples show that large, integrated firms resisted strong patent protection in the late 19th‐century railroad industry, as
did large, integrated firms like IBM in the computing industry of the 1960s and 1970s. Both industries have in common the fact that incumbents
offered a bundled package of intangible and tangible assets and therefore resisted patent protection that facilitated entry by suppliers of
discrete components of that package. More recent evidence shows that some of the largest
technology firms were among the
most vigorous supporters of the America Invents Act. Enacted in 2011, that statute substantially expanded
opportunities for third parties to contest the validity of patents, principally through the Patent Trial and
Appeal Board (PTAB). It is likely not accidental that these same firms have been among the most active
petitioners at the PTAB seeking to invalidate issued patents.
Now, a growing “post-Chicago school” argues that antitrust law should be enforced more vigorously. Antitrust
enforcement is
necessary, they believe, because unregulated markets cannot stop the rise and entrenchment of
anticompetitive monopolies. The shortcomings of the Chicago school’s approach to antitrust have also led to the “neo-Brandeisian
school” of antitrust. This group of legal scholars argues that the Sherman Act, the country’s early federal antitrust statute, was meant to protect
not just economic values but also political ones, such as free speech and economic equality. Since
digital platforms both wield
economic power and control communication bottlenecks, these companies have become a natural
target for this camp.
Big Tech poses unique threats to a well-functioning democracy.
It is true that digital markets exhibit certain features that distinguish them from conventional ones. For one thing, the coin of the realm is data.
Once a company such as Amazon or Google has amassed data on hundreds of millions of users, it can move
into completely new markets and beat established firms that lack similar knowledge. For another thing, such companies benefit greatly from
so-called network effects. The
larger the network gets, the more useful it becomes to its users, which creates a
positive feedback loop that leads a single company to dominate the market. Unlike traditional firms, companies
in the digital space do not compete for market share; they compete for the market itself. First movers can
entrench themselves and make further competition impossible. They can swallow up potential rivals, as Facebook did by purchasing Instagram
and WhatsApp.
But the jury is still out on the question of whether the massive technology companies reduce consumer welfare. They offer a wealth of digital
products, such as searches, email, and social networking accounts, and consumers seem to value these products highly, even as they pay a price
by giving up their privacy and allowing advertisers to target them. Moreover, almost every abuse these platforms are accused of perpetrating
can be simultaneously defended as economically efficient. Amazon, for instance, has shuttered mom-and-pop retail stores and gutted not just
main streets but also big-box retailers. But the company is at the same time providing a service that many consumers find invaluable. (Imagine
what it would be like if people had to rely on in-person retail during the pandemic.) As for the allegation that the platforms purchase startups to
forestall competition, it is hard to know whether a young company would have become the next Apple or Google had it remained independent,
or if it would have failed without the infusion of capital and management expertise it received from its new owners. Although consumers might
have been better off if Instagram had stayed separate and become a viable alternative to Facebook, they would have been worse off if
Instagram had failed altogether.
The economic case for reining in Big Tech is complicated. But there is a much more convincing political case. Internet
platforms cause political harms that are far more alarming than any economic damage they create. Their
real danger is not that they distort markets; it is that they threaten democracy.
Since 2016, Americans have woken up to the power of technology companies to shape information. These
platforms have allowed hoaxers to peddle fake news and extremists to push conspiracy theories. They
have created “filter bubbles,” an environment in which, because of how their algorithms work, users are exposed only to information that
confirms their preexisting beliefs. And they can amplify or bury particular voices, thus having a disturbing influence on
democratic political debate. The ultimate fear is that the platforms have amassed so much power that
they could sway an election, either deliberately or unwittingly.
Critics have responded to these concerns by demanding that the platforms assume greater responsibility for the content they broadcast. They
called for Twitter to suppress or fact-check President Donald Trump’s misleading tweets. They lambasted Facebook for stating that it would not
moderate political content. Many would like to see Internet platforms behave like media companies, curating their political content and holding
public officials accountable.
But pressuring large platforms to perform that function—and hoping they will do it with the public
interest in mind—is not a long-term solution. This approach sidesteps the problem of their underlying power,
and any real solution must limit that power. Today, it is largely conservatives who complain about Internet platforms’ political
bias. They assume, with some justification, that the people who run today’s platforms—Jeff Bezos of Amazon, Mark Zuckerberg of Facebook,
Sundar Pichai of Google, and Jack Dorsey of Twitter—tend to be socially progressive, even as they are driven primarily by commercial self-
interest.
Internet platforms’ real danger is not that they distort markets; it is that they threaten democracy.
This assumption may not hold up in the longer run. Suppose that one of these giants were taken over by a conservative billionaire. Rupert
Murdoch’s control over Fox News and The Wall Street Journal already gives him far-reaching political clout, but at least the effects of that
control are plain to see: you
know when you are reading a Wall Street Journal editorial or watching Fox News.
But if Murdoch were to control Facebook or Google, he could subtly alter ranking or search algorithms
to shape what users see and read, potentially affecting their political views without their awareness or
consent. And the platforms’ dominance makes their influence hard to escape. If you are a liberal, you can simply watch MSNBC instead of
Fox; under a Murdoch-controlled Facebook, you may not have a similar choice if you want to share news stories or coordinate political activity
with your friends.
Digital platforms’ concentrated economic and political power is like a loaded weapon sitting on a table.
At the moment, the people sitting on the other side of the table likely won’t pick up the gun and pull the trigger. The question for U.S.
democracy, however, is whether it is safe to leave the gun there, where another person with worse
intentions could come along and pick it up. No liberal democracy is content to entrust concentrated
political power to individuals based on assumptions about their good intentions. That is why the United States
places checks and balances on that power.
The lengthening shadow of authoritarianism would also reach out from Beijing. An increasingly assertive and nationalist
China would demand and compel submission to its growing strategic ambitions—not just in southeast Asia and the S outh C hina S ea but in the
Indian Ocean , all the way to the Mid dle East at one end and deep into the Pacific Ocean at the other. As China continued its march to technological
supremacy and global leadership, a declining, demoralized, and discredited United States would have to decide whether to go to war to defend democratic Taiwan
from being forcibly absorbed into China’s Communist dictatorship. Surging Chinese despotism would threaten the freedom of much of the rest of democratic Asia,
even if Japan, South Korea, and other U.S. allies—at best exposed, at worst forsaken—were able to resist Beijing's growing efforts to penetrate and compromise
their democratic political systems. It would be a hinge in history. How would democracy in Latin America fare in the face of this massive shift in global power and
momentum, with the corrupting influence of Chinese money eroding democratic forces in party politics, the media, and government? How would the brave
dissidents and demonstrators who cherish the values of self-government and human rights argue for the moral force of democracy as an idea with China on the
march and America in retreat? How many wreak and tentative democracies would survive in Africa as its elites saw ever more clearly which way the winds of global
power were blowing? How many multinational companies would conclude that their interests compelled them to ride the dictators' bandwagon? How many global
broadcasters and social media companies would resist the autocrats' demands for censorship and complicity? In such a near future, my fellow experts would no
longer talk of “democratic erosion.” We would be spiraling downward into a time of democratic despair, recalling Daniel Patrick Moynihan’s grim observation from
the 1970s that liberal democracy “is where the world was, not where it is going.”5 The world pulled out of that downward spiral—but it took new, more purposeful
American leadership. The planet was not so lucky in the 1930s, when the global implosion of democracy led to a catastrophic
world war, between a rising axis of emboldened dictatorships and a shaken and economically depressed collection of self-doubting
democracies. These are the stakes. Expanding democracy—with its liberal norms and constitutional
commitments — is a crucial foundation for world peace and security. Knock that away, and our most basic hopes and assumptions
will be imperiled. The problem is not just that the ground is slipping. It is that we are perched on a global precipice. That ledge has been gradually
giving way for a decade. If the erosion continues, we may well reach a tipping point where democracy goes bankrupt
suddenly—plunging the world into depths of oppression and aggression that we have not seen since the end of
World War II. As a political scientist, I know that our theories and tools are not nearly good enough to tell us just how close we are getting to that point—
until it happens.