Heath Economics Guide Handbook en
Heath Economics Guide Handbook en
Heath Economics Guide Handbook en
Page
1. Purpose of this handbook 2
2. Definitions of key health economics terminology 2
3. What is health economics? 5
4. Purpose of economic evaluation 6
5. Methods of economic evaluation 6
6. Social Return on Investment (SROI) 14
1
1. Purpose of this concise desktop handbook
This handbook, written by health economists at Bangor University is
intended to provide an introduction and define key economic terms, so
that those without health economics expertise can better understand
and appraise economic evidence. In particular, we are aware that you
may need to find and interpret economic evidence; this handbook is a
quick reference guide to key methods and terminology.
Bold key terms in the handbook are described in detail in the
“Definitions” section below.
2
Cost-utility analysis – a method of evaluation that measures health
benefits in preference-based non-monetary units such as Quality
Adjusted Life Years (QALYs) or Disability Adjusted Life Years (DALYs).
Decision analysis – a structured way of thinking about how an action
taken in a current decision would lead to a result, constructed as a logical
model describing the relationships between inputs and results.
Decision analytic modelling – a modelling technique used to estimate
the costs, outcomes and cost-effectiveness of different interventions and
programmes in health care and public health.
Disability Adjusted Life Years (DALYs) – used to generate health related
measures of utility for those living with a disability measured in terms
of time lost due to premature death (mortality) and time lived with a
disability (morbidity).
Discounting – a method of incorporating positive time preference (higher
value given to costs and benefits that occur now, compared to those
occurring in the future) into the evaluation when the costs and benefits
do not occur in the same time period.
Discount rate – the rate chosen to express the strength of preference
over timing of costs and benefits. Since 2003 the Treasury recommends
a 3.5% discount rate. To check the discount rate consult the HM Treasury
Green Book.
Direct medical costs – associated with the service/programme under
consideration. These are organisational and operational costs borne by
the health sector (e.g., health professionals’ time, supplies, equipment,
power etc).
Direct nonmedical costs – incurred by patient/families in the course of
treatment (e.g., transport costs, parking).
Health capital - defined by Grossman (1972) as the present value of a
person’s lifetime health.
Herd immunity – a form of indirect protection from infectious diseases
that occurs when a large percentage of the population becomes immune
to an infection and consequently provides a measure of protection to
those who are not immune.
Incremental cost – the difference between the costs of one intervention
and the costs of its comparator/alternative.
3
Incremental cost-effectiveness ratio (ICER) – obtained by dividing the
difference between the costs of the two interventions by the difference
in the outcomes, i.e. the extra cost per extra unit of outcome.
Indirect costs – losses in production due to absence from work. Indirect
costs can also fall on people other than the person receiving treatment,
for example, other members of the family may need to take time off
work to take a family member to the local GP clinic or A&E department.
Intangible costs – non-physical costs to the patient and their families
from ill health such as pain and anxiety.
Marginal costs – the additional cost increases or savings arising as a
consequence of small output changes within a health care programme.
Important to consider as part of resource allocation alongside wider
considerations such as capacity, staffing and equipment.
Opportunity cost – the value of benefits foregone by not using resources
in their next best alternative use.
Perspective – the point of view from which an analysis is conducted (e.g.,
public sector or societal).
Positive externalities – a benefit that is enjoyed by a third-party as
a result of an economic transaction (e.g., herd immunity through
vaccination programmes).
Quality Adjusted Life Years (QALYs) – calculated by aggregating the
number of years gained from a drug or health care intervention,
weighted by a proportion that represents the relative value attached to a
given health state of quality of life in those years.
Sensitivity analysis – analysis that tests the robustness of an economic
model by examining the changes in results when adjusting key
parameters.
Social Return on Investment (SROI) – analysis that results in a ratio of
benefits to costs, estimating the value created for every £1 invested.
Technical efficiency – the use of health care resources in such a way that
maximises output from given resources or minimises resource use for a
given level of output.
4
3. What is health economics?
Health economics is a sub-discipline of economics, which is the study of
how society uses scarce resources to meet its wants and needs.
Health economics views health and health care as an economic good (as
in goods and services) and is predominately concerned with how society
uses scarce health care resources to meet these wants and needs.
There are three basic economic questions:
1. What goods and services to produce?
2. How can we produce goods and services?
3. How should we distribute goods and services between members
of society?
Economic principles are applied to health and health care because;
- Resources are finite (e.g. there are only so many doctors and local
community services such as GP surgeries and pharmacies that are
open generally during business hours)
- In contrast, demand for health and health care is infinite
- To create a balance between finite resources and infinite wants
and needs, choices are necessary and consequently costs and
benefits must be compared
- Prioritisation is also required for investment and disinvestment
(e.g. do you utilise your scarce resources to implement
interventions to increase physical exercise or reduce tobacco
consumption?)
Public health and health care is different to how other goods and services
operate in a market because:
- Individual ill-health is unpredictable (individuals are not able to
control when they will fall ill, how long it will take them to recover
or how serious the illness is)
- There are indirect consequences to public health and health care,
these include positive externalities (whereby a benefit is enjoyed
by a third-party as a result of an economic transaction) such as
herd immunity through vaccination programmes
- Consumers have limited knowledge. They rely upon providers
(e.g. doctors, nurses, social workers, etc) to provide health care,
5
medicines, information, interventions and referrals to specialist
services if required
- Doctors, nurses, social workers, etc act as “gatekeepers”, deciding
who requires and receives treatment, and what type of treatment
they receive
- There are educational and financial barriers to entry into
the medical profession, thus maintaining limited consumer
knowledge in the general population
- The demand for health care is a derived demand, created from
the demand for health. Consumers typically want more health
capital and in order to achieve this, individuals allocate resources
in order to both consume and produce health (e.g. by engaging in
health promotion activities such as lifestyle changes)
6
Method Full or Partial Economic Evaluation
Cost-Minimisation Analysis (CMA) Full Economic Evaluations
Cost-Effectiveness Analysis (CEA)
They compare alternative services/
procedures/interventions in terms
Cost-Utility Analysis (CUA) of both their costs and outcomes/
Cost-Benefit Analysis (CBA) effects/benefits. It is worth noting
that each method measures
outcomes differently
Cost-Consequence Analysis (CCA) Partial Economic Evaluations
Cost-analyses They focus solely on costs or
resources used
Cost-description studies
Cost-outcome descriptions
Table 1. Methods used in health economics categorised by whether or
not they would be considered full or partial economic evaluations.
Each method of economic evaluation is described in turn below, with
limitations highlighted and an example paper listed demonstrating the
method.
7
individual costs of lost wages, travel and costs to relatives such as
childcare costs or transport. Other questions to consider include should
costs reflect opportunity costs and should one take account of the effects
of inflation and discounting. Discounting is a method of incorporating
positive time preference (higher value given to costs and benefits
that occur now, compared to those occurring in the future) into the
evaluation when the costs and benefits do not occur at the same time
period.
Example of cost-minimisation analysis in practice
Jones J, Wilson A, Parker H, Wynn A, Jagger C, Spiers N, Parker G. (1999).
Economic evaluation of hospital at home versus hospital care: cost
minimisation analysis of data from randomised controlled trial. BMJ, 319
(7224), 1547–1550.
9
Figure 2. Example cost-effectiveness acceptability curve (CEAC).
Figure 2 demonstrates at £7,500 per QALY, the probability of the
intervention being cost-effective is 50%.
10
Example of cost-effectiveness analysis in practice
Edwards RT, Céilleachair A, Bywater T, Hughes DA, Hutchings J. (2007).
Parenting programme for parents of children at risk of developing conduct
disorder: cost effectiveness analysis. BMJ, 334 (7595), 682.
Owen L, Morgan A, Fischer A, Ellis S, Hoy A, Kelly MP. (2012). The cost-
effectiveness of public health interventions. Journal of Public Health, 34 (1),
37-45.
11
argued that the QALY approach may be too narrow to capture the full
range of benefits from public health interventions. Though multiple
measures exist to generate utility scores, it is worth noting that different
measures produce different utility scores, making comparisons with
other studies sometimes difficult. Consideration of the population and
plans to compare the study with other published studies should be
undertaken before choosing a particular utility measure.
Example of cost-utility analysis in practice
Edwards RT, Linck P, Hounsome N, Raisanen L, Williams N, Moore L
Murphy S. (2013). Cost-effectiveness of a national exercise referral
programme for primary care patients in Wales: results of a randomised
controlled trial. BMC Public Health, 13 (1), 1021.
Use of ICERs in Economic Evaluations such as CUA and CEA
In the UK, governing bodies such as NICE use ICERS applying a ceiling
ratio/threshold to determine if an intervention, programme or service is
cost-effective. NICE typically use cost per QALY equations to determine
cost-effectiveness. NICE (2008) states the QALY should be used because
it is a standardised and internationally recognised method to compare
and measure clinical effectiveness and cost-effectiveness across different
treatments and patient groups. In the UK, the ceiling ratio has been
suggested at £20,000-£30,000 per QALY (NICE, 2008). In the USA, the
ceiling ratio is set at $50,000 per QALY, and between A$42,000-A$76,000
per QALY in Australia (Eichler et al., 2004).
12
Willingness to pay requires asking individuals how much they would be
prepared to pay to obtain the benefits or avoid the costs (e.g., money
or negative effects) of illness (Robinson, 1993d; Brazier et al., 2007;
McIntosh et al., 2010). Willingness to accept requires asking individuals
how much they would accept to be paid to abandon a good or put
up with something negative (e.g., side-effects from a medication that
reduced other symptoms) (Drummond & McGuire, 2007). Willingness
to pay and willingness to accept are often dependent upon how the
individual values money itself, as well as their valuation of benefits and
negative effects (Robinson, 1993d).
13
outcomes that are most important or salient to them (Berger et al.,
2003). The biggest criticism of cost-consequence analysis is that it has
no weighting system to appraise the results. Costs and consequences
are presented disaggregated, requiring the decision makers themselves
to devise a system to appraise the results (Berger et al., 2003). These
decisions, made at an individual level, may not always be in the best
interest of the patients or society.
Example paper of cost-consequence analysis in practice
Gage H, Kaye J, Owen C, Trend P, Wade, D. (2006). Evaluating
rehabilitation using cost-consequences analysis: an example in
Parkinson’s disease. Clinical Rehabilitation, 20, 232-238.
14
wider concept of value, capturing aspects across the triple bottom line of
economic, social and environmental value. SROI involves a stakeholder
consultation from the outset and throughout the process to help
establish boundaries, indicators and verify assumptions made in the
analysis.
The Cabinet Office (2011) have published ‘A Guide to Social Return
on Investment’. This guide provides step-by-step instructions on how
to conduct an accurate SROI. It was produced to help third sector
organisations better communicate their impact to the public, funders and
the Government.
The guide outlines six key stages to conducting an SROI analysis, which
are presented below.
The six stages to SROI as stated by The Cabinet Office (2011).
Stage Brief description of activity undertaken during that stage
1 Establishing scope and identifying key stakeholders
- Be clear about who is directly impacted by the intervention or
service
- What impact has the intervention had?
- How will these stakeholders be consulted during the process?
2 Map outcomes
- Engage with stakeholders to develop an impact map or theory
of change which is a diagram that shows the relationship
between inputs, outputs and outcomes
- Inputs are what a stakeholder puts into an intervention (e.g.
time to attend an exercise class as part of an intervention)
- Outputs are evidence that an activity has taken place (e.g.
number of hours conducting exercise or sessions attended)
- Outcomes are evidence that a change has taken place (e.g.
improvements in physical health from the intervention)
15
Stage Brief description of activity undertaken during that stage
3 Evidencing outcomes and giving them a value
- Find data from published sources or collect own data to show
whether outcomes have happened and value outcomes
4 Establishing impact
- After collecting evidence on outcomes, assign a monetary
value to these outcomes
- Also establish what changes would have happened without
the intervention (i.e. what happened in a control condition or
as a result of usual care)
- Are there changes from outside factors or other activity
that are not directly attributable to the intervention? (e.g.
is the improvement seen in physical health just from the
intervention or has the participant been engaging in exercise
outside the intervention – for example daily walks)
- How long are effects likely to last?
16
7. Critical appraisal of economic evaluations and decision
analytical models
7.1 The Drummond et al., (2015) Checklist for a Sound Economic Evaluation
In order to assess the results of a published economic evaluation, Drummond
et al., (2015) developed a checklist to identify elements they considered to
demonstrate a sound economic evaluation. It is worth noting that it is unlikely
that every study will satisfy all the points raised in the checklist. However, the
checklist provides a guide to the types of questions one should be asking when
reading published economic evaluations, so they can assess the strengths and
weaknesses of the study and make their own judgement of the usefulness
and relevance of the findings for their purposes. The checklist questions are
presented below.
The Drummond Checklist comprises of 10 main questions (adapted from
Drummond et al., 2015)
The Drummond Checklist adapted from Drummond et al (2015) Methods for
the Economic Evaluation of Health Care Programmes pp. 42-44. Copyright ©
2015 Oxford University Press. Reprinted by permission from Oxford University
Press. This reprinted Oxford University Press content is excluded from the
Handbook’s Creative Commons license. Anyone wishing to use the material
outside of this handbook needs to contact Oxford University Press for
permission (http://global.oup.com/?cc=gb)
17
3. Was the effectiveness of the programmes or services established?
- Was this done through a randomised controlled trial? Did the
trial reflect what happens in usual care or routine practice?
- Was this done though a systematic review of evidence from
clinical studies? If so, was the search strategy including inclusion
and exclusion criteria clearly described?
- Were observational data or assumptions used when establishing
effectiveness? If so, are there any potential biases in the results?
4. Were all the important and relevant costs and consequences for each
alternative identified?
- Was the range wide-enough for the research question at hand?
- Were all relevant perspectives covered (e.g., community, NHS,
patient)?
- Were capital costs as well as operating costs included?
Capital costs are one-time expenses typically incurred to set up a service
Operating costs are the recurrent delivery costs of a service, e.g. staff
18
6. Were costs and effects valued credibly?
- Were all sources of the values clearly identified?
- Were market values employed for changes involving resources
gained or depleted?
- Where market values were absent (e.g. volunteer labour) or
market values did not reflect actual values (e.g. equipment
given at a reduced rate), were adjustments made to
approximate market values?
- Was the valuation of effects appropriate for the question
posed? Was the appropriate type of analysis/analyses (e.g.
cost-effectiveness, cost-benefit or cost-utility analysis)
undertaken?
Market value is the price an asset would fetch in the marketplace
19
9. Were allowances made for uncertainty in the estimates of costs and
effects?
- Were appropriate analyses undertaken on patient-level data of
costs and effects?
- If sensitivity analyses were undertaken, were the justification
for the ranges and distribution of values chosen (for key
parameters) specified and explained?
- Were conclusions drawn sensitive to uncertainty from the
statistical and/or sensitivity analyses?
10 Did the presentation and discussion of study results include all issues of
concern to users?
- Were conclusions of the analysis based on an index or ratio
(e.g. cost-effectiveness or cost-benefit ratio)? Was this ratio
interpreted intelligently or in a mechanistic fashion?
- Were the results compared with those of others who have
investigated the same question? If so, were allowances made
for potential differences in methodology?
- Did the study discuss the potential of generalisability of the
results to other settings or patient/population groups?
- Did the study take in account other important factors in the
choice or decision under consideration (e.g. ethical issues,
limited staff numbers or wider policy context and relevance)?
- Did the study discuss issues of implementation (e.g. feasibility
of adopting recommendations)? Are there any potential issues
regarding finance and resources? Could resources be relocated
from other areas to assist the implementation?
20
7.2 Philips et al., (2004) checklist for critically appraising decision analytic models
Decision analytic modelling is widely used in the field of health economics as
a means of estimating the costs, outcomes and cost-effectiveness of different
interventions and programmes in health care and public health. A logical model
is presented with mathematical representation of the relationships between
inputs and results. These methods are often used to predict health outcomes
and costs when the intervention cannot be evaluated directly or the scope
of the evaluation falls outside of the existing evidence base. The checklist
questions are presented below.
The Philips et al., (2004) checklist for critically appraising decision analytic
models (adapted from Philips et al., 2004)
Permission to reproduce the Philips checklist has been granted by the authors
and the publishers of the checklist the National Institute for Health Research
(NIHR)
21
Dimension of Questions to ask
quality
Rationale for - Is the structure of the model consistent with a
structure coherent theory of the health condition under
evaluation?
- Are the sources of data used to develop the
structure of the model specified?
- Are the causal relationships described by the model
structure justified appropriately?
22
Dimension of Questions to ask
quality
Disease states/ - Do the disease states (state transition model) or
pathways the pathways (decision tree model) reflect the
underlying biological process of the disease in
question and the impact of interventions?
23
Dimension of Questions to ask
quality
Treatment - If relative treatment effects have been derived
effects from trial data, have they been synthesised using
appropriate techniques?
- Have the methods and assumptions used to
extrapolate short-term results to final outcomes
been documented and justified? Have alternative
assumptions been explored through sensitivity
analysis?
- Have assumptions regarding the continuing effect
of treatment once treatment is complete been
documented and justified? Have alternative
assumptions been explored through sensitivity
analysis?
24
Dimension of Questions to ask
quality
Data - Have all data incorporated into the model been
incorporation described and referenced in sufficient detail?
- Has the use of mutually inconsistent data been
justified (are assumptions and choices appropriate)?
- Is the process of data incorporation transparent?
- If data have been incorporated as distributions, has
the choice of distribution for each parameter been
described and justified?
- If data have been incorporated as distributions, is it
clear that second order uncertainty is reflected?
25
Dimension of Questions to ask
quality
Internal - Is there evidence that the mathematical logic of the
Consistency model has been tested thoroughly before use?
26
8. Useful Health Economics Resources
Health Knowledge
An online resource for anyone working in health, social care and well-
being. The website offers a broad range of learning materials, divided
into four different learning styles:
• A Public Health Textbook organised in relation to the Faculty of Public
Health Part A syllabus.
• Text courses with text, questions, answers and feedback on a range of
topics.
• Podcasts and Video PowerPoints with supporting resources.
• Management training with PowerPoint slides, workbooks and trainer
notes in four clinical areas: diabetes, coronary heart disease, stroke and
child health.
This online resource has a specific section on health economics.
www.healthknowledge.org.uk/public-health-textbook/medical-sociology-
policy-economics/4d-health-economics
27
NHS reference costs
A downloadable Excel file containing average unit costs to the NHS of
providing secondary health care to NHS patients. It is used in economic
evaluations to apply a cost to treatment received by participants to
calculate the cost of secondary care.
https://www.gov.uk/government/collections/nhs-reference-costs
Systematic Reviewing
Shemilt and colleagues (2013) reflect on the value and desire for the
consideration by end users for coverage of an economic perspective
in a Cochrane review and outlines two potential approaches and
future directions. This paper provides a good introduction to economic
perspectives and considerations when conducting systematic reviews.
http://www.systematicreviewsjournal.com/content/2/1/83
28
References
Berger ML, Bingefors K, Hedblom EC, Pashos CL, Torrance GW. (2003).
Health Care Cost, Quality, and Outcomes: ISPOR Book of Terms.
Lawrenceville, NJ: ISPOR.
BMJ (2012) Clinical Evidence Toolbox
http://clinicalevidence.bmj.com/x/set/static/ebm/toolbox/678253.html
Brazier J, Ratcliffe J, Saloman JA, Tsuchiya A. (2007). Measuring and
Valuing Health Benefits for Economic Evaluation. Oxford University Press:
Oxford, UK
Brazier JE, Harper R, Jones NM, O’Cathain A, Thomas KJ, Usherwood T,
Westlake L. (1992) Validating the SF-36 health survey questionnaire: new
outcome measure for primary care. BMJ. 305(6846): 160–164.
The Cabinet Office’s Guide (2011). A Guide to Social Return on
Investment.
http://www.bond.org.uk/data/files/Cabinet_office_A_guide_to_Social_
Return_on_Investment.pdf
Drummond MF, Sculpher MJ, Claxton K, Stoddart GL and Torrance GW.
(2015). Methods for the economic evaluation of health care programmes
(4th Ed.). Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK
Drummond MF, McGuire A. (2007). Economic Evaluation in Health Care,
Merging Theory with Practice. Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK
Eichler HG, Kong SX, Gerth WC, Mavros P, Jonsson B. (2004). Use of
Cost-Effectiveness Analysis in Health-Care Resource Allocation Decision-
Making: How Are Cost-Effectiveness Thresholds Expected to Emerge?
Value in Health, 7, 518-528.
The EuroQol Group (1990). EuroQol- a new facility for the measurement
of health-related quality of life. Health Policy 16(3):199-208.
Fenwick E, Byford S. (2005). A guide to cost-effectiveness acceptability
curves. British Journal of Psychiatry 187:106-108.
Glick HA, Doshi JA, Sonnad SS, Polsky D. (2007). Economic Evaluation in
Clinical Trials. Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK
Grossman M. (1972). On the concept of health capital and the demand
for health. The Journal of Political Economy 80(2):223-255.
Horsman J, Furlong W, Feeny D, Torrance G. (2003) The Health Utilities
Index (HUI®): Concepts, Measurement Properties and Applications.
Health and Quality of Life Outcomes (electronic journal), 1, 54.
29
McIntosh E, Clarke P, Frew E, Louviere J. (2010). Applied Methods of Cost-
Benefit Analysis in Health Care. Oxford University Press
Morris S, Devlin N, Parkin D. (2007). Economic Analysis In Health Care.
Wiley and Sons, Chichester, UK
National Institute for Health and Care Excellence (NICE) (2008).
Measuring effectiveness and cost effectiveness: the QALY.
http://publications.nice.org.uk/how-nice-measures-value-for-money-
in-relation-to-public-health-interventions-lgb10b/nices-approach-to-
economic-analysis-for-public-health-interventions
National Institute for Health and Care Excellence (NICE) (2012). Methods
for the development of NICE public health guidance (3rd edition).
http://www.nice.org.uk/article/pmg4/resources/non-guidance-methods-
for-the-development-of-nice-public-health-guidance-third-edition-pdf
Office of Health Economics (OHE) (2008) Glossary.
Owen L, Morgan A, Fischer A, Ellis S, Hoy A, Kelly MP. (2012). The cost-
effectiveness of public health interventions. Journal of Public Health, 34
(1), 37-45.
Phillips Z, Ginnelly L, Sculpher M, Claxton K, Golder S, Riemsma R,
Woolacoot N, Glanville J. (2004). Review of guidelines for good practice
in decision-analytic modelling in health technology assessment. Health
Technology Assessment 8 (36), 1-158.
Robinson, R. (1993a). Economic Evaluation in Health Care. Costs and cost-
minimisation analysis. BMJ, 307, 726-728.
Robinson, R. (1993b). Economic Evaluation in Health Care. Cost-
effectiveness analysis. BMJ, 307, 793-795.
Robinson, R. (1993c). Economic Evaluation in Health Care. Cost-utility
analysis. BMJ, 307, 859-862.
Robinson, R. (1993d). Economic Evaluation in Health Care. Cost-benefit
analysis. BMJ, 307, 924-926.
Acknowledgements
The authors wish to thank Dr Christopher Johnson, Public Health Wales;
Liz Green, Wales Health Impact Assessment Support Unit; and Dr Sam
Groves, Swansea Centre for Health Economics, Swansea University who
provided feedback on drafts of the handbook.
30
Joanna Charles is a Research Fellow at the Centre for Health
Economics and Medicines Evaluation at Bangor University. She
has an interest in the use of health economic techniques for
evaluating public health interventions, evidence synthesis and
micro-costing methodologies.