Actual - 1 s2.0 S0264999322003844 Main
Actual - 1 s2.0 S0264999322003844 Main
Actual - 1 s2.0 S0264999322003844 Main
Economic Modelling
journal homepage: www.journals.elsevier.com/economic-modelling
A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T
Handling editor: Angus Chu We estimate the economic impacts of COVID-19 in the U.S. using a disaster economic consequence analysis
framework implemented by a dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model. This facilitates identifi
JEL classification: cation of relative influences of several causal factors as “shocks” to the model, including mandatory business
C68 E37 I18 F19 closures, disease spread trajectories, behavioral responses, resilience, pent-up demand, and government stimulus
Keywords: packages. The analysis is grounded in primary data on avoidance behavior and healthcare parameters. The
Disaster economics decomposition of the influence of various causal factors will help policymakers offset the negative influences and
CGE Modeling
reinforce the positive ones during the remainder of this pandemic and future ones.
COVID-19
Avoidance behavior
Resilience
1. Introduction and overview COVID-19 deaths in the U.S. through December 2022 (CDC, 2022), are
greater than the U.S. death toll over the past four decades of the
1.1. Background HIV/AIDS epidemic of approximately 700,000 people (KFF, 2021) and
U.S. deaths from the Spanish Flu a century ago of approximately 675,
COVID-19 has had major consequences for the economy of the 000 people (CDC, 2020h). U.S. deaths from COVID-19 are more than
United States. Several studies have estimated its total impacts on GDP in nine times the country’s death toll from the influenza pandemic of
the trillions of dollars, even before the Delta and Omicron variants ran 1957–1958 (CDC, 2020h) and the Hong Kong flu in 1968 (CDC, 2020h).
their course (del Rio-Chanona et al., 2020; Dixon et al., 2020; Ludvigson COVID-19 is caused by the SARS-CoV-2 virus, first recorded in the U.S.
et al., 2020; Thunström et al., 2020; Walmsley et al., 2021b). The pan in January 2020.
demic’s total economic impacts are estimated to be twice as great as Initial studies of the economics of COVID-19 have primarily used
those of the Great Recession, 20 times greater than the 2001 World macroeconomic and financial models, likely because the most recent
Trade Center attacks, and 40 times greater than any natural disaster that great disaster to hit the U.S. was a financial meltdown. Moreover, given
befell the country in this century (Rose, 2021). The more than 1,000,000 the nature of these models in dealing with aggregates and the lack of
☆
The authors are grateful to the DHS Center for Accelerating Operational Efficiency (CAOE) for its financial support. We thank Tony Cheesebrough and other
members of the research project stakeholder team for their helpful comments on earlier presentations of our work. We acknowledge the input from audiences at
professional presentations of the research at meetings of various academic associations over the past year. We acknowledge Andrew Kinoshita, Bari Noor, Kon
stantinos Papaefthymiou, and Adam Einbinder for their research assistance. We are also grateful to the experts who have provided input to the team on epidemi
ological and health outcomes modeling. However, any opinions, findings, conclusions or recommendations in this document are those of the authors and do not
necessarily reflect views of DHS or the University of Southern California.
* Corresponding author. Department of Economics, Dana and David Dornsife College of Letters, Arts and Sciences, University of Southern California, 3620 South
Vermont Ave. Kaprielian (KAP) Hall, 300, Los Angeles, CA 90089, USA.
E-mail addresses: [email protected] (T. Walmsley), [email protected] (A. Rose), [email protected] (R. John), [email protected] (D. Wei), [email protected]
(J.P. Hlávka), [email protected] (J. Machado), [email protected] (K. Byrd).
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2022.106147
Received 7 March 2022; Received in revised form 30 November 2022; Accepted 12 December 2022
Available online 21 December 2022
0264-9993/© 2022 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
data at the early stages, the modeling approaches have primarily been model, while the current study utilizes primary data and performs the
top-down. Thus, they were only able to include a limited number of analysis with a dynamic CGE model.
causal factors unique to the pandemic and its impact on the overall The decomposition of the influence of various causal factors is
economy.1 important for several reasons. First, it improves analytical insight into
An alternative is a bottom-up approach that focuses on individual their workings and interrelationships. Second, it enables policymakers
causal factors prevalent in disasters, including economy-wide impacts, to identify the most prominent causal factors, which is the first step
though not including all financial considerations (likely to be minor in toward making adjustments to offset the negative influences and rein
comparison). Research on the impacts of disasters has led to the devel force the positive ones. For example, our analysis indicates that the
opment of a comprehensive economic consequence analysis (ECA) mandatory closures by far had the largest negative effect on the results
framework that has applicability to COVID-19. This framework extends and that the slow reopenings, due to such factors as supply-chain bot
ordinary impact analysis covering standard direct and indirect effects to tlenecks and mixed messages and political debate about COVID conta
include resilience and behavioral responses that have played an especially gion, continued some of that influence. Avoidance effects and telework
prominent role in a range of disasters including earthquakes, hurricanes, were also prominent influences. In the case of the former, improved risk
ocean oil spills, terrorist attacks among others (Rose et al., 2014; Rose communication, a relatively inexpensive way to quell fear, has great
et al., 2017; Prager et al., 2017; Botzen et al., 2020). We will demon potential to reduce economic losses. The same is true of public and
strate below how the framework is applicable to the COVID pandemic as private decision-makers placing a greater emphasis on providing remote
well. For example, resilience is exemplified by telework and spending work options.
out of pent-up demand. Behavioral responses are exemplified by
avoidance of public gathering places, mass transit, workplaces, and
1.3. Overview
educational institutions.
This paper is divided into 11 sections. Section 2 presents a summary
1.2. Purpose of the ECA framework. Section 3 provides the basis of the survey of
avoidance behavior and its results. Section 4 presents the modeling re
The purpose of this paper is to estimate the total economic impacts of sults of health outcomes under alternative pandemic scenarios in terms
COVID-19 in the U.S. We apply the CREATE ECA framework in the of the efficacy of interventions informed by healthcare interviews.
process, which enables us to identify the relative influence of several Section 5 presents the analysis of data on mandatory closures, reopen
causal factors. We utilize a state-of-the-art dynamic, multi-country CGE ing, telework, and pent-up demand, as well as the refinement of the
model to estimate the time path of the impacts of these factors. CGE avoidance and healthcare data for inclusion in the CGE model. This
analysis essentially models the economy as a set of interconnected section also presents an assessment of the six federal stimulus packages
supply chains, which enables us to calculate indirect effects as well. that have been enacted to date and how they are translated for use in the
Moreover, our analysis is based on the most up-to-date historical data on CGE model. Section 6 presents the workings of the CGE model. Section 7
key causal factors and primary data relating to avoidance behavior and provides a presentation and the interpretation of the aggregate impacts,
health outcomes and the effects of alternative intervention scenarios. as well as a decomposition of the results. Section 8 provides a compar
Avoidance is the main behavioral response, and in this case pertains to ison of the results with other recent findings and discusses the limita
people engaging in 10 types of activities like retail shopping, going to tions of our analysis. Section 8 provides a summary and suggestions for
work, sending children to school, using public transportation, and going future research.2
to entertainment venues. Moreover, we base our estimates of health
outcomes on interviews with medical professionals. We decompose our 2. A disaster economics framework
analysis by performing a set of sequential dynamic simulations begin
ning with mandatory closures, gradual reopenings, avoidance behavior, 2.1. Overview
and shifts in level and composition of healthcare. We include aspects of
resilience, such as the increase in telework and the injection of pent-up A major example of a disaster economics approach is the CREATE3
demand at later stages of the recovery. Finally, we include the impact of Economic Consequence Analysis (ECA) Framework (Rose et al., 2009;
various stimulus packages. All of these effects are disaggregated ac 2017; Rose, 2015), which has been applied to numerous actual and
cording to the 65 sectors of the dynamic CGE model to improve the simulated disasters (see, e.g., Rose et al., 2009; Sue Wing et al., 2016;
accuracy of the estimation since general equilibrium (supply-chain) ef Chen et al., 2017), including a moderate-sized pandemic (Prager et al.,
fects differ by sector. Given the many uncertainties around several
causal factors and the trajectory of infection/hospitalization/deaths due
to COVID, we consider alternative scenarios embodying combinations of 2
We also provide several data appendices for this paper, some of them quite
key assumptions, and including several sensitivity tests. extensive. Appendix A presents the modeling of the various intervention sce
This study builds on prior work of the research team on the economic narios; estimates of the number of infected international travelers, vaccination
consequences of COVID-19. Walmsley et al. (2021a) estimated the projections, and transmission reductions in each intervention scenario are also
consequences of mandatory closures not only in the U.S. but around the provided in this appendix. In Appendix B, direct output impacts by sector for
globe. Walmsley et al. (2021b) used more up-to-date data to examine the mandatory closures and the reopening process are estimated and presented for
effect of reopenings through the summer of 2020. Rose et al. (2021) six-month periods. This Appendix also presents the results of health-related
analyzed the transmission of these consequences through international impacts, including labor force workday losses and COVID-related health ex
penditures by health outcome category and by time period for individual sce
trade between the U.S., China, and the rest of the world. All of these
narios, as well as the data for estimating pent-up demand. In Appendix C,
studies included major causal factors analyzed in the current study,
detailed stimulus bill provisions, their mapping to CGE model sectors, and
though they omitted the effects of fiscal stimulus packages. Moreover, methods adopted to implement the simulations are presented. Appendix D
all of the studies were based on secondary data and used a static CGE provides detailed descriptions on the modeling of the impacts of causal factors.
Appendix E presents the impacts on sectoral production in the first semi-annual
period of 2020 due to the pandemic, decomposed by causal effect. In addition,
1
In fact, U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (2021) qualifies its recent eco we also provide a complete copy of the avoidance behavior survey as a separate
nomic forecasts by stating: “The full economic effects of the COVID-19 supplementary file to this paper.
3
pandemic cannot be quantified in the GDP estimate because the impacts are CREATE stands for the National Center for Risk and Economic Analysis of
generally embedded in source data and cannot be separately identified." Threats and Emergencies.
2
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
2017). It represents an advance over conventional economic impact CGE formulation enables us to model the time-path of the impacts of the
analysis that has been applied for decades to more ordinary situations various factors, including lags in their effects. In the next two sections
such as the closing of an automobile plant. we will indicate how two of these causal factors are incorporated into
It begins with the specification of direct economic impacts and then the modeling in terms of shocks.
typically applies a state-of-the-art economy-wide model, such as a
computable general equilibrium (CGE) model, to estimate total eco 3. Avoidance behavior survey
nomic impacts. However, its major contribution is the inclusion of two
additional considerations unique to disasters. 3.1. Overview
The first is resilience, which pertains to various actions taken by
producers, consumers, and governments to recover from the shock and Avoidance behavior has the potential to significantly affect the
mute the negative impacts on economic activity by using remaining bottom-line economic impacts of COVID-19. The present study advances
resources efficiently (Rose and Liao, 2005; Rose et al., 2009; Rose et al., prior methods developed for survey research by the authors on the
2017; Martin and Sunley, 2014). For example, Rose et al. (2009) esti public’s response to flu pandemics (Rosoff et al., 2012) and urban bio
mated that the rapid relocation of tenants of the World Trade Center logical terror attacks (Rosoff et al., 2013). The survey estimates changes
following the 9/11 attacks reduced the potential GDP impacts by 72%. in behavior due to the COVID-19 pandemic in 10 different domains:
Several other studies have found various other resilience tactics (e.g.,
conservation, input substitution, inventories, excess capacity) to be a 1) Staying home from work
powerful strategy to reduce business interruption (BI) losses from di 2) Keeping children home from school
sasters in the range of 20%–80% of the potential losses based on surveys 3) Canceling or postponing medical and dental appointments
and simulation analyses (see, e.g., Kajitani and Tatano, 2009; Wei et al., 4) Canceling or postponing professional grooming and spa
2020; Dormady et al., 2022). treatments
The ECA framework also includes behavioral responses, which are 5) Canceling or postponing domestic and international air travel
typically motivated by fear, often far beyond the site of the disaster, and 6) Avoiding public transportation, e.g., taking the bus, rideshare
exacerbate the losses (e.g., von Winterfeldt and O’Sullivan, 2006; Gor 7) Avoiding local leisure activities, e.g., dining out, bars
don et al., 2007; Rose, 2022). The 9/11 Study also found that more than 8) Avoiding shopping, e.g., grocery, miscellaneous shopping
80% of the GDP impacts were due to the almost two-year reduction in 9) Avoiding recreational activities, e.g., golf, tennis, swimming
airline travel and related tourism. Other studies have found that 10) Avoiding large crowds, e.g., sports events, concerts, shows
behavioral responses to disasters can increase BI losses by one or two
orders of magnitude (see, e.g., Giesecke et al., 2012; Rose et al., 2017; For each domain, a representative sample of U.S. adult participants
Gertz and Davies, 2019). was asked to consider their behavior over the six months from
November 2020 to April 2021 compared to their behavior before the
2.2. Causal factors affecting the economic consequences of COVID-19 pandemic (pre-March 2020). Participants indicated whether specific
activities had increased, decreased, or stayed the same in the previous
The CREATE ECA Framework helps us distinguish several different six months compared to the same activities before the pandemic. Par
categories of factors affecting the consequences of disasters. These fac ticipants who reported a change in the activity were asked to indicate
tors can be summarized in general terms as: the amount of increase or decrease and the reason for the change.
• Ordinary direct impacts relating to property damage, economic ac 3.2. Survey content
tivity, and health
• Remediation, repair, and reconstruction A series of specific activities were identified within each of the 10
• Resilience domains, and participants were asked to reflect on their engagement in
• Behavioral responses each activity during the two distinct periods. Participants who indicated
• Indirect economic impacts stemming from the above four categories. a change in engagement were also asked to estimate absolute fre
quencies or percentages of increase or decrease (depending on the ac
In this paper we populate these categories with specific causal factors tivity). To estimate changes due specifically to pandemic avoidance,
related to COVID-19, which become our model “shocks”: participants were also asked to indicate whether the change was due
primarily to one of three reasons: 1) Unavailability of the activity due to
1. Mandatory closures [Behavioral Linkage] COVID, 2) Avoidance of the activity by the respondent due to COVID, or
2. Reopenings [Behavioral Linkage] 3) Other.4 A complete copy of the entire survey can be found in Rose
3. Workforce declines due to health issues [Direct Effects] et al. (2021).
4. Telework [Resilience]
5. Consumption and workforce declines due to avoidance [Behavioral
Linkage] 3.3. Participants and sampling weights
6. Changes in net demand for health care services [Direct Effects of
Pandemic and Behavioral Linkage in part] Data were collected in two separate waves – April 23, 2021, and May
7. Pent-up demand [Resilience] 3, 2021. All data were collected using the crowdsourcing platform,
8. Stimulus packages [Resilience at the macroeconomic level]
9. Indirect effects of all of the above 4
For example, for medical appointments, participants were asked whether
they had avoided: a) routine medical exams, b) medical exams for non-life-
Nearly every one of these factors involves some aspects of resilience
threatening acute problems, and c) recommended medical procedures during
and behavioral linkages. This helps illustrate that conventional top-
the previous six months. Participants were also asked if they had substituted
down macroeconomic analysis is likely to miss important consider telemedicine for in-person appointments. Participants who reported avoiding
ations in estimating the impacts of the pandemic. This modeling an exam or procedure were asked how many they had avoided over the last six
approach serves as a valuable organizing framework for the various months and were asked to select the primary reason for avoidance: appoint
factors and is especially adept at estimating indirect effects (see Dixon ments have been unavailable due to COVID-19 and appointments have been
et al., 2020; Walmsley et al., 2021a, 2021b). Moreover, the dynamic available but were avoided due to the risk of COVID infection.
3
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Prolific, a widely accepted source of online participants for behavioral pre-pandemic activities. The only exceptions to this were two activities
research (Palan and Schitter, 2018; Peer et al., 2017). A sample of U.S. that did not require sustained presence in an indoor facility, namely to-
adults of just over 660 adult respondents was obtained in each wave, for go/delivery dining and outdoor recreational activities.
a total sample of N = 1328. Increases in shopping and dining substitution activities attributable
to COVID avoidance, over and above convenience considerations, or
mandated business closures, were also isolated and estimated in terms of
3.4. Estimating decrease in activities due to COVID-19 avoidance percentage increases in substitution activities. These substitution effects
are substantial, ranging from 23% to 30% for shopping activities to over
The sample of respondents who participated in paid work reported a 36% for the use of to-go and food-delivery dining alternatives, making
mean decrease of 1.25 days/week working outside the home during the up for some of the shopping and dining activity reductions attributable
pandemic due to all reasons, including avoiding exposure to COVID-19. to behavioral avoidance of COVID-19 during the pandemic.
The same sample of working respondents also reported a mean increase
of 0.86 days/week worked at home during the pandemic due to all
4. Trajectory of the pandemic under select intervention
reasons. The sample of respondents with school-age children reported a
scenarios
mean decrease of 2.02 days/week of in-person school attendance during
the pandemic due to all reasons, including parents’ decision to avoid
The U.S. started to screen for COVID-19 at select airports on January
children’s exposure to COVID-19.
20, 2020, and confirmed the first domestic case of the infection on
We estimated the impact of COVID-19 avoidance behavior on
January 21, 2020. A public health emergency was declared on February
health/medical and professional grooming visits in terms of the average
3, 2020, followed by a declaration by the WHO on March 11, 2020, of a
number of canceled or postponed appointments from November 2020
pandemic (American Journal of Managed Care, 2021).
through April 2021. We isolated the effects of behavioral avoidance of
COVID-19 from other effects, such as mandated closures. Respondents
indicated whether they had canceled or postponed three separate types 4.1. Scenarios
of medical-care visits and whether they had substituted telemedicine
visits for in-person visits during the pandemic. Respondents also indi We develop four COVID-19 pandemic scenarios in the U.S. between
cated the approximate number of medical visits avoided (or substituted) January 2020 and June 2022, with a benchmark scenario calibrated
and the primary reason for avoiding (or substituting) during this period. using reported COVID-19 deaths, and three scenarios with alternative
We focus on medical visits avoided due to behavioral avoidance of assumptions on the efficacy of interventions. Our estimates of SARS-
COVID, as opposed to other reasons, such as no insurance due to loss of CoV-2 transmission use a traditional Susceptible-Exposed-Infectious-
job or unavailability of in-person medical visits for whatever reason. Recovered (SEIR) compartmental model. We draw on estimates of dis
In order to calculate the mean number of health care visits avoided ease characteristics and mathematical models estimating the effective
per person due to COVID for those who utilized health care, we used the ness of select interventions and virus seasonality, referenced below.
following equation: Where empirical estimates were not available, we leveraged expert in
terviews to develop the most likely and realistic epidemiological sce
MVA = MVA|AE * p(AE|DV) * p(DV|UC) narios. Our model is described in detail in Hlávka et al. (forthcoming).
The key results of this model are reported in Tables A3, A4 and Figure A4
where, in Appendix A.
MVA = Mean number of health care visits canceled or not scheduled
to avoid COVID, 4.1.1. Scenario 1: real-world scenario
MVA|AE = Conditional mean number of health care visits canceled or In approximating real-world estimates, our model draws on data
not scheduled to avoid COVID for those who reported avoiding COVID published by the CDC until July 2021 (we calibrate it to approximate
exposure, mortality reported for the age bracket under-65-years and the age
p(AE|DV) = Proportion of those reporting decreased medical visits bracket 65-years and older in the U.S., using baseline modeling pa
who reported avoiding COVID exposure, rameters in Table 1 and transmission reduction ratios that result as
p(DV|UC) = Proportion of those utilizing health care who reported mortality estimates aligned with weekly CDC reporting) (CDC, 2021e).
decreased medical visits. The model makes projections through June 2022. Our calibration was
Avoidance of COVID-19 exposure during the pandemic (November conducted at weekly increments in 2020 and monthly increments
2020 through April 2021) was responsible for 0.73 fewer routine med thereafter. We assume that the reduction in the effective reproductive
ical visits, 0.26 fewer medical visits for non-life-threatening acute value attributed to behavioral interventions in July 2021 remains
problems, and 0.10 fewer visits for medical (diagnostic and treatment) consistent through June 2022, but we do not explicitly model new viral
procedures. Respondents’ desire to avoid exposure to COVID-19 strains that may increase compliance or decrease the effectiveness of
accounted for about 0.39 additional telemedicine visits substituted for behavioral and pharmaceutical interventions.5
in-person visits over six months of the pandemic.
The impacts of COVID-19 avoidance behavior across the six 4.1.2. Scenario 2: high-efficacy scenario
remaining activity categories were isolated and estimated in terms of We model a hypothetical high-efficacy scenario to indicate a com
percentage decrease during the pandemic using the same approach as bination of successful policies that would reduce the adjusted repro
described for medical/health appointments. Estimates are based on re duction number to under 1.0, which indicates suppression of
spondents who are engaged in each activity and are summarized in transmission over time. We consider effective disease management
Fig. 1, which plots the percentage of decreased activity. These per policies that other countries achieved through measures such as mask
centages isolate the effects of behavioral avoidance of COVID-19 from mandates, remote work, closure of non-essential businesses, contact
other effects, such as mandatory business closures and stay-at-home tracing, and quarantines (Brauner et al., 2021; Flaxman et al., 2020).
mandates. The bars represent the percentage decrease in activity dur
ing six months of the pandemic (November 2020 through April 2021)
compared to pre-pandemic (before March 2020) activity. Pure behav 5
Our calibration was conducted after seasonality trends (discussed below)
ioral avoidance effects, over and above business closures and other were taken into account, and was specific to the two age groups. Calibration
government mandates, resulted in a 40%–70% reduction in activities results, with cumulative intervention effectiveness estimates for each period in
during the pandemic (November 2020 through April 2021) compared to the two population cohorts, can be found in Appendix Figure A-3a/b/c/d.
4
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Fig. 1. Summary of percentage decreases in activities across six domains during the pandemic compared to pre-pandemic attributable to behavioral avoidance
of covid.
4.1.3. Scenario 3a: very low-efficacy scenario and effects of pandemic outcomes on the behavioral response. Further
The very low-efficacy scenario assumes limited willingness of policy- details about expert input are provided in Section B1 of Appendix B.
makers to adopt public health interventions affecting social contact,
such as business closures. As a result, compliant behavioral response 4.2.2. Data and model inputs
leads to a maximum behavior-attributed reduction in transmission of Drawing on published literature as well as expert input, our pa
32% (based on Sharma et al., 2021). This reduction reduces the effective rameters and assumptions for SEIR and health outcome modeling are
reproductive number from 3.32 to 2.26, on average. Behavioral fatigue listed in Table 1.6
is also taken into account, and, over time, effectiveness is expected to
decrease (see Figure A-3c in Appendix A). 4.3. Scenario specification
4.1.4. Scenario 3b: low-efficacy scenario We present the number of cases of COVID-19 by age, period, and
In this scenario, we use the estimated effectiveness of mask use from scenario in Table 2. Other outcomes of interest are reported in Section
Sharma et al. (2021) in conjunction with the restriction of gatherings. B6 of Appendix B.
Scenario 3b uses 50% as the maximum reduction (in the initial months
of intervention) before declining due to behavioral fatigue (see Appen 4.3.1. Scenario 1: real-world scenario
dix Figure A-3d). Vaccination was incorporated into both the real-world In our real-world scenario, we estimate 142.6 million cases of
scenario and the high-efficacy scenarios. Data for vaccination was drawn COVID-19 by June 2021. Over the full 30-month period, 159.4 million
from the CDC (CDC, 2021f). In our modeling, 90% of individuals who infections are expected (23.6 million among 65+, 135.8 million among
were vaccinated were removed from the susceptible population <65). These cumulative infection numbers represent 43.5% and 49.5%,
permanently and moved to the vaccinated population (see Section B3 of respectively, of the initial susceptible populations in each age group.
Appendix B). These infections result in 910,000 deaths between January 2020 and
June 2022 (see Appendix A for more detail).
Notably, even with a relatively high number of cases and deaths, and
4.2. Inputs
vaccination willingness at 73.54% for the <65 population and 84.96%
for the 65+ population, our model predicts another wave of COVID-19
4.2.1. Expert interviews
deaths in Fall (2021)/Spring 2022 if behavioral non-pharmaceutical
We conducted 12 interviews with experts from variable back
grounds, including scientists in the field of public health and epidemi
ology from the United States, Canada, and the United Kingdom, state- 6
The CDC estimates an undercount of actual cases as a multiple of reported
and federal-level government institutions and clinicians. IRB approval
cases to be by a factor of approximately 4.6; hence, our model does not refer
was obtained, and honoraria were offered. These interviews covered ence confirmed infections to calibrate real-world outcomes (CDC, 2021c). For
multiple areas of interest to the research team, including specification of this reason, we use reported deaths as a source of calibration in Scenario 1.
interventions (social distancing, mask-wearing, and others), uncertainty Where multiple parameter sources were identified, we discussed our choice
in key parameters of interest (notably the infection fatality rate (IFR), with the experts consulted and chose estimates with the greatest degree of
seasonality, hospitalization rates, vaccination effectiveness, and others), support (or least disagreement) among the experts.
5
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Table 1 group. These infections result in 65,000 deaths between January 2020
Modeling Parameters and Assumptions. and June 2022.
Parameter Value Source(s)
4.3.3. Scenario 3a: very low-efficacy scenario
Basic reproductive 3.32 Alimohamadi et al. (2020)
number (R0) Here we estimate 269.1 million cases of COVID-19 by June 2022.
Initial susceptible 274,165,495 (<65) U.S. Census Bureau (2019) These cumulative infection numbers represent 80.6% and 82.2%,
population 54,074,028 (65+) respectively, of the initial susceptible populations in each age group.
Initial infections on 0 Assumed These infections result in 1,993,000 deaths between January 2020 and
January 1, 2020
Daily infected 30 (January 2020) Calibrated based on real-
June 2022.
international arrivals, 45 (February 2020) world data
January and February 4.3.4. Scenario 3b: low-efficacy scenario
2020 Here we estimate 220.3 million cases of COVID-19 by June 2022.
Daily infected between 0 and 947 Calculated based on I-94
These cumulative infection numbers represent 67.4% and 67.1%,
international arrivals, Visitor Arrival Program;
March 2020 through Bureau of Transportation respectively, of the initial susceptible populations in each age group.
June 2022 Statistics 2019–2020 ( These infections result in 1,504,000 deaths between January 2020 and
Bureau of Transportation June 2022.
Statistics, 2021) Achieving the most optimistic outcomes would require a coordinated
Latent period (pre- 2.5 days Vardavas et al. (2021); Rhee
infectious) et al. (2021)
national response from early on in the pandemic (in our model, we
Infectious period 7.5 days CDC (2021b); Rhee et al. assumed most interventions would be in place by April 2020, consisting
(asymptomatic, pre- (2021) of measures such as broad testing, quarantines, isolation, social
symptomatic and distancing, and remote work) so that any further fluctuations in inci
symptomatic)
dence would not result in exponential growth, which was observed in
Hospitalization rate (h) 2.90% (<65) CDC (2021c)
21.21% (65+) the real world. Given insights from the pandemic responses of other
Age-specific infection 0.0969% (<65) O’Driscoll et al. (2021) countries, it is reasonable to contend that better management of the
fatality rate (IFR) 3.3049% (65+) pandemic could have saved hundreds of thousands of lives in the U.S.,
Vaccine effectiveness (VE) 90% CDC (2021a) particularly among the elderly (Brauner et al., 2021; Sharma et al.,
Proportion of population 73.54% (<65) Kapteyn and Gutsche (2021)
2021).
willing to vaccinate 84.96% (65+) weighted by American
Community Survey (U.S. Our analysis has several limitations. Notably, SEIR modeling as
Census Bureau, 2019) sumes homogenous mixing of the population with no specific modeling
IFR Multiplier during peak Under 75,000 Based on Rossman et al. of local outbreaks (Tolles and Luong, 2020). We aim to address the
hospitalization periods hospitalizations: 1.00 (2021)
different dynamics for younger lower-risk individuals, and older
Over 75,000
hospitalizationsa: higher-risk individuals by utilizing two different susceptible population
1.20 pools. Moreover, we adjust for temporal variability by introducing a
Over 125,000 seasonality coefficient, but the seasonal estimates we draw on are not
hospitalizationsb: specific to the United States. We also do not model other health out
1.30
comes – it is yet to be determined what the short- and long-term con
Seasonality adjustment 0.75–1.27 The effective reproductive
coefficient rate is a factor of the basic sequences of deferred health care will be. Another limitation includes
reproductive number and the the dependence on fixed parameters in the initial model design. We
seasonality coefficient. conducted expert interviews to collect independent input to key model
Based on Gavenčiak et al.
design choices. Finally, we draw on external estimates, including the
(2021), see Appendix 5.A.6
expected effectiveness of social distancing, which also contains uncer
a
Based on the onset of highest hospitalization counts in Fall (2020) and tainty and variability over time, and we finalize our disease modeling
Summer 2021, which resulted in local shortages of intensive care beds and inputs in June 2021, before data about the more infectious Delta
personnel. (B.1.617.2) and Omicron (B.1.1.529) variant were documented. As a
b
Based on the reported peak of hospitalizations when many states were
result, our results should be interpreted as approximations of possible
running out of intensive care beds and personnel to provide the highest-quality
disease dynamics rather than accurate estimates for each scenario we
care.
study.
Table 2
Age-Stratified COVID-19 Cases in Each 6 Months (in thousands).
Cases Age under 65 Cases Age 65 or Over
Scenario: 1 2 3a 3b 1 2 3a 3b
H1/2020 30,531 6564 209,178 134,521 3430 617 36,930 18,575
H2/2020 53,606 2143 15,611 47,298 6896 237 6571 17,200
H1/2021 43,923 3900 354 1505 4178 298 40 622
H2/2021 4433 1699 266 376 1834 92 27 36
H1/2022 3347 5455 91 198 7228 139 10 18
Total 135,840 19,761 225,500 183,897 23,565 1383 43,578 36,451
6
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
7
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Table 4
Impacts on Semi-annual U.S.GDP (billions of dollars, unless otherwise specified).
2020_1 2020_2 2021_1 2021_2 2022_1 2022_2 2023_1 2023_2
Difference (% change) − 27.5 − 21.6 − 22.3 − 12.4 − 13.7 − 10.8 − 8.8 − 6.5
Baseline 10,909 11,104 11,292 11,480 11,645 11,810 11,965 12,120
Policy 7898 8705 8774 10,057 10,050 10,534 10,912 11,332
Difference in Semi-annual GDP − 3011 − 2398 − 2518 − 1424 − 1595 − 1275 − 1053 − 788
activity represents of the total output in the relevant GTAP sector (see equilibrium model to examine the impact of COVID-19 on the U.S.,
Walmsley et al., 2021 for more discussion on the translation of survey China, and the rest of the world.8 The model is based on the publicly
results to CGE model inputs). Table 3 first presents the linkage that is available Dynamic GTAP model (Ianchovichina and Walmsley, 2012),
used to analyze the impacts of various types of avoidance behavior in the which is a dynamic adaptation of the widely used GTAP model (Hertel
CGE model and then summarizes the direct impact inputs to the corre et al., 1997; Corong et al., 2017).9 The model is further adapted to
sponding GTAP sectors.. incorporate supply chains based on Walmsley and Minor (2016a,
2016b).10 Current and earlier versions of the model have been used in
5.4. Pent-up demand numerous studies (Hertel et al., 2014; Walmsley et al., 2014, 2021a,
2021b; Walmsley and Minor, 2020a, 2020b, 2021; Rose et al., 2021). In
Pent-up demand represents another important source of economic the description below and in Appendix D, we focus on a few key dif
resilience that helps reduce the negative impacts from shutdowns and ferences between this model and the GTAP model.
individual avoidance behaviors during the pandemic. To estimate the In the model, in each region, personal income is received by
changes in consumer demand for key types of goods and services over households supplying factors of production, and business and personal
time because of COVID-19, we first estimate the “Lowest Point” level in tax revenues are collected by a regional household. This income is then
consumption since the onset of COVID-19. For most consumption cate allocated to private C and government G consumption, and to savings S
gories, this “Lowest Point” took place in early or mid-April 2020. Next, which fund investment, using a Cobb-Douglas demand function:
the percentage increase from the “Lowest Point” level for each category U = Cα .Gβ .Sγ (1)
is estimated at five points in time with three-month intervals. The esti
mates are presented in Appendix Table B-6, calculated based on micro- where: U is the total utility for the region; and.
level data from three distinct sources that track consumer credit card- α, β, γ are distribution (shares) parameters.
spending information or foot traffic data at retail locations across Changes in savings rates caused by the pandemic and to government
different industries (Opportunity Insights, 2021; Unacast, 2021; Safe spending due to the fiscal stimulus are modeled through the changes in
Graph, 2021). these distribution parameters (α, β, γ)11
Factors influencing consumer expenditures during the pandemic Private consumption is then allocated across commodities using
include, but are not limited to, closures and reopenings of businesses, constant difference elasticity (CDE)12
government stimulus paychecks, consumer avoidance behavior, and ( )Υ i
pent-up demand. It is difficult to collect data to separate the effects of 1=
∑
Bi .UP Υ i .Ri .
Pi
(2)
these individual factors. Therefore, we first simulate the actual changes i
C
in consumption using the data presented in Table B-6. Next we compare
the model output with the results of simulations in which several other Where: UP is the utility associated with private expenditure (C);
key factors are incorporated (including closures/reopenings, avoidance, Pi is the price of commodity i;
and fiscal policy), and then attribute any positive differences to the ef Bi are the distribution parameters of commodity i; and
fects of pent-up demand. Appendix D presents more details of the Υ i and Ri are the substitution and expansion parameters of com
method used. Table D-6 in Appendix D shows the actual shocks given to modity i.
private household demand. As in the case of savings and government spending, commodity-
8
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Table 5
Percent Changes in Semi-annual U.S. GDP by Causal Effect (cumulative percent differences from baseline).
2020_1 2020_2 2021_1 2021_2 2022_1 2022_2 2023_1 2023_2
Mandatory Closures − 26.3 − 22.9 − 21.7 − 15.9 − 12.3 − 10.3 − 8.9 − 7.8
Avoidance − 12.2 − 11.3 − 10.2 − 5.4 − 4.6 − 4.1 − 3.8 − 3.6
Deaths and Illness 0.0 − 0.1 − 0.3 − 0.5 − 0.6 − 0.7 − 0.8 − 0.8
Health Care 0.8 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.4
Pent-up Demand 3.1 2.9 5.0 5.4 6.1 5.8 6.2 6.9
Fiscal Policy
Rounds 1–4 7.1 8.9 2.1 1.9 1.2 1.4 1.4 1.6
Round 5 0.0 0.0 1.7 1.4 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1
Round 6 0.0 0.0 0.3 0.0 − 4.3 − 3.6 − 3.5 − 3.3
Totals − 27.6 − 21.6 − 22.3 − 12.4 − 13.7 − 10.8 − 8.8 − 6.5
(3)
− ρ − ρ ρ
Qi = (Di + Mi )
distribution parameter variables as changes in relative willingness to
pay (i.e., like prices) giving the following demand function (as it appears Where: Qi is demand for commodity i by private final consumers;
in the model code).13 Di is demand for the domestic commodity i by private final
qp(i,r) - pop(r) = sum(k, TRAD_COMM, EP(i,k,r) * pp(k,r)) + EY(i,r) * consumers;
[yp(r) - pop(r)] Mi is demand for the imported commodity i by private final con
sumers; and
- sum(k, TRAD_COMM, EP(i,k,r) * [dpp_agg(MAPTC2TCA(k),r) - ρ is the CES substitution parameter (which also differs by commodity
dppall_agg(r)]) i).
- sum(k, TRAD_COMM, EP(i,k,r) * [dpp_stop(k,r) - dppall_stop(r)]) At the second level:
( )−
where: qp(i,r) is private consumption of commodity i in region r;
1
∑ /ρ
(4)
M
ρM
Mi = Mi,r −
pop(r) is population; r
14
Since the model has been adapted to trace global supply chains based on
Walmsley and Minor (2016a, 2016b), the sourcing of imports for final con
13 sumers, investment purposes and firms’ demand for intermediate inputs are
Any change in one commodity’s willingness to pay will therefore impact
identified separately using distinct CES functions. This is not the case in the
demand for all goods depending on their cross-price elasticities with that
standard GTAP model, where imports by final consumers and firms are first
commodity, just like a change in actual prices does. This approach is consistent
aggregated, before foreign sourcing is determined using the CES function.
with the way willingness to pay is derived for the CES function in Walmsley and 15
We also examined COVID-19 impacts using a CES function at this level with
Minor (2020b), where the elasticity is also relevant. The distribution parame
small elasticities and found that the results were not significantly different.
ters must change relative to an average so as to ensure that income allocated to
private consumption equals the weighted sum of private expenditures by
commodity.
9
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
declines. This is achieved through an endogenous “phantom tax,“16 not important since we are examining the short run impacts of the
which raises prices, leading consumers and essential businesses to either pandemic.
reduce demand for these goods or purchase these goods from other Since the model is dynamic, a baseline scenario of how the world
(foreign) sources, where mandatory closures are less severe (equations economy was expected to change without the pandemic must be
(3) and (4)). One of the main benefits of a general equilibrium model is established. To build this baseline scenario, we use historical and pre-
its focus on the allocation of scarce factors of production across sectors. COVID forecasts from the Bureau of Economic Analysis for the U.S.
First, demand for factors (determined by Equation (5)) must equal factor and the International Monetary Fund’s World Economic Outlook (IMF,
supply (FSe )17 2019) for real gross domestic product (GDP), investment, and labor;
∑ United Nations (UN, 2017) data on population growth to update the
FSe = Fe,i (6) 2014 GTAP data to the beginning of 2020 and create a baseline for
i
2020_1 to 2023_2 (in semi-annual periods). The baseline scenario be
The supply of factors (FSe ) depends on exogenous changes in the tween 2020_1 and 2023_2 reflects what the global economy would have
supply of factors (FXe ), such as deaths and illness caused by the looked like if the pandemic had not occurred.
pandemic, and the rate of unemployment (URatee ): See Appendix D for explanations of how the model was applied to
FSe = FXe .(1 − URatee ) (7) each of the causal factors.
10
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Fig. 2. Percent Changes in Semi-annual GDP by Causal Factor. (cumulative percent change over time).
person shopping for goods and services and of the workplace also businesses, and services, in particular, tend to be more labor-intensive
contributed significantly to the decline in GDP. The decline in labor due and hence have a greater impact on labor than other factors of pro
to illness and deaths of workers was relatively small due to the low duction, such as capital.
percentage of workers impacted and the availability of other workers With deaths and illness, the supply of labor declines. Those left un
due to the high levels of unemployment. The small decline in real GDP employed as a result of the mandatory closures and avoidance fill these
here is due to the decline in population and demand rather than the vacant positions, causing unemployment to fall slightly. Similarly, with
decline in the labor force. avoidance, there is also a decline in labor supply as some employees
The remaining factors tended to alleviate the losses in economic avoid going to work for fear of unsafe working conditions, or the need to
growth. Increased demand on the health care sector to treat COVID stay home to take care of children or household members in need of care.
patients had positive implications for other sectors, albeit small. Pent-up Overall, however, unemployment still rises with avoidance as the
demand was found to be an important factor in the recovery, raising real decline in production and demand for labor resulting from the avoid
GDP in the first half of 2020 by 3% and by a further 2% in the first half of ance of non-essential goods and services is greater than the fall in the
2021, which then continued to boost growth due to a rise in investment. supply of labor due to avoidance of work. The fall in labor supply due to
Pent-up demand in the second half of 2020 was found to be relatively deaths, illnesses, and avoidance of work also leads to a shift towards
small but increased again in early 2021. It is worth noting that we only capital that has implications for investment, discussed below. Increased
capture pent-up demand in 2020 and the first part of 2021, although it is health care expenditures, pent-up demand, and Rounds 1–5 of the fiscal
likely that there is further pent-up demand in the latter part of 2021 and stimulus also raise the demand for labor.
perhaps even into 2022. Hence, this is likely to be an underestimate of The impact on investment (Table 7) is generally consistent with the
the longer-run impact of all pent-up demand. impacts on real GDP. There are a few notable exceptions: avoidance and
The fiscal stimulus was also found to positively impact the economy, fiscal stimulus (round 6). Avoidance by workers raises investment
particularly when first implemented. Rounds 1–4 had the greatest because the decrease in the supply of labor raises the use of capital (e.g.,
impact, alleviating the decline in growth at its most severe stages. Round increased automation). Increased demand for capital increases returns
5 provided further relief in 2021, while round 6 was found not to be to capital and hence investment. Investment then adds to capital stocks
beneficial for economic growth, in large part because it was becoming over time, and so increases in investment increase growth in real GDP in
harder to fund the fiscal stimulus using domestic savings.20 the following period. Similarly, declines in investment result in a decline
With the decline in production due to mandatory business closures in growth in real GDP in the following period.
and avoidance, employment of all factors declined, with the largest The different impacts of the various rounds of the fiscal stimulus on
declines due to the mandatory closure of businesses (Table 6). The investment reinforce the results in real GDP from the various fiscal
decline in labor is particularly large, with unemployment rising slightly stimulus rounds. Rounds 1–4 cause investment to increase, while in
more than GDP in percentage terms. This is because non-essential Round 6 investment decreases, resulting in declining growth in real GDP
in 2022 and beyond. This decrease in investment in Round 6 is caused by
government spending crowding it out. This crowding out is exacerbated
in Round 6 because much of its spending is implemented in late 2021,
20
In the first year after the pandemic, savings rates rose as mandatory closures just as savings rates are returning to normal. In 2020, as Rounds 1–4 of
and avoidance reduced private consumption. By the second year, however, the fiscal stimulus are implemented, savings rates rise as people could
savings rates were falling as businesses reopened and consumers increased not spend their money due to business closures and avoidance. This rise
purchases due to pent-up demand. In the early rounds of the fiscal stimulus, in savings provided the government with sufficient funds to stimulate
domestic savings were abundant and easy to access leading to a rise in GDP; but
the economy without significant crowding out of exports and invest
as domestic savings rates fell in the second year, the later rounds of the fiscal
ment. By late 2021, however, businesses are projected to be open, and
stimulus had to be funded from foreign savings. With increased demand for
foreign savings to fund the fiscal stimulus, the trade balance deteriorates, prices
savings rates have fallen; savings are therefore scarcer, and foreign
rise (i.e., real appreciation) and exports and investment decline. savings must be used to fund Round 6 of the fiscal stimulus, which has
11
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Table 6
Percent Changes in Semi-annual U.S. Employment by Causal Effect (cumulative percent differences from baseline).
2020_1 2020_2 2021_1 2021_2 2022_1 2022_2 2023_1 2023_2
Mandatory Closures − 27.9 − 23.5 − 21.2 − 15.6 − 11.2 − 8.8 − 7.0 − 5.7
Avoidance − 11.7 − 8.9 − 6.8 − 4.7 − 3.4 − 2.3 − 1.7 − 1.3
Deaths and illness 0.1 0.7 1.1 0.7 0.5 0.9 1.1 1.1
Health Care 0.1 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1
Pent-up Demand 2.1 0.4 6.1 9.4 5.4 3.9 4.1 5.0
Fiscal Policy
Rounds 1-4 12.0 12.0 1.0 0.7 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2
Round 5 0.0 0.0 2.2 1.5 0.2 0.1 − 0.1 − 0.2
Round 6 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.3 − 4.7 − 3.5 − 3.3 − 3.0
Totals − 25.4 − 19.0 − 17.2 − 7.7 − 13.1 − 9.6 − 6.9 − 3.9
Table 7
Percent Changes in Semi-annual U.S. Investment by Causal Effect (cumulative percent differences from baseline).
2020_1 2020_2 2021_1 2021_2 2022_1 2022_2 2023_1 2023_2
Mandatory Closures − 22.4 − 26.7 − 25.9 − 16.2 − 9.1 − 6.5 − 4.4 − 2.9
Avoidance 1.3 0.1 − 6.5 − 7.7 − 5.4 − 4.6 − 4.0 − 3.5
Deaths and Illnesses 0.1 2.4 3.9 3.5 1.7 2.7 3.1 3.2
Health Care − 0.1 − 0.6 − 1.5 − 1.0 − 0.7 − 0.6 − 0.4 − 0.3
Pent-up Demand − 0.7 0.8 2.4 1.2 6.7 10.1 13.9 18.3
Fiscal Policy
Rounds 1-4 5.1 5.0 6.0 8.5 12.4 12.9 13.4 13.4
Round 5 0.0 0.0 1.4 1.1 1.6 0.9 0.6 0.2
Round 6 0.0 0.0 − 0.1 − 6.9 − 1.1 − 1.4 − 1.4 − 1.5
Totals − 16.8 − 19.1 − 20.3 − 17.6 6.2 13.6 20.7 26.8
Table 8
Percent Changes in Semi-annual Real GDP Due to Deaths and Illnesses and Health Care Expenses under the Alternative Scenarios, (cumulative percent differences from
baseline).
Scenario 2020_1 2020_2 2021_1 2021_2 2022_1 2022_2 2023_1 2023_2
Scenario 1
Deaths and Illnesses 0.0 − 0.1 − 0.3 − 0.5 − 0.6 − 0.7 − 0.8 − 0.8
Health care expenses 0.8 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.4
Scenario 2
Deaths and Illnesses 0.0 0.0 − 0.1 − 0.1 − 0.2 − 0.2 − 0.2 − 0.2
Health care expenses 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2
Scenario 3a
Deaths and Illnesses 0.0 − 0.3 − 0.8 − 1.0 − 1.2 − 1.4 − 1.5 − 1.6
Health care expenses 7.4 5.3 2.9 2.1 1.9 1.9 2.0 2.0
Scenario 3b
Deaths and Illnesses 0.0 − 0.2 − 0.7 − 0.9 − 1.0 − 1.1 − 1.2 − 1.3
Health care expenses 5.8 4.9 3.1 2.5 2.2 2.0 2.0 1.9
implications for the trade balance and trade (see Walmsley et al., 2021). 8. Discussion
Appendix Figure E− 1 shows the impact of the various causal factors
on sectoral production in the first half of 2020. As expected, mandatory 8.1. Impact of alternative scenarios
closure of businesses causes most of the declines in production, followed
by avoidance. These declines are most significant for the non-essential In Table 8, we show how changes in our assumptions about the
sectors, although there are clear indirect implications for essential sec number of deaths and illnesses, and the resulting impact on the health
tors too, as incomes fall and non-essential businesses reduce their de sector, impact the economy. These are compared with Scenario 1. The
mand for intermediate inputs (e.g., pharmaceuticals used in health results show that increased efficacy of interventions (Scenario 2) re
care). The impact of avoidance behavior in accommodation and food duces the impact of the deaths and illnesses and health care expenses on
services, recreational services, transportation, and health care on pro the economy substantially. In Scenarios 3a and 3b, lower efficacy means
duction is also clear. We also see a reflection of some pent-up demand in that the impacts are larger in absolute terms, with deaths and illnesses
the first half of 2020, as people eager to enjoy restaurants increase de causing further declines in real GDP for Scenarios 1 and 2 and the in
mand when businesses resume operation. Rounds 1–4 of the fiscal crease in health care expenditures raising real GDP sizably. The extent of
stimulus (Rounds 5 and 6 are not implemented until 2021) have a clear, the changes depends on the level of social distancing assumed in
positive impact on most sectors.
12
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Scenarios 3a and 3b – with more social distancing in the latter resulting permanent. Nor do we include a measure of the total value of lives lost.
in fewer cases and hence a smaller absolute economic impact.21 Our results should be considered upper-bound estimates for several
reasons. First, we have assumed that reductions in business output are
accompanied by reductions in wages and salaries paid as people become
8.2. Comparison with results of other studies
unemployed, though some businesses continued paying their em
ployees. Second, we have omitted some sources of business resilience,
Few studies have performed a decomposition of the economy-wide
such as the use of inventories, relocation (e.g., haircuts in parking lots),
impacts of COVID-19 according to several causal factors, such as those
and the internet (e.g., education) to continue to help produce goods and
provided in this report. One of the reasons is that many of the estimates
services (Rose, 2017; Dormady et al., 2019). We also do not consider the
utilize macro-econometric or time-series models, which are typically
increase in demand for communications due to the increased use of the
“top-down” approaches and hence less amenable to decomposition in
internet and remote working. Finally, we only include avoidance and
comparison to “bottom-up” models such as ours. However, there are a
pent-up demand in 2020 and 2021. The extent to which avoidance may
few studies that lend themselves to comparison. The first set of studies,
continue is uncertain, but further increases in pent-up demand spending
including one by some of the authors of this paper, has focused on
that are likely to occur in the latter part of 2021 and into 2022 are not
mandatory closures and generally found the impacts on GDP to be in the
considered.
range of 20–25% for closure scenarios similar to those that took place
We also acknowledge the limitations of our model and its applica
(see del Rio-Chanona et al., 2020; Minor et al., 2015; Office of the Texas
tion, as well as of our assessment on how they bear on the results. As is
Governor, 2021; Walmsley et al., 2021a).22 Dixon et al. (2020), using a
the case in most GTAP-based analyses, we assume that, except for factor
quarterly dynamic CGE model, explored the macroeconomic impacts of
markets, all other markets clear and firms are perfectly competitive.
COVID-19 concerning several drivers over a two-year time horizon.
Factors of production are also assumed to be immobile across sectors
They estimated a 19% reduction in GDP at the trough of the economic
within six months, consistent with this paper focusing on the very short-
downturn at the end of the first quarter of 2020 and a 12% decline by the
run impacts of the pandemic. Our results also rely on the estimated
end of the second quarter. They incorporated our estimates of telework
elasticities taken from the literature and used in the GTAP database.
and also included government expenditures on health care and some
Although we calculated the expected changes in government savings
countervailing fiscal policies, such as unemployment compensation and
(deficit) and private household savings separately for our decomposi
tax relief, all of which dampen the negative impacts. CBO (2021b) es
tion, for modeling purposes these changes had to be aggregated into a
timates that real GDP would decline by 11% in the second quarter of
single change in domestic savings, as the model does not separately
2020, resulting in the number of people employed being almost 26
identify government savings (deficit) and private household savings.
million lower than the number in the fourth quarter of 2019. If this rate
were to continue, the decline in U.S. real GDP for the year was projected
to be up to 38% on an annual basis; however, given the reopenings, the 9. Conclusion
overall annual decline was projected to drop to 5.4%.
We refined a dynamic CGE model to estimate the economic conse
quences of COVID-19 over eight semi-annual periods during
8.3. Limitations 2020–2023. A baseline scenario in which the COVID pandemic is
assumed not to occur was first established based on pre-pandemic
This is a short-run study of the impact of the pandemic over the growth forecasts. The COVID pandemic was then incorporated into
period of 2020 to 2023 using data collected or estimated for that period. the model and compared to baseline growth. The various causal factors
While we partially examine the impact of higher and lower efficacy of of the pandemic were added sequentially to decompose their contribu
intervention scenarios on the labor force and health care, we do not tions to the overall impact of COVID on the U.S. economy. These causal
consider the potential ramifications of these or other alternative sce factors include the mandatory closure of businesses and gradual
narios on mandatory closures and avoidance. In addition, we do not take reopenings, the avoidance of workplace and various activities (such as
into account the impact of a long-term decline in labor due to longer- restaurant dining), the impact of deaths and illness on the labor force,
term illness, or “long COVID,” or the potential for behavior changes, the increase in hospitalizations and health care expenses, the fiscal
such as teleworking and avoidance of certain activities, to become more stimulus implemented in 2020 and 2021, and the increase in pent-up
demand once businesses were allowed to reopen. Sensitivity analysis
was performed on disease spread with various interventions relating to
21
We explicitly isolate changes in social distancing. Hence there are no vaccine availability, efficacy, and take-up. The decomposition of the
changes in the other causal factors considered above. For instance, less social influence of various causal factors will help policymakers make adjust
distancing is assumed not to cause less avoidance, and low-efficacy does not
ments to offset the negative influences and reinforce the positive ones
impact business closures or avoidance. This avoids the potential for having to
during the remainder of this pandemic and in anticipation of future
model further interactions between the causal factors and cases/death. As
illustrated above, these other causal factors can have serious implications for
ones.
economic growth (see Walmsley et al., 2021a). This is a stark example of how The analysis of the decomposition revealed that the largest losses
changes in a country’s real GDP (production) do not always coincide with from COVID were associated with the mandatory closure of businesses
welfare movements. and the slow reopening process, followed by the avoidance of workplace
22
Studies of the impact of mandatory closures have been performed for other and other activities by households. While deaths and illnesses resulted in
countries as well. For example, Cottafava et al. (2022) applied the interopera a minimal decline in real GDP, primarily due to the decline in demand
bility input-output model (see, e.g., Santos, 2020) to the impacts in Italy, caused by the declining population, the increase in demand for health
beginning with direct shocks to a few most constrained sectors, as did we. They care led to a rise in real GDP. Pent-up demand is a significant factor in
estimated impacts of approximately €230 billion in 2020, or approximately the recovery process, raising growth ever closer to the original baseline
143% of Italian GDP, which is about 57% as large as the impacts we found for
growth. Early rounds (1–4) of fiscal policy were also very helpful in
the U.S. economy. We offer two reasons for the divergence in the estimates in
alleviating some of the losses in economic growth due to mandatory
addition to the fact that the economic structures of the two countries differ.
First, the Italian study only includes lockdowns for the first 150 days of the year business closures, avoidance, and other causal factors. The benefits of
2020, while our estimates were for a longer period. Second, that study in the last round of fiscal policy are considerably lower, and even negative,
corporates a stylized single parameter measure of resilience, in contrast to the compared to earlier rounds due to crowding out of private investment
detailed analysis of resilience in our study with respect to factors such as and the need for businesses to repay loans.
telework. Several areas of future research present themselves. A prime example
13
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
would be developing future scenarios involving new variants, more examine the macroeconomic consequences of supply-chain bottlenecks
effective vaccines, and more effective anti-viral treatments. Another caused by the pandemic.
would be conducting surveys to ascertain the long-term impact of
avoidance and changes in the way people work. Survey research can also Data availability
be extended to improve the accuracy of estimates of pent-up demand by
major consumption categories. An additional topic area would be to Some data inputs can be provided, but not all data and models.
Supplementary data
We conducted 12 interviews with experts from variable backgrounds including scientists in the field of public health and epidemiology from the
United States, Canada, and the United Kingdom; health officials from state- and federal-level government institutions in the United States; and cli
nicians in the United States. The convenience sample was assembled from experts who work in academic, public, and clinical settings, and who have
published work on COVID-19. Interviews focused on specific issues of interest where literature (at the time of modeling) was limited, including the
effectiveness of social distancing, the likely behavioral response of the public, and the ability of the health care system to handle excessive numbers of
COVID-19 patients during pandemic peaks.
Due to the evolving nature of the COVID-19 pandemic and the limited availability of strong data regarding intervention effectiveness, experts were
consulted both on the parameters used in our model and on possible additions that should be accounted for. Two parameter changes we made on
expert advice are of note.
Multiple interviewees suggested that we account for the effects of seasonality on the effective reproductive number. To account for this variable,
we implemented monthly adjustments to the reproductive number based on Gavenčiak et al. (2021).
It was noted that some interventions, including stay-at-home orders, experienced differing compliance between age groups (CDC, 2020a). While
more granular modeling is possible, the dichotomous distinction between the population under 65 and the population 65 and older has been sufficient
for the outcome of interest in the employed model. Parameters including hospitalization rate, infection fatality rate, and vaccine hesitancy were
age-stratified.
COVID-19 was initially introduced to the U.S. through international travel (CDC, 2020c). Our model estimates the number of international
travelers entering the United States on any given day from 6 regions – the Americas, Africa, Europe, Middle East, Western Pacific, and South and
Southeast Asia. Our model utilizes historical estimates for the percentage of travelers from each region and predicts each traveler’s likelihood of
carrying COVID-19 to determine the likely number of COVID-19 cases entering the country.
International travel trends for the 2.5 years included in the model are adjusted based on domestic travel reduction trends in 2019 and 2020 (Bureau
of Transportation Statistics, 2021; International Trade Administration, 2021), referred to as the coefficient reduction due to travel avoidance (we
abstract from international travel restrictions, which affected the numbers of international travelers unevenly). The incoming travelers are then split
into two age groups: travelers under 65 and travelers over 65 based on historical estimates of traveler demographics (it is, however, possible that older
travelers reduced international travel to a higher degree than younger ones).
We draw on I-94 statistics (International Trade Administration, 2021) and develop a model of infection risk as well as an adjustment for lower
travel volumes due to avoidance behavior. We utilize domestic traveler data from 2019 to 2020 from the Bureau of Transportation Statistics to
determine how many fewer international travelers would have come to the United States, had there not been travel restrictions in other countries
(their effects were not modeled explicitly due to their time-varying nature and limited effect given the magnitude of domestic infection counts). Using
these data, we determine a coefficient reduction (as a fraction of 2020 travel relative to 2019). For 2021 and 2022, we estimate a stepwise growth in
international travel based on estimates by the U.S. Travel Association (2021). The calculation of coefficient reductions for each month between
January 2020–June 2022 is shown in Table A1.
Table A1
Estimating International Traveler Volumes due to the COVID-19 Pandemic
Month 2019 International 2019 Domestic Travelers 2020 Domestic Travelers Coefficient Reduction Coefficient Reduction Coefficient Reduction
Travelers (total) (total) (total) (19 vs 20) (21 vs 19) (22 vs 19)
14
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Table A1 (continued )
Month 2019 International 2019 Domestic Travelers 2020 Domestic Travelers Coefficient Reduction Coefficient Reduction Coefficient Reduction
Travelers (total) (total) (total) (19 vs 20) (21 vs 19) (22 vs 19)
Next, we divide countries of travel origin based on the WHO (2021) and U.N. World Tourism Organization’s classification: Americas, Africa, East
Asia and Pacific, Europe, Middle East, and South and Southeast Asia. Using data from the (WHO, 2021), the percentage of individuals infected with
COVID-19 within each region per month was estimated, which allowed us to calculate the likelihood of a traveler from that region being infectious
upon entry to the U.S.
As Figure A-1 shows, Europe had the largest risk of infection among travelers to the United States for most of 2020 while Africa had the least. For
periods when data were not yet available (starting in April 2021 at the time of modeling, shaded in the figure), we estimated 10% monthly decrements
of a moving average from the previous 6-month period, resulting in a near-complete elimination of the risk of infection by June 2022 (0.03% for a
traveler from the Americas, 0.02% from South (East) Asia, and 0.01% or less for travelers from the Middle East, Europe, and East Asia/Pacific.
Following this, we combine these estimates to determine the likely number of infected travelers by region entering the United States on any given
day. Initially, the most infected travelers came from Europe, similar to conclusions by Gonzalez-Reiche et al. (2020), who suggest that most index cases
of the March 2020 New York State outbreak originated in Europe. Figure A-2 shows the estimated numbers of daily infectious travelers entering the
United States by region of origin.
Figure A-2. Estimates of Infected International Travelers Entering the U.S.(Daily Average by Month).
15
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Vaccination projections for the period starting at the beginning of the model (January 1, 2020) and ending on August 12, 2021 were drawn from
CDC vaccination data and based on a delay period after vaccination, vaccine effectiveness, and an assumption on the number of vaccinated individuals
who had already been conferred immunity through previous infection.
Vaccine effectiveness (VE) was assumed as 90% based on a CDC real-world analysis of the Pfizer and Moderna mRNA vaccines (CDC, 2021d); the
effectiveness of the Johnson & Johnson vaccine was not incorporated due to a lack of data on the exact breakdown of administered vaccines by day and
the assumption that the vaccine was not prevalently used (Follow et al., 2021). We accounted for individuals being vaccinated who have already
conferred immunity from a previous infection by weighting the number of vaccinations (v) given by the proportion of the population susceptible to
disease (S) out of all initially susceptible (S0), as shown in the equation below.
S
S → Effectively vaccinated = v*VE*
S0
From August 13, 2021 until the end of the model (July 31, 2022), we halted data scraping from the CDC and stipulated that the number of in
dividuals transitioning from susceptible to vaccinated on a given day was equal to the average of model days August 6, 2021, through August 12, 2021
(a 7-day average) until the population that had undergone vaccination (including those determined to have had an “ineffective” vaccination regimen)
was equal to the population expected to be vaccinated (Kapteyn and Gutsche, 2021).
In Figures B-3a/b/c/d, we show the percentage reduction in R0 for each week of 2020 and months of 2021/2022 modeled in the four scenarios.
Percentage reduction estimates in scenario 2 were calibrated to approximate deaths due to influenza in the United States over a comparable period.
We use CDC data (CDC, 2020b) to calculate the mean number of influenza deaths over 2.5 years:
Table A2
Deaths Caused by Influenza from 2015 to 2020
16
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Table A2 (continued )
Year Deaths <65 Deaths 65+ Total
Liu et al. (2021) showed that the transmission rate of COVID-19 was time-dependent and cyclical, with reductions during the warm season in the
Northern Hemisphere of 46.38 ± 29.10%. We draw on seasonality adjustments estimated by Gavenčiak et al. (2021), calculated for 143 European
regions, and assume the reductions apply similarly in the United States.
Table A3
Age-stratified Estimated Hospitalizations due to COVID-19 in each 6 Months (in millions)
Scenario: 1 2 3a 3b 1 2 3a 3b
H1/2020 863.8 187.9 5963.7 3746.8 714.0 128.9 7546.6 3671.5
H2/2020 1493.3 64.0 561.6 1528.8 1399.3 51.5 1679.9 3906.4
H1/2021 1352.7 112.5 10.3 45.9 958.6 63.2 8.6 141.7
(continued on next page)
17
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Table A3 (continued )
Hospitalizations <65 Hospitalizations 65+
Table A4
Age-stratified Estimated Deaths from COVID-19 in each 6 Months (In millions)
Scenario: 1 2 3a 3b 1 2 3a 3b
H1/2020 28.3 6.2 228.4 128.3 109.7 19.8 1397.8 599.4
H2/2020 48.2 2.2 24.1 56.4 209.8 8.2 339.5 692.6
H1/2021 47.0 3.7 0.3 1.6 158.5 9.9 1.4 23.7
H2/2021 4.7 1.7 0.3 0.4 54.4 3.1 0.9 1.2
H1/2022 3.4 5.3 1.0 .204 245.6 4.7 0.4 0.6
Total 131.6 19.1 253.2 186.8 778.0 45.6 1739.9 1317.5
Note: Sums of semi-annual periods may not equal total due to rounding.
We indicate how cumulative deaths differ by scenario and between the age-stratified groups in Figure A-4.
18
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Appendix Table B-1 presents the estimated direct percentage reduction in U.S. annual GDP by sector due to mandatory closures and the phased-in
reopening process by 6-month period. We defined three categories of sectors based on the DHS Cybersecurity and Infrastructure Security Agency list of
Essential Critical Infrastructure Sectors during COVID-19 (CISA, 2020): Category 1 includes sectors that fall entirely under the non-essential category
and thus were shut down under the mandatory closures (such as Recreation & Entertainment); Category 2 includes sectors within which only some of
their subsectors are non-essential (such as Retail Trade and Business Services); Category 3 includes sectors that are essential and were, therefore, able
to maintain operation to the extent possible.
Table B1
Percentage Reduction of Output by Sector due to Mandatory Closure and Reopening Process (with Telecommuting)
1–25 Agriculture, Fishing, and Forestry; Mining; Food Processing 3 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%
26 Beverages and Tobacco products 2 2.90% 0.00% 1.30% 0.00% 0.00%
27 Manufacture of textiles 1 10.60% 0.00% 5.70% 0.01% 0.00%
28 Manufacture of wearing apparel 1 14.10% 0.00% 5.60% 0.02% 0.00%
29 Manufacture of leather and related products 1 14.10% 0.00% 5.60% 0.02% 0.00%
30 Lumber 3 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%
31–34 Paper and Paper Products; Petroleum and Coke Products; Manufacture of chemicals and 3 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%
products; Manufacture of pharmaceuticals, medicinal chemical, and botanical products
35 Manufacture of rubber and plastic products 1 11.50% 0.02% 5.50% 0.02% 0.00%
36 Manufacture of other non-metallic mineral products 1 12.00% 0.01% 5.50% 0.02% 0.00%
37 Iron & Steel: basic production and casting 3 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%
38, 39 Non-Ferrous Metals; Manufacture of fabricated metal products 3 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%
40 Manufacture of computer, electronic and optical products 1 13.80% 0.01% 5.70% 0.01% 0.00%
41–44 Manufacture of electrical equipment, machinery and equipment, and transport equipment 3 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%
45–47 Other Manufacturing: includes furniture 1 12.70% 0.01% 5.50% 0.03% 0.00%
46–48 Electricity; Gas manufacture, distribution; Water supply; sewerage, waste management 3 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%
and remediation activities
49 Construction 2 2.90% 0.00% 1.70% 0.01% 0.00%
50 Wholesale and retail trade; repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles 2 5.40% 0.01% 2.50% 0.01% 0.00%
51 Accommodation, Food and service activities 2 9.30% 0.02% 5.10% 7.44% 4.52%
52 Land transport and transport via pipelines 2 2.20% 0.00% 1.00% 0.15% 0.00%
53 Water transport 2 4.70% 0.00% 2.60% 0.28% 0.00%
54 Air transport 2 8.30% 0.01% 4.50% 0.51% 0.00%
55 Warehousing and support activities 3 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%
56 Information and communication 2 0.50% 0.00% 0.50% 0.00% 0.00%
57 Other Financial Intermediation: auxiliary activities but not insurance and pensions 2 1.40% 0.00% 1.40% 0.00% 0.00%
58 Insurance 3 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%
59 Real estate activities 1 7.50% 0.01% 7.70% 0.59% 0.00%
60 Other Business Services not elsewhere classified 2 5.10% 0.01% 5.10% 0.40% 0.00%
61 Recreation & Other Services 1 10.30% 0.01% 14.80% 23.32% 15.00%
62 Other Services (Government) 2 3.60% 0.01% 1.90% 0.13% 0.00%
63 Education 1 4.10% 0.01% 8.10% 10.06% 6.02%
64 Human health and social work 3 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%
65 Dwellings: imputed rents of owner-occupied dwellings 3 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%
a
Mandatory Closure Categories: 1. Sector is entirely non-essential and thus is completely shut down; 2. Sector for which only some subsectors are non-essential (see
notes in the last column); 3. Sector that is essential and thus still able to operate in its usual manner to the extent possible.
For the rest of the world, data were collected on the timings of mandatory closures in each country (Wikipedia, 2020), and the U.S. categorization
of essential/non-essential sectors are applied. Where closures were considered partial (e.g., city- or region-wide only), we applied a 50% closure rate.
Each country’s production data were then used to determine the overall share of the sector closed in the rest of the world, assuming the same essential
sector shares as in the U.S. case. The phased-in schedule of U.S. reopenings was also used to determine the timing of reopenings for the rest of the
world, adjusted for differences in the mandatory closure periods between each country and the U.S. Although our focus is on the U.S. economy, it is
important to capture the simultaneous slowdown of China and the rest of the world that occurred over this period, particularly in a global model. For
this reason, we compared the macroeconomic results for China and the rest of the world with actual data to ensure they were consistent. However, we
did not collect the same level of detailed information about China and the rest of the world, as our focus was on the U.S. and it is unlikely that these
additional details would have had a significant impact on our results.
Appendix Table B-2 presents the average per-patient health expenses by health outcome category and by age group. The total estimated COVID-
related health expenditures for each scenario are calculated by multiplying the number of outpatients, hospitalizations, and deaths by the corre
sponding per-patient cost, and are presented in Appendix Table B-3.
19
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Table B2
COVID per Patient Health Expenses by Treatment Category and by Age Group
Non-ICU ICU
Table B3
COVID Total Health Expenditures (in millions of 2020 dollars)
Scenario Outpatient Hospitalizations - Non-ICU Hospitalizations - ICU COVID Health Expenses % of Total Annual Output of GTAP Health Sector
Appendix Tables B-4 and B-5 present the per-patient productivity losses (measured in days) and the total losses in workdays for each health
scenario modeled in Section 3.
Table B4
COVID per Patient Lost Productivity (in days)
Non-ICU ICU Non-ICU ICU Productivity Days Loss Additional Days in Isolation
Table B5
Lost Productivity Due to Own COVID Illness and Caring for Sick Family Members from COVID (in thousands of days)
Scenario Outpatient Medical Treatment Hospitalizations Non-ICU Hospitalizations ICU Fatalities Total Percentage Change in Labor Force
Appendix Table B-6 presents the percentage increase of consumption from the “Lowest Point” level for major categories of goods and services at
five points in time with three-month intervals after the beginning of the reopening. The linkages to the CGE model sectors and the share of the sectoral
output affected are also presented in the table.
Table B6
Percentage Consumption Changes Compared to the “Lowest Level” after COVID by Commodity/Service Type and Mapping to CGE Sectors
Good/Service 2020.6 2020.9 2020.12 2021.3 2021.6 GTAP Sector Share of GTAP
Sector
Automobiles 79% 65% 20% 200% 200% 50 Wholesale and retail trade; repair of motor 5.5%
vehicles
Real Estate 50% 60% 55% 50% 59 Real estate activities 100%
Air Travel 32% 37% 25% 72% 56% 54 Air transport 94.1%
Restaurant Dining 56% 55% 43% 119% 120% 51 Accommodation, Food and service activities 71.7%
Live Experiences (sporting events, 39% 35% 30% 65% 85% 61 Recreation & Other Services 16.5%
concerts, etc.)
Apparel 72% 56% 66% 143% 148% 50 Wholesale and Retail Trade; Repair of Motor 4.1%
Vehicles
General Merchandise 67% 22% 19% 158% 142% 50 Wholesale and Retail Trade; Repair of Motor 6.8%
Vehicles
Hotels and other Hospitality 45% 49% 54% 79% 81% 51 Accommodation, Food and Service Activities 16.8%
Wellness and Fitness 54% 38% 12% 106% 96% 61 Recreation and Other Services 3.0%
20
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Table C-1 summarizes the main provisions of each of the six stimulus bills the U.S. Congress enacted.
Table C1
Summary of COVID-19 Stimulus Bills Enacted by the U.S. Federal Government
Coronavirus Preparedness and Response Supplemental March 6, Funding for federal, state, and local health agencies, and the purchase of 8
Appropriations Act, 2020 2020 vaccines and treatments
Families First Coronavirus Response Act March 18, Tax credits for paid medical leave, increased funding for nutritional 192
2020 assistance, and unemployment benefits
Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security (CARES) March 27, Cash payments for individuals, extra unemployment benefits, forgivable 1902
Act 2020 loans for small businesses, loans for medium and large businesses, and
corporate tax relief
Paycheck Protection Program and Health Care April 24, Extension of forgivable loan program for small businesses, 342
Enhancement Act 2020 reimbursements for health care providers, and funding for testing
Coronavirus Response and Relief Supplemental December 27, Cash payments for individuals, extra unemployment benefits, and 864
Appropriations Act, 2021 and Additional Coronavirus 2020 extension of the forgivable loan program for small businesses
Response and Relief Act
American Rescue Plan Act of 2021 March 11, Cash payments for individuals, extra unemployment benefits, support for 1825
2021 state and local governments
a
Estimated spending is based on preliminary projections by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO, 2021a) and includes increases in direct spending as well as
declines in tax and fee revenue.
The first bill was signed into law in early March 2020 and focused on enhancing the government’s preparedness and public health response by
providing funds to the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS) and state and local health agencies. Less than two weeks later, the U.S.
Congress passed the Families First Coronavirus Response Act (CBO, 2020a). Like the first bill, this Act aimed to improve the public health response to
the crisis, but it also sought to address the economic impact of the pandemic by enhancing safety net provisions. A paid sick leave provision, which
required certain employers to pay the full or partial salary of employees unable to work due to COVID-19, was estimated to cost $105 billion (more
than half the total cost of the bill) in tax credits.
As COVID-19 cases rose in mid-March, Congress enacted the Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security (CARES) Act, enacted in late March,
which amounted to more than $1.9 trillion in spending and tax credits (CBO, 2020b). The bill included $100 billion for hospitals and $50 billion for
other public health provisions. Airline companies received $w50 billion for not laying off employees. The legislation also provided $340 billion for
state and local governments, mostly directed to COVID-19 response efforts. Three other provisions amounted to approximately half of the bill’s total
cost: payments for individuals and dependents, enhanced unemployment insurance, and the Paycheck Protection Program (PPP), a forgivable loan
scheme for small businesses. The cash payments provided up to $1200 per person making less than $99,000 a year, with an additional $500 per child.
Unemployed individuals received supplemental weekly payments of $600 for 13 weeks. The PPP loans are fully forgivable if businesses use the funds
to cover payroll or other eligible expenses and meet certain conditions such as not laying off workers – we assume that they will not be paid back in our
simulations.
After the $350 billion allocated by the CARES Act to PPP ran out, Congress funded an extension in April 2020 (Duehren and Omeokwe, 2021). The
Paycheck Protection Program and Health Care Enhancement Act appropriated another $310 billion for PPP loans. It also included another $75 billion
for hospitals and $25 billion for testing. In our model, we group these initial four bills because they went into effect during a relatively short period,
from March to April 2020.
Eight months later, after a second wave of COVID-19 infections in the Fall of 2020, the U.S. Congress approved another comprehensive stimulus bill
of nearly $900 billion as part of the Appropriations Act of 2021 (Wall Street Journal, 2020). Many of its provisions were scaled-back extensions of
CARES Act provisions: cash payments of up to $600 for individuals earning up to $87,000 a year and additional $600 per dependent; weekly un
employment supplement payments of $300 for 11 weeks; and a third extension of the PPP program.
In March 2021, following a surge of COVID-19 cases and deaths, Congress approved another major stimulus bill. Some of the major provisions
extended support provided to households and unemployed individuals under the December 2020 package. These provisions included additional one-
time cash payments of up to $1400 per adult and child for eligible households and an extension of boosted unemployment payments through
September, additional funding for vaccines and testing, schools and universities, $350 billion to state and local governments, and an increase to the
child tax credit (CBO, 2021b).
Several issues with the implementation of the CARES Act delayed relief. These issues include confusion among borrowers and lenders about the
PPP program and its eligibility criteria, and difficulties in delivering cash payments to nine million, hard-to-reach individuals (GAO, 2020). State
governments were also overwhelmed and slow to process enhanced unemployment payments (Iacurci, 2021). Finally, the emergency programs
administered by the Federal Reserve only provided $41.1 billion in assistance, a fraction of the announced size of those programs of $4 trillion (CRS,
2021). In the analysis below, we do not model the Federal Reserve loans directly because we assume they will be repaid and because the low uptake
suggests the lending terms did not represent a subsidy relative to commercial credit.
Some economists have criticized the cash payments to individuals as not sufficiently targeted to those most in need, arguing that further increasing
unemployment benefits or extending their duration would be a more efficient use of resources (Schwartz and Friedman, 2020). Coibion et al. (2020)
find that those who received cash payments under the CARES Act on average planned to spend only 40% of their stimulus checks. Baker et al. (2020)
similarly estimate that during the first weeks, payment recipients spent 25–40% of the stimulus, but that share was higher for households with lower or
21
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
declining incomes, highlighting the importance of targeting. In our model, we assumed 7.8% of unemployment benefits and 36% of cash payments and
other household payments were saved based on household surveys (Armantier et al., 2020; Coibion et al., 2020; Leer, 2021).
Another criticism of the stimulus provisions is that they had a limited capacity to restore economic activity for the most impacted sectors such as
hospitality and entertainment, where consumer spending was constrained by mandatory shutdowns and avoidance (Chetty et al., 2020). We assumed
that the stimulus provisions could not raise production in sectors constrained by mandatory closures.
Furthermore, the PPP loans appear to have had a limited effect on preserving and creating jobs, the program’s main goal. The short- and medium-
term employment effects of the Program were small, with many firms using the loans to make non-payroll payments and build up savings (Granja
et al., 2020). Chetty et al. (2020) estimate that the initial round of PPP loans increased employment at small businesses by only 2%, at $377,000 per
job saved. For sectors constrained by mandatory closures, we assumed that a portion of the loans—equivalent to the portion of the sector subject to
mandatory closures—went directly to the owners or employees as income, allowing us to capture some of this effect.
The aforementioned studies suggest that stimulus provisions are not equally cost-effective, and that policy design is critical to meeting the specific
objectives of policymakers. Targeting and timing are important considerations. Provisions that provide aid to the most affected individuals (e.g.,
enhanced unemployment benefits), and sectors (e.g., forgivable loans to airlines) may be more effective than other measures.
For most stimulus provisions, we assume the federal government spends the stimulus funds over time rather than at once. The CBO provides
estimates of the direct cost of each provision, measured as an increase in spending or decline in revenue, yearly for the next 10 years. In the dynamic
CGE model, the effects of the stimulus are estimated every six months. Annual CBO cost estimates are converted to semiannual figures for each
provision by assuming an even distribution over a given year after accounting for the date that the related stimulus bill was passed. Some of the CBO
cost estimates are implemented after 2023 and hence do not enter our simulations, but 98% of the fiscal stimulus spending is estimated to take place
before then. Table C-2 shows how the funds were implemented into the model over time.
Funding for the PPP was assigned to various GTAP sectors based on loan disbursement breakdowns published by the Small Business Administration
(SBA, 2020a). The initial $342 billion provided by the CARES Act for PPP was apportioned to corresponding GTAP sectors based on loan approvals
through April 16, 2020, when the initial PPP funds had run out, but before the U.S. Congress had approved additional funds.23
The following assumptions are adopted when simulating the impacts of loans to businesses. The method used in the CGE simulations depends on
the assumption of whether the sector/firm receiving the forgivable loans is open or closed for business. The distribution of loans is assumed to take
place through the following two mechanisms:
• Option 1: As a direct payment to households when the intention is to give money directly to the workers or owners to survive a period when their
business or place of work is closed. This is simulated as increased payments to households in the CGE modeling.
• Option 2: As a subsidy to businesses when the intention is to help the business stay open and keep producing, despite issues with sick workers and
transition to telework. This is simulated as subsidies split between capital and labor using value-added shares for each sector in the CGE modeling
or where information on who the loans were intended for is available (e.g., workers or owners), this information was used to allocate the subsidy.24
Table C-2 depicts how the amounts for each provision over time for each of the 6 rounds were incorporated into the model as three rounds (1–4, 5,
and 6) and for five major categories (Unemployment assistance; Assistance to households (direct payments and assistance); Government spending
(Federal, State, and Local); Assistance to businesses (e.g., loans) and Corporate tax relief). Not all rounds included all categories and increases in
foreign aid and unallocated funds were not modeled.
Table C2
Total Spending Amount by Round and Aggregate Category Modeled over Time
Round Details 2020 2021 2022 2023 Post-2023 (or not captured) Total
23
The allocation of PPP funds made available by the Paycheck Protection Program and Health Care Enhancement Act, which extended funding for the program, was
based on the breakdown of approvals from April 16 to August 8, 2020, the last such report published by the SBA (2020b) that year. The distribution of the PPP loans
from the third round of funding, provided in late December 2020, is based on the cumulative loan approvals for 2021 after subtracting funds earmarked for live
entertainment venues ($15 billion). In the model, we assume all PPP loans are fully forgiven as Congress has greatly simplified the application process and relaxed the
criteria for forgiveness.
24
There can also be cases in which the loans help the sectors in both ways as illustrated in the above two options. In such cases, we split the loan amounts between
Option 1 and Option 2 depending on the extent to which the sector was subject to mandatory closures.
22
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Table C2 (continued )
Round Details 2020 2021 2022 2023 Post-2023 (or not captured) Total
6 Government spending (Federal, State and Local) 0.0 398.5 266.2 94.9 107.0 866.7
6 Assistance to Businesses (e.g., Loans) 0.0 72.8 3.3 0.6 − 2.6 74.1
6 Corporate tax Relief 0.0 2.7 5.7 − 3.1 − 26.3 − 21.0
6 Foreign aid 10.3 10.3
6 Unallocated 50.3 50.3
Totals 2035.7 2579.1 410.3 ¡16.0 106.5 5115.6
Note: The negative numbers for some of the provisions in later years represent the impacts of tax deferral or removal of some tax exemptions.
In this appendix we provide further details about the model, closures and shocks used in the simulations.
The dynamic model is run on a semi-annual basis. This is achieved using the variable time, provided in the GDyn model (Ianchovichina and
Walmsley, 2012) combined with the approach developed in Dixon et al. (2010):
1. Shocking the value of the variable time by 0.5 each period to represent half a year, rather than by 1 for a whole year. The GDyn model is set up so
that all of the equations that depend on the length of the period are multiplied by the variable time. By shocking time by a half, only half of a
region’s investment adds to the capital stocks during the period, and the percent change in capital stocks is half of what it would have done if time
had been shocked by 1.
2. While the cumulation equations were fixed by the inclusion of the time variable, some of the other convergence parameters needed to be reduced to
ensure slower convergence of rates or return and return to full employment.
3. Similarly, some of the shocks, primarily those related to avoidance,25 also need to be divided by two in order to obtain annualized 6-monthly
shocks. The results from the model were then converted back to semi-annual percent changes by multiplying the result by two.
D2. Baseline
Since some of these variables are endogenous in the standard closure of the model, we make the following closure changes provided in Table D-1:
Table D1
Closures used in Baseline
Variable in model (originally Description Variable in model used for swap Description
endogenous, becomes (originally exogenous, becomes
exogenous) endogenous)
GDP
qgdp(REG) Real GDP afereg(REG) (GDyn variable) Productivity on factors of production
Investment
sqcgdsreg(“all regions but last Shift variables in GDyn for fixing investment. When SDRORT(“all regions but last one”) Risk premium in GDyn (similar to
one”) (GDyn variable) sqcgdsreg(r) fixed, investment is fixed. Sqcgdsworld is fixed (GDyn variable) cgdslack in GTAP)
qcgds(r) = sqcgdsreg(r) + in the standard closure.
sqcgdsworld
sqcgdsreg(“last region”) (GDyn Shift variable related to investment for the last region25 dpsavewld (not in GTAP) Global savings adjustment that alters
variable) dpave. dpsave(r) = dpsaveshift(r) +
dpsavewld
Government spending
yg(REG) Government spending dpgov(REG) Distribution parameter on government
spending
The policy simulations were added consecutively to the baseline. In the initial mandatory business closures simulation, the difference between the
mandatory closure simulation and the baseline are attributed to mandatory closures. Avoidance, deaths and illness, health care, fiscal policy and pent-
up demand are then added consecutively to the previous simulation and the differences between policy simulations is attributed to the addition of that
25
The other shocks to mandatory business closures, labor etc were annualized as part of the initial calculations.
23
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
policy. In this section, we first examine some of the preliminary closure swaps (Table D-2), before turning to the closures and shocks used to implement
each of the causal factors (Table D-3).26
Preliminaries
Table D 2 provides a list of closure swaps incorporated to set the stage for the analysis of COVID.
First, we assume that consumption of essentials remains constant, thereby ensuring that the decline in demand resulting from lower household
income falls more heavily on non-essential items, as we might expect with unemployment and the mandatory closure of non-essential businesses.
As in the baseline, we also continue to fix government spending, but rather than allowing both private consumption and savings to adjust as is
typical in GTAP because of the regional household, we include an additional swap that ensures that any excess government spending over tax revenues
impacts only savings (i.e., the government deficit), and not private consumption. Later in the fiscal stimulus simulations, government spending will be
raised, but for the initial simulations, government spending is assumed to be fixed. We also assume that demand for health care services remains
unchanged in the initial simulations. This allows us to more easily implement the changes expected in health care due to avoidance, illness and
government spending in our subsequent simulations. This also ensures that any changes made to the share of private consumption implemented
through the distribution parameter (dppriv) will impact the savings rate.
Finally, we make a small change to the Dynamic GTAP (GDyn) model theory in order to stop the “normal” growth rate from moving with the actual
growth rate during COVID. This reflects our belief that COVID is an unusual and temporary event, and while COVID significantly reduces actual
economic growth in the short run, its impact on a country’s normal, long run, growth rate is uncertain – particularly over the short time horizon we
consider here. We therefore chose to fix the normal growth rate in the model. This was done to reduce some of the instability in investment and trade
balances caused by excess savings from the mandatory closure of businesses and avoidance, which were eventually used to pay for government
spending and pent-up demand.
Table D2
Closures used for COVID simulations
Causal Factors
To model the impact of COVID, we sequentially add each of the following contributing factors.
Mandatory closures
To capture the impact of the mandatory business closures, we reduce the production of the affected sectors using the expedient device of a
26
We are unable to fix investment for all regions because there is a balancing constraint that global savings must equal global investment. In order to capture
investment in the last region, we allow the global savings to adjust to ensure that forecast investment (for all regions) equals global savings.
24
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
“phantom tax” to raise prices and lower production through a reduction in final demand. To do this we use a closure swap to exogenise sectoral
production and endogenize the corresponding output tax (first section of Table D-3),. The rents, captured by the phantom output tax, accrue to the
GTAP regional household.27
Table D3
Closures and shocks by causal factor
Causal Factors CGE Model Shocks Closure swap (if required) Approach
Mandatory Closures Production (qo(“selected sectors”,REG)) Production tax (to(“selected “Phantom tax” approach used to raise prices and
sectors”,REG)) lower production through a reduction in demand
Reduction in share of private consumption and rise in savings n.a.
rate (dppriv(REG))
Decline in the workforce due Supply of labor (qedusup(REG)) n.a.
to deaths and illness
pop(REG) n.a.
qp_agg(“essentials”,REG) dpp_agg(“essentials”,REG) This closure swap appears in all simulations to fix
consumption of essentials
Avoidance Reductions in the effective supply of labor (qedusup(REG)) n.a.
Reductions in private demand (qp(“selected sectors”,REG)) dpp_stop(“selected sectors”, Distribution parameters approach
REG)
Reductions in government demand for health (qg(” hht”,REG)) dpg_stop(“hht”,REG) Distribution parameters approach
Reduction in share of private consumption and rise in savings n.a.
(dppriv(REG))
Increased demand for health Increased private demand for health care (qp(“hht”,REG)) dpp_stop(“hht”,REG) Distribution parameters approach
care
Increased government demand for health care (qg(“hht “, dpg_stop(“hht”,REG) Distribution parameters approach
REG))
Rise in share of private consumption and rise in savings n.a.
(dppriv(REG))
Rise in government spending (yg(REG)) dpgov(REG) This closure swap appears in all simulations to stop
government spending from falling with income.
Pent-up demand Increased demand for specific commodities and services (qp dpp_stop(“selected sectors”, Distribution parameters approach
(“selected sectors”,REG)) REG)
Rise in share of private consumption and rise in savings n.a.
(dppriv(REG))
Fiscal policy Unemployment and other direct payments to households n.a.
(dppriv(REG))
Rise in total government spending (yg(REG)) dpgov(REG) This closure swap appears in all simulations to stop
government spending from falling with income.
Rise in government spending for the public sector (vg(“ogs”, dpg_stop(“ogs”, REG) Distribution parameters approach
REG))a
Rise in government spending of other specific commodities dpg_stop(“selected Distribution parameters approach
(education and health) (vg(“selected commodities”, REG)) commodities”, REG)
Rise in public sector spending of specific commodities (vf dpf_stop(“selected Distribution parameters approach
(“selected commodities”, “osg”,REG))b commodities”, “osg”,REG)
Rise in health spending on pharmaceuticals (vf(“bph”, “hht”, dpf_stop(“bph”, “hht”,REG) Distribution parameters approach
REG))
Rise in spending on commodities for investment purposes (vf dpf_stop(“selected Distribution parameters approach
(“selected commodities”, “cgds”,REG))c commodities”, “cgds”,REG))
Subsidies to firms for workers and owners tfe(ENDW,“selected n.a.
sectors”,REG)
Corporate taxes tfe(“Capital”,“selected sectors”,REG)d n.a.
a
Variables labeled with a preceding “v” represent the sum of changes in the quantity and price relative to the numeraire. For instance, vg(i,r) is the percent change in
the value of government purchases relative to the model numeraire: vg(i,r) = qg(i,r) + pg(i,r) - ptradewld. Note adding ptradewld to this equation does nothing, it is
added for those who might be concerned about homogeneity when shocking so called ‘values’.
b
GTAP sectors cns, ele, ofi, otp and cmn.
c
GTAP sectors cmn and ele.
d
While tfe is not the most appropriate tax to use for corporate taxes, there is no explicit corporate tax rate in the GTAP model and the other alternative, to (production
tax), was being used for mandatory closures, making tfe the simpler option.
Production is then shocked by the share of the period where no production takes place (Table B-1), after taking into account the ability to telework
within an industry. For instance, if we take information from Table B-1 we see that the beverages and tobacco industry closed down for the equivalent
of 2.9 percent of the year in the first six months. The gradual reopening of businesses meant that businesses were closed for a further 1.3 percent, or a
total of a 4.2 percent (annualized) reduction in production in 2020_1. As sectors reopen or are closed for shorter periods in the second and later semi-
annual periods, these phantom taxes are removed gradually according to the rate of reopening. In the second period, the beverage sector was closed for
less than 0.01 percent (annualized) in total for the period, hence relative to the previous period, production of beverages rose, which we implement
through a fall in the ‘phantom tax’. In the first period of 2021, the sector was fully opened and the endogenously determined rent/phantom tax is
removed completely. In two cases (recreational services and accommodation and food services) mandatory business closures extend into the until the
first half of 2021, the rent/phantom tax only being fully removed in the second half of 2021.
27
We do not include a tax replacement closure, because the regional household collects all the income from factors and taxes (rents), which it then allocates across
private consumption, government spending and savings. Hence the rents from the phantom tax already go to private households, particularly as government
spending is fixed, and hence there is no need to reallocate the rents from the increase in the tax rate to private households by reducing other taxes through a tax
replacement closure change.
25
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
This must be done in several iterations to take account of the indirect effects of closing some sectors on other sectors. For instance, if restaurants are
forced to close, demand for fruit and vegetables or beverages and tobacco used in producing restaurant meals also declines. In some cases (beverages
and tobacco for instance), these indirect effects from the mandatory closures (of restaurants, for instance) are larger than the share of that sector
subject to the mandatory closure, and, hence, we allow these indirect effects to dominate and sectoral production to decline by more than the share of
the sector subject to the mandatory closure. This can be seen by looking at the sign of the endogenously determined rent/phantom tax (to). If the
endogenously determined rent/phantom tax falls (i.e., to is positive), then this was an indication that the model predicted a larger decline in pro
duction than the period during which businesses in that sector was closed. These sectors (and countries/regions) would then be removed from the list
of shocked sectors and the simulation re-run and rechecked. It can take several iterations to obtain the list of sectors that need to be shocked to ensure
all the sectors decline by at least the time of the mandatory closures. In the case or re-openings, we also need to ensure that the sector does not expand
beyond the share of the sector forced to close during that period. We take account of any potential expansion in production over this share; however, it
is captured under pent-up demand, rather than under mandatory closures. Below, in Table D-4, is a list of sectors by region that were shocked in period
1.28
Table D4
Shocks to capture the Mandatory Closure of Businesses in the
first period (2020_1)
qo(“rpp","USA") − 16.96
qo(“nmm","USA") − 17.55
qo(“nmm","China") − 1.86
qo(“ele","USA") − 19.52
qo(“omf","USA") − 18.26
qo(“ros","USA") − 25.10
qo(“osg","China") − 0.67
qo(“osg","ROW") − 1.70
qo(“edu","China") − 12.13
In addition to the business closures, we assume that any income from foregone consumption due to the mandatory closures was saved; savings rates
therefore rise via a shock to the share if private consumption (dppriv).
Table D5
Shocks to US labor force and population due to illness and death due to COVID in Scenario 1
(percent)
We assume all labor types, regardless of education level, are impacted by the same proportion. Thus, we assume that the pandemic does not
discriminate, even though evidence may suggest that lower-skilled workers in customer-facing occupations may have been affected more than other
workers. Given the impact of these deaths and illnesses on the workforce and the overall economy is very small relative to the other causal factors, this
assumption is unlikely to impact our results significantly.
In addition, private demand for essential goods was also reduced to reflect the decline in demand due to the decline in the population.
Avoidance
Avoidance behavior impacted both the supply of labor and the demand for certain goods and services. These were implemented directly as changes
in labor supply and changes in private consumers’ preferences for goods and services, and, in the case of health care, government preferences (Table D-
3). In the case of the changes to private and government demand, closures swaps are required. In this case we chose to endogenize the relevant
distribution parameters (preferences) to reduce demand exogenously rather than use the phantom tax approach. We also assume that total gov
ernment spending is fixexfd and shocked by the total increase in spending, and that any income from foregone consumption due to avoidance was
saved. As avoidance dissipated, preferences and savings return to normal.
The shocks are taken from Table 3 and are then applied to the following variables:
28
Although some declines in trade were also estimated, restrictions on trade were not required for any sector, region, region combination to achieve the estimated
declines, once production was restricted. We therefore implemented no changes in trade.
26
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
- Effective supply of labor by education (qedusup, not in the GTAP model) is shocked by − 3.6443 (or (4.58 + 2.71)/2)29 in the first period.
- Private demand (qp) for education (− 1.59/2), health care (− 29.16/2), trade (− 5.85/2), recreational services (− 21.17/2), accommodation and
food services (-(26.5 + 9.67)/2), air (− 57.48/2) and other (− 4.21/2) transport are applied to the relevant sector. Income not spent on private
consumption because of avoidance is allocated to savings rather than to other goods and services, hence we also shock the share of private
expenditure in income (dppriv) to reflect the decline in private consumption, which increases the savings rate.
- Government demand (qg) for health care (− 29.16/2). Again, government revenue not spent on health care services is assumed to increase savings
(or reduce the government deficit), hence we also shock government spending (yg) by the decline in government spending, causing savings to rise.
Avoidance is then assumed to reverse in the second half of 2021 which is simulated as the removal of the effective labor supply and the distribution
parameters.
Pent-up demand
Pent-up demand was simulated as an increase in demand for goods and services that final consumers had been unable to purchase due to
mandatory closures or avoidance. Pent-up demand was found by comparing actual changes in demand by final consumers to model estimates. Where
demand was found to be stronger than the model predicted, an increase in demand was simulated. Table B-6 provides estimates of demand for selected
goods relative to the fall in demand at the height of COVID (April 2020). Where the model predicts a lower demand for these commodities than the
actual, we assume that the difference is due to pent-up demand. Based on the model results we obtain the following shocks for the U.S. (Table D-6). As
in previous simulations we need to shock demand by private consumers for specific commodities and we again use the relevant distribution pa
rameters to exogenise demand (Table D-3).
Any increased private consumption was assumed to be funded from savings using shocks to the share of private consumption (dppriv). Again, the
rise in preferences and savings are reversed as pent-up demand subsides. Since we were only able to obtain estimates of pent-up demand for 2020 and
the first half of 2021, further pent-up demand in late 2021 and 2022 could lead to further increases in real GDP.
Table D6
Shocks to capture pent-up demand (based on Table B-6 and model results) (percent)
Fiscal policy
The various rounds of fiscal stimulus were decomposed according to both round and mechanism for the U.S. Unlike the other causal effects, where
we also created estimates for China and the rest of the world, we did not implement any fiscal policy changes in China and the rest of world. The
impacts of the fiscal stimulus were separated into three parts: 1) Rounds 1–4, implemented in early 2020, 2) Round 5, implemented in late 2020 and
early 2021, and 3) Round 6, implemented in early 2021. When we prepare the input data for the CGE modeling, detailed provisions in each of these
rounds were categorized by the type of fiscal stimulus implemented. Not all rounds used all these categories. The closures and shocks required to
implement the fiscal stimulus depended on the type of assistance and are summarized in Table D-3 and include:
- Unemployment and other direct payments and assistance to individuals are implemented as shocks to private household consumption via the
distribution parameter (dppriv). The shocks are given in Table D-7. Since these payments are temporary, the shocks are assumed to reverse in
subsequent periods.
- Government spending includes:
o increases in direct government spending on a product (vg);
o increases in public service sector purchases of the commodity (vf); or
o increases in investment (cgds) spending on electronics and communications.
These expenditures are swapped with the relevant distribution parameters shown in Table D-3. The choice between using direct government
purchases (vg) or funneling money through the public sector (vf) depended on which of these bought these goods or services in the base data. For
instance, government buys mostly public services, education and health. The public service then purchases electronics, construction, transportation,
communication and financial services.
29
The survey provided answers for declines over the last 6 months (i.e., 6-month declines in demand). In order to convert these into shocks for the model they are
halved as the way in which they were calculated they suggest total changes.
30
The declines represent the fact that by 2021 less people are admitted to hospitals and hence health expenditures are falling relative to the previous period.
27
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
The direct shocks to government spending over time are provided in Table D-8 below. Again, the increases are one-offs, leading to their removal in
subsequent periods.
- Assistance to businesses and corporate tax relief are implemented as subsidies to businesses’ labor and capital (tfe) or, while a business was subject
to mandatory closures, direct payments to households (dppriv). Amounts received were converted into changes in the power of the tax and
implemented as shocks and reversed as subsidies were later removed.
The fiscal stimulus was paid for by increased borrowing (i.e., using savings). As total government spending increases, savings fall automatically.
The shocks are obtained by taking the increase in cash payments or government spending as a share of the total annual private consumption or
government spending of the commodity, respectively. We assumed that a portion of the unemployment benefits and cash payments were saved and
hence had no impact on the results. The portion saved depended on the type of payment and was based on the data collected on savings rates discussed
in Section 5. Using these data as a guide, we assumed that the share of the cash payment saved (36%) was higher than the share saved from un
employment benefits (7.8%), reflecting the fact that unemployed households were found to have lower savings rates during the pandemic than
households in general.31 Further information on the fiscal policy simulations and results is available in Walmsley et al., 2022a.
Table D7
Shocks to private expenditure to capture unemployment benefits, direct cash payments and
relevant business subsidies
Table D8
Shocks to government spending
Mandatory closures Avoidance Labor Health Rounds 1-4 Round 5 Round 6 Pent-up demand Total
Wheat − 3 − 2 0 0 9 0 0 0 5
Cereal grains nec − 10 − 5 0 0 9 0 0 0 − 6
Vegetables, fruit, nuts − 7 − 2 0 0 9 0 0 − 3 0
Oil seeds − 5 − 2 0 0 9 0 0 0 2
Sugar cane, sugar beet − 12 − 7 0 0 10 0 0 1 − 9
Plant-based fibers − 16 − 6 0 0 12 0 0 − 1 − 11
Crops nec − 19 − 8 0 1 33 0 0 − 1 0
(continued on next page)
31
An issue was the extent to which sectors subject to mandatory closures could respond to the loans and other fiscal stimulus. While we assumed that all sectors
could respond to the fiscal stimulus, we adjusted the amount of the loans by assuming that the portion of the loans provided to closed businesses went directly to the
business owners and workers of those businesses, rather than through the businesses themselves. This limited the extent to which closed businesses responded to the
fiscal stimulus, at least partially addressing some of the issues raised by Chetty et al. (2020) discussed in Section 5. We also ran an alternative set of simulations to
capture the impact of fiscal policy, assuming that those sectors subject to mandatory closures could not respond to the fiscal stimulus. We found that limiting the
extent to which closed businesses could respond reduced the overall gains from the fiscal stimulus, particularly in the earlier rounds when more businesses were
closed. Since each round of fiscal stimulus is temporary, the unemployment benefits, cash payments, loans, etc., are reversed in the following period/s, often to be
re-introduced in the next round of fiscal stimulus.
28
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Table E1 (continued )
Mandatory closures Avoidance Labor Health Rounds 1-4 Round 5 Round 6 Pent-up demand Total
References Bartsch, S., Ferguson, M., McKinnell, J., O’Shea, K., Wedlock, P., Siegmund, S., Lee, B.,
2020. The potential health care costs and resource use associated with COVID-19 in
the United States. Health Aff. 39 (6), 927–935.
Aguiar, A., Chepeliev, M., Corong, E.L., McDougall, R., van der Mensbrugghe, D., 2019.
Brauner, J.M., Mindermann, S., Sharma, M., Johnston, D., Salvatier, J., Gavenciak, T.,
The GTAP data base: version 10. Journal of Global Economic Analysis 4 (1), 1–27.
Stephenson, A.B., Leech, G., Altman, G., Mikulik, V., Norman, A.J., Monrad, J.T.,
Alimohamadi, Y., Taghdir, M., Sepandi, M., 2020. Estimate of the basic reproduction
Besiroglu, T., Ge, H., Hartwick, M.A., Teh, Y.W., Chindelevitch, L., Gal, Y.,
number for COVID-19: a systematic review and meta-analysis. Journal of
Kulveit, J., 2021. Inferring the effectiveness of government interventions against
Preventative Medicine Public Health 53 (3), 151–157.
COVID-19. Science 371, 6531.
American Journal of Managed Care, 2021, 2021. A Timeline of COVID-19 Developments
Bunis, D., Rough, J., 2021. List of Coronavirus-Related Restrictions in Every State. AARP.
in 2020.
Bureau of Transportation Statistics, 2021. Passengers (All Carriers - All Airports).
Armantier, O., Goldman, L., Koşar, G., Lu, J., Pomerantz, R., van der Klaauw, W., 2020.
Botzen, W., Deschenes, O., Sanders, M., 2020. The Economic Impacts of Natural
How Have Households Used Their Stimulus Payments and How Would They Spend
Disasters: A Review of Models and Empirical Studies. Rev. Environ. Econ. Pol. 13 (2),
the Next? Federal Reserve Bank of New York [blog].
67–88.
Baker, S.R., Farrokhnia, R.A., Meyer, S., Pagel, M., Yannelis, C., 2020. Income, Liquidity,
Congressional Budget Office (CBO), 2020a. H.R. Families First Coronavirus Response
and the Consumption Response to the 2020 Economic Stimulus Payments (No.
Act.
W27097). National Bureau of Economic Research.
(CBO) Congressional Budget Office, 2020b. H.R. 748, CARES Act, Public Law 116-136.
(CBO) Congressional Budget Office, 2021a. Cost Estimates Search.
29
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
(CBO) Congressional Budget Office, 2021b. Estimated Budgetary Effects of H.R. 1319, Giesecke, J., Burns, W., Barrett, A., Bayrak, E., Rose, A., Slovic, P., Suher, M., 2012.
American Rescue Plan Act of 2021. Assessment of the Regional Economic Impacts of Catastrophic Events: A CGE
(CDC) Centers for Disease Control, 2020a. COVID-19 Mitigation Behaviors by Age Group Analysis of Resource Loss and Behavioral Effects of a Radiological Dispersion Device
— United States, April–June 2020 69 (43), 1584–1590. Attack Scenario. Risk Analysis 32 (4), 583–600.
(CDC) Centers for Disease Control, 2020b. Estimated Influenza Illnesses, Medical Visits, Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP), 2021a. GTAP Data Bases: GTAP 10 Data Base
Hospitalizations, and Deaths in the United States — 2018–2019 Influenza Season. Final Release 1 Release Candidate 1 Regions. Available at:
(CDC) Centers for Disease Control, 2020c. First Travel-Related Case of 2019 Novel Gonzalez-Reiche, A.S., Hernandez, M.M., Sullivan, M.J., Ciferri, B., Alshammary, H.,
Coronavirus Detected in United States. Obla, A., Fabre, S., Kleiner, G., Polanco, J., Khan, Z., Alburquerque, B., van de
(CDC) Centers for Disease Control, 2020h. Past Pandemics. Guchte, A., Dutta, J., Francoeur, N., Melo, B.S., Oussenko, I., Deikus, G., Soto, J.,
(CDC) Centers for Disease Control, 2021a. CDC Real-World Study Confirms Protective Sridhar, S.H., Wang, Y.C., Twyman, K., Kasarskis, A., Altman, D.R., Smith, M.,
Benefits of mRNA COVID-19 Vaccines. Sebra, R., Aberg, J., Krammer, F., Garcia-Sastre, A., Luksza, M., Patel, G., Paniz-
(CDC) Centers for Disease Control, 2021b. Ending Isolation and Precautions for People Mondolfi, A., Gitman, M., Sordillo, E.M., Simon, V., van Bakel, H., 2020.
with COVID-19: Interim Guidance. Introductions and early spread of SARS-CoV-2 in the New York City area. Science
(CDC) Centers for Disease Control, 2021c. Estimated COVID-19 Burden. 369 (6501), 297–301.
(CDC) Centers for Disease Control, 2021d. Interim Estimates of Vaccine Effectiveness of Gordon, P., Moore, J., Park, J., Richardson, H., 2007. The Economic Impacts of a
BNT162b2 and mRNA-1273 COVID-19 Vaccines in Preventing SARS-CoV-2 Infection Terrorist Attack on the U.S. Commercial Aviation System. Risk Analysis 27 (3),
Among Health Care Personnel, First Responders, and Other Essential and Frontline 505–512.
Workers — Eight U.S. Locations, December 2020–March 2021. Government Accountability Office, 2020. COVID-19: Opportunities to Improve Federal
(CDC) Centers for Disease Control, 2021e. Provisional COVID-19 Deaths by Sex and Age. Response and Recovery Efforts.
(CDC) Centers for Disease Control, 2021f. Trends in Number of COVID-19 Vaccinations Granja, J., Makridis, C., Yannelis, C., Zwick, E., 2020. Did the Paycheck Protection
in the US. Program Hit the Target? National Bureau of Economic Research. No. w27095.
(CDC) Centers for Disease Control, 2022. Coronavirus Disease 2019 (COVID-19): Cases in Hanoch, G., 1975. Production and demand models with direct or indirect implicit
U.S. additivity. Econometrica 43, 395–419.
Chen, Z., Rose, A., Prager, F., Chatterjee, S., 2017. Economic consequences of aviation Hertel, T., Tsigas, M., 1997. Structure of GTAP,” Global Trade Analysis Modeling And
system disruptions: a reduced-form computable general equilibrium analysis. Applications. Cambridge University Press, pp. 13–73. T. Hertel.
Transport. Res. 95, 207–226. Hertel, T., Hummels, D., Walmsley, T.L., 2014. In: Ferrarini, Hummels, D. (Eds.), The
Chen, J., Qi, T., Liu, L., Ling, Y., Qian, Z., Li, T., Li, F., Xu, Q., Zhang, Y., Xu, S., Song, Z., Vulnerability of the Asian Supply Chain to Localized Disasters” in Asia and Global
Zeng, Y., Shen, Y., Shi, Y., Zhu, T., Lu, H., 2020. Clinical progression of patients with Production” in B, Asia and Global Production Networks-Implications for Trade,
COVID-19 in Shanghai, China. J. Infect. 80 (5), e1–e6. Incomes and Economic Vulnerability. Asian Development Bank and Edgar Elgar
Chetty, R., Friedman, J., Hendren, N., Stepner, M., 2020. The Economic Impacts of Publishing.
COVID-19: Evidence from a New Public Database Built from Private Sector Data (No. Hlávka, J., Kinoshita, A., Noor, B., and Rose, A. (Forthcoming). Estimating Alternative
W27431). National Bureau of Economic Research. Case and Mortality Pathways of the COVID-19 Pandemic under Select Scenarios in
Coibion, O., Gorodnichenko, Y., Weber, M., 2020. How Did US Consumers Use Their the United States. CREATE, University of Southern California.
Stimulus Payments? National Bureau of Economic Research. No. w27693. Horridge, M., Jerie, M., Mustakinov, D., Schiffmann, F., 2018. GEMPACK Manual.
(CRS) Congressional Research Service, 2021. Treasury and Federal Reserve Financial GEMPACK Software.
Assistance in Title IV of the CARES Act (P.L. 116-136. Iacurci, G., 2021. Delays for Unemployment Benefits Persist, over a Year into Pandemic.
Corong, E., Hertel, T.W., McDougall, R., Tsigas, M.E., van der Mensbrugghe, D., 2017. CNBC.
The standard GTAP model, version 7. Journal for Global Economic Analysis 2 (1), Ianchovichina, E., Walmsley, T.L., 2012. Dynamic Modeling and Applications in Global
1–119. Economic Analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Cottafava, D., Gastaldo, M., Quatraro, F., Santhiá, C., 2022. Modeling Economic Losses Opportunity Insights, 2021. Economic Tracker. Retrieved from.
and Greenhouse Gas Emissions Reduction during the COVID-19 Pandemic: Past, International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2019. World Economic Outlook Database.
Present, and Future Scenarios for Italy. Economic Modelling, forthcoming. International Trade Administration, 2021. The I-94 Arrivals Program.
Cowan, J., Arora, P., 2021. When Is California Reopening?” New York Times. Kajitani, Y., Tatano, H, 2009. Estimation of Lifeline Resilience Factors based on
Cybersecurity & Infrastructure Security Agency (CISA), 2020. Identifying Critical Empirical Surveys of Japanese Industries. Earthquake Spectra 25 (4), 755–776.
Infrastructure during COVID-19. Retrieved from: Kapteyn, A., Gutsche, T., 2021. Understanding Coronavirus in America,” CESAR, USC.
del Rio-Chanona, R.M., Mealy, P., Pichler, A., Lafond, F., Farmer, D., 2020. Supply and Kff, (, Kaiser Family Foundation, 2021. The HIV/AIDS Epidemic in the United States: the
demand shocks in the COVID-19 pandemic: an industry and occupation perspective. Basics.
Oxf. Rev. Econ. Pol. S1, S94–S137. Leer, J., 2021. Analysis: how much will the $1,400 stimulus check help financially
Dixon, P., Rimmer, M., 2002. Dynamic General Equilibrium Modelling for Forecasting vulnerable Americans? Morning Consult.
and Policy: A Practical Guide and Documentation of MONASH Model. North- Liu, X., Huang, J., Li, C., Zhao, Y., Wang, D., Huang, Z., Yang, K., 2021. The role of
Holland, Amsterdam. seasonality in the spread of COVID-19 pandemic. Environ. Res. 195, 110874.
Dixon, P., Rimmer, M., 2011. You can’t have a CGE recession without excess capacity. Ludvigson, S.C., Ma, S., Ng, S., 2020. COVID-19 and the Macroeconomic Effects of Costly
Econ. Modell. 28 (1–2), 602–613. Disasters” (No. W26987). National Bureau of Economic Research.
Dixon, P., Lee, B., Muehlenbeck, T., Rimmer, M., Rose, A., Verikios, G., 2010. Effects on Martin, R., Sunley, P., 2014. On the notion of regional economic resilience:
the U.S. Of an H1N1 epidemic: analysis with a quarterly CGE model. J. Homel. conceptualization and explanation. J. Econ. Geogr. 15 (1), 1–42.
Secur. Emerg. Manag. 7 (1). Article 7. Minor, P., Walmsley, T.L., Strutt, A., 2015. Vietnam 2035: the Vietnamese Economy
Dixon, P., Rimmer, M., Giesecke, J., King, C., Waschik, R., 2020. The Effects of COVID-19 through 2035: Alternative Baseline Growth, State-Owned Enterprise Reform, a
on the US Macro Economy, Industries, Regions and National Critical Functions. Trans-Pacific Partnership and a Free Trade Area of Asia and the Pacific. International
Report to the US Department of Homeland Security, Centre of Policy Studies, Bank for Reconstruction and Development-World Bank Group (IBRD).
Victoria University, Melbourne, Australia. New York Times, 2021. See Reopening Plans and Mask Mandates for All 50 States.
Dormady, N., Rose, A., Morin, C.B., Roa-Henriquez, A., 2022. The Cost-Effectiveness of O’Driscoll, M., Ribeiro Dos Santos, G., Wang, L., Cummings, D.A.T., Azman, A.S.,
Economic Resilience. International Journal of Production Economics 244, 108371. Paireau, J., Fontanet, A., Cauchemez, S.’, Salje, H., 2021. Age-specific mortality and
Dormady, N., Rose, A., Rosoff, H., Roa-Henriquez, A., 2019. Estimating the cost- immunity patterns of SARS-CoV-2. Nature 590 (7844), 140–145.
effectiveness of resilience to disasters: survey instrument design and refinement of Office of the Texas Governor, 2021. Governor’s Strike Force to Open Texas.
primary data. In: Ruth, M., Reisemann, S.G. (Eds.), Handbook on Resilience of Socio- Palan, S., Schitter, C., 2018. Prolific.ac—a subject pool for online experiments. Journal of
Technical Systems. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham. Behavioral and Experimental Finance 17, 22–27.
Duehren, A., Omeokwe, A., 2021. What’s in the New Coronavirus Stimulus Bill,” Wall Peer, E., Brandimarte, L., Samat, S., Acquisti, A., 2017. Beyond the Turk: alternative
Street Journal. platforms for crowdsourcing behavioral research. J. Exp. Soc. Psychol. 70, 153–163.
Flaxman, S., Mishra, S., Gandy, S., Unwin, H.J.T., Mellan, T.A., Coupland, H., Prager, F., Wei, D., Rose, A., 2017. Total economic consequences of an influenza
Whittaker, C., Zhu, H., Berah, T., Eaton, J.W., Monod, M., , Imperial College COVID- outbreak in the United States. Risk Anal. 37 (1), 4–19.
19 Response Team, Ghani, A.C., Donnelly, C.A., Riley, S., Vollmer, M.A.C., Rhee, C., Kanjilal, S., Baker, M., Klompas, M., 2021. Duration of severe acute respiratory
Ferguson, N.M., Okell, L.C., Bhatt, S., 2020. Estimating the effects of non- syndrome coronavirus 2 (SARS-CoV-2) infectivity: when is it safe to discontinue
pharmaceutical interventions on COVID-19 in Europe. Nature 584 (7820), 257–261. isolation? Clin. Infect. Dis. 72 (8), 1467–1474.
Florida Department of Health, 2021. Plan for Florida’s Recovery. Rose, A, 2015. Macroeconomic Consequences of Terrorist Attacks: Estimation for the
Follow, L.H., Lopes, L., Sparks, G., Stokes, M., Brodie, M., 2021. KFF COVID-19 Vaccine Analysis of Policies and Rules. In: Mansfield, C., Smith, V.K. (Eds.), Benefit Transfer
Monitor: April 2021. Kaiser Family Foundation. for the Analysis of DHS Policies and Rules. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
Fusco, M., Shea, K., Lin, J., Nguyen, J., Angulo, F., Benigno, M., Malhotra, D., Emir, B., Rose, A., 2017. Defining and Measuring Economic Resilience from a Societal,
Sung, A., Hammond, J., Stoychev, S., Charos, A., 2021. Health outcomes and Environmental and Security Perspective. Springer, Singapore.
economic burden of hospitalized COVID-19 patients in the United States. J. Med. Rose, A., 2021. COVID-19 economic impacts in perspective: a comparison to recent U.S.
Econ. 24 (1), 308–317. Disasters. Int. J. Disaster Risk Reduc. 60, 102317.
Gavenčiak, T., Monrad, J.T., Leech, G., Sharma, M., Mindermann, S., Brauner, J.M., Rose, A., Liao, S., 2005. Modeling Regional Economic Resilience to Disasters: A
Bhatt, S., Kulveit, J., 2021. Seasonal Variation in SARS-CoV-2 Transmission in Computable General Equilibrium Analysis of Water Service Disruptions. Journal of
Temperate climates.” medRxiv. Regional Science 45 (1), 75–112.
Gertz, A., Davies, J., Black, S., 2019. A CGE framework for modeling the economics of Rose, A., Oladosu, G., Lee, B., Beeler Asay, G., 2009. The economic impacts of the 2001
flooding and recovery in a major urban area. Risk Anal. 39 (6), 1314–1341. terrorist attacks on the world trade center: a computable general equilibrium
analysis. Peace Econ. Peace Sci. Publ. Pol. 15 (2). Article 6.
30
T. Walmsley et al. Economic Modelling 120 (2023) 106147
Rose, A., 2022. Behavioral Consequences of Disasters: A Basis for Inclusion in Benefit- U.S. Census Bureau, 2019. American Community Survey.
Cost Analysis. Economics of Disasters and Climate Change 6, 213–223. Vardavas, R., Lima, P.N., Baker, L., 2021. Modeling COVID-19 Nonpharmaceutical
Rose, A., Avetisyan, M., Chatterjee, S., 2014. A framework for analyzing the economic Interventions: Exploring Periodic NPI Strategies,” medRxiv.
tradeoffs between urban commerce and security. Risk Anal. 34 (5), 1554–1579. von Winterfeldt, D., O’Sullivan, T.M., 2006. Should We Protect Commercial Airplanes
Rose, A., Avetisyan, M., Rosoff, H., Burns, W., Slovic, P., Chan, O., 2017. The role of Against Surface-to-Air Missile Attacks by Terrorists? Decision Analysis 3 (2), 63–75.
behavioral responses in the total economic consequences of terrorist attacks on U.S. Wall Street Journal, 2020. What’s in the $900 Billion Covid-19 Relief Bill.
Air travel targets. Risk Anal. 37 (7), 1403–1418. Walmsley, T.L., Minor, P.J., 2016a. ImpactECON Global Supply Chain Database:
Rose, A., Walmsley, T., Wei, D., 2021. Spatial transmission of the economic impacts of Documentation of Data Sources and the Construction Process of IE-SC_v2.0,” Data
COVID-19 through international trade. Letters in Spatial and Resource Sciences, 14, and Model Documentation—002 REV-2. ImpactECON, Boulder, CO, USA.
169–196. Walmsley, T.L., Minor, P.J., 2016b. ImpactECON Global Supply Chain Model:
Rosoff, H., John, R.S., Prager, F., 2012. Flu, risks, and videotape: escalation of fear and Documentation of Model Changes,” ImpactECON Working Paper No. 06.
avoidance behavior. Risk Anal. 32 (4), 729–743. ImpactECON, Boulder, CO, USA.
Rosoff, H., Siko, R., John, R.S., Burns, W., 2013. Should I stay or should I go? An Walmsley, T.L., Minor, P.J., 2020a. US trade actions against China: a supply chain
experimental study of health and financial risk communication following a severe perspective. Foreign Trade Rev. 55 (3), 337–371.
biological attack. Environment, Systems, and Decisions 33 (1), 121–137. Walmsley, T.L., Minor, P.J., 2020b. Non-tariff measures in applied trade models: demand
Rossman, H., Meir, T., Somer, J., Shilo, S., Gutman, R., Ben Arie, A., Segal, E., Shalit, U., shifts and willingness to pay. World Econ. 43 (6), 1499–1520.
Gorfine, M., 2021. Hospital load and increased COVID-19 related mortality in Israel. Walmsley, T.L., Minor, P.J., 2021. Reversing nafta: a supply chain perspective. In:
Nat. Commun. 12 (1), 1–7. Dixon, P., Francois, J., van der Mensbrugghe, D. (Eds.), Policy Analysis And Modeling
SafeGraph, 2021. The Impact of Coronavirus (COVID-19) on Foot Traffic. Retrieved Of the Global Economy: A Festschrift Celebrating Thomas Hertel. Singapore, vol. 76.
from: World Scientific Studies in International Economics.
Santos, J., 2020. Using input-output analysis to model the impact of pandemic mitigation Walmsley, T.L., Strutt, A., 2011. Implications of the Global Financial Crisis for China: A
and suppression measures on the workforce. Sustain. Prod. Consum. 23, 249–255. Dynamic CGE Analysis to 2020”. Economics Research International, October.
Schoening, E., Wilcox, L., 2021. State-by-State Status Updates on Covid-19 Restrictions. Walmsley, T.L., Hertel, T.W., Hummels, D., 2014. Developing a multi-regional IO
Northstar Meetings Group. framework from GTAP. In: Ferrarini, B., Hummels, D. (Eds.), Asia and Global
Schwartz, N.D., Friedman, G., 2020. Stimulus Money Should Have Gone to the Jobless, Production Networks-Implications for Trade, Incomes and Economic Vulnerability.
Economists Say. New York Times. Asian Development Bank and Edgar Elgar Publishing.
Sharma, M., Mindermann, S., Rogers-Smith, C., Leech, G., Snodin, B., Ahuja, J., Walmsley, T., John, R., Wei, D., Hlávka, J., Rose, A., Machado, J., Byrd, K., Kinoshita, A.,
Sandbrink, J.B., Monrad, J.T., Altman, G., Dhaliwal, G., Finnveden, L., Norman, A.J., Noor, B., 2021. Macroeconomic Consequences of the COVID-19 Pandemic. Final
Oehm, S.B., Sandkühler, J.F., Mellan, T., Kulveit, J., Chindelevitch, L., Flaxman, S., Report to the Center for Accelerating Operational Efficiency (CAOE), Center for Risk
Gal, Y., Mishra, S., Brauner, J.M., Bhatt, S., 2021. Understanding the Effectiveness of and Economic Analysis of Threats and Emergencies (CREATE). University of
Government Interventions in Europe’s Second Wave of COVID-19.” medRxiv. Southern California, Los Angeles, CA.
(SBA) Small Business Administration, 2020a. Paycheck Protection Program (PPP) Walmsley, T., Rose, A., Wei, D., 2021a. Impact on the U.S. Macroeconomy of mandatory
Report: Approvals through 12 PM EST 4/16/2020. business closures in response to the COVID-19 pandemic. Appl. Econ. Lett. 28 (15),
(SBA) Small Business Administration, 2020b. Paycheck Protection Program (PPP) 1293–1300.
Report: Approvals through 08/08/2020. Walmsley, T., Rose, A., Wei, D., 2021b. The impacts of the coronavirus on the economy
State of California, 2021. Current Safety Measures. of the United States. Economics of Disasters and Climate Change 5 (1), 1–52.
State of Illinois, 2021. Restore Illinois. Walmsley, T., Machado, J., Rose, A., Wei, D., John, R., Hlávka, J., Rose, A., Byrd, K.,
State of New York, 2021. Archived Industry Guidance. 2022a. In: The Impact of COVID-19 Fiscal Stimulus Legislation on the U.S. Economic
Sue Wing, I., Rose, A., Wein, A., 2016. Impacts of the USGS ARkStorm scenario on the Recovery. Center for Risk and Economic Analysis for Threats and Emergencies
California economy. Nat. Hazards Rev. 17 (4). A4015002-2. (CREATE)..
Thunström, L., Newbold, S.C., Finnoff, D., Ashworth, M., Shogren, J.F., 2020. The Walmsley, T., Machado, J., Rose, A., Wei, D., John, R., Hlávka, J., Byrd, K., 2022b. The
benefits and costs of using social distancing to flatten the curve for COVID-19. Impact of COVID-19 Fiscal Stimulus on the US Economic Recovery. Available at
J. Benefit-Cost Anal. 11 (2), 1–27. SSRN 4211727.
Ting, F., Duree, R., 2020. Governor Announces Phased Reopening Roadmap,” California Wei, D., Chen, Z., Rose, A., 2020. Evaluating the Role of Resilience in Recovering from
State Association of Counties. Major Port Disruptions: A Multi-Regional Analysis. Papers in Regional Science 99
U.S. Travel Association, 2021. TRAVEL FORECAST | SPRING/SUMMER 2021. (6), 1691–1722.
Tolles, J., Luong, T., 2020. Modeling Epidemics With Compartmental Models. JAMA WHO, 2021. WHO Coronavirus (COVID-19) Dashboard.
Guide to Statistics and. Methods 323 (24), 2515–2516. Wikipedia, 2020. COVID-19 Lockdowns.
Unacast, 2021. Retail Impact Scoreboard. Retrieved from. Wu, J., Smith, S., Khurana, M., Siemaszko, C., DeJesus-Banos, B., 2020. Stay-at-home
United Nations (UN), Population Division, 2019. World Population Prospects 2019,” Orders across the Country. CNBC.
United Nations. Available at: Zhao, W., Yu, S., Zha, X., Wang, N., Pang, Q., Li, D., Li, A., 2020. Clinical Characteristics
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), 2021. Labor Force Statistics from the Current and Durations of Hospitalized Patients with COVID-19 in Beijing: A Retrospective
Population Survey: Supplemental Data Measuring the Effects of the Coronavirus Cohort Study.
(COVID-19) Pandemic on the Labor Market.
31