Introduction To Dynamic Financial Analysis: Journal Article
Introduction To Dynamic Financial Analysis: Journal Article
Introduction To Dynamic Financial Analysis: Journal Article
Journal Article
Author(s):
Kaufmann, Roger; Gadmer, Andreas; Klett, Ralf
Publication date:
2001
Permanent link:
https://doi.org/10.3929/ethz-b-000422515
Rights / license:
In Copyright - Non-Commercial Use Permitted
This page was generated automatically upon download from the ETH Zurich Research Collection.
For more information, please consult the Terms of use.
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS
BY
ABSTRACT
In the last few years we have witnessed growing interest in Dynamic Financial
Analysis (DFA) in the nonlife insurance industry. DFA combines many eco-
nomic and mathematical concepts and methods. It is almost impossible to
identify and describe a unique DFA methodology. There are some DFA soft-
ware products for nonlife companies available in the market, each of them
relying on its own approach to DFA. Our goal is to give an introduction into
this field by presenting a model framework comprising those components
many DFA models have in common. By explicit reference to mathematical
language we introduce an up-and-running model that can easily be imple-
mented and adjusted to individual needs. An application of this model is pre-
sented as well.
1. WHAT is DFA
1.1. Background
In the last few years, nonlife insurance corporations in the US, Canada and
also in Europe have experienced, among other things, pricing cycles accompa-
nied by volatile insurance profits and increasing catastrophe losses contrasted
by well performing capital markets, which gave rise to higher realized capital
gains. These developments impacted shareholder value as well as the solvency
position of many nonlife companies. One of the key strategic objectives of a
1
The article is partially based on a diploma thesis written in cooperation with Zurich Financial Ser-
vices. Further research of the first author was supported by Credit Suisse Group, Swiss Re and UBS
AG through RiskLab, Switzerland.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
214 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
The first step to compare different strategies is to fix a time horizon they
should apply to. On the one hand we would like to model over as long a time
period as possible in order to see the long-term effects of a chosen strategy. In
particular, effects concerning long-tail business only appear after some years
and can hardly be recognized in the first few years. On the other hand, simu-
lated values become more unreliable the longer the projection period, due to
accumulation of process and parameter risk over time. A projection period of
five to ten years seems to be a reasonable choice. Usually the time period is
split into yearly, quarterly or monthly sub periods.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 215
of occurrence and the size of claims are uncertain. Claim costs in nonlife are
inflation sensitive, whereas they are expressed in nominal terms for many tra-
ditional life insurance products. In order to cope with the stochastic nature of
nonlife liabilities and assets, their number and their complex interactions, we
have to rely on stochastic simulations.
DFA is not an academic discipline per se. It borrows many well-known con-
cepts and methods from economics and statistics. It is part of the financial
management of the firm. As such it is committed to management of prof-
itability and financial stability (risk control function of DFA). While the
first task aims at maximizing shareholder value, the second one serves main-
taining customer value. Within these two seemingly conflicting coordinates
DFA tries to
• strategic asset allocation,
• capital allocation,
• performance measurement,
• market strategies,
• business mix,
• pricing decisions,
• product design,
• and others.
This listing suggests that DFA goes beyond designing an asset allocation
strategy. In fact, portfolio managers will be affected by DFA decisions as well
as underwriters. Concrete implementation and application of a DFA model
depends on two fundamental and closely related questions to be answered
beforehand:
1. Who is the primary beneficiary of a DFA analysis (shareholder, management,
policyholders)?
2. What are the company individual objectives?
The answer to the first question determines specific accounting rules to be
taken into account as well as scope and detail of the model. For example,
those companies only interested in getting a tool for enhancing their asset
allocation on very high aggregation level will not necessarily target a model
that emphasizes every detail of simulating liability cash flows. Smith [39] has
pointed out that making money for shareholders has not been the primary
motivation behind developments in ALM (or DFA). Furthermore, relying on
the Modigliani-Miller theorem (see Modigliani and Miller [34]) he put for-
ward the hypothesis that a cost benefit analysis of asset/liability studies might
reveal that costs fall on shareholders but benefits on management or customers.
Our general conclusion is that company individual objectives - in particular
with respect to the target group - have to be identified and formulated before
starting the DFA analysis.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
216 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
return
risk
FIGURE 1.1: Efficient frontier.
For each level of risk there is a maximal return that cannot be exceeded, giving
rise to an efficient frontier. But the exact position of the efficient frontier is
unknown. There is no absolute certainty whether a strategy is really efficient
or not. DFA is not necessarily a method to come up with an optimal strategy.
DFA is predominantly a tool to compare different strategies in terms of risk
and return. Unfortunately, comparison of strategies may lead to completely
different results as we change the return or risk measure. A different measure
may lead to a different preferred strategy. This will be illustrated in Section 4.
Though efficient frontiers are a good means of communicating the results
of DFA because they are well-known, some words of criticism are in place.
Cumberworth, Hitchcox, McConnell and Smith [10] have pointed out that
there are pitfalls related to efficient frontiers one has to be aware of. They criti-
cize that typical efficient frontier uses risk measures that mix together system-
atic risk (non-diversifiable by shareholders) and non-systematic risk, which
blurs the shareholder value perspective. In addition to that, efficient frontiers
might give misleading advice if they are used to address investment decisions
once the concept of systematic risk has been factored into the equation.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 217
A concept closely related to DFA is solvency testing where the financial posi-
tion of the company is evaluated from the perspective of the customers. The
central idea is to quantify in probabilistic terms whether the company will
be able to meet its commitments in the future. This translates into determin-
ing the necessary amount of capital given the level of risk the company is
exposed to. For example, does the company have enough capital to keep the
probability of loosing a • 100% of its capital below a certain level for the risks
taken? DFA provides a whole probability distribution of surplus. For each
level a the probability of loosing a • 100% can be derived from this distribu-
tion. Thus DFA serves as a solvency testing tool as well. More information
about solvency testing can be found in Schnieper [37] and [38].
/
output
/
analyze output,
revise strategy
Most DFA models consist of three major parts, as shown in Figure 1.2. The
stochastic scenario generator produces realizations of random variables repre-
senting the most important drivers of business results. A realization of a ran-
dom variable in the course of simulation corresponds to fixing a scenario.
The second data source consists of company specific input (e.g. mean severity
of losses per line of business and per accident year), assumptions regarding
model parameters (e.g. long-term mean rate in a mean reverting interest rate
model), and strategic assumptions (e.g. investment strategy). The last part,
the output provided by the DFA model, can then be analyzed by management
in order to improve the strategy, i.e. make new strategic assumptions. This
can be repeated until management is convinced by the superiority of a certain
strategy. As pointed out in Cumberworth, Hitchcox, McConnell and Smith
[10] interpretation of the output is an often neglected and non-appreciated
part in DFA modelling. For example, an efficient frontier leaves us still with a
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
218 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
variety of equally desirable strategies. At the end of the day management has
to decide for only one of them and selection of a strategy based on preference
or utility functions does not seem to provide a practical solution in every case.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 219
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
220 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
By setting y = 0.5 we arrive at CIR also known as the square root process
where
rt = instantaneous short-term interest rate,
b = long-term mean,
a = constant that determines the speed of reversion of the interest rate
toward its long-run mean b,
s = volatility of the interest rate process,
(Zt) = standard Brownian motion.
CIR is a mean-reverting process where the short rate stays almost surely pos-
itive. Moreover, CIR allows for an affine model of the term structure making
the model analytically more tractable. Nevertheless, some studies have shown
(see Rogers [36]) that one-factor models in general do not satisfactorily fit
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 221
where
rt = the instantaneous short-term interest rate at the beginning of year t,
Zt~Jf (0,1), Zu Z2, ... i.i.d.,
a, b, s as in (2.2).
Cox, Ingersoll and Ross [9] have shown that rates modelled by (2.2) are posi-
tive almost surely. Although it is hard for the short rate process to go negative
in the discrete version of the last equation the probability is not zero. To be
sure we changed equation (2.3) to
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
222 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
(2.6) r
t\~
where
2Ge(a+G)TI2
(a + G)(eGT-l)+2G'
G=Ja2+2?.
A proof of this result can be found in Lamberton and Lapeyre [27, pp. 129-
133]. Note, that the expectation operator is taken with respect to the martin-
gale measure <Q assuming that equation (2.2) is set up under the martingale
measure Q.as well. The continuously compounded spot rates RtT at time t
derived from equation (2.6) determine the modelled term structure of zero-
coupon yields at time t:
n-n R - lo&F(t,T,(rt))_rtBT-\ogAT
(2.8) it=a'+b'
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 223
where
£, 7 ~^(0,l), e(,e'2,... ild.,
a1, b1, a1: parameters that can be estimated by regression, based on historical
data.
(2.9) Sf=max(aF+bfit+GFsf,-l),
(2.10) df f
(2.H) df=(l+df)(l+df)~l,
where
ef~M(0,\), fif, ef, ... i.i.d.,
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
224 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
(e.g. when inflation is high) policyholders tend to report more claims in cer-
tain lines of business.
where
t0 + 1 = first year to be modelled.
The major asset classes of a nonlife insurance company comprise fixed income
type assets, stocks and real estate. Here, we confine ourselves to a description
of the model employed for stocks. Modelling stocks can start either with con-
centrating on stock prices or stock returns (although both methods should
turn out to be equivalent in the end). We followed the last approach since we
could rely on a well established theory relating stock returns and the risk-free
interest rate: the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) going back to Sharpe-
Lintner, see for example Ingersoll [22].
In order to apply CAPM we needed to model the return of a portfolio that
is supposed to represent the stock market as a whole, the market portfolio.
Assuming a significant correlation between stock and bond prices and taking
into account multi-periodicity of a DFA model we came up with the follow-
ing linear model for the stock market return in projection year t conditional
on the one-year spot rate Rtl at time t.
(2.14) E [r™\Rt, i] = a
where
u
e - l = risk-free return, see (2.7),
a , bM - parameters that can be estimated by regression, based on historical
M
Since we modelled sub periods of length one year, we conditioned on the one-
year spot rate. Note that rt must not be confused with the instantaneous
short-term interest rate rt in CIR. Note also that a negative value of bM means
that increasing interest rates entail expected stock prices falling.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 225
Now we can apply the CAPM formula to get the conditional expected
return on an arbitrary stock S:
(2.15)
where
e '•' - 1 = risk-free return,
rtM = return on the market portfolio,
Pt = ^-coefficient of stock S
= Covfrf, rtM)
where
m r = l + E[r ( s |i? u ] see (2.15),
a1 = estimated variance of logarithmic historical stock returns.
Again, we would like to emphasize that our method of modelling stock returns
represents only one out of many possible approaches.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
jBOiJOjsiq uo pasBq 'Aouanbajj pajBiupsa = fi li
ui pajjapoiu puB jiBjap ajoui ui paonpojjui !siiun ajnsodxa uaiiUM = 'M.
' ( , 'o ,, O'M\ = ., 'A
7VJ*fj f ) f'N
= fM
(8 IT)
pjaiA oj uasoqo d puB v qaiM
iX
'juapuadapui ••• iZjq ft
' ', (LVZ)
' N
:A JO M/ OJ (•• '^ 'x 'M) ;duosjadns B SuiqoBjjB Xq pajjajaa 9J3M SJOJOBJ
JO 93UBUBA pUB UB3UI JOJ
• 'A SOUBUBA puB 'r« ireaui UJIM uoijnqujsip reiuiouiq
-33U aqi jgpisuoD 3A\ ^ sjaquinu uirep JOJ uoijnqujsip v. j o 9[duiBX3 UB s y
sjaquinu ssoj j o sajBiupsa uo SmApj j o pBajsui sapuanbajj ssoy
j o suopBuiijsa pasn 3M 'saaquinu ssoj uBqj ajqBjs ajora 9ABqaq saiouanbajj ssoj
ssnBoag •siiun aansodxa uajjuM puB uoi}B]jui junoooB OJUI OSJB JJOOJ 9A\ 'saqi
-J3A9S SSOJ UB3UI pUB S3pU3tlb3JJ SSOJ JOJ BJBp [BOUOJSiq JO ^O 'p^O SUOIlBIASp
?i 'pjli S9ri|BA UB3UI pSZIJTjn 3M /'XjO§3JB0 [BA\3U3J pUB } pOIJ3d
JOJ ( ; ) ' x ',='[T A- = /jf S9IJU3A3S ssoj UB9UI puB ']$ sjaquitui ssoj
•uoijnqujsip (azis UIIBJO) BUIUIBS B puB (jsquinu IUIBJO) jBiuiouiq 3AIJB
-§9U B OJ SUIJJ9J3J Aq S3SSOJ SqdOJJSBJBO-UOU JO J3pOUJ JllO 31BJJSUOUI3p JJBqS
3A\ UOIJOSS siqj uj BiBp ssoj jBoiJoisiq j o sjuaiujsnfpB §mo§3joj
BjBp jBDUiduis oi suopnqujsip Supjij j o ijnssa sqj si puB sssuisnq j o SUTJ
uo spusdsp uopnqujSTp 3ZTS UIIBJO puB jsquinu UIIBJO Dijpsds B JO aoioqo
'[g\] U3UOS9J pUB U9UIB>[i;U3J 'UTJjXBQ 90UBJSUI JOJ 33S 'S3SSOJ JO AlIJ3A3S pUB
S3SSOJ j o jaquinu :SJB IUTIOUIB UIIBJD JBJOJ SuipsjjB SJOPBJ oijsBqooas UIBUJ OA\J
3qi 'JU3UJOUI 3qi JOJ JUSUlABd SSOJ JBJU3UI3JOUI JO 3UITJ 3qj §UTpjB§9iSIQ
'[pp] ll°M u ! P U B '[61] "Jnjqpjaj 'fej] puB [\\] ApaqoQ
pire Abjy^Q ui punoj sq UBO uouauiouaqd SUISB sqj jnoqB UOIJBUIJOJUI SJOJAJ
~(i jduosjadns) SJBA\3USJ juanbasqns puB puooss - ssauisnq JBA\3U3J .
puB '(j jduDSJsdns) JBAVSUSJ ISJIJ - ssauisnq JBA\3U3J •
'(0 jdijosjadns) sssuisnq
QNV aawavo v 'NNVWdnv^ "a
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 227
vfJ=\ar(XJ)=a92,
where
2.4. Catastrophes
We are turning now to losses triggered by catastrophic events like windstrom,
flood, hurricane, earthquake, etc. In Section 2 we mentioned that we could
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
228 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
where
mM = estimated number of catastrophes, based on historical data,
vM - estimated variance, based on historical data.
Contrary to the modelling of non-catastrophe losses, we simulated the total
(economic) loss (i.e. not only the part the insurance company in consideration
has to pay) for each catastrophic event i e {1,..., M,} separately. Again, there
are different probability distributions, which prove to be adequate for this
purpose, in particular GPD (generalized Pareto distribution) G^p. GPD's play
an important role in Extreme Value Theory, where G^p appears as the limit
distribution and Mikosch [16, p. 165]. In the following equation Y't describes
the total economic loss caused by catastrophic event i e {1,..., Mt\ in projec-
tion period t.
y y-
After having generated Y\ we split it into pieces reflecting the loss portions of
different lines of business:
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 229
where
k - line of business,
/ = total number of lines considered,
V/G{1,...,M,}: (aJ 1 .,...,a' j / )e{;te[0, 1]', 11x11,= l } c R ' is a random convex
combination, whose probability distribution within the (/-I) dimensional
tetraeder can be arbitrarily specified.
Simulating the percentages at, stochastically over time varies the impact of
catastrophes on different lines favoring those companies, which are well diver-
sified in terms of number of lines written.
Knowing the market share of the nonlife insurer and its reinsurance struc-
ture permits calculation of loss payments allowing as well for catastrophes.
Although random variables were generated independently our model intro-
duced differing degrees of dependence between aggregate losses of different lines
by ensuring that they were affected by same catastrophic events (although to
different degrees).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
230 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
high premiums are equivalent to high profit margin over pure premium, and
low premiums equal low profit margin. Changing from one state to another
might cause significant changes in premiums.
The transition probabilities py, i, j e {1, 2, 3}, which denote the probability
of changing from state / to state j from one year to the next are assumed to
be equal for each projection year. This means that the Markov chain is homo-
geneous. The pyS form a matrix T:
Pu Pu Pn
T = Pi\ P22 P23
Pn P12 />33
There are many different possibilities to set these transition probabilities py, i,j
e {1, 2, 3}. It is possible to model them's depending on current market con-
ditions applicable to each line of business separately. If the company writes /
lines of business this will imply 3l states of the world. Because business cycles
of different lines of business are strongly correlated, only few of the 3' states
are attainable. Consequently, we have to model L < 3l states, where the tran-
sition probabilitiesptJ, i,j s {1,..., L} remain constant over time. It is possible
that some of them are zero, because there may exist some states that cannot
be attained directly from certain other states. When L states are attainable, the
matrix T has dimension Lx L:
Pu Pn P\L
P21 P22 P2L
T=
Pu PL2 PLL
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 231
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 development
to - 9 year t2
to-8
to-7
to-6
to-5
to-4
to-3
in-2
to-1
to
to+1
to+2
to+ 3
to+4
to+ 5
accident calendar
year t\ year t1+t2
FIGURF; 2.1: Paid losses (upper left triangle), outstanding loss payments and future loss payments.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
232 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
entries (tu t2), h ^ lo> belonging to the right hand side of the bold line - are
based on deriving an average payment pattern from loss payments represented
by the loss triangle.
In the simplified model description of this section we will not take into
account the empirical fact that payment patterns of single large losses differ
from those of aggregate losses. We will also disregard changes in future claim
inflation, although it might have a strong impact on certain lines of business.
For each line we assumed an ultimate development year T when all claims
arising from an accident year would be paid completely. Incremental claim
payments denoted by Ztu,2 are known for previous years tx + t2< t0. Ultimate
loss amounts -Z"1: = 2<=o^«i.' v a r ^ by accident year tx. In order to determine
loss reserves taking into account reserving risk we first had to simulate ran-
dom loss payments Z,ut2. As a second step we needed to have a procedure for
estimating ultimate loss amounts Z" k at each future time.
We distinguished two cases. First we will explain the modelling of out-
standing loss payments pertaining to previous accident years followed by a
description to model loss payments in respect of future accident years.
For previous accident years (t{ < tQ) payments Z,u,2, with ;, + tt< t0 are
known. We used them as a basis for predicting outstanding payments.
We used a chain-ladder type procedure (for the chain-ladder method, see
Mack [31]), i.e. we applied ratios to cumulative payments per accident year.
The following type of loss development factor was defined
Z
(2-23) dtut2:= 2Y> , h>\.
2 ^
Note that this ratio is not a typical chain-ladder link ratio. When mentioning
loss development factors in this section we are always referring to factors
defined by (2.23).
Since a lognormal distribution usually provides a good fit to historical loss
development factors, we used the following model for outstanding loss pay-
ments in calendar years tx + t2 > t0 + 1 for accident years t, < t0:
where
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 233
This loss payment model is able to provide realistic loss payments as long as
there have been no significant structural changes in the loss history. However,
if for an accident year tl < t0 a high percentage of ultimate claim amount had
been paid out in one of the first development years t2 < t0 - tu this approach
would increase the reserve due to higher development factors leading to over-
estimation of outstanding payments. Consequently, single large losses should
be treated separately. Sometimes changes in law affect insurance companies
seriously. Such unpredictable structural changes are an important risk. A well-
known example are health problems caused by buildings contaminated with
asbestos. These were responsible for major losses in liability insurance. Such
extreme cases should perhaps be modelled by separate scenarios.
Ultimate loss amounts for accident years tx < t0 were calculated as
(2.25) Z^i
The second type of loss payments are due to future accident years /, > t0 + 1.
the components determining total loss amounts in respect of these accident
years have already been explained in Sections 2.3 and 2.4:
M
2 t\
(1 lf,\ 7 u l Vi-\ — V NJ (P\ YJ (P\4- h f t t V y ' —7? tlA
j=0 /=1 '
where
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
234 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
where
Btut2 = incremental loss payment due to accident year ?, in development year
t2 in relation to the sum of remaining incremental loss payments per-
taining to the same accident year
~ beta(a, /?), a,f}>-\.
vtlj2=\ar(Bhj2) =
(a + y?+2r(a + y?+3)
where
mtut2 = estimated mean value of incremental loss payment due to accident
year tx in development year t2 in relation to the sum of remaining
incremental loss payments pertaining to the same accident year, based
OH r-TT '. 1 ^—IT . 1 • ' • 1
=
vtut2 estimated variance, based on the same historical data.
It can happen that a > - 1 , ft > -1 satisfying (2.28) do not exist. This means
that the estimated variance reaches or exceeds the maximum variance
mtutl (1 - m,[j2) possible for a beta distribution with mean mt{Jr In this case,
we resorted to a Bernoulli distribution for Btutl because the Bernoulli distrib-
ution marks a limiting case of the beta distribution:
Btut2~ Be(mtut2)..
(2-30) Zt\ = f
t=t2+\ t=o
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 235
where
Ht = estimated logarithmic loss development factor for development year t,
based on historical data,
Z,{ , = simulated losses for accident year tx, to be paid in development year /,
see (2.24) and (2.29).
Note that (2.30) is an estimate at the end of calendar year tx + t2, whereas
(2.26) represents the real future value. Reserves in respect of accident year tx
at the end of calendar year tx + t2 are determined by the difference between
estimated ultimate claim amount Z" \ and paid to date losses in respect of
accident year t{. Reserving risk materializes through variations of the differ-
ence between the simulated (real) ultimate claim amounts and the estimated
values.
Similarly, at the end of calendar year tx + t2 we got an estimate for dis-
counted ultimate losses for each accident year tx. Note that only future loss
payments are discounted whereas paid to date losses are taken at face value:
where
R-t,T - T year spot rate at time t, see (2.7),
fi, = estimated logarithmic loss development factor for development year t,
based on historical data,
Zh , = simulated losses for accident year ?,, paid in development year t, see
(2.24) and (2.29).
As pointed out in Section 1.4, DFA is an approach to facilitate and help jus-
tify management decisions. These are driven by a variety of considera-
tions: maximizing shareholder value, constraints imposed by regulators, tax
optimization and rankings by rating agencies and analysts. Parties outside
the company rely on financial reports in making decisions regarding their
relationship with the company. Therefore, a DFA model has to bridge the gap
between stochastic simulation of cash flows and financial statements (pro
forma balance sheets and income statements). The accounting process helps
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
236 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
where
Pt = earned premiums,
/, = market value of assets (including realized capital gains in year i),
Ct = equity capital,
Zt = losses paid in calendar year /,
Et = expenses,
Rt = (discounted) loss reserves,
Tt = taxes.
Note that Ct - C,_, describes the result of capital measures like issuance of new
equity capital or capital reduction.
We derived earned from written premiums. For each line of business, writ-
ten premiums P't for renewal classy should depend on change in loss trends,
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 237
the position in the underwriting cycle and on the number of written expo-
sures. This leads to written premium PJt of
w!
(3.2) P/=(l+df)(l + cm,_um,)^-P/_l, 7 = 0,1,2,
w
t-\
where
where
The initial values wJt are known since they represent the current number of
exposure units. Choosing parameter y < 1 ensures stationarity of the AR(1)
process (3.3). When deriving parameters a.J and y, prior adjustments to
historical data might be necessary if jumps in number of exposure units
had occurred caused by acquisition or transfer of loss portfolios. We found it
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
238 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
m
(3.5) P/ = - ^ % ! ^ > - " - ^fP/, 7 = 0,1,2.
P/o represent written premiums charged for the last year and still valid just
before the start of the first projection year. We assumed that premiums P,JQ were
adequate and based on established premium principles allowing for the cost
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 239
where
We restricted ourselves to modelling only the most important asset classes, i.e.
fixed income type investments (e.g. bonds, policy loans, cash), stocks, and real
estate. Modelling of stock returns has already been mentioned in Section 2.2,
future prices of fixed income investments can be derived from the generated
term structure explained in Section 2.1. Our approach of modelling real estate
was very similar to the stock return model of Section 2.2.
Future investment profits depend not only on the development of market
values of assets currently on the balance sheet but also on decisions how new
funds will be reinvested. In order to build a DFA model that really deserves
to be called dynamic we should account for potential changes of asset alloca-
tion in future years compared to a pure static approach that keeps the asset
allocation unchanged. This requires defining investment rules depending on
specific economic conditions.
Capital measures AC, = C, - Ct_x were modelled as additions or deductions
from surplus depending on a target reserves-to-surplus ratio. A purely determin-
istic approach that increased or decreased equity capital by a certain amount
at specific times would have been an alternative.
Aggregate loss payments in projection year t were calculated based on
variables defined in Section 2.6:
(3.7) Zr=
k=l t2=0
where
Z,-,2 ,2(k) - losses for accident year t-t2, paid in development year t2; see
(2.24) and (2.29),
r(k) = ultimate development year for this line of business,
k = line of business.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
240 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
We used a simple approach for modelling general expenses Et. They were cal-
culated as a constant plus a multiple of written exposure units wJt{k). T h e
appropriate intercept aE{k) and slope bE(k) were determined by linear regres-
sion:
(3.8) Et=:
k=\ \ ;=0
4. D F A IN A C T I O N
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 241
Model choices
Number of non-catastrophe losses ~ NB (154, 0.025).
Mean severity of non-catastrophe losses ~ Gamma (9.091, 242), inflation-
adjusted.
Number of catastrophes ~ Pois (18).
Severity of individual catastrophes ~ lognormal (13, 1.52), inflation-
adjusted.
Optional excess of loss reinsurance with deductible 500000 (inflation-adjusted),
and cover °o.
Underwriting cycles: 1 = weak, 2 = average, 3 = strong. State in year 0: 1 (weak).
Transition probabilities: pu = 60%, pu = 25%, pn = 15%, p2l = 25%, p22 -
55%, p23 = 20%, pu = 10%, pn = 25%, p 33 = 65%.
All liquidity is reinvested. There are only two investment possibilities:
1) buy a risk-free bond with maturity one year,
2) buy an equity portfolio with a fixed beta.
Market valuation: assets and liabilities are stated at market value, i.e. assets
are stated at their current market values, liabilities are discounted at the
appropriate term spot rate determined by the model.
Model parameters
• Interest rates, see (2.4): a = 0.25, b = 5%, s = 0.1, rx = 2%.
• General inflation, see (2.8): a1 = 0%, b1 = 0.75, a1 = 0.025.
• No inflation impacting the number of claims.
• Inflation impacting severity of claims, see (2.10):
ax = 3.5%, bx = 0.5, ax = 0.02.
• Stock returns, see (2.14), (2.15) and (2.16):
M
aM = 4%, b = 0.5, 0? s 0.5, a - 0.15.
• Market share: 5%.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
242 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
Historical data
• Written premiums in the last year: 20 million.
• Initial surplus: 12 million.
Strategies considered
• Should the company buy reinsurance coverage or not?
• How should the reinvestment of excess liquidity be split between fixed income
instruments and stocks?
Projection period
• 10 years (yearly intervals).
a b
with without
reinsurance reinsurance
1 100% bonds 23.17 mio. 23.29 mio.
0 % stocks 0.49% 1.15%
2 50% bonds 25.28 mio. 25.51 mio.
50 % stocks 2.14% 2.48%
3 0 % bonds 27.17 mio. 27.70 mio.
100% stocks 9.69% 10.13%
4 < 5 mio. bonds 26.48 mio. 26.79 mio.
rest stocks 6.08% 6.52%
5 < 10 mio. bonds 25.74 mio. 26.06 mio.
rest stocks 3.64% 4.49%
6 <20mio. bonds 24.62 mio. 24.95 mio.
rest stocks 0.90% 1.65%
FIGURE 4.2: Simulated expected surplus and ruin probability for the evaluated strategies.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 243
Figure 4.4 shows that by choosing the median surplus as return measure and
ruin probability as risk measure all six strategies with a ruin probability above
3% (i.e. strategies 3a, 3b, 4a, 4b, 5a and 5b) are clearly outperformed by the
strategies 2a and 2b, where half of the money is invested in bonds and the
other half in stocks.
An advantage of median surplus is the fact that one can easily calculate
confidence intervals for this return measure. In Figure 4.5 we plotted confi-
dence intervals, based on the 10 000 simulations performed. These intervals
should be interpreted as 95% confidence intervals for ruin probability given a
specific strategy and 95% confidence intervals for median surplus given a spe-
cific strategy. Note that Figure 4.5 does not attempt to give joint confidence
areas. Furthermore it is important to be aware of the fact that a 95% confi-
dence interval for median surplus does not mean that 95% of the simulations at
the end of the projection period result in an amount of surplus that lies in this
FIGURR 4.3: Graphical comparison of ruin probabilities and expected surplus for selected
business strategies.
FIGURE 4.4: Graphical comparison of ruin probabilities and median surplus for selected
business strategies.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
244 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
FIGURE 4.5: 95% confidence intervals for ruin probability and median surplus, based on
10 000 simulations for each strategy.
interval. The correct interpretation is that given our observed sample of 10 000
simulations, the probability for median surplus lying in this interval is 95%.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 245
of traffic and with sales of new cars. Although rarely done it might be worth-
while modelling specific macroeconomic drivers like industrial capacity uti-
lization or traffic volume separately. This would require a foregoing econo-
metric analysis of the dynamics of particular factors.
5.1.3. Correlations
DFA is able to allow for dependencies between different stochastic variables.
Before starting to implement these dependencies one should have a sound
understanding of existing dependencies within an insurance enterprise. Esti-
mating correlations from historical (loss) data is often not feasible due to
aggregate figures and structural changes in the past, e.g. varying deductibles,
changing policy conditions, acquisitions, spin-offs, etc. Furthermore, recent
research, see for example Embrechts, McNeil and Straumann [17] and [18],
and Lindskog [28], suggests that linear correlation is not appropriate to model
dependencies between heavy-tailed and skewed risks.
We suggest modelling dependencies implicitly, as a result of a number of
contributory influences, for example, catastrophes that impact more than
one line of business or interest rate changes affecting only specific lines. The
majority of these relations should be implemented based on economic and
actuarial wisdom, see for instance Kreps [26].
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
246 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
DFA models provide generally deeper insight into risks and potential rewards
of business strategies than scenario testing can do. DFA marks a milestone
towards evaluating business strategies when compared to old-style analysis of
considering only key ratios. DFA is virtually the only feasible way to model
an entire nonlife operation on a cash flow basis. It allows for a high degree of
detail including analysis of the reinsurance program, modelling of catastrophic
events, dependencies between random elements, etc. DFA can meet different
objectives and address different management units (underwriting, invest-
ments, planning, actuarial, etc.).
Nevertheless, it is worth mentioning that a DFA model will never be able
to capture the complexity of the real-life business environment. Necessarily,
one has to restrict attention during the model building process to certain fea-
tures the model is supposed to reflect. However, the number of parameters
which have to be estimated beforehand and the number of random variables
to be modelled even within medium-sized DFA models contribute a big deal
of process and parameter risk to a DFA model. Furthermore one has to be
aware that results will strongly depend on the assumptions used in the model
set-up. A critical question is: How big and sophisticated should a DFA model
be? Everything comes at a price and a simple model that can produce reason-
able results will probably be preferred by many users due to growing reluctance
of using non-transparent "black boxes". In addition, smaller models tend to
be more in line with intuition, and make it easier to assess the impact of specific
variables. A good understanding and control of uncertainties and approxima-
tions is vital to the usefulness of a DFA model.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 247
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT
We would like to thank Paul Embrechts, Peter Blum and the anonymous
referees for numerous comments on an earlier version of the paper. We also
benefited substantially from discussions on DFA with Allan Kaufman and
Stavros Christofides.
REFERENCES
1. AHLGRIM K.C., D'ARCY S.P. and GORVETT R.W. (1999) Parametrizing Interest Rate Mod-
els, Casualty Actuarial Society Forum, 1-50
2. ARTZNER P., DELBAEN E, EBER J. and HEATH D. (1997) Thinking Coherently, RISK 10, 68-
71.
3. ARTZNER P., DELBAEN E, EBER J. and HEATH D. (1999) Coherent Measures of Risk, Math-
ematical Finance 9(3), 203-228.
4. BJORK T. (1996) Interest Rate Theory. In Financial Mathematics (ed. W. Runggaldier), Lec-
ture Notes in Mathematics 1656, 53-122, Springer, Berlin.
5. BLUM P., DACOROGNA M., EMBRECHTS P., NEGHAIWI T. and NIGGLI H. (2001) Using DFA
for Modelling the Impact of Foreign Exchange Risks on Reinsurance Decisions, Paper pre-
sented at the Casualty Actuarial Society 2001 Reinsurance Meeting on Using Dynamic
Financial Analysis to Optimize Ceded Reinsurance Programs and Retained Portfolios,
Washington D.C., July 2001. Available as ETH Zurich Preprint.
6. BRENNAN M.J. and SCHWARTZ E.S. (1982) An Equilibrium Model of Bond Pricing and a
Test of Market Efficiency, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 17, 301-329.
7. BUHLMANN H., DELBAEN E, EMBRECHTS P. and SHIRYAEV A.N. (1998) On Esscher Trans-
forms in Discrete Finance Models, ASTIN Bulletin 28(2), 171-186.
8. CHRISTOFIDES S. (1990) Regression Models Based on Log-Incremental Payments, Claims
Reserving Manual 2, Institute of Actuaries, London.
9. Cox J.C., INGERSOLL J.E. and Ross S.A. (1985) A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest
Rates, Econometrica 53, 385-407.
10. CUMBERWORTH M.P., HITCHCOX A.M., MCCONNELL W.M. and SMITH A.D. (1999) Corporate
Decisions in General Insurance: Beyond the Frontier, available from http://www.actuaries.
org.uk/library/sessionaL.meeting_papers.html.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
248 R. KAUFMANN, A. GADMER AND R. KLETT
11. D'ARCY S.P. and DOHERTY N. (1989) The Aging Phenomenon and Insurance Prices, Pro-
ceedings of the Casualty Actuarial Society 76, 24-44.
12. D'ARCY S.P. and DOHERTY N. (1990) Adverse Selection, Private Information and Low-
balling in Insurance Markets, Journal of Business 63, 145-164.
13. D'ARCY S.P., GORVETT R.W., HERBERS J.A., HETTINGER T.E., LEHMANN S.G. and MILLER
M.J. (1997) Building a Public Access PC-Based DFA Model, Casualty Actuarial Society
Forum, 1-40.
14. D'ARCY S.P., GORVETT R.W., HETTINGER T.E. and WALLING R.J. (1998) Using the Public
Access DFA Model: A Case Study, Casualty Actuarial Society Forum, 55-118.
15. DAYKIN CD., PENTIKAINEN T. and PESONEN M. (1994) Practical Risk Theory for Actuaries,
Chapman & Hall, London.
16. EMBRECHTS P., KLUPPELBERG C. and MIKOSCH T. (1997) Modelling Extremal Events for
Insurance and Finance, Springer, Berlin.
17. EMBRECHTS P., MCNEIL A.J. and STRAUMANN D. (1999) Correlation: Pitfalls and Alternatives,
RISK 12(5), 69-71.
18. EMBRECHTS P., MCNEIL A.J. and STRAUMANN D. (1999) Correlation and Dependence in
Risk Management: Properties and Pitfalls, Preprint ETH Zurich, available from http://www.
math.ethz.ch/~embrechts.
19. FELDBLUM S. (1996) Personal Automobile Premiums: An Asset Share Pricing Approach for
Property/Casualty Insurance, Proceedings of the Casualty Actuarial Society 83, 190-296.
20. HEATH D., JARROW R. and MORTON A. (1992) Bond Pricing and the Term Structure of
Interest Rates: A New Methodology for Contingent Claim Valuation, Econometrica 60, 77-
105.
21. HODES D.M., FELDBLUM S. and NEGHAIWI A.A. (1999) The Financial Modeling of Prop-
erty-Casualty Insurance Companies, North American Actuarial Journal 3(3), 41-69.
22. INGERSOLL J.E. (1987) Theory of Financial Decision Making, Rowman & Littlefield Studies
in Financial Economics, New Jersey.
23. JARVIS S., SOUTHALL F.E. and VARNELL E. (2001) Modern Valuation Techniques, Staple Inn
Actuarial Society, available from http://www.sias.org.uk/progold.htm.
24. KAUFMANN R. (1999) DFA: Stochastische Simulation zur Beurteilung von Unternehmensstra-
tegien bei Nichtleben-Versicherungen, Master Thesis, ETH Zurich.
25. KLETT, R. (1994) Asset-Liability-Management im Lebensversicherungsbereich, Master The-
sis, University of Freiburg.
26. KREPS, R.E. (2000) A Partially Comonotonic Algorithm for Loss Generation, Proceedings
of XXXIst International ASTIN Colloquium, 165-176, Porto Cervo, Italy.
27. LAMBERTON D. and LAPEYRE B. (1996) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Applied to Finance,
Chapman & Hall, London.
28. LINDSKOG F. (2000) Modelling Dependence with Copulas and Applications to Risk Manage-
ment, Master Thesis, ETH Zurich.
29. LONGSTAFF FA. and SCHWARTZ E.S. (1992) Interest Rate Volatility and the Term Structure:
A Two-Factor General Equilibrium Model, Journal of Finance 47, 1259-1282.
30. LOWE S.P. and STANARD J.N. (1997) An Integrated Dynamic Financial Analysis and Deci-
sion Support System for a Property Catastrophe Reinsurer, ASTIN Bulletin 27(2), 339-371.
31. MACK T. (1997) Schadenversicherungsmathematik, Veriag Versicherungswirtschaft E.V., Karls-
ruhe.
32. MARKOWITZ H.M. (1959) Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments, John
Wiley, New York.
33. MCNEIL A.J. (1997) Estimating the Tails of Loss Severity Distributions using Extreme Value
Theory, ASTIN Bulletin 27(1), 117-137.
34. MODIGLIANI M. and MILLER M. (1958) The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance, and the
Theory of Investment, American Economic Review 48, 261-297.
35. MUSIELA M. and RUTKOWSKI M. (1998) Martingale Methods in Financial Modelling, 2nd
edition, Springer, Berlin.
36. ROGERS L.C.G. (1995) Which Model for Term-Structure of Interest Rates Should One Use?
In Mathematical Finance, IMA Volume 65, 93-116, Springer, New York.
37. SCHNIEPER R. (1997) Capital Allocation and Solvency Testing, SCOR Notes, 55-104.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003
INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC FINANCIAL ANALYSIS 249
ROGER KAUFMANN
RiskLab
Department of Mathematics
ETH Zentrum
CH-8092 Zurich
Switzerland
kaufmann@math. ethz. ch
ANDREAS GADMER
Zurich Kosmos Versicherungen
Schwarzenbergplatz 15
A-1015 Wien
Austria
andreas. gadmer @zurich. com
RALF KLETT
Zurich Financial Services
Mythenquai 2
CH-8022 Zurich
Switzerland
ralf.klett@zurich. com
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 16:55:32, subject to the Cambridge Core terms
of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.2143/AST.31.1.1003