The Return Fiscal Policy
The Return Fiscal Policy
The Return Fiscal Policy
Abstract: This paper examines the implications of the experience with the fi-
nancial crisis of August 2007 for fiscal policy and the use made of it. We briefly
sketch the changing attitudes toward fiscal policy and the demise of arbitrary
rules for the budget deficits and the reassertion of purposeful fiscal policy, that
is fiscal policy for the purpose of helping to create the conditions for high levels
of employment. Instead of a focus on debt overall, there should be consideration
of the net balance sheet position. It is often argued that running a budget deficit
places upward pressure on interest rates. We argue that in the context of the use
of “functional finance,” the ability of the deficit to in effect fund itself removes
any underlying upward pressure on interest rates. We also deal with the issue
of balance-of-payments constraints, and argue that under such circumstances
the appropriate policy response is not to forgo fiscal policy but rather to tackle
the balance-of-payments constraint.
We have been arguing for a number of years that fiscal policy would be a
more potent policy tool than monetary policy (Arestis and Sawyer, 2003)
and that the arguments that fiscal policy was impotent were not valid
(Arestis, 2009a; Arestis and De Antoni, 2009; Arestis and Sawyer, 2006b;
Sawyer, 2009). The purpose of this paper is to consider the implications
of the experiences of the financial crisis and the use made of fiscal policy.
The section that follows this short introduction attempts to briefly sketch
the changing attitudes toward fiscal policy. And attitudes have changed
following the events post August 2007, especially after the collapse of
Philip Arestis is Honorary Senior Departmental Fellow, Cambridge Centre for Eco-
nomic and Public Policy, Department of Land Economy, University of Cambridge;
and Professor of Economics, Department of Applied Economics V, University of the
Basque Country. Malcolm Sawyer is a professor of economics in the Economics Divi-
sion, Leeds University Business School at the University of Leeds. An earlier version
of the paper was presented at the Sixth International Conference on Economic Theory
and Policy (Bilbao, July 2009). The authors are grateful to the conference participants
and to three referees for helpful comments. The usual disclaimer applies.
Journal of Post Keynesian Economics / Spring 2010, Vol. 32, No. 3 327
© 2010 M.E. Sharpe, Inc.
0160–3477 / 2010 $9.50 + 0.00.
DOI 10.2753/PKE0160-3477320301
328 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
1 For example, the nationalization of Northern Rock and other relative small finan-
cial institutions in the United Kingdom would increase public-sector debt by nearly
one quarter (“Budget 2009: Building Britain’s Future,” 2009, table C.14), and that
figure includes interventions over the Royal Bank of Scotland (RBS) and Lloyds
Banking Group.
2 It should be noted that there were cases where governments acquired preferential
shares that they were committed to sell back at the price which they paid for them. In
such cases, although no capital gain will be realized, the rate of interest paid on the
preferential shares has been rather high.
The Return of Fiscal Policy 329
3 In the event, a number of countries in the euro area broke the 3 percent limit rule
(Arestis and Sawyer, 2006a), and it is debatable whether even prior to the financial
crisis the UK government was meeting the “golden rule” (see, e.g., Sawyer, 2007).
330 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
d/g, where d is the deficit-to-GDP ratio and g is the (nominal) growth rate. With the
assumption of a nominal growth rate of 5 percent, 60 percent debt ratio, and 3 percent
deficit ratio are mutually compatible.
5 See the formula in note 4.
The Return of Fiscal Policy 331
designed to reduce public expenditure, raise taxes, and overall reduce the
budget deficits. In a related vein, it is also remarkable that a number of
governments (perhaps most notably the UK government) have dropped
adherence to (previously self-imposed) deficit or debt constraints. Sec-
ond, there has generally been a sharp change in attitude toward the use of
discretionary fiscal policy and increases in the budget deficit even though
budget deficits were already rising through the effects of the recession.6
A welcome feature of policy responses to the financial crisis has been
the speed with which fiscal policy (stimulus) has been brought into play.
However, having said all that, it is rather doubtful whether a paradigm
shift has occurred. We may cite as an example of this argument the Euro-
pean governments, which have dealt with this crisis as a crass exception
that makes extraordinary measures necessary, only to return to normal
once the crisis seems to have evaporated (see, e.g., OECD, 2009).
6 In the United Kingdom, the fiscal stimuli amounted to the following changes and
predictions (as a percentage of GDP): budget deficit to GDP: –3.1 percent (2008–9)
from –0.7 percent (2007–8), rising to –6.7 percent (2009–10), and thereby falling
to –6.4 percent (2010–11); debt to GDP: 43 percent (2008–9) from 36.5 percent
(2007–8), rising to 55.4 percent (2009–10), 65 percent (2010–11), and 74.5 percent
(2011–12), before peaking at 76.2 percent (2013–14).
332 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
Targets have also often been set for the size of the public debt rela-
tive to GDP—for example, 60 percent under the Stability and Growth
Pact of the European Monetary Union (EMU), 40 percent in the United
Kingdom.7 These types of figures are also quite arbitrary, and as far as
we are aware little justification has been advanced to justify them—for
example, why 40 rather than 50, why 60 rather than 100? As discussed
below, the intertemporal budget constraint would impose the condition
that the government–debt ratio tends to zero. We will also come back to
the point that the limits on debt are placed on gross financial liabilities
(rather than on, e.g., net worth).
What was labeled as the (UK) “Treasury view” argued for seeking to
balance the budget in each calendar year.8 The realization that fluctuations
in the private sector generate fluctuations in tax revenues (and to some
degree movements in public expenditure in the form of transfer pay-
ments), and hence in the budget deficit, has generally led to an acceptance
of such movements in the budget deficit and the avoidance of measures
seeking to reduce the budget deficit when it rises in economic downturns
(and reduce budget surplus when it rises in upturns). This implies that
variations in the budget deficit arise from variations in private-sector
activity and would arise even in the absence of variations in tax rates or
public expenditure. It would then seem a recognition that there can be
temporary shortages of aggregate demand, albeit offset by temporary
excesses of aggregate demand at other times and perception of a general
adequacy of aggregate demand. What is not explained is why aggregate
demand fluctuates and how it can be that aggregate demand is necessarily
sufficient over the long haul but not sufficient in the short term.
If the view is taken that individuals are subject to a binding budget
constraint and that individuals are nonsatiated in their consumption, then
it follows that individuals will spend up to their budget constraint. Hence,
all income is spent, and there is no aggregate demand issue. Introducing
savings and investment into the picture, of course, allows for a disjuncture
between the desire to save and the desire to invest, and Post Keynesians
would emphasize the driving role of investment and the way in which
output and employment would adjust to bring savings and investment
7 The way the debt is measured differs between the two cases; hence, the two fig-
1925) but was advanced and implemented in the 1930s, during the Great Depression,
by the UK Chancellor of the Exchequer. Simply put, this view argues that fiscal policy
does not have any effect on economic activity. Neither government expenditure nor
tax changes can affect the level of economic activity.
The Return of Fiscal Policy 333
into equality. But the mainstream view relies on the rate of interest to
balance savings and investment—in effect, the postulate of a “natural
rate of interest,” which balances the “forces of productivity and thrift”
(Woodford, 2003). Provided that the central bank is able to achieve the
“natural rate of interest,” there is no issue of divergence between (desired)
investment and savings. Specifically, there is no suggestion that there will
be differences between savings and investment, and hence inadequate or
excess aggregate demand in any time period.
The question is, then, whether the central bank is in a position to
achieve the “natural rate of interest.” A shift in the state of confidence
and expectations leading to a shift in the investment schedule would lead
to a change in this rate. In Arestis and Sawyer (2008a), we show that any
“natural rate of interest” would be defined for a specific fiscal stance,
specific world demand, and specific set of “animal spirits” influencing
investment, in addition to preferences and technology. Another example
is the study by Laubach and Williams (2001), where it is demonstrated
through the use of the Kalman filter technique that the “natural rate of
interest” estimates vary “one-to-one” with changes in the trend growth
rate of potential output. As the factors suggested in these studies vary,
so will the real rate of interest. Consequently, there is the real difficulty
and uncertainty that relate to establishing robust estimates of the “natural
rate of interest.” Furthermore, the “natural rate of interest” should be
readily computable from actual economic data. However, Weber et al.
(2008) demonstrate persuasively that there are serious problems with it.
The empirical estimates for the “natural rate of interest” are extremely
imprecise, so that this rate of interest “is not readily computable from
observable economic data” (ibid., p. 13). There is also the problem that
any cost–push shock is a significant source to inflation and an important
element of inflation information to monetary policymakers; but it “is not
mirrored by the natural rate of interest” (ibid., p. 13). This problem is
prevalent whichever method may be used for estimating the real equi-
librium rate of interest. In Arestis and Chortareas (2008), a time-varying
measure of the “natural rate of interest” is arrived at, which responds to
preferences and technology shocks and as such it is time varying. If there
were a “natural rate of interest,” which the monetary authorities could
persistently achieve even if it changed over time, then desired savings
and investment would be equal at the supply-side equilibrium, and there
would be no need for fiscal policy. But in the absence of that condition,
fiscal policy is required to maintain high levels of demand.
In many cases in the crisis, budget rules along the lines of balancing
the budget over some time frame have been suspended. The argument
334 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
in this section is that since the underpinnings for such rules are lacking,
then that suspension should be made permanent.
and the savings in excess of investment could not occur. Savings are
undertaken voluntarily, and the acquisition of financial assets is the
counterpart of savings. Thus, the debt is held voluntarily. Second, as
the relevant budget deficit is the overall one, then the debt-to-GDP ratio
would stabilize at d/g, where d is the deficit-to-GDP ratio and g is the
nominal growth rate.
The formulation in Equation (1) does not specify how frequently
adjustments should be made to tax and expenditure plans and hence to
the budget deficit. In Sawyer (2009), a distinction was drawn between
“coarse-tuning” and “fine-tuning” with regard to fiscal policy. In the
former, an equation such as (1) would be used based on the underlying
coefficients of the functions involved, and a “trend” budget deficit can
thereby be calculated. In effect, this forms the rule for fiscal policy. Fine-
tuning would then be the more short-term approach to fiscal policy. But
it is, of course, the case that fiscal policy, along with tax and expenditure
decisions, has to be set on an annual basis so that there is some form of
tuning. The question then arises as to whether more frequent adjustments
would be warranted, and the experience with the financial crises suggests
that there are at least occasions when within a year adjustments to the
fiscal stance are needed. A fiscal policy committee (FPC) analogous to
a monetary policy committee (MPC) has been suggested in a number of
forms (see, e.g., Arestis, 2009a; Wren‑Lewis, 2003). It is often objected
that the politically sensitive nature of tax and expenditure decisions
and the need for those to be taken by Parliament prevents this. Further,
while lowering taxes and raising transfers may be an acceptable way of
responding to a downturn, it is unlikely to be an acceptable way of dealing
with an upturn—“your benefit has been cut this week as the economy is
growing too fast” would not be well received. But there are taxes, such
as value-added tax and social security contributions, that could be varied
in this manner. Interest rates, which appear as a cost to many (though
income to others), are of course, already varied in this way. The role of an
FPC could then be to judge on, say, a six-month basis whether a change
in tax rates would be warranted. And, as Leith and Wren‑Lewis (2005)
comment on Wren‑Lewis’s (2003) suggestion:
Wren‑Lewis (2003) suggests giving a “fiscal stabilization authority” a
small number of fiscal instruments, chosen for their potency in influenc-
ing the macroeconomy. This authority would only be allowed to make
temporary changes in these instruments, and might even be given its own
budget which would have to be balanced within a specified time frame.
(Leith and Wren‑Lewis, 2005, pp. 595–596)
The Return of Fiscal Policy 337
Table 1
Government net capital stock in 22 OECD countries (as a percentage of
GDP at 1995 prices)
on the interest rate on government bonds. This is, though, not a general
crowding argument in that it is not envisaged that there is a general pres-
sure on interest rates and that interest rates for private borrowers rise,
thereby reducing investment (indeed, the first argument points to perhaps
lower interest rates for private borrowers). First, the continuing budget
deficit means that government bonds are being sold, and the relative
composition of financial assets is changing. A higher (than otherwise)
budget deficit clearly means that government bonds as a proportion of
total financial assets is greater than it would have been, and this could
entail lower price/higher interest rate on government bonds. But the other
side of that is that nongovernment bonds carry a higher price/lower inter-
est rate. However, because there is a general balance between demand for
and supply of funds, this would not constitute general upward pressure
on interest rates. When considering the level of interest rates, the role of
the central bank also has to be brought into the picture.
Second, it is a general proposition in Keynesian economics that there
is strong sense in which investment “causes” savings rather than savings
“cause” investment. For the moment, consider the simple case where there
is no government and no foreign sector. The accounting identity ensures
that ex post savings S * = ex post investment I *, and let us suppose that
in a given period that also corresponds to ex ante savings S + = ex ante
investment I +. Now conduct the thought experiment of increase in inten-
tions to invest. If those intentions are carried through, then in the relevant
period S * = I *, and after some adjustments S + = I +, and in that sense
corresponding savings will become available. But at the time when there
is the intention to invest, those savings do not exist. The realization of
the investment intentions requires availability of finance, and the usual
route postulated is by bank lending. Banks in this context have the abil-
ity to create loans and thereby create money and purchasing power. The
effect that increased investment intentions has on interest rates depends
on the reactions of banks. If, as is often assumed, banks readily supply
loans at the going loan interest rate, then there would be no immediate
pressure on interest rates.
Now introduce government into the picture. It is rather paradoxical that
while private firms have access to loans, which thereby change the money
supply, government (here taken to exclude the central bank) is not able to
“print money” to finance its spending. If there is a relationship between
budget deficit, sale of bonds, and the money supply, then it comes through
the endogeneity of money at the interface of banks and the central bank.
That is, the central bank (in normal times) provides reserves to the bank-
ing system in exchange for government bonds, and it is only at the point
The Return of Fiscal Policy 341
where government bonds are exchanged in this way for reserves that the
government deficit could be said to be money financed or monetized. The
immediate effect of a larger government budget deficit is that the govern-
ment has to borrow for what is at that point in time a pool of savings. If
the government deficit is increased, then a higher (than otherwise) level
of income will result, and subsequently higher tax revenues and higher
savings.9 It could then be anticipated that there will be occasions when
a government finds some difficulty in securing funds, particularly if its
“offering” is not as attractive as it might be.
Any expansion of demand starting from a position of low economic
activity faces the issue that the expenditure has to be financed, and that
the raising of finance may place some upward pressure on relevant rates
of interest. There is little that is unique about an expansion of public
expenditure rather than private expenditure in that respect. But any pres-
sure is limited, and when the expansion has taken place, corresponding
funds are generated.
9 Often, as in the present, larger budget deficits arise from a slowdown in the econ-
omy, which results in lower tax receipts. The government is then faced with the choice
of increased borrowing or attempting to raise taxes or reduce expenditure. The point
here is that without the increased budget deficit and borrowing, the level of economic
activity would continue to decline, and the budget deficit is acting as an “automatic
stabilizer.”
342 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
mestic interest rate would be associated with a rising exchange rate; if “sentiment” in
the exchange markets responds favorably to the prospect of higher domestic income,
then the exchange rate would tend to appreciate.
344 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
policy conclusion (easily stated but only resolved with great difficulty)
is to direct policy toward relieving the balance-of-payments constraints
rather than foregoing the use of fiscal policy.
Fiscal policy can itself only address issues of demand deficiency
(or excess) aggregate demand, though the composition of government
expenditure and the structure of taxation can address other issues (e.g.,
the role of public investment in terms of growth, taxation with respect
to income distribution). The effective use of fiscal policy can often be
constrained through (as discussed here) balance-of-payments constraints
and through a lack of productive capacity (which we have not addressed
here but which may prevent the achievement of high levels of employ-
ment through lack of capacity and hence also the achievement of desired
levels of output). But those constraints should be viewed as operating on
any policy options (including the “do nothing” policy) and not specific
to fiscal policy, and that the appropriate response is the development of
policy instruments, which directly address those constraints.
Concluding remarks
It is evident that the use of fiscal policy has been one of the major policy
instruments used in many countries to offset some of the devastation
wrought by the financial crisis. Its use has seen budget deficits in many
countries rise to high levels (when judged against previous experience)
and the prospects of debt-to-GDP ratios rising for a number of years to
come. This return of fiscal policy must be welcomed. The major chal-
lenge for fiscal policy in the years ahead is to establish the principles of
“functional finance” and the probable need for long-term budget deficits
in many countries. By reference to Equation (1), it can be readily seen
that budget deficits can only be reduced through some combination of
higher investment, lower savings, higher exports, and lower imports. The
danger is that with the prospects that firms will be reluctant to invest and
households spending less and saving more, the attempt will in effect be
made to reduce budget deficits through old-style deflation, cuts in public
expenditure, and increased tax rates.
The alternative, which must be pursued, is that unless and until invest-
ment strongly revives and households are able to spend without incur-
ring high debt levels, budget deficits will have to continue. It ought to
be noted also that in all this it should be remembered that the revival
of the banking-sector lending activity is also paramount. Tackling the
problem of the current frozen banking systems is also important and is
paramount.
The Return of Fiscal Policy 345
References
Arestis, P. “Fiscal Policy Within the ‘New Consensus Macroeconomics’ Framework.”
In J. Creel and M. Sawyer (eds.), Current Thinking on Fiscal Policy. Basingstoke, UK:
Palgrave Macmillan, 2009a, pp. 6–27.
———. “New Consensus Macroeconomics: A Critical Appraisal.” In E. Hein,
T. Niechoj, and E. Stockhammer (eds.), Macroeconomic Policies on Shaky
Foundations—Whither Mainstream Economics? Marburg, Germany: Metropolis,
2009b.
Arestis, P., and Chortareas, G. “Atheoretical and Theory-Based Approaches to the
Natural Equilibrium Real Interest Rate.” Eastern Economic Journal, 2008, 34 (3),
390–405.
Arestis, P., and De Antoni, E. “Minsky’s Financial Instability Hypothesis: The Crucial
Role of Fiscal Policy.” In J. Creel and M. Sawyer (eds.), Current Thinking on Fiscal
Policy. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan, 2009, pp. 51–77.
Arestis, P., and Sawyer, M. “On the Effectiveness of Monetary and Fiscal Policy.”
Review of Social Economics, 2003, 62 (4), 441–463.
———. Alternative Perspectives on Economic Policies in the European Union. Bas-
ingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan, 2006a.
———. “Fiscal Policy Matters.” Public Finance, 2006b, 54 (3–4), 133–153.
———. “A Critical Reconsideration of the Foundations of Monetary Policy in the
New Consensus Macroeconomics Framework.” Cambridge Journal of Economics,
2008a, 32 (5), 761–779.
———. “The Intertemporal Budget Constraint and the Sustainability of Budget Defi-
cits.” In J. Creel and M. Sawyer (eds.), Current Thinking on Fiscal Policy. Basingstoke,
UK: Palgrave Macmillan, 2008b, pp. 95–111.
Arestis, P., and Sawyer, M. (eds.). 21st Century Keynesian Economic Policies. Basing-
stoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan, 2010, pp. 81–119.
Blanchard, O., and Fischer, S. Lectures on Macroeconomics. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press, 1989.
“Budget 2009: Building Britain’s Future.” HM Treasury, London, 2009.
Godley, W.; Papadimitriou, D.; and Zezza, G. “Prospects for the United States and
the World: A Crisis that Conventional Remedies Cannot Resolve.” Strategic Analysis,
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, Annandale-on-Hudson, December 2008.
Hawtrey, R.G. “Public Expenditure and the Demand for Labour.” Economica, 1925, 5,
38–48.
Kalecki, M. “Three Ways to Full Employment.” In The Economics of Full Employ-
ment: Six Studies in Applied Economics. Oxford: Blackwell, 1944, pp. 39–58.
Kamps, C. “New Estimates of Government Net Capital Stocks for 22 OECD Coun-
tries, 1960–2001.” IMF Staff Papers, 2006, 53 (1), 120–150.
Laubach, T., and Williams, J.C. “Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest.” Finance and
Economics Discussion Series 2001-56, Federal Reserve Board, Washington, DC, 2001.
Leith, C., and Wren-Lewis, S. “Fiscal Stabilization Policy and Fiscal Institutions.”
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 2005, 21 (4), 584–597.
Lerner, A. “Functional Finance and the Federal Debt.” In W. Mueller (ed.), Readings in
Macroeconomics. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1966. [Originally published
in 1943.]
Meyer, L.H. “Does Money Matter?” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 2001,
83 (5), 1–15.
Nell, E. The General Theory of Transformational Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1998.
346 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
To order reprints, call 1-800-352-2210; outside the United States, call 717-632-3535.