2.0 The Fiscal Policy Multiplier in Good and Bad Times
2.0 The Fiscal Policy Multiplier in Good and Bad Times
2.0 The Fiscal Policy Multiplier in Good and Bad Times
It is crucial to the arguments of those opposing austerity that the fiscal policy multiplier is
reasonably large, or at least can be expected to be large in current economic circumstances. And
indeed there are some recent papers which do argue for a large multiplier: for example, s
estimate a multiplier of nearly 3 for tax changes and Christiano et al. (2011) suggest that a
government-spending multiplier of 3.7 might be plausible in a constant interest rate environment.
However, a crucial question is whether these multipliers are large in times of high (and/or rapidly
rising) public sector debt, and there is evidence that in such times fiscal policy multipliers may
be much lower and could indeed be negative. This is the message of Perotti (1999), who argues
that the effects of fiscal policy in good times (i.e. low debt) may be very different from its
effects in bad times (i.e. high debt). Ilzetzki et al. (2010) present evidence that the fiscal
multiplier is zero in countries with debt-GDP ratios above 60 per cent. It has in fact even been
suggested that fiscal contraction may be expansionary: Giavazzi and Pagano (1990) argue that
the fiscal consolidations undertaken by both Ireland and Denmark in the 1980s were
expansionary. There is also evidence (see Reinhart and Rogoff, 2010) that in countries with debtGDP ratios greater than 90 per cent economic performance deteriorates sharply.
The question that arises, of course, is why low and possibly negative fiscal policy multipliers
may occur with high public sector debt. The main mechanism in the literature (see, e.g.
Sutherland, 1997) is somewhat as follows. Suppose a country is experiencing a rapidly rising
public debt which is unsustainable. Some consolidation is necessary; the only question is when
will it be introduced? The longer the delay in introducing the policy, the more painful it will be.
The sudden introduction of a fiscal consolidation programme removes the uncertainty about
when it will be introduced and means that it is less painful than expected, and for both these
A recent IMF study (IMF 2010) has sometimes been cited as evidence that fiscal consolidation is
contractionary; the main finding is that a fiscal consolidation equal to 1 percent of GDP
typically reduces GDP by about 0.5 percent within two years (op. cit., p. 94). But this article
does not contend that fiscal contraction is never contractionary. Indeed, the evidence is
overwhelming that on average fiscal contraction is contractionary. Rather, the contention is that
when there is a problem with the public sector debt, the fiscal policy multiplier may well be
much smaller than on average and could possibly be negative.