Lost Autonomy Nationalism and Separatism
Lost Autonomy Nationalism and Separatism
Lost Autonomy Nationalism and Separatism
Citations:
Provided by:
The University of Edinburgh
-- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and
Conditions of the license agreement available at
https://heinonline.org/HOL/License
-- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text.
-- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope of your license, please use:
Copyright Information
Article
Abstract
Case studies suggest that ethnic groups with autonomous institutional
arrangements are more prone to secede, but other evidence indicates
that autonomy reduces the likelihood of secession. To address this debate,
we disaggregate their autonomy status into three categories-currently
autonomous, never autonomous, and lost autonomy-and then unpack
how each shapes the logic of collective action. We argue groups that were
never autonomous are unlikely to mobilize due to a lack of collective action
capacity, whereas currently autonomous groups may have the capacity but
often lack the motivation. Most important, groups that have lost autonomy
often possess both strong incentives and the capacity to pursue secession,
which facilitates collective action. Moreover, autonomy retraction weakens
the government's ability to make future credible commitments to redress
grievances. We test these conjectures with data on the autonomous status
and separatist behavior of 324 groups in more than 100 countries from
I960 to 2000. Our analysis shows clear empirical results regarding the
relationship between autonomy status and separatism. Most notably, we
find that formerly autonomous groups are the most likely to secede, and
that both currently autonomous and never autonomous groups are much
less likely.
Corresponding Author:
David S. Siroky, School of Politics and Global Studies, Arizona State University, P.O. Box
873902, Tempe, AZ 85287-3902, USA.
Email: [email protected]
4 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Keywords
nationalism, separatism, decentralization, autonomy
&
Amoretti, 2003; L. Diamond, 1999; Stepan, 1999). Others studies, however,
show that autonomy can actually exacerbate relations between the state and
ethnic groups, for it cultivates the capacity for collective action and self-rule
without significantly reducing desire for more of it (Brancati, 2009; Bunce,
1999; Coppieters, 2001; Comell, 2002; Roeder, 1991).
This article posits that the theoretical and empirical disagreement over the
effect of autonomy is partly due to conflating two distinct situations in the
implicit reference category-groups that are not autonomous. This binary
classification compares groups that are currently autonomous to a baseline
that is comprised of both groups that have never been autonomous, and those
that once had autonomy, but lost it. Groups that have never been autonomous
and those that have lost autonomy are distinct in their motivation and their
capacity for collective action. Whereas never autonomous groups may be
unlikely to mobilize due to a lack of collective action capacity, currently
autonomous groups may have such capacity, but should find the cost of
attempting to alter the status quo too high compared with the benefits they
currently enjoy from being autonomous. Most important, we argue that
groups which have lost autonomy possess both powerful incentives in the
form of grievances and often also have the capacity for collective action
capacity, which leads us to expect such groups to be more likely to pursue
secession.
Following previous studies, we define autonomy as a form of intemal self-
determination that provides a group with actual powers and resources for
self-govemance within a state (Brancati, 2009; Wolff, 2013; Zinn, 2006).1
Specifically, we build on Wolff's (2013) definition of "territorial self-gover-
nance," which he describes as "legally entrenched power of territorially-
delimited entities within the intemationally recognized boundaries of existing
states to exercise public policy functions independently of other sources of
authority in this state, but subject to its overall legal order" (p. 5). To this defi-
nition, we add Stepan's (1999) of asymmetric arrangements, meaning that the
powers devolved to a group must not apply for all of the groups within the
Siroky and Cuffe 5
state. For example, the United States has symmetric federal arrangements-
in theory, states are all treated equally relative to the central government. In
other countries, such as Spain, Indonesia, and Canada, particular regions are
granted asymmetric autonomous arrangements above and beyond what other
regions within the state possess. For example, the government in Catalonia in
Spain, currently headed by a regionalist-nationalist party (the Converg~ncia
Democritica de Catalunya, [CDC]), possesses high levels of formal auton-
omy through the constitution and high levels of control over the day-to-day
affairs within the province.2 As a result, Catalonia is coded as currently
autonomous.
We do not blindly follow formal laws, however, but also consider the
degree of de facto autonomy (especially in autocracies) in determining
whether to code a case as autonomous. For example, although Tibet is offi-
cially as an autonomous region in China, the Chinese government exerts con-
siderable control over the Tibetan government, appoints administrators from
foreign regions and directly selects its own Dalai Lama as an attempt to con-
trol Tibetan religious organizations, a key consideration considering the role
of Monks in Tibetan society. We therefore code Tibet as having lost auton-
omy in 1949.3
We argue that groups which have recently lost autonomy should be more
likely to engage in separatism than groups that are currently autonomous or
groups that were never autonomous, ceteris paribus. We hypothesize that lost
autonomy increases the likelihood of separatism through four main mecha-
nisms. First, it fosters ethnic resentment as a result of diminished status,
which engenders grievances that are increasingly hard to appease (e.g.,
Petersen, 2002). Second, it weakens the central government's ability to make
credible commitments, which reduces the viability of conciliatory political
strategies (e.g., Hale, 2008a; Hale, 2008b).
Third, retracting autonomy does not necessarily curb the group's collec-
tive action capacity, which was gained and developed under autonomy, as
leadership loss, generational replacement, and assimilation are relatively
slow processes (Siroky & Aprasdize, 2011). Finally, while the free rider prob-
lem is widely recognized, we suggest that the cost of free riding within a
group that recently lost autonomy may be higher than joining forces with
those who seek separation (Hechter, 2000; Kalyvas & Kocher, 2007), thus
making lost autonomy a particularly powerful basis for secession. Currently
autonomous groups must weigh the potential loss of their current status
against their unrealized desire for full independence, and we therefore predict
that they should be less prone to secession than those that recently lost
autonomy.
6 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
We develop this logic and derive several key empirical implications in the
next section. Using a data set that builds on the latest data sources on ethnic
politics and conflict, and covers roughly 330 ethnically distinct groups in
more than 110 states over a 40-year period, our analysis indicates that for-
merly autonomous groups are the most likely to secede, whereas currently
autonomous and never autonomous groups were significantly less likely to
do so. These results provide strong evidence regarding the impact of lost
autonomy on separatism, and are robust to matching on covariates, instru-
mental variables, different estimators, and confounding variables. 4 We also
find, in most models, that currently autonomous have a higher propensity for
separatism than groups that have never been autonomous. The results shed
new light on existing empirical results, and contribute to the long-standing
debate regarding the relationship between autonomy and separatism. The
final section discusses potential implications of this study for the design of
institutions in multiethnic countries and proposes several directions for future
research.
&
Okamoto, 2001; Horowitz, 1985; Kymlicka, 2008; Miodownik & Cartrite,
2010; Rogowski, 1985; Sambanis & Zinn, 2005; Treisman, 1997). Proponents
of autonomous institutional arrangements argue that political decentraliza-
tion is the primary means by which a large multiethnic state can relieve
ethno-regional tensions on its periphery and preserve a unified polity (Brass,
1991; Gurr, 2000; Kaufman, 1996; Lijphart, 1977; McGarry & O'Leary,
1993; Stepan, 1999; Tsebelis, 1990). The language of self-determination and
minority rights, which was originally used by the Great Powers to redraw
boundaries after World War I, and later used to justify the process of decolo-
nization, has been increasingly utilized by ethnic minority groups, which
have wielded it effectively to extract concessions from the central govern-
ment (Jenne, 2007; Jenne, 2010).
Most recently, decentralization of power to ethnic regions has been touted
as a potential solution to tensions with ethnic minority groups in Iraq and
Afghanistan (O'Hanlon & Joseph, 2007), and has been discussed in many
other hot spot regions around the world, including the Balkans (Guss
&
Siroky, 2012), Ethiopia (Ghai, 2000), and other parts of sub-Saharan Africa
(Forrest, 2004). Many studies have shown that autonomy bears a strong rela-
tionship to peace in the developed world (e.g., Spain, Germany, the United
Siroky and Cuffe 7
Okamoto, 2001), and we aim to provide some conceptual and empirical clar-
ity regarding the relationship between autonomy and separatism.
We suggest that to advance this debate it is crucial to disaggregate the
implicit baseline of comparison-"non-autonomous status." A binary (auton-
omous or not) framing of the debate over the effect of autonomy masks two
distinct scenarios: one in which an ethnic group has never been autonomous,
and another in which an ethnic group lost their autonomy. Although both are
technically not autonomous, we predict that one group (lost autonomy) is
highly prone to separatism, whereas the other group (never autonomous) is
very unlikely to pursue secession, because on average they lack both the lead-
ership and grievances required for collective action (Saxton, 2005).
By contrast, currently autonomous groups are more likely to have the
capacity to overcome collective action problems. The capacity for separatism
is largely irrelevant, however, if autonomous groups lack the desire for seces-
sion, either because the status quo satisfies their demand for self-determina-
tion or the potential risks associated with rebellion are excessively great.
8 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
&
Aprasdize, 2011; Siroky, Dzutsev, & Hechter, 2013). Retracted or lost auton-
omy provides a strong motive and need not significantly diminish the group's
collective action capacity. Moreover, it considerably weakens the govern-
ment's ability to make credible commitments that might otherwise prevent
tensions from escalating, making "voice" seem less likely to yield positive
results than exit, thereby increasing the probability of secession (Hirschman,
1970; North & Weingast, 1989; Siroky & Aprasdize, 2011).
Lost autonomy is not a new idea in political science. Gurr (1993) and Gurr
and Moore (1997), for example, both emphasized the impact of lost auton-
omy on rebellion. Our approach builds on this earlier literature and extends it
in two key ways. First, rather than comparing groups that have lost autonomy
to all other groups, we distinguish and disaggregate between groups that have
never been autonomous, groups that are currently autonomous and groups
that have lost autonomy. This conceptualization, we suggest, offers better
traction on the relationship between autonomy and separatism than a binary
classification. Second, we hypothesize that lost autonomy engenders resent-
ment, which increases the group's grievances, reduces the government's
capacity to make future credible commitments that might bring cooler heads
and calmer voices to the fore, and does not necessarily reduce the collective
action capacities and advantages that groups gained during autonomy (i.e.,
leaders, elite networks, and administrative experience). Autonomy retraction
may also decrease a group's collective action problems by increasing the cost
of free riding relative to participation (Kalyvas & Kocher, 2007).s In sum, we
argue that lost autonomy enhances both the motives and the capacities for
collective action, and reduces the government's ability to extend incentives
and attract moderates. This makes such groups (in the grey shaded box, Table
1) more likely to pursue secession than those groups with no history of auton-
omy and those that are currently autonomous (in the unshaded boxes, Table
1). This leads us to derive two main hypotheses:
Hypothesis 1: Groups that have lost autonomy are more likely to pursue
separatism than currently autonomous groups.
Hypothesis 2: Currently autonomous groups are more likely to pursue
separatism than groups with no history of autonomy.
Four Vignettes
Kosovo's Secession
Ethnic Albanians in Kosovo were granted special considerations under the
1946 Constitution, and were later granted full autonomy as a province
(Autonomna Pokrajina) in 1974 (Kubo, 2011). However, this situation was
quickly reversed in 1990, when the region effectively returned to its pre-1974
status. Slobodan Milosevic's increasing power within the quickly fragment-
ing Yugoslavia, along with the local government's discriminatory policies
toward ethnic Serbians (McGwire, 2000), led to public resentment over the
perceived "extremity" of Kosovo's autonomy within Yugoslavia (Petersen,
2002), and soon resulted in the formal revocation of Kosovo's autonomy in
1990 through constitutional changes (Silber, Little, & British Broadcast
Corporation, 1996; Zimmermann, 1999). These changes included abolishing
Kosovo's official public media, transferring control over state-owned compa-
nies to Belgrade, and replacing Albanian educational textbooks and educa-
tion in the Albanian language at Pristina University. Not surprisingly, the
revocation of autonomy led to reciprocal resentment among the ethnic
Albanians within Kosovo. Grievances escalated on both sides, and so did col-
lective action. On the Albanian side, the organizational structures developed
during their period of autonomy were still largely in tact, and played a crucial
role in their subsequent mobilization and eventual militarization.
Two factions emerged to represent the Kosovar Albanian case: Ibrahim
Rugova led the first group highlighting Kosovo's distinct ethnic identity and
heritage in ancient Dardania, a once independent kingdom and later a Roman
10 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
al., 1984). Between 1980 and 1983, the North seized several oil fields in the
South, which exacerbated tensions and increased the South's incentives to
pursue its own independence.6
The combination of political, economic, and cultural grievances let to the
formation of an opposition Southern People's Liberation Movement/Army
under the leadership of former national cabinet member John Garang. The
organization initially had the support of several international organizations
(Adar, 1998) and of Ethiopia (Kebbede, 1997b). The removal of Northern
President Nimeiri, due to backlash over drought, provided hope for a peace-
ful solution. In 1989, however, the National Islamic Front gained power in
the North (Kebbede, 1997b), rescinding many of the promises made to the
South and intensifying the conflict.
Despite several internal divisions, the Sudan People's Liberation Army
maintained an almost 30-year long separatist movement, which eventually
led to secession (Kebbede, 1997a). The movement for Southern Sudan used
the retraction of autonomy to powerful effect. While heterogeneous and
sometimes rival ethnic groups vied for power within the movement, its focal
point-a sense of cultural imperialism-sustained it. Moreover, leadership
experience gained during the period of autonomy, along with experience
gained from the regional legislative assembly, served the movement well in
overcoming the collective action problem required for the secessionist move-
ment to survive and ultimately to become the newest member of the United
Nations.
Parikh, 1988; Hechter, 1975). The Indian central government had been pro-
gressively encroaching on the traditional homeland of the Assamese since the
1970s. Tensions between "Assamese regional patriotism and pan-Indianism"
(Baruah, 2009, p. 953) escalated throughout the 1970s and 1980s (Gurr,
2009), especially during the 1983 local elections (Baruah, 2009; Dasgupta
&
autonomy reduced and ultimately retracted, and second, the leadership and
political capabilities developed during autonomy, first with the Movement
for Assam in the late 1970s and then with the UFLA, and through ties to the
former regional legislative assembly (Baruah, 2009). Both of these factors
have combined to sustain the movement for an independent Assam, despite
the overwhelming economic and military superiority of the Indian state, and
continue to serve as the movement's focal point for mobilization.
Summary of Vignettes
Although these cases all take place at different times and on different conti-
nents, a key dynamic clearly emerges and illustrates how lost autonomy
increased separatism relative both to the period during and prior to autonomy.
The case studies also clearly establish that, after losing autonomy, the groups
were struggling to move beyond autonomy, which was no longer credible,
rather than to regain autonomous status. When the central authorities retracted
autonomy from each of these groups (or full independence, in the case of
Tibet), the ethnic groups all responded by mobilizing and engaging in sus-
tained collective action to separate and establish an independent state. This
mobilization was more sustained and significant than collective action during
and before autonomy.
In Kosovo, the central government in Belgrade limited regional powers
and replaced local leaders with Belgrade-backed candidates. This led to the
"decisive protests" by Albanian workers that soon spread throughout the
region (Pula, 2004, p. 803). In the Sudan, the government in Khartoum
redrew the administrative lines of the South's autonomous region to control
oil supplies (Bennett, 1987) and later abolished the local government
(Kebbede, 1997a). This led to the formation of the South Sudanese Liberation
Army and widespread violence that dwarfed the conflict during and before
the period of autonomy, and ultimately resulted in a new state that has been
universally recognized. In Assam, the central government in New Delhi first
interfered directly into the economic affairs in the late 1970s and early 1980s,
and then formally revoked the region's autonomy. This led to significant vio-
lence and collective action aimed at secession from India, whereas prior ten-
sions had only been fully within the framework of autonomy.
In each case, revoking autonomy triggered collective action. If this rela-
tionship was endogenous-autonomy drove separatist collective action,
which led to autonomy retraction, then groups that lost autonomy should be
less separatist than groups that are currently autonomous, because the group
has lost the capacity to secede that it enjoyed under autonomy. The evidence
in these cases does not support this causal ordering, and instead indicates that
14 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Data Description
Our unit of analysis is the ethnic group-year within an individual state, mea-
sured every 5 years beginning in 1960 until 2000. This unit of analysis allows
us to analyze the differential mobilization of the same group in different
states. For example, using the research design, we are able to analyze why the
Kurds have mobilized in Turkey and Iraq much more than in Iran and Syria.
Moreover, the mechanisms that motivate the theoretical relationship between
lost autonomy and separatism focus on the relationship between the ethnic
group and the host state rather than on linkages across borders between
groups that are nominally the same. Common ethnic ancestry does not neces-
sarily imply cooperation across borders. Institutional differences between
states, for instance, can drastically alter perceptions of ethnicity, the salience
of cleavages and the demand for separatism.7 Most important, one state may
change the autonomous status of an ethnic minority, while the other state
does not, which would lead us to expect different group behavior and out-
comes. For instance, the retraction of autonomy in South Ossetia (in Georgia)
was not matched by the retraction of autonomy in North Ossetia (Russia), and
Siroky and Cuffe I15
the former mobilized for separatism, whereas the latter did not. The group-
year-state research design allows us to capture these crucial differences that
would be blurred if we were to use a more aggregated unit of analysis.
We built our data set drawing upon two primary sources. As our baseline,
we used the Ethnic Power Relations (EPR) data set,8 and then added addi-
tional data from the Minorities at Risk (MAR) project.9 For groups that were
omitted from the EPR and MAR data sets, or coded differently across the two
data sources, we conducted our search to sort out discrepancies. When groups
had the same name between MAR and EPR, the data were merged for every
group-year. For groups that were not in both MAR and EPR, we determined
whether one or the other data set: (1) had an exchangeable name for the same
group, (2) had aggregated distinct groups into a larger category, or (3) had no
equivalent in the other data set. In the case of (1), we simply renamed the
group to ensure a match. In cases of (2), we used the more disaggregated data,
and in cases of (3), we included the unmatched group in the new data set, and
coded missing covariates using secondary sources, if possible.
Our dependent variable is constructed on the basis of MAR's Separatism
Index, which we transformed from a 4-point unordered scale into a binary
indicator of a sustained political movement for separatism on behalf of an
ethnic group between 1960 and 2000.10 We also validated the coding of every
case in terms of its formal loss of autonomy and the timing of separatism
using qualitative data, and in most cases found that the coding from MAR
and EPR were accurate. When we could not identify clear separatist move-
ments, despite a civil war involving distinct ethnic groups, we adopted a con-
servative approach and coded the group as having no separatist movement.
This was especially relevant in cases of revolutionary conflict in which the
parties to the conflict could be distinguished by ethnicity (e.g., the Democratic
Republic of Congo), but none of the groups sought to separate from the cen-
tral state.
Our main independent variable is a trichotomous indicator of a group's
autonomy status. We utilize Wolff's criteria for "territorial self-governance"
with the qualification that the powers granted to groups must be asymmetric
within a state. To operationalize this concept, we relied on several sources. If
MAR's autonomy status indicator showed the group was autonomous in the
given year, we coded this as autonomous, unless it did not possess de facto
autonomy (e.g., Tibet). To distinguish between never autonomous groups and
those who lost their autonomy, we used MAR's AUTLOST index. This index
measures when, and to what degree, a group lost their autonomy. Any group
who's AUTLOST score was equal to or greater than "1" andwhere a specific
year of autonomy retraction was identified either through MAR's "autonend"
variable, the MAR Qualitative data on the group and EPR's "demoted"
16 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
&
Gleditsch, 2012). We argue that a similar mechanism occurs in the more spe-
cific case of separatism. As the number of politically excluded or vulnerable
ethnic groups in a state increases, the likelihood of a group becoming separat-
ist also increases. Third, we also include a measure of the group's spatial
concentration based on MAR's 4-point ordinal scale GCON. If a group is
highly concentrated, it is more likely to provide in-group social and eco-
nomic services to its members, a key role that must be played by rebel orga-
nizations aiming at secession (Mampilly, 2011; Toft, 2003; Weidmann,
2009).12 We also account for the presence of oil on the group's territory as an
indicator of economic viability and of the state's material interest in the
region (Collier & Hoeffler, 2004; Lujala, Rod, & Thieme, 2007). We include
a measure of external support for each ethnic group based data from Salehyan,
Gleditsch, and Cunningham (2011).13 We also control for GDP per capita at
the country level, which has been widely used as a proxy for state capacity
(Blattman & Miguel, 2010; Fearon & Laitin, 2003). Finally, in several speci-
fications, we include random effects for region and time to account for cross-
regional and temporal heterogeneity that is not explicitly modeled. 14
Before estimating our full model, we explore the straightforward bivariate
evidence, with autonomy status lagged 5 years. Figure 1 shows the propor-
tion of cases that engaged in separatism, sorted by autonomy status. It indi-
cates that, not controlling for other facts, groups which lost autonomy were
75% more likely to lead to separatism than groups that had autonomous sta-
tus. Moreover, autonomous groups were almost twice as likely to lead to
separatism than groups with no history of autonomy.
Figure 1 does not account for the possible correlation across group-years,
however. To account for these correlations and to investigate these
Siroky and Cuffe 17
Separatist
(0
C)
CL a
C
20
PAutonomy statuSikt
p(Separatism)ikt
P2 Regime Typekt P3 0 1 statuSikt
Autonomy
+P4 Region k P5 Excluded Group 5kt
P External Supportik ikt, +P6 LoggedGDPPCkt P70ilik 8
where i is the subscript for a given group in a country k in time period t. Such
a model allows us to control for correlation of observations both within each
country and across time. In the next section, we discuss the results of our
analysis of this model.
Discussion of Results
The core result shows that the loss of autonomy significantly increases the
likelihood of separatism. Table 2 depicts this result using a nonlinear mixed
model (Pinheiro, Bates, DebRoy, Sarkar, & R Development Core Team,
V: 1fl Il V: q~ OR qm l . .
~~~~~~~,
0 ~,~
'- ~
.
-0 4GMW~t~mgmm$9 "o o6~
O m- --oN OOcO ~ V -o
I I I I I I I I
,-- c- co c
- m m '0 ' m W 00 IO 0~ 0 '04
E m cp c -m m ,r 0 Nc0'0
0
-
0
E
0
E rN 0 -- ' - ccmc
0
m'0 c
-666666666 .--.
. .m. U
.
E
u
_0
0 E
0
z
-
0 0
0 0 o0 o E U0 0
0 L
> 2 o*
E Cv
CU >- U -J< coU (5
0 no L
a
(
0*O -
18
Siroky and Cuffe I19
C9
0
00 02 04 06 083 10
False Alarm Rate
-6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6
-
Hybrid Regime
-
Democracy
Group Concentration -
-
Excluded Groups
-
-
Europe and (former) USSR -
$
Latin America 0
North Africa and ME
-
Sub-Saharan Africa -
-
Western Dems.
-
Year (Fixed)
Robustness
As groups are not randomly assigned to their respective autonomy categories,
and researchers are unable to manipulate the assignment to groups, care must
be taken in making causal statements.
Autonomy is retracted and lost through disparate causal processes, which
fall outside the scope of our argument concerning its effect. Access to
resources may encourage a state to expand into its periphery, and thus to
encroach on an ethnic group's traditional territory. Or the motives may be less
economic and more political: A borderland inhabited by "ethnic others" is
deprived of its autonomous status for fear that it may become a fifth column
in an interstate dispute. This analysis is agnostic on which of these reasons
best accounts for a region's loss of autonomy, yet we would agree that further
disaggregation along these lines could result in the discovery of important
theoretical distinctions between economically motivated versus politically
driven autonomy retraction and status reversal.
Our primary concern is to address the possibility that the model is endog-
enous-separatist activity leads to the retraction of autonomy. Although we
22 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Never Never
Autonomous Autonomous Autonomous
-
Democracy 0.82 (1.47) -0.17 (0.68) -0.19 (0.96)
Partial Democracy 1.50 (1.21) -0.36 (0.49) 0.14 (0.61)
Group Concentration -1.02 (99) 1.15 (0.22)* 0.20 (0.25)
E. Europe and (fmr) USSR 1.93 (3.07) -3.54 (1.5 1)* -7.64 (2.3 1)*
Latin America -2.68 (2.22) -2.97 (1.97) -6.08 (3.40)*
North Africa and ME 3.25 (1.95) 0.26 (1.95) -0.32 (3.00)
Sub-Saharan Africa -1.86 (1.41) -2.93 (1.38)* -3.61 (2.16)*
Western Democracies 4.25 (3.23) 0.63 (2.10) 1.85 (4.02)
Excluded Groups -0.05 (0.07) -0.02 (0.02) 0.01 (0.02)
Logged GDPPC -0.10 (0.74) -0.14 (0.30) 0.12 (0.42)
Oil 0.77 (0.52) 0.11 (0.41) 0.53 (0.37)
Year (Fixed) -0.01 (0.05) 0.02 (0.02) -0.00 (0.03)
Random Effects
Country 1.58 (1.26)* 12.17 (3.48)* 20.75 (4.55)*
Log-Likelihood -23.39 -264.74 -214.61
Deviance 46.77 529.49 459.23
AIC 214.01 559.49 523.96
BIC 264.57 628.34 452.83
N 77 730 475
Groups 21 86 66
Standard errors in parentheses. Observations were weighted according to matched data. AIC = Akaike
information criterion; BIC = Bayesian information criterion. *p < 0.05.
that have lost autonomy are likely to engage in more intense separatism than
both currently autonomous and never autonomous groups.19
These results are displayed in Table 4.20 Figures 5 and 6 illustrate the pos-
terior densities and trace plots for groups that lost their autonomy and then for
21
groups which were never autonomous.
Conclusion
In his Second Treatise, John Locke observed that men are unlikely to cause
revolutions for trivial reasons. This analysis shows that a tangible loss of
autonomy is a nontrivial issue, and is robustly associated with separatism.
The retraction of autonomy provides a strong motive by invariably increasing
24 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Mean Credible
*
External Support 1.02 (0.24) [0.55, 1.50]
*
Excluded Groups 0.01 (0.02) [-0.02, 0.44]
GDPPC (Logged) -0. 1 (0.15)* [-0.42, -0.19]
E. Europe/former USSR -0.43 (0.71) [-1.71, 1.00]
Latin America -2.5 I (0.42) [-2.99, -1.57]
Middle East and North Africa 0.00 (.82) [-1.62, 1.57]
Sub-Saharan Africa -1.05 (0.64) [-2.13, 0.29]
Western Democracies 0.20 (0.95) [-1.52, 0.20]
Year 0.01 (0.31) [-0.02, 0.04]
Post-Cold War 0.16 (0.01) [-0.45, 0.76]
Cut-points
No Separatism: Peaceful Separatism - 1.98 (0.02)* [-1.99, -1.93]
Peaceful Separatism: Minor Conflict 0.35 (0.08) [0.16, 0.52]
*
Countries 100
Groups 324
Group-Years 1 198
Standard deviations are in parentheses, 95% credible intervals in brackets. Minor conflict if
less than 20 battle deaths per year, and major conflict if more than 20 battle deaths per year.
*Indicates the probability of the coefficient being <.05.
grievances against the central state while not necessarily decreasing the
group's collective action capacity. By disaggregating the omitted category in
research on the institutional determinants of conflict, and showing that lost
autonomy represents a conceptually distinct class of group status, our find-
ings go some way toward explaining the "empirical murkiness" within the
academic literature on the relationship between institutional arrangements,
such as ethno-federalism, and separatism.
Taking concept formation seriously can yield new insights and can high-
light important theoretical and empirical distinctions. By separating groups
that have lost autonomy from groups who have never been autonomous-
which were previously lumped together as "non-autonomous" in many
Siroky and Cuffe 25
Figure 5. Posterior density plot for autonomous (L) and lost autonomy (R).
Figure 6. Trace plot for autonomous (L) and lost autonomy (R).
Acknowledgments
This article and early musings on the subject benefited from helpful comments and
encouragement that we would like to recognize: Roy Allison, David Aprasidze, Yael
Aronoff, Mark Axelrod, Galia Benitez, Lenka Bustikova, Dennis Dafflon, Alexis
Diamond, Alexander Downes, Ross Emmett, Sherman Garnett, Norm Graham,
Bernard Grofman, Giorgi Gvalia, Henry Hale, Michael Hechter, Courtney Hillebrecht,
Donald Horowitz, Erin Jenne, Elene Jibladze, Alice Kang, Nam Kyu Kim, Matthew
Kocher, Ari Kohen, Hrant Kostanyan, Adria Lawrence, Levente Littvay, Jason Lyall,
Anthony McGann, Patrice McMahon, Ross Miller, Emily Molfino, Harris Mylonas,
Nino Pavlenishvili, Natalia Peral, Linda Racioppi, Wolfgang Reinicke, Nicholas
Sambanis, Tariel Sikharulidze, Erik Wibbels, and Matt Zierler. We are also grateful
for anonymous feedback from the review process, and for suggestions from audience
members at Arizona State University, Academic Swiss Caucasus Net, Association for
the Study of Nationalities, Central European University, Michigan State University,
University of California-Irvine, and University of Nebraska-Lincoln.
Funding
The authors received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publica-
tion of this article.
Notes
1. For a case to satisfy the definition of autonomy adopted here, this arrangement
must be institutionalized, yet we recognize that the extent of institutionalization
varies by country and context. For example, in relatively strong states, such as
Spain, the formal limits of autonomy (e.g., for Catalonia) may be very well spec-
ified, whereas in weaker states, autonomy may be less formalized, but nonethe-
less widely recognized and acknowledged (e.g., Westerners in Cameroon prior to
1975).
2. Artur Mas I Gavarro of the CDC.
3. We are cognizant that the meaning of autonomy is contextual, and may vary
not only from place to place but also over time. This is especially an issue for
autonomies in autocracies, where the degree of self-rule is often pro forma. In
China, for instance, formal autonomy is mainly a fiction-formally autonomous
Xinjiang and Tibet are arguably less autonomous than Shanghai or Guangdong,
which are not formally autonomous. In our coding of such cases, we are careful
to account for this contextual difference across countries. We also conduct the
analysis controlling for regime type, and with separate samples for each regime
type, to examine whether the main results are robust.
4. We are cognizant that separatism is often ill-defined. Some (Treisman, 1997)
argue separatism is a "spectrum" from demands to increased local powers
through full separation from the state (p. 214). Here, we follow Cederman,
Wimmer, and Min (2010) in defining separatism as the pursuit of independence
from the central government-not necessarily the achievement of independence.
5. Although we focus on the pursuit of secession, rather than on rebellion in this
article, this disaggregated approach may also shed light on the findings in Gurr
(1993) and Gurr and Moore (1997); in the former, lost autonomy was a signifi-
cant predictor of rebellion, but it was not in the latter.
6. These events have led some scholars to describe the ensuing conflict as one based
on contestation of resources, rather than ethnic differences (Suliman, 1997). Our
position is that seizing oil fields, and instituting Islamic policies, were both part
of the process of reducing the South's autonomy, and is therefore consistent with
our argument.
7. While not directly related to separatism, see Posner's (2004) discussion of how
the ethnic makeup within different states alters the salience of ethnic cleavages.
8. http://www.epr.ucla.edu/
9. www.cidcm.umd.edu/mar
10. The original coding is unordered with four levels: No Separatism, Latent
Separatism, Historical (1940-1980) Separatism, and Active (1980-2000)
Separatism. As our main interest here is on the presence of separatism, we
28 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
References
Adar, K. G. (1998). A state under siege: The internationalization of the Sudanese
Civil War. African Security Review, 7(1), 44-53.
Siroky and Cuffe 29
Agence France Presse. (1995, February 17). Unknown Albanian "liberation army"
claims Kosovo attacks. Retrieved from http://lexis-nexis.com/universe
Ahmed, F. (2012). The perils of unearned foreign income: Aid, remittances, and gov-
ernment. American PoliticalScience Review, 106, 146-155.
Baruah, S. (2009). Separatist militants and contentious politics in Assam, India: The
limits of counterinsurgency. Asian Survey, 49, 951-974.
Bennett, J. (1987). The hunger machine. Cambridge, UK: Polity Press.
Bermeo, N. (2002). The import of institutions. JournalofDemocracy, 13, 96-110.
Bermeo, N., & Amoretti, U. (2003). Federalismand territorialcleavages. Baltimore,
MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Beshir, M., Mohammad-Salih, M. A., & Abdul-Jalil, M. A. (1984). The Sudan:
Ethnicity and national cohesion (Bayreuth African Studies Series). Bayreuth,
Germany: Universitat Bayreuth.
Biel, M. R. (2003). The Civil War in Southern Sudan and its effect on youth and chil-
dren. Social Work and Society InternationalOnline Journal, 1, 119-127.
Blattman, C., & Miguel, E. (2010). Civil war. Journalof Economic Literature, 48,
3-57.
Bound, J., Jaeger, D. A., & Baker, R. M. (1995). Problems with instrumental variables
estimation when the correlation between the instruments and the endogenous
explanatory variable is weak. Journal of the American Statistical Association,
90, 443-450.
Brancati, D. (2009). Peace by design. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Brass, P. R. (1991). Ethnicity and nationalism: Theory and comparison. Newbury
Park, CA: Sage.
Bunce, V. (1999). Subversive institutions: The design and the collapse of socialism
and the state. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Bustikova, L. (2014). Revenge of the radical right. ComparativePoliticalStudies 48.
Cederman, L.-E., Wimmer, A., & Min, B. (2010). Why do ethnic groups rebel? New
data and analysis. World Politics, 62, 87-119.
Clark, H. (2000). Civil resistance in Kosovo. London, England: Pluto Press.
Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (2004). Greed and grievance in civil war. Oxford Economic
Papers,56, 563-595.
Coppieters, B. (2001). Federalism and conflict in the Caucasus. London, England:
Royal Institute of International Affairs.
Cornell, S. E. (2002). Autonomy as a source of conflict: Caucasian conflicts in theo-
retical perspective. World Politics, 54, 245-276.
Costalli, S., & Moro, F. N. (2012). Ethnicity and strategy in the Bosnian civil war:
Explanations for the severity of violence in Bosnian municipalities. Journalof
Peace Research, 49, 801-815.
Cunningham, K., & Beaulieu, E. (2010). Dissent, repressions, and inconsistency.
In E. Chenoweth & A. Lawrence (Eds.), Rethinking violence (pp. 173-196).
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Darnell, A. T., & Parikh, S. (1988). Religion, ethnicity, and the role of the state:
Explaining conflict in Assam. Ethnic and Racial Studies, 11, 263-281.
30 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Dasgupta, K., & Guha, A. (1985). 1983 assembly poll in Assam: An analysis of its
background and implications. Economic and PoliticalWeekly, 20, 843-853.
Deng, F. M. (2006). Sudan: A nation in turbulent search of itself. Annals of the
American Academy ofPoliticaland Social Science, 603, 155-162.
Diamond, A., & Sekhon, J. S. (2006). Genetic matching for estimating causal effects:
A general multivariate matching method for achieving balance in observational
studies. Review ofEconomics and Statistics, 95, 932-945.
Diamond, L. (1999). Developing democracy: Toward consolidation. Baltimore, MD:
Johns Hopkins University Press.
Eprile, C. (1974). War and peace in the Sudan, 1955-1972. London, England: David
& Charles.
Epstein, D., Bates, R., Goldstone, J., Kristensen, I., & O'Halloran, S. (2006).
Democratic transitions. American JournalofPoliticalScience, 50, 551-556.
Fearon, J. D., & Laitin, D. D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and Civil War. American
PoliticalScience Review, 97, 75-90.
Forrest, J. B. (2004). Subnationalism in Africa: Ethnicity, alliances, and politics.
Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Fuller, G., Morrison, R., Murphy, A., & Ridley, M. (2002). Potential for ethnic con-
flict in China. EurasianGeography and Economics, 43, 583-611.
Ghai, Y. (2000). Autonomy and ethnicity: Negotiating competing claims in multi-
ethnic states. Cambridge, UK: University Press Cambridge.
Gladney, D. C. (2003). Islam in China: Accommodation or separatism? The China
Quarterly, 174, 451-467.
Gleditsch, K. S. (2008). Modified polity P4 and P4D data (3rd ed.). Retrieved from
http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm
Gleditsch, N. P., Wallensteen, P., Eriksson, M., Sollenberg, M., & Strand, H. (2002).
Armed conflict 1946-2001: A new dataset. JournalofPeace Research, 39, 615-
637.
Greenhill, B., Ward, M., & Sacks, A. (2011). The separation plot: A new visual
method for evaluating the fit of binary models. American Journal of Political
Science, 55, 991-1002.
Gurr, T. R. (1993). Why minorities rebel: A global analysis of communal mobiliza-
tion and conflict since 1945. InternationalPoliticalScience Review, 14, 161-201.
Gurr, T. R. (2000). Peoples versus states: Minorities at risk in the new century.
Washington, DC: United States Institute of Peace.
Gurr, T.R., & Moore, W. (1997). Ethnopolitical rebellion: A cross-sectional analysis
of the 1980s with risk assessments for the 1990s. American Journalof Political
Science, 41, 1079-1103.
Gurr, T. R. (2009). Minorities at risk dataset. Retrieved from http://www.cidcm.umd.
edu/mar/
Guss, J., & Siroky, D. (2012). Living with heterogeneity: Bridging the ethnic divide
in Bosnia and beyond. Comparative Sociology, 11, Article 304.
Hadfield, J. (2010). Mcmc methods for multi-response generalised linear mixed mod-
els: The mcmc-glmm r package. JournalofStatisticalSoftware, 33(2), 1-22.
Siroky and Cuffe 31I
Salehyan, I., Gleditsch, K. S., & Cunningham, D. E. (2011). Explaining external sup-
port for insurgent groups. InternationalOrganization,65, 709-744.
Salih, M. (1994). The ideology of the Dinka and the Sudan People's Liberation
Movement. In K. Fukui & J. Markakis (Eds.), Ethnicity and conflict in the horn
ofAfrica (pp. 187-201). Oxford, UK: James Currey.
Sambanis, N., & Zinn, A. (2005). From protest to violence: An analysis of conflict
escalation with an application to self-determination movements. Unpublished
manuscript.
Sautman, B. (1999). The Tibet issue in post-summit Sino-American relations. Pacific
Affairs, 72, 7-21.
Sautman, B. (2005). China's strategic vulnerability to minority separatism. Asian
Affairs, 32, 87-118.
Saxton, G. (2005). Repression, grievances, mobilization, and rebellion: A new test
of Gurr's model of ethnopolitical rebellion. InternationalInteractions,31, 1-30.
Sekhon, J. S. (2004). The varying role of voter information across democratic soci-
eties. In Annual Meeting of the Midwestern Political Science Association.
Retrieved from http://polmeth.wustl.edu/mediaDetail.php?docId=39
Shakya, T. (1999). A dragon in the land of snows. New York, NY: Columbia
University Press.
Silber, L., Little, A., & British Broadcast Corporation. (1996). Yugoslavia: death of
a nation. Penguin Books. Retrieved from http://books.google.com/books/about/
Yugoslavia.html?id=QJztAAAAMAAJ
Sinha, S. (2007). Lost opportunities: 50 years of insurgency in the North-east and
India 's response. New Delhi, India: Lancer Publishers.
Siroky, D., & Aprasidze, D. (2011). Guns, roses and democratization: Huntington's
secret admirer in the Caucasus. Democratization, 18, 1227-1245.
Siroky, D., Dzutsev, V., & Hechter, M. (2013). The differential demand for indirect
rule: Evidence from the North Caucasus. Post-SovietAffairs, 29, 268-286.
Slezkine, Y. (1994). The USSR as a communal apartment, or how a socialist state
promoted ethnic particularism. Slavic Review, 53, 414-452.
Sovey, A. J., & Green, D. P. (2011). Instrumental variable estimation in political sci-
ence. American JournalofPoliticalScience, 55, 188-200.
Stepan, A. (1999). Federalism and democracy: Beyond the U.S. model. Journalof
Democracy, 10(1), 19-34.
Streat-Bartlett, A. (2009). Secessionist conflict in post-soviet republics. Presented at
annual meeting of the Southern Political Science Association, New Orleans, LA.
Suliman, M. (1997). Civil war in Sudan: The impact of ecological degradation.
Contributions in Black Studies, 15, 99-12 1.
Teufel, J. D. (2005). China's vulnerability to minority separatism. Asian Affairs, 32,
69-86.
Toft, M. D. (2003). The geography of ethnic violence: Identity, interests, and the
indivisibility of territory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Treisman, D. (1997). Russia's "ethnic revival": The separatist activism of regional
leaders in a post-communist order. World Politics, 49, 212-249.
34 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Author Biographies
David S. Siroky is an assistant professor of political science in the School of Politics
and Global Studies at Arizona State University, where he is a core faculty member of
the Center for Social Dynamics and Complexity and a faculty affiliate of the Center
for the Study of Religion and Conflict and the Melikian Center for Russian, Eurasian
and East European Studies. He received his PhD in political science and MA in eco-
nomics from Duke University and was a postdoctoral fellow at Yale University. His
research has appeared or is forthcoming in Comparative Sociology, Defence and
Peace Economics, Democratization, Ethnopolitics, International Organization,
Nationalities Papers, Polity, Post-Soviet Affairs, Security Studies, and Statistics
Surveys.