A Cultural History of Famine
A Cultural History of Famine
A Cultural History of Famine
The term “food security” does not immediately signal research done in
humanities disciplines. It refers to a complex, contested issue, whose cur-
rency and significance are hardly debatable given present concerns about
environmental change, resource management, and sustainability.
The subject is thus largely studied within science and social science dis-
ciplines in current or very recent historical contexts. This book brings
together perspectives on food security and related environmental con-
cerns from experts in the disciplines of literary studies, history, science,
and social sciences. It allows readers to compare past and contemporary
attitudes towards the issue in India and Britain – the economic, social, and
environmental histories of these two nations have been closely connected
ever since British travellers began to visit India in the latter half of the six-
teenth century. The chapters in this book discuss themes such as climate,
harvest failure, trade, technological improvements, transport networks,
charity measures, and popular protest, which affected food security in
both countries from the seventeenth century onwards. The authors cover
a range of disciplinary and interdisciplinary approaches, and their chap-
ters allow readers to understand and compare different methodologies as
well as different contexts of time and place relevant to the topic.
This book will be of great interest to students and researchers of eco-
nomic and social history, environmental history, literary studies, and South
Asian studies.
Editorial Board
Christina Alt, St Andrews University, UK
Alison Bashford, University of New South Wales, Australia
Peter Coates, University of Bristol, UK
Thom van Dooren, University of New South Wales, Australia
Georgina Endfield, Liverpool, UK
Jodi Frawley, University of Western Australia, Australia
Andrea Gaynor, The University of Western Australia, Australia
Christina Gerhardt, University of Hawai’i at Mānoa, USA
Tom Lynch, University of Nebraska, Lincoln, USA
Iain McCalman, University of Sydney, Australia
Jennifer Newell, Australian Museum, Sydney, Australia
Simon Pooley, Imperial College London, UK
Sandra Swart, Stellenbosch University, South Africa
Ann Waltner, University of Minnesota, USA
Jessica Weir, University of Western Sydney, Australia
Edited by
Ayesha Mukherjee
First published 2019
by Routledge
2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN
and by Routledge
52 Vanderbilt Avenue, New York, NY 10017
Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business
© 2019 selection and editorial matter, Ayesha Mukherjee; individual
chapters, the contributors
The right of Ayesha Mukherjee to be identified as the author of the
editorial matter, and of the authors for their individual chapters, has
been asserted in accordance with sections 77 and 78 of the
Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or
reproduced or utilised in any form or by any electronic, mechanical,
or other means, now known or hereafter invented, including
photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or
retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publishers.
Trademark notice: Product or corporate names may be trademarks or
registered trademarks, and are used only for identification and
explanation without intent to infringe.
British Library Cataloguing-in-Publication Data
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
A catalog record has been requested for this book
PART I
Historical interpretations 19
PART II
Roads and rivers 71
PART III
Politics of climate and relief 111
PART IV
Contemporary voices and memories 149
Bibliography 199
Index 223
Figures
I would like to thank the Arts and Humanities Research Council, UK, for
funding our project workshop, “Food Security and the Environment in
India and Britain” (2015), which first brought together the contributors
to this book. I am also grateful to the Smith School of Enterprise and the
Environment, University of Oxford, who provided us with a venue and
supported our workshop discussions in many ways. Thank you, all particip-
ants who contributed to the workshop. A Cultural History of Famine has
evolved from these discussions, and the exchanges and debates that con-
tinued beyond our first meeting. I am deeply grateful to colleagues who
have contributed chapters, for their sustained enthusiasm, time, and
patience.
At the University of Exeter, I would like to thank colleagues in the
Department of English, the Centre for South Asia Research, and the
Digital Humanities team; and at Jadavpur University and Aligarh Muslim
University, colleagues in the English and History departments and the
Institute of Persian Research. This book has benefited from their encour-
agement and support.
It has been a pleasure to work again with Routledge; many thanks, from
all contributors, to Leila Walker, Rebecca Brennan and Steve Turrington
for their wonderful and patient assistance.
Ayesha Mukherjee
Abbreviations
This line was translated by Sir Henry Miers Elliot in his edition of excerpts
as “the flesh of a son was preferred to his love” (1875: 26). Elliot’s trans-
lation obscures, in my opinion, the deliberate poeticism of
and Lāhawrī’s self-conscious shift to the poetic register of the macabre and
grotesque from the factual register of chronicling events. In early modern
accounts of famine, this kind of rhetorical shift is frequent, and cuts across
place, language, and literary mode or genre. Reports of famine-induced
cannibalism and desperate forms of eating abound in travelogues, poems,
and chronicles, across time and space. Lāhawrī’s predecessor, Abul Fazl,
the court historian of Shah Jahan’s grandfather, the emperor Akbar,
described men eating each other in desperation during a famine
(1554–56) that had inaugurated Akbar’s reign (Fazl, 1907–39, II: 30). The
East India Company (EIC) factor Peter Mundy, whose recording of the
Gujarat famine during Shah Jahan’s reign will be discussed later in this
book, noticed people who looked like human “annatomies”, sifting
through the dung of travellers’ horses in hopes of finding undigested
grain (Mundy, 1907–36, II: 44). In quite a different context, Piero Campo-
resi’s famous studies of hunger (1989, 1996) give numerous examples,
2 Ayesha Mukherjee
from early modern Italy, of extreme forms of eating. One of Camporesi’s
examples is Giovan Battista Spaccini’s Cronaca modenese which described
how, in 1601 in the town of Reggio, neighbours discovered three young
boys, whose parents had fled the famine: “they found two of the sons
dead, and the third dying with straw in his mouth, and on the fire there
was a pot with straw inside which was being boiled in order to make it
softer for eating” (1919, vol. 2: 177; Camporesi, 1989: 85). After the four-
year period of dearth and famine in 1590s England, the poetry anthology
Englands Parnassus (1600) personified Dearth and Famine as cannibals,
whose “greedie gorge” consumed their “owne deere babes”, as well as
their own flesh (256; Mukherjee, A., 2015: 1–3). A Cultural History of
Famine attends to such modes of representing famine and dearth, and
their historical contexts.
To regard such accounts as sensational disruptions of the narration of
factual evidence of famines would be to undermine the complex function
of the Mughal chronicle (or other literary writing) as a cultural document.
Lāhawrī was allegedly asked by Shah Jahan to model his chronicle on the
style of Abul Fazl. Thus, continuity of rhetorical tradition and style was as
important for Mughal imperial “self-fashioning”1 as the consistent record-
ing of key events across a temporal continuum that connected emperors
to their ancestry. Yet, to return to Lāhawrī’s trope, there seem to be few
accounts of famine cannibalism which utilised the macabre and the grot-
esque to such devastatingly succinct effect. This was rhetorically achieved
by words that selectively evoked fundamental things in human life: flesh,
sweet, love, son. Readers were asked to imagine the unimaginable: in what
condition of physiological deprivation and mental aberration would the
flesh of your son taste sweeter than his love? The horror of famine was lit-
erally and physically tasted in this trope, which used ironic exaggeration to
signal the absolute breakdown of closest kinship ties and moral agency
among human beings. What is also underlined here is the realisation that,
beyond a point, famine sufferers, physiologically and mentally, inhabit a
different zone from the rest of humanity. When we encounter representa-
tions of hunger-driven extremes, whether in Lāhawrī, or Spaccini, or – to
consider another representational mode and timeframe – in Zainul Abed-
in’s remarkable sketches of the 1943 Bengal famine (Sen, 1944), which
blended the horrific and the mundane, these demand extreme ways of
imagining human degradation and the breakdown of kinship, humanity,
and morality.2
Forms of representing famine, despite similarities in their rhetorical
strategies, are distinct and relate to their specific contexts. There are many
degrees of horror in the different types of famine representation and
reportage: not all are as brilliantly sensational as Lāhawrī. But even the
most factual kinds of reporting, such as official EIC correspondence, are
often emotive, beneath the surface of official structure. The sifting of fact
from fiction, in the strictest sense, is frequently difficult, because the
Introduction 3
reporting itself is coloured by human perceptions, imagination, a sense of
duty or loyalty, and politics. In seeking to understand how “a cultural
history of famine” might be constituted, this book considers how famines
(and their remedies) have been imagined, or, for that matter, misunder-
stood or forgotten, as part of the construction of famine history. Famines
are not only about sensational extremities – they are also linked with
periods of dearth, in differing degrees, so that the point at which “dearth”
slips into “famine” can be highly context specific and tricky to identify or
generalise.3 Indeed, in human memory and in literary sources, famine and
dearth are often conceived as interchangeable conditions, as in the similar
personifications of Dearth and Famine in Englands Parnassus. Moreover,
habits of economy and mundane life work alongside conditions of dearth
and famine (Thirsk, 1967, 2007; Mukherjee, A., 2015: 145–94). Both con-
ditions affect social norms, patterns of economic exchange, political
behaviour, and the moral life of human beings. A Cultural History of Famine
thus calls for an approach that looks at, but also beyond, causalities, such
as climate change, or market prices, or political events like wars and rebel-
lions, and towards human responses in times of dearth and famine.
India Britain
1554–56 1555–57
1596–1600 1596–1600
1630–32 1630–32
– 1647–49
1658–63 1658–61
1691–97 1693–97
– 1709–10
– 1727–28
1732–37 –
1752–55 1756–57
1767–70 –
1777–79 –
1783–84 –
1787–93 –
Sources: Hoskins (1964, 1968); Walter and Schofield (1989); Habib (1999); Moosvi (1987,
2008); Datta (2000); Grove and Chapell (2000).
In Britain, their effects and intensities varied locally, but in some cases (for
example, in the 1590s) the crises were experienced across the nation
(Hoskins, 1968; Appleby, 1978; Walter, 1989). In India, famines occurred
throughout the Mughal period in the Northern provinces, Bengal, and
the south (Habib, 1999; Moosvi, 2008; Datta, 2000; Subrahmanyam, 1990).
The famine chronologies of the two countries in this early period are
uncannily parallel, matched almost decade by decade, until the mid-
eighteenth century. After this, famines seem to no longer afflict Britain,
although they continue unabated in India, as Walter and Datta demon-
strate in the first two chapters of this book.
It may be argued that the reasons for this remarkable parallelism were
climatic: the links between severe El Niño events, the coldest periods of
the Little Ice Age, and droughts in tropical regions, have long been the
subject of investigation and debate among climate scientists and historians
(Grove, 1994; Grove and Chapell, 2000).7 Table I.1 shows the most acute
points of crisis, as represented in the existing historiography of famine
and dearth for both nations, covering the period 1550–1800.8 Climatolo-
gists have shown that difficult winters and poor crops in European regions
have coincided with El Niño events, and archival data uncovered by histor-
ians suggests that from the seventeenth to the nineteenth centuries, a
number of El Niños had wider and more intense global effects than those
of the twentieth century (Lamb, 1977; Grove and Chappell, 2000, 7–20;
Quinn et al., 1987; Ortlieb, 1998). But whether coincidence is evidence
remains a question. As Damodaran and her colleagues argue, in Chapter
3, finding answers to such questions requires “more detailed mining of
documentary and paleo sources” across time and space. Nevertheless, the
Introduction 5
congruence, this book suggests, shapes cultural evidence regarding famine
and dearth, especially if we consider this in relation to socio-economic
exchanges between the selected nations.
Forms of exchange
Grove and Chappell comment that
They suggest that these stresses may have facilitated European expansion.
India and Britain thus offer a useful case study of how pre-colonial experi-
ences of famine and dearth impacted on later crises during the course of
colonial expansion, when famines and their memories had arguably
become more remote in Britain itself, and were perceived as issues affect-
ing its distant colonies.9 Despite differences in scale and local ecologies,
from the sixteenth to the eighteenth centuries, both contexts register
chronic instabilities, sharp contrasts, and fears generated by the close
proximity of plenty and dearth. National and local economies struggled to
build physical infrastructures to cope with uncertainties of climate and
create a secure agricultural environment. This was a formative period for
cultural interactions between the two countries. British emissaries trav-
elled frequently through famine-ridden Indian terrain along with local
migrants displaced by shortages. One such example is Peter Mundy, dis-
cussed in Chapter 4, who travelled from Surat to Agra and back during the
Gujarat famine (1630–32), possibly caused by moderate El Niños which
led to acute drought in this and other Asian regions (Quinn, 1992; Grove
and Chappell, 2000: 15). The experience of constant mobility and unset-
tledness was shared by Company men and local populations. Indeed,
British travellers to India were familiar with negative ecological con-
sequences of dearth-driven vagrancy and displacement in their own
national context (see, for example, Fumerton, 2006).
Conditions for the exchange and interaction of cultural understandings
of famine, dearth, and ecological ethics were thus created. Early modern
and pre-colonial contexts of what these economic and environmental
issues meant, and how they were addressed across seemingly separate cul-
tural zones, are yet to be properly examined. At the same time, despite the
existence of many valuable historical studies of famines in Indian colonial
and post-colonial contexts, there is a need for more reflection, first, on
how this shared early modern and pre-colonial history of famine and
6 Ayesha Mukherjee
dearth may have impacted colonial famine and food security policies; and,
second, on how internal British concerns about food shortage, in key con-
texts such as the institution of the Poor Laws, or post-war food shortages,
may have played out in relation to remedial (or exploitative) actions
undertaken in the colonies. In its engagement with such questions, this
book is concerned with the ways in which the past relates to the present:
how we might understand the lessons of the past (temporally remote con-
texts), or learn from the experience of other communities (geographically
remote contexts).
Comprehensive coverage of five centuries of famine history, in two coun-
tries, and in a single volume, is therefore not the purpose here. The chap-
ters engage with methodological debates, and bring fresh perspectives often
by highlighting regional, micro-level conditions which had a wider impact.
In Part I, “Historical interpretations”, John Walter offers a vital overview of
responses to famine and dearth in early modern England, arguing that the
“infrapolitics” of the people tried to maintain, in the face of economic and
intellectual change and exchange, forms of social and governmental
responses offering protection against the crisis of dearth. In his reassessment
of moral economy and the English social order, Walter points out that,
despite demographic evidence of crisis mortality and the “silent violence” of
dearth, famine was regionally selective; and the reciprocities of “common-
wealth”, rather than profits of commodity, continued to be significant in the
mental world of early modern society, especially during harvest failure. In
this context, he examines the role of popular protest, characterised by a dis-
ciplined (frequently symbolic) violence, preferring negotiation, rather than
reflecting the elite stereotypes of thievery, random violence, and disorder. In
the next chapter, Rajat Datta shifts focus from the social and moral economy
of food crisis to questions of evaluating “subsistence crises” as economic
history; the context also shifts from early modern England to pre-colonial
Bengal. However, Datta, like Walter, raises wider interpretative issues. He
explores how we might construct an economic history of subsistence crises,
which are often seen as severe dislocations in the “normal” run of things,
whose economic consequences were considered “excess” points – excess
starvation, excess mortality, and so on. Addressing a different kind of (histo-
riographic) silence around the interims between excess points, Datta
demonstrates how a serious scarcity (even if not a full blown famine) dis-
mantled economic structures of subsistence in pre-colonial systems, reliant
on production, circulation, and consumption. Based on his data on
eighteenth-century Bengal, Datta advocates constructing an economic
history of subsistence focused on variables such as market networks, money,
exchange mechanisms, and price fluctuations.
While Walter’s and Datta’s introductions to the moral and subsistence
economies suggest ways of understanding human agency during famine
and dearth, in Chapter 3, Vinita Damodaran, James Hamilton, and
Rob Allan consider another possible agent – global climate change. By
Introduction 7
examining the links between climate signals, environment, and livelihoods
in the long seventeenth century in India, this chapter assesses the claim
that the synchronicity of the many disorders of mid-seventeenth century
Eurasia was no accident but associated with climatic conditions between
1610 and the winter of 1708–09. These conditions, as the historian Geof-
frey Parker (2013) argued, led to natural forces combining in this period
to generate cooler temperatures and greater climatic variability, reduced
solar energy, increased volcanic activity, and a greater frequency of El
Niño. The El Niño southern oscillation also disrupted the Asian monsoons
and North American rainfall. The idea of a “global crisis” in the seven-
teenth century, as Damodaran and her colleagues affirm, is here to stay,
but their chapter queries whether climate change was the primary agent
of seventeenth-century demographic change, and makes the case for an
approach which would focus on regional and national differences and the
resilience of agricultural production in the face of population pressure,
exogenous shocks, and environmental change.
As Part I of the book sets up fundamental debates about historical inter-
pretations of food crises, their causes, and human responses, it also dis-
cusses particular instances of famine in early modern Britain and India
– such as the famines in Gujarat in the 1630s, in Bengal in the 1770s, in
England in the 1590s and early seventeenth century. The chapters that
follow revisit some of these examples in more detail, and explore ways of
combining or modifying the approaches critically examined in the first
Part. Part II on “Roads and rivers” pays close attention to regional con-
texts, taking up the intersecting issues of navigation, settlement, mobility,
and representation in the selected local environments, and considering
their impact on agriculture, food supply, and distribution. Chapter 4
attends to individual, local, and state-guided discourses of famine and
dearth in seventeenth-century India and Britain, which expressed con-
cerns about climate, place, and mobility. The chapter thus focuses on per-
ceptions of space and place as driving factors for British and Mughal
understandings of alternating dearth and plenty in India. East India
Company men, such as Peter Mundy, were constantly on the move,
whether by sea or on land, and their accounts of travel and economic crisis
in India, Ayesha Mukherjee argues, adapted the developing modes of rep-
resenting domestic mobility in Britain. Using Mundy’s text and narration
during the notorious Gujarat famine of 1630–32 as a case study, the
chapter shows how themes and principles in British domestic travel writing
familiar to Mundy were adapted by him to describe the topography,
climate, politics, local resilience, and travel experiences during the Gujarat
famine. This is compared with the politics of representing the famine in
Mughal official and courtly accounts. Mukherjee suggests that, in the
process of narrating subsistence crises, seventeenth-century English travel
journals and Mughal chronicles recorded the beginnings of a global dis-
course of food security, which must be recovered in its own terms.
8 Ayesha Mukherjee
In Chapter 5, Ujjayan Bhattacharya observes that rivers in the region of
Bengal, by the nature of their seasonal flooding, and volatile change in
their courses of flow, determined the scale of ecological impact on agrar-
ian society. Changes in the direction of river flow altered ecological zones,
creating new deltaic spaces for expansion of agriculture, rendering the
older zones moribund. He identifies that channels of the Damodar in
1770 and the Teesta and Karatoya in 1787–89 had gone through rapid
changes in character, causing significant ecological shifts in western and
north-eastern Bengal, and argues that long-term changes resulting from
the considerable impact of inundations and the system of watercourses
were crucial for food security and the evolution of new agrarian settle-
ments. Moving on from the well-known Bengal famine of 1770, Bhattach-
arya focuses on official records and government responses to the flood
and famine situations in 1787 and 1790s. Though we may argue the evid-
ence of climate change, on a global scale, still needs to be fully discovered
and collated, the case of Bengal in 1787–90 suggests that this process can
be aided by considering the micro-dynamics of responses to specific cli-
matic events, evidenced in holdings of local archives which allow us to
reconstruct famine conditions from below. Bhattacharya’s detailed recon-
struction demonstrates how changes in local climate and ecology, market
exchanges, and conflicted notions of moral economy (from the
Company’s perspective) worked in tandem to determine the precise shape
of a food crisis.
I hope that the working class movement will be able now to forget the
horrors of the past in the joy of realising that we are living in a country
that is going to produce for the benefit of the citizens as a whole.
(Ibid.: col. 1636)
One hopes there might have been some irony here, in this call to memory
to serve the latent desire of forgetting, at a moment when the horrors of
famine smarted afresh among citizens of a recently relinquished colonial
state.
Indeed, the famine in Bengal received strikingly scant attention in
Britain (though the Indian national press and its special correspondents
reported it vividly16) where focus had shifted to the “humanitarian crisis”
and acute food shortages in occupied Europe (Walker, 1941; Famine
Relief Committee, 1942, 1943). However, the Bengal famine became the
first site of nutritional experimentation with the notorious F-Treatment
(intravenous administering of protein hydrolysates) which, after its spec-
tacular failure in Bengal, was used again for emergency feeding during the
“Hunger Winter” (1944–45) in Holland, where it also failed (Drummond,
1946, 1948; van der Zee, 1982). In Belsen, the apparatus triggered
patients’ memories of the implements of torture, and apparently, the starv-
ing, in both contexts, wanted food and not “capsules”. This, too, was not a
straightforward matter because, as a Times of India special correspondent,
complaining of woefully inadequate medical treatment in relief camps,
reported on 23 November 1943, “Improved food supplies may for a time
wreak havoc because once a certain stage of emaciation has been reached
long treatment is essential before a person can assimilate solid food.” The
correspondent added that the majority of the starving reacted against
treatments as far as their strength permitted, tried to run away from the
hospitals, “and sell the very sheets that cover them for a meal of rice – a
meal which is likely to kill them” (4). In the same month, the Bengali
newspaper Jugāntar (“New Age”) published regular counts of sick and
dying destitutes in local hospitals, reports of parliamentary discussions,
and subversive cartoons (7: 47 (6 November 1943), 48 (7 November 1943),
49 (8 November 1943), 52 (11 November 1943), 75 (4 December 1943)).
The newspaper’s weekly comic strip called Śeẏāl Pand.it (“Learned Fox”)
produced a parody titled Cāñdāpusht.a! (“Plumped by Charity”) on 6
November 1943. The Learned Fox, a familiar figure of Bengali oral tales,
could be used in political parodies to satirise the “cunning” of colonial
rulers or of those who were seen to imbibe this through blind emulation.17
Introduction 15
Śeẏāl Pand.it appeared in this cartoon series as an ambivalent and clever
trickster. In the 6 November version, a pair of skeletal and scruffy-looking
stray cats, one with a harmonium strapped round his neck, appear below
Śeẏāl Pand.it’s window. They sing a song of complaint in rhyming verse:
they claim they can no longer bear the pangs of hunger (
[jat.harer jwālā sahenā ār]) and are prepared to sing in praise of
Śeẏāl for a good meal ( / [khābār
āge balore dādā/jai Śeẏāler jai]). At the top left corner of the frame, Śeẏāl ’s
snout is just visible as he peers out of the window and dumps a pile of left-
over fish bones into the bin below. The cats dive in and gorge themselves,
having eked out this charitable donation from the proverbial trickster
himself by means of their sycophantic singing. The final frame shows the
cats prostrated by the bin with bulging bellies; they sing out a warning,
that if they ask for such charity when they are hungry again (
; [khete paini bole cāñdā/cāile punarbār]), they will
be thrown out by the scruff of their necks, or simply beaten (
/ [galā dhākkā debe kimbā/sreph lāgābe mār]) (Jugantar,
7.47 (6 November 1943): 7).18 A week later, on 11 November, another car-
icature appeared, this time more visibly on centre front page, above a
report on the Commons debate on the famine.19 The cartoon, titled
“ [Famine in Parliament]”, showed an abandoned parlia-
ment session, with empty seats and a few scattered figures weeping help-
lessly into their handkerchiefs. Signs in the background say “Members:
600” and “Present: 35”. A placard lies flat on the table which reads
“ [Special Session for the Famine
in Bengal]” (Jugāntar, 7.52 (11 November 1943): 1). Such representations
do not simply suggest nationalist outrage and demand for welfare from a
colonial state that appeared brutally forgetful, but a concerted scrutiny
and interrogation of the paradoxes driving this famine, often with self-
directed irony.
Amidst the contesting perspectives of relief workers, doctors, nutrition
scientists, journalists, cartoonists, nationalists, and politicians, the expecta-
tion of a magic solution was sharply satirised in a sketch in the 7 Novem-
ber 1943 edition of The Hindustan Times. The illustration showed
half-naked skeletal figures of natives queuing before a rotund officer
(strangely reminiscent, despite his modern suit, of Oliver Twist’s Mr
Bumble), who, elevated upon a stool, holds a large bottle in one hand,
and with the other administers drops of the miraculous medicine straight
into open starving mouths, with a look of benevolent assuredness. At the
other end of this production line, the bodies of the starving emerge trans-
formed into a state of obesity. Behind the official, in a corner, a Chinese
man in traditional dress holds out his hand, with a speech bubble, “Spare
one for me, Brother”. The caption above the sketch mockingly reported
that “masses of walking skeletons” in Bengal would be turned into “living
masses of flesh” by means of “Vitamin ‘A’ pills … coming from London”.
16 Ayesha Mukherjee
Meanwhile, in Britain, the controversies of post-war food rationing and
austerity policy and practice were imminent (Zweiniger-Bargielowska,
2000), and old and familiar arguments about “cultures of dependency”,
“loss of self-reliance”, and “the value of work” were about to resurface in
ways that might be worthy of representation in the mode of Dickensian
macabre. Perhaps the value of our shared ghosts of famines past lies in
their capacity to recall lessons in food insecurity that are yet to be learnt,
and to suggest that “hunger’s demise” is not only a slow but an
uncertain end.
Notes
1 I use the term “self-fashioning” in Stephen Greenblatt’s sense of the “fashion-
ing of human identity as a manipulable, artful process” (1980: 2). While Green-
blatt and others have applied this to English and European contexts in
particular, it is also applicable (bearing in mind cultural specificities) to literary
contexts outside Europe.
2 As the Bengali journalist Tushar Kanti Ghosh observed while reporting on the
1943 Bengal famine, “A child here or there, dead or dying from starvation, has
been removed from the pavement. Had the child parents? … What hunger can
do to break the most sacred and loving ties well-fed people cannot imagine”
(1944: 35).
3 See Datta, Chapter 2 of this book, where he itemises degrees of shortage across
the eighteenth century, for Bengal; Bhattacharya, Chapter 5, identifies the
Company official’s call for state relief as the indicator marking the turning
point from acute dearth to a famine situation. On the issues that arise while
attempting distinctions, especially in the early modern world, where precise
data is hard to find, see Hoskins (1964); Walter and Schofield (1989).
4 In the early modern English context, for example, the history and literature of
famine and dearth was shaped by wider social issues, such as marriages, kinship
patterns, formal welfare provision through poor laws, informal structures of
charity, household management, and popular protest (Kussmaul, 1985: 1–30;
Wrigley and Schofield, 1981: 421–2; Wrightson, 1980: 176–91; Sharpe, 1998: 62;
Hindle, 2004: 21; 2008; Mukherjee, A., 2015).
5 The changing definitions of “food security” can be traced through the follow-
ing documents. It was defined in 1974 in the Universal Declaration on the Eradica-
tion of Hunger and Malnutrition at the first World Food Conference convened by
the UN. For further definitions that have evolved since, see World Food Summits
(FAO, 1996 and 2002), Declaration of the World Summit on Food Security (FAO,
2009), FAO et al., The State of Food Insecurity in the World (2012).
6 On European famines, there are recent, thought-provoking overviews by
Cormac Ó Gráda (2010, 2015), and Alfani and Ó Gráda (2017). On famines as
accelerators of disparity and the creation of the “Third World”, see David
Arnold (1988) and Mike Davis (2002).
7 A recent investigation of the documentation of famine and dearth in historical
and literary sources corroborates this striking correlation between India and
Britain across two and a half centuries: Famine and Dearth (2016).
8 On famine mortality and climate in India, post-1800, see especially the figures
in Davis (2002: 2, 247).
9 On the better-known nineteenth-century famines, see Davis, 2002; Arnold,
1988, 1993; Sharma, 2001; Mukherjee, U., 2013. The experience of food
Introduction 17
shortage, however, did not disappear from Britain, as demonstrated in studies
of the history of hunger (Newman, 1990, rev. 1995: 213–80; Schofield in
Rotberg and Rabb, 1985: 67–93; Scholl, 2016; Vernon, 2007).
10 Among many studies of this topic, see reflections in Driver (1993) and Englan-
der (2013).
11 The figure is similar to the estimated deaths in Gujarat in the early 1630s,
though considerably less than the estimated deaths of 10 million in Bengal
during the dearth and famine years of 1769–72.
12 See especially The Calcutta Gazette, Supplements, 1943: 13 (1 April), pp. 295–300,
14 (8 April), pp. 319–22, 15 (15 April), pp. 353–6, 16 (22 April), pp. 379–98; 17
(29 April), pp. 509–10, 27 (8 July), pp. 1333–6, 34 (26 August), pp. 1501–4, 36 (16
September), pp. 1529–34).
13 In the collection of essays, Hunger in History, Kates and Millman suggest a
“middle ground” approach which seeks “hunger’s demise”, while acknow-
ledging that “further progress will require fundamental change in structures,
institutions, and values” (1995: 406). The question is whether the fundamental
values that define progress itself need to change.
14 For other arguments on the emergence of hunger as a moral imperative, see
Laqueur, 1989; Haskell, 1992; Boltanski, 1999: 170–92; Edkins, 2000.
15 See useful discussion on humanitarian action and desire in Boltanski,
esp. 188–90.
16 The Statesman newspaper in Calcutta published some of the earliest photo-
graphs (22 August 1943), and some of the special correspondents’ narratives
were printed as books: Freda Bedi, Bengal Lamenting (1944); K. Santhanam, The
Cry of Distress (1944); Santosh Kumar Chaterjee, The Starving Millions (1944).
An account of the famine, The Bengal Tragedy, by the editor of Jugāntar and
Amrita Bazar Patrika, Tushar Kanti Ghosh, was also published in 1944. As Ghosh
complained, despite the rapidly increasing deaths, “not a mouse stirs in
London or Washington” (1944: 35).
17 See, for example, the well-known Bengali author Bankim Chandra Chattopad-
hyay’s dark parody of the creation of the modern Bengali intellectual (imbued,
by the “redbearded savant” Creator, with “slyness from the fox”, among other
qualities) in his essay Anukaran (“Imitation”, 1872), in Bankim Rachanavali, II:
198–207.
18 On ways in which “local town humour” drew upon a Bengali satirical literary
tradition of self-directed irony, see Kaviraj, 2000.
19 The Jugāntar report, titled “ :
[India Matters in the Commons Session: Questions to Mr Amery [Secretary of
State for India] regarding the famine]”, summarised the discussion in the House
of Commons on 11 November 1943 (see Hansard, Commons, 1943, vol. 393, cols.
1278–81, nos. 40–4).
Part I
Historical interpretations
1 Famine and food security in
early modern England
Popular agency and the politics
of dearth
John Walter
yet reason and civill policy might prevaile so much with us for our
selves and those which are deare unto us, that we should not stay so
long until our neighbours flames take holde of our owne houses, nor
try the extremities that hunger, and famine may work amongst us.
(Platt, 1596: A3v)
Conclusion
While weaknesses in local ecologies, vulnerable surpluses and poor and
unfavourable market integration explain the occurrence of famine, in the
longer run better market integration and improved agricultural yields,
when married with the controls on population growth to be found in Eng-
land’s “low-pressure” demographic regime, explain its disappearance. But
in the interim the failure of agricultural output to keep pace with renewed
population growth exacerbated problems of food security for the harvest-
sensitive land-poor and labour-dependant social groups, whose numbers
swelled in years of harvest failure. As a telling comparison with the causes
of the more deadly medieval English famines makes clear (Slavin, 2014;
Smith, 2015), it was the redistribution secured by a combination of the
access to food to be found within the social economy of dearth and
transfer payments under the poor law and the government’s dearth policy
that allowed England to escape crises of subsistence.
A recurring theme in the anthropology of famine is the resilience or
otherwise of social structures and community relationships under pressure
from harvest failure. In this respect it is worth emphasising that a
Famine in early modern England 35
c ombination of factors ensured that early modern English society survived
the strains that atomisation of households and fraying of inter-personal
and inter-household relationships that famine might elsewhere cause.
Neighbourliness and reciprocity remained important for all because of
England’s particular, nuclear familial structure which made the com-
munity, not kin the immediate resource for those below the elite. The
strategies discussed here were only able to work because harvest failure
produced not absolute scarcity, but social and spatial shortages. The exist-
ence of a surplus, albeit a diminished one, meant that access to food for
the harvest-sensitive might still be secured within the circuits of exchange
within the social economy. Despite undoubted pressures in years of harvest
failure, redistributive charity and other forms of informal relief never
faced the uncomfortable challenge that absolute scarcity might have
posed. At the same time, the organised transfer of reduced surpluses
under the poor law and the government’s dearth policy could take place
because the structures of provincial and local and communal government
were sufficiently developed and sturdy enough to withstand the disloca-
tions that damaged other governments’ attempts to manage famine. In
the absence of a professional bureaucracy, the English Crown had
developed an effective government down to the local level of the parish of
self-government at the king’s command by co-opting the support and
social capital of provincial and local elites. The harvest-sensitive in early
modern England survived dearth then by being able to marry together the
protection offered by formal relief, charity and the informal practices and
exchanges of the social economy which insulated many from the full
impact of harvest failure within what has been called “the makeshift
economy” by which the poor survived. Where these were challenged, then
popular agency had a role to play in defending a “moral economy”,
prompting elites and government to renew practices and policies, some-
thing made easier for them by the fact that harvest failure was always a
temporary crisis.
By the later seventeenth century, England had escaped famine. But
this was not the case for her immediate neighbours of Scotland and
Ireland, to whom it might be argued England successfully exported
famine as a result of the unfavourable specialisation its growth prompted
there (Crawford, 1989; Drake, 1968; Flinn, 1977). But this did not mean
an end to the food insecurities that dearth caused. The disappearance
of “crises of subsistence”, precisely defined as a demographic measure,
should not be allowed to obscure the fact that for many individuals the
recurrence of harvest failure meant that hunger remained a very real
threat. For England’s poor, the silent violence of hidden hunger per-
sisted. The fact that problems of food security continued to raise ques-
tions of political legitimacy made food a source of continuing contest
between government and people.
36 John Walter
Notes
1 Demographically, mortality crises are defined statistically as a sharp increase
above the underlying death rate. Wrigley and Schofield (1981) define mortality
crises as years with recorded deaths at least 10 per cent above a 25-year moving
average.
2 The impact on nuptiality and fertility, it should be noted, was however stronger.
3 On the application of the doctrine of judgements to dearth, see Walter and
Wrightson, 1976; and for an analysis of the rhetoric of famine sermons and their
blending of Biblical and practical exempla, see discussion of Lavater and Barlow,
1596, in Mukherjee, A., 2015: 21–30.
4 During the Madras Presidency famine of 1854, the Commission further reported
that “crowds of applicants [for famine employment and relief] flocked in from
the Nizam’s dominions” for nine months (Part 1: 11). Similarly, in 1868–69,
relief houses in British cantonments in Rajputana struggled to accommodate the
numbers of applicants “so great that it was found impossible to exercise proper
supervision” (Part 1: 14). Such anxieties about disorder led to the 1880s’
codifying of official approaches to addressing famine. Some of the complexities
of administering, in India, officially approved forms of relief, based on models
developed in early modern England and Victorian Britain, are discussed by
Sharma in Chapter 7 of this book.
5 Early modern popular theatre engaged directly with specific instances of
regional crowd action. See Fitter (2000) on Shakespeare’s Romeo and Juliet,
dearth and the London riots of the 1590s; and Hindle (2008) on Coriolanus and
the Midlands Rising of 1607.
2 Subsistence crises and economic
history
A study of eighteenth-century
Bengal
Rajat Datta
The context
Historically, famine and dearth were two distinct, though interrelated
crises of survival. Famine was typically a situation when a subsistence and
mortality crisis became combined in a critical conjuncture lasting for a
length of time, which stretched beyond the critical threshold of a food
Subsistence crises and economic history 39
shock. This reveals how famines exacted large death tolls, despite some-
times being regionally uneven in their spread; had weather as their proxi-
mate cause; and resulted in considerable loss of output, as reflected in
sharp increases in food prices (Ó Grada, 2005: 146). These variables influ-
enced the extent of both excessive starvation and excessive mortality in a
famine. Dearth, on the other hand, constituted a more continuous saga of
smaller scarcities. Although periods of dearth had lesser impact than
famines, they were nevertheless important since their periodicity created
major problems of subsistence among the harvest-sensitive strata (the arti-
sans, labourers and the town poor), women and children in the house-
hold, as well as among a section of the peasantry, especially those who
worked for wages or cultivated lands with inadequate resources (Datta,
1996). It has been suggested that although crises of subsistence have been
identified through the combination of high mortality at a time of high
prices, prices need not reflect availability if most of the population was not
dependent on the market for food, or if there was a decline in purchasing
power, or, more generally, exchange entitlement, in Sen’s terms (cf. Cotts
Watkins and Menken, 1985). This chapter suggests prices did reflect avail-
ability, and people starved, or died, because they couldn’t afford to buy
food at prevailing prices.
In other words, crises of subsistence, both dearth and famines, were
severe dislocations in the “normal” run of things. Social perceptions classi-
fied various food-crises according to their scale and magnitude. Paul Gree-
nough correctly states that there are cultural perceptions of prosperity,
and conversely of adversity. In traditional Bengali society, such percep-
tions depended on the nature of the current paddy harvest and the ways
in which different social groups were allowed access to it (Greenough,
1982: 42–52).2 Yet, as I have argued elsewhere, dearth and famines were
more than rude shocks to established cultural constructs of plenitude
(“society’s conception of the good life” (Greenough, 1982: 12)) and scar-
city. They caused severe economic dislocations. Production faltered, prices
soared and people died. Traditional means of support within the com-
munity no longer sufficed to maintain social bonds, or to alleviate the suf-
ferings of the famine stricken (Datta, 2000: ch. 3). Table 2.1 shows the
number of times the province was affected during the eighteenth century.
In order to contextualize the dynamics of subsistence and surplus con-
sumption in eighteenth-century Bengal, as well as the economic implica-
tions of subsistence crises, one has to keep two specific aspects in mind:
the first was its highly fluvial environment; the second, its great wet-rice
producing economy. In 1656, the French traveller Francois Bernier, while
describing the “beauty of Bengale”, remarked that:
One must however keep in mind that rivers changed courses, which could
sometimes lead to moribundity in one place and a renewed fluviality in
another (cf. Bhattacharya, Chapter 5 of this book). The Ganges shifted
often. Its older arms like the Bhairab dried out, but it grew newer limbs in
the form of Bhagirathi which was crucial in the ensuing prosperity of
central and western Bengal. The Brahmaputra shifted eastwards and
enabled the huge recharging of the Ganga-Padma estuary on which so
much of Bengal’s early modern maritime economy came to depend in the
eighteenth century (Mukherjee, 1938: 7–8).
Despite these uncertainties, other observers largely corroborated Bernier
and Rennell in underscoring the centrality of fluvial interconnections in
Bengal’s maritime vibrancy. In the entire belt stretching from Dhaka to
Hughli which was subject to “seasonal inundations”, the continuity of eco-
nomic life was maintained by a seamless transfer from land to boats during
the monsoon. For James Taylor, writing in 1840, the “abundance of the nec-
essaries of life” in eastern Bengal was significantly due to the ease with which
these could be transported to the markets on boats (294). In 1893, Thomas
Twining noted how the innumerable rivers and natural canals that inter-
sected the province “afforded a most extensive and convenient communica-
tion through the interior in every direction”. From the “Jamuna to the
Burrampooter” down to the Bay of Bengal, rivers comprised a grid by which
“the productions of Europe, of China, and of the numerous islands in the
Straits of Malacca” passed on to the “northern parts of Hindostan destined
for every part of the world” (469). Walter Hamilton estimated that Bengal’s
rivers employed more than 300,000 boatmen on a continuous basis, c.1828
(186). The numbers would be substantially higher if we factor in those rivers
which were only seasonally navigable.
Turning to the second aspect, the province’s wet-rice producing
economy,3 we see that under normal circumstances, Bengal produced
42 Rajat Datta
three rice harvests, aman, boro and aus. Aman was the winter harvest which
was universally sown in the Bengali month of Assar (June–July) and har-
vested in Agrahan (November–December). This harvest was generally con-
sidered of great market value “bearing a higher price and sought after by
all”. The other major crop was that of aus (spring), sown in Baisakh (April–
May) and reaped in Bhadro (August–September). Compared to the winter
crop, the spring harvest was intrinsically inferior, being consumed over-
whelmingly by the “lowest and poorest classes”. Boro rice was an inter-
mediate crop producing the coarsest quality rice, which was sown in
Chaitra (March–April) on extremely low lands4 and reaped in either Assar
(June–July) or Srawan (July–August). Therefore, unlike the two major
crops which required a gestation period of six months, the boro was a
quick-ripening crop, capable of providing a harvest in four months
(WBSA, BRP (G) 1: 17 October 1794).
In western Bengal, boro rice land was “the lowest admitting of cultiva-
tion”, which “requires no manure, produces a constant succession of rice
ad infinitum, without any discernible decrease of vegetative power, requir-
ing only [to be] annually sown with successive varieties of grain” (OIOC,
Ms. Eur. F. 95, f. 30; emphasis original). In the largely flat alluvial plains of
southern and south-eastern Bengal, the same land was used to procure
multiple crops of rice in succession. Thus, in Midnapur, jala land of the
“1st kind … produces two crops of rice at the same time, the first called
ause … and the other aumeen” (IOR, BRC, P/51/15, 28 January 1787). In
eastern Bengal:
Figures 2.1 and 2.2 show the trends in the prices of four agricultural prod-
ucts during the severe famine of 1769–70 and the near-famine situation
in 1788.
Figure 2.3 shows the movement of monthly prices of ordinary rice
between October 1769 and September 1770 in Midnapur, a district which
had been severely hit by the famine.
My final data sets are given in Table 2.3, which contains prices of
ordinary rice (in rupees per maund) of the winter harvest in four areas of
the province which had been severely hit by the floods and had, in the
aftermath, experienced a near-famine situation.
Though the degree of excess mortality in 1788 was much lower than the
famine of 1769–70, there were some reports of deaths caused by unavailability
of food from eastern Bengal, whereas western Bengal remained relatively
unaffected. Both Figure 2.2 and Table 2.3 show that despite the degree of
the scarcity-induced spike in prices being less in 1788 than in 1769, the
sharpness in the rise was nevertheless significant. For instance, compared
1200 300
Prices (mustard oil and clarified butter)
1000 250
Prices (rice and lentils)
800 200
600 150
400 100
200 50
0 0
1768 1769 1770 1771 1772
Year
Rice Lentils Mustard oil Clarified butter
3ULFHV PXVWDUGRLODQGFODULILHGEXWWHU
3ULFHV ULFHDQGOHQWLOV
<HDU
5LFH /HQWLOV 0XVWDUGRLO &ODULILHGEXWWHU
3.5
3
Rupees per maund
2.5
1.5
1
January
1770
February
March
April
May
June
July
August
October
1769
November
December
September
to 1787 the price of ordinary rice in Calcutta went up by nearly 179 per
cent in 1788, whereas in the three other districts, prices increased between
143 and 275 per cent. Though this was undoubtedly much lower than the
almost 900 per cent escalation in the price of common rice between 1769
and 1770, the increase was still enormous, and caused great distress. On
the other hand, the sheer abnormality of the price rise in 1770, and its
persistence for over six months, explains the corresponding enormity of
the deaths which were reported, particularly from western Bengal in that
one year (cf. Datta, 2000: chs. 5, 6).
One of the most harvest- and price-sensitive social groups in rural
Bengal was the textile producer. Famine and dearth impacted upon them
by hitting directly at their access to markets for their consumption require-
ments. The evidence from Malda and Purnea suggests that between half
and one-third of those who died in the famine were spinners and weavers.
The disruption caused by the drought to mulberry and cotton in 1769 and
1770 meant that those who reared silk-worms (chassars) and those who
grew cotton (kappas) in these places were immediately affected. The
cultivation of mulberry was an expensive enterprise: “under the most
favourable circumstance mulberry will cost the Husbandman five or six,
and often from ten to fifteen rupees per bigha”, whereas the cultivation
cost of rice was “not above one, two or at best three rupees a bigha”
(WBSA, CCRM, vol. 6, 19 November 1771). This meant that once peasants
entered this sector their survival depended on conducive precipitation
and favourable food prices.
The situation in 1769–70 was precisely the opposite on both counts,
and therefore proved disastrous for such producers. There was an “incred-
ible mortality” among the chassars of Rajshahi during the famine (ibid.:
vol. 6, 11 November 1771). This was for two reasons. First, the high costs
involved in the culture of silk-cocoons meant that the chassars had no
reserves to buy food at famine-point prices. Second, the chassars belonged
to “only two casts [sic] of the Gentoos [Hindus]” who followed this voca-
tion as a specialized occupation (ibid.). For these reasons, they were
perhaps the most harvest-sensitive of all the affected social strata and, not
having enough food reserves to fall back upon, they died in large
numbers. Significantly, there appears to have been some mortality among
Subsistence crises and economic history 49
the chassars even in Dhaka which was otherwise largely unaffected by the
severity of the famine (WBSA, CCC 1: 15 October 1771; OIOC, BRC,
P/49/52, from Richard Barwell to Council, 7 April 1775). Finally, there
were the weavers, and it was reported that they also died in “large
numbers” (Sinha, 1956: 1: 160–1), but these deaths were especially con-
centrated in areas like Purnea, Rajshahi, Malda and Murshidabad. The
reports of such deaths suggest a higher concentration of excess mortality
among the chassars followed by deaths among the “winders and weavers”
who “suffered in proportion” to the chassars but not to the same extent
(WBSA, CCC 1: 19 April 1771). This is corroborated by the following
account from the famine of 1769–70.
[It] appears most probable that the mortality was mostly among the
workmen, manufacturers, and people employed in the rivers, who were
without the same means of laying by stores of grain as the husbandmen,
so that the number of consumers who suffered by this calamity was
greater, in proportion, than that of the cultivators of grain.
(Geddes, 1874: 421)
Conclusion
The intention of this chapter was to show how subsistence crises reveal the
economic history of subsistence from the point of consumption. In other
words, its two central arguments, namely, the market-oriented structure of
consumption, and starvation-misery outcome of market forces, were tied
to the movement of agricultural prices, and their deleterious impact on
subsistence in an already shortage hit economy. I briefly return to these
formulations in this concluding section.
As mentioned earlier, there existed a non-agricultural (sair jiha’at) tax
collected by the state. My recent study of these sair taxes showed that the
demand for goods in Bengal’s countryside was of a differentiated nature.
Most villages imported food grains. These imports could be as high as 68
per cent of the value of local trade conducted in the districts. Sugar, salt
and tobacco constituted the other three main elements of primary con-
sumption, followed closely by the consumption of betelnut and leaf (Datta,
2014). Francis Buchanan’s survey of the district of Rangpur (c.1807) also
showed that, in an aggregated sense, rice, various sorts of pulses, mustard
oil, vegetables, chillies, spices, tobacco, molasses or sugar, salt, turmeric,
betel nut and betel leaf were common items of food for all ranks. Clarified
butter was usually an upper social rank indulgence, but since cows and
other cattle were also maintained by the other social groups, it can be
assumed that they had access to some milk products, though most of these
were for sale (Buchanan, “Ronggoppur”, OIOC, Ms. Eur. G.11). More
importantly, the price of goods in the market (nirkh bazar) determined
how much of what commodity a peasant household could consume
50 Rajat Datta
beyond the stocks of rice or paddy available in their personal storehouses
(golahs). The latter facility was not something which rural artisans pos-
sessed, which meant anything between a quarter and a half of the rural
population did not keep food reserves beyond their daily requirements
and were thus critically vulnerable to even the minutest dislocation in the
food market.
Buchanan’s survey of Rangpur also shows that per capita consumption
in rural society was fundamentally linked to incomes and resources, and
expenditures on food-related items varied inversely proportional to
incomes. In other words, the lower the rank in terms of household
income, the higher the subsistence costs. This was expected in a situation
where the annual income differential between the first and the seventh
ranks was an insurmountable 4070 rupees a year (Buchanan, “Ronggop-
pur”, vol. 1, book 2, OIOC, MS. Eur. D.74, f.24). It is inconceivable that
such disparities did not exist in other places, and this perhaps explains
why, in April 1770, “the ryots [cultivators] in many villages, for want of
rain” were “reduced to the necessity of selling their grain for seed and
their cattle and utensils in order to support themselves”; and, as Camp-
bell’s records further observed,
half of those who pay their revenues and cultivate the land will
undoubtedly perish with hunger, whilst those remaining will be obliged
to purchase their subsistence at least 500 percent dearer than usual [and]
will be drained of that little stock which is the only resource for future
revenue and cultivation.
(1868: 20 April 1770, p. 115)
Notes
1 In Amartya Sen’s view, entitlement signifies economic and legal rights: to food,
access to food, or exchange of endowments for food. These can be identifiably
economic (like money or property), socially sanctioned, or state-directed
Subsistence crises and economic history 51
interventions to ensure people’s access to food. In this perspective, the market
factor in subsistence crises may operate against certain groups by pulling away
food to service the subsistence demands of groups with greater endowment
powers: for instance, food being sucked out of the countryside to feed the towns
because of higher prices in these places. Mohiuddin Alamgir argues that a
famine is caused basically by a food availability decline, and is
a general state of prolonged food grain intake deficiency per capita giving
rise to a number of a company sub-states (symptoms) involving individuals
and the community that ultimately lead, directly or indirectly, to excess
deaths in the region or country as a whole.
2 Perhaps such constructs were not unique to traditional Bengali society alone.
Did traditional European societies differ substantially in their conceptions of
dearth and plenty? It would be difficult to argue that they did. Compare, for
instance, Hoskins, 1968; Meuvret, 1988; Walter and Schofield, 1989; Mukherjee,
A., 2015.
3 This section is based on Datta, 2000: ch. 1.
4 In the district of Rajshahi, it was cultivated “chiefly in beds of lakes and in the
nullahs (small water courses)” (WBSA, CCRM, vol. 5, 30 April 1771).
5 In 1788 there was a severe food shortage caused by floods in eastern Bengal, and
that perhaps explains the reduced imports of rice by the city.
6 It has also been suggested that in pre-industrial Europe, a seasonal price rise
faster than usual could cause desperation among consumers, causing a further
demand-induced pressure on the already rising prices (Ó Gráda, 2005: 162).
3 Climate signals, environment
and livelihoods in the long
seventeenth century in India
Vinita Damodaran, James Hamilton
and Rob Allan
10
9
8
7
El Niño count
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
1
2
La Niña count
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1990s
1520s
1530s
1540s
1550s
1560s
1570s
1580s
1590s
1600s
1610s
1620s
1630s
1640s
1650s
1660s
1670s
1680s
1690s
1700s
1710s
1720s
1730s
1740s
1750s
1760s
1770s
1780s
1790s
1800s
1810s
1820s
1830s
1840s
1850s
1860s
1870s
1880s
1890s
1900s
1910s
1920s
1930s
1940s
1950s
1960s
1970s
1980s
El Niño
1964–69 6 1791–94 4
1957–59 3 1782–84 3
1937–42 6 1768–71 4
1924–26 3 1746–48 3
1918–20 3 1718–24 7
1911–15 7 1659–61 3
1876–78 3 1650–52 3
1864–66 3 1618–21 4
1856–58 3 1607–09 3
1844–48 5 1585–83 3
1814–17 4 1525–27 3
La Niña
1988–90 3 1808–11 4
1984–86 3 1785–90 6
1970–75 6 1778–80 3
1955–60 6 1750–58 9
1921–23 3 1739–43 5
1916–18 3 1730–1733 4
1907–10 4 1637–39 3
1890–94 5 1622–32 11
1878–80 3 1600–05 6
1870–75 6 1576–81 6
1866–68 3 1571–73 3
1860–64 5 1540–42 3
1847–51 5 1531–33 3
Total 26
1560 1580 1600 1620 1640 1660 1680 1700 1720 1740 1760
War Disease
Socio-political upheaval ENSO event
Famine Hurricane/extreme wind or rain
Earthquake Flood
Volcano Drought
Figure 3.3 Plot for India for the period 1560–1760 which allows identification of
groupings and coincidences between various occurrences and events
born of both natural and human causes.
60 Vinita Damodaran et al.
conditions for the Indian population in the late 1650s and early 1660s;
however, one should note that famine reports are mainly anecdotal and
sometimes highly subjective: “people [are] dying daily … the living hardly
able to bury the dead” (in Parker, 2013).
The Mughal ruler Akbar’s reign was dominated by major famines in
Gujarat in 1556 and in 1595, lasting three years. Abul Fazl, the court
historian, describing the horrors of this famine, noted that the mortality
was great: “Man ate their own kin and the streets were blocked with
corpses” (in Agarwal, 1983: 24). ‘Abd al-Qādir Badā’ūnī, another con-
temporary historian, noted that the whole country was deserted and no
husbandmen remained to till the ground (ibid.: 23). In 1595, when
another famine caused by the failure of rains affected northern India,
especially Kashmir and Lahore, Jesuit missionaries reported that the
streets of Lahore were blocked with human corpses (Agarwal, 2006: 30).
In 1618–19 there was famine in the Deccan and on the Coromandal coast
(ibid.: 31). The traveller Methwold, who left the East coast in 1622, wrote
of the ravages of the famine in Vijaynagara (1926: xiii). In the reign of
Shah Jahan, during the protracted La Niña episode in 1630–31, a severe
famine occurred which affected Golconda, Ahmednagar and parts of
Malwa. In these years no rain fell in the Mughal territories of the Deccan
or Gujarat and the drought was followed by severe floods (Lāhawrī, I,
1867: 362; Ray and Kuzhippalli Skaria, 2002: 132). The middle of the
seventeenth century, as noted, had seen the weakest period of monsoons
on record and the rains failed in 1646 and 1647. Heavy mortality was
reported from Pulicat and Madras and it was recorded that half the people
in the area of Nagapatnam were dead and the stench of the dead and
dying bodies was terrifying (Foster, 1906: xxvii). The first year of
Aurangzeb’s reign was likewise marked by intense famine causing unspeak-
able suffering in Northern and Central India. Colonel Tod noted: “There
was no longer distinction of caste, Sudra and Brahmin were indistinguish-
able. Men ate men” (in Agarwal, 2006: 36), cities were depopulated, and
Bihar experienced severe famine in 1671 which encouraged the slave
trade. In 1687 there was another severe famine in Golconda. The month
of June 1687 saw floods and the city of Hyderabad was depopulated,
houses, rivers and plains filled with corpses. In 1704–07 another great
famine hit the Deccan but proved less severe (Agarwal, 2006: 36).
On the face of it, then, Parker’s emphasis of climatic drivers in this
period of Mughal history appears justified by contemporary descriptions.
However, it should be pointed out that the usefulness of such descriptions,
without supporting statistical or demographic data or at least estimates of
numbers of people affected is questionable. Furthermore, the reliability
of, in particular European descriptions, has been strongly questioned by
work on the development of tropes in famine reporting of the period
(Agarwal, 1983: 21–78). Lack of comparative and contextual data on
monsoon failure also leaves Parker’s argument somewhat open to criticism
Climate signals, environment, livelihoods 61
– details of how common these were, their geographic extent, how long
they lasted, what traditional coping mechanisms existed, what social and
administrative contingencies were in place, are needed in order to form
any accurate idea of the meaning and significance of monsoon failure in
general, and of specific droughts for Indian society. Parker’s claim of
“exceptional violence” in the seventeenth century as a whole sits in some
contrast to the historiography. For example, John F. Richards, Irfan
Habib, and others, have described the seventeenth century as a period of
relative calm and stability. That Parker can point to near continuous
warfare is not in itself proof of exceptionalism in a rapidly expanding and
militaristic early modern empire, which, throughout its existence, failed to
define solid boundaries and was always involved either in expansion or
suppression of rebellion somewhere in its vast territory (Edwards and
Garrett, 1974; Gommans, 2002; Balabanlilar, 2012).
John F. Richards saw no evidence of a seventeenth-century crisis in
India, identifying, instead, continuity and prosperity which endured well
into the following century when the region experienced a distinct and
unrelated eighteenth-century crisis as Mughal emperors lost power to local
lords and, later, the EIC. Richards’ conclusions are not very different from
those reached some 30 years earlier by the distinguished economic
historian of early modern India, Irfan Habib, in his work The Agrarian
System of Mughal India. For Habib, it was the strength of the Mughal
Empire as an administrative unit which was its most remarkable feature;
the revolt of 1580 and the Rajput revolt a century later being practically
the only points at which the elite or the theocracy made any play of con-
testing the power of the semi-divine monarch. Moreover, Habib holds –
contrary to Parker – that in the light of the refusal of contesting parties to
ever discuss or consider partition, the wars of succession beginning in
1628, 1658 and 1707, should be viewed not as moments of weakness or
near collapse, but as markers of the remarkable durability and cohesion of
the empire (Habib, 1963).
According to Habib, Mughal military supremacy afforded security and
stability – albeit accompanied by violent suppression and coercion of the
masses of peasants and workers – and the extreme, if impermanent, power
afforded to the emperor via the Jagirdari system of delegated revenue col-
lection. This system rendered the Mansabdars “completely dependent on
the will of the Emperor” (317), and allowed for the collection of taxes
which reduced the populace to bare subsistence, producing enormous
and highly concentrated wealth for a small elite (320). The system was,
however, fundamentally flawed. Multiple layers of delegation in tax collec-
tion, the regular relocation of regional administrators, and a lack of
central control over these zamindārs, who were seen as the primary threat
to order in the empire, left the system open to exploitation whereby the
masses suffered enormously at the expense of the various layers of the elite
(320–2). In time, some local lords – particularly in Hindustan – began to
62 Vinita Damodaran et al.
rebel against centralised power, refusing to pass on revenue. Poor and sub-
jugated elements were drawn to rebellious regions by more tolerable and
equitable conditions, and thus the power of rebellious elements grew
(366). By the mid–late seventeenth century the Jat, and later the Maratha,
revolts had become a significant threat to imperial order – they would
eventually be its undoing (346) – yet these were slowly developing and
evolving states of confrontation, which spread gradually, slowly eroding
centralised power, rather than a well-defined crisis prompting its collapse
(346–99).
For David Clingingsmith and Jeffery Williamson (2008), it was again the
eighteenth century which witnessed the most significant upheavals in
India’s economic and political structure. Herein, it was seen that the
turmoil accompanying the dissolution of the Mughal Empire, into a con-
stellation of smaller states and their forced regrouping under the EIC,
frustrated commerce and industry, leading to economic decline. Even
here, however, the notion of crisis, and even of economic decline itself,
remains controversial and is far from settled as an historic fact. Work by
Chris Bayly (1993), Muzaffar Alam (1998) and Peter Marshall (1982) lays
emphasis on continuity rather than disruption, with Mughal administra-
tive units seen to remain largely intact, pre-existing growth trajectories are
maintained (Clingingsmith and Williamson, 2008: 211), and the only
major change is in the amount of money passed on by local powers to
central Mughal administration. It was, furthermore, in the latter part of
this era – the years 1700 to 1760 – that India peaked as a manufacturing
centre (ibid.: 223).
In light of the apparent historiographical consensus that the seven-
teenth century was a time of relative calm in the Mughal Empire and that
major upheaval did not occur until the early–mid-eighteenth century,
Parker’s attempt to extend the crisis into the subcontinent are considered,
at present, somewhat tenuous and, at the very least, in need of a more
solid evidential basis. Parker’s arguments in the case of India appear to be
open to exactly the same criticisms as those levelled at the arguments of
Hobsbawm, Trevor-Roper, and others beyond the 1960s: that levels
of upheaval were simply not that exceptional and continuity in systems of
power was more marked than transformation. What makes these weather
anomalies different from those a century earlier or a century later? Parker
asserts that “the seventeenth century experienced extremes of weather
seldom witnessed before … and never so far since” (2013: 112). In his ana-
lysis the LIA is decisive, intervening in historical processes, influencing the
outcome of battles and destroying empires. The claim requires com-
parative and quantitative evidence and more detailed work on documen-
tary and paleo sources. Furthermore, in terms of climate, it is important to
note that impacts are always asymmetric; simplistic notions such as weak or
strong monsoons or intense ENSO episodes take no account of the possib-
ilities of variation in mode of expression and centres of action of these
Climate signals, environment, livelihoods 63
climate events. A more useful approach, then, is one that focuses on
regional and national differences and the resilience of agricultural pro-
duction in the face of population pressure, exogenous shocks and environ-
mental change. Famine causation is complex and links between drought
and famine in the early modern period need to be reassessed. There is a
clear incentive to develop a database that will help improve famine,
climate, disease, wage and price series for South Asia and the Indian
Ocean world for 1500–1900, which are currently woefully inadequate.
the oppressions of India … under the rapine and cruelties of the ser-
vants of the company have now reached England and there is a
clamour here … to such monopolies were imputed the late famine in
Bengal and the loss of 3 million inhabitants.
(Walpole, I, 1910: 72; cf. Damodaran, 2007: 149; 2015)
famines in India have arisen from several different causes … the most
general cause has been the failure of rains. Distress has also, however,
been caused by hostile invasions; by swarms of rats or locusts [or ants
in the case of the 1790–91 famine in Kach], by storms and floods; and
not infrequently by the immigration of starving people from distant
distressed parts, into districts otherwise well provided with food sup-
plies; and excessive exports of grain into famine stricken districts, or
by combination of two or more of the above named circumstances.
(Danvers, 1877: 1)
I had made and noted down many observations on its uses, when in
large practice in the General Hospital at Madras in 1776, 77 and 78,
but lost them, with all my other papers, by the storm and inundation
at and near Coringa in May 1787.
(1832: 34)
The Madras typhoon of May 1787 was one of a series of very severe
storms which occurred that year in Bengal. Reports of floods from the
General Letter from India of 15 December 1787, describe a “violent inunda-
tion” of which the author states that
He continued:
The collector of Chittagong reported that “the deluge of rain which has
recently fallen in these parts exceeds, I am given to understand, the
memory of the oldest inhabitants” (ibid.: 147–53). Campbell’s collection
shows how very severe weather difficulties – again and again made worse
by repeated storms, and very likely combined with administrative determi-
nation to continue tax collection to the greatest possible extent – left great
want and dislocation amongst the poor. The collector of Nuddea wrote in
September 1787 that:
The rivers which run through this district have risen to so alarming a
height that I should consider myself deficient in my duty did I omit to
communicate the intelligence to you; the Jellingy in particular, which
68 Vinita Damodaran et al.
passes by this place has swelled to such a degree that there are few
parts where its banks are not overflowed on both sides and to judge
from my own observation and the opinion of people here, it must be
at least two feet higher than it was in the rains of 1785, and then it was
higher than the oldest inhabitants had ever remembered it.
(Campbell, 1868: 175–7)
Notes
1 See Le Roy Ladurie, 1971; Atwell, 2001. A window into recent developments in
Chinese climate history is Marks, 1998; see also Zhang and Lin, 1992, which
includes abundant historical information.
2 The seventeenth-century crisis was perhaps also linked to strong El Niños that
produced withering droughts and famines in much of south and south-east
Asia in 1614–16, 1623–24, 1629–32, 1660–62 and 1685–88. The last was one of
the most pronounced El Niños in recorded history. See also Grove, 2002.
3 Cited by Rob Allan of the MET office, Hadley Centre, who worked jointly with the
authors of the paper on a McGill University, Montreal, funded project on the
seventeenth-century crisis. See also his initiative, International Atmospheric
Circulation Reconstructions over the Earth (ACRE) Initiative (www.met-acre.org).
4 Climatological Database for the World’s Oceans (CLIWOC) 1750–1850 (http://
webs.ucm.es/info/cliwoc/intro.htm). A European Union-funded project which
ran from 2001to 2003. See also www.weatherdetective.net.au/about.
5 This climate data is provided by Rob Allan. Some of the EIC sources he con-
sulted include: Edward Terry (Chaplain to Sir Thomas Roe), A Relation of Sir
Thomas Roe’s voyage into the East Indies (1665); Foster Rhea Dulles, Eastward Ho!
The First English Adventurers to the Orient. Richard Chancellor – Anthony Jenkinson
– James Lancaster – William Adams – Sir Thomas Roe, etc. [With Plates, Including
Portraits.] (London: John Lane, 1931); Thomas Roe, Sir Thomas Roe’s Journal of
His Voyage to the East Indies and Observations There During His Residence at the
Mogul’s Court as Embassador from King James the First of England (1732).
6 For a version of Figure 3.1 in colour, see Damodaran, Allan, and Hamilton (2015),
unpublished paper, Food Security and the Environment in India and Britain
Workshop (http://foodsecurity.exeter.ac.uk/wp-content/uploads/2015/09/
17th-century.pdf).
70 Vinita Damodaran et al.
7 See figure 3 in Shi et al. (2014), where the grey periods indicate the 26 famine
events identified in India over the past millennium (www.nature.com/articles/
srep06739).
8 See figure 3 in Neukom et al. (2014), “Extreme periods” (www.nature.com/
articles/nclimate2174).
9 See figure 4 in Buckley et al. (2014) www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/
pii/S0277379114001462?via%3Dihub.
10 The 1630s Gujarat famine is discussed by Mukherjee in Chapter 4 of this book.
11 In Chapter 5, Bhattacharya reconstructs in detail the effect of the 1788 disasters
on local ecologies and economies.
Part II
Roads and rivers
4 Famine chorography
Peter Mundy and the Gujarat
famine, 1630–32
Ayesha Mukherjee
Famine chorography
While EIC factors like Mundy encountered pressures of defining place
from both the available English political model and from political and
administrative structures of the Mughal empire, they were also aware of
fundamental challenges to traditional, seemingly stable, conceptions
of place. In both contexts, vagrancy and/or migration for subsistence or
improvement, the operations of markets and trades, and travel within and
beyond national boundaries created “abstract spaces” of “networks”,
shaped by processes of mobility and exchange (Lefèbvre, 1991: 2). Mughal
transformations of spaces and Taylor’s local travels are illustrations of
these processes and challenges, which took specific forms in India and
Britain, but were comparable and potentially interactive, especially when
we consider their effect on verbal and visual demonstration of space in
contexts of famine and dearth. In a text like Mundy’s Travels, this repres-
entation itself occurred in a state of mobility – he wrote journal notes and
made sketches of scenes on the move (Bodleian Library, MS. Rawlinson
A315). As a result, the text was informed by direct, immediate, fluctuating
experiences of dearth and plenty, later revised and organised. This led to
the construction of a “famine chorography”: a dynamic kind of spatial
representation categorising places as a locus of plenty or want, and appear-
ing as a mode in genres of writing that depicted mobility – a journal,
journey poem, or vagrancy literature. Places of fluctuating plenty or want
were identified along or near routes with an established political or eco-
nomic significance, pre-defined by traditional, national, or imperial con-
ceptions of space, which the famine chorography of literature representing
mobility from below might question or challenge.
I use the term “chorography” in the Renaissance sense of written
description of regions, often combined with visual elements, including
maps, and considered distinct from chronicle history in its prioritising of
place above time (Schwyzer, 2009; McRae, 2009, 2015; Klein, 2001).
Mundy’s description of travel through famine-affected areas contained ele-
ments common to British domestic travel writing, which utilised and modi-
fied chorographic traditions. In seventeenth-century Britain, as McRae
notes, the empirical exercise of gathering data for the benefit of gentle-
men and the commonwealth was applied in domestic travel, which was a
cheap alternative or supplement to foreign tours, making England an
Famine chorography 79
equal object of scientific enquiry (2009: 7–18). Spatial knowledge acquired
through travel became a means of manipulating space. Consequently,
domestic travel writing used the mode of cornucopoeia, a figure of plenty,
applying it to natural resources, information, and objects of curiosity.
Travel allowed access to abundant findings, turning the itinerary form into
a crucial tool – specifics of date, place, coordinates, geographical features
needed codified presentation (McRae, 2009: especially 67–90). Categoris-
ing places as pleasant/unpleasant, I suggest, became part of the itinerary:
the distinction was often determined by economic factors, like poverty and
poor sanitation described by the eighteenth-century traveller Celia Fiennes
(1682–1712; Fiennes, 1984), or concerns with local hazards, hospitality,
and commerce in the poetry of Richard Corbett (1582–1635), Richard
James (1592–1638), or John Taylor (1580–1654). While Corbett, uncom-
fortable with the propensity of alehouses and inns to contest the status
quo of every fish and human being knowing their place, complained that
ostlers could rise to be innkeepers, tapsters could bully priests into paying
higher prices for bread and beer (1807: 161–84); in James’ journey poem,
an old fisherman offered more subtle criticism of travelling “gentlemen”
whose mobility, a product of affordable leisure, contrasted radically with
the localised labour of communities which ensured food availability.
James’ fisherman thus itemised his labour which rationed time: “making,
mending nett,/Preparing hooks and baits, wherewith to gett/Cod,
whiting, place…. Where with to feede ye markett and our selvs” ( James,
1845: ll. 126–36).
The issues Taylor raised were closer to the circumstances of Peter
Mundy’s travels in India. Locating labour in the persona of a penniless
pilgrim, Taylor focussed on finding food and categorising places as repre-
sentative of want or plenty as he “travailed on foot” from London to Edin-
burgh, reversing his Water Poet’s norm (“My legs I made my oars, and
rowed by land”) and encountering “strange (yet English) fashions” (1618:
1). In the itinerary mode, he ticked off provisions and practical hazards:
hunger, disease, and their remedies. He filled his “knapsack, (to pay hun-
ger’s fees)” with “good bacon, biscuit, neat’s-tongue, cheese/With roses,
barberries, of each conserves,/And mithridate, that vigorous health pre-
serves” (2), making a conscious choice, as his title page claimed, to under-
take this journey “not carrying any Money to or fro, neither Begging,
Borrowing, or Asking Meate, drinke or Lodging”. He conducted a
regional survey of the survival of hospitality in an economic context that
had placed under strain values of stewardship and communality. The pen-
niless “pilgrim” survived on the hospitality of ale houses, and the lack
thereof was, as Taylor called it, “drought” (6). In a comic, inverted famine
chorography, the drought was allied to parts of the route. Alternating,
unpredictable dearth and plenty not only defined spaces and places but
propelled Taylor’s narrative forward. Intermittently, the landscape yielded
free food for the penniless pilgrim and his starving horse:
80 Ayesha Mukherjee
My nag made shift to mump green pulse and peas.
Thus we our hungry stomachs did supply,
And drank the water of a brook hard by.
(6)
[sāl-i guz– ashtah dar mah.āl-i Bālāghāt khos.us.an nawāh.i-i Daulatābād bārān
nabārideh bud]
This year, although rain was less in the surrounding region, in Gujrat
and Daccan, it did not rain at all and the inhabitants of that place
were under great distress due to paucity of edibles and dearth of
nourishment.
(Ibid.)
[wa az qazz..ayāi āsmāni ke darin sāl ruy dād imsāk-i- bārān, waqu’e qah.t. wa
ghala dar kull-i vilāyat-i Deccan wa mulk-i khāndis wa Gujrāt ast. Sāl-i pish
dar aks–ar-i mahāl-i bālāyi khus.us. nawāh.i-i Daulatābād imsāk-i bārān shud
ammā darin sāl ām gardeedah bah.addi raseed ke pirān-i kohan sāl muddat-
ul‘umr mis–l-i ān nadeedah wa nashuneedah and]
And among the misfortunes brought about by the destiny that year
[1631] was scarcity of rain and occurrence of famine and drought in
the entire region of Daccan, Khandesh, and Gujrat. In the previous
year, too, there was scarcity of rain, particularly in the vicinity of
Daulatabad, but this year, it was more common, and reached the
extent that has never been witnessed and heard of earlier by the elders
in all their lives.
(Qazwīnī, British Library, MS. Add. 20734: ff. 218r–219v)
No trace of population was left in this region which was known for its
habitation. After this great calamity, which will later be cited as the
ultimate example and will be noted as legendary, all accounts of
previous epidemics and famines of the past which have been narrated
with wonder, shall become insignificant.
(Lāhawrī, I: 363)
Figure 4.1 Peter Mundy’s route from Surat to Agra 1630–31, showing his categoris-
ing of places on a scale of plenty to famine.
Source: the colour map, which designates plenty in green and famine in red, may be found
on the Famine and Dearth project web database: http://famineanddearth.exeter.ac.uk/
index.html.
Famine chorography 85
activity. This centre, as we have seen, shifted frequently, and famines
allowed the opportunity to demonstrate more starkly to his subjects that
the emperor was the only true source of sustenance. Highlighting the
spatial organisation of charity was therefore a concerted strategy in the
official chronicle’s account of famine. The Pādshāh nāmas made the point
that networks of charity beyond the imperial seat in Burhanpur were also
within Shahjahan’s control. Lāhawrī claimed that Rs 50,000 were distrib-
uted to relieve the poor in Ahmedabad; while tax remission amounting to
70 lakhs of rupees (apparently, one-eleventh of the whole revenue) was
offered in other regions. Lāhawrī commented, if this was the extent of
remissions from the imperial exchequer, one could accordingly imagine
how great the reductions made by noblemen holding jāgirs and mansabs
may have been. The emperor gauged, in other words, the extent and
severity of famine-related suffering and determined the extent and nature
of official support across the realm. The chronicle’s narration of local spe-
cificities in this regard was more nebulous.
Mundy’s itinerary shows how English travellers and traders negotiated
this environment, conflicted with ecological, socio-economic, and political
disparities and anxieties. The itinerary format in British domestic travel
writing emphasised that the nation depended on the circulation of people,
commodities, and information across local communities, not just within
communities bound by designated spatial limits of a piece of land.
Mundy’s journal constructed his itinerary acutely aware of the dynamics of
local mobility in his new setting.12
He started from Surat on 11 November 1630 and his narrative, filled
with local topographical detail, merged the journal form with a famine
chorography different from the imperial Pādshāh nāmas. His landscape
description suggested a practiced sensitivity to local engagement with
shortage, complicated the contrast between the fertile Malwa region and
deprived localities below the Narbada river, and identified tensions
between localities. There was a concentration of food supplies in Viara,
“fortefied with a good Castle and accommodated with a very prettie pond
or Talao stored with fish and fowle”, and market towns such as Chopda,
Navi, and Bahadurpur (Mundy, 1907–36, II.40; f. 32r–v). Between Viara
and Chopda, Mundy itemised places badly affected by famine. Just 14
miles from Viara was a poor town, “halfe burnt upp and almost voyd of
Inhabitants, the most part fledd, the rest dead, lyeing in the Streets and
on the Tombes” (II.40–1; f. 32v). In Daita, people sold their children
(II.42; f. 32v). Mundy’s party had difficulty pitching their tent at Nandur-
bar because the town was congested with dead bodies. They bought food
at “unreasonable rates”, and were overwhelmed by the smell “from a great
pitt, wherein were throwne 30 or 40 persons, men, woemen, and children,
old and young confusedly tumbled in together without order or Cover-
inge” and the sight of “poore people scrapeinge on the dunghills for food
… in the very excrements of beasts belonging to Travellers, for graine that
86 Ayesha Mukherjee
perchaunce might come undigested from them”. People looked like
“anatomies, with life, but scarce strength enough to remove themselves
from under mens feet” (II.43–4; f. 33r–v). For Mundy, the dead and starv-
ing constituted part of the landscape from Surat onwards, lying along
highways and near towns, piled outside city gates where bodies were
dragged and left. His analogies and images highlighted the way control
over the landscape was frustrated by famine which challenged the fixity of
quantification and the regulation of boundaries demarcating spaces such
as markets, towns, cities, estates, roads, rivers. The land was intractable and
rhetorically marked out as an inversion of any constructed “Jahān-āra”.
The rhetoric itself demands attention, because when describing
unpleasant places, moral or aesthetic disgust was complicated by empathy
in Mundy’s language. His perception was shaped by the communal con-
ditions of travel. His kāfila (caravan) had started at Surat with 150 people,
15 carts and some camels. Joined daily by people escaping famine, it con-
sisted, by Nimgul, of 1800 people, 300 carts, and cattle (II.45; ff. 34v–35r).
The flow of people – the rhythm of movement is vital to Mundy’s repres-
entation of landscape – progressed towards Burhanpur, the prosperous
city centred on Shahjahan’s castle and estate. If Burhanpur was an ima-
gined locus of plenty, the market towns leading to it brought into view
palpable contradictions between the “plentifull Bazaar” and starved bodies
in streets, obstructing trade and travel. Burhanpur was a site of imported
and tentative plenty:
The Bazare … which joins to the Castle is very faire and spacious, and
now, by reason of the Kinges being here, plentifully stored with all
provisions, beinge supplied with all things from all parts, farr and
neere, which otherwise, it may bee believed, would feele the same
Calamitie with her Neighbour Townes, for theire is litle or nothinge
growes neere it for many miles.
(II.50–1; f. 35r–v)
Mundy’s narrative of his journey through the fertile Malwa region was
countervailed by the practice of looking back at this politics of dearth.
Despite green fields, villages stored with grain, and plentiful rivers, the
sinister flow of this plenty towards Burhanpur army camps haunted
Mundy’s description throughout. Just as Hugh Platt’s or John Taylor’s
local engagement with communities coping with contradictions of dearth
and travail allowed them to query famine remedies and definitions of
place imposed from above, Mundy’s chorography questioned royal estate-
centred discourses which, as noted earlier, described charity flowing from
this centre, reinforcing the emperor’s benevolence, divinely constituted
political authority, and control over the environment, land, and resources.
Mundy felt removed from the resources consumed by imperial land-
marks he ambiguously admired and undermined. His own perspective
Famine chorography 87
was the diffused migratory one of travellers and tradesmen, local and
foreign. He camped with the local trader Mirza, learning from his
resourcefulness and the local knowledge of banjāras, local carriers or
drovers, whose trade served and depended on mobility (Habib, 1999:
69–70, 1990: 371–99; cf. Kothiyal, 2016). Mundy’s famine chorography
was thus informed by the mixing en route of racial and social groups
with different agendas, making cooperative and competitive demands
on resources, a characteristic ambivalence in chorographic works in his
own national context. Mundy thus saw kāfilas as practical demonstrations
of local cooperation: the mixing of people, lengthening of the caravan,
and shaping of mutual dependence, as the kāfila wended its way through
the land, demonstrated to him survival strategies and knowledge of land
organised from below. Like Taylor, he located positive industry in travel
itself. More than a train of carts, the kāfila was a temporary mobile
household travelling across, and coping daily with, the shortage-driven
landscape, exchanging information about the availability of resources
with seasoned local traders for whom mobility was also an endemic con-
dition. In Mughal Sarai, Mundy’s kāfila met a group of banjāras carrying
provisions:
They are sometimes hired by Merchants, but most commonly they are
the Merchants themselves, buyinge of graine where it is Cheape to be
had, and carryinge it to places where it is dearer, and from thence
again relade themselves with anythinge that will yield benefitt in other
places as Salt, Sugar, Butter, etts.
(Ibid.)
In other words, Mundy was aware that their trade was flexibly governed by
changing local space and demand, instead of being attached to static tra-
ditions of production and exchange. The banjāras’ position may have
seemed closer to EIC factors like Mundy, who served and depended on
the Company’s centrally authorised operations but, at the same time, had
to rely on mobility to meet their trading needs.
Notes
1 On the “seventeenth-century crisis” and global climatic events in the longue
durée, see especially Parker (2013), Grove (2002), Grove and Chappell (2000).
A critical examination of these ideas, with further evidence, is undertaken by
Damodaran, Allan, and Hamilton in Chapter 3 of this book.
2 Later figures like Edward Barlow, analysed by Fumerton in her account of
“unsettled subjectivities”, were drawing on decades of seafaring experience,
traditions of mobility, and identity formation in travel accounts.
3 There are differently nuanced arguments about this: Westerfield (1915, 1968)
for types of petty traders; McKendrick et al. (1982: 86–8) on the development
of a consumer society; Spufford (1984: 5–20) on the increasing circulation of
consumer goods; McRae from the viewpoint of domestic travel (2009: 102).
Woodbridge (2004: 151) argues pedlars were suppressed because they
Famine chorography 93
threatened commercial interests of (traditional) fairs, weekly markets, guilds,
and pawn shops.
4 Qazāq/qazāqliq had a specific usage in post-Mongol central Eurasia where it
described a state of political vagabondage (Lee, 2015: 23–5; Dale, 2004: 98–9;
Subtelny, 2007: 29). Fatrat had the more focused meaning of an interregnum,
highlighting the anxiety of being in a state of eternally seeking political
stability.
5 Daughter of Mirza Abu Said, great-grandson of Timur and Babur’s paternal
grandfather.
6 The idea that wit proceeds from want was a common motif in 1590s literature
of dearth (e.g. Weever, 1599: I.21, II.4).
7 On the decline of the Cornish pilchard trade which probably led Mundy to
seek employment with the EIC, see Carew (1602: 52–3); Pritchard (2011).
8 Accounts of the famine in Gujarat and the Deccan in the 1630s are found in
the following sources, from which the details here have been drawn: Qazwīnī,
MS. Add. 20734: 218r–219v, Or. 173: 220v–221r; Khān, Or. 174: 29r–32r, Or.
1671: 17r–18v; Lāhawrī, I: 362–3; Foster, 1630–33: 73, 134–96, 203–68; 1634–36:
40; Mundy, 1907–36, II: 38–70, 276; Van Twist, 1937: 63–77. For a wider chron-
ology of Mughal Indian famines, see Habib, 1999: 112–22.
9 Reported by the Portuguese Viceroy at Goa in 1631 (Foster, 1630–33: xxi).
Lāhawrī reported that Gujarat suffered most (I: 363).
10 Translations from Persian by Azarmi Dukht Safavi (with my occasional amend-
ments); transcription and transliteration by Md. Ehteshamuddin, in Famine and
Dearth, http://famineanddearth.exeter.ac.uk/index.html.
11 Sadiq Khan, however, reported excessive rain spoiling crops in 1630, drought
in 1631, and attack on crops by mice and locusts in 1632 (OIOC, Or. 174:
29r–32r, Or. 1671: 17r–18v). Habib, 1999 (115, n. 19) suggests this reflects the
different ways the famine was experienced in different regions – thus Khan is
possibly focussing here on the Deccan experience where excessive rain was the
initial cause.
12 Textual references to Temple and Anstey edition (1914, 1936) and Bod.,
Rawlinson MS. A315.
5 Rivers, inundations, and grain
scarcity in early colonial Bengal
Ujjayan Bhattacharya
River water movements and price inflation closely resemble each other in
their impacts on the agricultural economy. A moderate inflation is argu-
ably beneficial to the economy just as a continuous and moderate flow of
water enhances productive possibilities. But immoderate increase in prices
have a corrosive effect on the economy, just as excessive flow of water
wreaks destruction and havoc on the crops. Such similarities in the nature
of the two phenomena prompt us to investigate further how rivers and
inundation might directly affect prices and the economy in times of dearth
and famine. Floods, droughts, or other physical disruptions of normal life
bring about price rise in the core regions affected by such events, and
have a ripple effect on wider regions. This can produce famine-like situ-
ations, if not an actual famine. In 1787 and 1788, many districts of Bengal
experienced excessive, repeated, and violent flow of water on the crops,
caused, as Damodaran, Hamilton, and Allan demonstrated, by a series of
severe storms. This immediately increased the price of grain in the market.
Flood waters, by reducing the scope of producing food for the future, con-
tinued to impact on the price rise till 1790, when restrictions on the move-
ment of food were removed. While it has been claimed that inundations
are generally beneficial for an agricultural economy, excessive and destruc-
tive water currents reduce the scope of producing food and preserving
food-stock, and lead to economic degeneration. This chapter shifts our
focus to take a closer look at the socio-economic impact of exogenous cli-
matic shocks, such as that delivered by the Madras Typhoon of 1787. The
periodicity of rains and frequency of inundation were responsible for high
prices in core affected regions as much as human manipulations of food-
stock, and prices were liable to be affected even in the region beyond the
core. In this context, one should distinguish between annual inundations
that are the regular and characteristic (“normal”) feature of floods in
deltaic Bengal, and the exceptional flooding that had severe destructive
effects on food production. I aim to show, through this detailed case study
of the effects of a specific disaster, how severe climatic events could disrupt
local ecologies and affect the micropolitics of exchange and relief in local
economies. The high price of grain, total destruction of habitations, and
Rivers, inundations, and grain scarcity 95
change in the courses of rivers, severally or singularly, could change the
nature of local economies and thus have long-term effect on a region.
Such eventualities could be accompanied by famine and depopulation.
David Clingingsmith and Jeffrey Williamson have shown that India
experienced a historically low rate of drought during the period
1650–1735. Till 1640, the average rate of drought was one drought every
three years. The rate fell precipitously to the average of one drought every
six years after 1650, and remained at that level till 1725. It then fell to an
even lower level, i.e. one drought every ten years from 1735 to 1775, when
it rose again (Clingingsmith and Williamson, 2005). However, nine
instances of drought between 1767 and 1793 have been recorded by Rajat
Datta. Barring the drought of 1769–70, which caused a great famine in
many districts of Bengal, the other droughts of high intensity, causing
“famine panic” and “public scarcity” occurred in 1779 and 1783 (Datta,
2000: 243). Floods, during the eighteenth century, in the absence of pre-
vention measures, did cause heavy destruction and had the potential to
cause famine. They could be the cause behind scarcity, dearth, and near-
famine whenever river inundation was accompanied by excessive rainfall
(ten instances between 1737 and 1787) (ibid.: 240, 243). The only major
exception perhaps was the drought of 1769–70 in Bengal, when the misery
was caused, as Damodaran argues, primarily by unprecedented level of
revenue collection (Damodaran, 2007).
Prolonged effects
In 1787, the possibility of famine was increased by repeated inundations
and climatic distresses. Hopes of revival were raised by moderation of
weather at certain intervals, but extreme forms of climatic disturbances
leading to inundations brought about further misery for the cultivators. In
July 1787, it was reported from Sylhet that by “the great fall of rain …
since the month of March last” all the “low parganas [sub-districts] were
entirely overflown, the inhabitants driven from their houses and obliged
to take shelter on boats” and the greatest part of the cattle drowned. The
villages had lost not only the rising crops (that is boro) but also the seed
“which is the greater loss”. The price of rice was greatly enhanced as a
result of “many Gholas [grain stores] having been swept away” (BRP (M)
20: 31 July 1787, from Sylhet). The damage was sought to be salvaged by
cultivating in higher lands which had not experienced inundation till
then. But “the circumstance instead of being an alleviation has proved the
source of greater misfortunes”, said the reports. During “the interval of
98 Ujjayan Bhattacharya
fair weather which never exceeded a week many more were induced to
attempt to sow their lands”. Some of the ryots did so three times and
“instead of reaping the fruits thereof have had the misfortune to find that
they have not only lost their rising crops but also the seed which is greater
loss” (ibid.). Zamindars were called to raise another crop but their hopes
“vanished” – the Collector reported – as “after three repeated attempts
the crops have been drowned by succeeding inundation and the season is
gone” (BRP (M) 25: 21 September 1787, from Sylhet).
As a consequence, the ryots did not have resources to engage for the
next year’s revenues. At Dinajpur, in the early stages of the floods, “the
rubby [i.e. rabi, winter-sown] crop was entirely destroyed” and the ryots
refused to come to any settlement unless heavy remissions were granted or
the demand for revenue was altogether postponed and “thrown upon the
kurieff [kharif] and assasheen [ashwin, autumn] crops” (BRP (M) 24, 7 Sep-
tember 1787, from Dinajpur). Soon after this communication, the inunda-
tion was reported as calamitous, “water having risen at different periods
and the crop transplanted in the interval when the water apparently was
subsiding”. Due to the subsequent sudden rise of the river waters, crops
“decayed in the ground”. The local officials apprehended that the effect
on the kharif harvest would be ruinous, and particularly “upon the damage
done to the Ruby crop”, as the zamindars depended on it. The loss of
cattle was another result of prolonged and repeated flooding. This not
only prevented the possibility of cultivation but also did “materially retard
the bringing to the market the crop which may be reaped, as without
cattle the grain cannot be cleaned” (ibid; BRP (M) 21: 31 July 1787, from
Dinajpur). Thus, the initial vulnerability caused by the extended rains was
evident when the rabi crop was destroyed and the ryots could not engage
for the new year’s revenue in May and June with the zamindars or the gov-
ernment’s collectors. This was further aggravated by the continuing rain
and river flooding till the month of August. On the instruction of the
Board of Revenue to report on the effects of inundation and state of
floods in eighteen parganas, on 14 August 1787, the Collector reported
that the parganas where the ryots were in economic distress were laid waste
by rain and river water, and the principal casualty were the rabi crops
which had been sown in October of the previous year. These crops con-
sisted of the boro rice and spring crops consisting of peas, pulses, oilseeds,
and miscellaneous greens (Hunter, 1869: xii).3
Detailed reflection on the nature of calamity caused by rains and river
water suggests that, apart from the long drawn-out impact on the food pro-
ducing fields, which broke the cycle or the rhythm of agricultural economy,
it was the violence of river waters breaching through the mountainous passes
and falling on the plains which had caused enormous destruction to the
process of cultivation. At Mymensingh, the zamindars and ryots had signed
the revenue settlements “in the month of Jeet [Jyesth; May–June]” hoping
that they would be able to pay the rents regularly. Unfortunately, from the
Rivers, inundations, and grain scarcity 99
beginning of Assar (June–July) the waters rose to an extraordinary height
and destroyed all possibility of undertaking cultivation. The rains continued
for fifteen days at a stretch, and the floods drowned lands in eight parganas
causing scarcity of food and bringing agriculture to a halt (“Petition of the
Zemindars of the parganas Sreesory, Surriel, Jamshy and Lutluffpore to
Mymensingh”, BRP (M) 20: 31 July 1787).
Geographical impact
The floods and extreme weather conditions affected the grain prices
within a wider ambit, including places beyond the inundated regions.
Except in Chittagong, in the month of October, 1787, every district
recorded lesser availability of rice in the rice harvesting months of 1787,
compared to 1786. Table 5.1 shows the variation in grain prices between
October 1786 and December 1787 in six districts of Bengal.
Rice prices in December 1787 at Dinajpur, a district within the core
region affected by floods, were better than at Rangpur, the adjacent dis-
trict most affected by the floods. At Rangpur, the prices were 18 seer/rupee
in the countryside, and 23–5 seer/rupee in Rangpur town.
Transportation through the flooded rivers could not have been easy,
but there is no evidence to suggest this was hindered by the floods to cause
scarcity in different districts of Bengal. Yet, scarcity in the core famine
region had a cascading effect, as authorities laid embargo on the exporta-
tion of grain through river channels and prevented the transfer of grain
Table 5.1 Comparative prices of paddy and four sorts of rice in six districts of
Bengal in 1786 and 1787
Wheat Wheat Boot Buree Cally Boot doll Moog Musoory Motor
1st sort 2nd sort moog doll doll doll
from one region to another. In fact, evidence suggests there was not much
grain to be transferred, as what was in store, from the previous harvests,
was held back to provide relief. Thus, floods and the consequent scarcity
in northern Bengal affected grain trade all over the country, and the zone
of scarcity was extended to central and eastern Bengal, thereby giving the
impression of near-famine in the wider province of Bengal. The floods in
eastern Bengal were no less grim, and the possibility of depending on
their own supplies was as remote as in the northern districts (“A trans-
lation of the Arzee of Seid Aly Cawn enclosed in the letter from His High-
ness the Nawab Mobarick ud Dowlah to Mr. Pott Collector Government
Customs at Murshidabad”, BRP (M) 21: 31 July 1787; and, 31 July 1787,
from Chittagong reporting about Comilla; BRP (M) 25: 28 September
1787, from Rangpur). While Rangpur, and the adjoining district Dinajpur,
were epicentres of famine conditions, regions beyond it like Murshidabad,
Dhaka, and Rajshahi were also affected. The Murshidabad district, an agri-
cultural region feeding its own people, was also a major grain trading
centre of eighteenth-century Bengal, where grain merchants resided. The
district was linked to the grain-producing areas of northern and eastern
Bengal through water channels, and was dependent on those regions for
supply. It was apprehended that there would be a grain scarcity in Mur-
shidabad because the price of rice was raised considerably and the grain
merchants “continue daily increasing it” (BRP (M) 21: 31 July 1787, and
“enclosures from the Collector of Government Customs at Moorsheda-
bad”). This happened in consequence of information received of grain
scarcity “in the districts of Rungpore, Dinagepore, Dacca and Rajeshahy”.
The authorities feared that the “dreadful consequences” of a real scarcity
caused due to natural factors would be increased if the grain merchants of
Murshidabad, by trick and artifice, exported grain out of Murshidabad to
more profitable destinations like Calcutta. The collector thus proposed an
embargo out of Murshidabad (BRP (M) 21: 31 July 1787; “Private letter
from Mr. McDowal of Rungpore to Mr. Pott Collector Government
Rivers, inundations, and grain scarcity 101
Customs at Moorshedbad”, 6 July 1787; BRP (M) 26: 12 October 1787,
from Collector Govt. Customs).
The grain merchants in turn told the authorities that “from a great
length of time” they had constantly purchased at “Dubba in the district of
Rungpore, grain and other articles of merchandise” which was “kept in
store there”. In the rainy season, according to their annual custom, they
brought grain and foods to Murshidabad. This year, the collector of that
district prevented them from transporting the grain and told them to sell
it at Rangpur instead of Murshidabad (“Translation of a petition from the
11 dealers in grain to the Collector Government Customs at
Moorshedabad”, BRP (M) 21: 31 July 1787). The collector reported that
the people of Rangpur had been “threatened with a famine” and it was
necessary to lay an embargo on rice exportation out of the district. The
merchants were asked to send stored grain to Rangpur and sell it at one
maund per rupee, which they refused. At Dhaka, a situation similar to
Murshidabad prevailed. Consignments of grain were expected from
Bhagalpur, Rangpur, and Dinajpur, and the grain dealers were asked to
receive those at river junctions like Sooty and Jellingy. Because of the lack
of availability, grain became exceedingly dear in Dhaka and its neighbour-
hoods, and it was not possible to supply grain to areas of insufficiency,
which was a customary practice in times of dearth (“A translation of the
Arzee of Seid Aly Cawn”, BRP (M) 21: 31 July 1787).
The famine
By September 1787, there was widespread scarcity of grain and famine pre-
vailed all over the inundation affected areas. Even if there was hope that
some amount of crop could be grown “when the violence of weather”
abated, it was frustrated by an acute scarcity of cattle and fodder. On 13
September 1787, the first piece of local level information received sug-
gested that Rangpur was visited by a full blown famine (BRP 25 (M): 28
September 1787, from Collector of Rangpur, dated 13 September 1787).
The Collector of Rangpur not only reported a scarcity but also wrote to his
superiors that people were in need of relief or state charity, and could not
live without it. This was the point at which scarcity turned into famine, for
administrative purposes (Hunter, 1869: 7). The Collector could not
provide relief locally, and requested the assistance of the government for
provision of food. He reported that grain was selling for 23–5 seers per
rupee at Rangpur, and 18 seer per rupee in the countryside.4 In the early
stages of the scarcity, the Collector was hopeful that those “unhappy crea-
tures who by repeated inundations have been expelled from their places
of abode have resorted to this station and they have been relieved from all
the miseries of Famine, to which they otherwise have fallen a certain sacri-
fice”. But soon after, the numbers of these hapless people increased so
much that within a few days
102 Ujjayan Bhattacharya
3–4000 of them assembled at this place and they still continue to flock
from all quarters many of them not having tasted food for eight or ten
days, and dying in the streets before the necessary relief can be afforded.
there is scarce a village but has suffered some loss either in cattle or
desertion of the riots who have retired to the hills for safety; the few
surviving cattle are subsisted by the roots of grass drawn up by
bamboos; nothing but ocular demonstration can form an idea of the
unhappy state.
The human cost was now beyond description, it seems. The Collector,
however, assured that he would continue to provide relief, but did not
request assistance from the central authority (BRP (M) 25: 21 September
1787, from Sylhet).
Government response
The effect of the floods of 1787 on government decisions was visible not so
much in the effort to organize distribution of food, which was severely in
want even many months after the beginning of inundations, but rather in
Rivers, inundations, and grain scarcity 103
seeking to redeem a situation in which normal revenue collection was not
possible. Remissions were demanded and allowed, but in many instances the
revenue collectors were impeded, if not completely obstructed, by the phys-
ical dislocation of normal life in villages (BRP (M) 24: 7 September 1787,
from Dinajpur). Possibly due to the fear of food riots taking place in the
countryside, the officers asked for sepoys from Calcutta (BRP (M) 21: 31 July
1787, from Dinajpur). In the threshold years of the permanent settlement,
government revenue policies were premised on “uniform rate of taxation”
and “obtaining accurate knowledge” before an assessment could be made.
Faced with a terrible crisis as that of 1787–88, when a deduction amounting
to two-thirds of the estimated assessment was demanded by the zamindars,
the knee-jerk reaction of the central government was to declare the lands
khas [fallow], or bringing the lands under direct government supervision by
appointing sezawals [government officers] and suspending the authority of
the zamindars (Orders from BR to Rungpore, communicated to Governor-
General in Council, BRP 24: 11 September 1787; Governor-General in
Council’s instructions to Board of Revenue on Rungpore and Purneah, BRP
(M) 25: 25 September 1787). In the absence of accurate knowledge,
perhaps, the government felt obliged “to suspend the demands for the rents
where Inundation renders it necessary” (BRP (M) 26: 2 October 1787, from
Governor-General in Council to BR); but this always carried the proviso that
the “indulgence” was not to be abused by the zamindars and other categories
of revenue payers.
There was hardly any system of providing relief to the displaced popula-
tion. As Hunter noted about eighty years later, people knew that the Decem-
ber rice harvest (aman) was the great crop of the year, but few adequately
appreciated the impossibility of making up for its loss by the produce of the
preceding September harvest (aus), or of the green crops (rabi) in the fol-
lowing spring, or by the early rice crop (Hunter, 1869: 1). Thus, in a situ-
ation, as in 1787–88, when both aus and aman had been destroyed, the
stored grains of previous year had been inundated, and the seeds for next
year’s boro crop had been destroyed, the matter was even graver. The famine-
point, defined by Hunter as the point at which government relief operations
became necessary, was reached in 1787 when the Rangpur Collector
appealed for state charity. However, given the distance and isolation of the
north and east Bengal districts, it was not possible to arrange relief from Cal-
cutta, the central administrative location. Reliance had to be placed on the
availability of food in neighbouring areas which were not affected by floods,
and the ability of the Collector to co-ordinate (BRP (M) 25: 28 September
1787, from BR to Governor-General in Council).
Food markets
The food, particularly grain, crisis, occasioned by the floods of 1787, had
serious impact on the markets in 1788. Throughout that year, the grain
crisis continued unabated, and even in December 1788, the government
considered it unadvisable to lift the embargo due to uncertainties about
what could be “produced for export” after procuring for internal con-
sumption. In January, the price of grain had “risen to a scandalous
degree” in Murshidabad. The machinations of the grain merchants led to
exorbitant prices, complicating already straitened circumstances caused by
flooding. Rice was selling at a high price of 23 or 24 seers to a Sicca Rupee
(BRP (M) 30.2: 18–29 January 1788). The Collector of Customs reported
that suspension of duty on grain trade “has only been an additional profit
to the merchants, and no relief as was intended to the poor”. The Board
of Revenue, the coordinating agency, in advising the government on strat-
egies to be adopted on the apprehension of a scarcity before the “crops of
the next season” may be expected to ripen, said, “there exists at this
106 Ujjayan Bhattacharya
moment a scarcity of grain in most of the interior districts of Bengal, par-
ticularly in those that have suffered most from the inundation and storm”.
They feared this scarcity would probably increase
as the great crop of the current year is now in the market without
having removed the evil, and as the first crop of the ensuing season
being the smallest of the two will not be in the market before August.
(BRP (M) 30.2: Cons. 25 January 1788, from BR to
Governor-General in Council)
Table 5.3 Bazar prices of grain for three years in the markets of Calcutta
Wheat 23 5 32 13 34 9
Table Patna Rice 17 9 20 14 21 10
Table Country Rice 25 13 30 – 27 10
Middling 30 8 35 – 30 9
Coarse 33 13 40 – 34 9
Chatta Balam 36 12 41 – 36 8
Donny Balam 41 14 50 – 45 2
Chatta Lottee 47 4 55 6 48 –
Donny Lottee 52 12 60 6 52 13
Piarry 37 10 50 – 43 2
Moongy 31 10 39 8 36 –
Buddy 15!s baty – 18 baty – 7 baty –
Calley Gram 30 – 37 – 37 4
Boot Gram 23 10 39 2 44 –
We never saw or heard of such constant and severe rains and storms as
we have had since the beginning of assar, this greatly hurt the country –
the passes Rogonundun and Noorah Mountains breaking at the same
time rushed with such velocity as to overflow the banks of Burrumpoter,
Kaird, Burack etc. rivers and made an inundation into these Mehauls at
once in such a manner as to carry away whole villages.
(Representation of the zamindar of Jamshy and Lutluffpore,
BRP (M) 21: 31 July 1788)
Notes
1 Reports from Sylhet (July 1787) indicated that Azmerygunj and many golas were
swept away. Reports from Tipperah (July 1787) noted that at Sujahgunje, the
market with all its produce was carried away; while Jerwargunje in Comilla could
not be reached. In Mymensingh (July 1787), there was a representation from
the zamindar of Sussong pargana, stating that water rushed with violence to
“sweep down whole villages and carry away inhabitants, cattle, grain”.
2 Measures of weight used were: 1 maund (md) = 40 seer (sr); 1 sr = 16 chhatak
(cht). In metric measures, 1 md = 37.32 kg; 1 sr = 0.93 kg; 1 cht = 58 g.
Rivers, inundations, and grain scarcity 109
3 The spring crop of Bengal, or rabi crop, would also have included the boro seed
sown in October and reaped in March.
4 According to calculations by W. W. Hunter in 1866, the famine warning price
was 2 rupees, 10 anas per maund. The prices in 1787 at Rangpur were very close.
See Hunter, 1869: 9.
5 As Rennell explained, in his Memoir of a Map of Hindoostan or the Mogul Empire
(1793: 270):
The rice I speak of is of a particular kind; for the growth of its stalk keeps
pace with the increase of the flood at ordinary times, but is destroyed by too
sudden a rise of the water. The harvest is often reaped in boats. There is
also a kind of grass which overtops the flood in the fame manner, and at a
small distance has the appearance of a field of the richest verdure.
Part III
Politics of climate
and relief
6 Chaotic interruptions in
the economy
Droughts, hurricanes and
monsoons in Harriet Martineau’s
Illustrations of Political Economy
Lesa Scholl
However, as much as Martineau professes this line, and as much as she was
both celebrated and vilified as a proponent of political economy,1 her
counter-narratives of climatic extremes exacerbating hunger and despera-
tion overturn classical economic theory. In The Physiology of Common Life
(1859), George Henry Lewes would go on to describe hunger as “the very
fire of life, underlying all impulses to labour, and moving man to noble
activities by its imperious demands…. But when its progress is unchecked,
it becomes a devouring flame, destroying all that is noble in man” (1–2).
This observation, almost three decades after Martineau’s series, resonates
with Malthus’s depiction of the French Revolution “which, like a blazing
comet, seems destined either to inspire with fresh life and vigour, or to
scorch up and destroy the sinking inhabitants of the earth”, and
humanity’s “perpetual oscillation between happiness and misery, and after
every effort remain still at an immeasurable distance from the wished-for
goal” (1836: 1). In both Lewes and Malthus hunger is seasonal, but it is
still perpetual: the people are always hungry. Hunger is the catalyst for
momentum, with physical hunger feeding the social hunger for inequal-
ities and injustices to be addressed. What Martineau’s tales reveal, though,
is the chaotic nature of such hungers in dialogue with each other at
moments of environmental crisis. As she works to show what economic
theory would look like in practice, the characters who espouse political
economy’s ideals become increasingly problematic, marginalised and
116 Lesa Scholl
silenced in the face of environmental disasters that have an immediate
and sudden impact on the local economy.
While people have enough, they have little impetus for change; but
when one is hungry, there arises an acute awareness of lack, and a desire
to be satisfied. Historically, uprisings and revolutions can almost always
be tied to seasons of dearth and starvation, and a recognition that some
people are affected more than others by the lack. This visceral response
is exacerbated when supply is suddenly taken away through environ-
mental interventions. At the same time, though, extreme longstanding
hunger can lead to debilitating hopelessness; and it is in this kind of
state of inaction that climatic events necessarily move people to act. I
will examine three of Martineau’s tales in which extreme weather func-
tions to compel communities to react against economic strictures. Sowers
Not Reapers (2004, first published 1833) opens with an alienated local
community succumbing to drought during England’s 1830 Swing Riots.2
French Wines and Politics (1833b), set in France during the 1788 lead-up
to the French Revolution, is haunted by the hurricane that devastated
crops and caused the famous price rises in bread in October of that
year, which were considered instrumental in the immediate inspiration
of the revolution.3 Martineau, while commenting on France, also
emphasises Britain’s economic investment in the French Revolution,
refusing to allow her British readership to distance themselves from the
unrest. The third tale, Cinnamon and Pearls (1833a), is set in Ceylon
under the regime of the East India Company; and alongside the implica-
tions of imperialism and colonisation on the lives of the Cingalese, the
figure of the monsoon season operates to destabilise the economic and
cultural expectations of the community. Problems of scarcity and starva-
tion are exacerbated in each of these texts, while access to particular
foods – as well as food in general – becomes crucial to characters’ per-
ception of their social and political agency. The weather events operate
both literally to disrupt economic supply – crops are destroyed in each
of the tales – but they are also metaphorical representations of the
hunger of the people, and catalytically work to overturn political econo-
my’s myths of stability and order. The political merges with the environ-
mental, creating a dialogue akin to that between physical and social
hunger.
Others were also abroad, with the view of relieving their hardships
instead of seeking to avenge them. The dwellers on high grounds were
so far worse off than the inhabitants of the valleys, that they could not
quench their thirst, and lost in sleep their weariness and their appre-
hensions of hunger.
(2004: 297)
118 Lesa Scholl
The tale centres on the misfortunes of the Kay family, with Mrs Kay, who is
present in the opening scene, ironically succumbing to alcoholism. The
devastation of drought is intensified by Mrs Kay’s memories of abundance,
which she reminisces over with her sister-in-law, Mary, as they trespass on
the property of Mr Warden, the miller, in order to smuggle water from his
spring: “When I used to have my fill of meat every day, I little thought that
the bread I ate with it would grow scarce among us” (299). In this time of
extended drought, lines of criminality, like property borders, are broken
down in the community. Yet rather than condemning the women for tres-
passing and theft, Mr Warden sympathises with the women’s plight; after
all, whereas they look for water, he looks for wind to power his mill.
Neither they nor he have the ability to control the elements in order to
produce what they need. The sympathetic response in this community is
what prevents its ultimate devastation.
The tragedy of Mrs Kay’s situation is exacerbated by her alcoholism. It is
telling that while there is no water to drink, let alone to replenish the fields,
there is access to relatively cheap alcohol. Mrs Kay confesses to her husband
that she drinks to dull the pain of hunger, but her addiction overtakes her:
even when food is offered, when times seem to be improving, she is unable
to eat. She succumbs to her addiction in the end; and her hopeless ennui
reflects the desolation of unquenchable thirst. After her husband and family
have helped her to stop drinking alcohol, and she is “taking nothing stronger
than tea” (361), it remains that food is still in poor supply: “poppies coming
up instead of wheat, and stones strewed where lambs should have been
browsing” (370). In her last cold moments, Mrs Skipper, the baker, who was
sitting with her, recounts that Mrs Kay “kept stretching [her hand] out as if
she thought to reach something; and I supposed she was thirsty” (377), yet
this action is an impulse of her habit of drinking alcohol. Although Mary
pleads with her, “it was hunger that did all that! Don’t dwell upon that!”
(377), Mrs Kay cannot forgive herself, and dies, in a fading manner, voicing
her self-recriminations. The drought of Sowers Not Reapers portrays the most
lethargic, hopeless state of society along the lines of Lewes’s view of thirst.
Mrs Kay gives up hope, much in the same way as the men who raid towns in
the depth of night, causing devastating criminal damage. The loss of com-
munity boundaries in this way – the inability or refusal to respect the prop-
erty or boundaries of others in a seemingly unhuman quest for destruction
(or self-destruction in Mrs Kay’s case) – is evidence of having lost hope of
ever being able to regain an investment in the land and community.
Mrs Kay’s destruction is an individual, human representation of the
effects of natural crop failure on the community. Nature is more central
to the community’s concerns than political interference or selfish neglect
because it is more immediately present; yet the event of food destruction,
which was prevalent throughout the Swing Riots, provides evidence of
their social hunger and desperation. Martineau describes this response in
terms of economic panic:
Chaotic interruptions in the economy 119
There had been enormous importations of corn during the winter, –
importations which in the end proved as ruinous to the corn-dealer as
the farmer at home. The bargain with the foreign corn-growers having
been made in a panic was agreed upon at a panic price. The foreign-
ers had naturally laid heavy duties on corn, both because it was known
how much the English wanted food, and because what they bought
was not a surplus regularly grown for sale, but a part of the stock of
the countries they bought of. In the midst of a panic, and in entire
uncertainty how long the ports might be open, the corn importers
could not possibly calculate how much would be wanted, any more
than the people ascertain how much was brought in.
(357)
This account reveals the way in which political economy’s obsession with sta-
tistics and mathematical formulae falls down in the face of human, affective
response to scarcity. All figures are operating on panic rather than ration-
ality because numbers cannot be known. Economic politics clearly comes
into play on an international scale, with foreign traders not invested in the
plight of the starving British; rather they see an opportunity to take
advantage of the situation, perhaps justifying their actions to themselves on
a moral economic level through the fact that they are reselling what they
have themselves imported. However, as seen in French Wines and Politics, this
kind of exchange invariably leads to the prosperity of the seller, for whom
maintaining the profit margin is the most essential aspect, and for that
margin to diminish would be considered an irrecoverable loss.
It is the only way to keep what we have left…. There is no use, but
much peril, in complaint. Redress there is none; and ill-will towards
the lord’s pleasure is resented more deeply and lastingly than injury to
his property.
(Martineau 1833b: 9)
Antoine’s slippage into the term for the English aristocracy – “lord”
instead of “marquis” – linguistically ties the two businessmen together,
alongside their business transactions. Antoine’s passive acceptance,
though, also suggests that he will be able to recoup his costs in a way that
characters who do not at this stage have a voice would not be able to;
Antoine, like his brother Charles the winemaker, has enough wealth to
endure the marquis’ destructive pleasure.
In contrast to Antoine’s acceptance, however, the devastating hurricane
of the next day gives voice to the broader community. It rouses within the
people the resilience and outcry necessary for revolutionary determina-
tion. The preternatural noise of the hurricane becomes inseparable from
the hungry uprising of the people, operating as a deliberate motif of the
volatile, self-destructive power of hunger, and as a persistent response of
the natural world to the trauma of the nation. The storm returns through-
out the narrative, sometimes as thunder, sometimes as rain, to undergird
the violence of political unrest with the violence of the natural world. The
climactic scenes at the Bastille, and then with the guillotine, take place in
the rain, blood mixing with water; while the eye of the storm creates a
pregnant, ominous moment in the text, with the king fortressed in the
Tuileries, and soldiers and revolutionaries outside huddled around fires.
Yet, as much as Martineau uses the hurricane as a metaphor and a dra-
matic literary device, it is crucial to her economic illustration that this
hurricane was a real, historical event that caused material damage to the
land and produce:
The corn-fields were one vast morass. The almond groves were level with
the ground; and of the chestnut woods nothing remained but an assem-
blage of bare poles. The more exposed vineyards were so many quag-
mires, and many dwellings were mere heaps of ruins. All who witnessed
were horror-struck at the conviction of general, immediate, pressing
want; and the more thoughtful glanced forwards in idea to the number
of seasons that must pass away before all this damage could be repaired.
(1833b: 12–13)
Indeed, the devastation caused by this hurricane has been closely linked
to the French Revolution. Historian George Rudé notes its effects on
bread prices, which was particularly dire given that bread made up approx-
imately 50 per cent of the French diet:
It is important, then, that Martineau does not focus only on the immediate
destruction of food by nature, but also on the irrational food destruction
by angry crowds, and the long-lasting effects of both on the economy: she
is able to emphasise the economic inequalities that contribute to social
unrest. Unlike the political economists that Malthus references, through
literary representation Martineau is able to explore the causal complexi-
ties of economic instability and political unrest; and in doing so, she chal-
lenges political economy’s narrative of barely fazed progress in light of
environmental disaster.
Although Martineau’s tales were understood to be promoting political
economy, it is evident that only a few characters in each tale can afford to
122 Lesa Scholl
hold to its tenets. Her own claim of the complexity of her presentation can
be inferred from her response to her readers in her Autobiography: “but it
certainly seems to me that this course of imputation originated some obscure
dread of me and my works among timid and superficial readers” (Martineau
2007: 169). In French Wines, Antoine’s brother, Charles, espouses the ideals
of rational political economy; yet on closer observance he is shown to be able
to hold to this philosophy because, first, he comes from a position of luxury
and, second, he himself profits economically by the hurricane, and is able to
justify his progress to himself morally in spite of the plight of the poor. His
wealth and his investment in foreign markets enable him to diversify his eco-
nomic role: when the French cannot afford to buy his wine, Charles is able to
exchange his surplus wine for fruit from Italy and the Levant. He also pur-
chases large quantities of grapes from Steele, his brother’s English colleague,
to sell as fruit instead of wine, and in turn sells Steele his surplus second-
grade wine for England, for
Like the utilitarians Jeremy Bentham and Robert Owen, Martineau bought
into the idea of a free market. However, this conviction was not unqualified.
The network of foodstuffs throughout Europe is central to Martineau’s vision
of free trade, but it also reveals the way in which trade takes advantage of
lack, and promotes self-interest as a moral good over the interest of the com-
munity. In this way, Charles and Steele both represent what Regenia Gagnier
refers to as the “manifold irony” of Adam Smith’s political economy, “that
selfish individuals could make an altruistic society; that the pursuit of profit
could be an ethical failing in an individual but lead to the wealth of all”
(Gagnier 2000a: 316). The resolute blindness towards the real suffering
caused by such economic and social visions remains problematic in terms of
human concerns. Martineau thus challenges the ideals of utilitarianism that
would enable and give traction to the 1834 New Poor Laws.
When Charles “eagerly” tells his wife, Marguerite, of the great progress
being made in society through the character-building nature of starvation
and hardship, he evokes Malthus, saying: “I see every day, not only splen-
did instances of intellectual effort … but moral struggles and self-sacrifices
which dispose me more than ever to bow the knee to human nature”
(Martineau 1833b: 41). Malthus claims in the Principle of Population that
Chaotic interruptions in the economy 123
The sorrows and distresses of life form another class of excitements
which seem to be necessary, by a peculiar train of impressions, to
soften and humanize the heart, to awaken social sympathy, to generate
all the Christian virtues, and to afford scope for the ample exertion of
benevolence.
(2007, first published1798: 144)
Yet this view affords room for Charles’s justification of self-interest in a way
that Marguerite does not allow:
The advocate for the present order of things is apt to treat the sect of
speculative philosophers either as a set of artful and designing knaves,
who preach up ardent benevolence and draw captivating pictures of a
happier state of society, only the better to enable them to destroy the
present establishments and to forward their own deep-laid schemes of
ambition…. The advocate for the perfectibility of man … brands him as
the slave of the most miserable and narrow prejudices, or as the
defender of the abuses of civil society, only because he profits by
them…. In this unamicable contest the cause of truth cannot but suffer.
(2007: 2)
There is salt enough for every body here, and for half India besides;
and large quantities are destroyed every year, to keep up the price,
Chaotic interruptions in the economy 127
while many are dying for want of it…. If we could count the number
of Hindoos [sic] who die in India for want of salt which their own
country produces, we should find that a fearful reckoning awaits the
Company there, as there does the government here; a fearful balance
of human life against a high price of salt.
(45–6)
Conclusion
Throughout Martineau’s Illustrations of Political Economy, the role of the
physical, natural environment operates to overturn any human assump-
tion of power, violently usurping hubristic attempts to create order in
society and the economy. The natural world will always have precedence.
Rather than maintaining the aspect of most political economists, who
avoided contending with natural disasters, in Martineau’s work, these dis-
asters are brought to the fore in order to critique the mathematical simpli-
city of economic models, as well as the obsessive willingness of those who
professed political economy to maintain the myth of the theory’s moral
grounding. As much as she may provide details of political economic
theory in her tales, Martineau also refuses to deny the human cost that the
implementation of such theories would entail. The human cost is most
effectively shown through the effects of, and response to, natural disasters
– factors that would continue to plague the globe, and are, arguably, even
more pertinent in our contemporary world. Although forecasting systems
have been developed, and are able to predict storms, floods, and even
droughts to an extent, it is not possible to prevent them from happening;
it is only possible to mitigate their effect. In this way, the physical environ-
ment reflects the global economy; for as much as economics depends on
narratives of order, the systems in place are actually volatile, essentially
unpredictable and ultimately uncontrollable. Martineau is problematically
128 Lesa Scholl
blind to colonial and cross-cultural sensitivities in a way that could be seen
as buying into a similar ethos to the imperialists engaged with the East
India Company or other British trade; but this broad stroke is a gambit for
her deeper concern regarding the application of economic theories at
home as much as abroad. She overturns arrogant assumptions of political
economy through her assertion of climatic devastation; yet at the same
time, and somewhat idealistically, such disasters have the potential to
bring communities together to formulate solutions in their wake. These
solutions, however, prove more effective on the local level (although that
impact also remains limited), rather than depending on broad national or
international structures to assert order into chaos. Ultimately Martineau
rejects institutionalised structures of relief in favour of community-based
human interdependence.
Notes
1 See a more extended discussion of the critical reception of Martineau’s eco-
nomic tales in this regard in Scholl (2011: 105–10).
2 The Swing Riots took place throughout the south and east of England. Agricul-
tural workers and labourers were protesting against harsh working conditions
and the increase of machinery in farm production. The name comes from the
fictitious “Captain Swing” in whose name threatening letters were written to
landowners and magistrates. The participants were feared by many for their mid-
night raids and machine-breaking.
3 See Rudé (1964: 108) for a detailed discussion on this impact.
4 The Corn Laws (1815–46) were a tariff on imported grains, designed to keep
domestic grain prices higher. The result for many was that bread was unafforda-
ble and much ended up wasted.
5 The way in which droughts resist structural definition affects any kind of institu-
tionalised relief or aid. However, in Martineau’s tale, there is an entire absence
of institutionalised charity. In general, Martineau distrusted such institutions.
Her fictional works emphasise the importance of community-based relief that
focused on the individual relationships and interdependence between members
of the community across classes.
6 Throughout the first half of the nineteenth century, journalists, politicians and
commentators referred to The Terror of the 1789 French Revolution as a point
of fear and aversion, particularly in regard to social and political reform. It was a
persistent narrative in both official political documents, the periodical press and
novels. For further discussion see Scholl (2016: 16–20).
7 In the following chapter, Sanjay Sharma discusses how food insecurity could be
exacerbated due to the cultural inappropriateness of food served in north
Indian poorhouses during nineteenth-century famines.
7 Poorhouses and gratuitous
famine relief in colonial
North India
Sanjay Sharma
Hence it was made clear that official relief policies were to be structured
around the core idea of work, and therefore all those who were needy and
wanted state-support were expected to do some work. This policy was thus
a continuation of the principles of relief enunciated during the previous
famine of 1837–38. Accordingly, during the famine of 1860–61, the
departments in charge of irrigation and public works were instructed to
employ people on “works of utility”. Wages were meant to be as low as pos-
sible so as not to adversely impact the wages that a person could get by
working elsewhere. In the famine-affected districts, between 40,000 and
50,000 people were employed every day, mainly on the irrigation works
being built by the government and by the East Indian Railways that ran
through the middle of the central area worst affected in the famine tract.
Thus “setting people to work” was the central principle around which
relief policies were organised for the “able-bodied”.
However, it is in the sphere of gratuitous relief, i.e. for those unable to
perform any work (described as “helpless”) that the most noteworthy and
significant policy decisions were taken for the first time in this region. In
the previous famine of 1837–38,
Thus the principle of setting people to work lay at the heart of state relief
for those classified either as “able-bodied” or those deemed “helpless”. In
the rules for the relief of the “helpless” it was made absolutely clear at the
outset that those adults and children who were found fit to be able to
perform light work, like carrying a basket of earth, were not to receive any
gratuitous relief and were to be dispatched to a “labouring gang” (Girdle-
stone, 1868: Appendix IV, “Rules for the Relief of the Helpless in
1860–61”, No. I). The biographer of the 1860–61 famine, Col. Baird-
Smith, affirmed that the “principle that all who can work shall work in
ways suited to their capacity should be carried out as much as possible”
and desired that all relief houses for the “helpless” should be “gradually
developed into a true work-house” (Baird-Smith, 1861: Section I, 25 May
1861, para 22). Strachey had also emphasised that “the establishment of a
poor-house should at the same time be, strictly speaking, a work-house”
(Strachey, 1862: 5). In his view, making relief-seekers do some work would
enable the separation of the deserving and undeserving as, otherwise,
“professional beggars, fakirs, Brahmins, and imposters” managed to grab
a bigger share of relief than those who were “really fit objects of charity”.
134 Sanjay Sharma
Clearly the implication was that these groups were disinclined to work and
should therefore be discouraged to partake of state charity in poorhouses.
By stressing that “charity shall be, as far as possible, only afforded in
exchange for labor” (Strachey, 1862: 13), official policy made it apparent
that work and labour defined useful living, and unproductive sections of
the subject population had weak moral claims on state benevolence. Con-
sequently, poorhouse inmates were engaged in tasks like cotton spinning,
manufacture of cloth, niwar (coarse broad tapes often used to lace beds)
and durries (mats), rope-making, grinding corn, road-making and building
sheds for the poorhouse (ibid.: 10–11). The products were sold for money,
although Strachey observed that these activities were “undertaken without
any idea of profit, and even if they had been carried on at a loss, they
would not the less had been expedient” (ibid.: 10).
The second crucial feature of poorhouses was the serving of cooked food
to its inmates. This had been tried in earlier relief measures and, from the
1830s, arguments in favour of serving cooked food in prisons had found
acceptance among officials and doctors of the colonial establishment. Its
ideological context was provided by the emergence of the workhouse as the
key institution in Britain and its other colonies since the New Poor Law of
1834. Intended to be houses of correction, the workhouses were often
described as “prisons”, especially in their early years, but where work
replaced the whip (Reinarz and Schwarz, 2013: 1–16; Pemberton, 2013).
Among other aspects, a distasteful and unappetising diet contributed towards
making the workhouse a place of deterrence. These ideas found reflection in
the colonial drive to reform prisons in India in the early nineteenth century.
For example, the 1838 report of the Committee on Prison Discipline pro-
pounded a new structure of prison management in which punishment was
intended to ensure what has been described as the “right calculus of terror
and deterrence” (Yang, 1987: 30). In this, serving a diet of cooked food was
favoured for its disciplinary aspect. The next step in that direction was the
introduction of the system of messing that was introduced in Bengal prisons
in the 1840s. In this system, convicts were to be divided into groups and
cooked food was to be substituted for money or rations. This invited hostility
from prisoners for a number of reasons. Cooked food increased the working
time of the convict by taking away the time they spent in cooking, reduced
the choice of what they ate, how they varied their diet and acquired desirable
products like tobacco (Singha, 1998: 281). Above all, cooked food threat-
ened the caste and religious identities of the prisoners and several instances
of serious opposition to it were reported from the jails of Bengal Presidency.
However, the government was firm in dealing with them and was determined
to implement the policy of serving cooked food to its prison inmates. This
practice stepped out of colonial prisons and became the defining feature of
poorhouses that appeared during the 1860–61 famine in the NWP.
In the model poorhouse at Moradabad, elaborate rules were laid down
for doling out cooked food. Cooked food was given only once in 24 hours
Poorhouses and gratuitous famine relief 135
with little variation in the food that was served. Collector Strachey’s report
that was much cited in official circles reasoned:
The general good health of the paupers has shown that there is no
necessity for more frequent meals. Hitherto, there has been no vari-
ation in the diet, except that different kinds of dáls have, from time to
time, been supplied. Persons for whom other food is necessary can
obtain it from the hospital.
(Strachey, 1861: 9)
Rations were uniform for all classes of adults and children and the single
meal consisted of 10 chat.aks of flour and 2 chat.aks of dāl (pulses) for each
“working pauper” while “non-workers” received less.3
Separate cooking arrangements were made for Muslims and others who
had no objections on grounds of caste. For them cooking was done by
contract, something that was found to be “least troublesome and most
economical”. For Hindus with caste-prejudices, Brahmin cooks and kahars
(caste of carriers with low social status) were engaged but the amount
served to both the groups was the same. In Strachey’s view, the system was
so designed to keep out all those who had other means of support and the
amount of food was just about sufficient to preserve the health of the
poor. He also pointed out that the system of serving cooked meals worked
well to ensure checks and reduce fraudulence. The purchase, preparation,
and distribution of food were to be supervised by a sub-committee com-
posed of the “respectable members of the Native community, with some
trustworthy officer of Government as e.g., A Native Deputy Collector, or
Tehseeldar as their President” (Strachey, 1861, No. IV).4 The government
insisted that one or more of its officers should be part of each such local
committee to not only “safeguard against waste or abuse of funds” but to
ensure that “fundamental rules” were followed and to ensure “uniformity”.
There are several aspects here that are similar to the administration of the
new Poor Law in England. Felix Driver has noted a similar quest for uni-
formity in his study of the workhouse system in England: standardisation
of local procedures, to make local relief practices consistent with and
conform to the principles laid down by central authority, and to level out
Flour Daal
Adults of both sexes 8 chataks 1½ chataks
Children above 10 years 6 chataks 1½ chataks
Children below 10 years 4 chataks 1 chatak
Children in arms 2 chataks 1 chatak
Relief from hunger by the supply of cooked food is the main character-
istic of the system … in fact it is a corrective of or a preventive to
abuses, that the supply of cooked food works so well, and excepting in
very special cases, and under very peculiar circumstances. I am satis-
fied it should be rigidly adhered to; I found an absolute unanimity on
this point among Native Committees, and as all personal details con-
nected with the food are left exclusively to them, the plan has not in
my experience been the subject of a single complaint.
(Baird-Smith, 1861: Section I, p. 14)
I can account for the dislike in accepting relief at the Poor House only
to the general objection to giving up home and freedom and under-
going the confinement necessary if such relief is accepted and also to
the fear of being turned out of caste, a very strong feeling amongst the
rural population in this District, but which doubtless been overcome
by degrees had the distress continued much longer and had a larger
number of paupers thus been able to see for themselves what the
138 Sanjay Sharma
arrangements for cooking the food were. Some recruiters came to the
District at the commencement of the cold season and enlisted 205
emigrants for Demerara. I have since heard that this gave rise to a
rumour that if the people come to the Poor House they would be sent
across the seas.
(Collector Badaun, 21 May 1878)
The opposite view was articulated with no less force and backed by
arguments:
Thus there were conflicting expectations from the poorhouses. While the
colonial authorities in principle were not in favour of giving anything
gratis and expected work in return for any assistance even in poorhouses,
the popular norms and expectations ran contrary to that. Official advice
to “native” elites continued to firmly stress that they should avoid
142 Sanjay Sharma
indulging in muftkhairāt (literally, “free charity”) as it made the recipients
slow, lazy, and dull (sust) (Qahat Sāli Ke Zābate [Rules for Famine Years],
1897: 7).14 During famines, the needy did come to the poorhouses, but
once the conditions improved even the poorest stayed away from them
because of insistence on work and cooked food. So, for example, an offi-
cial from Bengal was of the opinion that
yet men do not go to works in large numbers. They are seen begging
in villages & towns and after a few days they are so reduced that Tah-
sildars have to send them to the Poor House which has so overflowed
with them that its expenditure is enormous.
(Robkar dated 28 February 1878, in “Abstract of Orders Issued on the
Occurrence of famine in the Bijnor district 1877–78”)
I have often heard the people say that Govt. aided the people without
any work even during the former temporary famines but they were at
a loss to know why hard labour was taken this time while the country
was suffering from the horrible famine. It appeared to me, that these
people expected aid from Govt. without doing any work. But it was
impossible to meet their desires and also inexpedient.
(“Petition from Munshi Parmanand, Tehsildar of Aonla,
28 May, 1878”)
Conclusion
Unlike in Britain, poorhouses in India had their origins in famine relief,
specifically in the famine of 1860–61 in colonial north India. As a part of
the policy of gratuitous relief they were organised around the idea of “less
eligibility” and were not meant for those who were deemed “able-bodied”.
Initially, their primary purpose was to prevent starvation-deaths and to just
about restore the health of the famished inmates to enable them to work
again and return them to a life of productive labour. As a matter of prin-
ciple, every inmate was expected to do some useful labour, however light,
even if she/he was incapable of doing so. This was grounded in the belief
that any form of assistance, including gratuitous relief, should not encour-
age indiscriminate charity. This belief had its roots in the shifts that had
been occurring in Europe, particularly from the sixteenth-century post-
Reformation period, as a result of which indiscriminate alms-giving and
beggary came to be regarded as inimical to the needs of a capitalist bour-
geois society (Frohman, 2008: chapters 1 and 2; Hindle, 2001). This led to
attempts at rationalisation of charity and the establishment of houses of
correction in most European countries.21 By the nineteenth century, pau-
perism, vagrancy, and criminality further stigmatised the marginal sections
of society and institutional mechanisms emerged in Britain in the form of
workhouses after the New Poor Law of 1834 (Driver, 1993). These work-
houses, that were products of a specific utilitarian dream, served as the
prototype for poorhouses when they were conceived by the colonial
146 Sanjay Sharma
bureaucracy in the later decades of the nineteenth century. Physical, geo-
graphical, and spatial confinement, insistence on extraction of work from
even the most feeble and debilitated inmates, a monotonous daily regu-
lated routine, a frugal subsistence diet and denial of all indulgence char-
acterised the poorhouses. As a corollary, virtues of discipline, diligence,
and obedience were sought to be inculcated in the inmates who, in official
perception, were to be weaned away from undesirable indigenous charity
that encouraged indolence, dependence, and parasitism. Indian charit-
able practices came to be located in non-Christian religious superstitions,
and were described as desultory and arbitrary, in need of reform. Poor-
houses were thus presented as alternative models of rational and institu-
tional philanthropy. They served as illustrative examples of the ways in
which utilitarian ideas were practised in the colonial context, which in
addition to being paternalistic had little regard for the perspectives of the
subject population. As Gagnier’s influential study of Victorian economics
and aesthetics points out, utilitarian reformers treated the poor and the
needy as means to an end and for “their own social planning rather than
ends in themselves” (Gagnier, 2000b: 224–6).
The successful functioning of poorhouses was marred by a number of
factors. The insistence on serving cooked food, and work and confine-
ment away from homes, prevented many needy caste Hindus and women
from coming to the poorhouses. Despite official efforts to take care of
these objections, over a period of time, poorhouses became unpopular
and even hated institutions that were shunned even by those rendered
destitute either due to famine or impoverishment. Yet they were not shut
down as they came to house the extremely sick, indigent, beggars,
maimed, orphans, and often lepers. The colonial administration there-
fore persisted with the poorhouses beyond famine situations and
entrusted their management to municipalities. Exclusion and confine-
ment of these extremely marginalised sections of society found support
among, certainly, elite Indians, many of whom also gave donations for the
establishment and running of poorhouses. However, poorhouses
remained under-funded and too few in number, and assisted only a very
small percentage of the population. Though metropolitan in their origins
in terms of their core ideas and principles, they eventually failed to
address the problem of poverty and hunger in the colony. As institutions,
their impact was therefore limited and they hardly served as “tools of
empire”, but the excavation and recovery of the principles and practices
embedded in them sheds light on a lost chapter in the history of hunger
and institutional care in India.
Acknowledgements
I would like to thank Pragati Mohapatra, Tanuja Kothiyal, and Ayesha
Mukherjee for their comments and suggestions. I am grateful for the input
Poorhouses and gratuitous famine relief 147
that I received on my paper presented at the conference held in Oxford
in 2015, which has resulted in this publication. Thanks are also due to my
colleagues at Ambedkar University Delhi for providing the intellectual and
institutional milieu in which many of my ideas took shape.
Notes
1 The famine reports of the late nineteenth century classified governmental
remedial measures under the category of “gratuitous charity” meant for those
considered incapable of work, for example, the old, sick, infirm, maimed,
“idiots and lunatics” etc. See among others, Report of the Indian Famine Commis-
sion, Part III, Famine Histories, 1885 and Report of the Indian Famine Commission,
1898. This was distinguished from private charitable acts undertaken by indi-
viduals in their personal capacity.
2 The ambivalence about whether and how to separate private and public
benevolence had a long history in the provision of English poor relief, going
back to the early modern period. Similar debates about the “deserving” and
“undeserving poor” led to a separation of private and public charity measures
in the context of the 1590s famines in England. For details, see Hindle, 2004:
15–95 and Mukherjee, A., 2015: 10–13, 20–1. For some aspects of hospitality
and alms-giving in late Elizabethan England and their complex relationship
with the statutory welfare provision, see Hindle, 2001.
3 Chat.ak, literally one-sixteenth. One ser contains sixteen chat.aks, and is equi-
valent to approximately 930 grams or 2 lbs, i.e. a little less than a kilogram.
4 For a useful description of gratuitous relief in the NWP and the working of the
poorhouses during the famine of 1860–61, see Srivastava, 1968: 38–45.
5 Those who were served cooked food in the poorhouses were divided into three
categories: adults (16 oz flour, 4 oz vegetables); children above 10 (12 oz and
2 oz); children below 10 (8 oz and 2 oz) (Henvey, 1871: 6).
6 Apparently the Brahmins of Puri, Cuttack, and Calcutta were consulted on the
issue of accepting cooked food during the 1866 Orissa famine. Among the
pundits “opinion was unanimous that no act committed to save life occasions
loss of caste”. However some pundits did insist on purificatory rituals with some
payment (Blair, 1874: 200).
7 There is a substantial literature on the cultural and ritual significance of
cooked and uncooked food in South Asia. See, for example, Khare, 1993, and
Bhushi, 2018.
8 This was, however, denied by others. See, for example, “Letter from Syed
Imdad Ali, Deputy Collector of Moradabad, 2 June 1878”.
9 Mustt: abbreviation of Musammat, an Arabic word meaning “woman” or “wife”,
usually written before a woman’s name, often in official documents.
10 Reported by the Jhansi correspondent of the Nasim-i-Agra of 7 January 1897 in
Selections from the Vernacular Newspapers.
11 In another instance cited in this letter, a chamar woman was served the food of
seven or eight persons for “immoral purpose” by two brothers known to
commit adultery. Ibid.
12 These factors created the “dread of entering the poor house” in Shahajanpur.
See “Note on the Scarcity in Rohilkhand Division, 1877–78”.
13 An official reported that in the newly opened poorhouse at Orai “over 30 starv-
ing waifs and strays having been picked up on the roads, fed and drafted to the
relief works when they have become fit for labour” (Collector Jalaun to Com-
missioner Allahabad, 3 March 1896).
148 Sanjay Sharma
14 I am grateful to my historian colleague Tanuja Kothiyal for sharing this docu-
ment with me.
15 The original poem is not cited in Selections.
16 The Trust also received private contributions from local notables like the raja
of Payagpur. (“Poor House Trust in the District of Bahraich during the year
1893–4”).
17 When poorhouses were opened in Kalpi and Orai they were under the charge
of the civil surgeon who maintained them through his subordinate staff.
However, attempts were being made to administer the poorhouses according
to famine code rules and not leave them under the civil surgeon. See Collector
Jalaun to Commissioner Allahabad. Div., 13 February 1896.
18 Some collectors were in favour of keeping lepers out of poorhouses as money
was given to leper asylums separately.
19 For colonial and indigenous attitudes towards leprosy and confinement, see
Buckingham, 2002.
20 In early nineteenth century Europe, after the Napoleonic secularisation of
many religious institutions in Germany, Switzerland, and Austria, benevolent
societies and charities increasingly played an important role “paving the way
for an institutionalised public welfare in the coming decades that eventually
superseded Christian caritas” (Collet and Krämer, 2017: 111).
21 In this context, a re-reading of Foucault’s classic account “The Great Confine-
ment” is rewarding (1965: chapter II).
Part IV
Contemporary voices
and memories
8 Farming tales
Narratives of farming and food
security in mid-twentieth-century
Britain
Michael Winter
This we were quite happy to do, without also realizing that we would
continue day by day for nearly five years before our trust would be
completed. Every day we fed and watered the birds, collected the eggs,
entering the number in a book, selling them each week.…. We set two
broody hens, reared the chickens, sold the surplus birds, and banked
the profits.
… until 1919, when a somewhat battle-scarred warrior returned to
civil life, and we expected to return the stock and hand over the
profits.…. Somewhat huskily, he made over the birds and profits for
our trouble.… The stock had grown from six birds to twenty-seven a
good strain of real old-fashioned Light Sussex.
(The Farming Ladder, 40–1)
158 Michael Winter
Henderson had no doubt that farming was what he wanted to do and, as
he recounts in The Farming Ladder, following this early success with urban
poultry, he set out both to learn about different types of farming and in
due course to find his own farm. He spent a year on a lowland mixed farm,
then a few months on a dairy and poultry farm. Then on an upland sheep
farm he learned more from the shepherd than he did from the failing,
and periodically drunken, farmer who eventually offered the young man a
partnership, which Henderson rejected because of his commitment to a
partnership and purchase of a farm with his brother. His quest during
these two years of learning, and in the farming career that followed with
his brother, was marked by a single-minded work ethic that might now-
adays be seen as verging on the obsessive:
Working from five in the morning to nine o’clock at night, I had few
opportunities for spending money. …. I was very happy in my work,
finding no toil or drudgery in it.
(The Farming Ladder, 18)
Certainly his hard work gave him the requisite knowledge and, with the
help of capital from his mother, he and his brother bought their Cotswold
farm in 1924 at the height of the inter-war agricultural depression. In the
years that followed he demonstrated how a small farm could be made to
pay, an experience which he set out in meticulous detail in his books.
Henderson is the quintessential “working farmer” writer. He wrote
solely about practical farming and confined his writing to his three pub-
lished books; no journalism, no novels, and certainly no romanticised
accounts of country living. His was a philosophy of self-reliance and the
spiritual and material values of hard work. He saw farming as both a way of
life – that was character-building and fulfilling – and a demanding busi-
ness. His is the classic story of the self-made man, and his ability to forge
business success at a time when many agricultural businesses were failing –
with consequent calls for government support for agriculture – led to an
Farming tales 159
ambivalent or even hostile attitude to the war-time and post-war consensus
that developed around a state supported agriculture to secure food
security:
To say that only the State has the means to rebuild and equip our
farms is ridiculous; any farm which is fully productive can earn the
capital necessary to restore it, and build on for future requirements, as
my brother and I have proved on our own holding.
(The Farming Ladder, Postscript to 1955 edition, 241)
Between 1939 and 1945 the urgent need to feed the nation resulted in
unprecedented levels of state intervention in agriculture, with a raft of
measures designed to encourage and cajole farmers to raise levels of pro-
duction and to focus on calorie-rich crops such as potatoes and cereals
(Collingham 2011). Crucial to these efforts were the County War Agricul-
tural Executive Committees (CWAEC) with tough powers to impose super-
vision orders and even to evict farmers unwilling or unable to comply with
the CWAECs’ requirements (Short 2014). Such an approach was ana-
thema to a free market proponent such as Henderson:
Good character, good habits, and industry, are impregnable to all the ill
luck this world ever dreamed of, proof against every misfortune, includ-
ing, I believe, legalized robbery by a state that caters for the lazy, the
selfish and the idle and penalizes the efficient, thrifty and industrious.
(The Farming Ladder, Postscript to 1955 edition, p. 219)
The Farming Ladder remained in print for over thirty years into the late
1970s, and Farmer’s Progress was nearly as popular. Copies were to be found
in the libraries of farm institutes, agricultural colleges, and universities,
and the books were read by numerous aspiring farmers, farm advisors, and
the like. It cannot have failed to have influenced the thinking of many,
and yet so many of its fundamental premises were at odds with the cor-
poratist agricultural settlement, championed by the NFU, that had
emerged as the seemingly undisputed answer to the UK’s food security
(Cox et al. 1986, 1991).
I inflict all this upon you because I foresee that by the time this book
gets published you will almost be deafened by bleatings about the
virtues of individual enterprise. An excellent exponent of it amongst
farmers is Mr. George Henderson.…. It might be taken as a Liberal
Party tract.…
(Reynolds, 1945: 93)
But Reynolds had one thing in common with Henderson, his disdain for
the NFU:
These are harsh words indeed, and Reynolds responds robustly. It is hard
to avoid the conclusion that Street, a conservative and traditionalist voice,
was responding as much to Reynolds’ subversive politics as to his actual
farming experiences. Street was mounting a spirited defence of conven-
tional agriculture and conventional agricultural politics.
Conclusions
The three farming writers explored in this chapter demonstrate that the
voices of agriculture were by no means united in their views. In 1996, I
wrote of a “firm and coherent policy community, capable of defending
and promoting the interests of farmers” (Winter 1996: 102). I identified
the factors that brought about this coherence based on a mutuality of
interests in post-war Britain. The farming industry was
One fact that needs to be noted is that famine conditions seem to have
been limited to Bengal and its environs, not the whole of India. Yet the
surplus stocks from major producing regions like the Punjab did not reach
Bengal, reportedly because of the complicity of traders, politicians, and
government officials.7
In an article in The Hindu (13 February 2013), written on the eve of the
passing of the National Food Security Act by the Indian Parliament, the
eminent agricultural scientist M. S. Swaminathan looked back at his deci-
sion to abandon medical studies and become a soil scientist. The most
powerful forces behind his decision, he pointed out, were the Quit India
call by Gandhiji and the photographs of dying multitudes in Bengal:
In Bengal, states Greenough, peasants are unfamiliar with the simple ideas
of scarcity and subsistence, preferring to refer to the notion of Laksmi,
standing for prosperity or well-being, which is realized when there is abun-
dance, and consequently the networks of mutual obligation that tie
together members of families – and families with the larger community –
are intact. Prosperity, he goes on to say, is expressed by the presence of
three related qualities “indulgence” (prasraya), “abundance” (raj-laksmi),
and “good health” (sri). The Bengal famine, that paradigmatic moment of
absence of well-being sees not violent peasant upsurges, but rather a wide-
spread breakdown in the ethic of care that normatively should be present:
The point about desperation is important: neither droughts nor floods nor
rapacious landlords and traders are unusual in Bengal, and scarcity is very
much a condition of being for the greater number of its inhabitants. The
exceptionality of the 1943 famine is what the literature of the period docu-
ments, and the question of moral agency is unlikely to have a simple
answer.
Let me then briefly consider two representations of the moral con-
sequences of famine in Bengali literature, not for their exemplary value,
but to propose that literature habitually suggests alternate ways of
response. The temporal closeness of the events to artists and audiences
alike might argue for a kind of mimetic force, even if fables – like Nabanna
– have ends that seem forced and propagandist. One should also point out
that representations of the human conduct in extreme crisis are extremely
varied, given the sheer bulk of literary famine narratives. The first text that
174 Amlan Das Gupta
.
I wish to briefly examine is Manik Bandyopadhyay’s short story “Chiniy e
.
khayni keno” (Why didn’t they snatch and eat?), first published in the 1947
volume of short stories, Khatiyan.13 In her detailed documentation of the
representations of the famine in Bengali literature, Binata Roychowdhury
observes that of all contemporary writers, Manik Bandyopadhyay com-
posed the greatest number of stories on the famine (1993: 55). The
present tale recounts a conversation between an unnamed narrator, and
Jogi, who has the fearsome reputation of having been a brigand in the
idealized traditional mode: he robbed the rich and fed the poor. Even
during the famine, he looted food to distribute to the hungry, and into
the bargain, saved several women from being sold into prostitution. He is
certainly not the docile Bengali peasant, mutely suffering extreme depriva-
tion. He has only recently been released after serving a prison sentence
for robbing a government supply boat.
Supriya Chaudhuri examines this story in the context of her study of
the moral economy of wellbeing, and finds in it a peculiar mimetic
anxiety:
Chaudhuri concludes:
Beyond that liminal point where the body crosses into the exhaustion
and physical depletion of hunger, the body is its own food, hunger
consumes it like an other, and in so doing it estranges and alienates
the self, so that it appears to have no worldly recourse.
(Ibid.)
I have chosen to revisit this tale because of the way it formulates and
answers the issue of passivity: “Not one, not ten, but hundreds and thou-
sands and millions of them went under … yet they didn’t move an arm to
snatch and eat their food, to grab it” (204). Jogi’s tone is ironic, and at
times openly derisive of the middle-class intellectualism of his interlocutor.
The economy of hunger 175
The city bābus (urban Bengali gentlemen and intellectuals) shouted them-
selves hoarse about the “food” crisis. For the poor, it was not a question of
food in the abstract, its many refined varieties, but of rice; for if there had
been the coarsest, maggot-ridden grain, even then people would have
lived, hung on to life somehow. There are wild roots, plants, and leaves in
the forest: all they needed was a little rice. Jogi is a privileged speaker, for
two different reasons. First, he is a witness in the double sense that Giorgio
Agamben uses the term of the survivors of the Holocaust, both testis and
superstes, witness and survivor (1999: 17); second, as a brigand and organ-
izer of revolt, he claims a distinct kind of agency, one that sets him apart
from his suffering fellows. There is thus a fierce pride in his claim that he,
and only he, can truly say why there was no violence, no forcible seizure of
food: “Now I – I know why they didn’t snatch – I alone do. No one else has
a clue” (206).
Jogi provides in fact a mocking commentary on urban middle-class
responses to this question, “all nonsense, just so much hot air” (206). Jogi
reports to his companion both the opinions of the “bābus” and his own
angry rejoinders. One lot say, these are poor and inoffensive farmers, they
can’t even dream of looting and robbing. Jogi’s response is appropriately
mordant. Who thinks of the law, he says, in the face of death? They would
sell their wives and daughters, they would strangle a dying sharer, just to
have that much more for themselves. To be arrested is to be saved, for at
least there is food in the prisons. Another bābu tells him that ordinary
people believe in fate, and accept it unquestioningly. But Jogi asks: Don’t
people seek recourse against snake-bite? Don’t they take precautions
against floods and try to save themselves from fire? So why wouldn’t they
at least try to save themselves by seizing the food in front of them? The
narrator feels a little uncomfortable at this vein of mockery: “I know what
such people say, Jogi. What about you?” (206) But Jogi is relentless. The
third opinion, voiced by a bābu whose heart bleeds for the poor, attributes
the docility of the peasants to their age-old habit of living with dearth.
They were used to not eating when there was no rice to be had. Jogi’s
response is appropriately savage: “So I told him, sir, they may have been
used to starving, were they also used to dying?” (107).
Jogi comes to the relief camp in the city as an outsider, having failed
earlier in his attempt to get together a gang to loot food rather than
money and ornaments. He dresses in rags, even though he clearly looks
better fed than the others. Some try to chase him away, others flatter him
for possible advantage. Jogi witnesses the condition of the relief-seekers,
and true to his recalcitrant nature tries to instill in them a rebellious spirit.
“I go around telling everybody, why don’t you snatch and eat? … We are
dying anyway, so let us die fighting” (210). Most of the supplies sent for
the relief kitchen disappear into the hands of the hoarders. But his incite-
ment appears to have little effect. The starving lot, feeding on miniscule
helpings of a watery concoction of rice and lentils, pays little heed to what
176 Amlan Das Gupta
he says, not because they do not want to but because they simply can’t.
They nod off, and in between ask him to repeat what he was saying. Only
some, after consuming the degrading fare doled out, are stirred into a
show of temper, but by evening it has all died again and all they are able
to do is to feebly jostle for a place in the queue.
Jogi arranges by contacting his earlier criminal associates to have a full
shipment of food sent to the camp. This seems to work wonders. The food
improves dramatically, the gruel is nice and thick, there is a potato per
head in the bargain:
(176)
. . .
[ār et.ai āsal kathā man diy e śonen bābu. chiniye khey e bāñcbār kathā jārā
.
keu kāne tole ni, duto din du-belā ek mog dāl ār ektu kore āluseddha kheye
. .
sakale kān pete śunte lāgla āmār kathā, sāy diy e bolte lāgla je ei t.hik, e char.a
.
bāñcbār upay nei.]
And then, sir, comes the most important part of my story, so listen
carefully. The same people who had paid no heed when I told them to
come and loot now grew attentive to my words, now that they were
getting two square meals … for the last couple of days. They started
agreeing that what I said was true, that there was no other way
but this.
(211)
They were ready to loot and plunder; they would take over the camp them-
selves and cook their own rations; even the children were oozing bravado.
Jogi takes upon himself the task of training this rag-tag lot the art of
professional brigandage with the same care that had taught his bandit
crew. He settles on Baikuntha Saha’s warehouse as the target of his attack,
and spends a couple of days surveying the spot. When he gets back, he
finds to his shock that food has run out, the old ration of thin gruel
resumed. The very people who had sworn violent deeds are back in their
state of inaction: “Hooked on to the thought of their watery pish-pash
once again they were. Lost the power of thinking of anything else” (211).
This then is the core of Jogi’s answer to the question that he formulates
himself: “Why didn’t they snatch and eat?” The question apparently exer-
cised nationalist leaders as well. Malini Bhattacharya observes that Jawahar-
lal Nehru is supposed to have asked the same question (headnote, 203).
The answer that Jogi finds is based on the nature of hunger itself: in a
state of radical privation, hunger inhibits its own redress.
The economy of hunger 177
(177)
.
[sedin bujhlām bābu keno eto lok nā-kheye morche, eto khābār hāter kāche
. . .
thākte chiniye khāyni keno. ek din khete nā pele śorirt.a śudhu śukāy nā, lar.āi
. . . .
kore chiniye kheye bẽce thākār tāgid-o jhimiye jāy . du-cār din ektu kichu khete
. . .
pele setā pher māthācār.ā diye ot.he. dudin khete nā pele pher jhimiye jāy. ta ete
aścorjo ki. eto sahaj sojā kathā.]
So then I knew, sir, why people starve to death, why they never snatch
and eat even with food within their reach. When one goes without a
meal, it is not just the body that gets dried up, the urge to fight for life
and grab food goes down too. Then you get something to eat once
more, and the urge is back. Then you starve for a couple of days, it
goes down again. No wonder. It’s all quite simple really.
(212)
(178)
. . . .
[āje-bāje khey āle – jesob khey āl tāderi mānāy, tāderi fyaśān, jārā chiniy e khey e
.
bāñcār prabrittit.a parjanta kẽce diy e mārte pāre lākhe-lākhe mā-bāp chele-meye
.
– anārthak akhuśi hote rāji noy mānush.]
Who would bother to grumble about silly fancies, fancies that suit only
those who can kill off billions of mothers, fathers and children simply
by crushing their instinct to snatch food and live?
(214)
. .
[grāme thākā khub muśkil hoy e por.lo Moti Mucinīr mrityu hoy ār par.
anāhāre mrityu ei pratham, er āge keu jānta nā bā biśwās kare ni je anāhāre
ābār mānush morte pāre. Eto phal thākte gāche gāche, nadir jale eto māch
thākte, biśesh kore eto lok jekhāne bāsh kore grāme o pāsher grāme, takhon
.
mānush kakhono nā khey e mare? … kintu Moti Mucinīr byapāre sakolei
.
bujhlo, nā kheye mānushe tāhole to morte pāre. etodin jā golpe-kāhinite shonā
jeto, āj tā sambhaber gandir modhye ese poũche gelo. koi ei je ektā lok mārā
.
gelo nā kheye, keu to tāke khete dile nā? sakoler mone bisham ektā āśangkār
.
srishti holo. sabāi to tāhole nā kheye morte pāre!]
The novel ends with two events. Moti’s body lies under the mango-tree,
people come to see and shudder, but ultimately it is Gangacharan and
Durga Bhattacharya, another Brahmin, who along with Ananga and the
Kapali woman, arrange for the last rites. Finally, Jadu Pora offers to take
the Kapali woman to the city and safety, but she refuses to go. One might
speculate about the possibility here of a “weak” ethical position, carefully
distinguished from numb passivity and heroic choice. Gianni Vattimo, the
propounder of the idea of “weak thought” writes of Benjamin’s angel in
the ninth thesis from the “The Concept of History”:
(1989: 98)
Human beings securely provisioned with food and water may feel in
control of their environment, thus unaware that they are “performed by
ecologies”, to borrow a phrase from Baz Kershaw (2015). In his article
Kershaw argues, with reference to the work of Jane Bennett (2010) and
Gregory Bateson (1972 and 2000), that the environment is “internal to
human beings”, and thus shapes everything human beings do (Kershaw,
2015: 125). The pun in my chapter title suggests that when human beings
are in the grip of famine and hunger, controlled by and no longer con-
trolling their resources, those affected become painfully aware of being
performed by dearth thus also by earthly ecosystems (d’Earth). What may
be forgotten in benign conditions is that this applies at all times, for the
Earth contains, encompasses, and subsumes everything we do and, as
James Lovelock suggests in his writings on Gaia (2006), ultimately, is far
more powerful than any individual species on the planet. Thus, the only
sense in which we should see ourselves as “performing the Earth” is
responsively, sensitively, collaboratively, and in tune with natural forces
thus recognising the bit part we play in the whole.1
When satisfying our daily need for food, we could not be more inti-
mately embedded in earthly ecosystems, even when we are consuming
modern-day processed food products that seem to be far removed from
the earth. It is an unavoidable fact that the consumption of food involves
human physiology at many levels – mechanical, chemical, and cellular, to
name three. As this implies, the ecosystem is (embedded in) the human
body and the human body is (embedded in) the ecosystem. In live
theatrical performance, the human body is centre stage, both on stage and
in phenomenological spectatorial responses in the audience. Thus,
Raymond Williams, discussing naturalism on stage, and describing the
“lives of the characters” as having “soaked into their environment” and
the environment as having “soaked into” their lives (Williams and Axton,
1997: 127), could be talking about any live theatrical performance or,
indeed, about life in a more general sense.
As a term, the “environment” is anthropocentric and throws into focus the
fundamental problem underpinning this chapter. This is the impossibility of
186 Julie Hudson
being integral to a system and at the same time having the perspective to
understand it. Perhaps because of this, the term environment is many-layered.
It can be used to denote the natural environment (separate from or com-
bined with humans); social structures formed by living beings (including
humans) within and as part of the natural environment; the hard and soft
infrastructure of human society or the complex system of conditions sur-
rounding and infused through the human mind and body. Such subtleties
notwithstanding, the environment, however defined, needs to be understood
as “fundamentally performed by Earth’s ecologies” (Kershaw, 2015: 113).
Sometimes, the way the term “environment” is used in the context of activ-
ities performed by human beings mistakenly implies that we are in control,
performing earthly ecologies rather than being performed by them. Dearth
has the power to destroy this illusion as demonstrated by many examples of
eye-catching real-life events theatrically delivered through the media. To give
just two of many possible examples, Michael Buerk’s striking eyewitness
account of the 1984 Ethiopian famine (YouTube) and, much later, the 2005
media pictures of the after-effects of Hurricane Katrina showing New Orleans
residents stranded on rooftops (Snyder, 2005), were memorable reminders
of the fragility of human beings disconnected from their ecologically
reshaped support systems. Twenty-first century commodity price volatility
(also performed by d’Earth, as discussed below) has resulted in outright
dearth in some countries, a recent example being the Mexican Tortilla Riots
(BBC News, 2007). Moreover, climate modelling predictions suggest that
dearth will be an inevitable consequence of uncontrolled global warming in
some regions (IPCC, 2013). Considering such examples, it would be surpris-
ing to find an absence of dearth in performance even in a seemingly unlikely
place such as modern theatre performed in conventional theatre spaces.
In this chapter, I identify a small number of plays that came to the stage
many years ago at times of famine or harvest failure, and could, because
they thematise dearth, be described as dearth plays (cf. Mukherjee, A.,
2015, “literatures of dearth”). This chapter considers what happens to
them in modern-day productions. If no food-insecurity resonance can be
identified in the production or reception of modern productions of early-
modern dearth plays, even perhaps to the extent that they are no longer
dearth plays in production, I want to argue that this may say something
potentially significant about the twenty-first century environmental and
social cultural context. My reading of the absence of such resonance
where it would reasonably be expected is that it signals a society (or at
least a group of people within that society) in denial. Absence or under-
emphasis would suggest a disturbing lack of awareness of the approaching
collision between growing populations and increasingly resource-hungry
economies, on the one hand, and constrained resources potentially under
threat from over-exploitation, on the other.
The methodology applied in this chapter borrows an idea from statis-
tics, where the impossibility of proving a negative proposition (such as the
Are we performing dearth? 187
absence of a theme in a play) requires the framing of research questions
in an affirmative form. Hence the need to identify older dearth play texts
in which dearth can be clearly identified in the text (as well as the context)
that are still in production. In theory, plays that came to the stage any time
from 1500 onwards are potentially relevant to this exercise; in practical
terms, I found the early-modern period to be the best source of earlier
plays still regularly performed. Works that came to the stage at this time
hold promise in this work for two reasons. First, it is a matter of record
that harvest failures and commodity price volatility were frequent in
England in the late 1500s and early 1600s. (For example, Mukherjee, A.
(2015: 309) cites Appleby (1978) as identifying 1587–88, 1597–98, and
1623 as “severe crises in the northwest”.) Second, several of them are still
in production. Where they still appear in production repertoires on a
regular basis, they present the possibility of informative empirical research
in the area of food insecurity in performance in modern times, thus indi-
rectly they may also reveal the extent to which we understand that we are
“performed by” the Earth we live on.
It is not known whether Shakespeare saw this exchange, but unlikely that
he was unaware of public sentiment in respect of the grain traders of his
day. Indeed, subject to the play’s having come to the stage early on in
1608, the 1607 anti-enclosure riots may have brought the issue of unequal
access to food and food-related resources back into focus again. One can
imagine the feelings of William Shakespeare, the well-to-do 1598 trader in
“ten quarters of malt” (cited by Chambers (99) with reference to docu-
mentation of “Returns made to the authorities” on 4 February 1598), con-
templating the anger of hungry people performed by dearth: “Let us
Are we performing dearth? 189
revenge this with our pikes, before we become rakes” (I.i.20–1). There are
strong arguments, as Steve Hindle demonstrates (2008), for associating
Coriolanus with the Midlands Rising, and Shakespeare is also thought to
have engaged with the immediate context of food riots in London in his
earlier play Romeo and Juliet (1599; cf. Fitter, 2000).
In our times, technology has provided new approaches to food produc-
tion and preparation, but there is plenty of evidence to suggest that this has
not banished food insecurity as a social concern. The profits made by food
commodity traders are as sensitive now as they were in early modern
England: so much so that some global banks have closed down their agricul-
tural commodity funds, in a good example of markets in the grip of ecolo-
gies (Archer et al., 2012). Food security and nutrition are front of mind for
politicians as I write this for a number of reasons, including: the prominent
discussions in the media of the food-related effects of the economic down-
turn (hunger in Greece, food banks in the UK, and political change under
way in both countries); long-standing discussions of climate change (to
which the food habits of some nations contribute) and its likely impacts on
unequal societies; science reports such as the Assessment Reports of the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change suggesting that severe water
shortages are likely in major food-producing parts of the world; and debates
about the nutritional quality of sugar, and processed food.5 Having enough
food, but not of a quality sufficient to meet nutritional standards sufficient
for good health, may be a problem the early moderns would have regarded
as nice to have when the challenge was to find the next meal, yet it can also
be framed as a modern-day form of dearth. In the twenty-first century micro-
nutritional inequality is highlighted by the fact that people continue to
suffer the effects of malnutrition in developing countries alongside a world-
wide obesity epidemic (also a form of malnutrition) in the west. Scientific
evidence suggests that the causes of the obesity problem are unlikely to be
Falstaffian – that is to say, caused by greed. Considering that NHS (National
Health Service) statistics find that the majority of British people have an
unhealthy Body Mass Index, and in 2011/12 a tenth of 4–5 years olds were
obese as they started school, it is more likely that something systemic is at
work. One of the causes named on the NHS (2013) website is as follows:
“There is easy access to cheap, high-energy food that is often aggressively
marketed to people.” Superficially speaking, economics (thus, a social
failure) seems to have something to do with this problem. A 2015 report of
the UK Overseas Development Agency by Wiggins and Keats analysing food
prices between 1990 and 2012 reported that junk food had become signifi-
cantly cheaper while the price of fruit and vegetables had risen significantly.
The effects of this on nutrition are inevitably unequal because of the vari-
ation of shares in family income with wage levels, thereby reminding us of
the rise in prices at the end of the sixteenth century.
In general terms, then, even if definitions of food insecurity vary with
specific geographical and cultural contexts, dearth still appears to be a
190 Julie Hudson
s ufficiently sensitive issue to be present in theatrical performances in
developed countries. Moreover, there are enough modern-day catalysts in
the broader context to magnify potential sensitivities, such as the significant
global economic downturns that occurred in 1973–75, 1980–81, 1990–91,
and 2008–10 (with continuing effects right up to the time of writing), and
the commodity price shocks of 1971–73 and 2005–08. Ingram et al. cite the
Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO): a “rapid
rise in food prices in 2007–8 […] increased the number of hungry people
to 923 million” (2010: 554). Globally speaking, the 2008 credit crunch
exacerbated the problem by constraining incomes available for food, taking
the number of hungry people to over 1 billion world-wide.
Coriolanus
William Shakespeare’s play Coriolanus stands out in the canon as clearly
connecting politics to food, thus it can be seen as a potentially interesting
litmus test of twenty-first century dearth awareness, described above. The
key scene I identified in this play as an informative focal point for modern
attitudes to food security is Act One, Scene One. The riot in the opening
scene is peopled by “mutinous” citizens armed with “staves, clubs and
other weapons”. These “plebians” are protesting against hunger, and its
inequitable distribution between the well-fed patricians and the rest.
The fact that the opening scene in Coriolanus is so core to the play raises key
questions about its modern performance and reception. What modern pro-
ductions do with this scene (whether it is emphasised or excised for
instance) is likely to say something about the cultural positioning of those
involved, in respect of dearth awareness, because productions that de-
emphasise it are removing a deeply embedded part of the overall structure.
After all, a key point about Coriolanus as a dearth play is that food security –
defined as the opposite of dearth – is presented as depending upon the
social order. The achievement of balance between the extremes of dearth
and plenty also depends on an ordered relationship with nature. This also
depends, in turn, upon a balance in the body politic – the opposite of which
is depicted in Coriolanus. In this play, bad governance or stewardship, which
leads to the opposite of stability, is at the root of the dearth suffered by the
plebeians. The play thus thematises broken-down social and natural rela-
tionships and their consequences. In modern parlance, dearth in perform-
ance is ultimately about system (and ecosystem) collapse.
Are we performing dearth? 193
In the following section, I assess this by focusing on the relatively well
documented production history of Coriolanus, studied through evidence
discovered in performance archives and critical reviews.
The 1745 production of Coriolanus by Thompson dispensed with the
first three acts in the name of “neoclassical unity of action” (Ormsby,
2014: 16), thus dismissing food politics to the margin.9 In contrast, in
Brecht’s 1959 post-war adaptation of the play, the opening scene dwells
more on food than on the lead protagonist Caius Martius, with the addi-
tion of a dialogue with The Man with the Child ready to flee the city for
“water, fresh air and a grave”, as well as lines that reinforce the import-
ance of food prices and food power-politics. This weaves in contemporary
socialist politics at the same time (Shakespeare and Brecht, 2014):
First Citizen: Are you prepared to stand fast until the senate agrees it’s
us citizens who decide the price of bread?
Citizens: Yes, yes.
First Citizen: And the price of olives?
Citizens: Yes.
Brecht’s 1953 analysis of the first scene of the play makes it clear that, for
him, this scene is absolutely indispensable to the play, and that the first
scene is in no way a superficial excuse for the battles that follow:
I don’t think you realise how hard it is for the oppressed to become
united. […] Later on this unity of the plebeians will be broken up, so
it is best not to take it for granted at the start but to show it as having
come about.
(Willett, 1957, 1963, 1964: 252)
“Hunger” […] issues solely from the mouths, not the souls and bodies
of the rebellious plebeians. The attire of several citizens plants them
firmly in the ranks of the middle class; […] and dissipates the tension
of acting “in hunger for bread, not in/Thirst for revenge”.
(Bedford, 1992: 31)
Greg Hicks (who played Tullus Aufidius) was interviewed by Bedford and,
in a similar vein, thought that “[…] the director [hadn’t] made an
opinion about what kind of citizens they are” (ibid.: 149–50). This produc-
tion could thus be described as out of tune with the play’s many eco-
systems, both natural and metaphorical.
As the discussion of Black’s response to King Lear, above, suggests, the
Royal Shakespeare Company’s (RSC) 1994 Coriolanus was well-positioned
in terms of its timing to reflect difficult economic conditions in the years
immediately preceding it. By all accounts, this Coriolanus was a memorable
production that put the issue of food security front and centre. So striking
was the opening – in which corn “[poured] like gold from the flies when
the play [opened] and [was] carried off in wooden bowls after the protag-
onist’s banishment” (Nightingale, 1994) – that an employee of the
Stratford-upon-Avon Shakespeare Bookshop responded (in February
2015), to my question about whether the latest edition of the play was in
stock, by spontaneously describing this as a memorable moment in the
most outstanding production he had seen (starring Toby Stephens) no
less than two decades ago. Thacker’s second innovation – to stage the play
in France in the years leading up to the French Revolution, in which food
insecurity brought out by crop failures in the summer of 1788 was one of
the catalysts for social unrest (Neumann and Detwiller, 1990), could
hardly be more in tune with the idea that human society is (and has histor-
ically also been) “performed by” the ecosystems driving food systems.
Nevertheless, this cross-connection between starvation and politics was not
appreciated by several newspaper critics (Coveney, Spencer, Hagerty, and
Peter, 1994) who variously described this transposition as “fatuous”,
“irritating”, “incongruous”, and “quite the wrong setting”. All did not
agree; for Irving Wardle (1994) the point was:
Are we performing dearth? 195
Famine, warfare, plenty: these are the mainsprings of human action,
and they dominate the stage from the opening sight of doors slam-
ming shut on the grain store, to the city gates closing on the blood-
soaked hero.
Questions left hanging in the air by this comment are whether this repres-
entation of the mob weakened the position of the plebeians, thus reinfor-
cing the imbalance of power generally encountered by the poor in the
context of food insecurity; and whether this (human) resource cut hap-
pened to be harsher on the plebeians than the patricians within the
production.
A few years on, there were two productions of Coriolanus in 2007. Both
took place early in the year, a few months before 15 September 2007,
which was the day savers queued round the block to try and get their
money out of Northern Rock, thus dramatically marking the start of the
credit crunch (Rayner, 2008). These productions both took place at a time
when irrational exuberance was still in full swing, increasing the likelihood
of reduced dearth (thus d‘Earth) awareness. Gregory Doran’s March 2007
production came just before the three-and-a-half year, £113 million refur-
bishment of the Royal Shakespeare Theatre (Levy, 2010), and as suggested
above, also happened to coincide with peak of the financial bubble at
work in markets. It “cluttered the stage with a big old-fashioned set” and,
recalling the 1984 production of Coriolanus, featured “woefully clean and
polite plebeians […] dwarfed by the set and unable to make up in energy
of menace what they lack in numbers”. Michael Dobson’s brief description
ironically suggests an emasculated mob in the presence of plentiful pro-
duction resources. In contrast, the Ninagawa Company (Barbican, 25–29
April) made good use of what must (also) have been a good production
budget for design and set and actors, but in a different spirit. The magnifi-
cation of the mob was achieved by a clever visual trick without physically
adding to the numbers involved:
196 Julie Hudson
As the house lights faded this immense, precipitous structure [resem-
bling an oriental ziggurat] was suddenly populated by an entire
brown-clad plebeian riot, twenty strong and doubled and redoubled
again by the side mirrors, converging down the centre of the stairs,
and all shouting at [enormous] volume.
(Dobson, 2007: 345)
The use of baguettes as props was [a] notable feature of this produc-
tion. All cast members brandished the baguettes as weapons while
their constant consumption of the bread reflected not just greed, but
the destruction and emasculation of Coriolanus (the baguette, after
all, can be a phallic symbol).
As the massive hangar sliding-door slid open and the 300-strong sell-
out crowd who’d been huddling outside, buffeted by a Welsh wind
driving straight down the open valley, surged forward, we met our-
selves coming towards us. We were being filmed. We were being
Are we performing dearth? 197
rojected, onto the big screen on the far wall and two smaller
p
screens closer to us.
(Chillington Rutter, 2013: 390)
Fusing the deprived mob and the audience seems all too appropriate in a
place disproportionately hit by the credit crunch because of the structure
of the job market and lower median levels of pay than elsewhere in the UK
(Fitzpatrick et al., 2013: 19).
In the physical Meadow Meanders created by Baz Kershaw, participants
who enter the maze are cryptically informed that the maze contains a puzzle
in the form of an earthly system, invisible from the ground, but potentially
visible to the mind’s eye of those who walk through it (2015: 127). In a
similar vein, the production history of Act One, Scene One of Coriolanus is
often about a collision of aesthetics and economics, but, meandering
through (and reading between the lines of) production archives, I found a
clear pattern. Some productions performed dearth responsively, sensitively,
and collaboratively. In such productions, dearth-awareness can be described
as “ecologically systemic”. When the reverse seems to be the case, this can be
seen as a deeply ironical flouting of the natural order of things, in the
context of Coriolanus in particular. There is a small note of hope in this
chapter. This lies in the fragments of dearth-awareness discerned in some of
the productions discussed above: perhaps human beings sometimes have suf-
ficient insight to stage dearth (or d’Earth) as if human life depends on it.
Notes
1 This chapter draws on an early draft of material in chapter 4 of my Warwick
University PhD (2017), “An Ecotheatrical Perspective on Dearth in Performance”.
2 The collection and interpretation of price data during dearth and famine in
early modern England has a long and complex historiography, which is summa-
rised in Walter and Schofield (1989) and Mukherjee, A. (2015).
3 This chapter does not provide an exhaustive list of dearth plays, and there is
significant scope for further research in this area.
4 Falstaff has most frequently been interpreted in relation to the “grotesque” and
the “festive”, without engaging fully with the context of dearth in which he
appears. Exceptions are: Whitney (1994); Mukherjee, A. (2015: 45–9, 189–91).
Critical debates on Falstaff in relation to festivity and order in Henry IV are use-
fully summarised in Ruiter (2003: 1–39).
5 See, for example: Smith, 2013; Hartocollis, 2015; Trussell Trust, 2017; Miller,
2017; United Nations, Water and Climate Change. On nutritional debates, see,
for example: Lustig, 2012; Hudson and Donovan, 2014: ch. 9.
6 Rio Earth Summit, UN Conference on Environment and Development (1992).
“Resulting document” included the “United Nations Framework Convention on
Climate Change” (UNFCCC). See www.un.org/geninfo/bp/enviro.html.
7 On the environment in general, see, for example, Churchill, 1994: 48: “It was
always possible to think whatever your problem there’s always nature. […] But
it’s not available any more.” In the banquet scene (35), a “hag” looks desperately
for her dismembered body – “head”, “heart”, “arm”, “leg”, “finger” – on the
banquet table.
198 Julie Hudson
8 Of the many literary and historical discussions of this infamous trope, the follow-
ing are especially pertinent to the politics of food: George, 2000; Wilson, 1993;
Patterson, 1991; Sharp, 2007, Hindle, 2008. My analysis focuses on Coriolanus as
a “dearth play”, replayed in contemporary contexts of food insecurity, when per-
formances appropriated, in differing degrees, the rhetorical and political
nuances of Menenius’ fable of the belly.
9 The date of this production coincided with the time (mid-eighteenth century
onwards) when famine and dearth started to become less frequent occurrences
in the history of England, although food shortage remains a significant problem
in British colonies, such as India (Hoskins, 1964; Walter, 1989, and Chapter 1 of
this book; Mukherjee, A., 2015).
Bibliography
Primary sources
Manuscript
Online
Climatological Database for the World’s Oceans, 1750–1850. http://webs.ucm.es/info/
cliwoc/intro.htm.
Famine and Dearth in India and Britain, 1550–1800: Connected Cultural Histories of
Food Security (2016). http://famineanddearth.exeter.ac.uk/index.html.
FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization) (1996). World Food Summits. www.fao.
org/docrep/003/w3613e/w3613e00.htm.
FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization) (2002). World Food Summits. www.fao.
org/worldfoodsummit/english/index.html.
FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization) (2009). Declaration of the World Summit
on Food Security. www.fao.org/fileadmin/templates/wsfs/Summit/Docs/Final_
Declaration/WSFS09_Declaration.pdf.
FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization) (2012). The State of Food Insecurity in the
World. www.fao.org/docrep/016/i3027e/i3027e.pdf.
International Comprehensive Ocean Atmosphere Data Set. http://icoads.noaa.gov.
International Atmospheric Circulation Reconstructions over the Earth. ACRE Initiative.
www.met-acre.org.
IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change) (2013). Assessment Report 5.
www.ipcc.ch/report/wg1/mindex.shtml.
Old Weather. www.oldweather.org.
Rio Earth Summit. UN Conference on Environment and Development (1992).
www.un.org/geninfo/bp/enviro.html.
Trussell Trust (25 April 2017). “UK Foodbank Use Continues to Rise”. www.trus-
selltrust.org.
Twentieth Century Reanalysis. Earth System Research Laboratory. NOAA. www.esrl.
noaa.gov/psd/data/20thC_Rean/#_blank.
United Nations. “Water and Climate Change”. www.unwater.org/water-facts/
climate-change.
Universal Declaration on the Eradication of Hunger and Malnutrition (1974). www.
ohchr.org/en/professionalinterest/pages/eradicationofhungerandmalnutrition.
aspx.
Weather Detective. www.weatherdetective.net.au/about.
Secondary sources
Agamben, Giorgio (1999). Remnants of Auschwitz: The Witness and the Archive. Trans.
D. Heller-Roazen. New York: Zone Books.
Bibliography 207
Agarwal, C. M. (1983, 2006). Natural Calamities and the Great Mughals. New Delhi:
Kanchan Publishers.
Ahuja, Ravi (2004). “State Formation and ‘Famine POLICY’ in Early Colonial South
India”. In Land, Politics and Trade in South India. Ed. Sanjay Subrahmanyam. New
Delhi: Oxford University Press, pp. 147–84.
Alam, M., and Sanjay Subrahmanyam, eds (1998). The Mughal State, 1526–1750.
New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Alamgir, Moiuddin (1980). Famine in South Asia. Political Economy and Mass Starva-
tion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Alfani, Guido, and Cormac Ó Gráda, eds (2017). Famine in European History. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Allan, R. J., C. J. C. Reason, J. A. Lindesay, and T. J. Ansell (2003). “Protracted
ENSO Episodes and Their Impacts in the Indian Ocean Region”. Deep Sea
Research. Part II 2: 2331–47.
Atwell, William (1990). “A Seventeenth Century General Crisis in East Asia”.
Modern Asian Studies 24.4: 661–82.
Atwell, William (2001). “Volcanism and Short-Term Climatic Change in East Asian
and World History, c.1200–1699”. Journal of World History 12: 29–98.
Appadurai, Arjun (1984). “How Moral is South Asia’s Economy? A Review Article”.
The Journal of Asian Studies 43.3: 481–97.
Appleby, A. B. (1978) Famine in Tudor and Stuart England. Liverpool: Liverpool
University Press.
Appleby, A. B. (1979). “Grain Prices and Subsistence Crises in England and France
1590–1740”. Journal of Economic History 39: 865–87.
Archer J. E., R. M. Turley, and H. Thomas (2012). “The Autumn King: Remember-
ing the Land in King Lear”. Shakespeare Quarterly 63.4: 518–46.
Archer J. E., R. M. Turley, and H. Thomas (2014). Food and the Literary Imagination.
Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Arnold, David (1988). Famine: Social Crisis and Historical Change. Oxford: Blackwell.
Arnold, David (1993). “Social Crisis and Epidemic Disease in the Famines of
Nineteenth-century India”. Social History of Medicine 6.3: 385–404.
Arnold, David (2008). “Vagrant India: Famine, Poverty and Welfare under Colonial
Rule”. In Cast Out: Vagrancy and Homelessness in Global and Historical Perspective. Ed.
A. L. Beier and Paul Ocobock. Athens: Ohio University Press, pp. 117–39.
Ascher J., P. Laszlo, and G. Quiviger (2012). “Commodity Trading at a Strategic
Crossroad”. McKinsey Working Papers on Risk 39 (December): 1–14.
ASLE (Association for the Study of Literature and Environment) (1994). Defining
Ecocritical Theory and Practice. www.asle.org/wp-content/uploads/asle_Primer_
DefiningEcocrit.pdf.
Balabanlilar, Lisa (2012). Imperial Identity in the Mughal Empire: Memory and Dynastic
Politics in Early Modern South and Central Asia. New York: I. B. Tauris.
Bateson, G. (1972, 2000). Steps to an Ecology of Mind. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Baxendale, J. and C. Pawling (1996). Narrating the Thirties: A Decade in the Making,
1930 to the Present. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Bayly, C. (1993). Rulers, Townsmen and Bazars: North Indian Society in the Age of
Expansion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
BBC News (2007). “Mexicans Stage Tortilla Protest”. 1 February. http://news.bbc.
co.uk/1/hi/6319093.stm.
208 Bibliography
Bedford, K. (1992). Coriolanus at the National: “Th’Interpretation of the Time”. Selins-
grove: Susquehanna University Press.
Beier, A. L. and Paul Ocobock, eds (2008). Cast Out: Vagrancy and Homelessness in
Global and Historical Perspective. Athens: Ohio University Press.
Beinart, William and Lotte Hughes (2007). “Irrigation in India and Egypt”. In
Environment and Empire. Oxford History of the British Empire Companion
Series. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 130–47.
Beloff, Max (1963). Public Order and Popular Disturbances 1660–1714. London:
Oxford University Press.
Benjamin, Walter (2006). “The Concept of History”. In Selected Writings. Ed.
Howard Eiland and Michael Jennings. Vol. 4. New York: Harvard University
Press, pp. 389–400.
Bennett, J. (2010). Vibrant Matter: A Political Ecology of Things. Durham and
London: Duke University Press.
Bhattacharya, S. (1982). “Eastern India”. In The Cambridge Economic History of India.
Ed. Dharma Kumar. Vol. 2, c.1757–c.1970. New Delhi: Cambridge University
Press, pp. 279–80.
Bhushi, Kiranmayi, ed. (2018). Farm to Fingers: The Culture and Politics of Food in
Contemporary India. New Delhi: Cambridge University Press.
Black, R. W. (1994). “What We Talk about When We Talk about Ecocriticism”.
Defining Ecocritical Theory and Practice. Electronic Publication: ASLE. www.asle.
org/wp-content/uploads/asle_Primer_DefiningEcocrit.pdf.
Boltanski, Luc (1999). Distant Suffering: Morality, Media and Politics. Trans. Graham
D. Burchell. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bose, Sugata (1986). Agrarian Bengal: Economy, Social Structure, and Politics,
1919–1947. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bose, Sugata (1990). “Starvation amidst Plenty: The Making of Famine in Bengal,
Honan and Tonkin, 1942–45”. Modern Asian Studies 24.4: 699–727.
Boshstedt, John (2010). The Politics of Provisions: Food Riots, Moral Economy, and
Market Transition in England, c.1550–1850. Farnham: Ashgate.
Brassley, P. (2005). “The Professionalisation of English Agriculture”. Rural History
16: 235–51.
Brassley, P., Y. Segers, and L. Van Molle, eds (2012). War, Agriculture and Food:
Rural Europe from the 1930s to the 1950s. London: Routledge.
Brewis, Georgina (2010). “ ‘Fill Full the Mouth of Famine’: Voluntary Action in
Famine Relief in India 1896–1901”. Modern Asian Studies 44.4: 887–918.
Brookfield, H. and H. Parsons (2007). Family Farms: Survival and Prospect. London:
Routledge.
Buckingham, Jane (2002). Leprosy in Colonial South India: Medicine and Confinement.
Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Buckley, B. M., R. Fletcher, S.-Y. S. Wang, B. Zottoli, and C. Pottier (2014).
“Monsoon Extremes and Society over the Past Millenium on Mainland South-
east Asia”. Quaternary Science Review 95: 1–19.
Buerk, M. (1984). Report on the Ethiopian Famine. BBC News, 23 October 1984.
YouTube recording.
Camporesi, Piero (1989). Bread of Dreams: Food and Fantasy in Early Modern Europe.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Camporesi, Piero (1996). The Land of Hunger. Trans. Tania Croft-Murray and
Claire Foley. Oxford: Polity Press.
Bibliography 209
Cannadine, D. (1990). The Decline and Fall of the British Aristocracy. New York and
London: Yale University Press.
Chambers, E. K. (1930) William Shakespeare. A Study of Facts and Problems. Vol. II.
Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Chatterjee, Partha (1984). Bengal 1920–1947: The Land Question. Calcutta: K. P.
Bagchi and Company.
Chatterji, Joya (1995). Bengal Divided: Hindi Communalism and Partition 1932–1947.
New Delhi: Cambridge University Press.
Chaudhuri, Pramit (1984). “Review of Prosperity and Misery in Modern Bengal: The
Famine of 1943–1944 by Paul R. Greenough”. Third World Quarterly 6.2: 529–30.
Chaudhuri, Supriya (2011). “Hunger: Some Representations of the 1943 Bengal
Famine”. In The Writer’s Feast: Food and the Cultures of Representation. Ed. R. B.
Chatterjee and S. Chaudhuri. Delhi: Orient Blackswan.
Chaudhuri, Supriya (2014). “Moral Economies of Well-Being”. In Shrapnel Minima:
Writings from Humanities Underground. Ed. Prasanta Chakravarty. Calcutta:
Seagull, pp. 107–18.
Chillington Rutter, C. (2013) “Shakespeare Performances in England (and Wales)
2012”. Shakespeare Survey 66: 354–94.
Clark, Peter (1976). “Popular Protest and Disturbance in Kent, 1558–1640”. Eco-
nomic History Review 29: 365–82.
Clingingsmith, David and Jeffery G. Williamson (2005). “Mughal Decline and
Climate Change, and Britain’s Industrial Ascent: An Integrated Perspective on
India’s 18th and 19th Century Deindustrialization”. Working Paper 11730. www.
nber.org/papers/w11730.
Clingingsmith, David and Jeffery G. Williamson (2008). “Deindustrialization in
18th and 19th Century India: Mughal Decline, Climate Shocks and British Indus-
trial Ascent”. Explorations in Economic History 45.3: 209–34.
Collet, Dominik and Daniel Krämer (2017). “Germany, Switzerland and Austria”.
In Famine in European History. Ed. Guido Alfani and Cormac Ó Gráda. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 101–18.
Collingham, L. (2011). The Taste of War: World War Two and the Battle for Food.
London: Allen Lane.
Conford, P. (2001). The Origins of the Organic Movement. Edinburgh: Floris Books.
Cotts Watkins, Susan and Jane Menken (1985). “Famines in Historical Per-
spective”. Population and Development Review 11.4: 647–75.
Coveney, M. (1994). “Coriolanus Review”. The Observer. 29 May.
Cox, G., P. Lowe, and M. Winter (1986). “From State Direction to Self Regulation:
The Historical Development of Corporatism in British Agriculture”. Policy and
Politics 14.4: 475–90.
Cox, G., P. Lowe, and M. Winter (1991). “The Origins and Early Development of
the National Farmers’ Union”. Agricultural History Review 39.1: 30–47.
Crawford, E. Margaret (1989). Famine: The Irish Experience 900–1900. Subsistence
Crises and Famines in Ireland. Edinburgh: John Donald.
Cullen, Karen J. (2010) Famine in Scotland: The “Ill Years” of the 1690s. Edinburgh:
Edinburgh University Press.
Dale, Stephen (2010). The Muslim Empires of the Ottomans, Safavids, and Mughals.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dalyell, T. (1998). “Obituary: Lord Donaldson of Kingsbridge”. The Independent. 10
March.
210 Bibliography
Damodaran, Vinita (1998). “Famine in a Forest Tract: Ecological Change and the
Causes of the 1897 Famine in Chota Nagpur, Northern India”. In Nature and the
Orient: The Environmental History of South and Southeast Asia. Ed. Richard H.
Grove, Vinita Damodaran, and Satpal Sangwan. New Delhi: Oxford University
Press, pp. 853–90.
Damodaran, Vinita (2007). “Famine in Bengal: A Comparison of the 1770 Famine
in Bengal and the 1897 Famine in Chotanagpur”. The Medieval History Journal
10.1–2: 143–81.
Damodaran, Vinita, Rob Allan, and James Hamilton (2015). “Climate Signals,
Environment and Livelihoods in Seventeenth Century India in a Comparative
Context”. Unpublished paper. Food Security and the Environment in India and
Britain Workshop. http://foodsecurity.exeter.ac.uk/wp-content/uploads/2015/09/
17th-century.pdf.
Das, Suranjan (1991). Communal Riots in Bengal: 1905–1947. New Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
Das, Suranjan (1995). “Nationalism and Popular Consciousness: Bengal 1942”.
Social Scientist 23.4/6: 58–68.
Dasgupta, Chittaranjan (2000). Bharater Shilpa Samskritir Patabhumikaye Bishnupurer
Mandir Terracotta. Bishnupur: Sushama Dasgupta.
Datta, Rajat (1986). “Merchants and Peasants: A Study in the Structure of Local
Trade in Grain in late Eighteenth Century Bengal”. Indian Economic and Social
History Review 23.4. Reprinted in Merchants, Markets and State in Early Modern
India. Ed. Sanjay Subrahmanyam. New Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1990.
Datta, Rajat (1996). “Crises and Survival: Ecology, Subsistence and Coping in
Eighteenth Century Bengal”. The Calcutta Historical Journal 17.1: 1–34.
Datta, Rajat (2000). Society, Economy and the Market. Commercialization in Rural
Bengal, ca. 1760–1800. New Delhi: Manohar Publications.
Datta, Rajat (2014). “The Rural–Urban Continuum and the Making of a Proto-
Industrial Economy in Early Modern India: A View from the East”. In Cities in
Medieval India. Ed. Pius Malekandathil and Yogesh Sharma. New Delhi: Primus.
Datta, Rajat (2015). “Towards an Economic History of Rural Households in Early
Modern India: Some Evidence from Bengal in the Eighteenth Century”. In
Looking Within, Looking Without: Exploring Households in the Subcontinent Through
Time. Essays in Memory of Nandita Prasad Sahai. Ed. Kumkum Roy. New Delhi:
Primus.
Davis, Mike (2002). Late Victorian Holocausts: El Niño, Famines, and the Making of the
Third World. London and New York: Verso.
De-la-Noy, M. (2004). “Frances Donaldson”. Oxford Dictionary of National Biography.
Djurfeldt, G. (1996). “Defining and Operationalizing Family Farming from a Soci-
ological Perspective”. Sociologia Ruralis 36.3: 340–51.
Dobson, M. (2004). “Shakespeare Performances in England, 2003”. Shakespeare
Survey 57: 258–89.
Dobson, M. (2007). “Shakespeare Performances in England, 2007”. Shakespeare
Survey 60: 318–50.
Drake, Michael (1968). “The Irish Demographic Crisis of 1740–1”. Historical Studies
6: 101–24.
Drew, W. (2012). “Review, The Serpent’s Tooth, Shoreditch Town Hall”. 7–12 Novem-
ber. Exeunt Magazine. OWE and Fringe. www.exeuntmagazine.com/reviews/
the-serpents-tooth.
Bibliography 211
Driver, Felix (1993). Power and Pauperism: The Workhouse System, 1834–1884. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dyer, Christopher (1998). “Did the Peasant Really Starve in Medieval England?”.
In Food and Eating in Medieval Europe. Ed. Martha Carlin and Joel T. Rosenthal.
London and Rio Grande: Hambledon, pp. 53–71.
Dyer, Christopher, ed. (2007). The Self-Contained Village? The Social History of Rural
Communities, 1250–1900. Hertford: University of Hertfordshire Press.
Eaton, Richard (1993). The Rise of Islam and the Bengal Frontier, 1204–1760.
Berkeley: University of California Press.
Edkins, Jenny (2000). Whose Hunger? Concepts of Famine, Practices of Aid. Minneapolis:
University of Minnesota Press.
Edwards, S. M. and H. M. O. Garrett (1974). Mughal Rule in India. London: S.
Chand.
Englander, David (2013). Poverty and Poor Law Reform in Nineteenth-Century Britain,
1834–1914: From Chadwick to Booth. London: Routledge.
Farson, D. (1986). Henry Williamson: A Portrait. London: Robinson.
Federowicz, J. K. (1980). England’s Baltic Trade in the Early Seventeenth Century: A Study
in Anglo-Polish Commercial Diplomacy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Fitter, Chris (2000). “ ‘The Quarrel is between Our Masters and Us Their Men’:
‘Romeo and Juliet’, Dearth, and the London Riots”. English Literary Renaissance
30.2: 154–83.
Fitzpatrick, S., H. Pawson, G. Bramley, and S. Wilcox, with B. Watts (2013). The
Homelessness Monitor: Wales 2012. Institute for Housing, Urban and Real Estate
Research, Heriot-Watt University and Centre for Housing Policy, University
of York.
Flinn, M. W., ed. (1977). Scottish Population History from the 17th Century to the 1930s.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Friedmann, H. (1978). “World Market, State, and Family Farm: Social Bases of
Household Production in the Era of Wage Labor”. Comparative Studies in Society
and History 20.4: 545–86.
Frohman, Larry (2008). Poor Relief and Welfare in Germany from the Reformation to
World War I. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Foucault, Michel (1965). Madness and Civilization: A History of Insanity in the Age of
Reason. New York: Vintage Books.
Fumerton, Patricia (2003, 2004). “Making Vagrancy (In)Visible: The Economics of
Disguise in Early Modern Rogue Pamphlets”. English Literary Renaissance 33.2:
211–27. Reprinted in Rogues and Early Modern Literary Culture: A Critical
Anthology. Ed. Craig Dionne and Steve Mentz. Michigan: University of Michigan
Press, pp. 193–210.
Fumerton, Patricia (2006). Unsettled: The Culture of Mobility and the Working Poor in
Early Modern England. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Gagnier, Regenia (2000a). “The Law of Progress and the Ironies of Individualism
in the Nineteenth Century”. New Literary History 31.2: 315–36.
Gagnier, Regenia (2000b). The Insatiability of Human Wants: Economic and Aesthetics
in Market Society. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.
Gander, A. (2001). Adrian Bell: Voice of the Countryside. Wenhaston: Holm Oak
Publishing.
George, David (2000). “Plutarch, Insurrection and Dearth in Coriolanus”. Shake-
speare Survey 53: 60–72.
212 Bibliography
Gergis, J. L. and A. M. Fowler (2009). “A History of ENSO Events since 1525:
Implications for Future Climate Change”. Climate Change 92: 343–87.
Ghose, Ajit Kumar (1982). “Food Supply and Starvation. A Study of Famines with
Reference to the Indian Sub-Continent”. Oxford Economic Papers (New Series)
34.2: 368–89.
Gole, Susan (1989). Indian Maps and Plans from Earliest Times to the Advent of Euro-
pean Surveys. New Delhi: Manohar.
Gommans, Jos (2002). Mughal Warfare: Indian Frontiers and Highroads to Empire,
1500–1700. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Gordon, Stuart (1993). The Marathas: 1600–1818. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
Greenblatt, Stephen (1980). Renaissance Self-fashioning: From More to Shakespeare.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Greenblatt, Stephen (2004). Will in the World: How Shakespeare Became Shakespeare.
London: Jonathan Cape.
Greenough, Paul (1980). “Indian Famines and Peasant Victims: The Case of
Bengal in 1943–44”. Modern Asian Studies 14.2: 205–35.
Greenough, Paul (1982). Prosperity and Misery in Modern Bengal: The Famine of
1943–44. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Greenough, Paul (1983). “Indulgence and Abundance as Asian Peasant Values: A
Bengali Case in Point”. Journal of Asian Studies 42.4: 831–50.
Griffiths, C. (2010). “Socialism and the Land Question: Public Ownership and
Control in Labour Party Policy, 1918–1950s”. In The Land Question in Britain,
1750–1950. Ed. M. Cragoe and P. Readman. Basingstoke: Palgrave, pp. 237–56.
Grigg, D. (1989). English Agriculture: An Historical Perspective. Oxford: Blackwell.
Gronke, M. (1992). “The Persian Court between Palace and Tent: From Timur to
‘Abbas I”. In Timurid Art and Culture: Iran and Central Asia in the Fifteenth Century.
Ed. L. Golombek and M. Subtelny. Leiden: Brill, pp. 18–22.
Grove, Richard H. (1994). Green Imperialism: Colonial Expansion, Tropical Island
Edens, and the Origins of Environmentalism, 1600–1860. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Grove, Richard H. (1998). “Global Impact of the 1789–93 El Niño”. Nature 393:
318–19.
Grove, Richard H. (2002). “El Niño Chronology and the History of Socio-
Economic and Agrarian Crisis in South and Southeast Asia, 1250–1900”. In Land
Use – Historical Perspectives: Focus on Indo-Gangetic Plains. Ed. Y. P. Abrol, S.
Sangwan, and M. K. Tiwari. New Delhi: Allied Publishers.
Grove, Richard H. and John Chapell (2000). El Niño: History and Crisis. Winwick:
White Horse Press.
Habib, I. (1963, 1999). The Agrarian System of Mughal India. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Habib, I. (1990). “Merchant Communities in Pre-Colonial India”. In The Rise of
Merchant Empires: Long Distance Trade in the Early Modern World. Ed. James D.
Tracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 371–99.
Habib, I. (1996). “Notes on the Economic and Social Aspects of Mughal Gardens”.
In Mughal Gardens: Sources, Places, Representations, and Prospects. Ed. James L.
Wescoat and Joachim Wolschke-Bulmahn. Washington, D.C.: Dumbarton Oaks.
Hagerty, B. (1994). “Coriolanus Review”. Today, 10 June.
Bibliography 213
Hall-Matthews, David (1996). “Historical Roots of Famine Relief Paradigms: Ideas
on Dependency and Free Trade in India in the 1870s”. Disasters 20.3: 216–30.
Harrison, C. J. (1971). “Grain Price Analysis and Harvest Qualities, 1465–1634”.
Agricultural History Review 19: 135–55.
Hartocollis, Anemona (2015). “Greece Financial Crisis Hits Poorest and Hungriest
the Hardest”. New York Times, 11 July.
Haskell, Thomas L. (1985, 1992). “Capitalism and the Origins of the Human-
itarian Sensibility”. 2 parts: American Historical Review 90 (April 1985): 339–61;
(June 1985): 547–66. Reprinted in The Anti-Slavery Debate: Capitalism and
Abolitionism as a Problem in Historical Interpretation. Ed. Thomas Bender. Berkeley:
University of California Press.
Heal, Felicity (1990). Hospitality in Early Modern England. Oxford: Oxford Univer-
sity Press.
Heal, Felicity and Clive Holmes (1994). The Gentry in England and Wales 1500–1700.
Basingstoke and London: Palgrave.
Healey, Jonathan (2011). “Land, Population, and Family in the English Uplands: A
Westmorland Case Study, c.1370–c.1650”. Agricultural History Review 59: 151–75.
Healey, Jonathan (2014). The First Century of Welfare: Poverty and Poor Relief in Lan-
cashire, 1620–1730. Woodbridge: The Boydell Press.
Higginbottom, M. D. (1992). Intellectuals and British Fascism: A Study of Henry Wil-
liamson. London: Janus.
Hindle, Steve (2001). “Dearth, Fasting and Alms: The Campaign for General Hos-
pitality”. Past & Present 172: 44–86.
Hindle, Steve (2004). On the Parish? The Micro-Politics of Poor Relief in Rural England
c.1550–1750. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hindle, Steve (2008). “Dearth and the English Revolution: The Harvest Crisis of
1647–50”. Economic History Review 61: 64–98.
Hipkin, Stephen (2008). “The Structure, Development, and Politics of the Kent
Grain Trade, 1552–1647”. Economic History Review 61: 99–139.
Hobsbawm, E. J. (1954). “The General Crisis of the European Economy in the
17th Century”. Past & Present 5.1: 33–53.
Holderness, B. A. (1985). British Agriculture since 1945. Manchester: Manchester
University Press.
Hoskins, W. G. (1964). “Harvest Fluctuations and English Economic History,
1480–1609”. Agricultural History Review 12: 28–46.
Hoskins, W. G. (1968). “Harvest Fluctuations and English Economic History,
1620–1759”. Agricultural History Review 16: 15–31.
Hoyle, R. W. (2010). “Famine as Agricultural Catastrophe: The Crisis of 1623–4 in
East Lancashire”. Economic History Review 63: 974–1002.
Hudson, Julie (2017). The Environment on Stage: Scenery or Shapeshifter? PhD Thesis,
University of Warwick.
Hudson, Julie and Paul Donovan (2014). Food Policy and the Environmental Credit
Crunch: From Soup to Nuts. London: Routledge.
Hutson, Lorna (1987). Thomas Nashe in Context. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Ingram, J., P. Ericksen, and D. Liverman (2010). Food Security and Global Environ-
mental Change. London and Washington: Earthscan.
Islam, M. M. (2007). “The Great Bengal Famine and the Question of FAD Yet
Again”. Modern Asian Studies 41.2: 421–40.
214 Bibliography
Israel, J. (1974). “Mexico and the General Crisis of the Seventeenth Century”. Past
& Present 63: 33–57.
Jefferies, M. and M. Tyldesley, eds (2011). Rolf Gardiner: Folk, Nature and Culture in
Interwar Britain. Farnham: Ashgate.
Jones, P. (2007). “Swing, Speenhamland and Rural Social Relations”. Social History
32.3: 271–90.
Kates, Robert W. and Sara Millman (1995). “On Ending Hunger: The Lessons of
History”. In Hunger in History: Food Shortage, Poverty, and Deprivation. Ed. Lucile
F. Newman. Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 389–407.
Kaviraj, Sudipta. (2000). “Laughter and Subjectivity: The Self-Ironical Tradition in
Bengali Literature”. Modern Asian Studies 34.2: 379–406.
Kelly, Morgan and Cormac Ó Gráda (2014). “Living Standards and Mortality since
the Middle Ages”. Economic History Review 67: 358–81.
Kershaw, B. (2015). “Performed by Ecologies: How Homo Sapiens Could Subvert
Present-day Futures”. Performing Ethos 4.2: 113–34.
Khare, R. S., ed. (1993). The Eternal Food: Gastronomic Ideas and Experiences of
Hindus and Buddhists. Delhi: Sri Satguru Publications.
Kinney, A. F. (1993). “Textual Signs in The Merry Wives of Windsor”. Yearbook of
English Studies, Early Shakespeare Special, 23: 206–34.
Klein, Bernhard (2001). Maps and the Writing of Space in Early Modern England and
Ireland. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Kolff, D. (1990). Naukar, Rajput, and Sepoy: The Ethnohistory of the Military Labour
Market in Hindustan, 1450–1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Kothiyal, Tanuja (2016). Nomadic Narratives: A History of Mobility and Identity in the
Great Indian Desert. New Delhi: Cambridge University Press.
Kussmaul, Ann (1981). Servants in Husbandry in Early Modern England. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Kussmaul, Ann (1985). “Time and Space, Hoofs and Grain: The Seasonality of
Marriage in England”. The Journal of Interdisciplinary History 15.4: 755–79.
Lal, Ruby (2005). Domesticity and Power in the Early Mughal World. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Lamb, H. H. (1977). Climate: Present, Past and Future. Climatic History and the Future.
Vol. 2. London and New York: Methuen.
Langelüddecke, Henrik (1998). “ ‘Patchy and Spasmodic’? The Response of the
Justices of the Peace to Charles I’s Book of Orders”. English Historical Review 113:
1231–48.
Laqueur, Thomas W. (1989). “Bodies, Details, and the Humanitarian Narrative”. In
The New Cultural History. Ed. Lynn Hunt. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Laslett, Peter (1965). The World We Have Lost. London: Methuen.
Lawson, P. G. (1986). “Property Crime and Hard Times in England, 1559–1624”.
Law and History Review 4: 95–127.
Le Roy Ladurie, Emmanuel (1971). Times of Feast, Times of Famine: A History of
Climate since the Year 1000. New York: Doubleday.
Lee, A. (2013). “Coriolanus, Directed by Motoi Miura for the Chiten Theatre
Company (Kyoto, Japan) at Shakespeare’s Globe”. In A Year of Shakespeare. Ed.
Paul Edmondson, Paul Prescott, and Erin Sullivan. London: Bloomsbury, Arden,
pp. 47–50.
Lee, Joo-Yup (2015). Qazaqlïq, or Ambitious Brigandage and the Formation of the
Qazaqs: State and Identity in Post-Mongol Central Eurasia. Leiden: Brill.
Bibliography 215
Lefèbvre, Henri (1974, 1991). The Production of Space. Trans. Donald Nicholson-
Smith. Oxford: Wiley-Blackwell.
Lentz, Thomas W. (1996). “Memory and Ideology in the Timurid Garden”. In
Mughal Gardens: Sources, Places, Representations, and Prospects. Ed. James L.
Wescoat and Joachim Wolschke-Bulmahn. Washington, D.C.: Dumbarton Oaks.
Leonard, E. M. (1900). The Early History of English Poor Relief. Cambridge University
Press.
Levy, P. (2010). “Age Shall Not Wither Her”. The Wall Street Journal, 26 November.
Lovelock, J. (2006). The Revenge of Gaia. London and New York: Allen Lane.
Lucas, A. T. (1959). “Nettles and Charlock as Famine Foods”. Breifne 1: 137–46.
Lustig, Robert (2012). Fat Chance: The Hidden Truth about Sugar, Obesity and Disease.
London: The Fourth Estate.
Mann, Michael (2015). South Asia’s Modern History: Thematic Perspectives. New Delhi:
Routledge.
Marks, Robert V. (1998). Tigers, Rice, Silk, and Silt: Environment and Economy in Late
Imperial South China. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Marshall, P. J. (1977). East Indian Fortunes: The English in Bengal in the Eighteenth
Century. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Marshall, P. J. (1982). The Great Map of Mankind. London: Harvard University Press.
Martin, J. (2000). The Development of Modern Agriculture: British Farming since 1931.
Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Marvin, Julia (1998). “Cannibalism as an Aspect of Famine in Two English Chron-
icles”. In Food and Eating in Medieval Europe. Ed. Martha Carlin and Joel T.
Rosenthal. London and Rio Grande: The Hambledon Press, pp. 73–86.
McIntosh, Marjorie J. (2014). “Poor Relief in Elizabethan English Communities:
An Analysis of Collectors’ Accounts”. Economic History Review 67: 331–57.
McKendrick, Neil, J. Brewer, and J. H. Plumb (1982). The Birth of a Consumer
Society: The Commercialization of Eighteenth-Century England. Bloomington: Indiana
University Press.
McNeill, John (2003). “Observations on the Nature and Culture of Environmental
History”. History and Theory 42: 5–43.
McRae, Andrew (1996). God Speed the Plough: The Representation of Agrarian England,
1500–1660. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
McRae, Andrew (2009). Literature and Domestic Travel in Early Modern England.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
McRae, Andrew (2015). “Early Modern Chorographies”. Oxford Handbooks Online.
Oxford University Press. www.oxfordhandbooks.com/view/10.1093/oxfordhb/978
0199935338.001.0001/oxfordhb-9780199935338-e-102.
Melchiori, G. (2000). “Introduction”. The Merry Wives of Windsor. London:
Bloomsbury, Arden, pp. 18–30.
Meuvret, J. (1988). “Food Crises and Demography in France in the Ancien
Regime”. In French Studies in History, Vol. 1: The Inheritance. Ed. Harbans Mukhia
and M. Aymard. New Delhi: Orient Longman.
Miller, Sarah G. (2017). “Climate Change is Transforming the World’s Food
Supply”. Live Science, 16 February.
Moore-Colyer, R. J. (2001a). “Rolf Gardiner, English Patriot and the Council for
the Church and Countryside”. Agricultural History Review 49: 187–209.
Moore-Colyer, R. J. (2001b). “Back to Basics: Rolf Gardiner, H J Massingham and
‘A Kinship in Husbandry’ ”. Rural History 12.1: 85–108.
216 Bibliography
Moore-Colyer, R. J. (2002). “A Voice Clamouring in the Wilderness: H J Massing-
ham (1888–1952) and Rural England”. Rural History 13: 199–224.
Moore-Colyer, R. J. (2004). “Towards ‘Mother Earth’: Jorian Jenks, Organicism, the
Right and the British Union of Fascists”. Journal of Contemporary History 39: 353–71.
Moore-Colyer, R. J. and P. Conford (2004). “A ‘Secret Society’? The Internal and
External Relations of the Kinship in Husbandry, 1941–52”. Rural History 15.2:
189–206.
Moosvi, Shireen (1987, 2015). The Economy of the Mughal Empire, c.1595: A Statistical
Study. Oxford and New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Moosvi, Shireen (2008). People, Taxation, and Trade in Mughal India. New Delhi:
Oxford University Press.
Moran, W., G. Blunden, and J. Greenwood (1993). “The Role of Family Farming
in Agrarian Change”. Progress in Human Geography 17.1: 22–42.
Muir, Cameron (2014). The Broken Promise of Agricultural Progress: An Environmental
History. London and New York: Routledge.
Mukerjee, Madhusree (2010). Churchill’s Secret War: The British Empire and the Rav-
aging of India During World War II. New York: Basic Books.
Mukherjee, Ayesha (2015). Penury into Plenty: Dearth and the Making of Knowledge in
Early Modern England. London and New York: Routledge.
Mukherjee, Janam (2015). Hungry Bengal: War, Famine and the End of Empire.
London: Hurst & Company.
Mukherjee, R. K. (1938). The Changing Face of Bengal. A Study of its Riverine Economy.
Calcutta: University of Calcutta Press.
Mukherjee, Tilottama (2013). Political Culture and Economy in Eighteenth-Century
Bengal. Networks, Exchange and Communication. New Delhi: Orient Blackswan.
Mukherjee, Upamanyu Pablo (2013). Natural Disasters and Victorian Empire:
Famines, Fevers and Literary Cultures of South Asia. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Murdoch, J. and N. Ward (1997). “Governmentality and Territoriality: The Statisti-
cal Manufacture of Britain’s ‘National Farm’ ”. Political Geography 16.4: 307–24.
Neukom, R., H. Wanner, J. Elbert, C. C. Raible, D. Frank, J. Gergis, D. J. Karoly, M.
Curran, A. D. Moy, T. Van Ommen, M. Curran, T. Vance, F. Gonzalez-Rouco, B.
K. Linsley, I. Mundo, R. Villalba, E. J. Steig, and J. Zinke (2014). “Inter-
Hemispheric Temperature Variability over the Past Millennium”. Nature Climate
Change 4: 362–7.
Neumann, J. and J. Detwiller (1990). “Great Historical Events that were Signifi-
cantly Affected by the Weather: Part 9, the Year Leading to the Revolution of
1789 in France (II)”. Bulletin of the American Meteorological Society 71.1: 33–41.
Newman, Lucile F., ed. (1995). Hunger in History: Food Shortage, Poverty, and Depri-
vation. Oxford: Blackwell.
NHS (National Health Service) (2013). “Latest Obesity Stats for England
Are Alarming”. 2 February. www.nhs.uk/news/2013/02February/Pages/Latest-
obesity-stats-for-England-are-alarming-reading.aspx.
Nielsen, Randall (1997). “Storage and English Government Intervention in Early
Modern Grain Markets”. Journal of Economic History 57: 1–33.
Nightingale, B. (1994). “Coriolanus Review”. The Times. 26 May.
Ó Gráda, Cormac (2005). “Markets and Famines in Pre-Industrial Europe”. Journal
of Interdisciplinary History 36.2: 143–66.
Ó Gráda, Cormac (2007). “Making Famine History”. Journal of Economic Literature
45.1: 5–38.
Bibliography 217
Ó Gráda, Cormac (2009). Famine: A Short History. Princeton: Princeton University
Press.
Ó Gráda, Cormac (2011). “Famines Past, Famine’s Future”. Development and
Change 42.1: 49–69.
Ó Gráda, Cormac (2015). “Neither Feast nor Famine: England before the Indus-
trial Revolution”. In Institutions, Innovation and Industrialization: Essays in Eco-
nomic History and Development. Ed. Avner Greif, Lynne Kiesling, and John V. C.
Nye. Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 7–31.
Ormsby, R. (2014). Shakespeare in Performance: Coriolanus. Manchester: Manchester
University Press.
Ortlieb, L. (1998). “Historical Reconstructions of ENSO Events from Documentary
Sources from Chile, Peru, Brasil, and Mexico: Evidence for Variability of the Tel-
econnection Regime in the Last Centuries”. In Abstracts of the Pole-Equator-Pole
Conference on the Paleo-climate of the Americas. Convenor V. Markgraf, University of
Colorado. Merida, Venezuela.
Outhwaite, R. B. (1991). Dearth, Public Policy and Social Disturbance in England,
1550–1800. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Parker, Geoffrey (2013). Global Crisis, War, Climate Change and Catastrophe in the
Seventeenth Century. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Parker, G. and L. M. Smith, eds (1978, 1985, 1997). The General Crisis of the Seven-
teenth Century. London: Routledge.
Patterson, Annabel (1991). Fables of Power: Aesopian Writing and Political History.
Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
Pemberton, Rita (2013). “Workhouse Medicine in the British Caribbean,
1834–38”. In Medicine and the Workhouse. Ed. Jonathan Reinarz and Leonard
Schwarz. Rochester and Suffolk: University of Rochester Press.
Perry, P. J., ed. (1973). British Agriculture 1875–1914. London: Methuen.
Peter, J. (1994). “Coriolanus Review”. Sunday Times. 29 May.
Pritchard, R. E. (2011). Peter Mundy, Merchant Adventurer. Oxford: Bodleian
Library.
Quinn, W. H. (1992) “A Study of Southern Oscillation-related Climatic Activity for
A.D. 622–1900 Incorporating Nile River Flood Data”. In El Niño: Historical and
Paleoclimate Aspects of the Southern Oscillation. Ed. H. E. Diaz and V. Markgraf.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 119–49.
Quinn, W. H., V. T. Neal, and S. E. Antunez De Mayolo (1987). “El Niño Occur-
rences over the Past Four and a Half Centuries”. Journal of Geophysical Research 92
(C13): 14449–61.
Raj, K. N, N. Bhattacharya, S. Guha, and S. Padhi, eds (1985). Essays on the Commer-
cialization of Indian Agriculture. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Ramachandran, V. K. (1998). “Documenting Society and Politics”. Frontline. Sep-
tember.
Ray, A. and M. Kuzhippalli Skaria (2002). Studies in the History of the Deccan. New
Delhi: Pragati.
Rayner, G. (2008). “Credit Crunch Time Line: From Northern Rock to Lehman
Brothers”. Telegraph. 15 September.
Reid, Anthony (1990). “The Crisis of the Seventeenth Century in Southeast Asia”.
Modern Asian Studies 24.4: 639–59.
Reinarz, Jonathan and Leonard Schwarz, eds (2013). Medicine and the Workhouse.
Rochester and Suffolk: University of Rochester Press.
218 Bibliography
Richards, John (1990). “The Seventeenth Century Crisis in South Asia”. Modern
Asian Studies 24.1: 625–38.
Riley, M. and D. Harvey (2007). “Oral Histories, Farm Practice and Uncovering
Meaning in the Countryside”. Social and Cultural Geography 8: 391–415.
Robb, Peter (2007). Peasants, Political Economy, and Law. New Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
Rotberg, Robert I. and Theodore Rabb, eds (1985). Hunger and History: The Impact
of Changing Food Production and Consumption Patterns on Society. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Roychowdhury, Binata (1993). Ponchasher Monnontor O Bangla Sahitya. Kolkata:
Sahityalok.
Rudé, G. (1964). The Crowd in History: A Study of Popular Disturbances in France and
England 1730–1848. New York: Wiley.
Ruiter, David (2003). Shakespeare’s Festive History: Feasting, Festivity, Fasting, and Lent
in the Second Henriad. Farnham: Ashgate.
Sayce, R. V. (1953/54). “Need Years and Need Foods”. The Montgomeryshire Collec-
tions 53: 55–80.
Scholl, Lesa (2011). Translation, Authorship and the Victorian Professional Woman:
Charlotte Brontë, Harriet Martineau and George Eliot. Farnham: Ashgate.
Scholl, Lesa (2016). Hunger Movements in Early Victorian Literature: Want, Riots,
Migration. London: Routledge.
Schwyzer, Philip (2009). “John Leland and His Heirs: The Topography of
England”. In The Oxford Handbook of Tudor Literature. Ed. M. Pincombe and C.
Shrank. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 238–53.
Scott, James (1976). The Moral Economy of the Asian Peasant. New Haven: Yale
University Press.
Sen, Amartya (1981a). Poverty and Famines: An Essay on Entitlement and Deprivation.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Sen, Amartya (1981b). “Ingredients of Famine Analysis: Availability and Entitle-
ments”. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 96.3: 433–64.
Sharma, Sanjay (2001). Famine, Philanthropy and the Colonial State: North India in the
Early Nineteenth Century. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Sharp, Buchanan (2007). “Shakespeare’s Coriolanus and the Crisis of the 1590s”.
In Law and Authority in Early Modern England: Essays Presented to Thomas Garden
Barnes. Ed. Buchanan Sharp and Mark Fissel. Newark, NJ: University of Delaware
Press.
Sharpe, J. A. (1998). Crime in Early Modern England, 1550–1750. 2nd edition.
London: Routledge.
Shi, Feng, Jianping Li, and Rob J. S.Wilson (2014). “A Tree-Ring Reconstruction
of the South Asian Summer Monsoon Index over the Past Millennium”. Scientific
Reports 4: 6739.
Short, B. (2014). The Battle of the Fields: Rural Community and Authority in Britain
during the Second World War. Suffolk: Boydell Press.
Short, B., C. Watkins, and J. Martin (2007). “ ‘The Front Line of Freedom’: State-
Led Agricultural Revolution in Britain, 1939–45”. In The Front Line of Freedom:
British Farming in the Second World War. Ed. B. Short, C. Watkins, and J. Martin.
Exeter: British Agricultural History Society, pp. 1–15.
Singha, Radhika (1998). A Despotism of Law: Crime and Justice in Colonial India. New
Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Bibliography 219
Sinha, N. K. (1956). The Economic History of Bengal. Calcutta.
Slack, Paul (1980). “Books of Orders: The Making of the English Social Policy,
1575–1631”. Transactions of the Royal Historical Society, 5th series, 30: 1–22.
Slack, Paul (1988). Poverty and Policy in Tudor and Stuart England. London and New
York: Longman.
Slack, Paul (1990). The English Poor Law, 1531–1782. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Slack, Paul (1999). From Reformation to Improvement: Public Welfare in Early Modern
England. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Slavin, Philip (2014). “Market Failure and the Great Famine in England and Wales
(1315–17)”. Past and Present 222: 9–49.
Smith, Helen (2013). “Greece’s Food Crisis: Families Face Going Hungry during
Summer Shutdown”. Guardian, 6 August.
Smith, M. J. (1989). “Land Nationalisation and the Agricultural Policy Com-
munity”. Public Policy and Administration 4.3: 9–21.
Smith, M. J. (1990). The Politics of Agricultural Support in Britain. Aldershot:
Dartmouth.
Smith, M. M. (2015). The Smell of Battle, the Taste of Siege: A Sensory History of the Civil
War. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Smith, Richard M. (2011). “Social Security as a Developmental Institution? The
Relative Efficiency of Poor Relief Provisions under the English Old Poor Law”.
In History, Historians and Development Policy: A Necessary Dialogue. Ed. C. A. Bayly,
Vijagendra Rao, Simon Szreter, and Michael Woolcock. Manchester: Manchester
University Press, pp. 75–102.
Smith, Richard M. (2015). “Dearth and Local Political Responses: 1280–1325 and
1580–1596/7 Compared”. In Peasants and Lords in the Medieval English Economy:
Essays in Honour of Bruce M. S. Campbell. Ed. Maryanne Kowaleski, John Langdon,
and Philip Schofield. Turnhout: Brepols, pp. 377–406.
Snyder M. G. (2005). “It Didn’t Begin with Katrina”. (US) National Housing
Institute, Shelterforce Online 143. September/October. www.nhi.org/online/
issues/143/beforekatrina.html.
Spencer, C. (1994). “Coriolanus Review”. Daily Telegraph. 27 May.
Spufford, Margaret (1984). The Great Re-Clothing of Rural England: Petty Chapmen
and their Wares in the Seventeenth Century. London: Hambledon.
Srivastava, Hari Shanker (1968). The History of Indian Famines, 1858–1918. Agra: Sri
Ram Mehra & Co.
Steensgaard, Niels (1990). “The Seventeenth-Century Crisis and the Unity of Eura-
sian History”. Modern Asian Studies 24: 683–97.
Street, P. (1969). My Father, A. G. Street. London: Robert Hale.
Sturmey, S. G. (1955). “Owner-farming in England and Wales, 1900 to 1950”. Man-
chester School 23: 246–68.
Subrahmanyam, Sanjay (1990). The Political Economy of Commerce: Southern India,
1500–1650. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Subtelny, Maria Eva (1995). “Mīraki Sayyid Ghiyās and the Tīmurid tradition of
Landscape Architecture”. Studia Iranica 24: 19–60.
Subtelny, Maria Eva (2007). Timurids in Transition: Turko-Persian Politics and Accul-
turation in Medieval Iran. Leiden: Brill.
Sundar, Pushpa (2000). Beyond Business: From Merchant Charity to Corporate Citizen-
ship: Indian Business Philanthropy through the Ages. New Delhi: Tata McGraw-Hill.
220 Bibliography
Sunderason, Sanjukta (2017). “Shadow-Lines”. Third Text 31.2–3: 239–59.
Swaminathan, M. S. (2013). “From Bengal Famine to Right to Food”. The Hindu.
13 February. www.thehindu.com/todays-paper/tp-opinion/from-bengal-famine-
to-right-to-food/article4409557.ece.
Swanson, Scott (1997). “The Medieval Foundations of John Locke’s Theory of
Natural Rights of Subsistence and the Principle of Extreme Necessity”. History of
Political Thought 18: 399–459.
Thirsk, Joan (1967). The Agrarian History of England and Wales, 1500–1640. Vol. 4.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Thirsk, Joan (2007). Food in Early Modern England: Phases, Fads, Fashions,
1500–1760. London: Bloomsbury.
Thomas, Keith (1983). Man and the Natural World: Changing Attitudes in England
1500–1800. London: Allen Lane.
Thompson, E. P. (1971). “The Moral Economy of the English Crowd in the Eight-
eenth Century”. Past and Present 50: 76–136.
Thompson, E. P. (1975). “The Crime of Anonymity”. In Albion’s Fatal Tree: Crime
and Society in Eighteenth-Century England. Ed. Douglas Hay, P. Linebaugh, J. G.
Rule, E. P. Thompson, and C. Winslow. London: Verso, pp. 255–344.
Thompson, E. P. (1993). “The Moral Economy Reviewed”. In Customs in Common:
Studies in Traditional Popular Culture. New York: New Press.
Thorpe, Andrew (1992). Britain in the 1930s: A Deceptive Decade. Oxford: Blackwell.
Tichelar, M. (2003). “The Labour Party, Agricultural Policy and the Retreat from
Rural Land Nationalisation during the Second World War”. Agricultural History
Review 51.2: 209–25.
Tilley, Morris Palmer (1950). A Dictionary of the Proverbs in England in the Sixteenth
and Seventeenth Centuries. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Tilly, Charles (1975). “Food Supply and Public Order in Modern Europe”. In The
Formation of National States in Western Europe. Ed. Charles Tilly. Princeton: Prince-
ton University Press, pp. 380–455.
Trevor-Roper, Hugh (1967, 2001). The Crisis of the Seventeenth Century: Religion, the
Reformation and Social Change. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.
Turner, M. (1992). “Output and Prices in UK Agriculture, 1867–1914, and the
Great Agricultural Depression Reconsidered”. Agricultural History Review 40.1:
38–51.
van der Zee, Henri A. (1982). The Hunger Winter: Occupied Holland, 1944–45.
Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.
Vattimo, G. and A. Rovatti, eds (2018). Weak Thought. Trans. P. Carravetta. New
York: SUNY Press.
Vernon, James (2007). Hunger: A Modern History. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univer-
sity Press.
Waddell, Brodie (2012). God, Duty and Community in English Economic Life,
1660–1720. Woodbridge: Boydell and Brewer.
Wakeman, F. (1986). “China and the Seventeenth Century Crisis”. Late Imperial
China 7.1: 1–26.
Walsham, Alexandra (1999). Providence in Early Modern England. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Walter, John (1989). “The Social Economy of Dearth in Early Modern England”.
In Famine, Disease and the Social Order in Early Modern Society. Ed. John Walter and
R. S. Schofield. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bibliography 221
Walter, John (2001). “Public Transcripts, Popular Agency and the Politics of Sub-
sistence in Early Modern England”. In Negotiating Power in Early Modern Society:
Order, Hierarchy and Subordination in Britain and Ireland. Ed. Michael J. Braddick
and John Walter. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 123–48.
Walter, John (2006). Crowds and Popular Politics in Early Modern England.
Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Walter, John (2015). “The Politics of Protest in Seventeenth-century England”. In
Crowd Actions in Britain and France from the Middle Ages to the Modern World. Ed.
Michael T. Davis. Basingstoke: Palgrave, pp. 58–79.
Walter, John and R. S. Schofield, eds (1989). Famine, Disease and the Social Order in
Early Modern Society. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Walter, John and Keith Wrightson (1976). “Dearth and the Social Order in Early
Modern England”. Past and Present 71: 22–42.
Wardle, I. (1994). Coriolanus Review. Independent on Sunday. 29 May.
Watt, Carey Anthony (2005). Serving the Nation: Cultures of Service, Association, and
Citizenship in Colonial India. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Webster, Charles (1982). “Healthy or Hungry Thirties?” History Workshop Journal
13: 110–29.
Welch, Anthony (1996). “Gardens that Babur Did Not Like: Landscape, Water,
and Architecture for the Sultans of Delhi”. In Mughal Gardens: Sources, Places,
Representations, and Prospects. Ed. James L. Wescoat and Joachim Wolschke-
Bulmahn. Washington, D.C.: Dumbarton Oaks.
Wescoat, James (2007). “Questions about the Political Significance of Mughal
Garden Waterworks”. Middle Eastern Garden Traditions. Ed. Michel Conan. Wash-
ington, D.C.: Dumbarton Oaks, pp. 177–96.
Wescoat, James (2011a). “The Changing Cultural Space of Mughal Gardens”. A
Companion to Asian Art and Architecture. Ed. Rebecca M. Brown and Deborah S.
Hutton. Oxford: Blackwell.
Wescoat, James (2011b). “Gardens, Pavilions and Tents. The Art of Shelter”. In
Architecture in Islamic Arts: Treasures of the Aga Khan Museum. Geneva: Aga Khan
Trust for Culture.
Westerfield, Ray B. (1915, 1968) Middlemen in English Business: Particularly between
1660–1760. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Whetham, E. (1972). “The Agriculture Act 1920 and Its Repeal: The ‘Great
Betrayal’ ”. Agricultural History Review 22.1: 36–49.
Whetham, E. (1978). The Agrarian History of England and Wales. 1914–1939. Vol. 8.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
White, Sam (2011). Climate of Rebellion in the Early Modern Ottoman Empire. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Whitney, Charles (1994). “Festivity and Topicality in the Coventry Scene of I Henry
IV”. English Literary Renaissance 24.2: 410–48.
Wiggins, S. and S. Keats, with E. Han, S. Shimokawa, J. A. Vargas Hernandez, and
Claro R. Moreira (2015). The Rising Cost of a Healthy Diet. Changing Relative Prices
of Foods in High-Income and Emerging Economies. London: Overseas Development
Agency.
Willett, J. (1957, 1963, 1964). “Study of the First Scene of Shakespeare’s
Coriolanus”. In Brecht on Theatre. London: Methuen.
Williams, Raymond and Marie Axton, eds. (1977) English Drama: Forms and Devel-
opment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
222 Bibliography
Williams, W. (1977). “Social Environment and Theatrical Environment: The Case
of English Naturalism”. In English Drama. Forms and Development. Ed. M. Axton
and R. Williams. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 202–23.
Williams, W. M. (1963) A West Country Village: Ashworthy. Family, Kinship and Land.
London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Wilson, Richard (1993). “Against the Grain: Representing the Market in Coriola-
nus”. Will Power: Essays on Shakespearean Authority. Hemel Hempstead: Harvester
Wheatsheaf.
Wilt, A. F. (2001). Food for War: Agriculture and Rearmament in Britain before the
Second World War. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Winter, Michael (1986). The Survival and Re-Emergence of Family Farming: A Study of
the Holsworthy Area of West Devon. Unpublished PhD Thesis, Open University.
Winter, Michael (1996). Rural Politics: Policies for Agriculture, Forestry and the
Environment. London: Routledge.
Winter, M. and M. Lobley (2016). Is there a Future for the Small Family Farm in the
UK? London: Prince’s Countryside Fund.
Wittfogel, Karl A. (1958). Oriental Despotism. A Comparative Study of Total Power. New
Haven: Yale University Press.
Woodbridge, Linda (2004). “The Peddler and the Pawn: Why Did Tudor England
Consider Peddlers to Be Rogues?” In Rogues and Early Modern English Culture.
Ed. Craig Dionne and Steve Mentz. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press,
pp. 143–70.
Wrightson, Keith (1980). “The Nadir of English Illegitimacy in the Seventeenth
Century”. In Bastardy and its Comparative History. Ed. P. Laslett, K. Oosterveen,
and R. M. Smith. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 176–91.
Wrightson, Keith (2000). Earthly Necessities: Economic Lives in Early Modern Britain.
New Haven and London: Yale University Press.
Wrigley, E. A. and R. S. Schofield (1981). The Population History of England
1541–1871: A Reconstruction. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Yang, Anand A. (1987). “Disciplining ‘Natives’: Prisons and Prisoners in Early
Nineteenth Century India”. South Asia, N.S., 10.2: 29–45.
Yong, Tan Tai (2005). The Garrison State: Military, Government and Society in Colonial
Punjab. New Delhi: Sage.
Zeeveld, W. Gordon (1962). “Coriolanus and Jacobean Polities”. Modern Language
Review 57: 321–34.
Zhang, Jiacheng, and Zhiguang Lin (1992). Climate of China. New York: Wiley.
Zins, H (1972). England and the Baltic in the Elizabethan Era. Manchester: Manches-
ter University Press.
Zweiniger-Bargielowska, Ina (2000). Austerity in Britain: Rationing, Controls, and
Consumption, 1939–1955. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Index
Page numbers in bold refer to tables and those in italic refer to figures