Enders4 - APPLIED ECONOMETRIC TIME SERIES
Enders4 - APPLIED ECONOMETRIC TIME SERIES
Enders4 - APPLIED ECONOMETRIC TIME SERIES
Chapter 4
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
The Random Walk Model
yt = yt–1 + t (or yt t).
t
Hence yt y0 i
i 1
Given the first t realizations of the {t} process, the conditional mean of yt+1 is
Similarly, the conditional mean of yt+s (for any s > 0) can be obtained from
s
Et yt s yt Et t i yt
i 1
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Random Walk Plus Drift
yt = yt–1 + a0 + t
ts
y t s y 0 a0 ( t s ) i
i 1
Etyt+s = yt + a0s.
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
The autocorrelation coefficient
E[(yt – y0)(yt–s – y0)] = E[(t + t–1+...+ 1)(t–s+ t–s–1 +...+1)]
= E[(t–s)2+(t–s–1)2+...+(1)2]
= (t – s)2
s (t s) / (t s)t
= [(t – s)/t]0.5
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Panel (a): Random Walk Panel (b): Random Walk Plus Drift
12 60
10 50
8 40
6 30
4 20
2 10
0 0
10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Panel (c): T rend Stationary Panel (d): Random Walk Plus Noise
60 14
12
50
10
40
8
30
6
20
4
10
2
0 0
10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Figure 4.3: The Business Cycle?
200
150
100
50
0
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
60
40
20
-20
-40
-60
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Table 4.1: Selected Autocorrelations From Nelson and Plosser
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Worksheet 4.1
Consider the two random walk processes
8
2.5
6
0.0
4
2
-2.5
0
-5.0
-2
-4 -7.5
20 40 60 80 100 20 40 60 80 100
Since both series are unit-root processes with uncorrelated error terms, the regression of
yt on zt is spurious. Given the realizations of {yt} and {zt}, it happens that yt tends to increase as
zt tends to decrease. The regression line shown in the scatter plot of yt on zt captures this
tendency. The correlation coefficient between yt and zt is 0.69 and a linear regression yields yt =
1.41 0.565zt. However, the residuals from the regression equation are nonstationary.
4
8
3
6
2
4
1
2 0
-1
0
-2
-2
-3
-4
-4
-7.5 -5.0 -2.5 0.0 2.5 5.0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Worksheet 4.2
Consider the two random walk plus drift processes
yt = 0.2 + yt1 + yt zt = 0.1 + zt1 + zt
25 2.5
0.0
20
-2.5
15
-5.0
10
-7.5
5
-10.0
0
-12.5
-5 -15.0
10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Here {yt} and {zt} series are unit-root processes with uncorrelated error terms so that the regression is
spurious. Although it is the deterministic drift terms that cause the sustained increase in yt and the overall
decline in zt, it appears that the two series are inversely related to each other. The residuals from the
regression yt = 6.38 0.10zt are nonstationary.
20 5.0
15 2.5
10 0.0
5 -2.5
0
-5.0
-5
-7.5
-15.0 -12.5 -10.0 -7.5 -5.0 -2.5 0.0 2.5 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Panel (a): Detrended RGDP
1.00
0.75
0.50
0.25
0.00
-0.25
-0.50
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
0.50
0.00
-0.50
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Autocorrelations PACF
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
3. UNIT ROOTS AND REGRESSION RESIDUALS
• yt = a0 + a1zt + et
• Assumptions of the classical model:
– both the {yt} and {zt} sequences be stationary
– the errors have a zero mean and a finite variance.
– In the presence of nonstationary variables, there might be
what Granger and Newbold (1974) call a spurious
regression
• A spurious regression has a high R2 and t-statistics that
appear to be significant, but the results are without any
economic meaning.
• The regression output “looks good” because the least-
squares estimates are not consistent and the customary
tests of statistical inference do not hold.
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Four cases
• CASE 1: Both {yt} and {zt} are stationary.
– the classical regression model is appropriate.
• CASE 2: The {yt} and {zt} sequences are integrated of different orders.
– Regression equations using such variables are meaningless
• CASE 3: The nonstationary {yt} and {zt} sequences are integrated of
the same order and the residual sequence contains a stochastic trend.
– This is the case in which the regression is spurious.
– In this case, it is often recommended that the regression equation be estimated in
first differences.
• CASE 4: The nonstationary {yt} and {zt} sequences are integrated of
the same order and the residual sequence is stationary.
– In this circumstance, {yt} and {zt} are cointegrated.
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
The Dickey-Fuller tests
p
Δyt yt 1 i yt i 1 t
i 2
p
Δyt a0 yt 1 i yt i 1 t
i2
p
Δyt a0 yt 1 a2 t i yt i 1 t
i2
The 1, 2, and 3 statistics are constructed in exactly the same way
as ordinary F-tests:
i
SSR ( restricted ) SSR (unrestricted ) / r
SSR (unrestricted ) /(T k )
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Figure 4.6: The Dickey-Fuller Distribution
0.09
0.08
0.07
0.06
0.05
percentile
0.04
0.03
0.02
0.01
0
-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3
t-statistic
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Table 4.2: Summary of the Dickey-Fuller
Tests
Model Hypothesis Test Critical values for
Statistic 95% and 99%
Confidence Intervals
yt = a0 + yt-1 + a2t + t =0 -3.45 and -4.04
= a2 = 0 3 6.49 and 8.73
a0 = = a2 = 0 2 4.88 and 6.50
yt = a0 + yt-1 + t =0 -2.89 and -3.51
a0 = = 0 1 4.71 and 6.70
yt = yt-1 + t =0 -1.95 and -2.60
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Table 4.3: Nelson and Plosser's Tests For
Unit Roots
p a0 a2 +1
p is the chosen lag length. Entries in parentheses represent the t-test for
the null hypothesis that a coefficient is equal to zero. Under the null of
nonstationarity, it is necessary to use the Dickey-Fuller critical values. At the
.05 significance level, the critical value for the t-statistic is -3.45.
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Quarterly Real U.S. GDP
lrgdpt = 0.1248 + 0.0001t 0.0156lrgdpt–1 + 0.3663lrgdpt–1
(1.58) (1.31) (1.49) (6.26)
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
EXTENSIONS OF THE DICKEY–FULLER TEST
yt = a0 + a1yt–1 + a2yt–2 + a3yt–3 + ... + ap–2yt–p+2 + ap–1yt–p+1 + apyt–p + t
p
p
1 ai and i a j
i 1 ji
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Rule 1:
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
• Rule 1 indicates that you can conduct lag length tests using t-
tests and/or F-tests on
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Selection of the Lag Length
• general-to-specific methodology
– Start using a lag length of p*. If the t-statistic on lag p*
is insignificant at some specified critical value, re-
estimate the regression using a lag length of p*–1.
Repeat the process until the last lag is significantly
different from zero.
– Once a tentative lag length has been determined,
diagnostic checking should be conducted.
• Model Selection Criteria (AIC ,SBC)
• Residual-based LM tests
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
The Test with MA Components
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Example of a Negative MA term
yt = yt-1 + εt – β1εt-1; 0 < β1 < 1.
The ACF is:
γ0 = E[(yt – y0)2] = σ2 + (1 – β1)2E[(εt-1)2 + (εt-2)2 + … + (ε1)2]
= [1 + (1 – β1)2(t – 1)]σ2
γs = E[(yt – y0)(yt-s – y0)]
= E[(εt +(1–β1)εt-1 + … + (1–β1)ε1)(εt-s + (1–β1)εt-s-1 + … + (1–β1)ε1)
= (1 – β1) [1 + (1 – β1) (t – s – 1)] σ2
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Multiple Roots
• Consider
2yt = a0 + 1yt–1 + t
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Panel (a) yt = 0.5yt−1 + t + DL
10.0
7.5
5.0
2.5
0.0
-2.5
10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
7.5
5.0
2.5
0.0
-2.5
-5.0
10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Perron’s Test
• Let the null be yt = a0 + yt–1 + 1DP + 2DL + t
– where DP and DL are the pulse and level dummies
• Estimate the regression (the alternative):
yt = a0 + a2t +m1DP + m2DL + m3DT + t
– Let DT be a trend shift dummy such that DT = t – for t > and zero
otherwise.
• Now consider a regression of the residuals
yˆ t a 1 yˆ t 1 1 t
If the errors do not appear to be white noise, estimate the equation in the
form of an augmented Dickey–Fuller test.
The t-statistic for the null hypothesis a1 = 1 can be compared to the critical
values calculated by Perron (1989). For = 0.5, Perron reports the
critical value of the t-statistic at the 5 percent significance level to be
–3.96 for H2 and –4.24 for H3.
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Table 4.6: Retesting Nelson and Plosser's Data For
Structural Change
T k a0 1 2 a2 a1
The appropriate t-statistics are in parenthesis. For a0, 1, 2, and a2, the
null is that the coefficient is equal to zero. For a1, the null hypothesis is a1
= 1. Note that all estimated values of a1 are significantly different from unity
at the 1% level.
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Power
a1 10% 5% 1%
0.80 95.9 87.4 51.4
0.90 52.1 33.1 9.0
0.95 23.4 12.7 2.6
0.99 10.5 5.8 1.3
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Nonlinear Unit Root Tests
• Enders-Granger Test
1 if yt 1
It
0 if yt 1
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Schmidt and Phillips (1992) LM Test
• The overly-wide confidence intervals for means that you are less
likely to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root even when the true
value of is not zero. A number of authors have devised clever
methods to improve the estimates of the intercept and trend
coefficients.
t
y t a0 a 2 t t
i 1
yt = a2 + t
• The idea is to estimate the trend coefficient, a2, using the regression
yt = a2 + t. As such, the presence of the stochastic trend i does not
interfere with the estimation of a2.
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
LM Test Continued
• Use this estimate to form the detrended series as
ytd yt ( y1 aˆ2) aˆ2t
• Then use the detrended series to estimate
p
y t a 0 y d
t 1 ci ytdi t
i 1
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
The Elliott, Rothenberg, and Stock Test
Instead of creating the first difference of yt, Elliott, Rothenberg and
Stock (ERS) preselect a constant close to unity, say , and subtract
yt1 from yt to obtain:
= a0z1t + a2z2t + et
The important point is that the estimates a0 and a2 can be used to detrend
the {yt} series
p
y y
d
t
d
t 1 ci ytdi t
i 1
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Panel Unit Root Tests
pi
•
yit = ai0 + iyit–1 + ai2t +
y
j1
ij it j + it
• One way to obtain a more powerful test is to pool the estimates from a
number separate series and then test the pooled value. The theory
underlying the test is very simple: if you have n independent and
unbiased estimates of a parameter, the mean of the estimates is also
unbiased. More importantly, so long as the estimates are independent,
the central limit theory suggests that the sample mean will be normally
distributed around the true mean.
– The difficult issue is to correct for cross equation correlation
• Because the lag lengths can differ across equations, you should perform
separate lag length tests for each equation. Moreover, you may choose
to exclude the deterministic time trend. However, if the trend is
included in one equation, it should be included in all
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Table 4.8: The Panel Unit Root Tests for Real Exchange Rates
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Limitations
• The null hypothesis for the IPS test is i = 2 = … = n = 0. Rejection of the null
hypothesis means that at least one of the i’s differs from zero.
• At this point, there is substantial disagreement about the asymptotic theory
underlying the test. Sample size can approach infinity by increasing n for a given T,
increasing T for a given n, or by simultaneously increasing n and T.
– For small T and large n, the critical values are dependent on the magnitudes of
the various ij.
• The test requires that that the error terms be serially uncorrelated and
contemporaneously uncorrelated.
– You can determine the values of pi to ensure that the autocorrelations of {it}
are zero. Nevertheless, the errors may be contemporaneously correlated in that
Eitjt 0
– The example above illustrates a common technique to correct for correlation
across equations. As in the example, you can subtract a common time effect
from each observation. However, there is no assurance that this correction will
completely eliminate the correlation. Moreover, it is quite possible that is
nonstationary. Subtracting a nonstationary component from each sequence is
clearly at odds with the notion that the variables are stationary.
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
The Beveridge-Nelson Decomposition
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
BN 2
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
The HP Filter
Let the trend of a nonstationary series be the {t} sequence so
that yt – t the stationary component
1 T T 1
( yt t) + t+1 t
2
[( ) ( t t -1 ) ]
2
T t=1 T t= 2
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
Panel (a) The BN Cycle Pane l (b) The HP Cycle
0.03 0.04
0.03
0.02
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.00 0.00
-0.01 -0.01
-0.02
-0.02
-0.03
-0.03
-0.04
-0.04 -0.05
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.
14
RGDP
12
10
trllions of 2005 dollars
Consumption
6
Investment
2
0
1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Figure 4.12: Real GDP, Consumption and Investment
Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.