Bureaucracy in Modern Society (Peter M. Blau)
Bureaucracy in Modern Society (Peter M. Blau)
Bureaucracy in Modern Society (Peter M. Blau)
OM/y
9/\.'% STUDIES
iI r r
IN SOCIOLOGY
Bureaucracy
in Modern Society
by P E T E R M . B L A U , University of Chicago
With a foreword by
Random House
NEW YORK
FIFTEENTH 1>1unT1nG, NOVEMBER 1966
_
suits, religion,
. .. social welfare, and recreation. These facts
. .. .
5
6 BUREAUCRACY IN MODERN SOCIETY
FOOTNOTES 119
IN MODERN SOCIETY
I
1
'interference
be suppressed, the best way fo check their
with efficiency is to exclude from the administrative hier-
archy those interpersonal relationships that are character~
ized by emotional attachments. While relatives sometimes
work for the same company, typically they are not put
in charge of one another. Impersonal relationships assure
the detachment necessary if efficiency alone is to govern
administrative decisions. However, relationships between
employees who have frequent social contacts do not re-
main purely impersonal, as we shall see.
These four factors-specialization, a hierarchy of au-
Mority, a system of rules, and impersonality-are the
basic characteristics of bureaucratic organization. Fac-
tories are bureaucratically organized, as are government
agencies, and if this were not the case they could not
operate efficiently on a large scale. Chapter Two is devoted
to a more detailed analysis of bureaucratic structure and
the conditions that give rise to bureaucratization. But
actual operations do not exactly follow the formal blue-
print. To understand how bureaucracies function, we must
observe them in action. This is the task of Chapters Three
and Four, which are concerned, respectively, with bureau-
cratic work groups and relationships of authority. After
discussing the internal structure and functioning of bu-
reaucracies, we shall turn in the final two chapters to
their implications for the society of which they are a part.
20 BUREAUCRACY IN NIODERN SOCIETY
Bureaucracy in Process
In the IJavy
The existence and importance of the informal struc-
ture of the Navy would hardly be denied by any experi-
enced participant . . . Like the formal, it consists of
rules, groupings, and sanctioned systems of procedure.
They are informal because they are never recorded in
the codes or official blueprints and because they are
generated and maintained with a degree of spontaneity
always lacking in the activities which make up the
formal structure. These rules, groupings, and proce-
dures do, nevertheless, form a structure, for, though not
officially recognized, they are clearly and semiperma-
nendy established, they are just as "real" and just as
compelling on the membership as the elements of the
official structure, and they maintain their eidstence and
social significance throughout many changes of person-
nel. . . .
Bureaucracy in Process 47
In a Factory
Of the fourteen men, or operators, as they were called
in the Western Electric Company, who were regularly
in the Observation Room, nine were wiremen, ...
. .
three were soldernten, . and two were inspectors.
... The men were engaged in making parts of switches
for central office telephone equipment. Specically, they
were connecting wires tO banks of terminals. . . A .
Wireman took the necessary number of banks for an
equipment and placed them in a holder or mixture on a
workbench. Then he connected the terminals of the
banks together in a certain order with wire. ..
.A
wireman worked on two equipments at a time. Having
finished a level on one equipment, he moved to the
second equipment. In the meantime, a solderrnan fixed
in place the Finished connections of the first equipment,
and an inspector tested and scrutinized the work of both
men. ...
Let us now turn to some of the activities, over and
above each man's special job, that were observed in the
Bureaucracy in Process 49
ing games with some coworkers and not with others, his
role became socially defined as part of one of the two
cliques, or of neither, and the group became structured ac-
cordingly. Simultaneously, there developed normative be-
liefs shared by all members of the group: "Don't be a rate»
buster by working too fast" "Don't be a chiseler by work-
ing too slowly" "Don't act bossy" "Dorl't be a squealer"
These unofficial standards governed the behavior of the
workers. One inspector was excluded from both cliques,
because he acted officiously and even reported other
workers to superiors. Despite a complicated wage incentive
system, there existed some restriction of output. Since too
fast as well as too slow work was condemned, wirernen
did not try to produce as much as they could, although
doing so would have increased their pay, but slacked
their pace after they had completed what they considered
to be "a fair day's work." Differences in output within
this group would probably have been smaller if it had not
been divided into two cliques. One of these emphasized
that the worker should not produce too much, and the
other, that he should not produce too little, so that the
members of each clique enjoyed social support for work-
ing slower or faster, respectively, than those of the other.
To be effective, social norms must be enforceable. Un-
less a member of a formal organization conforms with its
official regulations to a certain minimum degree, he will be
expelled. The reverse of this statement is also true: unless
expulsion is a serious threat, the prevalence of conformity
cannot be assured. The individual's motivation to remain
part of the organization makes him subject to its control.
Salaried employees are more dependable than unpaid vol-
unteers in large part because economic dependence is a
reliable mechanism for interesting the members of the
organization in keeping their positions. The same principle
holds for the enforcement of unofficial norms. Whereas
Bureaucracy in Process 55
the work group does not have the power to remove one
of its members from his job and deprive him of his in-
come, it can. ostracize him and thereby exclude him from
genuine group membership. But for such exclusion to be
a threat that discourages deviant tendencies, the individual
must first wish to be included in the group. If a person
did not care about maintaining congenial relations with
his coworkers, being cold-shouldered by them would
neither disconcert him nor deter him from 'disregarding
their social norms, and for him it would be "their" norms
rather than "ours."
This is the reason why the existence of social cohesion
is SO significant for work groups. Strong mutual ties be~
tween the members of a group make each interested in
maintaining his position in the group. In, In: situation,.__
_
relationship. If a mutinous crew refuses to obey the cap-
tain's orders, he does not in fact have authority over his
men. Whatever the superio as official rights to command
obedience and the subordinates' official duties ."'"
Power of Sanction
The preceding comments apply to informal leadership
as well as to burea socratic authority. The informal leader,
like the prudent bureaucratic superior, establishes his au-
thority over his followers by creating social obligations?
Once a relationship of authority exists, both bureaucratic
superior and informal leader can alford to word their
orders as mere suggestions, because even these are readily
followed by the rest of the group. Neither of them usually
needs sanctions to command obedience, though sanctions
are available to both of them in case they wish to use
special inducements, since praise or blame of the person
in the superordinate position itself exerts a powerful injiu-
ence.
Nevertheless, there is a fundamental distinction between
informal leadership and bureaucratic authority. Informal
leadership freely emerges among a group of peers. It is
initially the result of personality differences that have be-
come socially magnified. Some members of the group ex-
cel in activities that are highly valued by all, whether
these are street fighting or solving complex problems;
these few will be more respected, and their opinions will
carry greater weight. The person in the extreme position,
if he also finds ways to obligate the others to him, is ex-
pected to be the group's leader.
Bureaucratic authority, on the other hand, prevents the
group itself from conferring the position of leadership
upon the member of their choice. The voluntary obedience
of subordinates must converge upon the individual offli-
cially placed in the position of supervisor, irrespective of
his personal characteristics. The bureaucratic mechanism
Bureaucrazie Authority 75
_
ment of goals whereby "an instrumental value becomes
a terminal value." Discinline, readily interpreted as con-
formate with regulations, whatever the situation, is
seen not as a measure designed for specific purposes but
becomes an immediate value in the life-organization of
the bureaucrat.-2
The prevention of arbitrary decisions requires that a
high respect for disciplined performance of duties be fos-
tered among the members of a bureaucracy. This emphasis
sometimes becomes overpowering, with the result that
punctilious adherence to formalized procedures is elevated
into the primary objective of bureaucratic activities and
displaces their original objectives in the thinking of offi-
cials. Compelled by this orientation to find the right rule
Bureaucracy and Social Change 89
Conservative Pressures in
Two Social Contexts
A brief review of two empirical investigations of pro-
gressive programs and their fate indicates the complex re-
lationship between bureaucratic structures and changes in
social policies. Whereas both studies found strains toward
conservativism, the social forces responsible for them
were quite different.
Philip Selznick's study of the Tennessee Valley Authority
shows that the grass-roots policy adopted by this New
Deal agency had unanticipated consequences that brought
about fundamental changes in its progressive program?
The principle of grass-roots democracy emphasizes that
the central government should not simply impose its au-
thority upon the people in a region, but should give them
a voice in the management of the federal agencies that
affect their lives. Since all people in the Tennessee Valley
could not directly participate in administrative decisions,
Bureaucracy and Social Change 97
CHAPTER 1
1. See Pitirim Sorokin, Social and Cultural Dynamics, New
* " r i c a n Book Company, 1937-1941. The author
traces fluctuations in cultural emphasis O11 science I and
rationality, on the one hand, and faith and supernatural
phenomena, on the other, from the earliest times to the
present, and w'gorously condemns the present trend toward
rationalization.
5. Ibid., p. 232.
119
120 BUREAUCRACY IN MODERN SOCIETY
CHAPTER 2
1. From Max Weber- Essays in Sociology, translated by
H. H. Gerth and C. Wright Mills, New York: Oxford
University Press, 1946, p. 196. By permission.
2. Max Weber, The Theory of Social and Economic Organi-
zation, translated by A. M. Henderson and Talcott Par~
sons, New York' Oxford University Press, 1947, p. 331.
3. bid., p. 330.
4. laid., p. 340.
5. Ibid., p. 334.
6. Ibid., p. 337.
.
11 From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology, op. cit., pp. 256-57.
The advanced student will have recognized the indebted-
ness of the foregoing discussion to Weber's (pp. 204-16).
It goes without saying that Weber's fund of historical
knowledge and his profound theoretical insights about
bureaucracy can be acknowledged as outstanding contribu-
tions in the field even if one rejects his use of the ideal-
type construct.
Footnotes 121
CHAPTER 3
CHAPTER 4
1. Daniel Katz, Nathan MacCoby,. .and Nancy C. Morse,
Productfviry, Supervision ~and Morale in an Office Situs
dion, Ann Arbor: Institute for Social Research, University
of Michigan, 1950, especially pp. 17, 21, 29.
25. See, for instance, F J. Rbéthlisberger and William I.
Dickson, Management and the_ Worker, Cambridge: Har-
vard University Press, 1946, p`p. 452-53.~
3. For a clear illustration of this point in a street comer
gang, see William F. Whyte, Street Corner Society, Chi-
cage' University of Chicago Press, 1943, pp. 257-62.
CHAPTER 5
1. Walter R. Sharp, The French Civil Service' Bureaucracy
in Transition, New York: Macmillan Company, 1931, pp.
446-50 (by permission); reprinted in Robert K. Merton
Ailsa P. Gray, Barbara Hockey, and Hanan C. Selvin
(eds.), Reader in Bureaucracy, Glencoe, IH.: Free Press,
1952, pp. 407-9.
2. Robert K. Merton, Social Theory and Social Structure,
Glencoe, HI.: Free Press, 1949, pp. 154-55. By permission.
8. Ibid., p. 204.
CHAPTER 6
1. Alvin W. Gouldner, "Red Tape as a Social Problem," in
Robert K. Merton, Ailsa P. Gray, Barbara Hockey, and
Hanan C. Selvin (eds.), Reader in Bureaucracy, Glencoe,
Ill.: Free Press, 1952, pp. 410-18.
2. Adolf A- Berle, Jr., and Gardiner C. Means, The Modern
Corporation and Private Property, New York: Macmillan
Company, 1932.
$El.ECTED READINGS