The Effect of Reservations On Caste
The Effect of Reservations On Caste
The Effect of Reservations On Caste
They say that time changes things, but you actually have to change them yourself ~ Andy Warhol
INTRODUCTION
In these sixty four years of independence, we have seen our problems passing from one generation to other. Corruption, terrorism and the list goes on. Here, I would like to contemplate on an issue that has plagued us for centuries and has now taken a completely different form to aggravate our situation. Contrary to the expectations of some social theorists, Indias caste system has shown remarkable persistence in the face of industrialization. 1. Many explanations have been proposed for this persistence, including ongoing discrimination by upper castes2, benefits derived from social insurance groups, and caste based patronage from government programs. 3 This paper will examine the relationship between caste persistence and the primary government program responsible for allocating benefits to disadvantage groups, the reservation system. Reservation or Quota system in our country is a rarely seen example where the solution of a problem becomes a greater nuisance than the problem itself. It is only ironical that in the land of Lord Ram, who enthusiastically relished the half eaten berries of an untouchable devotee Shabri, the fault lines of cast ran deep into the society.
As expressed by Karl Marx, Modern industry, resulting from the railway system, will dissolve the hereditary divisions of labour, upon which rest the Indian caste system. 2 I will use caste to refer to sub-caste networks, or jati 3 Craig Jeffrey. A Fist Is Stronger than five fingers: caste and dominance in rural north India. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 26(2):217236, 2001.
1
Page
Nevertheless, a solution of was provided by the architects of Indian Constitution in the form of Quota system, where a certain proportion of jobs and positions in all government institutions were to be given to the candidates from the underdeveloped segments of society under relaxed criteria.
HISTORY OF RESERVATIONS
Reservations for the most depressed groups have existed in some form since the days of British rule. These groups are collectively referred to as Dalits, or untouchables, and Adivassi, or tribal groups, though they are actually composed of hundreds of distinct groups. After India achieved independence, the composition of these two groups was finalized into lists of Scheduled Castes and Scheduled Tribes, and their protection was enshrined in the Constitution. 4 The Constitution specifically prohibits discrimination on the basis of caste, and reserves 22.5% of seats in institutions of higher education and government employment. 5 The next major expansion of the reservation system was initiated on the recommendation of the Mandal commission of 1979, which was organized to address the problem of other socially and educationally backwards classes.6 These groups, while not burdened with the stigma of untouchability, still suffered from a persistent lack of opportunity. The Mandal commission
Government of India. National Commission for Backward Classes, 2010. 5 Government of India and Ministry Of Law and Justice. The constitution of India, 2006. 6 Bhagwan Das. Moments in a History of Reservations. Economic And Political Weekly, 35(43/44):WS31WS34, 2000.
4
Page
recommended the creation of a third category of groups eligible for reservations, Other Backwards Classes (OBC).7 The commission recommended an additional 1,257 groups that should be eligible for reservations, and estimated the population of these groups at 52% of the total population of India. The commission also recommended that the total number of seats subject to reservation be increased from 22.5% to 49.5%. These recommendations were quite controversial, but were all eventually implemented between 1990 and 2006. 8 The commissions recommendations reflect a common understanding of the caste system, as a natural and permanent feature of Indian society. In this view, caste is analogous to race, an immutable, biological fact. Caste classification in itself is morally neutral, and it is only the extreme inequality between castes that necessitates intervention. A British contemporary of Mandal commented on the empowering nature of caste solidarity, remarking that strong caste groups have the effect of raising the status and prestige of the Caste as a whole and freeing its members from exploitation and victimization by other caste. 9 The Mandal commission does not recognize persistent inequality as a natural result of caste stratification, but rather as a result of structural inconsistencies imposed by years of British rule. The British rulers produced many structural disturbances in the Hindu caste structure, and these were contradictory in nature and impact.... Thus, the
will use eligible castes to refer to all backwards classes, though not all backwards classes are strictly defined along caste lines 8 Evan Osborne. Culture, Development, and Government: Reservations in India. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49(3):659685, 2001. 9 A. P. Barnabas and Subhash C. Mehta. Caste in Changing India. The Indian Institute of Public Administration, New Delhi, India, 1965.
7
Page
various impacts of the British rule on the Hindu caste system...set the stage for the caste conflicts in modern India.10 The reservation system proposed by the Mandal commission was not intended to decrease the influence caste, but rather to restore the natural order of the caste system by counteracting the structural inequalities imposed by British rule. Far from denouncing the caste system, the report actually justifies the reservation system by citing its consistency with the historic functioning of the caste system, where certain jobs were reserved for certain castes. The report appeals to a popular legend, in which two characters were punished for abandoning their traditional occupations. In fact the Hindu society has always operated a very rigorous scheme of reservations, which was internalized through caste system. Eklabya lost his thumb and Shambuk his neck for their breach of caste rules of reservation. 11 The idea that strong caste identification is not mutually exclusive with egalitarian principals was not unique to the Mandal commission. John Harris writes of the people of Tamil Nadu, that social relationships are still structured hierarchically, but in the minds of individuals, it appears that a form of society can be envisaged in which hierarchy would disappear, and yet caste identities would still persist. 12 The Mandal commissions proposal for a system of positive discrimination then was consistent with their underlying beliefs on the nature of the caste system. These beliefs, however, are not universal. Indeed, as shall be explored in the next section, much of the conflict surrounding reservation policy can be traced to different beliefs about the nature of the caste system, rather than simple disagreements on policy prescriptions.
B.P. Mandal. The Mandal Commission Report, 1980. ibid 12 John Harris. Why Poor People Stay Poor in Rural South India. Social Scientist, 8(1):20, August 1979.
10 11
Page
CHARACTERIZATION OF CASTE
Many economic phenomena spring from path-dependent economic processes, which imply that it is necessary to make a careful study of the historical past of an economic phenomenon to help explain its present. In other words, we must be good economic historians to be good economic theorists. 13 Any attempt to identify the complex interactions between reservations and caste identity must begin with a strong conceptual understanding of caste. In the following section, I will present the major theories concerning the nature of the caste system and its source of its lasting influence in India.
HORIZONTAL CHARACTERIZATION In the years since the Mandal commission report, caste has been increasingly understood as a form of traditional social identity, separate and distinct from race. This view rejects the existence of any fundamental organizing principle, such as race, class, or hereditary occupation. Instead caste groups are defined by arbitrary symbols and rituals that exist primarily to define the identity of each caste relative to outside castes. Dipankar Gupta defines the caste system as a form of differentiation wherein the constituent units of the system justify endogamy on the basis of putative biological differences which are semaphored by the ritualization of multiple social practices.14 The caste equilibrium is thus sustained by the loyalty of individuals to their own caste above all others, rather than through a fixed hierarchical power structure.
Page
13Government
of India. National Commission for Backward Classes, 2010. 14 Dipankar Gupta. Continuous Hierarchies and Discrete Castes Consequences of the Above. Economic and Political Weekly, 19(48):20492053, 1984.
This view of caste can be characterized as horizontal, as compliance is enforced through mutual threats by peers. An article from the Hindustan Times in 1961 illustrates this horizontal enforcement: Everyone of the hundreds of sections into which this nation is divided suffers from discrimination and every group practices discrimination against all others. 15 VERTICAL CHARACTERIZATION The vertical approach supposes a strict hierarchy with top-down enforcement, such as that found in a racially segregated society. Vertical theories of caste include the race-based theory of Chakraberty 16 or the puritybased theory of Louis Dumont17. Biological and anthropological evidence provide more support for the horizontal formulation of caste over the vertical formulation. The theory of a racial basis for caste has been thoroughly refuted by modern biological science. A recent study by Harvard Medical School 18 examined genetic markers across caste groups. The study found evidence of distinct biological markers from successive waves of immigrating groups, which is superficially consistent with a racial foundation of caste. The markers, however, were mixed across castes making identification of specific castes or tribes via genetic markers impossible. In other words, though distinct genetic groups could be identified, there was no correlation between these groups and observed caste groups.
A. P. Barnabas and Subhash C. Mehta. Caste in Changing India. The Indian Institute of Public Administration, New Delhi, India, 1965. 16 C. Chakraberty. Racial Basis of Indian Culture. Aryan Books International, New Delhi, India, 1997. 17 L Dumont. Homo hierarchies. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1966. 18 David Reich, Kumarasamy Thangaraj, Nick Patterson, Alkes L Price, and Lalji Singh. Reconstructing Indian population history. Nature, 461(7263):48994, 2009.
15
Page
The authors concluded that the caste system evolved independently from the in migration of successive genetically-distinct groups. The same conclusion is reached by several other studies in Biology and Anthropology.19 One of the most influential 20 conceptualizations of the caste system was developed by Louis Dumont in the 1960s.21 Dumonts hierarchical characterization of caste is superficially consistent with the public manifestation of caste dynamics, but does not accurately reflect the views of non-dominant castes. According to Dumont, castes are aligned according to their relative purity or impurity, along a single axis. This alignment is known and accepted by all castes. The exact structure of Dumonts hierarchy is never stated explicitly, though it is assumed that all those within the system are familiar with the structure and know their place within it. Brahmin, the traditional specialists in religious rituals, are at the top of Dumonts hierarchy. The idea that Brahmin are the most pure caste is consistent with most publicly expressed views on the caste hierarchy, but this particular alignment is only fully accepted by Brahmin. Other castes generally subscribe to a set of beliefs in which they are as pure as or purer than any other caste. One low-caste, the Kuricchan of Malabar, will ritually purify their homes if it is polluted by the entry of a Brahmin, and others refuse to eat with
L. Leigh Field, Sira Surje, and K. Ajit Ray. Immunoglobulin (GM and KM) allotypes in the Sikh population of India. American Journal of Physical Anthropology, 75(1):3135, 1988. D.N. Majumdar and Rao C.R. Race Elements in Bengal: A Quantitative Study. Asia Publishing House and Statistical Publishing Society, Calcutta, 1960. Partha P. Majumdar, B. Uma Shankar, Amitabha Basu, Kailash C. Malhotra, Ranjan Gupta, Barun Mukhopadhyay, M. Vijayakumar, and Subrata K. Roy. Anthropometric variation in India: A statistical appraisal. Current Anthropology, 31(1):94, 1990. 20 Evan Osborne. Culture, Development, and Government: Reservations in India. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49(3):659685, 2001. 21 L Dumont. Homo hierarchies. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1966.
19
Page
Brahmins. Even the Meghavals or Dheds, whose traditional occupation is carrying carrion, and are thus very low on the purity hierarchy, refuse to dine with castes that are publicly considered more pure. Caste claims to superiority are often based on seemingly arbitrary distinctions, with no clear appeal to purity. The Kaibartta, a traditional fishing caste, consider themselves superior to the Malos, another fishing caste, on the grounds that the Kaibartta always pass the netting needle from the above downwards, working from left to right; while the Malo passes it from below upwards, forming meshes from right to left. 22 Sociologist Dipankar Gupta remarks, perhaps with some hyperbole, that there are probably as many hierarchies in practice as there are castes. 23 Typically, non-ruling castes attribute their depressed status to historical misfortune or trickery on the part of the current ruling caste. According to the dominant caste theory of M.N. Srinivas, dominant castes impose their private beliefs on those within their territory. 24 The publicly accepted hierarchy, thus, is determined by the ruling group, rather than the ruling group being determined by a publicly accepted hierarchy as Dumonts theory would suggest. The horizontal view of caste, as a flexible system of selfdifferentiating groups rather than a strict vertical hierarchy with a well-defined power structure, challenges researchers to explain the persistence of the caste system in the face of industrialization. A 1995 country report commissioned by the US Library of Congress, states, One irony of Indian politics is that its modern secular democracy has enhanced rather than reduced the political salience of traditional forms of social identity such as caste. 25 Identifying the mechanisms that have sustained caste identification through industrialization will clarify the theoretical relationship between reservations and caste persistence.
Dipankar Gupta. Continuous Hierarchies and Discrete Castes. Economic And Political Weekly, 19(47):20032005, 1984. 23 Dipankar Gupta. Caste, Race, Politics. Seminar, 508(1), 2001. 24 M. N. Srinivas. The Dominant Caste and Other Essays. Oxford University Press, Delhi, Oxford, 1987. 25 James Heitzman and Robert L. Worden, editors. India: A Country Study. GPO for the Library of Congress, Washington, 1995.
22
Page
EXOGENOUS ENFORCEMENT: PUNISHMENT FOR DEVIATION One class of explanation posits that individuals remain within the boundaries of their caste network out of fear of punishment from society as a whole. An economic model employing this assumption was proposed by George Akerlof in 1976 and expanded on by James Scoville in 1996. 28 These models demonstrate the existence of stable caste equilibrium in the labour market, where deviators are completely excluded from the labour market. Those who fail to follow, or even to enforce the caste customs do not gain the profits of the successful arbitrageur but instead suffer the stigma of the outcaste. 29
26Dipankar
Gupta. Caste, Race, Politics. Seminar, 508(1), 2001. 27 A. P. Barnabas and Subhash C. Mehta. Caste in Changing India. The Indian Institute of Public Administration, New Delhi, India, 1965. 28 George Akerlof. The Economics of Caste and of the Rat Race and Other Woeful Tales Author (s): George Akerlof Source: The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 90, No. 4 (Nov., 1976), pp. 599-617 Published by: The MIT Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/sta. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90(4):599617, 1976. James G. Scoville. Of Labour Market Underpinnings of a Caste Economy: Foiling the Coase Theorem. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 55(4):385394, 1996. 29 George Akerlof. The Economics of Caste and of the Rat Race and Other Woeful
Page
This assumption implies a high degree of rigidity in the labour market, which is consistent with the long-term equilibrium that existed before Indias industrialization, but is difficult to justify in modern India. The enforcement of caste customs generally takes place at the village level, through a local extra-judicial body known as the caste panchayat.30 These punishments are only enforceable within a single caste. Furthermore, caste identity is not linked to physical appearance outside of a given geographical region.31 Punishments, then, that rely on the coordination of agents outside of the violators network, are simply not credible. An outcaste individual will pay a price, but it is not complete exclusion from the labour market across India. Given the lack of an identifiable enforcement mechanism that fulfils the necessary assumptions, models based on exogenous enforcement alone are not sufficient to analyze the relationship between marriage and reservations
ENDOGENOUS ENFORCEMENT: INCENTIVES TO MEMBERSHIP More recent work on caste persistence has focused on the benefits that individuals derive from their caste networks rather than outside punishments for deviation. The forfeiture of these benefits can be interpreted as the punishment an individual accepts for exiting his caste network, and rely only on the local caste network for enforcement. In industrialized India, an
Tales Author (s): George Akerlof Source: The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 90, No. 4 (Nov., 1976), pp. 599-617 Published by: The MIT Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/sta. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90(4):599617, 1976. 30 Prem Chowdhry. Caste Panchayat and the Policing of Marriage in Haryana: Enforcing kinship and territorial exogamy, chapter 1, pages 142. Sage Publications, New Delhi, Thousand Oaks, London, 2004. 31 D.N. Majumdar and Rao C.R. Race Elements in Bengal: A Quantitative Study. Asia Publishing House and Statistical Publishing Society, Calcutta, 1960. Partha P. Majumdar, B. Uma Shankar, Amitabha Basu, Kailash C. Malhotra, Ranjan Gupta, Barun Mukhopadhyay, M. Vijayakumar, and Subrata K. Roy. Anthropometric variation in India: A statistical appraisal. Current Anthropology, 31(1):94, 1990
Page
10
individual is not excluded from the work force but he does lose the benefits of his caste network. Kaivan Munshi of Brown University and Mark Rosenzweig of Harvard University have identified non-governmental benefits to caste membership, modelling caste networks as informal credit and insurance markets.32 This work implies that many Indians lack access to modern credit and insurance markets, and instead rely on informal caste networks. Munshi and Rosenzweig look at individuals who migrate from rural to urban areas for increased employment opportunities. These individuals no longer have access to their traditional credit and insurance network. An important implication of this model is that caste networks are substituting for modern institutions to which members do not have access; caste networks are not providing any benefits that cannot be replaced by modern financial institutions. Given the implications of this model, it is reasonable to suppose that the influence of caste will fade as members gain access to modern financial institutions. Another type of benefit from caste membership is identified by Evan Osborne of Wright State University who proposes a theory of political pressure groups. According to Osborne, caste networks serve as pre-existing, rentseeking factions who alleviate the traditional collective action problems of freeriding and excludability. Osborne documents a wide range of behaviours that support the theory that caste groups are increasingly motivated by political rentseeking, including shifting, non-traditional alliances between caste groups, increasing proportions of Indians entitled to reservations, and a disproportionate growth in benefits to more populous groups. 33
KD Munshi and MR Rosenzweig. Why is mobility in India so low? Social insurance, inequality, and growth. NBER Working Paper, 2009 Mark R. Rosenzweig and Oded Stark. Consumption smoothing, migration, and marriage: Evidence from rural India. Journal of Political Economy, 97(4):905, 1989. 33 Evan Osborne. Culture, Development, and Government: Reservations in India. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49(3):659685, 2001.
32
Page
11
For the majority of Indians, the benefits that accrue to these political pressure groups cannot be duplicated by any other modern institution. Although political special interest groups exist in many modern democracies, they are not as efficient or accessible as caste based interest groups. The conceptualization of caste groups as political pressure groups provides no indication that caste identification will fade with time, and has given rise to concerns that the reservation system is actually strengthening caste identification. 34
A. P. Barnabas and Subhash C. Mehta. Caste in Changing India. The Indian Institute of Public Administration, New Delhi, India, 1965.
34
Page
12
POLICY IMPLICATIONS
An accurate understanding of the caste system is critical to understand the full implication of reservation policies. The conflation of race and caste, for example, changes the ultimate goal of reservation policy. Once we apply the language of race to the caste situation the emphasis shifts from removing the scourge of caste from Indian society to making ones caste identity a fixed political resource. In which case, quite understandably, castes would tend to be viewed as permanent fixtures and caste identities as political assets. The task would then be not so much to eradicate castes but to give proportionate representation to different castes in educational institutions, in jobs, housing, and so on. 35 NORMATIVE CONSIDERATIONS While some Indians clearly favour eradication of caste over equalization, the actual intent of policy makers remains unclear. Members of the Mandal Commission, for example, were clearly more concerned with equalization than with eradication, but that was not true of all politicians of that time 36 , nor is it true of all politicians today. The Supreme Court of India demonstrated the relevance of this question in a recent opinion: There is another question which has been emphasized by learned counsel for the petitioners is that the policy of reservation cannot be and should not be intended to be permanent or perpetuate backwardness. 37 These views express concern over the long-term implications of caste identification, but one must also account for the private benefits of caste membership before passing judgement on the system. Members receive the economic benefits identified by Munshi and Rosenzweig, but also derive nonDipankar Gupta. Caste, Race, Politics. Seminar, 508(1), 2001. M.N. Srinivas. There is a Vested Interest in Backwardness, 1961. 37 Arijit Pasayat and Lokeshwar Singh Panta. Writ Petition 256 of 2006 Thakur Vs. Union of India and Ors, 2007.
35 36
Page
13
tangible benefits from belonging to a dense kinship network. Although the inequalities created by the caste system are universally condemned, it is not clear that public opinion supports the abolition of the caste system. Supposing that negative aspects of the caste system, such as inequality, discrimination, and labour-market rigidity, could be neutralized; there are still reasons to believe that the very existence of caste networks will have negative consequences for the future of India. Caste networks are similar in many ways to Mancur Olsons distributional coalitions38 or James Madisons factions. 39 Both of these political theorists warn against the growth of groups, united in a common interest, that organize with the intent of influencing the democratic process to favour their private interest over the public good. While these arguments certainly have merit, it is not clear how well they apply to India. Madisons prescription against faction was a large and diverse republic, where a single faction would be unable to capture political power. India is nothing if not large and diverse, so it may be protected from capture by a single caste or caste coalition. Olsons argument, too, leaves hope for India even under the continued influence of caste. Olson writes that his theory of collective action is consistent with the observed stagnation of India, though he cautions that there may be too little sound data to draw conclusions about the effects of the caste system. 40 Ultimately, the distinction between equalization and elimination is normative, and should be made by the people of India. There is not enough evidence to make a positive judgement on a theoretical caste system where opportunities have been equalized between castes. Caste networks could simply
Mancur Olson. The Rise and Decline of Nations. Yale University Press, New Haven, 1982. 39 Michael A. Genovese, editor. The Federalist Papers: Alexander Hamilton, James Madison, John Jay. Palgrave Macmillan, New York, 2009. 40 Mancur Olson. The Rise and Decline of Nations. Yale University Press, New Haven, 1982.
38
Page
14
evolve to resemble large, closely-knit extended families. The purpose of this paper, then, is not to recommend one strategy over the other as a solution to caste inequality, but only to clarify the actual impacts of reservations. FITTING THEORY TO REALITY Proponents of reservations, argue that non-governmental benefits, such as those identified by Munshi and Rosenzweig, are sufficient to sustain the caste system and its accompanying inequalities. Individuals from rural, backwards classes will lose access to their traditional savings and insurance networks if they pursue education or work in an urban area. They must be given priority access to educational and employment opportunities to reduce the risk associated with this migration. Proponents may acknowledge the drawbacks of the reservation system, but argue that reservations are the only feasible mechanism to reduce inequality in the short-run. A system based on some other measure of inequality, such as income, is simply not practical. Opponents of reservations may recognize the historic inequalities imposed by the caste system, but argue that reservations are actually counterproductive. While they may decrease inequality for select individuals from disadvantaged castes, they also serve to perpetuate caste identity and caste based discrimination. Reservations perpetuate caste identity by providing incentives for caste groups to organize into political pressure groups.41 They fuel discrimination by giving priority access to individuals from disadvantaged groups, who may be judged as undeserving as or less competent than their peers.42
Evan Osborne. Culture, Development, and Government: Reservations in India. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49(3):659685, 2001. 42 A. P. Barnabas and Subhash C. Mehta. Caste in Changing India. The Indian Institute of Public Administration, New Delhi, India, 1965
41
Page
15
Both of these arguments are consistent with the current social theory surrounding the caste system, but there is no empirical evidence supporting one view over the other. Quantitative studies have generally focused on the effect of reservations on inequality. These studies investigate whether the reservation system is meeting its stated goals, that of reducing inequality. Empirical work has shown that reservations do reduce inequality, but no empirical studies have been done on the unintended consequences of the reservation system
Page
16
CONCLUSION
Reservation policy is an extremely contentious issue in India. The argument that reservations perpetuate caste affiliation is one of many made against reservations. Proponents of reservations either do not recognize caste affiliation as inherently negative or argue that the benefits of reservations outweigh the drawbacks. The analytical results presented in the studies of Michael D. Barker43 support the latter argument, that caste based reservations help members of historically depressed castes to advance socially and transcend their historic positions in society, with some caveats. The first caveat concerns the effects of unobserved caste network characteristics. According to the observable evidence, individuals eligible for reservations are more likely to marry out of their caste than individuals who are not eligible for reservations, all other things equal. The direction of the effect is well-supported, given reasonable assumptions about the nature of unobserved characteristics of caste networks. The second caveat is related to the assumption of exogenous preferences such that some proportion of individuals will prefer to marry out of their own caste. If individuals who are more ambitious, less caste conscious, and of higher ability (high-types) consistently renounce their caste affiliation, average caste characteristics will become more caste conscious, less ambitious, and of lower ability (low-types). In the absence of reservations, networks subject to these pressures would dissolve as the benefits of network membership decline. With reservations, however, it is conceivable that new, stable caste equilibrium could emerge, in which primarily low-type caste networks persist indefinitely.
Michael D. Barker THE EFFECT OF RESERVATIONS ON CASTE PERSISTENCE IN INDIA Washington, DC April 15, 2010
43
Page
17
The existence of equilibrium of this type would imply that the effect of reservations on exogamy, while currently positive, would gradually decrease and become negative. Thus while this analysis suggests that reservations are currently helping individuals transcend their hereditary station, it does not imply that reservations will always have this effect. Arguments against reservation policy based on the perceived retrenchment of caste networks may not be valid given the current composition of caste networks, but they have the potential to gain relevance with time. While it is always useful to learn more about the effects of a given policy, this analysis and others like it will have little impact unless the actual goal of reservation policy is clarified. Is the intent of reservations to equalize the opportunities between castes or to leave caste behind completely? If the reservations are intended to equalize opportunity between castes, then they should be expanded to include all caste groups according to their share of the total population.
If the goal instead is the eventual elimination of caste boundaries, then the reservation system may have to be phased out or transitioned to a non-caste system of benefit allocation. Without this change, it is likely that the caste system will maintain its highly influential role in Indian society.
Cast struggle exists because we fail to educate our own compatriots; we fail to take the responsibility. You can argue that there are still some areas where people are struggling with their status in society to this present day and change comes slow in our lives but that is simply an excuse for running away from our social responsibilities
Page
18
SELECTED BIBLIOGRAPHY
George Akerlof. The Economics of Caste and of the Rat Race and Other Woeful Tales Author (s): George Akerlof Source: The Quarterly Journal of Economics , Vol. 90, No. 4 (Nov., 1976), pp. 599-617 Published by: The MIT Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/sta. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90(4):599617, 1976. Abhijit Banerjee, Esther Duflo, Maitreesh Ghatak, and Jeanne Lafortune. Marry for What? Caste and Mate Selection in Modern India. 2009. A. P. Barnabas and Subhash C. Mehta. Caste in Changing India. The Indian Institute of Public Administration, New Delhi, India, 1965. C. Chakraberty. Racial Basis of Indian Culture. Aryan Books International, New Delhi, India, 1997. Prem Chowdhry. Caste Panchayat and the Policing of Marriage in Haryana: Enforcing kinship and territorial exogamy, chapter 1, pages 142. Sage Publications, New Delhi, Thousand Oaks, London, 2004. Bhagwan Das. Moments in a History of Reservations. Economic and Political Weekly, 35(43/44):WS31WS34, 2000. Rajeev H. Dehejia and Vivek H. Dehejia. Religion and Economic Activity in India: An Historical Perspective. Journal of Economics and Sociology, 52(2):145153, 1993. Sonalde Desai, Amaresh Dubey, B.L. Joshi, Mitali Sen, Abusaleh Sharif, and Reeve Vanneman. India Human Development Survey: Design and Data Quality. L Dumont. Homo hierarchies. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1966. L. Leigh Field, Sira Surje, and K. Ajit Ray. Immunoglobulin (GM and KM) Allotypes in the Sikh population of India. American Journal of Physical Anthropology, 75(1):3135, 1988. Michael A. Genovese, editor. The Federalist Papers: Alexander Hamilton, James Madison, John Jay. Palgrave Macmillan, New York, 2009. Dipankar Gupta. Continuous Hierarchies and Discrete Castes. Economic And
Page
19
Page
20
Political Weekly, 19(47):20032005, 1984. Dipankar Gupta. Continuous Hierarchies and Discrete Castes Consequences of the Above. Economic and Political Weekly, 19(48):20492053, 1984. Dipankar Gupta. Caste, Race, Politics. Seminar, 508(1), 2001. John Harris. Why Poor People Stay Poor in Rural South India. Social Scientist, 8(1):20, August 1979. James Heitzman and Robert L. Worden, editors. India: A Country Study. GPOfor the Library of Congress, Washington, 1995. Government of India. National Commission for Backward Classes, 2010. Government of India and Ministry Of Law and Justice. The constitution of India, 2006. Craig Jeffrey. A Fist Is Stronger than five fingers: caste and dominance in rural North India. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 26(2):217236, 2001. Dharma Kumar. The Affirmative Action Debate in India. Asian Survey, 32:290 302, 1992. D.N. Majumdar and Rao C.R. Race Elements in Bengal: A Quantitative Study. Asia Publishing House and Statistical Publishing Society, Calcutta, 1960. Partha P. Majumdar, B. Uma Shankar, Amitabha Basu, Kailash C. Malhotra, Ranjan Gupta, Barun Mukhopadhyay, M. Vijayakumar, and Subrata K. Roy. Anthropometric variation in India: A statistical appraisal. Current Anthropology, 31(1):94, 1990. B.P. Mandal. The Mandal Commission Report, 1980. Steven Martin, Manjistha Banerjee, and Sonalde Desai. Is Education Associated with a Transition towards Autonomy in Partner Choice? A Case Study of India. 2008. Karl Marx and Frederick Engels. Collected works, vol. 12. International Publishers, New York, 1979. KD Munshi and MR Rosenzweig. Why is mobility in India so low? Social insurance, inequality, and growth. NBER Working Paper, 2009. Mancur Olson. The Rise and Decline of Nations. Yale University Press, New Haven, 1982. Evan Osborne. Culture, Development, and Government: Reservations in India. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49(3):659685, 2001. Arijit Pasayat and Lokeshwar Singh Panta. Writ Petition 256 of 2006 Thakur Vs. Union of India and Ors, 2007.
David Reich, Kumarasamy Thangaraj, Nick Patterson, Alkes L Price, and Lalji Singh. Reconstructing Indian population history. Nature, 461(7263):48994, 2009. Mark R. Rosenzweig and Oded Stark. Consumption smoothing, migration, and marriage: Evidence from rural India. Journal of Political Economy, 97(4):905, 1989. James G. Scoville. Of Labour Market Underpinnings of a Caste Economy: Foiling the Coase Theorem. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 55(4):385394, 1996. M. N. Srinivas. The Dominant Caste and Other Essays. Oxford University Press, Delhi, Oxford, 1987. M.N. Srinivas. There is a Vested Interest in Backwardness, 1961. Reeve Vanneman, S. Desai, and James Noon. Social Capital in India: Networks, Organizations, and Confidence. 2006 Michael D. Barker THE EFFECT OF RESERVATIONS ON CASTE PERSISTENCE IN INDIA Washington, DC April 15, 2010
Page
21