Ipo Anomalies Truncated Excess - 2
Ipo Anomalies Truncated Excess - 2
Ipo Anomalies Truncated Excess - 2
Roy H. M. Sembel
J.M.Katz Graduate School of Business, University of Pittsburgh
Comments and suggestions are welcome.
(412) 621 8547, e-mail:[email protected]
First Draft: September 1994
This version: 16 March 1995
Abstract
I. INTRODUCTION
II. IPO ANOMALIES AND EXISTING EXPLANATIONS
III. MODEL AND IMPLICATIONS
IV. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
APPENDIX
I. INTRODUCTION
Capital is the bloodstream of firms/corporations. There are several ways firms can acquire
capital.1 Selling stock to the general public is one important way to do it. When a firm
raises capital by selling shares for the first time to the general public, the offering is called
the initial public offering. The stock offerings usually involve investment bankers.2 Initial
public offerings (IPOs) are man-hour-intensive deals for underwriters and important big
decisions for the private owners of firms. Each year there are a lot of firms launching their
initial public offerings (see table 1).
Year 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91
Number of IPOs 259 438 198 848 516 507 953 630 435 371 276 367
1 For an excellent discussion of problems/anomalies related to the capital acquisition process, see Smith (1986).
2 For a theoretical discussion about underwriting agreement between firms and investment bankers, see Mandelker and Raviv (1977),
Bower (1989).
Source: Loughran et al, 1994.
IPO has always been an interesting research topic for decades. IPO involves a large sum of
money and yet several phenomena are still puzzling. For example, right after the IPO, the
prices of the stocks on average jump significantly causing a large average initial return
(many researchers call it 'underpricing' phenomenon/anomaly). However, in the long run,
the IPO stocks on average underperform the market (the long-term underperformance
anomaly). In addition, there is an apparent cycle of period with high and low initial returns
(the hot-cold issue phenomenon).
Existing explanations for the phenomena are still not satisfactory. Some explanations
based on underpricing by underwriters, investors rationality and market efficiency can
explain the existence of the 'underpricing' anomaly but can not explain the long-term
underperformance anomaly. Other set of explanation can explain the anomalies, but it is
based on investors' irrationality and overreaction, and does not give economic reasons why
they fail to behave rationally and/or why the investors consistently overreact (as opposed
to underreact). A more complete comprehension of the phenomena is useful for all parties
involved in the IPO process. Research to look for new or complement explanations are
still needed. The objective of this article is to find an explanation that can explain the IPO
anomalies without having to assume investors irrationality, and build a simple model to
capture the idea.
I develop and model a different view for explaining the anomalies. Unlike the mainstream
explanations that assume underwriters set the initial price deliberately below their
valuation, my model is based on assumptions that the underwriters price the IPOs exactly
at their valuations and their valuations on average hit the full information value of the
firms. Furthermore, it is based on investor rationality assumptions and takes into account
deviations from perfect market conditions caused by the IPO procedures. These
circumstances are shown to imply the existence of the IPO anomalies.
My simple model turns out to have rich implications that can explain not only the
'underpricing', long-term underperformance, and hot/cold issue phenomena, but also other
related empirical evidence on IPOs such as the relationship between 'underpricing' and
uncertainty, cross sectional variation in the IPO initial returns, certification hypothesis, etc.
I also explore the implications of the model on the over-allotment option, IPO volume,
institutional investors' role, etc.
Chapter II describes the IPO anomalies and the existing mainstream explanations.
Empirical evidence and arguments are presented to show the weaknesses of the existing
explanations. Also, in this chapter, I briefly explain the differences between my model and
the existing explanations. Chapter III discusses my model. First, the intuition behind the
model is presented. Second, the simple formal model is developed. Then, the IPO
anomalies and other related empirical evidence are analyzed using the model as the point
of reference. Some ways to directly test my model are also suggested. The summary,
conclusions, and further possible extension/future research agenda are given in chapter IV.
2
To make the model easier to follow, the IPO procedures and example of IPO time table
are described in the appendix. 1.
As a result of previous empirical research, researchers have found some interesting IPO
anomalies. There are three most important and puzzling IPO phenomena:
3
Aggarwal, et al (1993) Brazil 1980-90 90.2%
Aggarwal et al (1993) Chile 1982-90 19.1%
Aggarwal et al (1993) Mexico 1987-90 33%
* The latter is the average initial return for IPOs whose opening were delayed due to excessive demand,
the former is for the non-delayed IPOs.
It is puzzling that the price of IPO shares on average jumps in the after-market. The jump
cannot be explained by the market movement. If this phenomenon is really what its name
('underpricing') connotes then it may hurt the firms. It implies that the firms on average get
less than what they deserve. The implicit assumptions behind the terminology
'underpricing' are the prices in the after-market reflect the market-perceived true value of
the firm while the prices set by underwriter/firm in the initial market (the offering prices)
are on average below the market-perceived true value of the firm.
Empirical evidence on this anomaly is relatively still in the early stage. An early evidence
of long-term underperformance was documented by Stern and Bornstein (1985). Out of
1922 IPOs between January 1 1975 and June 30 1985, they found only 600 IPOs (31%)
performed better than the contemporaneous S&P 500 index. Another important article in
this area is the article by Ritter (1991). Using IPO data 1975-84 Ritter found that in the
after-market, IPO stocks underperformed the market after about three years of seasoning.
The evidence of underperformance is later updated and confirmed by Loughran & Ritter
(1993) using IPO data 1970-89. Long-term underperformance was also documented by
Keloharju (1993) for IPO in Finland, Levis (1993) for UK, Aggarwal et al (1993) for
Brazil, Chile and Mexico, but was insignificant for IPO in Japan according to research by
Hwang & Jayaraman (1992).5 6
Hot issues are defined as stock issues whose prices have risen from their offering prices to
higher than average premia in the after-market. Hot issue IPO markets happen when
5 Hwang & Jayaraman used the data from the bull market of the 1980s up to 1989. The Japanese market fell sharply since the market
peak at the end of 1989. Their results are also sensitive to the benchmark used.
6 Another possibly related anomaly is the underperformance of newly listed stocks on the NYSE and AMEX during the postlisting period.
Makhija, et al, (1989) found that this anomaly was not caused by (temporary) reduction in the riskiness of the stocks after the listing.
Using data of 2,235 newly listed stocks 1965-1984, they found evidence that instead of lower risk after listing, riskiness was greater than
in later periods.
T
∑
7 CAR (T) = (rt - bt)
t=1
CAR(T) = Cumulative Abnormal Return at from time 0 to time T
rt = return of the IPO portfolio from time t-1 to time t (t=0 is the offering time)
bt = return of the benchmark portfolio from time t-1 to time t
4
average initial returns on the new issues are abnormally high for a prolonged period.
Ibbotson & Jaffe (1975) and Ritter (1984) found that the degree of 'underpricing' (initial
return) varied from period to period and formed a cycle of high (hot) and low (cold)
initial return and sometimes varied from sector to sector. The cycle is also visible for the
IPO volume.
A lot of research are devoted to searching the explanation of the anomalies. Most of the
research looked for explanations of the 'underpricing' phenomenon. The mainstream
explanations can be categorized into three groups: Underpricing, overreaction, and other
(miscellaneous) explanations. In general, the underpricing-based explanations argue that
for some reasons, the offering price is deliberately set by the firm/underwriter below the
market-perceived true value per share. In the immediate after-market, price correctly
reflects the market-perceived true value per share, therefore the price will be higher than
the offering price. As a result, a positive initial return will be observed. This explanation
can not explain the occurrence of the long-term underperformance anomaly. The second
group of explanations (overreaction) can explain the 'underpricing' as well as the long-
term underperformance anomaly. However, the word overreaction and the view that
investors are irrational are very uncomfortable and hard to swallow for most finance
scholars that believe in the rationality of investors.
1. Underpricing-based explanations:
1.1. Compensation against risk. Under a firm commitment contract, underwriter will have
to absorb the remaining new issue stocks that cannot be absorbed by the market (e.g.,
because of overpricing). 'Underpricing' -this explanation suggests- is a way to compensate
the risk averse underwriter against this risk. However, it is not clear whether this
mechanism is efficient to compensate the underwriter. It is always possible to take this risk
into account directly in the underwriter compensation contract. In addition, this
explanation also implies that the firm commitment IPOs should be underpriced more than
the best efforts IPOs. Empirical evidence does not support this implication. Using 1977-
1982 IPO data, Ritter (1984) found that best efforts IPOs were on average 'underpriced'
more than the firm commitment ones (average initial returns: 47.78% for best efforts
offers, 14.80% for firm commitment offers).
1.2. Mitigation of winner's curse. Some researchers argue that the 'underpricing' is set
deliberately by the firm/underwriter to mitigate winner's curse problem facing the
uninformed investors (Rock[1986], Beatty and Ritter [1986]). According to this
explanation, the informed investors, who know the market-perceived true value of the
stock, only submit their bids if the offer price is less than the market-perceived true value
per share. The uninformed investors do not know whether the price is higher or lower than
the market-perceived true value per share. Therefore if the uninformed investors were to
submit bid in every IPOs, they would face an unfortunate situation: when the offer price is
greater than the market-perceived true value (overpricing) the probability of the
5
uninformed getting allocation is relatively high, because the number of investors
submitting bid is relatively small (since the informed investors do not participate), and
when the offer price is less than the market-perceived true value ('underpricing') the
probability of getting allocation is relatively low, because the number of investors
submitting bid is relatively large (since the informed investors participate). This is called
the winner's curse phenomenon: when the uninformed investors get allocation (become a
'winner'), it is more likely that the stock is overpriced. Therefore the return on investment
for the uninformed investors is lower than the unconditional return. To induce the
uninformed investors to submit bid, IPOs should be on average underpriced. Implicit
assumption behind this explanation is that the demand from the informed investors is not
sufficient to absorb the IPO stocks. However, the empirical evidence indicates that it is
very common for the new issues to be oversubscribed significantly. For example, the
oversubscription of IPOs in Singapore is on average 29.4 times the offering size (Koh and
Walter [1989]). Moreover, even if the demand from the informed investors is not
sufficient, there is still a potential free rider problem among the issuers. The issuers know
that in aggregate IPOs should be underpriced to attract the uninformed, but individual
issuer has incentive to free ride, i.e., to deviate from 'underpricing' scheme and let the
other issuers underprice their issue.
1.3. Leaving good taste in investors mouth or signaling the quality of firms. Some
researchers argue that 'underpricing' is a way of high quality firm to signal its quality.
Grinblatt and Hwang [1989], Allen and Faulhaber [1989], Welch [1989]8 developed
formal models to capture this idea. Under some range of parameters' values a separating
equilibrium exists in which the high quality firm will underprice its share in the IPO market
while the low quality firm prefers not to mimic the high quality firm's action. The high
quality firm can afford to underprice in the first issue because it can recover the lost in the
subsequent issues after their true quality is revealed, i.e., the total proceed from the IPO
market plus the seasoned market is larger than what it will receive if it does not underprice
(in which case a pooling equilibrium exists, both high and low quality firm will be valued
at the same price, the average price, based on the average quality). Thus, the positive
initial return is a result of the underpricing by the high quality firm under the separating
equilibrium conditions. Using a sample of 494 IPOs between January 1 1980- December
31 1983, Garfinkel [1993] found evidence that did not support this explanation:
- 'underpricing' has an insignificant effect on the likelihood of reissue after controlling for
other variables that may affect both the probability of reissue and 'underpricing'.
- 'underpricing' has no significant impact on the probability that insiders will sell shares in
the open market some time after the IPO (under signalling theories, firms with greater
'underpricing' should exhibit greater insider selling in the after-market), after controlling
for ex-ante uncertainty, the firms' post IPO stock price performance, and the partial
adjustment phenomenon.
8 Another classic signalling-like theoretical model, that is not developed specifically for IPO, is Leland and Pyle (1977).
6
'underpricing' their IPOs. 'Underpricing' makes it easier for the underwriter to market the
issue. The explanation fails to take into account the long-term reputational effect of
cheating and the possibility of the new issuers to learn from previous historical
performance of the underwriters combined with the competition among the underwriters.
Other researchers see 'underpricing' as an agency conflict between the firm -the principal-
and the underwriter -the agent- (Barron, [1982]). In Baron's model, the underwriter is
better informed about the appropriate price of the new issued stock. New firms that want
to go public seek pricing advice from the underwriter. The underwriter has an incentive to
underprice the issue because the lower the price the less effort the underwriter must
expend to market the new issue and also the lower the probability that the underwriter has
to absorb the remaining unsold stocks because the issue is undersubscribed. Interestingly,
this model implies that if the issuing firm is an investment banker/underwriter, there should
not be any 'underpricing'. This implication is tested and refuted by Muscarella and
Vetsuypens [1989]. Using 38 IPOs of investment banking firms who market their own
IPOs, they found that the issues were 'underpriced' at a similar level compared to other
regular IPOs. That is a direct evidence against the principal-agent explanation.
1.5. Insurance against lawsuits. This explanation is based on the fact that in the USA,
investors can sue an investment banker to recover damage of buying bad IPOs. The
'underpricing' is a form of insurance against lawsuits launched by the IPO buyers if the
after-market price drops (Tinic, [1989]). Firms/underwriters underprice the issue to
reduce: (i) the probability of lawsuit, (ii) the conditional probability of adverse judgement
if a lawsuit is filed, (iii) the amount of damages in the event of an adverse judgement.
Drake and Vetsuypens [1993] studied 93 IPOs that were later sued. Their findings do not
support Tinic's hypothesis. They found no significant relation of 'underpricing' and
probability of being sued. Law suit occurs after a significant drop in the after-market
performance (as opposed to initial overpricing).9 The 93 IPOs are not overpriced, but
instead as 'underpriced' as other IPO stocks of similar size. In addition, the law suits are
usually a class action ones. All shareholders who bought shares within about 15 months
after the IPOs are eligible. The eligibility of the after-market shareholders makes the initial
'underpricing' irrelevant. International evidence of 'underpricing' in the countries where
there are no lawsuit against IPO firms also support Drake and Vetsuypens conclusion. In
these countries, 'underpricing' phenomenon still exists.10 Thus, this insurance hypothesis
can not be a major driving force to generate the 'underpricing',
1.6. Cascade behavior. Welch (1992) suggested that if the sales of the IPO are done in
sequence and investors who are offered later can observe the decisions of investors who
are offered earlier, then if the earlier investors decline the offer, the later investors will
revised their valuation downward. If the earlier investors happen to be investors who have
lower valuation, the cascade behavior will result in the failure of the IPO. To reduce the
probability of failure caused by this cascade/domino effect, the IPOs need to be
underpriced. Notice that the implication of model is very sensitive to the questionable
9 The significant price drop is usually caused by bad news about firm's financial condition, and shareholders who file law suit often claim
that the insiders knew this unfavorable development before the offering but did not properly disclose this information.
10 For comprehensive review of IPO underpricings in many countries see Loughran et al (1994).
7
assumption that the investors can observe the decision by the earlier investors. Also, it can
not explain the long-term underperformance anomaly.
1.7. Cost of soliciting information. Other hypotheses try to explain 'underpricing' for
example by combining Rock's winner's curse hypothesis and the cost of soliciting
information during the marketing process (Benveniste & Spindt [1989], Benveniste &
Wilhelm [1990]). Similar to the other underpricing-based explanations, it can not explain
the long-term underperformance anomaly.
Common to the previous explanations is the notion that the positive IPO return is a result
of deliberate actions (deliberate underpricing) of the firms/underwriters and the
explanations suggest reasons for the rational underwriters to underprice the IPOs. The
explanations treat the investors as a homogenous group or at most consisting of only two
types (informed vs uninformed). I propose that the positive average initial
returns/'underpricing' phenomenon can be observed even without any deliberate actions of
firms/underwriters to underprice the IPO relative to the underwriters' valuation. In my
model, the positive average initial return is a result of the difference/heterogeneity in the
information set facing different potential investors, average excess demand and the
rationing (fixed price and fixed supply) mechanism of the IPO, while the underwriters
price the IPOs on average at the market-perceived true value per share.
2. Overreaction
11 The overreaction hypothesis has its root in some research on stock prices behavior by Werner F De Bondt, Richard H. Thaler, Robert
Shiller, etc. Some of their important works are collected in: Richard Thaler (ed.), 1993, Advances in Behavioral Finance, New York:
Russell Sage Foundation.
8
3. Price support/stabilization by underwriter.
Explanations of the hot-cold issue cycle are usually indirect implications of the explanation
of positive initial return. For example, Ritter (1984) used the Rock's winner's curse model
to develop the changing risk composition hypothesis. Using an implication of the Rock's
model that there is a positive relation between uncertainty and underpricing, the changing
risk composition hypothesis predicts that IPO markets during hot issue periods consist of
firms with high risk. Ritter claimed that he found evidence that did not support changing
risk composition hypothesis because the relation between risk and initial return was not
linear and stationary. However, he did find that the hot IPO market (1980-81) consisted of
riskier firms, and the initial returns are positively related to the some measures of firms'
risk. Claiming that the hot issue market was industry specific (attributable to IPOs of new
firms from the natural resource industry), Ritter suggested an alternative explanation. He
argued that the monopsony power of the fringe underwriters might have been exercised
against the natural resource firms. This monopsony power, in turn, caused the high level
of 'underpricing'. Dunbar (1992) reexamined Ritter's findings by separating the IPOs based
on the underwriting contract: Best efforts vs firm commitment. He found that the hot issue
market of 1980-81 was not industry specific.
1. General ideas
9
Because of costly information and limited wealth, investors will only search for
information until its marginal cost equals expected marginal revenue. Different investors
find different information subset (although the information subset can be overlapping due
to some common public information).
The differential information facing different investors causes some investors to value the
firm's share higher or lower than the market-perceived true value. This diversity in
valuation, combined with the limited wealth available for IPO investment, result in a
downward sloping demand curve. It is assumed that on average the firm/underwriter set
the price correctly at the market-perceived true value per share. When demand exceeds
the fixed supply at the offering price, rationing occurs. Some investors -who based on his
information set- value the share highly but do not receive allocation at the initial price will
bid the price up in the after-market. A new equilibrium is achieved at a price higher than
the initial price. A positive initial return is observed.
The first task is to explain why on average there will be an excess demand in the initial
market. During the pre offering period, the underwriter comes up with a valuation of the
firm, a price estimate of the firm's stock, number of shares to be sold, and then receives
preliminary indications from potential investors about the (potential) market demand at
that price. When the market demand at that price is very disappointing, the underwriter
can always (advise the firm to) withdraw the offering.12 Note that even the firm
commitment contract is not signed until a couple of days before the offering. As a result,
when an IPO is carried out, what is observed is a truncated distribution of excess demand,
i.e., the extreme excess supply (or the negative excess demand) is cut off, such that the
observed excess demand is either about equal to zero or positive.
Suppose when the price is equal to the market-perceived true value the excess demand is
~ ~
X = Demand - Supply. Unconditionally (inter-temporally or over time periods), X is
distributed as q(x), where q(x) is a density function with zero mean. For any x^ ,
~ ^x ~
~
E( X) = ⌠
⌡ x q(x) dx = ⌠
⌡ x q(x) dx + ⌠
⌡ x q(x) dx = 0.
-~ -~ ^x
~ ^x
⌡ x q(x) dx = - ⌠
<=> ⌠ ⌡ x q(x) dx )
^x -~
~ ~
The conditional density of X given X > ^x is
~
~ ^
q(x | X > x ) = q(x)/L, where L = ⌠
⌡ q(x) dx.
^x
12 For example, for the period from January 1 1980 to December 31 1981 Dunbar (1992) found 326 successful (76%) vs 105
withdrawn (24%) firm commitment IPOs, 119 successful (61%) vs 76 withdrawn (39%) best efforts IPOs.
10
~
If left tail ( X < x^ < 0) is truncated, then
~ ^x
E( X | X > ^x ) = ⌠x dx = - ⌠x
~ ~ q(x) q(x)
dx > 0, because q(x) > 0 and for the left tail, x < 0.
⌡ L ⌡ L
^x -~
Thus, on average, there will be a (positive) excess demand.
Another factor that also contributes to the observed average excess demand is the
possibility for the firm to time the IPO. Even before the firm enters into a negotiation with
an investment banker, the firm can make its own investigation about the potential
price/demand schedule of its share. If the firm feels that the current market condition is
too weak to absorb its share, it can always wait for a while until a window of opportunity
appears.13
3. Underwriters
Unlike the existing explanations that take a view that the underwriters deliberately set a
price lower than their estimate of the market-perceived true value per share, my model
take a view that the price set by the underwriter in the initial market on average matches
the market-perceived true value per share (value per share conditional on information
collected by the market as a whole) while the (immediate) after-market price is bid up by
some rational investors based on limited information that the investors possess at that
particular point in time.
A legitimate question arises: If there are investors that will bid the price up in the after
market, why do the underwriters not set the initial price equal to the after-market price? If
one takes a short-term view, the statement sounds very compelling. The problem with the
statement is, the underwriters are long-term players who 'play' the IPO game not just once.
Their reputation (in the investors' point of view) is the key here. When an underwriter
values a company stock at Pa but sell it at Pb > Pa, sooner or later the investors will learn
this overvaluation. If the underwriter continue to play this 'overpricing' game, in the long
run the investors will notice it and will punish the underwriter by stop doing business with
the underwriter or even worse, the investors may sue the underwriter. It will further ruin
the underwriter's reputation and makes it difficult for the underwriter to attract investors
for future IPOs. This reputational notion is substantiated by a 'wisdom' among
practitioners to seek a highest sustainable price for IPO instead of a highest attainable
price.14 When the underwriter set the price at Pa, it is confident that the price is
sustainable. As an added bonus, the underwriter and the firm will enjoy a good
publication when the media report the IPO as a winner (i.e., experiencing price
13 For a recent example of a firm timing its IPO, see Glenn Rifkin, "Anatomy of a Highflying IPO, Nosebleeds and All," The New York
Times, February 19, 1995, p F7. Shiva corporation, a software maker, originally hoped to launch its IPO by summer 1994. After shoping
around, Shiva management found that at that time, market condition was not favorable for the high tech sector. The management decided
to wait. Finally, around the beginning of fall season 1994, the market for high tech rebounded. The wait paid off. Shiva IPO turned out to
be a highflying IPO.
14 See for example, A. M, Adlerman and K. Y. Hao, 'The Initial Public Offering Process', in J. E. Riley and L. H. Simons, III (eds.), How
to Prepare an Initial Public Offering, Practising Law Institute, New York, 1994, p. 389.
11
appreciation afterward). An additional disincentive to adjust the price upward significantly
is the risk of receiving objection from the SEC. SEC gives green light based on the
registration statement. The registration statement contains a preliminary prospectus in
which the estimate range of offering price is stated. The final price has to be reported in
the pricing amendment. If the SEC has objections to the amendment because there are
substantive changes in the amendment, then all the confirmed sales is cancelled. The firm
has to file a post-effective amendment, and the review process begins anew. This situation
can be very costly in term of time and money, and very embarrassing for the firm and the
underwriter. On the other edge, the underwriter also needs to protect its reputation (in the
issuing firms' point of view) by not underpricing the issue. These two 'stabilizing' forces
induce the underwriter to (i) price the IPO at Pa, the market-perceived true value, instead
of Pb, the attainable temporary excess-demand-induced value, and (ii) not to price below
Pa (not to underprice the issue).
4. The investors
Some researchers, using behavioral and psychological arguments, suggested that the
positive initial return is an overreaction phenomenon. The word overreaction conveys an
irrational decision making. Unlike the overreaction proponents, I use economic arguments
and rationality assumption to explain the anomalies. I argue that the positive initial return
is a natural consequence of rational investors who act properly conditioned on their
information set (which consists of public and private information) at the time they make
their decision. It is the differences in the information set (under which the investors react
properly/rationally and hence not overreact) that leads to different valuation that -
combined with the IPO mechanisms that cause deviations from perfect market conditions,
and excess demand circumstances- leads to positive initial returns (improperly called
'underpricing').
At the first glance, the investors, who adopt a strategy to buy in the after-market, are
irrational because they will lose money. There some problems with that statement. It
assumes that (i) ALL investors know ex ante that if they buy shares in the immediate after-
market, on average they will lose money, and (ii) the investors can adopt only a static buy
and hold strategy. If there are some fractions of investors who do not have the knowledge
in their information set (to have the knowledge in the information set is defined as to know
and believe the knowledge) that the price in the immediate after-market on average higher
than the market-perceived true value per share, then ex-ante, it is rational for them to buy
shares in the immediate after-market if based on their valuation the price is cheap.
Also, recall that I assume the underwriter on average (not necessarily in all individual
issues) set the price correctly. It is very possible that for a particular issue the
underwriter's valuation is on the low side of the distribution. In that case, buying at a price
slightly higher than the offering price may result in some profits. Therefore, although on
average the investors will lose money if they adopt the static buy and hold strategy, when
they adopt a slightly different strategy, for example a dynamic cut loss/capital preservation
strategy, they can make money. In a dynamic cut loss strategy, investors get out if the
12
price goes down by a certain percentage point and ride the bull when the price
appreciates.15 This asymmetric option-like payoff makes the strategy suitable for buying
high risk/volatile shares. IPO shares are more likely to face higher level of heterogeneity in
valuations compared with the established/seasoned firms. This high level of heterogeneity
in valuations translates into high risk/volatility because arrival of new information is
relatively more intense surrounding IPO events. Some investors may choose to utilize the
dynamic investment strategy on the IPO shares because the IPO firms have some new
characteristics that are not possessed by the existing seasoned firms. These new
characteristics are reflected in the price behavior of the firms' shares and act as market
completers. They enable the investors to hedge some part of their future consumption
variability/risk. Thus, (i) the option to adopt dynamic strategy explains how the investors
can do better than the benchmark even if buy and hold strategy will on average
underperform the benchmark, (ii) the market completion argument gives one reason for
the investor to utilize the strategy on the IPO shares as opposed to the risky seasoned
shares. The arguments, used together, can explain why it is rational for some investors to
buy IPO shares in the immediate after-market.
Moreover, buy and hold strategy is only for investors with relatively long-term investment
horizon. The underperformance of buy and hold strategy for investing in the IPO stocks is
only significant if the shares are held for relatively long-term period. For some investors,
who have short-term investment horizon (for example the speculators) for any given
shares, the underperformance is not significant. For these short-term investors, decision to
buy shares in the immediate after-market based on their information set is tenable and
rational.
5. Long-term performance
Until now, it has been discussed that one implication of the model is that the immediate
after-market equilibrium price is on average greater than the full information value and/or
the market-perceived true value. This discrepancy will be corrected gradually as
information is revealed over time. The question is how long will it take for the price to
converge to the true value. To answer the question, let's make some comparison with the
seasoned shares. From the literature on empirical evidence regarding mispriced securities,
there are two widely cited empirical studies: DeBondt and Thaler (1985, 1987), and
recently by Lakonishok, et al (1994). The empirical studies found evidence that are
consistent with a hypothesis that overpriced shares gradually converge to their true values
and the convergence process takes 3-5 years. The portfolio of the overpriced shares (the
'winner' portfolio in DeBondt and Thaler, and the 'glamour' portfolio in Lakonishok, et al)
underperformed the benchmark after 3-5 years. Based on this figures, it is not very
surprising for the (excess-demand-induced mispriced) IPO shares to converge gradually, in
3-5 years, to their true values.
15 One popular varian of this strategy is the 'buy high sell higher' strategy, where the investors invest in the firm with high growth potential
and its price is appreciating. An example of this strategy is the C.A.N.S.L.I.M stock investment strategy popularized by Investor's Business
Daily's William J. O'Neil (William J. O'Neil, 1995, 100 Ways to Improve Your Investment Results!, Los Angeles: Investors Business
Daily).
13
Furthermore, let's consider the following theoretical scenario. The demand at the offering
date and the immediate after-market is generated based on N investors who are aware of
the company and considered it to be included in their portfolio. After the company went
public, more information is generated about the company. The information generation
causes two things: (1) the distribution of valuations becomes more precise/less variations,
(2) more investors become aware of the new company and start to consider it to be
included in their portfolio, therefore N increases gradually. This gradual increase in
demand will slow down the convergence process of the market price to the full
information value. As fraction of investors who are aware of the company gets closer to 1,
the speed of the arrival of the newly aware investors becomes slower. It will weaken the
dampening effect of increase in demand. There are also other factors that eventually limit
the dampening effect, for example, competition from existing seasoned shares as well as
new IPO shares. The point is, there are factors that reduce the speed of convergence, but
the factors eventually die down. As a result, the market price will converge to the full
information value, and this convergence process takes some time.
A3. There are many investors, but the number of investors is not infinity.
This, together with A1 and A2, implies even the market collectively can only collect
limited amount of information (out of all possible information) about a particular firm at a
point in time.
A5. Only a fraction of investors know and believe the scenario of the model.
14
The words 'scenario of the model' refer to: (i) underwriters do not underprice, and they on
average prices IPO shares correctly, (ii) due to average excess demand and heterogeneous
valuations by investors, equilibrium price in the immediate after-market is on average
greater than the market-perceived true value per share. A4 and A5 implies that the
knowledge of the scenario of the model is an integrated part of the underwriter's
information set, while -as a part of heterogeneity of information- only a fraction of
investors has this knowledge in their information set. It is realistic to assume that this
knowledge is in the underwriter's information set. It can be defended by the fact that the
underwriter is a long-term/permanent participant and an experienced player/expert in the
IPO market (see also A11). In the meantime, only a fraction of investors (the IPO-
experienced investors) participate regularly and hence can be assumed to also possess the
knowledge in their information set.16 The other investors are occasional/transitory
participants in the IPO market, therefore their knowledge is limited. They do not know the
peculiar characteristic of the IPO market.
A8. On average, the market-perceived true value reflects the full information
value.
Full information value of the firm is the value conditioned on all possible information at a
particular time (Ψt). Market-perceived true value of the firm is the value conditioned on
information set possessed/collected by the market as a whole at a particular time (Ωt). A6
says that market as a whole on average price stocks correctly.
A10. Underwriters, on average price the IPOs at the full information value.
16 Benveniste and Spindt (1989), Benveniste and Wilhelm (1990) argued that 'underpricing' is one mechanism for underwriter to
compensate this permanent investors for revealing their information to the underwritier. For empirical evidence on the existence of
investors that regularly participate in the IPOs, see Hanley and Wilhelm (1995).
17 This assumption can be formalized as a Wiener process:
dµ(t) = a(µ,t) dt + s(µ,t) dZ(t), where dZ(t) = dt u~ and u~ ~ N(0,1)
The certain component a(µ,t) is assumed to be zero.
15
I assume that the firm/underwriter has done their homework properly such that the offered
price is on average equal to the full information value per share.
Short-sellers are most likely to be parties who (i) are very confident with their private
valuations, (ii) have above average credit rating, (ii) have large wealth (as a buffer against
the gambler's ruin problem). Based on these characteristics, the most likely candidate for
short-sellers are the institutional investors who frequently participate in the IPOs.
However, these most likely candidates will not have a good incentive to short-sell because
(i) they have built a good long-term relationship with the underwriters/investment bankers,
(ii) the underwriters reward them by giving them priority in allocation of IPO shares
(Hanley and Wilhelm[1995]), (iii) the underwriters, practicing price stabilization to
prevent after-market price drop, will not be happy to see the institutional investors short-
sell the IPO shares and will punish the short-sellers by excluding them from future
allocation of IPO shares. The threat of being excluded from a relatively secured lucrative
deals provide an economic disincentive to short-sell the IPO shares.
Note also that short selling strategy is on average unprofitable to be applied here.
Although the long-term CAR (starting from the immediate after-market price equilibrium)
is on average negative, the raw return is still on average positive. Short-selling strategy
cannot make money if the price is non-decreasing function of time, which on average is
the case for IPO shares.
16
A13. Without loss of generality, the risk-free interest rate is assumed to be zero.
In term of the Wiener process (A9), the drift component is zero. Overtime, new
information will arrive randomly and changes the full information value. But on average,
the full information value at the time of price setting is the best prediction of the full
information true value of the firm over time.
A14. Investors' wealth available for investment and is exogenously determined and
is the same for all investors.
The purpose of this assumption is to concentrate on important features that affect the final
result without having to complicate the process with unnecessarily difficult to manage
math. Relaxation of this assumption will not likely to change the qualitative results
(positive initial return, long-term underperformance, etc). Differences in individual
valuation regarding the firm, rational decision based on the valuation, limited wealth, and
same wealth across investors enable us to work with smooth demand distribution.
Furthermore, if the distribution of investors' valuations is assumed to be normal/symmetric
bell-shaped distribution, then the demand curve is of a rotated S shape.
A16. ft( ~
v ) does not change between t=T2 to t=0.
For the base case scenario, the unconditional distribution of value per share is assumed to
be the same at T2 (the time the underwriter announces the preliminary offering price) as at
the offering date. This assumption will be relaxed later when analyzing the partial
adjustment phenomenon.
17
Ωt C Ψt
-
Ψt = Set of all possible information at time t = (Ωt, Ωt)
(See Figure 3)
~
v = Per share value of the risky asset, ~ ft( ~ v ),
ft( ~
v ) = The unconditional distribution of ~ v at time t.
Et ( ~
v ) = µt, Vart( ~ v ) = σt2
Mt
E( v |Ωt) = vΩt = ∑ vj / Mt =Market-perceived true value at time t
~ -
j=1
E( v~- Ωt) = µt and Var( v~- Ωt) = σt2 / Mt
Mt = total number of data points or 'random samples' accumulated by the market as a
whole until time t.
E( ~
v |Ψt) = µt = Full information value at time t.
Note that if all possible information is collected by the market, then the market-
perceived true value is exactly the same as the full information value, i.e.,
as Mt --> ~ , Ω --> Ψ , and Var( v~- ) --> 0.
t t Ωt
Underwriter
Ωut = Underwriter's information set at time-t.
The process of information gathering by the underwriter is abstracted as if the
underwriter collects m random samples from the unconditional ft( ~ v ) density, and
summarizes the information in term of a simple average of the samples = v- u which
will become an official offering price (Po) if the IPO is not withdrawn. The
~
distribution of v- u has mean µt, and variance σt2/m. For the base case scenario, it
is assumed that at the time (t) underwriter announces v- u, ft( ~
v ) = f0( ~
v ) (i.e., Ψt =
Ψ0).
Investors
N = Number of investors.
Ωit = {Πt , φit} = Investor-i's information set at time-t
18
on v- u. At around t=0, the final investor-i's valuation becomes a weighted average of the
valuation based on his (private) information, v- i, and the underwriter's valuation, v- u:
v- wi = ki v- u + (1-ki) v- i where 0 < ki < 1
~
thus, the distribution of v- wi has a mean µ0, and a variance σ02[ki2 (1/m + 1/n) - 2ki + 1].
As an abstraction of heterogeneity in investors' confidence in the underwriter's valuation,
the weight ki varies among investors.
ki = k (yi)
y = vector of independent variables that affect k. For example:
(i) Belief about the scenario of the model. Investors who believe in the
underpricing based scenario (in which the underwriter underprices the IPO shares
and the immediate after-market price reflects the market-perceived true value) will
put insignificant weight on v- u. On the other hand, investors who believe that the
underwriter on average price the IPO shares correctly and the immediate after-
market price is bid up by average excess demand, will put substantial weight on v- u.
(ii) Type of investors -long-term investors vs short-term speculators. The
speculators are more likely to put larger weight on his own valuation v- i.
Note that σ02[ki2 (1/m + 1/n) - 2 ki + 1] is a decreasing function of ki. Thus the degree of
heterogeneity in valuations is higher among investors with low k. 18
µio = v- wi
The µio's make up the go(.) density function,
go(.) = Distribution (density function) of individual valuations at t=0;
this distribution is important in forming the market demand function
N
= ∑ ~
density function of v- wi / N
i=1
N
Thus, go(.) has mean = µ0 and variance = ∑ Var( ~v-wi) / N. 19
i=1
19 If g(x), h(x) are density functions with variance Var and Var , and with the same mean µ, and f(x) = c1 g(x) + c2 h(x), c1, c2
g h
constant 0<c1<1, 0<c2<1, c1+c2=1, then based on f(.),
19
Investors as a whole, on average value the shares correctly.
It has been assumed that the firm/underwriters have done their homeworks properly such
that the offered price (P ) is on average equal to µ (i.e., E ( ~
0 v |Ψ ) ), the full information
0 0
value per share at t=0.
Based on the rationality and risk neutrality assumptions, for investor i, the individual
demand function is:
(See Figure 5)
Excess demand function consists of a random (error) component and a systematic (error).
It is assumed that if Po is set exactly at the full information value µ0, then the market
demand is on average equal to the supply. At Po = µ0, excess demand occurs because of
the random component (the noise). The noise is caused by (aggregate) sampling error by
investors as a whole. When Po is not equal to µ0, in addition to the random error, there is
a systematic error component.
∆0(.) = The intrinsic demand function, i.e., the demand if the random component is zero,
and therefore demand equals supply.
20 If µ is not a continuous variable, the integral becomes summation, but the main results stay the same
it
20
ε(.,.) = The random component, due to sampling error by investors/the market as a
whole.
τ(.,.,.) = The systematic component, due to sampling error by the underwriter, and the
difference between, underwriter's sampling error and investors' sampling error.
Time ----------T1-------------T2-----T3-0-0+-------------------------
STEP 1, 2, 3, 4,5, 6, 7,8, 9
STEP 1. Firm has a project that needs capital, and has decided to raise capital through
IPO. Based on NPV and potential dilution consideration, it has been determined that the
minimum required capital to be raised is C min, the maximum number of shares to be issued
is Q, and the minimum acceptable price is Pfloor = Cmin/Q. The unconditional density at
time-t of the firm's value per share is f t( ~
v ), with mean µt and variance σt2
STEP 2. At t = T1 to T2, the underwriter collects information about firm's value. The
information collection will be abstracted as if the underwriter takes a random sample of
size m out of the density f( ~
v ). The underwriter gets v u1, vu2,...,vum , and summarizes the
information:
m
u ∑ vuj
-v =
j=1
2 ~ 2
If ft(.) is N(µt, σt ) then v-u ~ N(µt, σt /m).
Thus, the underwriter on average prices the IPOs correctly at µt. It is assumed that
between t=T2 and t=0 there is not any change in Ψt, ft(.), and hence no change in µt.
STEP 3. At t=T2, the underwriter announce v- u
STEP4. Investors observe v- u. Each investor-i. collects information about firm's value. The
information collection will be abstracted as if the investor takes a random sample of size n
out of the density f( ~ v ). The investor-i gets vi1, vi2,...,vin , and summarizes the
information,
n
v- i = ∑ vij
j=1
2 ~ 2
If f(.) is N(µt, σt ) then v- i ~ N(µt, σt /n).
21
The final investor's valuation takes into account v- i and v- u. Therefore go(.) -the density of
investors' valuations- can be regarded as a distribution of sample mean statistic. Thus, each
investor, and investors as a group, on average come up with the correct valuation µt.
STEP 5. Between T2 and T3, underwriter collects indications of interest from investors,
based on the announced price v- u.
STEP 6. Excess demand consists of a random component (the noise), and a systematic
component (the signal). Using some projection/signal extraction techniques, the
underwriter estimates the systematic component, the full information value, the random
component and the market-perceived true value.
a. IF the random component is significantly negative, and thus the estimated total demand
at the new estimate of µ0 is significantly less than S, THEN the offer is withdrawn.
Otherwise the new price estimate becomes the official offering price Po.
b. IF the random component is positive, and thus estimated total demand is greater than S
THEN the shares are allocated proportionally to investors based on their initial demand.
STEP 7. Based on the final offer price Po and their final valuations (which already took
into account v- i, v- u, and Po) investors make their buying decisions.
STEP 8. In the immediate after-market (t=0+), investors are free to buy and sell the shares.
New equilibrium is achieved at price = P* that equates S and D.
STEP 9. Uncollected information is gradually revealed. As the information is gradually
revealed, the level of the heterogeneity of information is reduced. In the long run, the
market price will converge to the full information value.
Proof:
In the previous section, it has been argued that on average there will be an excess
demand. In the after-market, investors that -based on their information set- value
the firms highly and did not get initial allocation will bid the price up until a new
equilibrium is achieved. The new equilibrium price P* is such that total amount
that the existing shareholders are willing to sell at P* = total amount that investors
are willing to buy at P*.
(See Figure 6 and Figure 7)
P* P0max
N W b⌠ ⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0 = N W (1-b) ⌠ ⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0
P0 P*
S
( b = Probability of getting allocation = min { , 1})
D0(P0)
22
P* P0max P0max
<=> ⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0} = ⌠
⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0 + ⌠
b{ ⌠ ⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0
P0 P* P*
P0max
⌠
⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0
P0max P0max
P*
<=> b ⌠
⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0 = ⌠
⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0 <=> b=
P0max
P0 P*
⌠
⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0
P0
Note that gt(.) > 0 and 0 < b < 1. Therefore,
P0max
⌠
⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0 P0max P0max
P*
0 < P max < 1 <=> 0 < ⌠ ⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0 < ⌠
⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0
0
P* P0
⌠
⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0
P0
=> P0 < P* < P0max o
The main driving forces used in the proof are the fact that there is an average excess
demand and in the after-market, investors are free to buy and sell, and therefore in
equilibrium the shares will be owned by a subset of investors who value the shares higher
than the rest of the pool. Proposition 1 says that in the after-market, price will jump from
P0 to P* even without arrival of any new information or without any change in the full
information value. Note that the positive initial return is not a result of a deliberate action
of the underwriter to underprice the issue (in the sense that the underwriter set the price
below the value according to underwriter's valuation, or P0 < µ0). It is a logical
consequence of excess demand and quantity rationing in the initial distribution of the new
issue.
The following corollary gives the relation between excess demand and initial return. A
higher excess demand can be pictured as: (1) lower supply for a given demand
distribution, or (2) Larger D(Po) for a given supply. Both cases can be represented as a
lower b. Therefore to check the relation between excess demand and the initial return, we
just need to check the relation between b and P*, keeping other variables constant.
Proof:
From proposition 1,
23
P0max
⌠
⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0
P*
b = ,
P0max
⌠
⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0
P0
=>
db
=
- g0(P*)
dP* P0max
< 0, because g0(.) > 0 and P0 < P0max o
⌠
⌡ g0(µi0) dµi0
P0
Corollary 1.1 says that keeping other variables constant, there is a negative relation
between b and P*. The lower the b (the higher the excess demand), the higher the P*,
Because other variables including Po have been kept constant, a higher P* implies a higher
initial return.
Proof:
For IPO shares (t = 0, is the offering date for the IPO shares), by proposition 1
at t = 0+, Pt = P* > Po, and by market efficiency assumption,
E(Po) = µ , E(µ ) = µ , and lim (P - µ ) = 0.
0 t 0 t ->~ t t
For the market benchmark (marked by subscript B), that consists of seasoned
stocks, by market efficiency,
PBt - µBt ~ 0 both at t = 0 and t = T
24
the long run the IPO stock will underperform the market benchmark/seasoned stocks in
the same risk category.
IPO initial return varies from firm to firm. The following proposition (proposition 2) is an
important starting point to investigate the variation in the initial return. It says that the
flatter tail of the gt(µit) implies the position of P* is shifted to the right. Therefore the
difference between P0 and P*, i.e., the initial return, becomes larger.
(See figure 8)
Proof:
To shorten the notations, without loss of generality, we will normalize N W = 1
(so that the density function is the demand function). We will compare two density
functions (previously we used g(.) as a name of the demand density function, but
for this proof other names will be used), one with a thicker tail -call it h(.)- and the
other with a thinner tail -call it k(.).
To save place, we will suspend the subscript for h(.), k(.), and µ.
Because of (1) and because h(.) has a thicker tail than k(.),
∃ x* in interval (P0 ; P0max) ∋ h(µ) > k(µ) for µ > x*, and h(µ) < k(µ) for µ < x*
(see Figure 9).
Suppose under k(.) and h(.), the after-market equilibrium is achieved at P*k and
P*h. Thus,
P0max P0max
Dk(P*k) = ⌠ ⌡ k(µ) dµ = S = ⌠
h h
⌡ h(µ) dµ = D (P* ) .....(2)
P*k P*h
25
P*k P*h
Dk(P0) - S = ⌠
⌡ k(µ) dµ = ⌠
h
⌡ h(µ) dµ = D (P0) - S .....(3)
P0 P0
26
P*k P*k
THEN Dk(P0) - S = ⌠
⌡ k(µ) dµ > ⌠
⌡ h(µ) dµ
P0 P0
Therefore, by equation (3), P*k can not be an equilibrium price under h(.)
Proof:
Higher heterogeneity in valuations is caused by more diverse information sets
facing individual that leads to greater variation in individual valuation. Other things
kept fixed, greater variation will be reflected in a thicker tail distribution of initial
o
valuations by investors, then it follows from proposition 2 that, higher degree of
heterogeneity in valuations implies higher initial return.
27
Corollary 2.1. can also be regarded as a relation between risk and return. The terminology
risk here is risk in general sense (variation in the distribution), but it is slightly different to
the terminology risk used in the asset pricing literature. In the latter field, risk is defined as
volatility of price change over time.
Some researchers have suggested certification as a factor that affects the variation in the
initial IPO return (see for example Booth and Smith [1986]). They argue that if there exist
some credible/qualified long term players that get involved in an IPO, the level of initial
return of the IPO will be closer to zero. The higher the quality/reputation of the certifier,
the closer to zero will be the level of the initial return. Some long term players as certifiers
have been suggested: auditor (Titman and Trueman [1986]), investment banker (Carter
and Manaster [1990]), commercial banker (Slovin and Young [1990]), venture capitalist
(Barry, et al [1990], Megginson and Weiss [1991]), NYSE, AMEX, NASDAQ-NMS
(Afflect-Graves, et al [1993]).
Proof:
Investors will take into account information about quality of underwriter/auditor in
forming their private valuation. The higher the quality of the underwriter, the more
confidence/weight the investors put on the price set by the underwriter, therefore
the distribution of valuation will be more concentrated around that price. It means
o
that the demand distribution has a thinner tail. By proposition 2, the bid in the after
market will be closer to the initial price.
The hot and cold cycle phenomenon can also be understood using the model. When there
are positive exogenous shocks to the market or a particular sector of the market, the
distribution of valuation changes. A greater proportion of investors receives favorable
information and become optimistic about the potential of the to-go-public firms. In the
meantime, underwriters who do not want to jeopardize their reputation will set the initial
price at the market-perceived true value per share. This results in a higher than average
initial returns. The positive shock/new information, works like a positive multiplier to the
original random variable, or can also a combination of shift and multiplier (i.e., ~
v =c+ new
d ~v old, where c > 0 and d > 1) resulting in higher mean and variance21 . It implies a thicker
tail distribution which -by proposition 2- translates into a higher initial return.
21 E( ~
v
~ ~ ~ 2 ~ ~
new) = c + d E( v old) > E( v old), and Var( v new) = d Var( v old) > Var( v old)
28
Alternatively, allowing variation across individual in the wealth available for investment
(Wi), during the hot issue period, optimistic investors are in command of larger pool of
funds available for new investment. As a result, the degree of 'underpricing' is more
severe.
Relation between excess demand and hot/cold issue markets can be analyzed as follows.
According to the logic of the model, the larger is the excess demand, the higher is the
positive initial return. Unconditional (inter-temporal/over time periods) distribution of
excess demand has been assumed to have zero mean. Most of the realizations of positive
excess demand occurs during the hot issue markets, most realizations of the excess supply
(negative excess demand) occurs during the cold markets. Therefore the model predict
that, keeping other factors constant, the fraction of fail IPOs (IPOs with extreme excess
supply) is larger/smaller during the cold/hot issue periods.
Issues that have final offer prices which exceed the limits of the offer range (disclosed in
the preliminary prospectus) have greater initial return than all other IPO and are also more
likely to increase the number of shares issued (Hanley [1993]). Benveniste and Spindt
(1989) predict that the initial return is positively related to revisions in the offer price from
the filing of the preliminary prospectus to offer date; the final offer price only partially
adjusts to new information.
This finding is in line with the reasoning behind my model. The final offer price in my
model already incorporate all information gathered by underwriter during the preliminary
period. Following the reasoning of my model, a positive shock/new information, that may
arrive between the period of preliminary marketing and the time the final offer is set,
works like a positive multiplier to the original random variable, or can also a combination
of shift and multiplier, resulting in higher mean and variance. It implies a thicker tail
distribution which translates into a higher initial return. The higher mean causes an upward
adjustment, the higher variance/thicker tail causes a higher initial return (even after the
initial price is adjusted to the new mean). Thus, although the underwriter already adjusts
properly, it looks as if the price is only partially adjusted.
Alternatively, still in line with my model, it can be explained using a Bayesian updating
argument. Underwriter has a prior estimate/knowledge about the market-perceived true
value of the firm. The underwriter uses this prior to set the range of offering price in the
preliminary prospectus. When the underwriter learn that the excess demand is large, the
underwriter is more likely to update his valuation. Bayesian updating uses both the prior
knowledge and the new information. It works like weighted averaging the prior and the
new information. The final result is somewhere between the prior mean and the new
information mean. Based on the Bayesian updating process, the more confident the
underwriter with his prior valuation, the 'less fully' the price adjusts. In any case, it will be
29
observed as a partial adjustment phenomenon. Appendix 2 gives an example of a Bayesian
updating process.
The period of high IPO volume tends to follow hot issue period (Ritter [1984]). Using my
model, it can be explain as follows: the issuers try to time the offering when there are
plenty of optimistic investors in the market to reduce probability of failure. Price is still set
on average at the market-perceived true value. When firms see a hot issue period, they
know that there are plenty of optimistic investors in the market, and the market is
characterized by excess demand. Thus, they will launch their IPO because the probability
of failure is relatively low. Over time, the flow of these IPOs will reduce the aggregate
excess demand and hence reduce the average initial return. As a result, the market cools
down.
1. Institutional investors.
By relaxing the simplifying assumption of equal wealth to be invested, we can analyze the
role of (informed) institutional investors. If we are willing to assume that institutional
investors (who possess larger amount of wealth (W)) are more informed, then my model
implies the larger participation of institutional investors in the IPO, the more concentrated
to the center is the demand distribution (Wi x g0). Therefore the demand distribution has a
thinner tail, and consequently, it implies lower initial return.
2. Over-allotment option
Over-allotment option is an option to sell extra share at the initial market. Exercising this
option caused an increase in the supply S and therefore will increase b. This will reduce
the excess demand. Selling more stocks at the preset price after knowing the existence of
excess demand will reduce the price increase at the after-market. It implies a lower initial
return. In addition, selling more stocks when the total full information value of firms stays
the same will cause the full information value per share of the stock decline (dilution
effect). However, the over-allotment option is more likely to be exercised when the
potential initial return is very high.
Therefore the exercise of the option has several effects: (1) Supply effect: reduce the
excess demand, (2) Dilution effect: shift the distribution of valuation to the left, (3)
Situational effect: it is more likely to be exercised when the excess demand, and hence the
potential initial return, is relatively high. On one hand, the exercise of the option will cause
a lower initial return (compared with if it is not exercised). On the other hand, it is more
likely to be exercised when the potential initial return is very high in the first place.
Therefore without additional reason and/or assumption we can not tell whether IPOs
without exercise of over-allotment option will have lower or higher initial return than IPOs
30
with exercise of the option. Note that the negative effect is weakened by limitation of
overallotment option. The maximum number of extra shares that can be sold is limited (to
about 10% of the IPO). For large excess demand situation, this limitation may significantly
dampen the negative effect, and therefore the positive effect dominates the negative effect.
My conjecture is IPOs in which the option is exercised will on average experience higher
initial return.
Relaxation of assumption A1-A3, A5 moves the model toward a perfect world without
uncertainty. Under this ideal world, there is not any heterogeneity in information and the
main engine of the previous model breaks down. Therefore these assumptions are very
crucial to the model. However, these assumptions are more realistic than the ideal perfect
world.
Assumption A12 (short-selling is limited) has been discussed in the assumption section.
This assumption turns out to be crucial to get the results. Without short-selling limitation,
the price in the immediate after-market will not be higher than the Po. In the assumption
section, the institutional reason for limited short-selling has been given. In addition, as
long as investors still prefer regular buying transactions compared to short-selling, the
immediate after-market price will on average be higher than Po.
Assumption A16 (no arrival of new information between T2 and 0) has been relaxed and
discussed under section partial adjustment phenomenon. Assumption A14 (Wi = W for all
i) has been analyzed in section institutional investors. Relaxing these assumptions does not
change the qualitative results of the model.
The risk neutrality assumption is needed so that the individual valuation can be abstracted
in much simpler mathematical notations. If we assume risk aversion, then the distribution
of valuations should be corrected for some risk premium. And the final individual
valuation can be formulated as,
v- i,risk averse = v- i,risk neutral - Premium(σt2)
Using this formulation, the distribution of valuation is shifted to the left. Based on this new
distribution, we still have heterogeneity in valuations, therefore the qualitative prediction
of the model will follow through.
The proportional allocation assumption can be relaxed without changing the qualitative
results. This assumption is made to make it mathematically easier to prove the
propositions. Changing this assumption will not change the intuition of the proof which
can be directly seen based on Figure 6 and 7. When the allocation is not proportional, the
shaded areas in Figure 6 and 7 are not as neat (geometrically proportional) as it is pictured
in these Figures. However, as long as there are heterogeneity in valuations and average
excess demand, the equilibrium immediate after-market price P* is greater than Po.
31
In proving the propositions, I have implicitly assumed a nicely behave symmetric
distribution of valuations. Again this assumption is only to make the proof mathematically
less messier and easier to follow. The intuition of the proofs, as can be seen in Figure 6
and 7, is not affected by the shape of the distribution. As long as there are heterogeneity
in valuations, average excess demand if price is set at Po which is on average equals µ0,
P* will be greater than Po.
Proposition 1 gives the positive average initial return result. This result is driven by (1) the
average excess demand, and (2) the uncertainty or heterogeneity of information/variation
in the distribution of investors' valuations. Variation in the initial return is affected by (1)
the level of excess demand (+), and (2) the level of the heterogeneity of information
among investors.
One possible way to directly test the model is by separating the IPOs with and without
excess demand and compare the average initial returns of the two groups. The model
predicts that the IPOs with excess demand will experience positive average initial returns,
while those with excess supply will experience negative initial returns. Furthermore, the
number of successful IPOs with excess demand should exceed the number of successful
IPOs without excess demand. One good proxy for excess demand is the level of
oversubscription. Another good proxy is the volume of trade in the immediate after-
market. The larger the excess demand, the lower the b, the larger the total shares bought
and sold in the immediate after-market. Figure 7 gives an illustration of this process.
H1: IPOs with excess demand have positive average initial return.
H2: The number of IPOs with excess demand is greater than the number of IPOs with
excess supply.
Next, based on the empirical evidence, during hot issue periods the average initial return
of IPOs is relatively higher than the average initial return during other periods. Following
the reasoning of my model, the relatively higher return must be caused by, (1) larger than
average excess demand, and/or (2) higher than average uncertainty/variability in investors'
valuations.
H3: Hot issue periods are characterized by above average excess demand, and/or above
average uncertainty in investors' valuations on the IPO shares.
H4: Fraction of withdrawn IPOs is smaller (larger) during the hot (cold) issue periods.
It is well documented that best efforts IPOs have higher average initial return compared
with the firm commitment IPOs (Ritter [1987]). Therefore, my model predicts that on
32
average, (successful) best efforts IPOs are characterized with higher excess demand in the
initial market, and/or higher uncertainty/variability in investors' valuations.
H5: Best efforts (firm commitment) IPOs are characterized with higher (lower) excess
demand, and/or higher (lower) uncertainty in investors' valuations.
Corollary 1.2 establishes that because the immediate after-market equilibrium price is on
average higher than the full information value, and market price will converge to the full
information value, in the long run IPO shares on average underperform the benchmark
(market) portfolio. In relation to H1, H3, and H5, the following hypotheses are suggested.
H6: IPOs with excess demand have more negative long-term abnormal performance
H7: IPOs during hot (cold) issue periods have more (less) negative long-term abnormal
performance
H8: Best efforts (firm commitment) IPOs have worse (better) long-term abnormal
performance.
For comparison, other IPO models are categorized into three groups: (1) Price support,
(2) underpricing, and (3) overreaction. For a brief review of these models see section II.2.
General features of the models are summarized in figure 10.
1. Vs Price support/stabilization.
Among the existing explanations of IPO anomalies, the price support explanation is
relatively the most appealing one. It is relatively simple, and does not assume underpricing
and also does not assume individual irrationality.
Comparing my model and price support explanation, there are neat ways to test them.
(1) My model predict that in the long run, the positive initial return will on average be
erased in the after-market. The price support hypothesis predicts that IPOs that experience
positive initial return will not underperform the market, while IPOs with zero initial return
will on average underperform the market.
(2) Excluding IPO with zero return, my model predict a negative relation between the
initial return and the long-term performance, while the price support predict no relation
between initial return and long-term performance.
(3) My model implies a positive relation between excess demand and initial return, and a
negative relation between excess demand and long-term performance. Price support does
not predict any relation between excess demand, initial return and long-term performance.
33
2. Vs underpricing-based models
My model predicts that in the long run, the IPO shares will underperform the shares of
seasoned firms from similar risk category. The underpricing-based explanations are silent
about the long-term abnormal performance of the IPO shares.
3. Vs overreaction
Among the three alternative models, overreaction model generates the most similar
predictions as my model. Both are based on hypotheses that the underwriters price the
IPO correctly and the immediate after-market price is on average higher than the full
information value. However, the mainstream overreaction model uses psychological
and/or behavioral arguments to get the results. My model put some economic
reasons/structures to generate the results.
The overreaction model says nothing about the role of the truncated excess supply caused
by the possibility to withdraw IPOs with very weak demand. This truncation/withdrawal
phenomenon is a crucial integral part of my model. Based on this argument, (1) the
overreaction model states that the unconditional distribution of investors' valuations in the
immediate after-market has a mean that is greater than µ0, and (2) my model states that
the unconditional distribution of investors' valuations in the immediate after-market has a
mean that is equal to µ0, it is the (observed) conditional distribution (after adjusting for the
truncated excess supply) that has a mean that is greater than µ0. Unfortunately, this direct
comparison is impossible. However, the existence of (a relatively many) withdrawn IPOs
can be regarded as a weak/indirect evidence in favor of my model as opposed to the
mainstream overreaction model. The existence of withdrawn IPOs lends support to the
argument that it is the conditional distribution (as opposed to the unconditional
distribution) of investors valuations that has a mean greater than µ0.
1. For issuers
The fact that a firm's shares experience high initial return in the immediate after-market
does not necessarily mean that the firm did not get a fair price. The price set in the initial
market is more likely reflecting the market-perceived true value per share than the excess
34
demand induced price in the immediate after-market.
2. For underwriters
On average underwriters have been doing a good job in pricing IPOs. To prevent
disappointment/regret by the issuers that may occur after seeing price jump in the after-
market, underwriters need to educate issuers that the excess demand induced prices in the
immediate after-market on average do not reflect the market-perceived true value per
share.
When the issuers can wait and the market is weak, it may be beneficial to advise the
issuers to wait for a window of opportunity. It will reduce the probability of failure,
increase the expected profit (by increasing the probability of success), and increase the
underwriter reputation of being a high success rate IPO underwriter.
3. For investors
In valuing firms' shares, investors on average should put more weight on the price
proposed by the underwriters. Long-term buy and hold strategy applied on buying IPO
shares in the after-market just for the consideration of risk and return alone on average
will be a bad strategy. Unless there is other reason, long-term investors should avoid that
strategy.
4. For regulators
More disclosure of information about firms going public is on average beneficial because it
will reduce the level of the heterogeneity of information facing investors. This in turn will
reduce the average initial return. It will reduce the perceived 'money left on the table'.
Issuers will be less regretful, which is good news for underwriters. It is also a good service
for the IPO buyers. On average, it will reduce their underperformance while they still can
satisfy their needs for completion of their portfolio.
35
information (gather information about the value of the firm's shares). The model is silent
about the choice of producing information vs buying information, and/or allocation of
wealth to get information (produce and buy) vs to invest in securities.
My model abstracts out from the choice between IPO/equity financing and other
alternative financing sources. Self selection, censoring and truncation phenomena may play
some roles in this choice. This choice can potentially have interesting implications.
The issue to be addressed is to look for some economic differences between IPO and
seasoned offering (SO) because SO has some similar procedures as IPO but the stock
price behavior substantially differs. IPOs have an average positive initial returns/price
jump, while SOs have a small negative average abnormal return (about -3%)22
surrounding the announcement.
22 See Table 6-1 in Masulis, R., 1988, The Debt/Equity Choice, Ballinger Publishing Co., Massachusetts, p. 58.
36
are 2 opposing forces: (1) old price as an upper bound, and excess supply which lead to
price reduction (2) 'excess demand' that may lead to price increase from the offering price.
Due to the existence of the implicit upper bound, the net result will be negative abnormal
return. Of course other explanations (agency, information, etc.) can be added to explain
the negative reaction. The point here is: There are substantial differences between IPO and
SO.
Equity carve-out represents the initial public sale of equity in a wholly owned subsidiary of
a parent firm. Spin-off occurs when a parent company distributes its entire holdings of
stock in a subsidiary to the parent's stockholders. Equity carve-out and spin-off cause a
parent company and its subsidiary to be valued separately. Empirical research documented
small positive announcement return on the parent company's stock (about 2% for carve-
outs and 3% for spin-off).23
Using similar reasoning, Prob(N investors collect favorable information for parent AND N
investors receive favorable information for subsidiary) > Prob(N investors receive
favorable info for both parent and subsidiary at the same time). Therefore, if it is possible
for investors to value the parent company separately, there is a higher probability that
more investors collect favorable information and bid the price up. Other things being
equal, heterogeneous information theory predicts that equity carve-outs, spin-offs,
divestitures are good news for parent company's shares.
Extending this reasoning to breaking up conglomerate companies, the model predict that
other things being equal, the break up value of conglomerates is on average greater than
the value of the conglomerates. This empirical evidence was documented by LeBaron and
Speidell.24
3. Merger/acquisition
23 Ibid, p.74
24 In Bhagat, S., A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, 1990, Hostile Takeovers in the 1980s: The Return to Corporate Specialization', Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, p 9.
37
(return to the acquirers' shareholders is negative, especially for period after 1968 and
when there is competition among several bidders25 , also the post merger performance of
the acquiring firms suffer a statistically significant loss of about 10% over the 5-year post
merger period.26 This phenomenon is in line with the heterogenous valuation model. The
acquirer is the investor who has the highest valuation and happen to control large amount
of money to buy all or most of the acquired company's shares. Other things being equal,
the bidders pay a price higher than the full information value. Roll's Hubris Hypothesis27 is
one varian along this line of thinking.
25 Bradley, M., A. Desai, and E. H. Kim, 1988, 'Synergistic gains from Corporate Acquisitions and their division between shareholder of
target and acquiring firms', Journal of Financial Economics, 3-40.
26 Agrawal, A., J. Jaffe, and G. Mandelker, 1992,'The Post-Merger Performance of Acquiring Firms: A Re-examination of an Anomaly',
The Journal of Finance, 1605-1621.
27 R. Roll, 1986,'The Hubris Hypothesis of Corporate Takeovers', Journal of Business, 197-215.
38
IV. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
There are three important IPO anomalies: the positive average initial return (improperly
called short-term 'underpricing'), the long-term underperformance, and the cycle of
hot/cold issue markets.
The main driving forces of my model are the heterogeneous information (that leads to
differences in valuations among rational investors), average excess demand, and the fact
that underwriters are long-term participants in the IPO market. The average excess
demand is generated because we only observe a truncated distribution of the difference
between supply and demand. The truncation is caused by the possibility to withdraw the
IPOs when demand is very disappointing.
Using the relation between the thickness of the tail of the demand distribution and the
initial return, my model can also explain the existence of the hot/cold issue markets
anomaly and partial adjustment phenomenon. The model also predicts that the
involvement of (informed) institutional investors will reduce the level of initial return.
39
H8: Best efforts (firm commitment) IPOs have worse (better) long-term abnormal
performance.
Comparative tests to differentiate my model and the other explanations are also described.
For comparison with the price support and underpricing based explanations, the
comparative tests are based on the relation between initial return and long-term
performance of the stocks. For comparison with the overreaction model, the test is based
on conditional vs. unconditional distribution of valuations.
Extensive information disclosure about firms going public is beneficial to all parties
involved. Long-term investors should not buy (and hold) IPO shares in the after-market
just for the consideration of risk and return alone.
As the logical next steps, I plan to do empirical studies to test the implications.
Furthermore, the logic behind the model -truncation and heterogeneous information- can
be very useful for analyzing many other phenomena in other research areas.
40
APPENDIX 1. IPO PROCEDURES
STEP 4. Filing the registration statement with the regulators: SEC, NASD, States ('Blue-
sky' laws)
STEP 5.
a. Selling efforts are allowed to be carried out: Forming underwriter syndication,
distributing the 'red herring' prospectus, publishing 'tombstone' ads, conducting 'road
show', receiving indications of interest.
b. Waiting period: SEC, NASD, States review the filed documents
STEP 7. Final pricing meeting to agree upon the offer price, compensation terms.
STEP 8. Filing the pricing amendment. Start collecting oral commitments of sales on
effective date.
STEP 9. If the regulatory bodies have objections to the final pricing amendment, then all
confirmed sales is cancelled. Post-effective amendment is filed. Go back to step 5 b.
STEP 11. Closing. Firm receives funds from the underwriter according to the final
underwriting agreement.
General Comments
The underwriting agreement does not become effective/binding until it is signed after step
7. In the meantime, the relation between the firm and the underwriter is guided by the
letter of intent. In this firm commitment offers, the underwriter effectively does not
guarantee anything until the final prospectus is issued.
41
In a best efforts offer, offer price, minimum/maximum number of shares to be sold are
agreed upon. After the SEC approves the offering, the underwriter circulates the
prospectus and try its best efforts to sell the shares to investors. The indications of interest
are collected during this period by depositing investors' money in an escrow account. The
offer will be withdrawn if until a specified period of time the total number of shares sold
has not reached the minimum required. The money in the escrow account will be refunded
to the investors.
Week Activity
1 Information exchange meeting
:
: Negotiations of terms of contracts, signing letter of intent
:
6 Draft of Registration Statement
7 Revision of the draft
8 Final draft agreed
9 File Registration Statement with the regulatory bodies
: Circulation of 'red herring' prospectus,
: road show, 'tombstone' ads,
: collecting indications of interest,
: registration statement is being reviewed by the regulatory bodies
13 Receive Comment Letters from SEC
14 Final revisions, pricings
Oral sales
Effective date,
distribution of final prospectus, confirmed oral sales
15 Closing, firm receives funds
Arkebauer, J. B., and R. Schultz, (1991), Cashing Out: The Entrepreneur's Guide to
Going Public, Harper Business, USA.
Riley, J. E, and L. H. Simons, III, (1994), How to Prepare an IPO, Practising Law
Institute, New York.
42
APPENDIX 2. EXAMPLE OF BAYESIAN UPDATING
∑ni=0(xi-θ)2 ]
1
exp[- 2
2σ
= (Let x0 = µ)
2σ2∑i=0 i
⌠~ exp[- 1 n (x -θ)2 ]
dθ
⌡-~
∑ni=0xi + ∑ni=0xi2}]
1
exp[- 2 {(n+1) θ2 - 2θ
2σ
=
⌡-~ 2σ2 ∑i=0 i ∑ni=0xi2}]
⌠~ exp[- 1 {(n+1) θ2 - 2θ n x +
dθ
∑
1
and dividing both by exp[- n xi2 ]
2σ2 i=0
n+1
exp[-( 2) { θ2 - 2θ
2σ ∑ n xi
i=0
∑
n+1 + (
n
i=0
xi
(n+1) )2 }]
∑ (∑
=
⌠~ n+1 n xi n xi
exp[-( 2) { θ2 - 2θ n+1 + )2 }] dθ
⌡-~ 2σ i=0 i=0
(n+1)
1
2
2πσ /(n+1)
n+1
exp{-( 2) [θ -
2σ ∑ n
i=0
xi
2
(n+1)] }
∑
= 1 ⌠~ n xi
- n+1
2πσ /(n+1) exp{ (2σ2) [θ -
2
2 (n+1)] } dθ
⌡ -~ i=0
43
=
1
2πσ2/(n+1)
exp{-( 2
1
2σ /(n+1)
) [θ - ∑ n
i=0
xi
2
(n+1) ] } ~ N ( ∑ n
i=0
xi
(n+1)
, σ )
2
(n+1)
µ+n ∑ n xi
_
∑ µ + n Xn
n xi n
i=1
Therefore E(Θ | Xn) = (n+1) = (n+1) = (n+1)
i=0
which is a kind of weighted average of the prior mean and the sample mean.
_
_ µ + n Xn _
If Xn > µ then µ < (n+1) < Xn .
44
REFERENCES
Aggarwal, Reena and Pietra Rivoli. "Fads in the Initial Public Offering Market?" Financial Management
19 (1990), 45-57.
_____, R. Leal and L. Hernandez, "The After-market Performance of Initial Public Offerings in Latin
America". Financial Management 22 (1993), 42-53.
Affleck-Graves, J., S. P. Hegde, R. E. Miller, and F. K. Reilly. "The Effect of the Trading System on the
Underpricing of Initial Public Offerings." Financial Management (1993), 99-108.
Allen, F. and G. Faulhaber. "Signalling by Underpricing in the IPO Market." Journal of Financial
Economics 23 (1989), 303-323.
Baron, D. P. "A Model of the Demand for Investment Banking and Advising and Distribution Service for
New Issues." Journal of Finance 4 (1982), 955-977.
Barry, Christopher R., Chris J. Muscarella, John W. Peavy, and Michael R. Vetsuypens."The Role of
Venture Capital in the Creation of Public Companies: Evidence from going public process."
Journal of Financial Economics 27 (1990), 447-471.
Beatty, R. P. and J. R. Ritter. "Investment Banking, Reputation, and Underpricing of Initial Public
Offerings." Journal of Financial Economics 15 (January/February 1986), 213-32.
Benveniste, Lawrence M. and Paul A. Spindt. "How Investment Bankers Determine the Offer Price and
Allocation of New Issues." Journal of Financial Economics 24 (1989), 343-361.
Booth, J. and R. Smith. "Capital Raising, Underwriting and the Certification Hypothesis." Journal of
Financial Economics 15 (1986), 261-281.
Bower, Nancy L. "Firm Value and the Choice of Offering Method in Initial Public Offerings." Journal of
Finance (1989), 647-662.
Carter, Richard and Steven Manaster. "Initial Public Offerings and Underwriter Reputation." Journal of
Finance 45 (June 1990), 1045-1067.
Dawson, S. M. "Secondary Stock Market Performance of IPOs: Hong Kong, Singapore and Malaysia
1978-1984." Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 14 (1987), 65-76.
Drake, P and M. Vetsuypens. "IPO Underpricing and Insurance against Legal Liability." Financial
Management 22 (1993), 64-73.
Dunbar, Craig. "Withdrawn IPOs, Contract Choice, and the 'Hot Issue' Market of 1980". Working Paper,
University of Pittsburgh (1992).
Finn. F. J. and R. Higham. "The Performance of Unseasoned New Equity Issues-Cum-Stock Exchange
Listings in Australia." Journal of Banking and Finance 12 (1988), 333-351.
Garfinkel, J. "IPO Underpricing, Insider Selling and Subsequent Equity Offerings." Financial
Management 22 (1993), 74-83.
Grinblatt, M. and C. Y. Hwang. "Signalling and the Pricing of New Issues." Journal of Finance 44
(1989), 393-420.
45
Hanley, K. "The Underpricing of Initial Public Offerings and the Partial Adjustment Phenomenon."
Journal of Financial Economics 34 (1993), 231-250.
Hanley, K., A. Kumar and P Seguin. "Price Stabilization in the Market for New Issues." Journal of
Financial Economics 34 (1993), 177-197.
_____, and W. J. Wilhelm. "Evidence on the Strategic Allocation of Initial Public Offerings." Journal of
Financial Economics 37 (1995), 239-257.
Hwang C Y, and N Jayaraman. "Long-term Performance of IPOs and Non-IPOs: Japanese Evidence."
Working Paper (1992), J. M. Katz Graduate School of Business, University of Pittsburgh.
Ibbotson, Roger G. "Price Performance of Common Stock New Issues." Journal of Financial Economics 2
(September 1975), 235-272.
_____ and J. Jaffe. "'Hot Issue' Markets." Journal of Finance 30 (September 1975), 1027-42.
_____, J. Sindelar and J. Ritter."Initial Public Offerings." Journal of Applied Corporate Finance (1993).
Jog, V. M. and A. L. Riding, "Underpricing in Canadian IPOs." Financial Analysts Journal (1987), 48-
55.
Keloharju, M, "Winner's curse, legal liability, and the long-run performance of initial public offerings in
Finland." Journal of Financial Economics 34 (1993), 251-277.
Kim, E. H. and Y. K. Lee. "Issuing stocks in Korea". Pacific Basin Capital Market Research (1990), 243-
253.
Koh, F and T. Walter. "A Direct Test of Rock's Model of the Pricing of Unseasoned Issues." Journal of
Financial Economics 23 (1989), 251-272.
Levis, M. "The Long-run Performance of Initial Public Offerings: The UK experience 1980-88, Financial
Management 22 (1993), 28-41.
Logue, D. "On the Pricing of Unseasoned Equity Issues, 1965-69." Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 8 (January 1973), 91-103.
Loughran, T and J. R. Ritter, "The Timing and Subsequent Performance of IPOs: Implications for the cost
of equity capital." Unpublished University of Illinois working paper.
Loughran, T, J. R. Ritter and K. Rydqvyst. "Initial Public Offerings: International Insights." Pacific-Basin
Finance Journal 2 (1994), 165-199.
Makhija, A., Bhandari, A., Grammatikos, T., and Papaioannou, G. "Risk and Return on Newly Listed
Stocks." Journal of Financial Research 12 (1989), 90-102.
46
McDonald, J. and A. K. Fisher. "New Issue Stock Price Behavior." Journal of Finance 27 (March 1972),
97-102.
McGuiness, Paul. "An Examination of the Underpricing of Initial Public Offering in Hongkong : 1980--
90." Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 19 (January 1992), 165-186.
Megginson, William L. and Kathleen A. Weiss. "Venture Capitalist Certification in IPOs." Journal of
Finance 46 (July 1991), 879-903.
Miller, R. and F. Reily. "An Examination of Mispricing, returns, and uncertainty for Initial Public
Offerings." Financial Management 16 (1987), 33-38.
Muscarella, Chris J. and Michael Vetsuypens."A Simple Test of Baron's Model of IPO Underpricing."
Journal of Financial Economics 24 (1989), 125-135.
______ and _____. "The Underpricing of 'Second' Initial Public Offerings." Journal of Financial
Research 12 (1989), 183-192.
Ritter, Jay R. "The Long-Run Performance of Initial Public Offerings." Journal of Finance 46 (March
1991), 3-27.
______. "The Cost of Going Public." Journal of Financial Economics 19 (1987), 269-281.
______. "The 'Hot Issue' Market of the 80s." Journal of Business 57 (April 1984), 215-40.
Rock, K. "Why New Issues are Underpriced." Journal of Financial Economics 15 (January/February
1986), 187-212.
Ruud, J. "Underwriter Price Support and the IPO Underpricing Puzzle." Journal of Financial Economics
34 (1993), 135-151.
Saunders, Anthony. The Underpricing of Initial Public Offerings (IPOs) in Singapore: Public Policy
Issues and Possible solutions. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, 1989.
______ and Joseph Lim. "Underpricing and the New Issue Process in Singapore." Journal of Banking and
Finance 14 (August 1990), 291-309.
_____ & _____. "SESDAQ: The Early Evidence." in S. G. Rhee & R. P. Chang (ed.), Pacific Basin
Capital Market Research (1990), 137-154.
Slovin, M. B. and John E. Young. "Bank Lending and Initial Public Offering." Journal of Banking and
Finance 14 (October 1990), 729-740.
Smith. C. W. "Investment Banking and the Capital Acquisition Process." Journal of Financial Economics
15 (1986), 3-29.
Stern, R. L. and P. Bornstein. "Why New Issues are Lousy Investments." Forbes 136 (December 2, 1985),
152-90.
Sum, Lam Swee. "Underpricing of IPOs in Singapore." Asia Pacific Journal of Management 8 (October
1991), 175-184.
Tinic, Seha M. "Anatomy of Initial Public Offerings of Common Stock." Journal of Finance 43
(September 1988) 789-822.
47
Titman, S. and B. Trueman."Information Quality and the Valuation of New Issues." Journal of
Accounting and Economics 8 (1986), 159-172.
Uhlir, H. "Going Public in the F.R.G," in A Reappraisal of the Efficiency of Financial Markets, R.
Guimaraes, et al (eds), 1989, Berlin, Springer-Verlag.
Welch, Ivo. "Seasoned Offerings, Imitation Costs and the Underpricing of Initial Public Offerings."
Journal of Finance 44 (June 1989), 421-449.
Wessels, R. E. "The Market for Initial Public Offerings: An Analysis of the Amsterdam Stock Exchange,"
in A Reappraisal of the Efficiency of Financial Markets, R. Guimaraes, et al (eds), 1989, Berlin,
Springer-Verlag.
48
IPO: Price support vs Heterogeneous Information
Price support implies:
(1) IF zero initial return THEN long-term underperformance
IF positive initial return THEN no long-term underperformance
(2) No relation between excess demand and initial return and underperformance
(2) Excess demand --> positive initial return --> long-term underperformance
no excess demand --> insignificant initial return --> no long-term underperformance
- Model the effect of P/E limitation on the price behavior of the IPO stocks (P/E limitation
was introduced to Jakarta Stock Exchange and later the restriction was softened)
- Model the effect of limitation in foreign investors' holding on the price behavior of the
stocks.
- Herd behavior, heterogeneous information and IPO initial returns.
Empirical research:
- Check the average holding period in relation to the after market price decline. when
optimistic investors start to sell, price decline because they cannot find buyers at current
price. Recall strong hand phenomenon discussed by Aggarwal and Rivoli (1990).
- Study management turnover after IPO, introduction of option as a part of managerial
compensation, vs long-term performance of IPO
- Modelling effect of P/E limitation on the underpricing
- Tangible vs intangible asset and underpricing. (Implication of my model: more tangible,
less uncertainty, lower initial return).
- Study the behavior of IPO stock prices in the Jakarta Stock Exchange.
In addition to developing a new model, I also plan to use a new data set -the Indonesian
stock market data- to investigate the short-term underpricing, long-term
underperformance, the cycle of the hot and cold issued period, and the effect of foreign
ownership and P/E limitation. Moreover, I plan to investigate the use of IPO as a mean to
privatize state-owned enterprises.
- To some extent, selling stock is like selling dollar bill whose value changes over time (the
point is, there is intrinsic market-perceived true value, but it can change over time).
Market price based on S/D under less than perfect market conditions is not always in line
with the market-perceived true value. However, over time it will converge to the market-
perceived true value.
Useful findings:
- - Kim, Krinsky and Lee (JBFA 93), using 177 IPO listed on the Korean Stock Exchange
1988-1990, avrg IR is substantially higher when entrepreneur view the equity financing as
49
a last resort for raising funds (68.9%) than it is when existing shareholders intend to
diversify their portfolio holding (40.22%)
- Affleck-Graves, Hegde, Miller, Reilly (FM 93) using data 1983-87: Avg UP NYSE and
AMEX (auction mkt) is 4.82% and 2.16% , Nasdaq NMS and non National Market
System (negotiated dealer market) 5.56% and 10.41%. For long-term performance of
NASDAQ and NYSE IPO see Loughran (JFE 93)
- Alternative measurement of IR from the point of view of issuer and investors, see
McGuiness (Omega, May 1993)
- Jang & Lin (JAPubl Pol 1993), Trading volume on the first trading days was significantly
larger for Big 8 9accounting firm) clients than for non-Big 8 ones;no clear difference for
several subsequent days; a reverse relationship emerged from day 6 to 30 in which the
daily volume was smaller for Big 8 client than for non big 8 firms. The hypothesis
is:trading volume reaction to a release of more reliable information is initially stronger but
less persistent
- Opening price of IPO and closing price to study intraday behavior (whether all initial
return is captured only by the initial purchaser, see for example Barry and Jennings (FM
93))
- Pricing of auditor fee, Beatty JAR 1993:
* IPO clients are more likely to exhibit financial distress than establish client
* IPO auditor compensation is related to the traditional audit fee model variables.
Auditors charge a conditionally higher fee for client that subsequently filed for bankruptcy,
were delisted or were the subject to a shareholder lawsuit.
- For reverse LBO 1983-88, Mian and Rosenfeld (FM 93) documented that there was no
long-term underperformance.
`1234567890-=
~!@#$$%^&*()_+
qwertyuiop[]
QWERTYUIOP{}|
asdfghjkl;'
ASDFGHJKL:"
zxcvbnm,./
ZXCVBNM<>?
50
1234567890−=
∼!≅#∃∃%⊥&∗()_+
θωερτψυιοπ[]
ΘΩΕΡΤΨΥΙΟΠ{}|
ασδφγηϕκλ;∋
ΑΣ∆ΦΓΗϑΚΛ:∀
ζξχϖβνµ,./
ΖΞΧςΒΝΜ<>?
51