Bureaucratic Corruption in Africa The Futility of
Bureaucratic Corruption in Africa The Futility of
Bureaucratic Corruption in Africa The Futility of
net/publication/42763950
CITATIONS READS
122 726
1 author:
SEE PROFILE
All content following this page was uploaded by John Mukum Mbaku on 13 November 2014.
Cato Journal, vol. 16, No. 1 (Spring/Summer 1996), Copyright C Gate Institute. All
tights reserved.
John Mukum Mbaku is Professor of Economics at Weber State University and President
of the African Educational Foundation, Inc. I-Ic thanks Ian Vasquez for helpful comments
on an earlier version of the article. Financial support from the Willard L. Eceles Foundation
is gratefully acknowledged.
99
CATO JOURNAL
bureaucrats discover they can earn more income from providing ser-
vices to groups seeking state favors than from their regular (public)
jobs, they may pay more attention to the demands of such interest
groups than to the proper enforcement of state laws and regulations
and the effective implementation of national development plans. In
societies where civil service compensation levels are relatively bow, a
significant part of the public employee’s total compensation may be
derived from engagement in outside activities, resulting in a significant
increase in bureaucratic corruption (Mbaku 1991a).
The rules that regulate socio-politicab relations in a country have a
significant impact on the ability of civil servants to seek and secure
(either legally or illegally) outside income. In nondemocratic societies,
as has been shown by Mwangi Kimenyi (1987), bureaucrats are less
constrained in their employment of public resources to bobby legisla-
tors and influence those individuals with direct responsibility fordeter-
mining bevels of compensation for the public sector. In fact, in many
African countries, most civil servants are members of the politically
dominant group and have significant influence over the allocation of
resources. Under these conditions, civil servants behave like interest
groups whose primary objective is to put pressure on the political
system in an effort to redistribute wealth to themselves.
In countries with poorly constructed, inefficient, and non self-
enforcing constitutional rules, opportunistic behaviors (including rent
seeking) are usually quite pervasive. In such countries, the rules that
regulate socio-political interaction have failed to adequately constrain
the government. As a result, state intervention in private exchange is
equally pervasive. Excessive regulation of economic activities creates
many opportunities for rent seeking, including bureaucratic
corruption.
Corruption has been an important subject of analysis by social
scientists for many years. In the 1960s, however, two major events
rekindled interest in the study of corruption, especially in developing
countries. First, the development by Samuel Huntington (1968, 1990)
and others of theories of modernization and political development
renewed discussions on bureaucratic corruption and the role of laws
and institutions in economic growth and development (Leff 1964,
Huntington 1990, Myrdal 1990). Second, the economies and markets
of the newly independent countries of Africa and Asia were over-
whelmed by corruption, bureaucratic inefficiency, and incompetence.
Since the early 1960s, researchers have devoted significant effort to the
examination of bureaucratic corruption in the developing economies,
paying much attention to the effects of the behavior of civib servants
on economic growth and development (Heidenheimer, Johnston, and
100
BUREAUGRATIG CORRUPTION IN AFRIGA
101
CATO JOURNAL
102
BUREAUGRATIG CORRUPTION IN AFRICA
103
CAm JOURNAL
104
BUREAUCRATIC CORRUPTION IN AFRICA
105
CATO JOURNAL
106
BUREAUCRATIC CORRUPTION IN AFRICA
107
CATO JOURNAL
108
BUREAUCRATIC CORRUPTION IN AFRICA
109
CATO JOURNAL.
viduabs can interact with each other, provide a means for the settlement
of conflict, and generally place constraints on individual behavior, as
well as that of the groupand collectivity (Brennan and Buchanan 1985).
Effective rules allow individuals to pursue their private ends in
such a way that they do not infringe on the ability of others to do the
same. The rules that regulate socio-political interaction can be explicit
(e.g., a written constitution) or based on custom and tradition. Given
an existing set of rules, corruption can be viewed as opportunistic
behavior on the part of individuals or groups. In this vein, corruption
can be seen as a problem of constitutional maintenance that can be
handled appropriately only through rules reform.
In an effort to explain the relevance of rules, Brennan and Buchanan
(1985: 13) return to the “tragedy of the commons,” an illustration
that is used quite often in economics. If, for example, the rules of a
society require that agricultural land be owned communally, and farm-
ers are assumed to be utility maximizers in the traditional sense, then
overgrazing will be the outcome. The overgrazing is not a result of
market failure, as is often assumed, but a problem associated with
the nature of the rules that regulate socio-political relationships in
this society, including the behavior of farmers. In other words, given
the existing rules, utility maximization will bead to overgrazing. As is
the case in many African societies, policing is usually the method
employed to minimize the problem of overgrazing. Unfortunately, in
the absence of privatization and appropriate institutions to protect
and enforce property rights, efforts to force certain outcomes within
the existing set of rules are rarely successful.
Present cleanup programs in Africa suffer from several problems.
First, they are being carried out within inefficient and nonviable rules.
Second, corruption cleanup ipvobves efforts to manipulate outcomes
within existing rules through policing. Third, the counteracting agen-
cies charged with policing and enforcement of the laws and the bureau-
crats who work in those agencies are not properly constrained by the
laws. Finally, many bureaucrats are themselves corrupt and cannot
be counted on to provide the leadership needed to run effective
cleanup programs. Thus, effective corruption cleanup needs to begin
with rules reform to make certain that the outcomes generated within
the rules are those desired by society.
Efforts to clean up corruption would be futile if the rules that
regulate socio-pobitical relations provide an incentive system that
makes opportunism highly lucrative. If, as a result of the adopted
rules, rent-seeking activities, as opposed to genuine entrepreneurship,
are highly rewarding, entrepreneurs are likely to devote most of their
time and effort to rent seeking. In such a case, using the police force
110
BUREAUCRATIC CoRRUPTIoN IN AFRICA
111
CATO JOURNAL
112
BUREAUCRATIC CORRUPTION IN AFRICA
‘See, for example, Cowen (1961) for a discussion of how the majority black population was
excluded from the development of the first constitution of the Urnon of South Africa. For
a discussion of the first constitution of’ thc Republic of Camomon ~the former Fmnch
Cameroons), see Levine (1964). Note that in addition to the Pact that the Republic of
Cameroon’s first constitution was practically a copy of tile constitution of the French Fifth
Republic, the UPC party, the largest indigenous political party iu the colony, was ehminated
from participation in the design of constitutional rules.
113
CATO JOURNAI~
people. Many Africans today live under rules that were not unani-
mousby agreed upon by the relevant population groups within each
country or by their representatives. To ensure that the outcome is an
efficient set of rules, agreement must be unanimous and must be
achieved voluntarily.
Since post-independence attempts at rube reform have failed to
produce more efficient constitutions, the last several years have wit-
nessed a tremendous increase in bevels of bureaucratic corruption
in Africa.
Conclusion
The purpose of this paper was to reexamine corruption cleanup
strategies in Africa and seek to show why they have been ineffective.
African countries, like many developing countries, have tried several
strategies in an effort to minimize bevels of bureaucratic corruption.
These include societal, legal, market, and political strategies. All those
approaches to corruption cleanup represent the manipulation of out-
comes within a given set of rules and presuppose the existence of
efficient counteracting institutions. The evidence shows, however,
that most judiciary systems and police forces in the African
countries are not properly constrained by the law and that most civil
servants (includingjudges and police officers) are themselves corrupt.
As a result, most cleanup programs in Africa have been unsuc-
cessful.
Bureaucratic corruption is an outcome generated within a given
set of rules. An effective normative evaluation of such an outcome
can only be undertaken after a thorough understanding of the rules
that generate the outcome. Thus, to understand why people engage
in corruption requires an examination of the rules that regulate the
socio-political behavior of individuals. Since these rules determine
how individuals behave and relate to each other, they also determine
the outcomes to be generated in the post-contractual society. Thus,
effective corruption cleanup should not involve efforts to manipulate
outcomes within rules. Instead, an effective approach should involve
reform of existing rules and the subsequent selection and adoption
of new rules that can generate the outcomes desired by society. Since
the rules determine the incentive system that will prevail in the post-
contractual society, society can effectively impose the outcomes it
wants through rules design. For example, the problem of overgrazing
of agricultural lands can be minimized by establishing private property
rights in land during rules selection. Usually, the establishment of
political rules and a political order precede the establishment of an
114
BUREAUCRATIC ConRurnoN IN AFRICA
115
CATO JOURNAL
References
Agbese, P.O. (1992) “With Fingers on the Trigger: The Militaw as Custodian
of Democracy in Nigeria.” Journal of Third World Studies 9(2): 220—53.
Alam, M.S. (1989) “Anatomy of Corruption: An Approach to the Political
Economy of Underdevelopment.” American Journal of Economics and
Sociology 48(4): 441—56.
Mi, S. (1985) Corruption: A Third World Perspective. Lahore, Pakistan:
Aziz Publishers.
Anderson, T.L., and Hill, P.J. (1986) “Constraining the Transfer Society:
Constitutional and Moral Dimensions.” Cato Journal 6(1): 317—39.
Apter, D.E. (1963) Ghana in Transition. New York: Antheneum.
Aranson, P.11. (1988) “Procedural and Substantive Constitutional Protection
of Economic Liberties.” In Gwartney and Wagner (1988: 285—313).
Bayley, D.H, (1966) “The Effects of Corruption in a Developing Nation.”
The Western Political Science Quarterly 19(4): 719—32.
Becker, CS. (1994) “To Root Out Corruption, Boot Out Big Government.”
Business Week, 31 anuary: 18.
Brennan, 0., and Buc anan, J.M, (1985) The Reason ofRules: Constitutional
Political Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Buchanan, J.M., and Faith, R.L, (1987) “Secession and the Limits of Taxation:
Toward aTheoiy of Internal Exit.” American Economic Review 77 (Decem-
ber): 1023—31.
Couch, J.F.; Atkinson, K.E,; and Shughart, W.F. (1992) “Ethics Laws and
the Outside Earnings of Politicians: The Case of Alabama’s ‘Legislator-
Educators’” Public Choice 73(2): 135—45.
Cowen, DV. (1961) The Foundations of Freedom: With Special Reference
to Southern Africa. Cape Town: Oxford University Press.
Crowder, M. (1987) ‘Whose Dream Was Jt Anyway? Twenty-Five Years of
African Independence.” African Affairs 86(342): 7—24.
Dobel, J.P. (1978) “The Corruption of a State.” American Political Science
Review 72 (September): 958—73.
Doxey, G.V. (1961) The Industrial Colour Bar in South Africa. Cape Town:
Oxford University Press.
Etzioni-Halevy, W. (1979) Political Manlpulatioin and Administrative Power.
London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Fatton, B. Jr. (1990) “Liberal Democracy in Africa.” Political Science Quar-
terly 105(3): 455—73.
Friedrich, C.J. (1990) “Corruption Concepts in Historical Perspective.” In
Heidenheimer et al. (1990: 15—24).
Gillespie, K., and Oknthlik, 0. (1991) ‘The Political Dimensions of Corrup-
lion Cleanups: A Framework for Analysis.” Comparative Politics 24(1):
77—95,
Goodman, M. (1990) “Preserving Privilege in Yucatan.” In Heidenheimer
et al. (1990: 639—58),
Gould, D.J. (1980) Bureaucratic Corruption Underdevelopinent in the Third
World: The Case of Zaire. New York: Pergamon Press.
Could, D.J., and Mukendi, TB. (1989) “Bureaucratic Corruption in Africa:
Causes, Consequences and Remedies.” International Journal of Public
Administration 12(3): 427-57.
116
BUREAUCRATIC C0RRUFrI0N IN AFRICA
Gwartney, J.D., and Wagner, RE., eds. (1988) Public Choice and Constitu-
tional Economics. Greenwich, Conn,: JAI Press.
Harsch, F. (1993) “Accumulators and Democrats: Challenging State Corrup-
lion in Africa” Journal of Modern African Studies 31(1): 31—48.
Huzlett, T.W. (1988) “Economic OriginsofApartheid.” Contemporary Policy
issues 6: 85—104.
Heidenheimer, A.J.; Johnston, M.; and LeVine, VT., eds. (1990) Political
Corruption: A Handbook. New Brunswick, N. J.: Transaction Publishers.
Huntington, S.P. (1968) Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven:
Yale University Press.
Huntington, S.P. (1990). “Modernization and Corruption.” In Heidenheimer
et al. (1990: 375—88).
Hutt, H.W. (1964) The Economics of the Colour Bar. London: Institute of
Economic Affairs.
Ihonvbere, JO., and Ekekwe, F. (1988) “Dependent Capitalism, Structural
Adjustment and Democratic Possibilities in Nigeria’s Third Republic.”
Afrika Spectrum 1(1): 273—92.
Jabbra, J.G. (1976) “Bureaucratic Corruption in the Third World: Causes
and Remedies.” Indian Journal of Public AdmInistration 22: 673—91.
Kimenyi, M.S. (1987) “Bureaucratic Rents and Political Institutions. “Journal
of Public Finance and Public Choice 3: 39—49.
Klaveren, van J. (1990) “The Concept of Corruption.” In Heidenheimer et
al. (1990: 25—28).
Leff, N.H. (1964) “Economic Development through Bureaucratic Corrup-
tion.” American Behavioral Scientist 8(3): 8—14.
LeVine, VT. (1964) The Cameroons: From Mandate to Independence. Stan-
ford, Calif.: Hoover Institution.
Leys, C. (1965) “What is the Problem About Corruption?”Journal ofModern
African Studies 3(2): 215—24,
Lowenberg, AD. (1992) “A Post-Apartheid Constitution for South Africa:
Lessons from Public Choice.” Cato Journal 12(2): 297—319.
Lowenberg, AD., and Yu, B.T. (1992) “Efficient Constitution Formation
and Maintenance: The Role of Exit.” Constitutional Political Economy 3
(Winter): 51—72.
Macrae, J. (1982) “Underdevelopment and the Economics of Corruption: A
Came Theory Approach.” World Development 10 (August): 677—87.
Mbaku, J.M. (1991a) “Militaty Expenditures and Bureaucratic Competition
for Rents.” Public Choice 71(2): 19—31.
Mbaku, J.M. (1991b) “Property Rights and Rent Seeking in South Africa.”
Cato Journal 11(1): 135—50.
Mbaku, f.M. (1992) “Bureaucratic Corruption as Rent-Seeking Behavior.”
KonJunkturpolitik (Germany) 38 (4): 247—65.
Mbaku, J.M. (1993). “Markets and the Economic Origins of Apartheid.”
Indian Journal of Social Science 6(2): 139—58.
Mbaku, f.M. (1994) “Bureaucratic Corruption and Policy Reform in Africa”
Journal of Social, Political and Economic Studies 19(2): 149—75.
MeMullan, M. (1961) “A Theory of Corruption.” Sociological Review
9(2): 181—201.
117
CATO JOURNAL
118